working paper series · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations,...

39
University of Pittsburgh • Dietrich School of Arts and Sciences • Department of Economics 4700 Wesley W. Posvar Hall • 230 South Bouquet Street • Pittsburgh, PA 15260 WORKING PAPER SERIES 20/003 Declining Market Competition in China Daniel Berkowitz and Shuichiro Nishioka April, 2020

Upload: others

Post on 18-Jul-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

University of Pittsburgh • Dietrich School of Arts and Sciences • Department of Economics 4700 Wesley W. Posvar Hall • 230 South Bouquet Street • Pittsburgh, PA 15260

WORKING PAPER SERIES

20/003

Declining Market Competition in China

Daniel Berkowitz and Shuichiro Nishioka

April, 2020

Page 2: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

Declining Market Competition in China

Daniel Berkowitz∗and Shuichiro Nishioka†

April 17, 2020

Abstract

Using methods in Hall and Jorgenson (1967) and Barkai (2020), we find that pure profitshares rose 25.6 percentage points in China during a period when reforms were enacted thatshould have strengthened market competition. Increases in firms’markups accounts for roughlyfive-sixths of the increase of pure profit shares in manufacturing. Firms that raised markupsoperated primarily in industries where state owned enterprises (SOEs) were pervasive, net entryof firms was slow, and there was a strong reallocation of market shares to SOEs and a weakreallocation to competitive firms. While there was an overall decline in market competition,markets became more competitive in industries where SOEs had small market shares.

Keywords: Pure profit shares, labor’s share, capital’s share, markups, state owned enterprises,competitionJEL Classification: E25, O19, O52, P23, P31.

∗Department of Economics, University of Pittsburgh, 4913 WW Posvar Hall Pittsburgh PA 15216, Tel: +1(412)648-7072, Email: [email protected]†John Chambers College of Business and Economics, West Virginia University, 1601 University Avenue Morgan-

town WV 26506-0625, Tel: +1(304) 293-7875, Email: [email protected]

Page 3: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

1 Introduction

Companies in which a national or subnational government holds a majority interest have a strong

presence in emerging market economies including China, Brazil, Russia, Malaysia, India, and In-

donesia.1 These state owned enterprises (SOEs) can improve social welfare when they supply public

goods and services that private firms tend to under provide such as electricity, water supplies, and

financial services. And, because it can be diffi cult for private firms in emerging markets to ob-

tain external finance, SOEs operating in activities that have substantial capital costs, for example,

mineral extraction and road construction, can contribute to economic development.

The presence of SOEs, however, can reduce market competition for several reasons. First,

SOEs that are less productive than private firms may receive concessions from the state including

financial bailouts and soft-budget constraints (Lin and Tan, 1999; Kornai et al, 2003), access to

cheap credit, and barriers to entry against more productive firms (see Song et al, 2011). These state

concessions distort markets because they shift resources and market shares to less productive firms.

And, resource may be misallocated, and markets may become less competitive when the state uses

its SOEs to pursue political objectives such as over-staffi ng and investing in white elephant projects

(Shleifer and Vishny, 1994).

Do SOEs operate as a drag on market competition? In particular, can unproductive SOEs

that depend upon state concessions hold onto or even expand their market shares? Or, do the

forces of competitive selection reallocate market shares from relatively unproductive SOEs to more

productive private firms? China around the turn of the twenty-first century is an ideal setting for

studying this issue for several reasons. First, China was enacting reforms that should have made

markets more competitive: laws were enacted protecting the property rights of private businesses

(Li et al, 2008); measures were taken to reduce internal product and labor mobility costs (Tombes

and Zhu, 2019); and Chinese firms had to compete with more productive foreign firms after China

joined the World Trade Organization (WTO) at the end of 2001. And, there is evidence indicating

that domestic markets became competitive: in studies of manufacturing firms, Brandt et al (2012)

document the massive entry of firms and impressive growth in firm-level productivity; and, Brandt

et al (2017) and Yu and Lu (2015) show that firms’markups fell and became less dispersed following

1https://www.wisdomtree.com/blog/2014-12-04/emerging-markets-and-state-owned-enterprises;https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/governance/the-size-and-sectoral-distribution-of-state-owned-enterprises_9789264280663-en#page16

1

Page 4: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

China’s accession to the WTO.

Second, during this period, China enacted reforms of “grasping the large and letting go of the

small” that should have made the SOEs and domestic markets more competitive (see Hsieh and

Song, 2015). Starting in the mid-1990s, unproductive SOEs that were burdens on local budgets were

privatized and even liquidated. And, larger SOEs were consolidated and, put under less pressure

to fulfill political objectives such as hiring excess labor, and, given more incentives to be more

productive and profitable (Cooper et al, 2015). There is evidence that these reforms made SOEs

and the markets in which they operated more competitive because the total factor productivity of

the large SOEs that survived or newly entered during 1998-2007 was close to private firms (Hsieh

and Song, 2015).

However, there is evidence suggesting there were major distortions in domestic markets asso-

ciated with state interference and SOEs. Hsieh and Klenow (2009, pp.1419-1420) find evidence of

massive resource misallocation in China’s manufacturing sector, suggesting that the state issued

capital subsidies and monopoly protections to select industries. Several studies document that

provincial governments blocked local sales of non-local goods in order to protect their local SOEs

(see Young, 2000; Bai et al, 2004; Bai and Liu, 2017; Barwick et al, 2020). Milhaupt and Zhang

(2015, pp.679-680) suggest that the managers of SOEs had lots of cash for perks and empire build-

ing because the state collected no dividends from SOEs between 1994 and 2007,2 even though SOEs

(in particular those under direct jurisdiction of the central government) were highly profitable (see

Kujis et al, 2005; Berkowitz et al 2017). Li et al (2015, section 2) argue that around the time China

joined the WTO, SOEs began to monopolize upstream industries such as petroleum, natural gas,

and electricity and, with protection of the state, the SOEs were able to maintain market power and

charge high markups to firms in downstream industries.

Figure 1 provides an overview of market competition and illustrates the aggregate pure profit

shares in manufacturing during 1998-2007. A firm’s pure profit share is its value added net of

payments to labor and capital costs divided by value added,3 and the aggregate pure profit share

is the sum of the product of each firm’s pure profit share and its share of value added. Over a

2See Nicholas Borst, “SOE Dividends and Economic Rebalancing,”(Peterson Institute for International Economy,May 11, 2012, http://www.piie.com/blogs/china/?p 1258).

3Except for the cost of capital, all variables required for calculating firm-level pure profit shares are reported infirms’balance sheet data. Later in this section, we describe how we can use Hall and Jorgenson’s (1967) method toimpute capital costs and Barkai’s (2020) method for estimating pure profit shares.

2

Page 5: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

period when aggregate revenues in manufacturing increased almost six-fold, aggregate pure profit

shares increased a massive 25.6 percentage points,4 and this can reflect market competition for two

reasons. First, in the extreme case where all firms are charging higher markups because market

competition weakens, firms enjoy higher pure profit shares, and aggregate pure profit shares increase

through a within-firm effect. Second, in the polar opposite case where firms’markups are stable,

but market shares are reallocated because there is competitive selection on firms that have high

markups, aggregate profit shares increase through a between-firm effect. We provide a model of this

relationship between firm-level markups, competitive selection and aggregate pure profits share in

section 3.2 of the paper.

We find within-firm effects were about five times stronger than the between-firm effects, indi-

cating that markets became less competitive. Firms in the chemical fertilizers versus textile goods

industries provide an overview of our argument. The sales shares of SOEs in the chemical fertiliz-

ers and textile goods industries were ranked 13th (36.1-percent) and 107th (2.3-percent) out of the

136 3-digit CIC industries in 2007, respectively.5 Consistent with the view that the state tends to

protect its SOEs from competition, firms in the chemical fertilizers industry received concessions

from the state including value added tax exemptions, subsidies on capital and intermediate goods,

increases in tariff rates on imported final goods,6 preferential loans, and debt forgiveness.7 And,

there was much less state intervention in textile goods. For example, prior to 1992, firms were

heavily regulated and required to obtain permits for business commissions, expansions and distri-

bution from the Department of Textile Industry (DTI). However, the DTI lost all of the authority

by 2002 (Shen, 2008).

Figures 2 and 3 contain several proxies for market competition. As markets become more

competitive, firm entry barriers fall, and there tends to be more net entry. Consistent with the

view that competition should be stiffer in textiles, Panel A shows that net entry of firms grew by 97-

4 In order to get a sense of the enormity of this trend, note that Barkai (2020) argues the 13.5 percentage pointsincrease in pure profits shares that he calculates in the corporate non-financial sector in the United States over athirty year period (1984-2014) is very large.

5The Chinese Industry Classification (CIC) system is similar to the International Standard Industrial Classification(ISIC) system. The classification of whether or not a firm is state owned enterprise (SOE) follows the definition inHsieh and Song (2015, pp.301-302).

6The simple average of applied tariff rates across 4-digit sub-industries within the chemical fertilizers industryincreased from 5.1-percent in 1998 to 11.1-percent in 2007. China used import tariff rate quotas to protect domesticproducers.

7See the U.S. Trade Representative (USTR) NTE China, 2013, pp.5-9 and “An Assessment of China’s Subsidiesto Strategic and Heavyweight Industries,” which was submitted to the U.S.-China Economic and Security ReviewCommission by Capital Trade Incorporated.

3

Page 6: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

percent (from 1,466 to 3,869 firms) in textiles but only by 18.2-percent (from 1,640 to 1,967 firms) in

chemical fertilizers.8 As markets become more competitive, most firms tend to have smaller market

shares, implying there is less market concentration. Panel B illustrates the Hirshman-Herfindahl

index (HHI), where concentration falls as the HHI goes from one to zero. While textiles and chemical

fertilizers initially have a similar HHI index, chemical fertilizers become more concentrated over

the period.

Figure 3 illustrates trends in average and aggregate pure profit shares for survivor firms, where

the latter is the sum of each firm’s pure profit shares weighted by value added shares. Following

China’s accession to the WTO, nominal revenues in the manufacturing sector increased roughly

six-fold.9 Thus, a firm that had market power was in a good position to withhold output and

increase its pure profits. Panel A shows that the aggregate pure profit share was only slightly

larger and grew only slightly faster than the average pure profit share in chemical fertilizers. Thus,

the aggregate pure profit share grew primarily through a within-firm effect, suggesting that firms

gained market power. In contrast, Panel B shows that the average pure profit share in textile goods

barely changed, whereas the aggregate pure profit share increased, most notably after 2005 when

the United States, the European Union, and Canada eliminated quotas that they had imposed for

decades on China’s textiles and clothing (see Khandelwal et al, 2013, p.2174-75). Figure 3 Panel

B is consistent with Khandelwal et al (2013) who find that the elimination of the quotas enabled

more effi cient firms to capture larger shares of the export market. And, the aggregate pure profit

share increased through a between-firm effect.

In order to compute pure profit shares at the firm level, we adapt Barkai’s (2020) industry

level approach to firms and subtract each firm’s labor and capital shares of value added from one.

And, to compute capital shares, we use Hall and Jorgenson’s (1967) ex-ante approach to impute

capital costs from the opportunity costs of holding capital assets. While firm-level capital assets

cannot be divided into distinct categories such as buildings versus equipment, we can construct

firm-specific required rates of return on capital service using detailed firm-level data on debts and

assets. Intuitively, a firm that relies heavily on financial institutions to acquire capital goods has

a higher required return. However, a firm that finances its investments primarily from retained

8Total industry-level nominal sales grew 5.5-fold in textiles and 4-fold in chemical fertilizers.9The six-fold nominal increase is close to the real growth because inflation during 1998-2007 was about 12.1-percent

over the entire period, or roughly 1.15 percent per year.

4

Page 7: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

earnings has a lower required return. We then calculate capital’s share of value added in each firm

using the constructed series of firm-level required capital returns and values of capital stock.

To determine whether market competition became stronger or weaker, we use a model that

provides a firm-level foundations for aggregate pure profit shares and, highlights the importance of

firms’markups. In the model, when a firm can increase its markups, it also increases its pure profit

shares, leading to an increase in aggregate pure profit share through a within-firm effect. This

prediction is consistent with the argument in De Loecker et al (2020) that a positive association

between increases in firm-markups and aggregate profitability indicates a decline in market compe-

tition.10 And, when markets become more competitive say, because China joined the WTO, then

there is a reallocation of market shares to high markup firms, leading to an increase in aggregate

pure profit shares through a between-firm effect. We find that the within-firm effect dominates: the

8.6 percent point increase in average markups account for roughly five-sixths of the 25.6-percentage

point increase in pure profit shares. And, these within effects were concentrated in industries where

SOEs were pervasive and had several characteristics suggestive of weak competition: net entry of

firms was slow, and there was a strong reallocation of market shares to state owned firms and a

weak reallocation to high markup firms.

Our paper contributes to several literatures. First, our findings that firm-level markups grew

and, in some cases, do not strongly converge during 1998-2007 are different from Brandt et al (2017)

and Lu and Yu (2015) who show that after China’s entry to the WTO firm-level markups declined

and sharply converged. Our results differ because of the timing of the analysis. Brandt et al (2017)

and Lu and Yu (2015) studied how firms immediately adjusted to tariff cuts following China’s

accession to the WTO; and, thus, estimate markups assuming that only intermediates inputs are

variable. This paper studies how firms operate during a ten year period in which there was a robust

reallocation of labor and capital within SOEs that were being privatized and restructured and, labor

markets became flexible (Feng et al, 2017). Thus, we take a longer term macroeconomic view and,

following the approach in De Loecker et al (2020), we allow firm-level production functions to

vary over time when we estimate markups. Our results are robust even if we assume that only

intermediate inputs and labor are flexible inputs, and capital is a fixed input.

10An increase in average firm markups does necessarily indicate markets are not competitive. Notably, De Loeckeret al (2020) argue that firms may increase their markups without earning large profits because they are recoveringlarge operating costs. The model in this paper is based on Azmat et al (2012) and Autor et al (2020) who derive howa firm’s optimal labor share is a function of its markup and other fundamentals.

5

Page 8: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

Our results complement Bai et al (2019) who document how market were not competitive

because the state made special deals with selected firms. Our paper is also related to Piketty et

al (2019) who document the growth of income and wealth inequality in China during 1978-2015,

which contains the period of our study. They show that the privatization of state assets such as

housing is an important driver of this trend; and, we show that the partial privatization of SOEs

set the stage for a pervasive state ownership underlying the rise of profit’s share and the decline in

labor’s and capital share in manufacturing.

The next section describes the data and profit shares in the Chinese manufacturing sector.

Section 3 contains the theory and empirical results; and section 4 concludes.

2 Pure Profit Shares

Capital Costs

To compute pure profit shares at the firm level similar to Barkai’s (2020) application at the industry

level, capital costs must be imputed at the firm level. However, as Syverson (2011) notes “obtaining

capital costs is usually the practical sticking point.” Thus, we follow Hall and Jorgenson (1967)

and estimate the firm-level required rate of return on capital services using the opportunity costs

of holding capital assets. This approach has applied mainly in macroeconomic studies including

Caballero and Lyons (1992), Karabarbounis and Neiman (2018), and Barkai (2020).11

The method is applied to the Chinese firm-level data in the following manner. First, a real

capital stock series is constructed using the perpetual inventory method as described in Brandt et

al (2012). We have the book value of firms’fixed capital stock at the original purchase prices. Since

these book values are the sum of nominal values for different years, they cannot be used directly.

Thus, we use the first difference of nominal value of fixed capital stock (BKit−BKi,t−1) as a proxy

for nominal investment and construct a real capital stock series using the following formula:

Kit = (1− δ)Ki,t−1 + (BKit −BKi,t−1)/Pt (1)

where BKit is the book value of the capital stock for firm i in year t; and Pt is the investment

deflator. To construct the real capital stock series, we then need to know the initial nominal value

11See also Timmer et al (2007) for the explanations for ex-ante versus ex-post approaches.

6

Page 9: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

of the capital stock, which is projected from the perpetual inventory method:

BKi,t0 = BKi,t1/(1 + g)t1−t0

where BKi,t1 is the book value of capital stock when firm i first appears in the data set in year t1,

and g is the average growth rate of capital, calculated using province-industry level capital growth

rate between the earliest available survey (1995) and the first year that the firm is included in the

data set.12 For firms established later than 1998, the initial book value of capital stock is taken

directly from the dataset.

Using information on the age of firm i, we can obtain the projected book value of the capital

stock for the initial year t0 (BKi,t0), which can be thought of the initial nominal value of capital.

In this case, the real capital stock is Ki,t0 = BKi,t0/Pt0 . We could also compute the real capital

stock in each year, assuming an annual depreciation rate as 0.09 and using the perpetual inventory

method as in equation (1). As a robustness check, we also use an alternative depreciation rate of

0.05 used in Hsieh and Klenow (2009) and find that our results are qualitatively similar.

To calculate a firm’s opportunity cost of holding capital assets, we follow Jorgenson and Griliches

(1967) and compute its required rate of return on capital services, rt:

rtKit = PtKit(iS + δ −∆P/P ) (2)

where iS is the country-level risk free interest rate (i.e., we use the saving interest rate, which is

2.5-percent on average over the period), δ is the depreciation rate as discussed above, and ∆P/P

is the rate of appreciation for capital goods (i.e., we use the investment goods deflator, which is

3.3-percent on average over the period). Thus, the opportunity cost, rtKit, equals the interest rate

that could be collected when the capital stock is traded in for a risk free asset, PtKitiS , plus the

avoided net depreciation in assets, PtKit(δ−∆P/P ), which equals the current value of the capital

stock time its depreciation net of appreciation.

To compute the equation above, we would ideally have data on disaggregated capital assets

such as buildings and machines as in Barkai’s (2020) application to the U.S. industry-level data.

12To be more concrete, we use 1995 industrial census and calculate the province-sector level growth rate for thebook value of capital. Note that Brandt et al (2012) use the province-sector level aggregate capital stock growth,which ignores entry and exit. We instead use the province-sector level average capital stock growth.

7

Page 10: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

However, this data is not available for Chinese firms. Thus, we apply this equation for each firm’s

real aggregate capital stock, PtKit. Setting the savings interest rate to 2.5-percent, the depreciation

rate to 9-percent, and the appreciation rate to 3.3-percent, then iS + δ−∆P/P equals 8.2-percent.

This estimate is similar to Hsieh and Klenow (2009) who use 10-percent across all firms in China’s

manufacturing.

Next, we follow Hall and Jorgenson (1967) and compute an alternative measure for capital costs

that accounts for firm-level debt and equity financing and the business income tax. In particular,

this measure is implementable because we have firm-level debt-equity ratios, which generate firm-

specific required rates of capital returns:

ritKit = PtKit (iit + δ −∆P/P )1− zit1− τ (3)

where the corporate tax rate is τ , which is 33.3-percent over the sample period, the weighted average

cost of capital is iit = bitiL + (1− τ) (1− bit) iS where bit is the debt (liabilities) to asset (total

assets) ratio at the firm level, and iL is the loan interest rate (around 5.9-percent on average over

the period), and the present value of depreciation deductions on investment is zit = δτ/ (iit + δ).

Figure 4 compares the required return to capital services (rit) computed from Jorgenson and

Griliches (1967), Hall and Jorgenson (1967), which is our baseline measure, and Hsieh and Klenow

(2009). We find that the required rates of returns are higher when we use Hall and Jorgenson in

equation (3) than when we use Jorgenson and Grilliches in equation (2); and the estimates using

Hsieh and Klenow’s (2009) assumptions are in the middle.

2.1 Pure Profit Shares and SOEs

We use the data from the Chinese Annual Surveys of Industrial Production (ASIP), which covers all

state owned enterprises (SOEs) and private firms with total annual sales exceeding 5 million RMB

per year or roughly 612,000 US dollars. A firm that produces good i at time t in industry j uses

a production function that converts labor (Lit), capital (Kit), and intermediate inputs (Mit) into

real output (Qit). The corresponding input prices, wages (wit), rental rates (rit), and intermediate

prices (pit), are strictly positive, exogenous for firms, and firm-specific.

Because a firm’s value added (V Ait) is its revenues (Rit = PitQit) minus spending on in-

termediate inputs (pitMit), then a firm’s value added is the sum of its pure profits (πit), labor

8

Page 11: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

compensation (witLit), and capital costs (ritKit). A firm’s labor and capital shares are computed

as sLit = witLit/V Ait and sKit = ritKit/V Ait, respectively; and, its pure profit share of gross value

equals one minus labor share and capital shares:

sit =πitV Ait

= 1− (sLit + sKit ). (4)

Throughout the paper, we show that the degree of market competition differs substantially

across industries, depending on the pervasiveness of the SOEs. The classification of whether or

not a firm is an SOE follows the definition in Hsieh and Song (2015, pp.301-302): a firm is state-

owned when the share of its paid-in-capital “directly held by the state”is greater than or equal to

50-percent; or, the state (and not a collective, foreigner, or private person) is the controlling share-

holder. The following procedure is used to split the sample of 136 industries into state quartiles.

First, the state ownership share in each industry equals the sum of SOEs’revenues divided by its

total revenues in 2007. Then, the industry-level state ownership share is sorted from the highest to

the lowest. Finally, the 34 industries in the 75th or above percentile are placed in the top quartile;

they are followed by the 34 industries in the second (50th-75th percentiles), the 34 industries in

the third (25th-50th percentiles), and the 34 industries in the bottom (25th percentile or below)

quartiles.

Table 1 reports the summary statistics that compare pure profit shares from equation (4) versus

accounting profit shares.13 The table shows that pure profit shares were higher than accounting

profit shares. Aggregate pure profit share from all firms was 64.3-percent in 2007, which is higher

than aggregate accounting profit share by 40.2 percentage points. This is because accounting

profits deduct taxes, financial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other

unobserved benefits paid to workers, and one-time large expenses for capital goods and intermediate

goods, while pure profits do not. The table also shows that pure profit shares grew faster than

accounting profit shares. Aggregate accounting profit shares increased 13.1 percentage points for

all firms, which is almost half the 25.6 percentage point growth rate in aggregate pure profit share.

The rise in pure profit shares concentrated on the industries where SOEs were pervasive. Columns

(3) and (6) shows that the difference between aggregate accounting and pure profit share is most

pronounced in the top quartile where SOEs were most pervasive, and almost the same in the bottom

13For example, see Brooks et al (2019) who use accounting profits to derive firm-level markups.

9

Page 12: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

quartile where SOEs were least pervasive.

Table 2 reports summary statistics for profit, labor, and capital shares of gross value added

by SOE quartiles. During the sample period, pure profit shares increased by 36.8 percentage

points in the top quartile for SOEs, and, then declined to 21.4, 20.2, and 9.3 percentage point

increases in the second, third, and bottom quartiles, respectively. The rise of pure profit shares

suppressed both labor’s and capital’s shares in all quartiles. For example, column (6) shows that

labor shares declined by 14.6 percentage points in the top quartile, and, then declined to 9.2, 7.2,

and 1 percentage point declines in the second, third, and bottom quartiles, respectively.14,15

2.2 Between and Within Analysis

In the introduction, chemical fertilizers and textile goods industries were examples of how the sharp

increase in the aggregate pure profit share can reflect two different forms of market competition:

(1) in the chemical fertilizers industry, there are within-firm effects where firms on average increase

their pure profit shares; and (2) in the textile goods industry, there are between-firm effects where

there was selection on firms with the highest markups or productivity (Khandelwal et al, 2013).

In order to generalize these examples, we conduct a standard between and within decomposition

analysis for the sample of 34,571 survivor firms in the manufacturing sector. In subsequent sections,

we show that firms that had higher markups had higher pure profit shares. Then, if market shares

are reallocated to firms that have the highest markups, between-firm effects should explain most of

the increase in aggregate pure profit shares. However, if competition softens, and firms can charge

higher markups, then within-firm effects should explain the increase in pure profit shares. Thus,

14Our measure of labor’s share is lower than the comparable figure from China’s national accounts. This is becauseour labor compensation measure includes wage and unemployment insurance while labor compensation in the nationalaccounts include wages and a broader set of benefits paid to labor. However, the trends in the labor shares are almostidentical, suggesting that the omission of some types of benefits do not distort the results in the paper. In ourempirical work, we do not follow the approach in Hsieh and Klenow (2009) and Brandt et al (2012) who inflate wagepayments across all firms at the same rate for each year so that the aggregated firm-level labor share values areconsistent with the values from the national accounts. Our main conclusions do not change even if we follow theirapproach.15Our data excludes private manufacturing firms with sales less than 5 million RMB per year. Gollin (2002)

notes that in the system of national accounts the income of small firms in which the proprietors are self-employed isgenerally treated as capital income. Gollin (2002) then finds that labor shares become more stable once the incomeof self-employed proprietors is treated as wage income. In China the income of self-employed proprietors is classifiedas labor income during 1997-2003 and then as capital income since 2004. However, this is not a problem for ouranalysis because there are no self-employed proprietors in our sample.

10

Page 13: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

we use the following equation:

4ss ≡∑i∈s4ωisi +

∑i∈s4siωi (5)

where 4ss is the change in the aggregate profit share from the sample of survivor firms.

The first term on the right-hand side of equation (5) is the between-firm effect,∑

i∈s4ωisi,

where 4ωi = ωi,07 − ωi,98 is the change in a firm’s value added share in the manufacturing sector,

and si = 0.5(si,98 + si,07) denotes a firm’s average profit share during 1998-2007; and 4siωi in

the second term is the within-firm effect, where 4si = si,07 − si,98 is the change in profit shares

within a firm, and ωi = 0.5(ωi,98 + ωi,07) denotes a firm’s average value added share within the

manufacturing sector.

Columns (1)-(3) in Table 3 report the between, within, and total effects for the survivor firms.

The first panel of Table 3 applies equation (5) to all survivor firms, and shows that the within-firm

effects dominate between-firm effects and account 21.2 percentage points or, roughly 86-percent

(five-sixths) of the overall increase in pure profit shares. Consistent with our view that firms can

increase pure profit shares in the top state quartile industries such as chemical fertilizers where

SOEs are pervasive, the within-firm effects account for 31.2 percentage points of the 36 percentage

point increase in pure profit share in the top quartile. However, for firms in the bottom state

quartile industries where the presence of SOEs is negligible, the between-firm effect accounts for

6.4 percentage points, or about 84-percent of the 7.6 percentage point increase in pure profit share.

During the sample period of 1998-2007, there was substantial net entry because the 118,018

and 268,452 firms in operation in 1998 and 2007 period greatly exceed the 34,571 survivors that

operated in 1998 and 2007. In order to understand the impacts of firm exit and entry on pure profit

shares, we use the following equation from Melitz and Polanec (2015):

4s−s ≡ ωx,98(ss,98 − sx,98) + ωe,07(se,07 − ss,07). (6)

In equation (6), 4s−s is the change in the aggregate profit share between entrants and exiters,

ωx,98 (ωe,07) is the value added share of exiters in 1998 (entrants in 2007) in the full sample, and

sx,98, se,07, ss,98, and ss,07 are the aggregate pure profit shares for exiters in 1998, entrants in 2007,

survivors in 1998, and survivors in 2007, respectively. Thus, the first term on the right hand side

11

Page 14: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

is the contribution of exit and is reported in column (4) in Table 3: it is the difference between the

weighted average of survivors’profit share (ss,98) and exited firms’profit share (sx,98), weighted

by the value added share of exiters in 1998 (ωx,98). The second term on the right hand is the

contribution of entry and is reported in column (5): it is the difference in the aggregate averages

between entrants’profit share (se,07) and survivors’profit share (ss,07), weighted by the value added

share of entrants (ωe,07).

The results reported in columns (4) and (5) in Table 3 indicate that exit and entry had a

negligible impact. A potential reason for this is the way in which SOEs were restructured (see

Hsieh and Song, 2015). The strategy of “grasping” the large SOEs and “letting go”of the small

SOEs meant that exiting SOEs accounted for a relatively small share of value added. In addition,

private sector entrants were relatively small and concentrated in competitive markets where state

ownership was not pervasive.

3 Competition and Profit Shares

3.1 Markups

We derive markups in the next subsection, and then describe our model in subsection 3.2. Consistent

with our model, the baseline markups are estimated under the assumption that labor, capital and

intermediate inputs are all variable. However, we estimate markups under different assumptions

about which inputs are variable and show how they compare with our baseline estimates.16

Short and Medium Run Markups

We first follow the approach in De Loecker and Warzynski (2012), De Loecker et al (2016), and De

Loecker et al (2020), and derive markups from the following cost minimization problem for each

firm i:

L = pitMit + witLit + ritKit + λit[Qit − ΩitF (Mit, Lit,Kit)]

where Qit = ΩitF (Mit, Lit,Kit) is a general form of production functions, and the Lagrange multi-

plier (λit) is the firm’s marginal cost for the output target, Qit.

16See Basu (2019) for review of alternative methods for estimating markups.

12

Page 15: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

In order to estimate markups, Brandt et al (2017) use an industry-level Cobb-Douglas produc-

tion function that places no restrictions on returns to scale:17

Qit = ΩitMαM

it LαL

it KαK

it . (7)

In this setup, the output elasticities (αM , αL, and αK) are the same for each firm in an

industry18 and are constant over the sample period. Firms are heterogenous according to their

productivity, denoted Ωit, and, this shapes their entry and exit. And, the firm’s only variable

input is intermediates. Using the first order condition for intermediate inputs,19 and imposing

Qit = ΩitF (Mit, Lit,Kit), where a firm’s labor and capital are fixed, the cost-minimizing values of

Mit and λsit are obtained. It is assumed that a firm has market power and can find the price Pit at

which it can sell Qit. Then, the short run markup (µsit = Pit/λsit) is the estimated industry-level

output elasticity of intermediate inputs, αM , divided by the firm’s payments to intermediates as a

share of its revenues:

µsit = αMPitQitpitMit

. (8)

To estimate short-run markups, the data for revenues and payments for intermediate inputs

are taken from firm-level balance sheet data; and, the estimated output elasticities of intermediate

inputs come from production function estimates.

Next, we assume that both labor and intermediate inputs are variable inputs, and a firm pro-

duces a medium run target level of output (Qit). Using the first order conditions20 and imposing

Qit = ΩitF (Mit, Lit,Kit), the cost-minimizing values of Mit, Lit, and λmit for reaching the output

target are derived. Then, it follows that a firm’s medium run markup (µmit = Pit/λmit ) is the sum

of its estimated output elasticities of intermediate inputs and labor divided by its payments to

materials and labor as a share of revenues:

µmit =(αM + αL

) PitQitpitMit + witLit

. (9)

17Appendix I reports the estimation results of production functions from the method similar to De Loecker et al(2016). See Table A3.18Notation denoting an industry is suppressed.19pit = λsitα

M QitMit

.20pit = λmitα

M QitMit

and wit = λmitαL QitLit.

13

Page 16: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

In this setup, one single output elasticity of labor plus intermediate inputs (αM+ αL), and the

output elasticity of capital (αK) are the same for each firm in an industry and constant over the

sample period.21 This approach allows for the output elasticity of labor and that of intermediate

inputs to vary over time; however, we do not observe these changes. The additional data necessary

to derive medium run markups is labor compensation, which comes directly from firm-level balance

sheet data.

Baseline Long Run Markups

In our model, firms choose their optimal pure profit shares, which equals one minus their optimal

capital and labor shares. Thus, to be consistent with this model, firms should optimize over their

intermediates, labor, and capital. Olley and Pakes (1995) and Ackerberg et al (2015) argue that

the adjustment time to hire labor and to install capital takes longer than purchasing and using

intermediate inputs. Studies following this approach generally assume that it takes more than a

year to adjust capital, less than a year to adjust labor, and firms can optimally choose intermediate

inputs at any point in time. Thus, we assume that firms optimize all of their inputs as of 1998 and

2007, given their time-specific input prices and technologies.

In this setup, we can allow for each firm to have a firm-specific Cobb-Douglas production

function that can change over time:

Qit = ΩitMαMitit L

αLitit K

αKitit (10)

where the subscripts i and t denote a firm and a year (either 1998 or 2007), and each firm has an

industry-specific scale elasticity of output, αMit + αLit + αKit = ρt, that can vary during the sample

period.

In this case, a firm chooses intermediates, labor, and capital, in order to minimize its cost of

attaining the long run target output level (Qit). The three first order condition are:

pit = λitαMit

QitMit

, wit = λitαLit

QitLit

, and wit = λitαKit

QitKit

, (11)

implying that the long run markup for any firm equals its industry’s scale elasticity times its sales

21See De Loecker et al (2020).

14

Page 17: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

divided its costs:22

µit =ρtPitQit

pitMit + witLit + ritKit. (12)

This expression for long run markups follows the approach in Diewert and Fox (2008) and is

used as a robustness check in De Loecker et al (2020). To estimate this equation, we use firm-level

balance sheet data for revenues, payments to labor and intermediates, imputed capital costs, and

estimated scale elasticities.23

Table 4 reports summary statistics for short run, medium run, and long run markups. Several

patterns emerge. First, while the weighted and simple means of medium and long run markups

increased from 1998 to 2007, the short run weighted and simple means are constant. In our analysis,

we use long run markups as our baseline measure because they allow production technologies

(output elasticities of input) to vary over time, which, as emphasized by De Loecker et al (2020), is

essential for studying the long run implications of markups for macroeconomic dynamics. Second,

consistent with Lu and Yu (2015), the standard deviation of short run markups across firms declined

substantially by 35.8-percent. However, the magnitudes of the decline in standard deviations is

much smaller using the other markup measures. Finally, in appendix Table A4, we show that these

markup measures are strongly correlated to each other, and long run markups are more strongly

correlated with medium run markups and less strongly correlated with short run markups. Thus,

in what follows, we use long run markups because they are consistent with our theory and show

that our results are robust when we use medium run markups. We do not use short-run markups in

subsequent analysis because, as previously discussed, they are relevant to studies of the immediate

impacts including tariff reductions on markups but, not a longer run study.

3.2 Microfoundations of Aggregate Pure Profit Shares

To derive aggregate pure profit shares at any point in time, we first derive each firm’s pure profit

share and its value added and then derive the value added weighted sum over all firms in the man-

22When all the inputs are optimized, the first order conditions also imply, for example for intermediate inputs, thatαMit = ρtpitMit/(pitMit +witLit + ritKit). In other words, we can approximate firm-specific and time-variant outputelasticities from corresponding cost shares, pitMit/(pitMit + witLit + ritKit), and industry- and time-specific scaleelasticities, ρt.23Following De Loecker et al (2020), the log of firm output is regressed on the sum of the log of each factor input

times its cost share, and the estimated regressor is the scale elasticity for an industry in a period.

15

Page 18: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

ufacturing sector. Thus, we first use the first order conditions for all inputs and derive expressions

for labor’s and capital’s shares, sLit and sKit :24

sLit =αLit

µit − αMitand sKit =

αKitµit − αMit

. (13)

And, pure profit shares are one minus labor’s share and capital’s share:

sit =µit − ρtµit − αMit

(14)

where ρt > αMit because αMit + αLit + αKit = ρt.

Equations (13) and (14) predict that when a firm increases its markups, it reduces its labor

and capitals shares, and, thus, increases its pure profit shares. Equation (14) captures within-firm

effects of markups on aggregate pure profit shares; and it also shows that, conditional on markups,

pure profit shares are increasing in a firm’s output elasticity of intermediate inputs and decreasing

in its scale elasticity.

The predicted pure profit shares in equation (14) closely match the estimated aggregate pure

profit shares in 1998 and 2007 reported in Table 1. Using data in Table 4 and Table A5, the

weighted average firm-level markup, the scale elasticity, and the output elasticity of intermediate

inputs in 1998 was 1.168, 1.066, and 0.898, respectively; and the predicted aggregate pure profit

share in 1998 was 0.379, which is slightly lower than our estimate of the aggregate share, 0.387.

Similarly, the predicted average pure profit share in 2007 is 0.652, which is mildly higher than our

estimate, 0.643.

The substantial changes of 25.6 and 27.3 percentage points in the estimated and predicted

aggregate pure profit shares stem from increases in markups and intensiveness of intermediate

inputs in production. Between 1998 and 2007, the aggregate markups increased by 10.3 percentage

points (from 1.168 to 1.271), and the aggregate output elasticities of intermediate inputs increased

by 6.9 percentage points (from 0.898 to 0.967);25 however, the average scale elasticity was relatively

stable and increased by 1.2 percentage points (from 1.066 to 1.078). Figures 5 and 6 show that the

24The labor share equation is a familiar formula in Azmat et al (2012) and Karabarbounis and Neiman (2014) thatcaptures a within-firm effect and identifies firm’s labor share as a function of its markups and output elasticities oflabor.25Brandt et al (2012) and Yu and Lu (2015) have detailed production function estimates for the manufacturing

and also show that production functions in the manufacturing sector are highly intensive in intermediate inputs.

16

Page 19: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

changes in markups and output elasticities of intermediate inputs grew most rapidly in the quartile

where SOEs were most pervasive, which is consistent with the observation that the aggregate pure

profit share grew most rapidly in the same quartile (see Table 1).

In order to capture the between-firm effects of markups on aggregate pure profit shares, we use

the first order conditions and derive an expression for a firm’s value added:

V Ait ≡ (1− αMit /µit)Rtmsit(µit). (15)

The first term, (1−αMit /µit = V Ait/Rit) is a firm’s value added share of revenue and, does not

change over time because αMit and µit grow at roughly the similar rate for firms.26 And, the second

term, (Rt =∑

iRit), which is the size of the firm’s industry is not firm-specific and, thus, has no

firm-between effects. The third term explains the positive association between a firm’s value added

and market share. Moreover, a firm’s market share should increase as its markups increases, which

captures the reallocation of market shares to the highest markup firms. This property holds in

the standard Cournot oligopoly model with heterogeneous marginal costs27 as well as monopolistic

competition and product differentiation models in Atkeson and Burstein (2008) and Feenstra and

Weinstein (2017). We will test for this association in later in the paper.

3.3 Components of Industry Markups

To understand why markups grew more rapidly in the industries where SOEs were pervasive, we

decompose the growth in markups at the industry level. In particular, using all the first order

conditions, we can derive the following form of marginal cost (λt) that corresponds to industry-

level production function in equation (10) as a function of the average of input prices (pt, wt, and

rt), weighted by their cost shares, scale effects, and productivity (Ωt):

λt =1

ΩtQ1/ρt−1t [p

csMtt w

csLtt r

csKtt ] =

ctΩtQ1/ρt−1t (16)

where csMt , csLt , and cs

Kt are cost shares of corresponding inputs, which are the corresponding

output elasticities of each factor divided by the scale elasticity of output, ct denotes unit costs, and

26At the aggregate level, markups grew 8.6 percentage points, and the output elasticity of intermediate inputs grewby 6.9 percentage points. Thus, the change in the first term on average was less than 2 percentage points.27Our theoretical narrative for this model is available upon request.

17

Page 20: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

Q1/ρt−1t captures the effect of scale on marginal costs.

We also derive productivities as residuals from the industry-level production function in equation

(10),28 and use the following equation for markups:

µt =PtΩt

ctQ1−1/ρtt (17)

where µt equals the scale elasticity times revenues divided by total costs at the industry level.

Using the detailed 4-digit industry-level output and input prices from Brandt et al (2017) as

well as imputed cost shares, we can use equation (17) and decompose the growth in markups into

the growth in output prices, productivities, scale, and weighted input costs:

∆ ln(µt) = ∆ ln(Pt) + ∆ ln(Ωt) + ∆(1− 1/ρt) ln(Qt)−∆ ln(ct). (18)

Table 5 reports the results of the decomposition. Column (1) shows that markups grew the

fastest in the top quartile where SOEs were most pervasive, and this difference between the quartile

where SOEs were most pervasive and the other three quartiles is statistically significant. In columns

(2) through (5), the growth in markups for the different quartiles is decomposed into the growth of

the output price, productivity, scale effects, and weighted input cost, respectively. Although stan-

dard deviations across industries are often large, and not all differences are statistically significant,

cross-quartile differences in nominal prices are systematic. Output prices increased most rapidly in

the top quartile, and input prices grew much slower in the top three quartiles than in the bottom

quartile. As a result, markups grew most rapidly in top quartile where SOEs were most pervasive.

Columns (6)-(11) decomposes the components of the growth of the weighted input prices into

the growth in intermediate prices, wages, and required returns to capital services as well as the

changes in cost shares of corresponding inputs. It is notable that wages grew most rapidly in the

top quartile, and intermediate input prices grew slowly in the top three quartiles. In addition, the

cost share of intermediate inputs increased the most in the top state quartile and increased the least

in the bottom quartile. It is a reasonable speculation that firms in the upper quartiles may have

found that it was relatively easy to reduce costs of intermediate inputs because they had access to

28

ln(Ωt) = ln(Qt)− αMt ln(Mt)− αLt ln(Lt)− αKt ln(Kt).

18

Page 21: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

cheaper inputs due to tariff cuts after China’s entry to the WTO.

3.4 Competitive Selection

In this section, we check for the importance of competitive selection and estimate the association

between market shares and markups. We define a market in a year as a 136 3-digit CIC industry

or a 136 3-digit CIC industry in each of four supra regions (North, East, South, and West). A

firm’s market share is its sales divided by overall sales in its market, where sales include both

domestic and foreign transactions. Table 6 reports several summary statistics. In 1998, there were

35,092 SOEs and 82,992 private (including collective and foreign) firms; and, by 2007, the number

of SOEs was cut by more than two-thirds, to 11,561, while the number of private firms more than

tripled, to 256,891. However, the market share of the average SOE became larger than the average

private firm. In 1998, the average market share of SOEs was 0.55-percent and marginally higher

than 0.43-percent for private firms. However, SOE shares increased to 0.75-percent as the larger

SOEs consolidated; and private market shares decreased to 0.18-percent. This increase in market

shares of SOEs was most pronounced in the top quartile and went form 0.67-percent in 1998 to

1.1-percent in 2007.

To examine empirical associations between market shares and markups, we regress a firm’s

market share on its markups. If there is competitive selection, consistent with standard imperfect

competition models including the Cournot oligopoly model with heterogeneous marginal costs and

product differentiation models (e.g., Atkeson and Burstein, 2008; Feenstra and Weinstein, 2017),

we would expect a strong positive association between a firm’s markups and its market share. We

also include the SOE dummy variable as this captures how connections to the state can also matter

for a firm’s market share.

Table 7 reports the results. In all the specifications, the firm-level markup variable is positively

and statistically significantly associated with firm-level market shares, indicating there is compet-

itive selection. Columns (1)-(3) use the entire sample during 1998-2007; and, the sign of the SOE

dummy variable is negative, which is consistent with the expectation that there was negative se-

lection on state connections in a period when the private sector was growing. However, when we

exclude exports from the measure of market shares in column (3), the SOE dummy is statistically

insignificant.

19

Page 22: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

Columns (4) and (6) are the cross-sectional results for the top quartile of state ownership in

1998 and 2007. In 1998, there was selection on markups and, a one percent higher markup was

associated with a 0.89-percent higher market share; and, there was no selection on state ownership.

However, by 2007, the markup elasticity of market shares fell from 0.89 to 0.58 and, conditional on

fixed effects and other variables, SOEs on average had 284 percent larger (i.e., exp(1.044)) market

shares than private firms. These results indicate selection on political connections strengthened, and

competitive selection weakened. This is consistent with our findings in Table 3 that between-firm

effects were negligible in this quartile.

Columns (5) and (7) contain results for the bottom quartile where state ownership was least

pervasive. Between 1998 and 2007, the markup elasticity of market shares increase from 0.50 to

0.97, indicating that reallocation of market shares to competitive firms became stronger. However,

while there was no selection on SOEs in 1998, by 2007, surviving SOEs had 118-percent (i.e.,

exp(0.162)) market shares, on average, than private firms. And, this increase in selection on both

markups and SOEs is consistent with moderate between-firm effects in this quartile reported in

Table 3.

4 Conclusions

We have documented that aggregate pure profit shares in China’s manufacturing sector grew a

striking 25.6 percentage point during a ten-year period. And, we use a simple firm-level model

to understand whether this trend is indicative of weaker or stronger market competition. In this

model, when competition is weak, and firms charge higher markups, aggregate pure profit share

can increase because of a within-firm effect; and, when there is a reallocation of market shares to

high markup firms, and competition is stiff, aggregate pure profit share can also increase because

of a between-firm effect. We have found that within-firms effect are roughly five times stronger

than between-firm effects, indicating that market competition has declined. And, firms that raised

their markups operated primarily in industries where state ownership was pervasive, and had the

sharpest increases in the intermediate-intensiveness of their production technologies.

This paper also raises concerns about state owned firms. Sectors where state ownership were

pervasive had the sharpest increase in markups and pure profits shares and did not have impressive

productivity growth. And, while state ownership declined during the period of our study, there is

20

Page 23: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

some evidence that state ownership has been expanding since 2008. Moreover, there is evidence that

after 2008 (see Brandt et al, 2018) that productivity growth in Chinese manufacturing fell sharply.

While the connection between the pervasiveness of the state ownership, market competition, and

productivity growth is somewhat speculative at this point, this is an important area for future

research.

Appendix

I. Estimation Method

We follow an approach proposed by De Loecker et al (2016) and obtain production function para-

meters and unobserved input price parameters for the 28 2-digit sectors. We follow Brandt et al

(2017) and De Loecker et al (2020) and estimate the Cobb-Douglas production functions that allow

variable returns to scale. While De Loecker et al (2016) propose to control for input price variations

across firms using information on firm-level output prices by assuming producers of more expensive

products use more expensive inputs, we do not observe the direct measure of output or input prices

at the firm level. Thus, we follow their intuition and approximate unobserved input prices using

a dummy variable for SOEs, a dummy variable for exporters, and controlling for domestic market

shares of each firm. Because we do not have firm-level output prices, it is crucial to have detailed

deflators. We use the deflators from Brandt et al (2017) who construct an output deflator at the

most detailed industry level possible.

To estimate production functions in equation (7), we follow the timing assumption in Acker-

berg et al (2015) that firms need more time to optimize labor and install capital than purchase

intermediate inputs. It follows from this timing assumption that a firm’s demand for intermediate

inputs depends on its productivity and the predetermined amounts of labor and the current stock

of capital. We also follow De Loecker et al (2016) and handle unobserved input price biases with

an exporter dummy (dexit ), an SOE dummy (dsoeit ), and log domestic market share (ms

dit):

mit = ht

(ωit, lit, kit, d

exit , d

soeit ,ms

dit

)where lowercase variables are logged variables (e.g., lit = ln(Lit)).

Following Ackerberg et al (2015), we assume the above equation can be inverted with log

21

Page 24: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

productivity:

ωit = h−1t

(mit, lit, kit, d

exit , d

soeit ,ms

dit

).

We then approximate log real output (qit) with the second order polynomial function of the

three inputs and that interacted with the three variables for input price biases and separate the

predicted value (Φt) from the idiosyncratic error term (εit):

qit ≈ Φt

(mit, lit, kit, d

exit , d

soeit ,ms

dit

)+ εit. (19)

Next, we compute the corresponding value of productivity for any combination of parameters.

The parameter we need to estimate has a constant term and output elasticities (αMs , αLs , and

αKs ) and, also unobserved input price biases, the interactions of the three variables (dexit , d

soeit , and

ln(msdit)) with mit (βexs , βsoes , and βmss ). This enables us to express the log of productivity as the

predicted log output minus the logged contribution of three inputs:

ωit = Φt −(cs + αMs mit + αLs lit + αKs kit + β

exs mitd

exit + β

soes mitd

soeit + β

mss mitms

dit

).

Our generalized method of moments (GMM) procedure assumes that firm-level innovations to

productivity, ζit, do not correlate with the predetermined choices of inputs. To recover ζit, we

assume that productivity for any set of parameters (ωit) follows a first order Markov process. As in

De Loecker (2013) argue, we introduce the two dummy variables follow a Markov process because

they influence the evolution of firm-level productivities. While Brandt et al (2017) include input

and output tariffs in the Markov process in their study of how firms immediately respond to tariff

cuts, we use the SOE and export dummy variables in our longer term macro study of markups..

The results that include these additional controls do not change the main conclusions. Thus, we

can approximate the productivity process with the following function:

ωit = γ0 + γ1ωi,t−1 + γ2dexit + γ3d

soeit + ζit.

From the equation above, we can recover the innovation to productivity (ζit) for a given set of

the parameters. Since the innovation to productivity (ζit) cannot be correlated with the current

22

Page 25: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

choice of capital (kit) and the lagged choices of labor and intermediate inputs (mi,t−1 and li,t−1),

we use the following moment condition to estimate the parameters:

E [ζit(Ω)Yit] = 0 (20)

where Yit = kit, li,t−1, mi,t−1, dexi,t−1mi,t−1, dsoei,t−1mi,t−1, and ln(msdi,t−1)mi,t−1.

Before we report the GMM results in Table A3, we report the OLS results in Table A2. Al-

though the OLS results cannot solve the endogeneity and simultaneity biases, it still provides us

with the sense of the data. We find that Chinese manufacturing firms use technologies that are

intensive in intermediate inputs, and output elasticities of intermediate inputs increased by around

2-3 percentage points over the period.

Table A3 reports the estimated parameters at the 2-digit or 3-digit industry level. The results

are consistent with our understanding that Chinese firms use intermediate inputs intensively. The

mean output elasticity of labor is 0.095 (0.099); and that of output elasticities of intermediate

inputs is 0.862 (0.865) at the 2-digit (3-digit) level.

II. Output Elasticities

Table A5 reports the summary statistics for output elasticities of labor, capital, and intermediate

inputs from the full and survivor samples of firms in 1998 and 2007 as well as the aggregates by the

state quartiles. Our measure of output elasticities are the products of industry- and time-specific

scale elasticities of output and firm-level cost shares of corresponding inputs. The first panel of

the table shows that the aggregate average of the output elasticities of labor and capital from the

full sample of the firms declined by 1.9 percentage points and 3.8 percentage points, respectively;

however, the output elasticities of intermediate inputs increased by 6.9 percentage points over

the period. And, the results are very similar even if we use the sample from the survivor firms.

Overall, Chinese manufacturing firms use more intermediate inputs and less labor and capital

over the period. And, consistent with the production function parameters in Table A3, Chinese

manufacturing firms use production technologies that are intensive in intermediate inputs.

The second panel of the table shows that the aggregate averages of the output elasticities of

intermediate inputs increased the most (by 9.0 percentage points) in the top state quartile, and it

declined to 5.9, 6.5, and 3.3 percentage points in the second, third and bottom quartiles.

23

Page 26: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

References

[1] Ackerberg, D., K. Caves, and G. Frazer, “Identification Properties of Recent Production Func-

tion Estimators,”Econometrica, 83, 2411-2451, 2015.

[2] Atkeson, A, and A. Burstein, “Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative

Prices,”American Economic Review, 98(5), 1998-2031, 2008.

[3] Autor, D.H. D. Dorn, L.F. Katz, C. Patterson, and J. Van Reenan, “The Fall of the Labor

Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms,”mimeo, MIT, Harvard, 2020.

[4] Azmat, G., A. Manning, and J. Van Reenen, “Privatization and the Decline of Labour’Share:

International Evidence from Network Industries,”Economica, 79, 470-492, 2012.

[5] Bai, C., Y. Du, Z. Tao, and Y. S. Tong, “Local Protectionism and Regional Specialization:

Evidence from China’s Industries,”Journal of International Economics, 63, 397—417, 2004.

[6] Bai, J., and J. Liu, “The impact of Local Trade Barriers on Export Activities, Firm Perfor-

mance, and Resource Misallocation,”Working Paper, 2017.

[7] Bai, C., C-T Hsieh, and Z.M. Song, “Special Deals with Chinese Characteristics,” in NBER

Macroeconomics Annual 2019, 34, Martin S. Eichenbaum, Erik Hurst, and Jonathan A. Parker,

editors.

[8] Barkai, S., “Declining Labor and Capital Shares,”forthcoming Journal of Finance, 2020.

[9] Barwick, P.J., S. Cao, and S. Li, “Local Protectionism, Market Structure, and Social Welfare:

China’s Automobile Market,”mimeo, 2020.

[10] Berkowitz, D., H. Ma, and S. Nishioka, “Recasting the Iron Rice Bowl: The Reform of China’s

State Owned Enterprises,”Review of Economics and Statistics, 99(4), 735-747. 2017.

[11] Basu, S., “Are Price-Cost Markups Rising in the United States? A Discussion of the Evidence,”

Journal of Economic Perspectives, 33(3), 3-22, 2019.

[12] Brandt, L., J. Van Biesebroeck, and Y. Zhang, “Creative Accounting or Creative Destruc-

tion? Firm-Level Productivity Growth in Chinese Manufacturing,” Journal of Development

Economics, 97, 339-351, 2012.

24

Page 27: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

[13] Brandt, L., J. Van Biesebroeck, L. Wang, and Y. Zhang, “WTO Accession and Performance

of Chinese Manufacturing Firms,”American Economic Review, 107(9), 2784-2820, 2017.

[14] Brandt, L., T. Tombe, and X. Zhu, “Factor Market Distortions Across Time, Space and Sectors

in China,”Review of Economic Dynamics, 16(1), 39-58, 2013.

[15] Brooks, W.J., J.P. Kaboski, Y.A. Li, and W. Qian, “Exploitation of Labor? Classical Monop-

sony Power and Labor’s Share,”NBER Working Paper 25660.

[16] Caballero, R.J., and R.K. Lyons, “External Effects in U.S. Procyclical Productivity,”Journal

of Monetary Economics, 29, 209-225, 1992.

[17] Cooper, R., G. Gong and P. Yan, “Dynamic Labor Demand in China: Public and Private

Objectives,”RAND Journal of Economics, 46(3), 577-610, 2015.

[18] De Loecker, J., “Detecting Learning by Exporting,”American Economic Journal: Microeco-

nomics, 5(3), 1—21, 2013.

[19] De Loecker, J., J. Eeckhout, and G. Unger, “The Rise of Market Power and the Macroeconomic

Implications,”forthcoming Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2020.

[20] De Loecker, J., and F. Warzynski, “Markups and Firm-Level Export Status,”American Eco-

nomic Review, 102(6), 2437-2471, 2012.

[21] Diewert, W.E., and K.J. Fox, “On the Estimation of Returns to Scale, Technical Progress and

Monopolistic Markups,”Journal of Econometrics, 145, 174-193, 2008.

[22] Feenstra, R.C., and D.E. Weinstein, “Globalization, Markups, and US Welfare." Journal of

Political Economy, 125(4), 1040-1074, 2017.

[23] Feng, S., Y. Hu, and R. Moffi tt, “Long run trends in unemployment and labor force partici-

pation in urban China," Journal of Comparative Economics, 45 (2), 304-324, 2017.

[24] Gollin, D., “Getting Income Shares Right,” Journal of Political Economy, 110(2), 458-474,

2002.

[25] Hall, R.E., and D.W. Jorgenson, “Tax Policy and Investment Behavior,”American Economic

Review, 57(3), 391-414, 1967.

25

Page 28: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

[26] Hsieh, C-T, and P.J. Klenow, “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India,”

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(4), 1403-1448, 2009.

[27] Hsieh, C-T, and Z. Song, “Grasp the Large, Let Go of the Small: The Transformation of the

State Sector in China,”Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2015(1), 295-346, 2015.

[28] Jorgenson, D.W., and Z. Griliches, “The Explanation of Productivity Change,” Review of

Economic Studies, 34(3), 249-283, 1967.

[29] Karabarbounis, L., and B. Neiman, “The Global Decline of the Labor Share,”Quarterly Jour-

nal of Economics, 129(1), 206-223, 2014.

[30] Karabarbounis, L., and B. Neiman, “Accounting for Factorless Income,”NBERWorking Paper

#24404, 2018.

[31] Kornai, J., E. Maskin, and G. Roland, 2003, “Understanding the Soft Budget Constraint,”

Journal of Economic Literature, 41(4), 1095-1136, 2003.

[32] Kujis, L., W. Mako, and C. Zhang, “SOE Dividends: How Much and to Whom?”World Bank,

Washington DC #56651, 2005.

[33] Li X., X. Liu and Y, Wang, “A Model of China’s State Capitalism,”HKUST Institute for

Emerging Market Studies, WP 2015-12, 2015.

[34] Lin, J.Y., and G. Tan, “Policy Burdens, Accountability, and the Soft Budget Constraint,”

American Economic Review, 89(2), 426-31, 1999.

[35] Lu, Y., and L. Yu, “Trade Liberalization and Markup Dispersion: Evidence from China’s

WTO Accession,”American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 7(4), 221-253, 2015.

[36] Melitz, M., and S. Polanec, “Dynamic Olley-Pakes Productivity Decomposition with Entry

and Exit,”RAND Journal of Economics 46(2), 362-375, 2015.

[37] Milhaupt, C.J., and Z. Zheng, “Beyond Ownership: State Capitalism and the Chinese Firm,”

Georgetown Law Journal, 665-722, 2015.

[38] Olley, G.S., and A. Pakes, “The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equip-

ment Industry,” Econometrica, 64(6), 1263-1297, 1996.

26

Page 29: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

[39] Piketty, T., L., Yang, and G.l., Zucman., “Capital Accumulation, Private Property, and Rising

Inequality in China, 1978—2015,”American Economic Review, 109(7), 2469-2496, 2019.

[40] Shen, D, “What’s Happening in China’s Textile and Clothing Industries?”Clothing & Textiles

Research Journal, 26(3), 203-222, 2008.

[41] Song, Z., K. Storesletten, and F. Zilibotti, “Growing Like China,”American Economic Review,

101 (1), 196-233, 2011.

[42] Shleifer, A., and R. W. Vishny, “Politicians and Firms,” Quarterly Journal of Economics,

109(4), 995-1025, 1994.

[43] Song, Z., K. Storesletten, and F. Zilibotti, “Growing Like China,”American Economic Review,

101(1), 196-233, 2011.

[44] Syverson, C., “What Determines Productivity?”Journal of Economic Literature, 49(2), 326-

65, 2011.

[45] Timmer, M.P., T. van Moergastel, E. Stuivenwold, G. Ypma, M. O’Mahony, and M. Kan-

gasniemi, "EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts Version 1.0 Part I Methodology,"

Working Paper, 2007.

[46] Young, A., “The Razor’s Edge: Distortions and Incremental Reform in the People’s Republic

of China,”Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(4), 1091-1135, 2000.

27

Page 30: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

28

Figures and Tables

Notes: (1) Net profit shares include tax payments, executive compensations, and some unobserved non-wage

compensation for labor. (2) Prices for capital services are computed from Hall and Jorgenson’s (1967) approach that

accounts for corporate tax and liability at the firm level.

Notes: (1) See the text for an explanation of why we choose chemical fertilizers (262) and textile goods (175) as examples.

(2) The Herfindahl-Hirschman index (HHI) equals the sum of the squares of total sales of each firm in a market.

Page 31: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

29

Notes: (1) We use the sample of survivor firms, (2) The top and bottom 2.5-percent of firm-level net profit share for each

year and industry are outliers and dropped.

Notes: (1) See equations (3) and (4) for Jorgenson and Griliches (1967) and Hall and Jorgenson (1967) methods of

computing capital returns. (2) Hsieh and Klenow (2009) use 10 percent real rate of capital returns.

Page 32: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

30

Table 1. Pure versus accounting profit shares

Notes: (1) The classification of whether or not a firm is state-owned enterprise (SOE) follows the definition in Hsieh and

Song (2015, pp.301-302): a firm is state-owned when the share of its paid-in-capital “directly held by the state” is greater

than or equal to 50-percent; or, the state (and not a collective, foreigner, or private person) is the controlling shareholder.

(2) The following procedure is used to split the sample of 136 industries into state quartiles. First, the state ownership

share in each industry equals the sum of SOEs’ revenues divided by its total revenues. Then, the industry-level state

ownership share is sorted from the highest to the lowest. Finally, the 34 industries in the 75th or above percentile are

placed in the top quartile; they are followed by the 34 industries in the second (50th-75th percentiles), the 34 industries

in the third (25th-50th percentiles), and the 34 industries in the bottom (25th percentile or below) quartiles. (3) We

report the means that are weighted by firm-level value added for the sample of all firms, survivors, or all firms in each

state quartile. (4) The notation “Δ” represents the percentage point change.

Pure profit shares Accounting profit shares

1998 2007 Δ 1998 2007 Δ

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Aggregate

All firms 0.387 0.643 0.256 0.111 0.241 0.131

Survivors 0.378 0.632 0.254 0.142 0.262 0.120

Within the industry state quartile

75th percentile or above 0.288 0.656 0.368 0.088 0.273 0.185

50th - 75th percentiles 0.428 0.642 0.214 0.154 0.237 0.083

25th - 50th percentiles 0.464 0.667 0.202 0.106 0.207 0.101

25th percentile or below 0.481 0.574 0.093 0.117 0.210 0.093

Page 33: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

31

Table 2. Summary statistics for profit, labor and capital shares in value added

Notes: (1) We report the means that are weighted by firm-level value added for the sample of all firms, survivors, or all firms in each state quartile. (2) The notation “Δ”

represents the percentage point change.

Pure profit shares Labor shares Capital shares

1998 2007 Δ 1998 2007 Δ 1998 2007 Δ

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

Aggregate

All firms 0.387 0.643 0.256 0.294 0.196 -0.098 0.318 0.160 -0.158

Survivors 0.378 0.632 0.254 0.296 0.198 -0.098 0.326 0.170 -0.156

Within the industry state quartile

75th percentile or above 0.288 0.656 0.368 0.296 0.150 -0.146 0.416 0.193 -0.222

50th - 75th percentiles 0.428 0.642 0.214 0.290 0.198 -0.092 0.282 0.159 -0.123

25th - 50th percentiles 0.464 0.667 0.202 0.276 0.203 -0.072 0.260 0.130 -0.130

25th percentile or below 0.481 0.574 0.093 0.322 0.312 -0.010 0.197 0.114 -0.083

Page 34: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

32

Table 3. Between and within decompositions for profit shares

Notes: (1) The notation “” represents the percentage point change. We report the means and percentiles from the sample

of survivors. (2) Exit and entry terms are from Melitz and Polanec (2015).

Table 4. Summary statistics for markups

Notes: (1) We derived markups for Models 1 and 2 from the output elasticities estimated at the 2-digit industries (see

Table A2). Model 1 uses the first order condition of intermediate inputs (see Brandt et al, 2017) to compute short run

markups, whereas Model 2 uses the first order conditions of intermediate inputs and labor to compute medium run

markups. Model 3 derives markups from all the first order conditions, which is the scale elasticity times revenues divided

by total costs. (2) Top and bottom 0.5% of samples for each year are outliers and are dropped for Models 1 and 2. (3) We

use the firm-level revenues as weights for Models 1 and 2 and the firm-level total costs as weights for Model 3.

Survivors Exit and entry All firms

Between Within (1)+(2) Exit Entry (3)+(4)+(5)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Aggregate

All firms 0.042 0.212 0.254 -0.009 0.011 0.256

Within the industry state quartile

75th percentile or above 0.048 0.312 0.360 -0.003 0.010 0.368

50th - 75th percentiles 0.006 0.184 0.190 -0.015 0.039 0.214

25th - 50th percentiles 0.070 0.102 0.172 0.026 0.005 0.202

25th percentile or below 0.064 0.012 0.076 0.009 0.008 0.093

1998

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

(Short run) (Medium run) (Long run)

(1) (2) (3)

Weighted mean 1.200 1.184 1.168

Simple mean 1.235 1.156 1.175

s.d. 0.541 0.343 0.320

2007

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

(Short run) (Medium run) (Long run)

(1) (2) (3)

Weighted mean 1.210 1.218 1.271

Simple mean 1.235 1.205 1.293

s.d. 0.347 0.285 0.274

Page 35: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

33

Notes: (1) Markups are computed from scale elasticities time total revenues divided by total costs. (2) We report the simple means across all firms for each state quartile. Top and bottom 0.5% values of the yearly entire sample are outliers, and thus, they are dropped.

Notes: (1) Output elasticities of intermediates are scale elasticities time cost shares of intermediate inputs. (2) We report

the simple means across all firms for each state quartile. Top and bottom 0.5% values of the yearly entire sample are

outliers, and thus, they are dropped.

Page 36: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

34

Table 5. Summary statistics for long run markups and components

Notes: (1) Changes in this table, %, are computed from log differences and equal percentage growth during 1998 to 2007. All industry variables are normalized to the

initial year. (2) In the first panel, we report the mean across 34 industries within each quartile for 1998 and 2007 values and the changes between the two years. (3) In

the second panel, we regress each variable from 136 industries with quartile fixed effects. We report the standard errors that are clustered at the industry level in the

second panel. ***, **, and * indicate that industry-level variables are statistically different from the industries in the top quartile at the 1%, 5%, and 10% confidence

levels.

Components of markups Components of input costs Cost shares of inputs

Price TFP Scale Costs Δln(p) Δln(w) Δln(r) materials labor capital

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11)

Mean across industries within the quartile

75th percentile or above 0.132 0.111 0.137 0.114 0.253 0.190 1.114 0.310 0.069 -0.029 -0.040

50th - 75th percentiles 0.104 0.071 0.134 0.137 0.258 0.199 1.037 0.293 0.049 -0.020 -0.028

25th - 50th percentiles 0.103 0.075 0.116 0.142 0.251 0.194 1.027 0.291 0.038 -0.011 -0.027

25th percentile or below 0.068 0.085 0.141 0.147 0.326 0.268 0.955 0.303 0.010 0.007 -0.018

Mean difference from the top quartile

50th - 75th percentiles -0.029** -0.040 -0.003 0.023 0.006 0.008 -0.077** -0.017* -0.020** 0.008 0.011*

(standard error) (0.012) (0.051) (0.052) (0.015) (0.030) (0.035) (0.034) (0.010) (0.010) (0.005) (0.006)

25th - 50th percentiles -0.029** -0.036 -0.021 0.028* -0.001 0.004 -0.087*** -0.019* -0.031*** 0.018*** 0.013**

(standard error) (0.013) (0.046) (0.055) (0.015) (0.039) (0.043) (0.032) (0.010) (0.009) (0.005) (0.005)

25th percentile or below -0.064*** -0.026 0.004 0.033** 0.074* 0.078 -0.160*** -0.007 -0.059*** 0.036*** 0.022***

(standard error) (0.012) (0.044) (0.054) (0.016) (0.043) (0.049) (0.043) (0.009) (0.009) (0.005) (0.005)

Observations 136 136 136 136 136 136 136 136 136 136 136

Δln(μ)

Page 37: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

35

Table 6. Market shares by state ownership

Notes: Mean market shares report simple means across firms.

Table 7. Market shares and long run markups at the firm level

Notes: (1) Standard errors that are clustered at the industry level are in the parentheses. (2) ***, **, and * indicate that

they are statistically different from zeros at the 1%, 5%, and 10% confidence levels. (3) We use definitions of a market

that exclude external sales (columns (3)) and include external sales (all other columns).

SOEs Private firms

1998 2007 1998 2007

(1) (2) (3) (4)

All firms

Number of firms 35,092 11,561 82,992 256,891

Mean market shares 0.55% 0.75% 0.43% 0.18%

Top state quartile

Number of firms 12,044 50,191 17,834 4,468

Mean market shares 0.67% 1.09% 0.31% 0.17%

Bottom state quartile

Number of firms 4,652 1,158 24,645 71,516

Mean market shares 0.42% 0.41% 0.47% 0.18%

Dependent variable: ln (market shares)

1998-2007 1998 2007

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

0.905*** 0.913*** 1.038*** 0.893*** 0.503*** 0.583*** 0.968***

(0.033) (0.032) (0.039) (0.097) (0.064) (0.056) (0.052)

-0.220** -0.186** -0.058 -0.120 -1.276*** 1.044*** 0.162**

(0.084) (0.087) (0.084) (0.173) (0.107) (0.097) (0.074)

Markets

3-digit industries Yes No No No No No No

3-digit industries × 4 regions No Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes

3-digit industries × 4 regions w/o exports No No Yes No No No No

Fixed effects

3-digit industries Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Regions Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Sample

SOE quartiles All All All Top Bottom Top Bottom

Year All All All 1998 1998 2007 2007

Observations 1,689,894 1,689,894 1,582,551 29,878 29,297 54,659 72,674

R-squared 0.359 0.412 0.297 0.299 0.461 0.400 0.532

ln (long run markups)

SOE dummy

Page 38: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

36

Appendix Tables

Table A1. Summary statistics by the industry SOE shares

Notes: SOE shares in revenues and revenues shares across the quartiles are aggregated values.

Table A2. Production function parameters (OLS)

Notes: (1) Standard errors that are clustered at the industry level are in the parentheses. (2) ***, **, and * indicate that

they are statistically different from zeros at the 1%, 5%, and 10% confidence levels.

Number of firms SOE shares in revenues Revenue shares

1998 2007 Survivors 1998 2007 Δ 1998 2007 Δ

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

Within the industry state quartile

75th percentile or above 29,878 54,659 9,591 0.628 0.362 -0.266 0.394 0.414 0.020

50th - 75th percentiles 29,421 67,221 8,689 0.317 0.111 -0.206 0.211 0.213 0.001

25th - 50th percentiles 29,422 73,898 8,608 0.221 0.045 -0.176 0.233 0.235 0.002

25th percentile or below 29,297 72,674 7,683 0.089 0.016 -0.074 0.162 0.138 -0.024

Total 118,018 268,452 34,571 0.380 0.186 -0.194 1.000 1.000 0.000

Dependent variable: ln (real output)

1998-2007 1998 2007

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

0.902*** 0.903*** 0.888*** 0.878*** 0.879*** 0.891*** 0.904***

(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.005) (0.004) (0.005)

0.043*** 0.041*** 0.060*** 0.062*** 0.053*** 0.059*** 0.064***

(0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) (0.004) (0.005)

0.036*** 0.036*** 0.035*** 0.029*** 0.044*** 0.037*** 0.036***

(0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.004)

-0.081*** -0.084*** -0.048*** -0.078*** -0.047*** 0.002 -0.012*

(0.006) (0.006) (0.004) (0.005) (0.006) (0.006) (0.007)

-0.004 -0.003 -0.001 0.012*** 0.006 -0.018*** -0.015**

(0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.005) (0.007)

Fixed effects

2-digit industries Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Regions No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year No No Yes No No No No

Sample

SOE quartiles All All All All Survivors All Survivors

Year All All All 1998 1998 2007 2007

Observations 1,689,894 1,689,894 1,689,894 118,018 28,028 268,452 28,028

R-squared 0.957 0.957 0.960 0.960 0.965 0.959 0.975

αL (labor)

αK (capital)

Exporter dummy

αM (intermediate inputs)

SOE dummy

Page 39: WORKING PAPER SERIES · pro–ts deduct taxes, –nancial losses or gains, executive compensations, investments, some other unobserved bene–ts paid to workers, and one-time large

37

Table A3. Summary statistics for production function parameters (GMM)

Notes: (1) We use the method in De Loecker et al (2016). See Appendix I. (2) We drop 5 2-digit industries and 32 3-digit

industries to compute the statistics because their output elasticities of labor or intermediate inputs are negative.

Table A4. Correlation matrix across various markup measures

Notes: See Table 4 for the models we use to derive markups.

Table A5. Summary statistics for

Output elasticities of labor, capital and intermediate inputs

Notes: The notation “Δ” represents the percentage point change. We report the weighted means.

2-digit industries 3-digit industries

Mean s.d. Min Max % (>0) Mean s.d. Min Max % (>0)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

Output elasticities

αM (intermediate inputs) 0.862 0.107 0.635 1.012 1.000 0.865 0.170 0.062 1.244 1.000

αL (labor) 0.095 0.102 0.007 0.429 1.000 0.099 0.133 0.004 0.772 1.000

αK (capital) 0.043 0.068 -0.060 0.215 0.857 0.027 0.072 -0.220 0.345 0.846

Scale elasticity 1.000 0.056 0.882 1.133 1.000 0.991 0.125 0.270 1.572 1.000

Input price biases

βex (exporter dummy) 0.004 0.005 -0.012 0.015 0.821 0.007 0.070 -0.350 0.583 0.831

βsoe (SOE dummy) 0.002 0.017 -0.005 0.080 0.321 0.101 0.591 -0.059 5.418 0.603

βms (log market share) 0.008 0.010 -0.009 0.029 0.821 0.006 0.022 -0.059 0.161 0.735

1998 2007

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Model 1: Short run 1.000 1.000

Model 2: Medium run 0.755 1.000 0.765 1.000

Model 3: Long run 0.599 0.841 1.000 0.663 0.841 1.000

Intermediates Labor Capital

1998 2007 Δ 1998 2007 Δ 1998 2007 Δ

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

Aggregate

All firms 0.898 0.967 0.069 0.081 0.061 -0.019 0.087 0.049 -0.038

Survivors 0.892 0.960 0.068 0.083 0.062 -0.021 0.091 0.052 -0.038

Within the industry state quartile

75th percentile or above 0.867 0.957 0.090 0.082 0.046 -0.036 0.115 0.058 -0.056

50th - 75th percentiles 0.906 0.965 0.059 0.082 0.064 -0.018 0.079 0.051 -0.028

25th - 50th percentiles 0.927 0.992 0.065 0.071 0.060 -0.011 0.066 0.038 -0.028

25th percentile or below 0.926 0.959 0.033 0.090 0.104 0.014 0.055 0.038 -0.017