immigrant and ethnic enterprise in north america* · immigrant and ethnic enterprise in north a...

23
This article was downloaded by: [T&F Internal Users], [Zoe Sternberg] On: 28 June 2013, At: 01:08 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Ethnic and Racial Studies Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rers20 Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America Ivan Light a a University of California, Los Angeles Published online: 13 Sep 2010. To cite this article: Ivan Light (1984): Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America , Ethnic and Racial Studies, 7:2, 195-216 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/01419870.1984.9993441 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae, and drug doses should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand, or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.

Upload: truongthuy

Post on 15-Jun-2019

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

This article was downloaded by: [T&F Internal Users], [Zoe Sternberg]On: 28 June 2013, At: 01:08Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House,37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

Ethnic and Racial StudiesPublication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rers20

Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North AmericaIvan Light aa University of California, Los AngelesPublished online: 13 Sep 2010.

To cite this article: Ivan Light (1984): Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America , Ethnic and Racial Studies, 7:2,195-216

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/01419870.1984.9993441

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematicreproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form toanyone is expressly forbidden.

The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contentswill be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae, and drug doses shouldbe independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims,proceedings, demand, or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly inconnection with or arising out of the use of this material.

Page 2: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

Immigrant and ethnic enterprise inNorth America*

Ivan LightUniversity of California, Los Angeles

In the decade 1820-30, 80 per cent of free white Americans owned theirown means of livelihood (Corey, 1966: 113). This decade was the high-water mark of self-employment in America, and subsequent trends haveshown an almost uninterrupted decline. Generations of sociologists havedeclared that business self-employment in the modern United States hasbecome an economic anachronism which is in the process of disappearance(light, 1979: 31). Following Marx on this point, they have observed thatthe progressive concentration of capital reduced the once numerous classof free enterpreneurs that existed in the last century. Indeed, three decadesago C. W. Mills (1951) already showed the steady decline of agriculturaland non-agricultural self-employment in the United States between 1870and 1950:

A larger number of small businesses are competing for a smaller share ofthe market. The stratum of urban entrepreneurs has been narrowing, andwithin it concentration has been going on. Small business becomes smaller,big business becomes bigger. (Mills 1951: 24)

After Mills wrote this evaluation the decline of self-employment in theAmerican labor force unambiguously continued until 1973. In that year aslim majority of American farmers continued to be self-employed, but lessthan 7 per cent of non-farm workers were self-employed (Ray, 1975). Giventhese trends, government and business analysts agreed that the probability ofself-employment had become poorer than in the past and its rewards corres-pondingly more meagre (Cingolani, 1973: 8-10; Special Task Force, 1973:21). In this economic context, social scientists generally concluded that smallbusiness self-employment was incompatible with capitalist economic concen-tration and could be expected to slide into oblivion for this reason (Bottomore,1966: 50; O'Connor, 1973: 29-30; Horvat, 1982: 11-15; Auster andAldrich, 1981).

However, on the cultural side, sociologists had to explain the atavisticpersistence of entrepreneurial values and ambitions in the American laborforce (Chinoy, 1952; Walker and Guest, 1952) as well as the extent of self-employment among the wage-earning population (Iipset and Bendix, 1959:

Ethnic and Racial Studies Volume 7 Number 2 April 1984© R.K.P. 1984 0141-9870/84/0702-0195 $1.50/1

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 3: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

Table 1. Self-employed and unpaid family workers in the United States, 1948-79 (number in thousands)

1948

Non-agricultural industriesTotal employedSelf-employedPercent of totalUnpaid family workersPercent of total

AgricultureTotal employedSelf-employedPercent of totalUnpaid family workersPercent of total

1948

51,9756,109

11.83850.7

6,3094,664

73.91,31820.9

1958

56,8636,102

10.75881.0

4,6453,081

66.394120.3

1968

72,9005,102

7.04850.7

3,2661,98560.855016.8

1972

78,9295,332

6.85170.7

3,0051,789

59.546715.5

1979

94,6056,652

7.04550.5

2,9931,58052.8

. 30410.1

Source: T. Scott Fain, 'Self-Employed Americans: Their Number Has Increased,' Monthly Labor Review 103 (1980):Table 1, p. 4.

!

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 4: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197

102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it waseasy to understand entrepreneurial ambitions and frustrated aspirations ascultural residuals of an economically bygone era (Vidich and Bensman,1960: 305-6). Thus, Riesman (1950) juxtaposed the 'inner-directed' old-fashioned individualism of yesteryear's entrepreneurs with the gr-1 -handed'other-direction' of corporate executives, finding in this contrast a shifc inthe modal personality from the former to the latter. In a similar exercise,Miller and Swanson (1958: 123) found that achievement imagery in theAmerican middle class had shifted away from self-employment towardbureaucratic careers in corporate hierarchies. Bell's (1976: 84) analysis ofthe 'cultural contradictions of capitalism' identified the Puritan traditionas a self-destructive rationality whose adolescent heirs had discarded thedisciplines of planning and work in favor of 'voluptuary hedonism'.

Entrepreneurship's protracted decline provided a neat illustration ofcultural lag, the belated adjustment of superstructure to changes in produc-tion relations (Aronowitz, 1973: 257). A small business economy neededentrepreneurial motivations in its labor force. When the economic basis ofsmall business deteriorated, socialization lagged behind, continuing to produceentrepreneurial ambitions and values in lifelong wage workers (Lynd andLynd, 1937: 70). The temporary result was a glut of disappointed aspirantsfor small business self-employment, a situation of imbalance between supplyand demand (O'Connor, 1973: 29-30). Ultimately, the market's surplus ofaspiring entrepreneurs reached back into the socialization system, causingreallocation of motivational resources away from this overpopulated occu-pation in diminishing demand. As salaried workers corrected their aspirationsfor realistic prospects, the social origins of American small business ownersdeclined (Newcomer, 1961: 490; Meyer, 1947: 347; Mills, 1966). By 1952the 'creed of the individual enterpriser' had become 'a working class pre-occupation' (Iipset and Bendix, 1964: 462).

Ethnic and immigrant enterprise in America

Taken very generally, cultural lag still offers a satisfactory explanation ofwhat happened to entrepreneurial individualism in twentieth-century America.However, the cultural lag orthodoxy encounters two serious objections, oneempirical, the other conceptual. First, as Giddens (1973: 177-8) has observed,the rate of decline in self-employment was never so rapid as Marxistshad expected even though the direction of change was mostly negative.Moreover, in the specific period 1972-9, 'the number of self-employedAmericans rose by more than 1.1 million, reversing decades of steady decreases'(Fain, 1980: 3). This stabilization suggests that a plateau in self-employedpopulation firmly supports an ideology of entrepreneurship among a minority(see Table 1). This conclusion is particularly appealing since Boissevain(1984) has reported that in 1978 'Common Market countries registered a netincrease in the number of entrepreneurs and family workers' thus reversingtheir postwar trend of decline.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 5: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

198 Ivan Light

Second, cultural lag orthodoxy depends upon a simplifying, inaccurateassumption of homogeneity in economy and labor force. A homogeneouseconomy means uniformity in industrial conditions among the varioussectors as well as a uniform rate of capitalist concentration in each. Laborforce homogeneity means all workers are identical in values, attitudes, skills,employment access, and return on human capital. Both assumptions areunrealistic. The USA economy actually consists of a plurality of sectorswhich differ in respect to industrial conditions, capitalist concentration,and rates of change. O'Connor's (1973) distinctions between competitive,monopoly and state sectors need attention, and this tripartite division couldeasily be augmented in the interest of exactitude (reviewed in Kallenbergand Sorenson, 1979). Additionally, the USA labor force consists of unequallysituated groups which differ in cultural heritages. At the very least, one mustdistinguish the immigrant, the nonwhite, and the native white labor forcesectors. Workers in these sectors experience differential returns on humancapital, rates of under- and unemployment, welfare and legislative support,and career opportunities.

Given variation in the economy and labor force, uneven resolution ofcultural lag follows. On the one hand, some business sectors retain contrary-to-trend compatibility with entrepreneurial activities. On the other, someworking populations retain atavistic aspirations for business self-employment.In point of fact, immigrant and nonwhite workers cluster heavily in theeconomy's competitive sector within which, by definition, a small businessmilieu persists (Waldinger, 1982:1-2; Zenner, 1982: 474; Auster and Aldrich,1983). Thus, on structural grounds alone, there is reason to predict thatold-fashioned entrepreneurial ideology should remain among immigrant andminority sector workers long after native white workers have resigned them-selves to salaried and wage employment in the monopoly and state sectors.

This situation is not really novel. In actual fact, the foreign-born havebeen overrepresented in American small business since 1880 and probablyearlier (Light, 1980: 33; Higgs, 1977: 92). Two explanations seem plausible.The first is disadvantage in the labor market. Such disadvantage causesforeigners to concentrate in small business because they suffer under- andunemployment as a result of poor English, unvalidated educational credentials,discrimination, and so forth (Reitz, 1980: 191). Anyone who is disadvantagedin the labor force derives from this unfortunate situation a special incentiveto consider self-employment, and the greater his disadvantage, the greaterhis incentive. The unemployed apple vendors of the Great Depressionepitomize the resourcefulness of workers who, unable to find wage-earningjobs, turn to any and every pitiful self-employment from economic desperation.

However, labor markets' disadvantage cannot be the whole explanation ofthis phenomenon, because some immigrant and ethnic minority groups havehigher rates of urban self-employment ('entrepreneurship') than do others(Goldscheider andKobrin, 1980: 262-75; Boissevain, 1984; Jenkins, 1984).Given equal disadvantage why do some foreign groups have higher ratesthan others, and why should the foreign-born in general have higher rates

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 6: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America 199

of business self-employment than disadvantaged native minorities, especiallyblacks (Handlin, 1959: 74)? Native blacks are more disadvantaged thannative whites, yet the blacks' rates of business self-employment have beenand remain lower than the native whites' rates and much lower than theforeign-born rates despite presumptively higher disadvantage of the blacks(Light, 1972,1979;Wright etal, 1982: 724).

Orthodox and reactive cultural contexts

The orthodox answer to this issue has fastened upon transplanted culturalendowments of various ethnic minority groups. Derived from Max Weber,this model of entrepreneurship has claimed that individuals introject culturalvalues in the course of primary socialization. When a group's values andmotivations encourage business enterprise, cultural minorities producesocialized adults who prosper in business. The prototype is Weber's (1958a)Protestant sectarians who espoused the values of diligence in a calling, thrift,profit, and individualism. These values and attendant motivations causedadult sectarians to prosper in business. With appropriate adjustments, thismodel might account for the anomalous and persistent overrepresentationof selected cultural minorities in self-employment. American examplesinclude Jews, Chinese, Japanese, Greeks, Macedonians, West Indians,Dominicans, Gypsies, Iraqi Christians, Lebanese, Koreans, and Arabs.1 Inall such cases, cultural theory has explained business overrepresentationand/or success in terms of intact, unmodified cultural heritages. A fineexample is the migration of Gypsy fortunetellers. Before debarkation inNew York City, the Gypsies already knew how to tell fortunes, and theircultural baggage included ready-to-use skills (crystal balls, tarot cards,palmistry) other groups simply lacked. Gypsy practice of these skills in theUnited States only involved the utilization of a cultural tradition for thespecific purpose of self-employment (Sway, 1983).

This view has merit, but research in ethnic enterprise has disclosed itsinadequacy. In reality, immigration and alien status release latent facilitatorswhich promote entrepreneurship independently of cultural endowments(Turner and Bonacich, 1980: 145, 148). Three facilitators are especiallyimportant. The first is psychological satisfaction arising from immigrationto a high-wage country from a low-wage country. Immigrants in the UnitedStates have recurrently proven willing to accept low money returns, longhours of labor, job-related danger, and domestic penury in order to maintainbusiness self-employment. Relative to their countries of origin, even adverseconditions look good to immigrants and, until fully adapted to the Americanstandard of living, immigrants obtain satisfaction from squalid proprietorshipsthat would not attract native-white wage earners. This is relative satisfaction.

A second, much-documented reaction is enhanced social solidarity attendantupon cultural minority status. Chain migrations create immigrant communitieswith extraordinarOy well-developed social networks. Numerous studies haveshown that these social networks create resources upon which immigrant

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 7: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

200 Ivan Light

co-ethnics can draw for business purposes (Light, 1972; Bonacich, 1973,1975 ;Bonacich and Modell, 1980; Wilson and Portes, 1980). 'The cornerstoneof an ethnic subeconomy is the communal solidarity of a minority group'(Hraba, 1979: 374). Insofar as reactive solidarity encourages immigrantentrepreneurship, a situation has brought out a collective response which isnot cultural in the orthodox sense (Young, 1971). A concrete example isthe influence of immigrant Landsmannschaften upon business enterprise.Immigrant Landsmanner belong to a primary group which did not exist assuch in their country of origin. Thus, among the Japanese of Los AngelesHiroshimakenjin formed a solidaristic subgroup within the metropolitanpopulation — all the brothers hailed from Hiroshima. On the other hand,contemporaneous residents of Hiroshima did not share the sense of localsolidarity so the immigrants had obviously created a solidarity abroad thatdid not exist in Hiroshima, their city of origin (Modell, 1977: 99-117).This is a reactive solidarity which required alien status to liberate, and assuch is quite different from the practice of fortunetelling by immigrantGypsies.

The third endowment is sojourning (Siu, 1952). Sojourning arises whenimmigrants intend to repatriate, and derive from this intention a desire toamass as much money as possible as quickly as possible. As Bonacich (1973)has shown, sojourning implies a battery of entrepreneurial motivationswhich give middleman minorities an advantage in business competition overnonsojourners. Admittedly, the cultural status of sojourning is uncertain,and the phenomenon arguably arises liturgically as well as situationally(Light, 1979: 33-4). Nonetheless, sojourning is a frequent (but not invariant)accompaniment to international immigration, and its presence provides aneconomic edge to the foreign born in small business enterprise (Zenner,1982: 458; Portes, Clark and Lopez, 1981-2: 18).

Light's (1980: 34-6) distinction between reactive and orthodox culturalcontexts of entrepreneurship is a new one necessitated by the rapidly growingliterature on this topic, but anticipated by earlier writers (Young, 1971).Orthodox and reactive contexts in Light's rubric correspond closely towhat Turner and Bonacich (1980: 145, 148) elsewhere identified as culturaland situational variables. In both cases, authors responded to the tendencyof ethnic business researchers to 'talk past' real issues on the one hand or,on the other, to engage in 'unnecessary and wasteful polemics' about pseudo-issues (Turner and Bonacich, 1980: 145,147). Authorities agree that, howevernamed, the conceptual distinctions identified do not necessitate an empiricalrepugnance because different variables can contribute to the entrepreneurshipof the same ethnic groups. Old-fashioned cultural analysis (Belshaw, 1955)stressed only orthodox etiologies, thus creating the erroneous implicationthat only culturally intact transmission affected entrepreneurship (Freedman,1959). Conversely, Bonacich's (1973) model of 'middleman minorities'ignored orthodox contributions, focussing only upon reactivities. In Light's(1972) treatment of prewar blacks and Asians in the USA the overrepresen-tation of Asians in business proprietorships is credited to reactions arising

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 8: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America 201

from relative satisfaction and immigrant solidarity as well as to rotatingcredit associations, culturally transmitted institutions fitting the orthodoxmodel (see also Woodrum, Rhodes and Feagin, 1980: 1245).

Orthodox, reactive, or mixed entrepreneurship arises when only-orthodox,only-reactive or mixed orthodox and reactive components of entrepreneurshipfigure in an empirical analysis. On the face of the available evidence, somegroups belong in one, other groups in another category. The crucial evidencearises from two comparisons. On the one hand, the foreign-born in generalhave been overrepresented in American small business since at least 1880and are still overrepresented. On the other hand some foreign-born groupshave higher rates of business self-employment than do others. For example,Jews have been and remain extraordinarily entrepreneurial whereas Irishhave been lower than the foreign-born average (Goldscheider and Kobrin,1980). The general overrepresentation of the foreign-born betokens asituationally-induced responsiveness to self-employment. This responsivenessis prima facie evidence for a reactive model. On the other hand, the higherthan average rates of selected foreign-born groups suggest unique culturalendowments. Unique endowments imply cultural heritages transmitted intact,the orthodox cultural model. The best fit of theory and evidence occurswhen theory acknowledges the additive possibilities of orthodox and reactivecomponents. On this view, the foreign-born in general experience the reactiveentrepreneurship arising from their alien situation, but middleman minorities(Jews, Chinese, Greeks,' etc.) add to this reaction their culturally intactheritages of sojourning entrepreneurship (Bonacich and Modell, 1980: Ch. 2).As a result, rates of entrepreneurship are higher among middleman minoritiesthan among the foreign-born in general, and higher among the foreign-bornthan among the native-born whites.

Ethnic and class resources

Efforts to explain ethnic and immigrant entrepreneurship invariably turn upbatteries of special causes. That is, the immigrants developed higher thanaverage rates of entrepreneurship because they drew upon special resourceswhich native groups lacked. In Barth's (1962) terminology these facilitiesconstitute entrepreneurial 'assets,' but the term resources is more generaland does not lend itself to confusion with financial assets (light, 1980:35). Ethnic resources are any and all features of the whole group whichcoethnic business owners can utilize in business or from which their businessbenefits (Reitz, 1982; Wallman, 1979a: ix; 1979b: 10). Thus, ethnic resourcesinclude orthodox cultural endowments, relative satisfaction, reactive solidar-ities, sojourning orientation, and these four encompass all types of ethnicresources empircally described in the existing literature (cf. Turner andBonacich, 1980: 152). As such, ethnic resources should be distinguishedfrom class resources. Class resources are cultural and material. On the materialside, class resources are private property in the means of production anddistribution, human capital, and money to invest. On the cultural side,

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 9: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

202 Ivan Light

class resources are bourgeois values, attitudes, knowledge and skills trans-mitted intergenerationally in the course of primary socialization (Di Maggio,1982: 190—1). An established bourgeoisie equips its youth with appropriateclass resources, and, having them, the youth are well endowed to prosperin a market economy. Class resources exist, and sociological theory hasamply and basically acknowledged their importance. An analytical disputehas arisen, however, when studies of ethnic entrepreneurship have soughtto distinguish ethnic resources from class resources. The mainstream viewignored ethnic resources, assuming that only class resources do or even canexist. On this view, an ethnic bourgeoisie is just a bourgeoisie rather than abourgeoisie which has unique access to ethnic resources.

In principle, class and ethnic resources might occur singly or in combination.This compatibility yields four basic etiologies: class-only, ethnic-only, class-ethnic mixed, and no resources. A class-only etiology explains ethnic minorityor immigrant entrepreneurship strictly on the basis of class origins, property,money, and human capital. Class-only explanation is Type 1 in Table 2.Ethnic-only analysis omits the above, focussing explanation wholly uponethnic resources such as cultural heritages, reactive solidarities, sojourning,and relative satisfaction. Ethnic-only explanation is Type 2 in Table 2. Mixedanalysis combines elements of ethnic and class analysis to suit empiricalcases of entrepreneurship. Mixed explanation is Type 3 in Table 2. Sinceclass-only analysis is most compatible with a macro-theory of the economy,the mixed and ethnic-anly analytic possibilities signal a newly discoveredfrontier of theoretical controversy. If the latter types exist, class macro-Table 2. Ethnic and class resources of entrepreneurship

1. Class-only

2. Ethnic-only

3. Mixed

4. Mixed: classpredominant

5. Mixed: ethnicpredominant

6. No resources

EthnicOrthodox

0

X

X

X

X

0

Resource

Reactive

0

X

X

X

X

0

Basis

Material

X0

X

X

X

0

ClassCultural

X

0

X

X

X

0

0 = nonex = someX = much

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 10: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 203

theory needs adjustment to take into account complexities currently ignored.The North American literature contains no examples of class-only or

ethnic-only resource-mobilizing entrepreneurial subgroups. All the empiricalcases are mixed. The evidence thus reduces the theoretical polarities to idealtypes. Admittedly some cases of ethnic minority or immigrant entrepreneur-ship weigh more heavily on one side or the other of this class/ethnic balance.Especially in the past, immigrant entrepreneurship seems to have dependedmore heavily upon ethnic resources than it currently does. Turn-of-the-centuryChinese and Japanese immigrants in California are the best-documentedillustrations. Disadvantaged in the general labor market, they turned inextraordinary proportion to self-employment, apparently mobilizing ethnicresources very effectively to this end (Light, 1972; Modell, 1977; Bonacichand Modell, 1980). Post-1970 Asian immigrants in North America continueto mobilize ethnic resources to support business ownership, but the balancehas shifted toward money, human capital, and bourgeois culture. Thus, allcases of Asian entrepreneurship have been mixed, but in the last half-centurythe balance has appreciably swung from ethnic toward class resources(Thompson, 1979).

In contemporary American and Canadian society, immigrant entrepreneur-ship still combines ethnic and class resources, thus creating an empiricalproblem of sorting out each contributor and assessing its contribution.Thorny as is this measurement problem, the empirical dualism is clear especi-ally in the important cases of political refugees from the Third World. To asubstantial extent, Korean, Vietnamese, Taiwanese, Hong Kong, Cuban, andIranian immigrants now in the United States derived from property-owningupper classes in their countries of origin.2 Fearing or experiencing socio-political turmoil in their homelands, these refugees entered the UnitedStates with human capital, money to invest, and bourgeois cultural values.Accordingly, it is no surprise that their involvement in small business hasbeen extensive, their success in it remarkable, and their achievements muchcelebrated in popular media (Ramirez, 1980). On a class-only model thesmall business success of these refugees reflects only the class resourcesthey brought with them, and any group of wealthy refugees would havecreated as many small businesses. Ethnicity conferred nothing: this is thenull hypothesis.

Class resources indisputably help, but empirical research suggests that aclass-only explanation is inadequate. An' immigrant bourgeoisie utilizesethnic resources in supplementation of class resources. The two best-studiedexamples are Cubans in Miami, and Koreans in Los Angeles.3 Wilson andPortes (1980; Portes, 1981; Wilson and Martin, 1982) found that about one-third of Cubans in Miami were employed in Cuban-owned business andanother fragment were self-employed. For the Cubans returns on humancapital were more favorable among the self-employed than among thoseemployed for wages in the competitive sector. Indeed, returns on humancapital were equivalent to those in the primary sector. Explaining this success,Wilson and Portes (1980: 315) conclude:

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 11: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

204 Ivan Light

Immigrant entrepreneurs make use of language and cultural barriersand of ethnic affinities to gain privileged access to markets and sourcesof labor The necessary counterpart to these ethnic ties of solidarityis the principle of ethnic preference in hiring and of support of otherimmigrants in their economic ventures.

Since these resources would be unavailable in Cuba, the Cuban immigrantbourgeoisie acquires access to ethnic resources in Miami where they aremembers of a cultural minority. To a substantial extent, these reactiveresources permit the Cubans to thrive in small business and even to out-perform the native whites in this sphere despite the material advantagesof the latter.

Bonacich, Light and Wong (1977, 1980; see also light, 1980; Bonacichand Jung, 1982) have looked into the entrepreneurial success of 60,000Koreans in Los Angeles. In 1980, approximately 40 per cent of employedKorean men headed small firms (Yu, 1982: 54).4 An additional 40 per centof Koreans worked in these firms so only about 20 per cent of the Koreanimmigrants found employment in non-Korean-owned firms or governmentagencies. Admittedly, the Korean immigrants were highly educated: on oneaccount nearly 70 per cent of men had college degrees compared with only15 per cent of Los Angeles County residents in general. Additionally, theKoreans brought with them sums of capital rarely less than $25,000 andsometimes millions. On the other hand, these class resources supplementedethnic resources; they did not exclude them. As among the Cubans in Miami,Koreans in Los Angeles made effective business use of language and culturalbarriers distinguishing co-ethnics from the general population, reactive socialsolidarity, nepotistic hiring, and formal and informal mutual support networks.Additionally, Koreans made some use of rotating credit associations,5

nationalistic appeals for labor peace, vertical and horizontal integration offirms, informal and formal restraints of trade,6 and political connectionswith City Hall developed by leading Korean business organizations. In allthese respects, Korean entrepreneurship drew upon ethnic resources notmerely upon class resources.

Collectivist and individualist styles of entrepreneurship

Textbook treatments of entrepreneurship have long begun with the econom-istic assumption that small business owners are individualists. Indeed, theterm 'entrepreneurial individualism' remains in general currency as a reflectionof this persisting assumption. Underlying the microeconomic theory of thefirm are the class resources of the bourgeoisie which provide facilities forindividual business owners. In Schumpeter's famous image, these entrepren-eurs behave like spectators in a crowded stadium during a rainstorm. Feelingrain, each spectator independently decides to raise his umbrella, and decidesto put it away when the sun once again comes out. In this analogy, thematerial resource is the umbrella, and the cultural resource is the trained

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 12: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America 205

wisdom to utilize it properly. But each entrepreneur thinks and acts indepen-dently albeit in utilization of class-linked resources.

Accepting Schumpeter's (1934: 81, n.l, 2) class-only model of entrepren-eurship,7 sociology has, however, parted company with neoclassical economicson the issue of consciousness. Insofar as a resource-transmitting bourgeoisiedevelops self-consciousness, this consciousness becomes a class resourcecapable of affecting the economic success of members. Thus, elitist studiesof the American upper class have long claimed that debutante cotillions,preparatory schools, swank vacation resorts, exclusive suburbs, and stuffydowntown clubs reflect and forge upper-class consciousness (Useem, 1980:53-8). Group consciousness enhances the chances of individual bourgeoisto monopolize access to material and status rewards. For instance, clubsprovide a private place to concoct business and political deals or to arrangemarriages. Admittedly the importance of bourgeois group consciousnesshas not been so systematically examined in its economic as in its politicalramifications. However, class-only theories of the bourgeoisie have acknowl-edged the development of an entrepreneurial collectivism which enhancesthe competitive chances of the individual members of the bourgeoisie.Evaluating two generations of social research on the American businesselite, Useem (1980: 58) finds 'internal cohesion' strikingly in evidence.'Unity is far more extensively developed at the top than anywhere else inthe class structure.'

A similar evolution has characterized sociological studies of ethnic business(Jenkins, 1984). Classical sociologists called attention to cultural endowmentswhich governed the style of business ownership, and explained in historicalcontext the transition from merchant to bourgeois. The prototype was, ofcourse, Weber's (1958a) Protestant sectarians whose economic style reflectedreligio-cultural values. Their disciplined lifestyle caused them to prosperin business, but they were expected to do so as noncooperating individualsstanding or falling on individual merits. Of course, there is no denying thatunder some cultural or situational conditions, small business owners canbe individualistic nor that introjected values of hard work, thrift, and economicrationality encourage business survival and success.8 Bechofer et aVs (1974)study of Scottish business owners in Edinburgh depicts individualistic businessconduct. Jarvenpa and Zenner (1979) reported the same individualismamong Scots in the Canadian fur trade. On the other hand, even Weberoverstated the extent of individualism among Protestant sectarians and,aware of this error, was more careful (1958b) in some writings. Historicalresearch among Puritan business owners in seventeenth-century New Englandhas not disclosed the expected individualism. On the contrary, Bailyn (1955),Hall (1977), and Griffen and Griffen (1977: 150) concluded that observantlyCalvinist business owners in New England were active participants in commer-cial networks knit together on the basis of extended kinship and friendship,these networks actually Unking ports of origin in the British Isles and NewEngland cities.

In the same sense, cultural treatments of middlemen minorities in North

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 13: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

206 Ivan Light

America began with the assumption that cultural subgroups acted out theirvalues in enterprising individualism based upon hard work, thrift, rationality,and self-denial (Auster and Aldrich, 1983). In this model, immigrant entre-preneurs drew upon a cultural tradition, then fanned out into the economyin individualistic search for profitable opportunities. Equipped with culturalresources, co-ethnics knew how to make the most out of such businessopportunities as they encountered — but each did so as an isolated individual.

There is, of course, no question that ethnic values and motivations doaffect individual behavior. However, ethnic research has shown there existsa largely ignored dimension of collective action which goes beyond individual-istic value or motivational effects, important as those are (Leff, 1979). Thisis the dimension of entrepreneurial collectivism in the ethnic minority(Young, 1971: 140-1 ;Cummings, 1980). Collective styles of entrepreneurshipdepend upon group resources in which business owners only participateinsofar as they maintain active, adult participation in community life (Herman,1979: 84). For example, a rotating credit association requires cooperatorsto establish a reputation for trustworthiness in the ethnic community, andthis reputation depends in turn upon active involvement (light, 1972: Ch. 2).Similarly, an immigrant or ethnic informational network confers benefitsupon business owners, but to obtain these benefits an owner needs to belongto the network. Isolates cannot share network information so this ethnicresource only benefits participants in ethnic community networks. Finally,trade guilds may regulate and control internal competition, but the benefitsof collusion in restraint of trade accrue to members. Isolates suffer theconsequences of collusion by others.

In principle, class and ethnic resources both confer potentialities forindividualist or collectivistic styles of business managment. As before, however,all empirical cases in the literature have been mixed. For instance, Koreansin Los Angeles have utilized both class and ethnic resources, and these resourceshave here supported individualistic and there collectivistic entrepreneurship.Taken together, Korean entrepreneurship in Los Angeles is a pastiche ofethnic and class resources and individualist and collectivist styles. On theother hand, the balance of individualism and collectivism in immigrantentrepreneurship appears to have shifted in three generations. Chinese andJapanese immigrants in California at the turn of the century utilized entre-preneurial strategies which were more collectivistic than those currentlyutilized by Chinese immigrants in Toronto (Chan and Cheung, 1982). In thesame manner, Polish, Finnish, Irish, Mormon, and Jewish entrepreneurshipappears to have undergone a shift in this century away from an immigrant-generation dependence upon collective resources toward a native-borngeneration dependence upon individual resources.9

Two related changes explain this shifting balance. On the one hand, thecompetitive sector has become smaller in size and the price of admissionhigher in response to capitalist concentration. Ethnic collectivism may be lessadequate than in the past. On the other hand, upward social mobility hasconferred class resources upon native-born ethnics whose progenitors did

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 14: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America 207

not have them. Specifically, native-born descendants of immigrant businessowners enter the business sector with money, education, and skills theirforebears lacked. Possessing class resources, immigrant and ethnic minorityentrepreneurs become more individualistic in style. Thus, impoverishedimmigrants needed to combine their small amounts of capital in rotatingcredit associations in order to assemble a sum large enough to finance smallbusiness. Dependent upon kinsmen and landsmen for initial capital, immigrantbusiness owners could not thereafter operate their businesses as if they wereisolated individualists. With personal money to invest, the descendants ofthese immigrants and contemporary 'new' immigrants no longer need toborrow from kin and friends (Kim, 1977). Therefore, they establish theirbusiness enterprises without rotating credit associations, and operate themin a more individualistic manner.10 Similarly, poor immigrants did notunderstand inventories or balance sheets so they turned to kin and friendsfor advice in business management. Equipped with MBAs, their descendantsand North America's new immigrants possess the business skills they need asclass resources. Therefore, they do not need to turn for management adviceto informal, ethnically linked agencies, and they are free to operate theirbusiness enterprises as if they were isolated individuals. In this manner,access to class resources may obviate collectivism in ethnic enterprise — butnot exclude it altogether. In Toronto, Thompson (1979) reports, a bipolarbusiness class has actually emerged as a result of these processes. On theone side are the old-fashioned, ethnic-dependent Mom and Pop store owners;on the other, Hong Kong millionaires operating investment corporations.'The new stratum of entrepreneurial elites differ in both origin and lifestylefrom the traditional merchant elites who for years controlled the [Chinese]ethnic community' (Thompson, 1979: 311).

In principle, ethnic and immigrant small business ought to run out ofsolidarity to exploit because cultural assimilation and higher educationundercut the ascriptive solidarities from which immigrant-generation businessowners derived the resources to power their business network (Turner andBonacich, 1980: 157). Much evidence suggests that over generations ethnicresources do decay for this reason (Bonacich and Modell, 1980: Chs 6, 9;Borhek, 1970; Goldscheider and Kobrin, 1980; Montero, 1981). 'Over thelong run,' Reitz (1980: 231) observes, 'there is a progressive trend towardabandonment of ethnic group ties for all groups in which long-term experiencecan be measured.' However, the rate of deterioration has been much slowerthan sociologists once expected (Wilensky and Lawrence, 1979). The indis-putable profitability of ethnic capitalism is an apparent cause of this retar-dation. Especially relative to equally qualified members of the same ethnicgroup in the general labor market, owners of ethnic sector business enterprisesearn high incomes in business. Big profits make ethnic business attractive(Wilson and Portes, 1980: 314; Sway, 1983; Reitz, 1982; Bonacich andModell, 1981: 257). Ethnic business owners identify with their ethniccommunity and participate actively in it. They provide the leadership forethnic institutions. Ethnic attachments also persist more strongly among

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 15: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

208 Ivan Light

wage workers whose workplace is a co-ethnic firm whose language is that ofthe homeland, not English (Bonacich and Modell, 1980; Reitz, 1980; Wobdrum,Rhodes and Feagin, 1980: 1240-52). These two classes often account forbetween 40 and 80 per cent of the total ethnic population. Ethnic-ownedbusinesses 'help prop up other institutions which recruit and maintain ethnicmembership' (Reitz, 1980: 223). Ethnicity supports the ethnic economy,and the ethnic economy supports ethnic perpetuation (Bonacich and Modell,1981:257).

No resources entrepreneurship

The preceding analysis offers a satisfactory account of why equally dis-advantaged ethnic and immigrant minorities display unequal rates of entre-preneurship: survival and success depend upon group resources. Groups withmore resources outperform groups with less; and groups with class resourcesare individualistic whereas groups with ethnic resources are collectivistic.On this view, entrepreneurship is highest when disadvantaged immigrantminorities are well endowed with class and ethnic resources; endowment withone or the other is intermediate; and neglible endowment in both class andethnic resources implies correspondingly low rates of entrepreneurship.

Behind this conclusion lies the assumption that immigrant minorities'rate of business ownership is a fair measure of their entrepreneurship. Therate of business ownership has been operationally defined as self-employedper 1000 in the urban labor force.11 A major objection to this definition,it is increasingly clear, arises from the inadequacy of published statistics(Karsh, 1977; light, 1979: 39-40; US Small Business, 1980). 'The Censushas a completely nonsociological way of defining "self-employment"' (Wrightetal, 1982: 712n). US statistics routinely exclude petty traders without fixedbusiness premises, no-employee firms, illegally operated firms in legitimateindustries, and firms producing unlawful goods or services. Since minoritiesand immigrants bulk very large in such firms, their exclusion from officialtabulations results in undercounts of minority-owned business enterpriseas well as theoretical misperception of the whole phenomenon of ethnicentrepreneurship. No one knows how many untabulated firms exist nor whatis their distribution among various sectors of the labor force.

The case of native-born black Americans is instructive because blacks aredisadvantaged but native-born. All statistical and ethnographic sources haveuniformly reported that rates of business self-employment among urbanblacks have been and remain lower than among even native-white, let alonethe foreign-born (Light, 1972, 1979, 1980). At the same time, ethnographicsources have stressed the importance of 'hustling' as an economic activityamong underclass urban blacks (Valentine, 1978; Glasgow, 1980: 9, 90;light, 1977b). Hustling involves piecing together a livelihood by operatinga variety of legal, semi-legal, and sometimes illegal business activities. Legalenterprises of urban blacks include street corner and door-to-door peddlingof trinkets, objets d'art, junk, salvage, and fire-damaged merchandise. Unlaw-

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 16: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America 209

fully conducted legal enterprises include unlicensed taxicabs, unlicensedpharmacies, unlicensed medical services, welfare cheating, tax-evading laborservices and so forth. Illegal enterprise includes gambling administration,pimping, prostitution, narcotics vending, and other victimless crimes (light1977a, 1977b). Predatory crimes include armed robbery, burglary, shop-lifting,and all similar activities. All these self-employed activities are entrepreneurialin that they involve risk and uncertain return (Harbison, 1956: 365). Althoughcomprehensive statistics are lacking, there seems little doubt that urbanblacks are as overrepresented in marginal legal and unlawfully operated self-employment as crime statistics indicate they are in illegal enterprise andpredatory crime. Taken together, this package suggests much higher thanaverage self-employment among economically marginal blacks in unmeasuredbusiness at the same time that official statistics reveal much lower than averageself-employment in measured business.

Given the presumptively high rates of black self-employment in theseundocumented industries, it is improper to conclude that native blacks areless entrepreneurial than other economically disadvantaged immigrants andethnic minorities. It rather appears that native-born blacks have elaboratedan alternative, heavily illegal, highly individualistic style of coping withprotracted economic marginality. Compared to the foreign-born in general,and middleman minorities in particular, native-born blacks are low in ethnicresources of entrepreneurship, but share economic disadvantage (Wong,1977; Light 1972; Chs 2, 6-8; Venable, 1972: 30). Compared to nativewhites, native blacks are high in economic disadvantage, low in class resourcesof entrepreneurship, but similar in respect to ethnic resources of entrepreneur-ship. Table 3 documents these contrasts. Low on ethnic resources of entre-preneurship but high in economic disadvantage, native-born blacks werecompelled to depend upon class resources in which they have been under-endowed for centuries. As an overall result, marginal black enterprises havenot broken into the circle of legal, officially enumerated small businessenterprises. Their problem has been nonpromotion of their very large classof petty but invisible enterprises such that a visible minority enjoy upwardsocial mobility within the legitimate, competitive sector (Glasgow, 1980:189). It is in the assistance of upward mobility that ethnic and class resourcesmake themselves appreciably manifest (Gelfand, 1981: 185, 190). Givenlabor force disadvantage, chronic unemployment or both, any ethnic orimmigrant minority resorts to self-employment, but only resources makepossible the promotion of marginal enterprises into small businesses whoselong-term profitability brings along the social mobility of proprietors, theirkin, and their heirs (Wilson and Martin, 1982: 155-7).

Summary and conclusion

Uneven development has created economic enclaves within which smallbusiness can still be profitable. Success in small business requires, however,a combination of class and ethnic resources with some evidence indicating

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 17: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

210 Ivan Light

Table 3. Profiles ofentrepreneurship

Comparison groups

Middleman Foreign- Native Nativeminorities born blacks whites

Rotating creditassociations

Precapitalist commercialbackground

Landsmannschaften

Extended kinship

Relative satisfaction

Sojourning

Unpaid family labor

Labor forcedisadvantage

Ineligible for publicwelfare

Language barrier

Special consumerdemands

the former have increased their importance in the last generation. Nonetheless,ethnic resources persist, and immigrant and ethnic minority groups areoverrepresented in small business in large part because their access to ethnicresources permits them to outcompete native workers. In this comparativerespect native whites and blacks are similar but the native blacks lack classresources and additionally suffer labor market disadvantage which gives thema motive to seek self-employment income.Underclass blacks do find this incomein the form of hustling, but hustling has by and large failed to create firmsthat are large and legal enough to achieve visibility in government statistics.

Ethnic resources of entrepreneurship often depend upon premodernvalues and solidarities. So long as these survive in the ethnic community,co-ethnic business owners are able to utilize them in business, achievingadvantage over fully proletarianized, native-born workers among whomblacks are conspicuous. In theory, ethnic capitalism and cultural assimilationshould first undercut and then demolish precapitalist solidarities, thus elimin-ating an ethnic group's competitive edge in small business. In the perspectiveof history, this self-destruction probably occurs. However, its rate should not

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 18: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America 211

be exaggerated. Ethnic enterprises still earn handsome financial returns, andthese substantial rewards prop up the ethnicity upon which owners dependfor resources. Profitability brakes the rate of deterioration of ethnic solidarity,supports the persistence of ethnic-owned firms in the competitive sector,and perpetuates the whole competitive sector.

Notes

*An earlier version of this paper was presented at the 10th World Congress of the Inter-national Sociological Association, Mexico City, August 19, 1982.

1. See Gelfand, 1981; Chs 4, 5; Goldscheider and Kobrin, 1980; Light, 1972: Ch. 5;Light and Wong, 1975; Wong, 1977; Sassen-Koob, 1981:30-1; Modell, 1977;Bonacichand Modell, 1981;Lovell-Troy, 1980, 1981;Chock, 1981; Sway, 1983;Sengstock, 1967;Bonacich, Light, and Wong, 1977, 1979; Blackistone, 1981;Herman, 1979: 90;Zenner,1982; Waldinger, 1982; Yu, 1982; Bonacich and Jung, 1982.2. 'Most of the refugees are ethnic Chinese, most of whom were shopkeepers orbusinessmen who had little future under a communist system.' 'Bleak outlook forVietnam refugees,' East/West (San Francisco), June 20, 1979: 1. See also: McMillan,1982; Rogg, 1971: 480; Chan and Cheung, 1982; Thompson, 1979; Wilson and Portes,1980.3. But two recent studies have produced important new documentation. In NewYork City's garment industry, Waldinger (1982) reported extensive and critically impor-tant utilization of ethnic networks among Dominican entrepreneurs. In Los Angeles'staxi industry, Russell (1982) documented the mutual assistance common among SovietJews seeking to break into the occupation.4. A similar situation apparently exists in New York City, site of the second largestKorean settlement in the United States. See Illsoo Kim, 1981: 110; see also 'Faced withprejudice and language difficulties, New York Koreans turn to private business,' Korea-town (Los Angeles), December 14, 1981: 8-9.5. $400,000 kye broke,' Joong-ang Daily News (Los Angeles: in Korean), February20, 1979; Kim, 1981: 210-11.6. 'Markets agree to cut down on competition,' Korea Times English Section (LosAngeles), November 23, 1981: 1. 'KCCI asks bizmen for more cooperation,' KoreaTimes English Section, February 6, 1980; 'Fifteen Korean chambers unite,' Koreatown,November 17, 1980; 'Prosperity of shops leads community development,' Korea TimesEnglish Section, November 22, 1976.7. Schumpeter's (1934) views are endorsed in Beveridge and Oberschall, 1979: 207,225, 229; criticized in Jones and Sakong, 1980: 211;reviewed in Hagen, 1968: 221-7.8. 'When individuals go into business they must be prepared to lower standards ofliving and make personal sacrifices until their firms begin to prosper,' Cingolani, 1972.9. See Chas 4-10 in Cummings (ed.), 1980.10. In the wake of extremely high interest rates, white Californians began to utilizethe Pandero, a Brazilian rotating credit association, for purposes of home purchase.In this situation, a class-based, individualistic style reverted to old-fashioned collectivismas class resources became inadequate because of high interest rates. See DeWolfe, 1982.11. Gerry and Birkbeck (1981) and Portes (1981) argue that marginal self-employedof the Third World are 'thinly disguised wage workers' because of their indirect economicdependencies upon big firms. However, Aldrich and Weiss (1981) have shown that alinear relationship exists between employment size and business owners' incomes, andlinearity persists in the USA when non-employer firms are introduced. 'Owners withoutemployees are simply the "poorest of the poor" among small capitalists. This group. . . should be assigned to the owner class in future research.'

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 19: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

212 Ivan Light

References

ALDRICH, HOWARD, and WEISS, JANE 1981 'Differentiation Within the US CapitalistClass,' American Sociological Review 46: 279-90.ARONOWITZ, STANLEY 1973 False Promises. New York: McGraw Hill.AUSTER, ELLEN, and ALDRICH, HOWARD 1984 'Small Business Vulnerability,Ethnic Enclaves, and Ethnic Enterprise,' in Ethnic Business in Britain, ed. Robin Ward.Cambridge University Press (forthcoming), Ch. 3.BAILYN, BERNARD 1955 The New England Merchants in the Seventeenth Century.Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.BARTH, FREDRICK 1962 The Role of the Entrepreneur in Social Change in NorthernNorway. Bergen: Norwegian Universities Press.BECHOFER, FRANK; ELLIOTT, BRIAN; RUSHFORTH, MONICA; and BLAND,RICHARD 1974 'Small Shopkeepers: Matters of Money and Meaning,' SociologicalReview 22: 465-82.BELL, DANIEL 1976 The Cultural Contradictions of Capitalism. New York: BasicBooks.BELSHAW, CYRIL 1955 The Cultural Milieu of the Entrepreneur,' Explorations inEntrepreneurial History 7: 146-63.BEVERIDGE, ANDREW A., and OBERSCHALL, ANTHONY R. 1979 AfricanBusinessmen and Development in Zambia. Princeton University Press.BOISSEVAIN, JEREMY 1984 'Small Entrepreneurs in Contemporary Europe,' inEthnic Business in Britain, ed. Robin Ward. Cambridge University Press (forthcoming),Ch.2.BLACKISTONE, KEVIN B. 1981 'Arab Entrepreneurs Take Over Inner City GroceryStores,' Chicago Reporter 10: 1-5.BONACICH, EDNA 1973 'A Theory of Middleman Minorities,' American SociologicalReview 38: 583-94.BONACICH, EDNA 1975 'Small Business and Japanese American Ethnic Solidarity,'Amerasia Journal 3: 96-112.BONACICH, EDNA 1978 'Korean Immigrant Small Business in Los Angeles,' inSourcebook on the New Immigration, ed. Roy S. Bryce-Laporte. New Brunswick, NJ:Transaction Books, pp. 167-84.BONACICH, EDNA; LIGHT, IVAN; and WONG, CHARLES 1977 'Koreans in Business,'Society 14: 54-9.BONACICH, EDNA, and MODELL, JOHN 1981 The Economic Basis of EthnicSolidarity. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.BONACICH, EDNA, and JUNG, TAE HWAN 1982 'A Portrait of Korean Small Businessin Los Angeles: 1977,' in Koreans in Los Angeles, ed. Eui-Young Yu, Earl H. Phillips,and Eun Sik Yang. Los Angeles: Koryo Research Institute and Center for Korean-American and Korean Studies, California State University, Los Angeles.BONNETT, AUBREY W. 1980 'An Examination of Rotating Credit Associations amongBlack West Indian Immigrants in Brooklyn,' in Sourcebook on the New Immigration,ed. Roy S. Bryce-Laporte. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Books, pp. 271-83.BORHEK, J. T. 1970 'Ethnic Group Cohesion,' American Journal of Sociology 76:33-46.BOTTOMORE, T. B. 1966 Classes in Modern Society. New York: Pantheon.CHAN, JANET B. L., and CHEUNG, YUET-WAH 1982 'Ethnic Resources and BusinessEnterprise: A study of Chinese Businesses in Toronto.' Paper Presented at the AnnualMeeting of the American Sociological Association, San Francisco, September 6.CHINOY, ELY 1952 'The Tradition of Opportunity and the Aspirations of AutomobileWorkers,' American Journal of Sociology 57: 453-9.CHOCK, PHYLLIS P. 1981 'The Greek-American Small Businessman: a CulturalAnalysis,' Journal of Anthropological Research 37: 46-60.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 20: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America 213

CINGOLANI, CINDY 1973 'Avoiding Management Pitfalls,' Bank of America SmallBusiness Reporter 11, No. 5.COREY, LEWISH 1966 'The Middle Class,' in Class Status, and Power, 2nd edn, ed.Reinhard Bendix and Seymour Lipset. Glencoe, Illinois: Free Press, pp. 371-80.CUMMINGS, SCOTT A. 1980 'Collectivism: The Unique Legacy of ImmigrantEconomic Development,' in Self-Help in Urban America, ed. Scott Cummings. PtWashington, NY: Kennikat Press, pp. 5-32.DEWOLFE, EVELYN 1982 'Fund Pools Blocked by Postal Law,' Los Angeles Times,February 21, VII, p. 1.DIMAGGIO, PAUL 1982 'Cultural Capital and School Success: The Impact of StatusCulture Participation on the Grades of U. S. High School Students,' AmericanSociological Review 47: 189-201.FAIN, T. SCOTT 1980 'Self-Employed Americans: Their Number Has Increased,'Monthly Labor Review 103: 3-8.FREEDMAN, MAURICE 1959 'The Handling of Money: A Note on the Backgroundto the Economic Sophistication of the Overseas Chinese,' Man 59: 64-5.GELFAND, MITCHELL BRIAN 1981 'Chutzpah in El Dorado: Social Mobility ofJews in Los Angeles, 1900-1920.' PhD dissertation, Carnegie-Mellon University.GERRY, CHRIS, and BIRKBECK, CHRIS 1981 'The Petty Commodity Producer inThird World Cities: Petit-Bourgeois or "Disguised" Proletarian?' in The PetiteBourgeoisie, ed. Frank Bechofer and Brian Elliott. New York: St Martin's Press, pp.121-54.GIDDENS, ANTHONY 1973 The Class Structure of the Advanced Societies. NewYork: Harper & Row.GLASGOW, DOUGLAS G. 1980 The Black Underclass. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.GOLDSCHEIDER, CALVIN, and KOBRIN, FRANCES 1980 'Ethnic Continuity andthe Process of Self-Employment,' Ethnicity 7: 256-78.GRIFFEN, SALLY, and GRIFFEN, CLYDE 1977 'Family and Business in a SmallCity: Poughkeepsie, N. Y., 1850-1880,' in Family and Kin in Urban Communities,1700-1930, ed. Tamara Hareven. New York: New Viewpoints, pp. 144-63.HAGEN, EVERETT E. 1968 The Economics of Development. Homewood, Illinois:Richard D. Irwin.HALL, PETER DOBKIN 1977 'Family Structure and Economic Organization:Massachussetts Merchants, 1700-1850,' in Family and Kin in Urban Communities,1700-1930, ed. Tamara Hareven. New York: New Viewpoints, pp. 38-61.HANDLIN, OSCAR 1959 The Newcomers: Negroes and Puerto Ricans in a ChangingMetropolis. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.HARBISON, FREDERICK 1956 'Entrepreneurial Organization as a Factor in EconomicDevelopment,' Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 364-79.HERMAN, HARRY VJEKOSLAV 1979 'Dishwashers and Proprietors: Macedoniansin Toronto's Restaurant Trade,' in Ethnicity At Work, ed. Sandra Wallman. London:Macmillan, pp. 71-90.HIGGS, ROBERT 1977 Competition and Coercion. Cambridge University Press.HORVAT, BRANKO 1982 The Political Economy of Socialism. Armonk, NY: M.E.Sharpe.HRABA, JOSEPH 1979 American Ethnicity. Itasca, Illinois: F. E. Peacock.JARVENPA, ROBERT, and ZENNER, WALTER P. 1979 'Scot Trader/IndianWorker Relations and Ethnic Segregation: a Subarctic Example,' Ethnos 44: 58-78.JENKINS, RICHARD 1984 'Ethnicity and the Rise of Capitalism,' in Ethnic Businessin Britain, ed. Robin Ward. Cambridge University Press (forthcoming), Ch. 4.JONES, LEROY, and SAKONG, IL 1980 Government, Business and Entrepreneurshipin Economic Development: The Korean Case. Harvard University: Council on EastAsian Studies.KALLEBERG, ARNE L., and SORENSON, AAGE B. 1979 'The Sociology of LaborMarkets,' Annual Review of Sociology 5: 351-79.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 21: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

214 Ivan Light

KARSH, NORMAN C. 1977 What Is a Small Business? Washington, DC: Small BusinessAdministration.KIM, HYUNG-CHAN 1977 'Ethnic Enterprises among Korean Immigrants in America,'in The Korean Diaspora, ed. Hyung-Chan Kim. Santa Barbara: ABC-CLIO.KIM, ILLSOO 1981 New Urban Immigrants: The Korean Community in New York.Princeton University Press.LEFF, NATHANIEL 1978 'Industrial Organization and Entrepreneurship in theDeveloping Countries: The Economic Groups,' Economic Development and CulturalChange 26: 661ff.LIGHT, IVAN H. 1972 Ethnic Enterprise in America. Berkeley and Los Angeles:University of California Press.LIGHT, IVAN H. 1977a The Ethnic Vice District, 1880-1944,' American SociologicalReview 00: 464-79.LIGHT, IVAN H. 1977b 'Numbers Gambling: A Financial Institution,' AmericanSociological Review 43: 892-904.LIGHT, IVAN H. 1979 'Disadvantaged Minorities in Self-Employment,' InternationalJournal of Comparative Sociology 20: 31-45.LIGHT, IVAN H. 1980 'Asian Enterprise in America,' in Self-Help in Urban America,ed. Scott Cummings. Pt Washington, NY: Kennikat Press, pp. 33-57.LIGHT, IVAN H., and WONG, CHARLES 1975 'Protest or Work: Dilemmas of theTourist Industry in American Chinatowns,' American Journal of Sociology 80: 1342-68.LIPSET, SEYMOUR, and BENDIX, REINARD 1959 Social Mobility in IndustrialSociety. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.LIPSET, SEYMOUR, and BENDIX, REINARD 1953 'Social Mobility and OccupationalCareer Pattern, II: Social Mobility,' in Class, Status, and Power, 1st edn, ed. ReinhardBendix and Seymour Lipset. Glencoe, Illinois: Free Press.LOVELL-TROY, LAWRENCE A. 1980 'Clan Structure and Economic Activity: theCase of Greeks in Small Business Enterprise,' in Self-Help in Urban America, ed. ScottCummings. Pt Washington, NY: Kennikat Press, pp. 58-85.LOVELL-TROY, LAWRENCE A. 1981 'Ethnic Occupational Structures: Greeks in thePizza Business,' Ethnicity 8: 82-95.LYND, ROBERT S., and LYND, HELEN M. 1937 Middletown in Transition. New York:Harcourt Brace.McMILLAN, PENELOPE 1982 'Vietnamese Influx: It's Chinatown with Subtitles,'Los Angeles Times, February 14: II, p. 1.MAYHEW, LEON 1968 'Ascription in Modern Societies,' Sociological Inquiry 38:105-20.MEYER, KURT 1947 'Small Business as a Social Institution,' Social Research 14:332-49.MEYER, KURT 1953 'Business Enterprise: Traditional Symbol of Opportunity,' BritishJournal of Sociology 4: 160-80.MILLER, DANIEL R., and SWANSON, GUY E. 1958 The Changing American Parent.New York: John Wiley.MILLS, C. W. 1951 White Collar. New York: Oxford University Press.MILLS, C. W. 1966 The Middle Classes in Middle-Sized Cities,' in Class, Status, andPower, 2nd edn, ed. Reinhard Bendix and Seymour Martin Lipset New York: FreePress, pp. 275-81.MODELL, JOHN 1977 The Economics and Politics of Racial Accommodation: TheJapanese of Los Angeles, 1900-1942. Urbana: University of Illinois Press.MONTERO, DARREL 1981 'The Japanese Americans: Changing Patterns ofAssimilation Over Three Generations,' American Sociological Review 46: 829-39.NEWCOMER, MABEL 1961 'The Little Businessman: A Study of Business Proprietorsin Poughkeepsie, N.Y.,' Business History Review 35: 477-531.O'CONNOR, JAMES 1973 The Fiscal Crisis of the State. New York: St Martin's Press.PORTES, ALEJANDRO 1981 'Modes of Structural Incorporation and Present Theories

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 22: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America 215

of Labor Immigration,' in Global Trends in Migration: Theory and Research on.International Population Movements, ed. Mary M. Kritz and Charles B. Keely. NewYork: Center for Migration Studies of New York, Inc., pp. 279-97.PORTES, ALEJANDRO; CLARK, JUAN M.; and LOPEZ, MANUEL M. 1981-82 'SixYears Later, the Process of Incorporation of Cuban Exiles in the United States:1973-1979,' Cuban Studies 11-12: 1-24.RAMIREZ, ANTHONY 1980 'Cubans and Blacks in Miami,' Wall Street Journal, May 29.RAY, ROBERT N. 1975 'A Report on Self-Employed Americans in 1973,' MonthlyLabor Review 98: 49-54.REITZ, JEFFREY G. 1980 The Survival of Ethnic Groups. Toronto: McGraw-Hill.REITZ, JEFFREY G. 1982 'Ethnic Group Control of Jobs.' Paper presented at theAnnual Meeting of the American Sociological Association, San Francisco, September 6.RIESMAN, DAVID 1950 The Lonely Crowd: A Study of the Changing AmericanCharacter. New Haven: Yale University Press.ROGG, ELEANOR 1971 'The Influence of a Strong Refugee Community on theEconomic Adjustment of Its Members,' International Migration Review 5: 474-81.RUSSELL, RAYMOND 1982 'Ethnic and Occupational Cultures in the New TaxiCooperatives of Los Angeles.' Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the AmericanSociological Association, San Francisco, September 6.SASSEN-KOOB, SASKIA 1981 'Exporting Capital and Importing Labor: the Role ofCaribbean Migration to New York City.' Center for Latin American and CaribbeanStudies, New York University, Occasional Papers, No. 28.SCHUMPETER, JOSEPH 1934 The Theory of Economic Development, trans. byRedvers Opie. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.SENGSTOCK, MARY CATHERINE 1967 'Maintenance of Social Interaction Patternsin an Ethnic Group.' PhD dissertation, Washington University.SIU, PAUL C. P. 1952 The Sojourner,' American Journal of Sociology 58: 34-44.SPECIAL TASK FORCE TO THE SECRETARY OF HEALTH, EDUCATION, ANDWELFARE 1973 Work in America. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.SWAY, MARLENE. 1983 'Gypsies as a Middleman Minority.' PhD dissertation,University of California, Los Angeles.THOMPSON, RICHARD H. 1979 'Ethnicity vs. Class: Analysis of Conflict in a NorthAmerican Chinese Community,' Ethnicity 6: 306-26.TURNER, JONATHAN H., and BONACICH, EDNA 1980 'Toward a Composite Theoryof Middleman Minorities,' Ethnicity 7: 144-58.US SMALL BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION, OFFICE OF ADVOCACY 1980 The SmallBusiness Data Base. Washington, DC: US Small Business Administration.USEEM, MICHAEL 1980 'Corporations and the Corporate Elite,' Annual Review ofSociology 6: 41-77.VALENTINE, BETTYLOU 1978 Hustling and Other Hard Work. New York: Macmillan.VENABLE, ABRAHAM S. 1972 Building Black Business: An Analysis and a Plan.New York: Earl G. Graves.VIDICH, ARTHUR, and BENSMAN, JOSEPH 1960 Small Town in Mass Society.Garden City, NY: Doubleday Anchor Books.WALDINGER, ROGER 1982 'Immigrant Enterprise and Labor Market Structure.'Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Sociological Association, SanFrancisco, September 6.WALKER, CHARLES, and GUEST, ROBERT 1952 The Man on the Assembly Line.Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.WALLMAN, SANDRA 1979a 'Foreword,' in Ethnicity at Work, ed. Sandra Wallman.London: Macmillan, pp. ix-xii.WALLMAN, SANDRA 1979b 'The Scope for Ethnicity,' in Ethnicity at Work, ed.Sandra Wallman. London: Macmillan, pp. 1-14.WEBER, MAX 1958a The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, trans. byTalcott Parsons. New York: Scribner.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3

Page 23: Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North America* · Immigrant and ethnic enterprise in North A merica 197 102-3, 177-81). Given the USA's laissez-faire traditions (Meyer, 1953) it

216 Ivan Light

WEBER, MAX 1958b 'The Protestant Sects and the Spirit of Capitalism,' in From MaxWeber, ed. Hans H. Gerth and C. W. Mills. New York: Oxford University Press, pp.302-22.WILENSKY, HAROLD L., and LAWRENCE, ANNE T. 1979 'Job Assignment inModern Societies: A Reexamination of the Ascription-Achievement Hypothesis,' inSocietal Growth, ed. Amos H. Hawley. New York: Free Press, pp. 202-48.WILSON, KENNETH L., and PORTES, ALEJANDRO 1980 'Immigrant Enclaves:An Analysis of the Labor Market Experience of Cubans in Miami,' American Journalof Sociology 86: 295-319.WILSON, KENNETH L., and MARTIN, W. ALLEN 1982 'Ethnic Enclaves: AComparison of the Cuban and Black Economies in Miami,' American Journal ofSociology 88: 135-60.WONG, CHARLES CHOY 1977 'Black and Chinese Grocery Stores in Los Angeles'Black Ghetto,' Urban Life 5: 439-64.WOODRUM, ERIC; RHODES, COLBERT; and FEAGIN, JOE R. 1980 'JapaneseAmerican Economic Behavior: Its Types, Determinants and Consequences,' SocialForces 58: 1235-54.WRIGHT, E. O.; COSTELLO, CYNTHIA; HACHEN, DAVID; and SPRAGUE, JOEY1982 'The American Class Structure,' American Sociological Review 47: 709-26.YOUNG, FRANK W. 1971 'A Macrosociological Interpretation of Entrepreneurship,'in Entrepreneurship and Economic Development, ed. Peter Kilby. New York: FreePress, pp. 139-49.YU, EU1-YOUNG 1982 'Occupation and Work Patterns of Korean Immigrants,' inKoreans in Los Angeles, ed. Eui-Young Yu, Earl H. Phillips, and Eun-Sik Yang. LosAngeles: Koryo Research Institute and Center for Korean-American and Korean Studies,California State University, Los Angeles.ZENNER, WALTER P. 1982 'Arabic-Speaking Immigrants in North America asMiddlemen Minorities,' Ethnic and Racial Studies 5: 457-77.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

T&

F In

tern

al U

sers

], [

Zoe

Ste

rnbe

rg]

at 0

1:08

28

June

201

3