negrettogabriel ii[1]

Upload: daiana-neri

Post on 08-Apr-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    1/36

    Minority Presidents and Types of Government in Latin America

    Gabriel L. NegrettoCentro de Investigacin y Docencia Econmicas (C.I.D.E)

    Draft: March 2003

    Prepared for delivery at the 2003 meeting of the Latin American Studies Association,Dallas, Texas, March 27-29,2003

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    2/36

    2

    Abstract

    A widely accepted argument among students of presidential regimes is that inter-

    branch cooperation is impaired when the presidents party does not control a

    majority of seats in congress. This argument, however, fails to take into accountthree variables that should affect the performance of minority presidentialgovernments: the location of the president s party in the policy space, the strengthof the executive veto and the formation of executive coalitions. Based on a new

    typology of presidential regimes, I propose the hypothesis that the most conflictiveforms of minority government are those in which the president s party does not

    control the median legislator, the president lacks effective veto power, and amajority or median minority executive coalition is not formed. Preliminary evidenceto sustain this hypothesis is provided with data on interrupted Latin American

    presidencies in the period 1980-2002

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    3/36

    3

    Introduction

    A rich literature on presidential regimes has repeatedly associated party fragmentation, and

    its likely effect, minority presidents, with ineffective government, high levels of executive-

    legislative conflict, and even democratic instability. So far, however, neither single-case

    studies provide an accepted causal explanation of this association nor large-n statistical

    studies prove beyond doubt that the relevant variables are significantly correlated. This

    paper argues that the absence of conclusive theories or results is due to the lack of attention

    to variables other than the share of seats of the presidents party in congress to explain the

    different performance of minority presidential governments.

    This paper proposes that there are several possible categories of minority government, not

    all them in principle related to poor government performance. Using an analytic model of

    executive-legislative relations, I argue that the most conflictive forms of minority

    presidential government are those in which the presidents party does not control the

    median legislator in congress, the president lacks effective veto power, and majority or

    median minority executive coalitions are not formed. Preliminary evidence to sustain this

    hypothesis is provided with data on interrupted Latin American presidencies in the period

    1980-2002.

    The argument is presented as follows. In section I, I critically review the literature on

    minority presidential governments. Section II proposes a new typology of presidential

    regimes and a series of hypotheses about inter-branch cooperation based on whether or not

    the party of the president controls the pivotal legislators necessary to pass a bill or sustain a

    veto. Section III analyzes the frequency at which majority coalitions or coalitions including

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    4/36

    4

    the median party in congress are formed in each type of government. In section IV, the

    level of inter-branch conflict in new Latin American democracies is tested using data on the

    early termination of a presidential term. I conclude by indicating the lines of research that

    should follow from this study.

    Presidentialism and minority government

    The separate origin and survival of presidents and assemblies has been the source of

    several hypotheses about the comparative performance of presidential democracies. The

    most radical of them was initially proposed by Linz (1990, 1994) and other critics of

    presidentialism (Valenzuela 1994; Skach and Stepan 1994; Linz and Stepan 1996), who

    argued that separate elections and fix terms induce inter-institutional conflict and make

    difficult if not impossible the resolution of political crises. According to this view, the

    fusion of powers induced by the logic of parliamentary constitutions is, under all political

    conditions, a much better formula to foster effective and stable democracies.

    In response to Linz and his colleagues, a new literature originated in the work of Shugart

    and Carey (1992) and followed by a series of influential studies (Mainwaring 1993; Jones

    1995: Mainwaring and Shugart 1997) proposed that not all presidential regimes are equally

    problematic from the point of view of good governance. In particular, the so-called

    defenders of presidentialism proposed that presidents should be able to govern effectively

    when the right electoral system, by containing party fragmentation, provides them with

    partisan majorities in congress.1 For this literature, then, the problem is not presidentialism

    per se but the difficult combination of presidentialism and multipartysm that breeds weak

    1From this perspective, the right combination of electoral variables is a president elected by plurality rule,

    legislators elected by party-list PR with moderate district magnitudes and concurrent electoral cycles for the

    election of presidents and assemblies. See Shugart and Carey (1992), Jones (1995), and Mainwaring and

    Shugart (1997).

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    5/36

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    6/36

    6

    In spite of the significant progress made during the last decade, the main problem with the

    current research on presidential regimes is that it still uses too crude a measure, namely the

    share of seats of the presidents party in congress, to conceptualize different types of

    presidential government and make predictions about their performance. The most glaring

    example of this problem is the notion of minority or divided government. According to

    almost all definitions, presidential government is unified when the president s party holds

    more and divided when it holds less than 50 percent of seats in congress (or in one

    chamber, for bicameral assemblies).3 But while the concept of unified presidential

    government is unambiguous, a number of substantially different situations can take place

    once presidents fail to obtain majority support in the legislature.

    One could expect, for instance, that if the presidents party is centrally located in the policy

    space and a single dimension prevails, presidential proposals would be supported by a

    legislative majority even if that party controls only a minority of congressional seats. In

    other words, although opposition parties formally control the legislative process they may

    be unable to agree on a policy different from the one proposed by the executive. A second

    possible situation is that of a non-median minority president, but with an effective veto.

    This reactive power could be skillfully used to forge tacit legislative coalitions on different

    pieces of legislation that neither the presidents nor opposition parties have the power to

    approve without mutual support. Finally, a non-median minority president, even without a

    veto, may still be able to govern with relative effectiveness through an executive coalition

    holding a majority of seats or including the median party in congress. Obviously enough,

    one cannot derive the same consequences from all these forms of government.

    3Perhaps only Shugart (1995) departs from this conventional definition to restrict the term divided

    government to situations in which a party different from the presidents control more than 50 percent of the

    seats in congress. As we will see later, this corresponds to the notion of unified congressional government

    that I propose below.

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    7/36

    7

    Since the size of the president s party in congress is related to the number of parties holding

    seats in congress, different authors also use the effective number of congressional parties to

    explain the dynamics of minority governments. The typical statement here is that as

    fractionalization increases, the size of the presidents party decreases thus making more

    difficult to induce legislative support either by ad hoc negotiations with congress or by

    making and maintaining majority executive coalitions (Mainwaring 1993, Jones 1995).

    This association, however, does not amount to a real explanation of the relation between

    fractionalization and executive-legislative conflict and/or regime stability. To see this,

    compare two situations, one where a few large parties hold most of legislative seats and

    another where many small parties hold a relatively equal share of seats.

    Suppose that in the first situation the party of the president is located at the extreme left,

    holding 40 percent of the seats, and that the main opposition party is a center-right party

    holding 50 percent of the seats, followed by a small rightist party, with 10 percent of the

    seats. The effective number of legislative parties here is 2.4. In the second situation, while

    the party of the president is a centrist party holding 30 percent of the seats the 3 opposition

    parties are distributed as follows: one in the center-left, holding 25 percent, one in the

    center-right also with 25 percent, and one in the right with 20 percent. The effective

    number of parties here is 3.9. Clearly enough, inter-branch cooperation should be extremely

    more difficult in the first situation, even though the level of fractionalization is low.

    This analysis indicates that any hypothesis or explanation about the consequences of

    minority presidential government should start by taking into account not only the share of

    seats of the president s party in congress or the effective number of legislative parties but

    also the location of the former in the policy space. I turn to this task in the next section.

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    8/36

    8

    Pivotal politics and types of presidential government

    Using a modified version of Krehbiel s model of pivotal politics (1996, 1998), it is possible

    to create a typology of presidential governments according to the particular location of

    three decisive actors: the presidents party (PP), the veto party (VP) and the median party

    (MP) in congress (Colomer and Negretto 2003). PP is the party that controls the executive

    office, VP is the party that controls the legislator whose support is crucial to override a

    possible presidential veto, and MP is the party that controls the median legislator, that is,

    the legislator whose proposals gather the support of a legislative majority. The central

    assumptions of this model are 1) a unidimensional policy space, 2) single-peaked

    preferences, 3) disciplined parties, and 4) absence of agenda-setters.

    The central or single dimension of policy is assumed to be here the position of parties

    regarding state intervention in the economy and the adoption of redistributive social

    policies, where parties on the left support more and parties on the right support less state

    intervention and redistributive policies, with parties on the center advocating a moderate

    position. That preferences are single-peaked means that each player has an ideal point in

    the policy space so that utility never increases as policies move away (in any direction)

    from the players ideal point. The assumption of disciplined parties, in turn, means that the

    median and veto legislators are expected to vote according to the policy position of the

    party they represent in the legislature. The absence of an agenda-setter means, in turn, that

    no special procedures give any player an advantage to get his or her proposals approved. I

    will later show the different predictions one can obtain by changing this assumption.

    Following this model, one can distinguish three basic forms of government in separation-

    of-powers systems: presidential, divided, and congressional. As shown in Figure 1,

    presidential government occurs whenever the president's party has the support of both the

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    9/36

    9

    veto and the median legislator. This form of government logically includes two possible

    situations. One, which can properly be defined as unified presidential government, derives

    from an election in which the presidents party obtained more than 50 percent of the seats

    in the assembly. The other, which can be labeled median presidential government, takes

    place whenever the president's party, even with less than 50 percent of legislative seats, is

    appropriately located around the 'center' of the policy space.

    While unified presidential government is usually the result of plurality formulas to elect

    presidents and concurrent electoral cycles (Mainwaring and Shugart 1997), there is in

    principle no institutional variable that guarantee that the president s party, short of a

    legislative majority, will be the median party in congress.4 The effective number of

    legislative parties (ENP), which may be affected by electoral rules, is obviously related to

    the location of presidential governments in one or the other category. While unified

    presidential government is more likely when the effective number of legislative parties

    approach a two-party setting (e.g. ENP 1.8-2.4), median presidential government is more

    likely at a moderate level of multipartism (e. g. ENP 2.5-3.9).

    [Figure 1 here]

    Turning to hypotheses of government effectiveness and executive-legislative conflict, there

    is no doubt that, other things being equal, a president whose party controls by itself a

    majority of legislators should be more able than minority presidents to implement most of

    4According to Colomer (2001) and Colomer and Negretto (2003), majority runoff elections for president

    result in the selection of median candidates in a higher proportion than in plurality elections. This does not

    mean, however, that the party of the president would be in those cases the median party in congress. The

    reason is that there may be more parties competing in the congressional election than parties presenting

    candidates in the presidential election so that the medians in both election do not necessarily coincide.

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    10/36

    10

    his agenda with very little cost in terms of inter-branch negotiation. Thus the allure of

    unified presidential government among many scholars. Nevertheless, if the analytic model

    here presented holds, one should expect a minority president whose party is centrally

    located in the policy space to be also more effective and face less executive-legislative

    conflict than any other minority president.

    A median minority president may be in this sense equivalent to the phenomenon of

    minority governments in parliamentary regimes (Strom 1990; Laver and Schofield 1990).

    As Laver and Schofield point out (1990: 80), even in a regime that by definition requires

    majority legislative support to remain in power, a single-party minority government can be

    a viable government if there is no majority coalition of opposition parties which can defeat

    its proposals. If we apply this logic to presidential regimes, it is possible to argue that a

    median presidential government should have a record of legislative success and democratic

    stability not so different from unified presidential government.

    Figure 2 shows what in strict sense we can call divided presidential government, that is, a

    situation where the presidents party controls the veto legislator but a party other than the

    presidents has the support of the median legislator in congress. Whenever elections are not

    decisive in the sense of providing the same party with control over the presidency and the

    legislature, the occurrence of divided government is determined by the effective number of

    parties in the legislature and by the majorities required to override a presidential veto. In

    particular, the probability of having a divided government should increase as the effective

    number of legislative parties is equal or above 3 and the president can sustain a veto with

    the support of relatively few legislators, such as one-third in a unicameral assembly or in

    any of the two chambers in a bicameral assembly.

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    11/36

    11

    [Figure 2 here]

    This definition of divided government is closely associated to the notion of deadlock that

    many authors use (Przeworski et al; Cheibub 2002). This is so because it is precisely in this

    type of government that a party (or parties) other than the presidents may gather a majority

    to pass legislation and still be unable to change the status quo if the president prefers the

    latter to the new policy and the legislative majority lacks the necessary votes to override his

    veto. In other words, neither the president (who lacks a majority) nor the opposition parties

    (who lack the votes to override a veto) are able to rule. The risk of a stalemate, of course,

    is the reason why this type of presidential regime is often supposed to constitute the most

    undecisive, costly, and conflictive form of minority government. But this association lacks

    theoretical foundations.

    The occurrence of gridlock under divided government depends on the location of the

    legislative status quo and the policy preferences of the pivotal actors, in this case, the

    presidents (or veto) party and the median party (Krehbiel 1998). If the initial status-quo

    policy is located in between the preferences of the median party and the president with

    effective veto, policy changes may be, in effect, impossible. The president will veto any

    change approaching the outcome to the median partys preference and moving it away from

    the presidential one. It is for this reason that the policy space between the two decisive

    actors defines the 'gridlock interval', that is, the set of policy decisions that will be stable in

    spite of the existence of a legislative majority favoring policy change as illustrated in

    Figure 2.

    But whenever the legislative status quo is outside the gridlock interval, policy change is

    still possible. If the legislative status quo is located at a rather extreme position with respect

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    12/36

    12

    to the ideal points of the decisive actors, policy change may occur at exactly the ideal point

    of the median party. This is so because the president will not veto proposals made by the

    median party if they are closer to his preferences than the status quo is. In addition, if the

    legislative status quo is outside the gridlock interval but closer to the preferences of the

    president than the ideal point of the median party is, policy change is also possible if the

    median party moderates its proposal to make the president at least indifferent between

    using the veto or signing the bill. As Cameron (2000) point out, whenever the president

    has an incentive to veto policy changes and congress knows it, the latter will anticipate the

    veto and modify the content of the new policy to head it off.

    In other words, policy immobilism is not a structural trait of divided government.

    Presidents will support policy change when the new policy brings them more utility than

    the status quo does and also when the legislative majority, anticipating a veto, modifies

    legislation to induce the president to accept a new policy.

    This does not mean, of course, that we should expect from divided government the same

    level of government effectiveness and inter-branch cooperation as we can expect from

    median presidential government. To the contrary, divided government is likely to produce

    less legislative change and at higher cost than a minority but median presidential

    government. In addition, we should expect divided government to produce gridlock from

    time to time and, in the absence of perfect information among the players, inter-branch

    conflict as well. The central point is simply that looking at divided government as the worst

    possible situation for minority presidents may be looking at the wrong place.

    Following the logic of this analysis, a third possible category of government in a

    separation-of-powers system is that where a party different from the presidents controls

    both the median and the veto legislator. To keep symmetry with the previous concepts we

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    13/36

    13

    can call this form of government congressional, which just like the presidential one,

    may include two possible situations. One, which we can call unified congressional, takes

    place when a party different from the presidents controls not only 50 percent of the seats in

    congress but also the number of seats necessary to override a presidential veto. This form of

    government is likely to occur in two-party systems with a low veto override, usually an

    absolute majority.5 A second situation, which we can call median congressional, is that

    where the policy position of an opposition party allows it to control the veto and the median

    legislator, even without having a majority of its own. This form of government is more

    likely in multiparty presidential systems, also with a low veto override.

    [Figure 3 here]

    Congressional government is in principle the most complex form of government in a

    separation-of-powers system. Not only the president has no control over the medial

    legislator but he also lacks an effective veto. For this reason, everything else being equal,

    one should expect congressional government to be less decisive and more conflictive than

    both median presidential and divided government.

    In Table I, I have listed the types of government that according to this classification have

    existed in 18 Latin American countries since the last inauguration of a democratic regime.

    Within each country, presidencies are classified according to the legislative share of the

    presidents party and its policy location vis--vis the location of the median and the veto

    party on a left-right scale. Whenever a nonconcurrent congressional election changed any

    5As we will see, the only two cases of unified congressional government in Latin America since the

    beginning of the transition to democracy were the presidencies of Betancourt from 1982-86 and Pastrana from

    1998-2002 in Colombia, a country that gathers the two characteristics just mentioned.

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    14/36

    14

    of these relative positions, the correspondent years of the presidency are counted as a

    different case. According to this methodology, the table gathers 97 cases, of which 33

    correspond to unified presidential government, 22 to median presidential government, 22 to

    divided government and 21 to congressional government. The total number of minority

    presidencies located in the median, divided, and congressional category represents a clear

    majority of 64 cases, or 66 percent of the sample.

    [Table I here]

    It is important to note how this classification of presidential regimes, and the predictions

    one can obtain from it, differs from the conventional analysis based on the levels of party

    fragmentation. In the first place, as I noted before, it is not simply the ENP but the veto

    override rule what matters to classify certain kinds of minority governments.

    Both Chile under Alwyn (1989-94) and Per under Fujimori I (1990-92) had an ENP in the

    Lower House above 5. However, while the Chilean constitution requires 2/3 of the vote in

    each chamber to override a presidential veto, in Per congress could override a veto with

    only a majority of votes in each chamber. Thus the classification of Chiles Alwyn as

    divided and Pers Fujimori I as congressional government. On the other hand, Colombia

    under Betancourt (1982-86), and Pastrana (1998-2002) had an ENP in the Lower Chamber

    of 1.97 and 2.09, respectively. However, since the presidents party did not reach a majority

    of seats and the constitution required a majority of votes to override a veto, a party different

    from the presidents was able to control the law-making process thus creating a unified

    congressional government. Table II shows the relation between ENP, veto strength and

    presidential types of government.

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    15/36

    15

    [Table II here]

    Perhaps more important is the fact that even if we hold constant the ENP and veto override

    rules within one country, presidencies may still differ according to the policy location of

    the decisive players. Bolivia is the case in point. Both during the presidencies of Paz

    Estenssoro and Siles Suazo the ENP in the Lower Chamber was above 4 and the

    constitution required 2/3 of a joint session of congress to override a presidential veto.

    Nevertheless, while Paz Estenssoros MNR occupied the position of the median party in

    congress, Siles Suazos UDP had a rather extreme location in the policy space and

    possessed only a veto to negotiate with the opposition. Logically, one cannot expect the

    same consequences from these two very different cases of presidential governance.

    Minority presidents and coalition-making

    In the previous section I have argued that, other things being equal, congressional

    government should be expected to be the least decisive and most conflictive form of

    minority government. Yet, congressional government opens up different possibilities, not

    all them implying the same negative consequences for democratic governance.

    A non-median minority president who also lacks an effective veto has two basic options:

    either to accept or to challenge congressional rule. Acquiescence to congressional rule

    would usually take the form of a coalitional government in which non-median presidents

    may try to overcome their disadvantage in congress by creating a majority executive

    coalition or a minority coalition including the median party in congress. Defiance to

    congressional rule, instead, would usually take the form of unilateral presidential

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    16/36

    16

    government, either by using powers granted by the constitution, like decrees, or by extra-

    constitutional actions, like the usurpation of legislative powers or the irregular dissolution

    of congress. Clearly enough, it is only when presidents prefer to challenge congressional

    rule that congressional government should be the most problematic form of government in

    a separation-of-powers system.

    In order to explain this choice, we need to take a step back and look more closely at the

    more general problem of coalition-making under presidential regimes.6 The separate origin

    and survival of presidents and assemblies creates several structural differences between the

    process of coalition-making in multiparty presidential and multiparty parliamentary

    regimes. In the first place, whereas in a presidential regime the constitution establishes that

    the president is the formateur regardless of the representation of his party in congress and

    its policy location, in a parliamentary regime the formateur is usually the largest and/or the

    median legislative party (Laver and Schofield 1990). In addition, while the autonomy of

    presidents in terms of government formation is subject to variations, in a parliamentary

    regime cabinets are strictly dependent on legislative support to obtain investiture and win

    confidence votes. These differences, should and do make coalition governments a more

    frequent event under parliamentarism than under presidentialism (Samuels and Eaton 2002;

    Cheibub, Przeworski, and Saiegh 2002).

    Within presidential regimes, however, one should expect variations in the frequency and

    nature of coalitions depending on the type of government. Table III shows these variations

    according to whether an executive coalition is formed, whether the party members of the

    coalition hold together a majority of seats in congress, and whether a minority coalition

    6On cabinet coalitions in presidential regimes, see Deheza (1997), Amorim Neto (1998), Altman (2001),

    Chasquetti (2001), and Amorim Neto (2001).

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    17/36

    17

    includes the median party in congress.7 An executive (or government) coalition is defined

    here as the set of legislators belonging to parties that hold cabinet positions. This coalition

    is considered to be a majority coalition only if the parties holding cabinet posts gather a

    majority of seats in one chamber for unicameral assemblies or in both chambers for

    bicameral assemblies.

    [Table III here]

    As one would expect, Table III shows that the frequency of executive coalition formation is

    the lowest in unified presidential government (.22). The reason is that in this category,

    obviously, presidents do not need outside support to accomplish their agendas. One of the

    frequent reasons why presidents form coalitions in spite of the fact that their parties have

    majorities in congress is the intention to integrate a National Unity government in the

    context of power-sharing agreements, as did Betancourt (1958-63) in Venezuela and the

    Colombian presidents who continued the practice initiated with the National Front (1958-

    74) until president Barco abandoned it (1986-90).

    Among the different categories of minority presidents, the lowest percentage of coalitions

    in general (.28) and of majority coalitions in particular (.00) corresponds to divided

    governments. In 2 out of 18 cases (.11), the presidencies of Alwyn (1989-94) and Frei

    (1994-200) in Chile minority coalitions included the median party, but only for the

    Chamber of Deputies.8 This case is not immediately intuitive but it may fit the logic of

    divided government explained above. Since in this situation minority presidents have a

    7The presidencies of Prez Balladares and Moscoso in Panam were excluded due to the absence of

    information.8

    The median position in the senate has been consistently occupied since 1989 by the RN, which for obvious

    ideological reasons can never be part of a center-left executive coalition.

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    18/36

    18

    weapon (the veto) to force concessions from legislative majorities, they might not need an

    executive coalition to influence policy. At the same time, it may be the case that in divided

    government opposition parties also lack the incentives to give explicit support to the

    government by joining an executive coalition. Since party fragmentation is on average

    moderate in divided government, the median party (by definition the party whose support is

    necessary to provide the president with the support of a legislative majority) may be one of

    the main opposition parties which needs to differentiate its position from the government in

    order to compete in coming presidential elections.

    In median presidential governments coalitions are formed with a relatively high frequency

    of 52 percent for coalitions in general and 38 percent for majority coalitions. A minority

    president whose party controls the median legislator in congress may form a single-party

    government and still be able to obtain majority support in congress. For the same reason,

    however, a median president has nothing to lose in terms of policy and may actually obtain

    some electoral benefit (in terms of public image, for instance) by incorporating outside

    parties to the executive coalition. Opposition parties, in turn, may derive some utility from

    office by supporting policies that they would approve anyway. This is precisely the

    argument used in parliamentary regimes to explain why a median minority party, knowing

    it will be dominant in policy terms, may either chose to form a single-party government, a

    minimal winning or a surplus majority coalition (Laver and Schofield 1990).

    Congressional government, in turn, is the minority government with the highest number of

    coalitions. In 20 out 23 cases (.87) presidents in this category ruled through executive

    coalitions. Given that congressional government on average occurs at relatively high levels

    of party fragmentation, this result clearly shows that, against a previously held belief in the

    literature, neither coalitions are rare in minority governments nor party fragmentation

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    19/36

    19

    makes coalition-making more difficult.9 The incentives of presidents to form executive

    coalitions seem clear in the case of congressional government: neither their parties have a

    pivotal role in policy-making nor they have an instrument, like the veto, to shape

    legislation. At the same time, given the presence of many small parties in this type of

    government it may be that parties in the opposition also have an interest in joining the

    government either because they have no chance of winning coming presidential elections or

    because even if they win, they will not be able to govern alone.

    Yet, although most minority presidents in this category managed to incorporate outside

    parties in the cabinet, not all them forged coalitions that would make congressional

    government viable in policy terms. Of the 23 cases, only 9 (.39) presidents managed to

    form a majority coalition. In addition, in 1 case (.04), the presidency of Lagos (2000-06) in

    Chile, a minority coalition included the median party, but only in the Chamber of

    Deputies. The obvious question, then, is why some presidents in congressional government

    did while others did not form viable coalitions.

    One possible answer is that not all presidents in this situation (regardless of the incentives

    of opposition parties) may have the same incentives to rely on outside support to govern.

    One of the assumptions of the pivotal model of decision-making outlined above was that no

    player has special agenda-setting powers. In reality, however, many presidents do have

    these powers and they can used them to change legislation without sufficient legislative

    support. This is the case, in particular, with the ability of presidents to issue decrees of

    legislative content. These powers may allow non-median minority presidents to change the

    legislative status quo and impose a new policy if the median party in congress prefers the

    latter to the reversionary outcome, that is, the outcome that would result from rejecting the

    9Cheibub, Przewroski and Saiegh (2002) show a similar finding.

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    20/36

    20

    decree after it produced effects (Figueiredo and Limongi 1998; Negretto forthcoming). If

    this is the case, then, a president invested with these powers may not feel the need to rely

    on a majority coalition as much as a president without them.

    At the same time, the incentives of presidents to make viable coalitions may also be

    determined by their degree of autonomy in terms of the formation and maintenance of

    cabinets. In spite of the separate origin of presidents and assemblies that characterizes

    presidential regimes, there is wide range of variation in terms of congressional control over

    cabinets (Shugart and Carey 1992; Colomer and Negretto 2003). A president who has the

    formal power to appoint and remove cabinet members may be in fact restricted in his

    degree of autonomy if legislators are able to vote a binding censure or impeach ministers

    by majority vote. The same could happen if in the absence of majority winners in a

    presidential election, congress regularly intervenes in the final selection of presidents,

    somewhat resembling the investiture vote in a parliamentary system.

    With these elements in mind, we can make sense of the choice that minority presidents in a

    congressional form of government have. The incentives to accept congressional rule by

    building a portfolio coalition large enough to muster majority support in congress should be

    greater when presidents are subject to congressional control and have no decree powers

    than when they face no congressional control and/or have decree powers.10 Table IV lists

    the information about coalition-making in congressional government along with the

    relevant institutional variables for each case. A president was considered to have decree

    powers if the constitution explicitly grants him the authority to initiate policy by decree

    (constitutional decree authority or CDA) or when general emergency provisions include the

    capacity of presidents to make law and regulate rights by decree. A congress was

    10Amorim Neto and Tafner (2002) and Amorim Neto (2002) show that there is a relation between the use and

    existence of decree powers and coalition-making strategies.

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    21/36

    21

    considered to have control over cabinets when presidents are selected by congress or when

    legislators from opposition parties had the necessary votes established by the constitution to

    propose and decide a binding censure and/or impeach ministers.11

    [Table IV here]

    According to this table, a large majority of 18, out of 23 presidents in the category of

    congressional government had the capacity to issue decrees of legislative content. Only 6

    (.26) of these presidents formed policy viable coalitions while 13 of them (.56) either did

    not form coalitions or formed a non-median minority coalition. In addition, while 13

    presidents were subject to congressional control, only in 3 cases ( 2 in Bolivia and 1 in

    Uruguay) presidents were both subject to congressional control and had no decree powers.

    In these 3 cases presidents formed majority executive coalitions.

    This analysis cannot conclusive since too many presidents in this category hold explicit or

    residual decree powers. In fact, there may be a causal relation between minority presidents

    in congressional governments and strong proactive powers.12 Whatever the reason,

    however, it may be the frequent presence of decree powers what explains why if the

    number of coalitions is so high in congressional government so few of them hold a majority

    of seats in congress or have the support of the median party in congress.

    To sum up, not all minority presidents inevitably need a majority coalition to influence

    policy and secure a minimum of inter-branch cooperation. Some minority presidents can

    11Opposition parties usually reach the necessary votes to control cabinets when the constitution requires a

    vote by absolute majori ty in congress but congressional control could also exist with a requirement of two-

    thirds if the president lacks the support of more than one-third of legislators.12

    The existence of a correlation between CDA and separation of purpose in presidential regimes has been

    indicated by Shugart (1998) and Shugart and Haggard (2001).

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    22/36

    22

    compensate their lack of majority support with their control over the median legislator in

    congress or with their veto power. Coalition-making, however, may be crucial for minority

    presidents in congressional government and those who fail to do so in this category are

    expected to be the most problematic of all minority presidencies.

    Interrupted presidencies in Latin America

    There are several possible indicators to test the hypothesis that minority presidencies are

    different in nature and present different potential for government effectiveness and

    executive-legislative conflict. For government effectiveness, the percentage of bills

    initiated by presidents and approved by congress is one possible indicator (Saiegh 2002).

    For executive-legislative conflict, one could construct an index to measure the number of

    conflicts that each presidency experienced in terms of legislation and inter-institutional

    conflict (Jones 1995). However, in the absence of these data for all the presidencies within

    the period under consideration I will provisionally rely on a more crude but nonetheless

    significant indicator of presidential performance: the regular termination of the

    constitutionally defined presidential term.

    Presidents may end their constitutional terms prematurely either because they are ousted

    from office after a successful impeachment process, because they are forced to resign after

    the emergence of widespread social mobilizations against the government or a coup, or

    because they decide to dissolve congress as a way to govern effectively in the face of a

    particular crisis. Within the third wave of democracy in Latin America, there are 11 cases

    of interrupted presidencies. Table V provides a list of these presidencies indicating the

    president, year and reason for termination.

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    23/36

    23

    [Table V here]

    In 4 cases (Collor, Prez, Bucaram, and Cubas), presidencies were terminated in the context

    of a process of impeachment either initiated or concluded by congress, and in 1 case

    (Suazo) in the context of a series of executive-legislative conflicts that included the threat

    of impeachment. In 3 cases presidents resigned or abandoned the office, 2 times (Alfonsn

    and De la Ra) due to social mobilizations against the government and 1 time (Mahuad)

    due to an attempted coup. Finally, in 3 cases (Fujimori, Serrano and Chvez) presidents

    terminated their terms by their own decision to rule without the existing congress, although

    in 1 case (Serrano) the president failed in his attempt.

    In spite of these variations, the premature termination of a presidential term signals the

    breakdown of cooperation between presidents and congresses. Whatever the nature of the

    crisis that presidents and legislators had to face, it seems clear that either congress or the

    president saw the potential solution in the elimination of the other. From this perspective,

    the forced resignation or impeachment of presidents, on the one hand, or the dissolution of

    congress by presidents, on the other, are two possible non-cooperative outcomes of a

    bargaining game between executives and legislators.

    According to the hypothesis presented in this paper presidential regimes can be located in a

    continuum that goes from a maximum to a minimum of expected cooperation between

    separate branches of government. The maximum corresponds to unified presidential

    governments and the minimum to congressional governments without majority (or median

    minority) executive coalitions. The intermediate categories are median presidential,

    divided, and coalitional congressional government. In order to support this hypothesis, one

    should see some correlation between expected levels of cooperation and the number of

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    24/36

    24

    interrupted presidencies in each category. Table VI shows the existence of such a

    correlation.

    [Table VI here]

    As expected, unified presidential government has the lowest (.03) and minority

    congressional government the highest (.38) percentage of interrupted presidencies. Also as

    expected, median presidential governments indicate a lower percentage of inter-branch

    conflicts than divided governments. Coalitional congressional governments, in turn, have

    no cases of interruption of presidential terms.

    This does not necessarily mean that coalitional congressional government is free from

    conflicts but, rather, that the difference between having or not the support of a majority or

    median coalition is crucial when the president does not have a veto or control the median

    legislator in congress. So crucial, indeed, that it may turn the most problematic form of

    minority presidential government into a successful one.

    It is suggestive to note that most minority congressional governments in which presidents

    did finish their terms in office also presented high levels of executive-legislative conflict

    that could have ended in the same way as those who did not. The presidencies of Febres

    Cordero, Borja (for the period 1990-92), and Durn-Balln in Ecuador are all well-known

    cases of government infectiveness and executive-legislative conflict.

    All of these presidents intended to alleviate Ecuadors fiscal crisis and debt problems by

    means of austerity policies that were paralyzed or watered-down in congress. In addition,

    and as a demonstration of congressional reaction to massive social protests generated by

    those policies, opposition legislators continuously harassed the president through the

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    25/36

    25

    impeachment of his ministers (Conaghan 1995: 452-53; Isaacs 1996). In fact, in the last

    year of Borjas presidency, congress formally requested the Supreme Court to initiate

    impeachment procedures against the president himself and in 1995 (after the censure of

    several of his ministers) congress impeached Durn-Ballns vice-president. Durn-Balln

    responded with a failed attempt to call a constitutional reform to strengthen the powers of

    the president vis--vis the congress.

    Other presidencies in this category also present similar indicators of conflict. President

    Pastrana, la Chvez, intended but failed to call a referendum on constitutional reform that

    included cutting the number of congressional seats by half and calling new congressional

    elections. During Wasmosys presidency in Paraguay, executive and legislators were

    engaged in a bitter conflict that included a threat by congress to impeach the president.

    Finally, both terms of Caldera became a symbol of problematic presidencies in Venezuela.

    During his first presidency, Caldera faced permanent obstruction from congress and

    institutional attacks that eventually led to a constitutional crisis when the opposition

    approved a law depriving the president from his participation in the nomination of judges

    (Coppedge 1994: 339).13 In his second presidency, Caldera decided to face the deep

    economic crisis affecting the country by suspending economic rights and implementing

    economic measures by decree (Crisp 2000). Once congress attempted to restore those

    rights, it was forced to back down by Calderas threat to call a referendum on a proposal of

    constitutional reform which would have enabled him to dissolve congress.14

    In other words, if we were to measure the performance of presidential democracies under

    less dramatic measures of conflict than the early termination of a constitutional term, we

    13Accodring to Coppedge (1994: 339), those institutional attacks included at one point ADs attempt to

    change the presidential regime into a parliamentary one.14

    SeeLatin America Weekly Report, 11/08/94

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    26/36

    26

    would probably find that the number of critical cases within minority congressional

    government is much larger than the one presented here. This calls, of course, for a

    continuation of this research with more exhaustive tests.

    Conclusions

    Since the early 1990s, the idea that presidential regimes are inherently unstable has been

    replaced by the hypothesis that it is not presidentialism but the combination of

    presidentialism, multipartysm, and low levels of party discipline what affects government s

    effectiveness and democratic survival in separation-of-powers systems. As a consequence,

    most research on presidentialism has focused since then on the electoral variables that are

    supposed to contain party fragmentation, grant the president substantive congressional

    support and secure at least moderate levels of party discipline.

    The difficult combination hypothesis is today under attack by a series of studies that

    question the correlation between multipartysm, legislative effectiveness and democratic

    survival and point out to other variables, such as presidential term limits or the degree of

    centralization of decision-making to explain the performance of presidential regimes. To

    date, however, no study has provided a plausible and theoretically grounded explanation of

    the causal mechanisms that foster or hinder cooperation between executives and legislators

    in minority presidential governments.

    This paper is a first attempt to elaborate such an explanation. I have argued that different

    forms of presidential government should be distinguished taking into account not only the

    size of the president s party in congress but also its location in the policy space and its

    relation with two pivotal actors: the median and the veto legislator. Following this logic, I

    proposed that there is a continuum from more to less expected cooperation between

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    27/36

    27

    presidents and assemblies that goes from unified presidential to congressional government,

    with minority median and divided government in between. I have also suggested that

    congressional government is the least effective and most conflictive form of minority

    government only when presidents fail or do not attempt to build executive coalitions

    holding a majority of seats or including the median party in congress.

    In order to test this hypothesis, I used the constitutional (impeachment, forced resignation)

    or unconstitutional (coups) interruption of a presidential term as an indicator of terminal

    institutional conflict between presidents and assemblies and found that the hypothesis,

    although not probed, is at least plausible. Of the 11 presidents that left office before the

    term specified in the constitution, the largest percentage corresponded to the predicted most

    conflictive category. Although the number of cases was small, no constitutional term was

    interrupted when presidents in congressional governments formed majority coalitions

    suggesting that coalition-making may indeed be a key variable to explain government

    survival under difficult circumstances.

    The analysis provided in this paper suggests that research on presidential democracies

    should shift from its exclusive focus on electoral variables affecting the effective number of

    parties to the electoral and institutional variables that make cooperation between branches

    possible in the absence of a legislative majority supporting the president in congress. In this

    respect, a new research agenda should pay attention to the electoral formulas that make

    more likely than others the selection of presidents whose parties occupy a median position

    in congress, the influence of presidential vetoes on policy output, and the interaction

    between the proactive legislative powers of presidents and congressional control over

    cabinets over the likelihood of majority coalition formation.

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    28/36

    28

    Decisive actors in Congress

    Veto

    legislator

    Median

    legislator

    Presidents party

    Outcome

    President

    Figure 1. Presidential government

    Presidents party

    Gridlock interval

    President

    Figure 2. Divided government

    Median

    legislator

    Veto

    legislator

    Median party

    Figure 3. Congressional government

    Veto

    legislator

    Median

    legislator

    Presidents party

    Outcome

    President

    Median party

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    29/36

    29

    Table I. Types of Government in Latin America

    Presidential Divided Congressional

    Unified Unified

    Argentina 1995-97 (Menem II) Argentina 1983-89 (Alfonsn) Colombia 1982-86 (Betancourt)

    Colombia 1974-78 (L: Michelsen) Bolivia 1980-85 (S. Suazo) Colombia 1998-2002 (Pastrana)

    Colombia 1978-82 (Turbay) Chile 1989-94 (Alwyn) MedianColombia 1986-90 (Barco) Chile 1994-2000 (Frei) Argentina 1999-2001 (De la Rua)

    Colombia 1990-94 (Gaviria) Costa Rica 1966-70 (T. Fernandez) Bolivia 1989-93 (P. Zamora)

    Colombia 1994-98 (Samper) Costa Rica 1978-82 (C. Odio) Bolivia 1997-2001 (Bnzer)

    Costa Rica 1953-58 (Figueres I) Costa Rica 2002-06 (Pacheco E.) Brazil 1985-90 (Sarney)

    Costa Rica 1962-66 (Orlich) Dom. Rep. 1986-90 (Balaguer) Brazil 1990-92 (Collor)

    Costa Rica 1970-74 (Figueres II) Dom. Rep. 1990-94 (Balaguer) Brazil 1992-94 (Franco)

    Costa Rica 1982-86 (Monge A.) Dom. Rep. 1994-96 (Balaguer) Brazil 1994-98 (Cardozo I)

    Costa Rica 1986-90 (Arias S.) Dom. Rep. 1998-2000 (F. Reyna) Brazil 1998-2002 (Cardozo II)

    Costa Rica 1990-94 (Caldern F.) Dom. Rep. 2002-04 (H. Meja) Chile 2000-06 (Lagos)

    Costa Rica 1998-2002 (Rodriguez) Ecuador 1998-2002 (Mahuad) Ecuador 1984-88 (F. Cordero)

    Dom. Rep. 2000-02 (Hiplito M.D.) El Salvador 1988-89 (Duarte) Ecuador 1990-1992 (Borja)

    El Salvador 1985-88 (Duarte) El Salvador 1991-94 (Cristiani) Ecuador 1992-96(Durn-Balln)

    El Salvador 1989-91 (Cristiani) El Salvador 1994-99 (Caldern) Guatemala 1991-95 (Serrano)

    Guatemala 1986-91 (Cerezo) El Salvador 1999-2002 (Flores) Paraguay 1993-98 (Wasmosy)

    Guatemala 1995-99 (Arz) Mexico 2000-2003 (Fox) Per 1990-92 (Fujimori I)

    Guatemala 1999-2003 (Portillo) Panam 1999-2004 (Moscoso) Uruguay 1989-94 (Lacalle)

    Honduras 1981-85 (Suazo Crdoba) Total divided=19 Venezuela 1968-73 (Caldera I)

    Honduras 1985-89 (Azcona) Venezuela 1978-83 (H. Campins)

    Honduras 1989-93 (Callejas) Venezuela 1993-98 (Caldera II)

    Honduras 1993-97 (Reina) Venezuela 1998-2000 (Chvez I)

    Honduras 1997-2001 (Flores) Venezuela 2000-2006 (Chvez II)

    Nicaragua 1990-96 (Barrios) Total congressional=23

    Nicaragua 2001-06 (Bolaos)Paraguay 1989-93 (Rodriguez)

    Paraguay 1998-2002 (Cubas/ G. M)

    Per 1985-90 (Alan Garca)

    Per 1995-2000 (Fujimori II)

    Venezuela 1958-63 (Betancourt)

    Venezuela 1973-78 (Andres Prez I)

    Venezuela 1983-88 (Lusinchi)

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    30/36

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    31/36

    31

    Table II: ENP, Veto Strength and Type of Government

    Average ENP Range ENP % strong veto Type of government2.33 1.89-2.98 59 Unified presidential

    3.32 2.29-5.0 54 Median presidential

    3.5 2.1-6.5 100 Divided

    4.8 1.97-8.68 25 Congressional

    Table III. Frequency and Type of Executive Coalitions

    Type of Government Executive coalitions Majority coalitions Median coalitions

    Unified presidential .21 - -

    Median presidential .52 .38 -

    Divided .28 .00 .11

    Congressional .87 .39 .04

    Table IV. Coalition-Making in Congressional GovernmentsPresidency Coalition Majority Median Decree powers Congressional control

    De la Ra Yes No No Yes (CDA) Yes

    Paz Zamora Yes Yes No No Yes

    Bnzer Suarez Yes Yes No No Yes

    Sarney Yes Yes Yes Yes (CDA) No

    Collor Yes No No Yes (CDA) No

    Franco Yes Yes Yes Yes (CDA) No

    Cardoso I Yes Yes Yes Yes (CDA) No

    Cardoso II Yes Yes Yes Yes (CDA) No

    Lagos Yes No Yes No* No

    Betancourt Yes Yes Yes Yes (CDA) NoPastrana Yes No No Yes (CDA) Yes

    Febres Cordero No - - Yes (CDA) Yes

    Rodrigo Borja Yes No No Yes (CDA) Yes

    Durn-Balln Yes No No Yes (CDA) Yes

    Serrano Yes No No Yes (emergency) Yes

    Wasmosy No - - No No

    Fujimori I Yes No No Yes (emergency) Yes

    Lacalle Yes Yes Yes No Yes

    Caldera I Yes No No Yes (emergency) Yes

    H. Campins No - - Yes (emergency) No

    Caldera II Yes No No Yes (emergency) Yes

    Chvez I Yes No No Yes (emergency) Yes

    Chvez II Yes Yes Yes Yes (emergency) No

    Source: Elaborated by the author based on Zucco (2002) and Cidob.com for coalitions, and Political Data

    Base of the Americas for decree powers and congressional control

    *CDA restricted to budgetTotal cases=23

    Cases with executive coalition= 20

    Cases with majority or median minority coalition=10

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    32/36

    32

    Table V. Interrupted presidencies in Latin America 1980-2001

    President Month/Year MotiveSiles Suazo November/1984 Forced resignation in the context of an

    economic crisis, social upheaval, threat of a

    coup, and executive-legislative conflicts,including a threat of impeachment

    Alfonsn July/1989 Forced resignation in the midst of an

    economic crisis and social upheaval

    Fujimori April/1992 Dissolution of congress by president with

    support of the military after a series of

    executive-legislative conflicts on thepowers of the president to rule by decree on

    the areas of economic management and

    terrorism

    Collor August/1992 Impeachment by congress due to charges of

    corruption in the midst of an economic

    crisis, social upheaval and a long series ofexecutive-legislative conflicts

    Serrano May/ 1993 Forced resignation after a failed attempt to

    dissolve congress and rule with support ofthe military

    Andrs Prez II August/1993 Destitut ion by congress due to charges of

    corruption initiated after a violent socialupheaval against the presidents economic

    policy and a failed coup

    Bucarm February/1997 Destitution by congress under the charges

    of mental incapacity initiated after social

    social mobilizations against the presidents

    economic policy and the alleged corruptionof the government

    Cubas March /1999 Resignation after impeachment process

    initiated by the chamber of deputies

    Chvez April/1999 Convocation of an irregular constituentassembly that terminated the previous

    constitutional period and replaced existingcongress

    Mahuad January/2000 Abandonment of presidency after social

    upheaval and an attempted coup

    De la Ra December/2001 Forced resignation due to social

    mobilization against De la Ras economic

    policy and after the opposition in congress

    rejected the possibility of a national union

    coalition to support the government

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    33/36

    33

    Table VI. Interrupted presidencies per type of government

    Type Cases Interrupted presidencies Percentage

    Unified presidential 33 1 .03

    Median presidential 22 2 .09Divided 19 3 .16

    Coalitional congressional 10 0 .00

    Minority congressional 13 5 .38

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    34/36

    34

    Bibliography

    Amorim Neto, Octavio.1998. Of Presidents, Parties and Ministers: Cabinet Formation andLegislative Decision-Making Under Separation of Powers. Unpublished PhD

    dissertation, University of California, San Diego

    _____________________.2002.Presidential Policy-Making Strategies and CabinetFormation in Latin Americas Presidential Democracies, 1946-1995. Paperpresented at the conference on El Gobierno Dividido en Mxico: Riesgos yOportunidades,May 6-7. 2002, C.I.D.E, Mexico City

    Amorim Neto, Octavio y Paulo Tafner. (2002). Governos de Coalizao e Mecanismos de Alarme eIncendio no Controle Legislativo das Medidas Provisorias.Dados, 45 (1), 5-38

    Cameron, Charles M. 2000. Veto Bargaining. Presidents and the Politics of NegativePowers. Nueva York: Cambridge University Press.

    Carey, John y Matthew S. Shugart. 1998 eds.Executive Decree Authority. Nueva York:

    Cambridge University Press.Chasquetti, Daniel. 2001. Democracia, Multipartidismo, y Coaliciones en Amrica Latina:

    Evaluando la Difcil Combinacin.In Jorge Lanzaro (ed.), Tipos dePresidencialismo y Coaliciones Polticas en Amrica Latina. Buenos Aires:CLACSO.

    Cheibub, Jos Antonio.2002. Minority Presidents, Deadlock Situations, and the Survivalof Presidential Democracies.Unpublished manuscript, Yale University.

    Cheibub, Jos Antonio, Adam Przeworski, and Sebastan Saiegh. 2002. GovernmentCoalitions and Legislative Effectiveness Under Presidentialism andParliamentarism, unpublished manuscript.

    Cheibub, Jos Antonio, and Fernando Limongi. 2002. Modes of Government Formationand the Survival of Presidential Regimes: Presidentialism and Parliamentarism

    Reconsidered.Annual Review of Political Science.

    Colomer, Josep and Gabriel Negretto. 2003. Governanza con Poderes Divididos enAmrica Latina. Poltica y Gobierno, January-March.

    Conaghan, Catherine M. 1995. Politicians Against Parties: Discord and Disconnection inEcuadors Party System. In Scott Mainwaring and Timothy Scully. Building

    Democratic Institutions: Party Systems in Latin America, Stanford: StanfordUniversity Press.

    Coppedge, Michael. 1994. Venezuela: Democratic despite Presidentialism, in Juan Linz

    and Arturo Valenzuela (eds.). The Failure of Presidential Democracy. Baltimore:The Johns Hopkins University Press.

    ______________ 1997. A Classification of Latin American Political Parties. WorkingPaper #244, Kellog Institute, University of Notre Dame.

    Crisp, Brian. 2000. Democratic Institutional Design: The Powers and Incentives ofVenezuelan Politicians and Interest Groups. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Deheza, Grace Ivana. 1998. Gobiernos de coalicin en el sistema presidencial: America

    del Sur, in Dieter Nohlen and Mario Fernndez (eds.). El presidencialismorenovado: Institucionalismo y cambio poltico en America Latina. Caracas: nuevaSociedad: 151-169.

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    35/36

    35

    Figueiredo, Argelina Chebub, y Feranado Limongi. 1998. Institutional legacies andaccountability: executive decrees in Brazil and Italy. Paper presented at the

    Conference on Institutional Legacies, Buenos Aires.Isaacs, Anita. 1996. Ecuador: Democracy Standing the Test of Time?. In Jorge

    Domnguez and Abraham Lowenthal (eds.), Constructing Democratic Governance:

    South America in the 1990s. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.

    Jones, Mark P. 1995. Electoral Laws and the Survival of Presidential Democracies. NotreDame, Ind.: University of Notre Dame Press.

    Krehbiel, Keith. 1996. Institutional and Partisan Sources of Gridlock: A Theory ofDivided and Unified Government',Journal of Theoretical Politics, 8: 7-40.

    -- 1998. Pivotal Politics: A Theory of U.S. Lawmaking. Chicago: The University ofChicago Press.

    Lanzaro, Jorge ed. 2001. Tipos de presidencialismo y coaliciones polticas en AmricaLatina. Buenos Aires: CLACSO.

    Laver, Michael y Kenneth Shepsle. 1991. Divided Government: America Is Not

    Exceptional, Governance, 4, 3, 250-69.Linz, Juan J. 1990a. The Perils of Presidentialism,Journal of Democracy, 1, 1: 51- 69.

    -- 1990b. 'The Virtues or Parliamentarism,Journal of Democracy, 1, 4: 84-91.Linz, Juan y Arturo Valenzuela eds. 1994. The Failure of Presidential Democracy.

    Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Mainwaring, Scott. 1993. Presidentialism, Mutipartism, and Democracy: The DifficultCombination, Comparative Political Studies, 26: 198- 228.

    Mainwaring, Scott, and Timothy Scully (eds.). 1995. Building Democratic Institutions:Party Systems in Latin America, Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Mainwaring, Scott y Matthew S. Shugart eds. 1997. Presidentialism and Democracy in

    Latin America. Nueva York: Cambridge University Press.Negretto, Gabriel., forthcoming. Government Capacities and Policy-Making by Decree in

    Latin America: The Cases of Brazil and Argentina , Comparative Political Studies.

    Nohlen, Dieter y Mario Fernndez B. eds. 1998. El presidencialismo renovado. Caracas:Nueva Sociedad.

    Przeworski, Adam, Michael E. Alvarez, Jos A. Cheibub y Fernando Limogi. 2000.Democracy and Development. Nueva York: Cambridge University Press.

    Shugart, Mattthew. 1995. The Electoral Cycle and Institutional Sources of DividedGovernment.American Political Science Review 89 (2): 327-43Saiegh. Sebastan. 2002. Coalition-Formation, Cross-Voting and Legislative Success: A

    Model of Presidential Policymaking with Application to Argentina. Paper presentedat the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston,

    August 29-September 1, 2002Samuels, David, and Kent Eaton. Presidentialism And, Or, and Versus Parliamentarism:

    The State of the Literature and an Agenda for Future Research. Paper presented atthe Conference on Consequences of Political Institutions in Democracy, DukeUniversity, April-5-7, 2002.

    Shugart, Matthew S. y John M. Carey. 1992. Presidents and Assemblies. ConstitutionalDesign and Electoral Dynamics. Nueva York: Cambridge University Press.

    Shugar, Matthew. 1998. The Inverse Relation Between Party Strength and Executive

    Strength: A Theory of Politicians Constitutional Choices. British Journal ofPolitical Science, 28, 1-29.

  • 8/6/2019 NegrettoGabriel II[1]

    36/36

    36

    Strom, Kaare. 1990. Minority Government and Majority Rule. Cambridge, Mass.:Cambridge University Press.