innovation and internationalization: the case of italy

27
1 Innovation and internationalization: the case of Italy Rosanna PITTIGLIO, Edgardo SICA, Stefania VILLA R. Pittiglio and E. Sica Department of SEMS, Faculty of Economics, University of Foggia, Largo Papa Giovanni Paolo II n. 1, 71100 Foggia, ITALY. S. Villa Birkbeck College, University of London, Malet Street, WC1E 7HX, UK e-mail: [email protected] This work was jointly conceived and produced by the three authors. However, sections 3 and 5 were written by Rosanna Pittiglio, sections 4 and 6 by Edgardo Sica, and sections 1 and 2 by Stefania Villa.

Upload: unifg

Post on 19-Nov-2023

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

1

Innovation and internationalization: the case of Italy

Rosanna PITTIGLIO, Edgardo SICA, Stefania VILLA

R. Pittiglio and E. Sica Department of SEMS, Faculty of Economics, University of Foggia, Largo Papa Giovanni Paolo II n. 1, 71100 Foggia, ITALY. S. Villa Birkbeck College, University of London, Malet Street, WC1E 7HX, UK e-mail: [email protected] This work was jointly conceived and produced by the three authors. However, sections 3 and 5 were written by Rosanna Pittiglio, sections 4 and 6 by Edgardo Sica, and sections 1 and 2 by Stefania Villa.

2

Abstract The aim of this paper is to analyze the impact of international activities on knowledge output. At this end, we employ a dataset containing exclusively qualitative information about a sample of small and medium Italian manufacturing firms. In the econometric analysis, a probit model is used. The results of the estimations highlight that firms active in international markets generate more knowledge than their counterparts which sell in the national market only. There are two possible explanations of this result. First, globally engaged firms employ more knowledge inputs, such as higher innovation expenditures. Second, international firms are more innovative because they can access to a larger flow of ideas from external sources.

Keywords: firms’ internationalization, innovation, knowledge flows. JEL classification: F14, O14, O31, O40.

1. Introduction

In the latest years the availability of longitudinal micro-level data has determined a

remarkable increase in empirical studies on innovation, with particular regard to the

analysis of factors affecting firms’ knowledge output. The firm investing in innovation

might develop and license new technologies, adopt more efficient and less costly

production techniques, introduce new product and processes, and, therefore, become

more competitive (Mansfield, 1968; Castellani and Zanfei, 2007). The firm’s incentive

to invest in innovation decreases if knowledge generated by its innovation effort can be

appropriated costless by competitors. Spence (1984) showed that the appropriability

problem leads to a reduction of firm’s incentives to invest in R&D.

In the prevailing literature (Teece, 1996, for a survey), two broad classes of variables

are found to influence firm’s decision to engage in innovative activities:

firm’s characteristics and other internal factors;

external factors.

Firm’s characteristics are, for example, the monopoly power and size. The internal

factors are inputs used in the innovation process; as standard in this literature (Griliches,

3

1979, 1990; Romer, 1990), the inputs, which affect the production of innovation, are

innovation expenditure and the existing stock of knowledge available in the economy.

Teece (1996) also considered the internal formal structure and internal informal

structure as other internal factors.

In order to test the empirical validity of these factors influencing the production of

knowledge, the knowledge production function (KPF), formalized by Griliches (1990),

has been used as an analytical tool. According to this function, the production of new

knowledge depends on some observable measure of resources invested in innovative

activity, on the stock of knowledge available to the firm, and other control variables,

such as firm size. It is worth noting that not all the variables introduced in the literature

are easily measurable, such as the internal informal structure.

In the latest years a great deal of attention has been devoted to the “external” inputs

to innovation activity: firms may create knowledge not only from their own R&D

laboratories, but they can also take advantages from research activities carried out by

universities and by other firms, and, generally speaking, from collaborations with other

agents in the domestic and foreign markets. People share knowledge for different

reasons; for example, to get feedback from other people, to receive acknowledgment of

own ideas, or in team working. Once this knowledge is spread, it can be used to benefit

other people’s work and could lead to other inventions, resulting in spillovers and other

knowledge externalities. There is an associated risk of knowledge spillovers, which

arises due to the imperfect mechanism of protection of knowledge generated in an

innovating firm; firms may guard against unintended use of their innovation.

The flow of knowledge can happen within a country as well as abroad; a strand of

literature links internationalization and innovation. International research collaboration,

4

international networking for innovation inputs and ideas, international recruitment of

research and managerial staff encourage exchange of ideas. According to Keeble et al.

(1998), internationalization is a very important process underpinning firms’ innovative

activities and technological dynamism. The returns to innovation can be affected by

internationalization (Grossman and Helpman, 1991; Kafouros et al., 2008, among many

others). Hitt et al. (1997) illustrated that globally engaged firms may benefit from

product and geographical diversifications through economies of scale and scope.

Criscuolo, Haskel and Slaughter (2005), (CHS), and Wagner (2006) demonstrated

that international firms innovate more thanks to the access to a larger flow of ideas from

external sources. CHS used a knowledge production function (KPF) as an analytical

tool. They divided the existing stock of knowledge available in the economy in two

types of flow: internal and external, demonstrating that globally engaged UK firms

innovate more not only because they use more researchers, but also because they have a

better access to external stock of knowledge.

Using the same knowledge production framework and a data set of plant level data in

Germany, Wagner (2006) demonstrated that firms active on international markets

generate more knowledge than domestic firms, also because the former learn more from

external sources.

External linkages and knowledge spillovers are particularly important for small

enterprises, because they are means to supplementing and complementing limited

internal resources (Freel, 2000). Financing R&D activities can be a serious constraint on

small firms’ innovative effort. Innovation requires access to capital; alternatively,

alliances can be entered which reduce the need for new investment in complementary

assets. Adding external factors in the KPF introduces another channel through which

5

small enterprises get the innovation producing inputs. This channel is particularly

important in Italy, where between 2001-2003 Italian large firms (more than 250

employees) represented only about 1.7 percent of total Italian manufacturing firms

(source: authors’ elaborations on AIDA database from Bureau van Dijk). Therefore, the

SMEs represent a qualitatively peculiar and quantitatively relevant component of the

Italian productive structure.

The above discussion suggests that three categories of variables influence innovation

output:

the variables generally included in the standard KPF;

external factors, which allow flows of ideas within a country;

external factors, which allow flows of ideas from abroad.

And the last two factors are particularly important for SMEs.

In this paper we consider what affects the propensity to innovate among the Italian

SMEs. Adopting, to the best of our knowledge, the CHS approach for the first time to

the Italian case, the present work contributes to the existing literature by including

international activities among the potential determinants of knowledge output for the

Italian SMEs. In particular, we consider two measures of knowledge output, patents and

product innovations, and two indicators of global engagement, exports and

collaboration agreements with foreign firms. The empirical approach consists in

estimating the knowledge production function, in which the regressors are not only

innovation expenditure and internal flow of knowledge, but also external flow of

knowledge and indicators of international activities.

The structure of the paper is as follows: section 2 reviews the theoretical framework;

section 3 gives some descriptive statistics; section 4 discusses the variables used;

6

section 5 presents the estimation results; and the final section ends with some

concluding remarks.

2 Theoretical Framework

According to the literature, three main factors affect innovation output: 1) innovative

inputs and firm’s characteristics; 2) external factors, which allow flows of ideas within a

country; and 3) external factors, which allow flows of ideas from abroad.

Griliches (1979, 1990) and Romer (1990) assumed that devoting more capital - both

physical and human - to R&D leads to a higher production of knowledge. The

production of new knowledge, the output, depends not only on investment in the

process of knowledge creation but also on the existing stock of knowledge in the firm

available to researchers. The transfer of knowledge within the firm itself is another input

which generates innovative output. The literature proposed other (control) variables

potentially affecting the creation of new knowledge, such as firm size and monopoly

power.

External factors may also play a significant role in the innovation process.

Evolutionary models of the innovation process suggest the importance of networks as a

cause of knowledge transfer (Cagliano et Al., 2000; Love and Roper, 1999). These

external inputs basically come from three different sources. First, the firm can enhance

its innovation activity by making contracts and establishing alliances with other firms

(Santos et al., 2004). Second, firms are also the recipients of R&D spillovers from

knowledge generated in universities. Finally, the flow of ideas can also come from

sources such as customers and suppliers.

7

Links with other firms results in benefits and costs. Schmookler (1966) noted that

technological progress achieved by a firm might not solely be the result of its own

research efforts, but also the consequence of other firms’ research. According to

Dodgson (1994), collaboration with other enterprises can lead to positive sum gains, as

firms can achieve mutual benefits that could not be obtained independently. Other

benefits consist in accessing new markets, complementing and supplementing internal

product development efforts (Rothwell and Dodgson, 1991), and the transfer of explicit

and tacit knowledge (Karlsson and Olsson, 1998). The concern over appropriability

increases the costs of links with other firms, which may be, at the same time,

competitor; and the other part should have no interest in giving a wrong suggestion and

should be competent in giving a good advice.

Links with public research organizations allow firms to contact a source of

significant innovation-generating knowledge. This contact is extremely useful for small

firms, which can alleviate the scarcity of internal resources by accessing university

resource networks (Westhead and Storey, 1995).

As Freel (2000) noted, there are at least four gains from links with customers. First,

customers may provide their technical and managerial skills to firms; second, customers

involvement may easily results in user feedback and associated product improvement

that can lengthen the product life span. Third, user involvement is the ideal way to

establish the best optimum price/quality combination; and finally, the participation of

customers in the product design and development stages is likely to reduce the post-

delivery learning required by customers to get used to the new item.

External inputs may be particularly important for SMEs. The dynamic view of

industrial organization emphasizes the role of SMEs as “agents of change through

8

innovative activity” (Audretsch, 2002). Some authors (Acs et al. 1994 and Piergiovanni

et al. 1997) noted that, even if small firms are generally lacking of substantial R&D

investment, they provide a significant contributions in terms of innovative output.

Evidently they rely on other types of inputs; these authors found that spillovers from

university research laboratories are more important in producing innovative output in

small firms, rather than in large firm, where R&D expenditure play an important role in

generating innovation. As technology is far from costless (Pack and Westphal, 1986),

external transfer of knowledge and knowledge spillovers can alleviate the problem of

the lack of financial resources for new and growing SMEs. For this reason, venture

capital represents the instrument that may mitigate the high cost of R&D investment.

When the role of venture capital in financing innovative firms is marginal (as in our

sample where only 12 percent of firms use venture capital as a source of funds), not

only flows of ideas within a country but also flows from abroad may be another

important channel for the production of knowledge. According to Coe and Helpman

(1995), the advantages from foreign R&D are both direct and indirect; direct advantages

consist in learning about new technologies and materials, production processes, or

organizational methods. Indirect advantages originate from imports of goods and

services developed by trade partners. In this paper we concentrate on direct advantages

since our database does not contain any information on import.

Internationalization can influence the innovation activity in many ways. According to

Kotabe (2002) and Hitt et al. (1997), a globally engaged firm can improve its innovative

capacity by being better able to use a wider range of resources available globally, often

unavailable to domestic firms. Internationalization provides the opportunity to capture

ideas from a greater number of new and different markets, as well as from a wide range

9

of cultural perspectives; therefore, globally engaged firms have more opportunities to

learn (Hitt et al. 1997). Moreover, internationalization allows firms to reach a large

number of potential buyers (Riviera-Batiz and Romer, 1991).

Some researchers have stressed the benefits which derive to firms from exporting. As

Blalock and Gertler (2004) noted, exporting firms may benefit from exposure to intense

competition of international markets. Whereas non-exporting firms may be insulated

from such competition by trade policy or geographical barriers, firms producing for

world markets likely cannot survive without adopting best practice technology. At the

firm level exporting might improve productivity via the transfer of knowledge from

overseas buyers to the exporting firms. Grossman and Helpman (1991: 166) pointed out

the foreign purchasing agents may give some suggestions to exporters on how to

improve the manufacturing process. In fact, according to Evensond and Westpahl

(1995), a good deal of information needed to augment basic capabilities comes from the

international buyers who freely provide product designs and offered technical assistance

to improve process technology in the context of their sourcing activities. The

international collaboration agreements may also contribute to this process since they

represent another form of participation in international activities (Vitali, 1990).

Internationalization, therefore, appears to be a stimulus for successful networking

and research and technology collaboration. It is also an additional channel of

international knowledge spillovers and it alleviates the internal resource limitation of

SMEs.

Our empirical equation builds on the previous literature, which distinguishes among

internal and external (domestic and foreign) factors influencing firms’ propensity to

innovate. Instead of assuming a specific functional form, we define the following KPF:

10

Ki = f (Hi, Kii, Ki_i, IAi, Zi) (1)

where Ki is the innovative output in firm i, Hi represents the investment in R&D, Kii

indicates the internal transfer of knowledge, and Ki_i indicates the external transfer of

knowledge to firm i from outside. The term IAi indicates if the firms carry out

international activities; and the vector Zi indicates other (control) variables potentially

affecting the creation of new knowledge, such as firm size and market dimension.

In equation (1) there are two additional terms with respect to the standard literature

on the KPF. First, adding the term Ki_i allows to distinguish information flows within

firm and flows from outside: firms intentionally accumulate their stock of knowledge,

which is a fundamental ingredient to innovate. The term Ki_i considers the additional

flow of knowledge that firms may benefit from intra-firm pool of information,

suppliers, customers and public research organizations.

Second, the term IAi identifies firms active in international markets; international

activities might enable firms to gain access to foreign knowledge sources. For example,

exporting firms are more easily aware of potential innovations taking place abroad, that

enterprises might assimilate to improve their position and to compete successfully both

in domestic and foreign markets.

3 Descriptive Statistics

In this paper we used a microeconomic dataset of Italian manufacturing small and

medium sized enterprises (SMEs). The database has been built up on the basis of

11

information collected by Unioncamere-Tagliacarne through personal interviews with

firm owners or top managers relatively to years 2001-2003.

Although the starting sample included 3,409 firms, the number of firms for which we

have constructed our model is 2,603 because of missing values. The response rate of

about 76 percent is relatively high in comparison with similar researches in literature,

such as CHS whose response rate for UK enterprises is 42 percent.

A detailed analysis about the structure of the questionnaire and some characteristics

of the sample are presented in Morone and Testa (2005) who examined the determinants

of Italian SMEs’ turnover growth and in Reganati (2004) who analyzed the

determinants of internationalization of SMEs. In this study we prefer to summarize the

characteristics of the sample strictly linked to the aim of our analysis.

Tables I - IV show the main characteristics of our sample distinguishing between

firms that have undertaken product innovation and firms that have registered a patent in

the period considered.

In the specific case, about 28 percent of firms in our sample have undertaken product

innovation and 8 percent have registered at least a patent in order to protect their

innovations (Table I).

Table I: Innovation activity of the Italian manufacturing firms according to the size

Product

Innovations Patents

Total firms

Micro firms (0 - 9) 21.9 5.2 83.0 Small firms (10 - 49) 5.4 2.2 15.1 Medium firms (50 - 249) 0.7 0.5 1.9

Total firms 28.0 7.9 100.0

(Source: own elaboration on Tagliacarne data)

12

These relatively low percentages of innovation activity resulting from our analysis

might reflect two main aspects of the Italian productive system characterized by a high

presence of micro firms (about 83 percent of total firms present in our sample have less

than nine employees) together with a strong specialization in traditional and specialized

suppliers sectors.

Moreover, considering both innovation activity and geographical distribution, most

of innovative firms are concentrated in North Italy while only 21 percent of innovative

firms are located in South Italy of which about 70 percent are micro firms. This picture

reveals the strong gap between North and South Italy. The situation is almost the same

if we consider patents as a proxy for innovation activity; in fact, in this case 55 percent

of firms that have registered a patent in the period 2001-2003 are located in North Italy

and only 16 percent in the South of Italy.

When we take into account two activities in serving foreign markets – exports and

foreign agreements - we find some interesting results (Table II). In the specific case

about 44 percent of firms present on foreign markets through export have realized

product innovation and 23 percent have registered a patent. While more than 50 percent

of firms that have concluded collaboration agreements with foreign firms have

undertaken at least one product innovation and about 31 percent of them have registered

a patent. Most of them are located in only three markets (UE15, United States and

Japan). These data confirm that firms entering in industrialized country’s foreign

markets through collaborations agreements might generate more innovation than their

counterparts operating exclusively on local markets.

13

The percentages of domestic firms that have realized product innovations (23.6%)

and patents (6.7%) are rather low. This picture shows that firms present on foreign

markets are more innovative than their non-exporting counterparts.

Table II: Innovation activity of the Italian manufacturing firms according to the internationalization activities

Product Innovations Patents Total firms Export 44.4 23.0 20.4 Foreign Agreements 52.5 30.9 5.7

UE15 55.3 36.8 3.9 Japan 62.7 39.0 0.4

United States 59.0 49.3 0.9 Domestic firms 23.6 6.7 78.2

(Source: own elaboration on Tagliacarne data)

When we consider the sectoral distribution of innovative firms, Table III shows that

most of innovative firms are concentrated in the sector of Electronics and transport

equipment (4.8%), followed by Food products, beverages and tobacco (4.7%) and

Wood and products of wood (3.7%). Considering patents as an indicator of innovation

activity, the same table shows that firms which have undertaken a patent are

concentrated in Food products, beverages and tobacco, followed by Machinery and

equipment and Electronics and transport equipment with the percentages rather low.

14

Table III: Sectoral distribution of Innovation activity of the Italian manufacturing firms

Product

Innovations Patents Total firms

Food products, beverages and tobacco 4.7 1.4 12.4 Textiles and wearing apparel 3.1 0.5 13.6 Leather, leather products and footwear 0.7 0.4 4.0 Wood and products of wood (furniture inclusive) 3.7 0.7 15.0 Chemicals, chemical products, rubber and plastics products 1.1 0.4 3.5 Non-metallic mineral products 0.7 0.0 4.9 Basic metals and fabricated metal products 3.4 0.8 18.8 Machinery and equipment 3.0 1.3 7.8 Electronics and transport equipment 4.8 1.3 11.0 Others 2.8 1.1 9.1

(Source: own elaboration on Tagliacarne data)

Finally, Table IV shows summary statistics on the three knowledge inputs:

innovation expenditure, internal transfers of knowledge and external transfers of

knowledge. Globally engaged firms (i.e. firms active on international markets through

both exports and foreign collaborations) use more inputs for making new ideas; this is

true not only for the first two inputs, but also for the external flows of knowledge. In

particular, a significantly higher fraction of globally engaged firms (29.9%) make use of

the latter input compared to domestic firms, whose fraction is only 19.2 percent.

Table IV: Knowledge inputs in the globally engaged and domestic firms

Globally engaged

firms Domestic firms Total firms

Innovation expenditure 69.0 44.3 49.7 Internal flows 40.3 23.5 27.2 External flows 29.9 19.2 21.6

(Source: own elaboration on Tagliacarne data)

From tables II and IV we conclude that globally engaged and domestic firms differ

along three dimensions of the knowledge production function: knowledge outputs,

knowledge investment and access to internal and external stock of knowledge. The last

15

dimension captures the idea that the firms active on international markets benefit from

many channels for technology diffusion.

4 Variables used

The present section analyses the variables used to estimate equation (1), starting from

the measurement of the knowledge in the firm i (Ki). There is an ongoing debate in

economic literature about how best to conceptualize and operationalize this variable. In

general, innovation can be interpreted following both an object and a subject approach.

In the first, the unit of observation is the individual innovation; in the second, the unit of

observation is the product/process developed or improved at the firm level. Since in the

object approach individual innovations are selected on the perceptions of experts, with

the consequence that comparisons between studies and countries are difficult (Amara

and Landry, 2005), in this study we followed the subject approach: innovative firms are

determined according to the kind of innovation they have adopted during the previous

two years. Obviously, in case a firm has not adopted any type of innovation it is

classified as ‘not-innovative’. We suppose that, to compete in international markets,

firms need to develop different products both in terms of quality and features, i.e.

product innovation (Herguera and Lutz, 2003). As a consequence, we proxy the

knowledge in a firm through a dummy variable assuming a value equal to one if the

enterprise has adopted at least one product innovation and zero otherwise.

Following most of the studies on this topic, in order to test the robustness of our

model we use patent data as another measure of innovation output.

16

However, this proxy generally exhibits a number of weaknesses. In particular, we

employ a dummy variable assuming a value equal to one if a firm has registered some

patents in the previous two years, and zero otherwise.

To measure the current flow of resources devoted to the generation of innovation

(Hi), we use as a proxy the amount of innovation expenditure. More specifically, we

employ a dummy variable assuming a value equal to one if the firm has invested in

innovation and zero otherwise. We should expect a positive relationship between the

amount of innovation expenditure and innovativeness. However, as observed by some

authors (Cabral, 1998; Cohen and Levin, 1989), this proxy is valid under the

assumption that innovation is a ‘linear’ consequence of innovation expenditure.

Alternatively, we could employ the percentage of people working in R&D, but our

dataset do not contain information about it.

The variable Kii was proxied through a dummy variable indicating whether or not

suggestions/ideas for innovations come from: technical workforce or R&D area or

parent company. It is worth noting that since we assume that innovations may be

developed, independently of R&D, from an interactive process characterized by

technological interrelations between various subsystems (Caloghirou, 2004; Teece,

1996), the restrictive hypothesis of a linear relationship between innovation and amount

of innovation expenditure is overcome.

The flow of ideas from outside (Ki_i) was assessed through the introduction of a

dummy variable, indicating whether or not innovation originates from: R&D activities

with Universities, Research Organizations, or Scientific and Technological Parks or

suggestions from suppliers, customers, technical consultants and other upstream and

downstream firms in the same supply chain. Furthermore, we consider the possibility

17

that the ideas to develop a new product come from a process of imitation of other firms.

It is widely recognized, in fact, that innovation and imitation interact with each other:

successful innovations encourage imitations as well as imitations lead to a larger

diffusion of innovation (Zeng, 2001). On the whole, we expect that the coefficient of the

dummy variable Ki_i is positive.

The variable IAi was measured through two different dummies. The first assumes a

value equal to one if a firm supplies its product(s) mainly to international markets. The

second assumes a value equal to one if a firm has entered into some collaboration

agreement with foreign companies located in industrialized countries. Actually the main

forms of international penetration are exports and Foreign Direct Investments (FDI)

(Basile et al., 2002), but due to the lack of data on FDI, we have included

“Collaboration agreements” as an additional measure of firms’ internationalization. In

fact, being the latter “the process of increasing involvement in international operations”

(Welch and Luostarinen, 1988), collaboration agreements with foreign enterprises may

represent a good alternative way to measure the level of companies’

internationalization. For the reasons illustrated in the section 2, we expect a positive

coefficient for both these variables, meaning that the global engaged companies are

more innovative.

Finally, the vector of other variables which might favor the creation of new

knowledge (Zi) includes indicators concerning firm’s and market’s size.

Firm size was measured in terms of total number of employees, using a dummy

variable assuming the value equal to one whether the firm is considered ‘larger’ (i.e. if

the total number of employees is included between 50 and 249 units) and zero

otherwise. The question of whether a large firm is more innovative compared to a small

18

one or vice versa has been subject of a great deal of controversy and research (Rogers,

2004; Stock et al., 2002; Symeonidis, 1996; Cohen and Klepper, 1994; Rothwell and

Dodgson, 1994; Acs and Audretsch, 1991). From a Schumpeterian perspective, there

exists a positive relationship between market power and innovation, mainly due to the

possibility to reach economies of scale in R&D activities. When a firm dominates a

market it is able to finance investment in innovation and, since it typically produces

different types of products, needs to develop new technologies (Marlin and Scott, 2000).

Thus, larger enterprises should be more innovative compared to the small ones. On the

opposite, part of literature argues that a smaller firm might be more innovative given its

flexibility and its major willingness to new challenges and changes. As a consequence,

the expected sign of this variable is uncertain: it could be both positive and negative.

The market’s size was proxied through a control variable assuming a value equal to

one if a firm supplies its product(s) mainly in a niche market, and zero otherwise. The

reason is that focusing on a niche, a firm addresses a need for a product not addressed

by the mainstream suppliers: in this way it obtains the great advantage of being alone in

that subset of market. Obviously, this asks for a deep specialization in a specific

product/service. According to the characteristics of the product supplied, some firms

will need to innovate incessantly to preserve their position in the niche, while others

could not have this necessity. Being this only an hypothesis, the expect sign of this

variable is uncertain.

5 Methods of estimation and results

Before conducting a complete discussion about the results of econometric

estimations, we provide some explanations about the choice of the model.

19

In implementing our estimations, we face two difficulties. First of all, we can build

only binary variables since the Tagliacarne Institute supplies exclusively qualitative

information (such as export/not export or invest/not invest and so on). Secondly, our

database does not contain the fiscal code or VAT number of any single firm. Therefore,

we cannot match this database with others in order to include other firms’ specific

variables that might be relevant for our analysis.

Thus, given these limitations, we believe that the best econometric specification to

investigate the relationship between innovative activity and firm’s characteristics is a

probit model which is well-suited to analyze qualitative data when we have two

alternatives. As we have seen in section 4, we used two different measures of

innovation. We start considering as innovative a firm that has implemented at least one

product innovation in the period under analysis. Subsequently, we test for the

robustness adopting an alternative model specification where we define as innovative a

firm that has registered at least a patent.

For expositional simplicity we consider a linearized version of the KPF of equation

(1), specified in the following way:

iiiii XY

with E[ε] = 0 and V[ε]=σε2

To determine the influence of the international activity on a firm’s innovativeness we

implement two main estimates according to the definition of innovation used (Table V

and Table VI). For any estimation we report, respectively, the estimated coefficients,

their standard errors and their marginal effects. Following CHS we estimate equation

(1) by adding different regressors in the course of analysis; this method allows us to

20

have more precise information about the impact of global engagement variables.

Estimations have been implemented using “STATA” econometric software.

Table V reports estimation results when product innovation is used as a dependent

variable. Column 1 summarizes the results when only global-engagement indicators

(Export and Industrialized) are used. Both the variables are statistically significant.

Precisely, the coefficients on Export and Industrialized indicate that the firms of our

sample are, respectively, 23 percentage points and 18 percentage points more likely to

be innovative than their counterparts which are active only on the national market. In

the specific case, the variable Industrialized confirms the relevance of collaboration

with firms located in industrialized countries in order to develop innovation activity.

Adding to the estimation in column 1 the variable Innovation expenditure, we obtain

column 2, where all the coefficients are statistically significant and have the expected

sign; the addition of this variable reduces only slightly the coefficients of global-

engagement variables. These results are consistent with those obtained by CHS.

21

The results change when we add information flows from existing knowledge inside

and outside the firm (Table V column 3). In this case, the coefficients of global

engagement have the expected signs, but the variable Industrialized becomes significant

at 5 percent level. Many considerations could be argued. Firstly, the addition of these

measures of information flows reduces the marginal impact of both our global

engagement variables (by almost 33 percent for export and 30 percent for

industrialized). As CHS noted, this is an important finding of our analysis: almost 30

percent of innovative activity of globally engaged firms is explained by their superior

access to information from existing knowledge, both internal and external.

Distinguishing between information flows, external flows have a slightly higher

marginal effect than internal flows: a firm who learns a great deal from external sources

Table V: Probit estimations for 'Product Innovation'

coeff.marginal effects

coeff.marginal effects

coeff.marginal effects

coeff.marginal effects

-0.751 -0.965 -1.411 -1,418(-23.41)*** (-26.40)*** (-33.43)*** (-33.16)

0.637 0.231 0.531 0.189 0.403 0.136 0,413 0.139(10.75)*** (10.49)*** (8.65)*** (8.38)*** (6.03)*** (5.80)*** (6.05)*** (5.81)***

0.479 0.179 0.373 0.136 0.296 0.102 0,284 0.097(4.57)*** (4.34)*** (3.41)*** (3.22)*** (2.70)*** (2.54)** (2.54)** (2.40)**

0.845 0.307 0.436 0.148 0,427 0.144(14.16)*** (13.91)*** (6.10)*** (5.78)*** (5.96)*** (5.65)***

0.911 0.314 0,916 0.315(13.62)*** (13.15)*** (13.67)*** (13.2)***

0.986 0.352 0,984 0.351(13.93)*** (13.39)*** (13.87)*** (13.31)***

-0,067 -0.021(-0.74) (-0.76)

0,419 0.149(2.51)*** (2.32)***

N. of Obs. 2603 2603 2603 2603

Pseudo R2 0.0565 0.1204 0.2560 0.2584*, **, *** statistically significant at the 10, 5 and 1 percent level, respectively

probit probit probit(1) (2) (3) (4)

Const

probitIndipendent variables

Dependent variable: PRODUCT INNOVATION

Export

Internal Flows

Industrialized

Innovation Expenditure

Niche

External Flows

Size

22

(competitors, customers, suppliers) for innovation would be 35 percentage points more

likely to be innovative. The coefficient on internal flows indicates that a firm benefiting

from intra-firm knowledge flows is 31 percentage points more likely to innovate.

Secondly, adding the set of control regressors – Size and Niche - the impacts of

global engagement and ‘information-source’ regressors do not change to a large extent

(column 4). The coefficient of Niche is positive and highly statistically significant,

whereas the coefficient on Size is negative but not significant.

Table VI replicates the regression results when Patents is used as a dependent

variable. In this case, the pattern of findings is broadly similar. All the variables

considered are highly significant at 1 percent level (except for Niche in the column 4

significant at 10 percent level). Also in this case, the impact of global engagement

variables decreases once the internal and external flows variables are included (columns

2-4). However, the magnitude of the marginal effect of export variable is now slightly

lower while that of Industrialized is higher.

23

6 Summary and concluding remarks

This study has explored the differences in innovation output across the Italian

manufacturing firms with a different degree of international commitment.

We have adopted the knowledge production function’s approach, which consists in

exploring the differences in the production of new knowledge across firms. Therefore,

we have examined the innovation output in a firm as depending on a set of variables,

specifically the level of international engagement, innovation expenditure, and the

amount of internal and external flows of knowledge transfer. In particular, we have

assumed that a firm’s international activity is carried out through both exports and/or

collaboration agreements with foreign firms.

Table VI: Probit estimations for 'Patents'

coeff.marginal effects

coeff.marginal effects

coeff.marginal effects

coeff.marginal effects

-1.439 -1.579 -1.942 -1.979(-33.77)*** (-32.45)*** (-33.90)*** (-34.01)***

0.768 0.185 0.693 0.159 0.598 0.118 0.531 0.103(11.22)*** (9.93)*** (9.97)*** (8.81)*** (8.19)*** (7.19)*** (7.04)*** (6.21)***

0.743 0.204 0.682 0.179 0.599 0.136 0.554 0.123(6.88)*** (5.49)*** (6.29)*** (5.01)*** (5.36)*** (4.20)*** (4.92)*** (3.90)***

0.518 0.115 0.216 0.038 0.218 0.039(7.56)*** (6.76)*** (2.68)*** (2.49)*** (2.69)*** (2.49)**

0.856 0.176 0.838 0.171(11.28)*** (9.64)*** (10.98)*** (9.39)***

0.423 0.082 0.426 0.082(5.45)*** (4.74)*** (5.44)*** (4.71)***

0.344 0.067(3.88)*** (3.38)***

0.319 0.064(1.82)* (1.54)

N. of Obs. 2603 2603 2603 2603

Pseudo R2 0.1142 0.1405 0.2220 0.2302*, **, *** statistically significant at the 10, 5 and 1 percent level, respectively

(4)probitprobit

Dependent variable: PATENTS(2) (3)(1)

Const

probit probitIndipendent variables

Export

Internal Flows

Industrialized

Innovation Expenditure

Niche

External Flows

Size

24

In order to test for estimations’ robustness, we have employed alternative measures

of innovation (product innovations and ‘patents’).

Our findings - broadly in line with the results of the recent studies on UK and

German firm level data - can be summarized as follows.

First, firms active in international markets generate more knowledge than their

counterparts which sell in the national market only; this is true for alternative measures

of innovation.

Second, the previous result may be partly explained by the fact that globally engaged

firms employ more knowledge inputs, such as higher innovation expenditures.

Third, international firms innovate more thanks to the access to a larger flow of ideas

from external sources. In other words, they have many more opportunities of learning

from external flows of knowledge with respect to ‘domestic-market-oriented’

companies. These flows of ideas can originate from several sources, such as suggestions

and proposals from people external to the firm but someway involved in the production

process (customers, suppliers etc.), and inter-firm structural linkages, i.e. cooperative

relationships which take place between a firm and its competitors or between a firm and

external organizations (Universities, Research Organizations, Scientific and

Technological Parks etc.). This suggests the importance of foreign sources of

technology as a strategic key of firms to generate more knoweledge output.

Consequently, we conclude that, in order to generate innovation, the investment

intensity on internal R&D should be supported by international engagement, networking

capabilities, and by the use of external sources of knowledge and information.

25

As a future line of research, therefore, it would be interesting to analyze the effects

on firms’ knowledge production of the policy measures adopted with the purpose of

promoting firms’ internationalization.

References Acs, Z. J. and Audretsch, D. B., 1991, ‘R&D, Firm Size and Innovative Activity’, in Acs, Z. J. and

Audretsch, D. B. (eds.), Innovation and Technological Change, London, Harvester Wheatsheaf, 39-59.

Acs, Z., D. Audretsch and M. Feldman, 1994, ‘R&D Spillovers and Recipient Firm Size’, Review of

Economics and Statistics, 76, 336-340. Amara, N. and R. Landry, 2005, ‘Sources of information as determinants of novelty of innovation in

manufacturing firms: evidence from the 1999 statistics Canada innovation survey’ Technovation 25, 245–259.

Audretsch, D., 2002, ‘The Dynamic Role of Small Firms: Evidence from the U.S.’, Small Business

Economics, 18, 13-40. Basile R., A. Giunta and J. Nugent, 2002, ‘Foreign Expansion by Italian Manufacturing Firms in the

Nineties: an Ordered Probit Analysis’, Discussion Paper Series 27, Università della Calabria, Dipartimento di Economia e Statistica.

Blalock, G. and P. Gertler, 2004, Learning from Exporting Revisited in a Less Developed Setting’,

Journal of Development Economics,397-416. Cabral J.E.O., 1998, ‘Survey on Technological Innovative Behavior in the Brazilian Food Industry’

Scientometrics 42(2), 129-169. Cagliano, R., V. Chiesa and R. Manzini, 2000, ‘Differences and similarities in managing technological

collaborations in reserach, development and manufacturing: a case study’ Journal of Engineering and Technology Management 17, 193-224.

Caloghirou, Y, I. Kastelli and A. Tsakanikas, 2004, ‘Internal capabilities and external knowledge sources:

complements or substitutes for innovative performance? Technovation 24, 29–39. Castellani, D. and A. Zanfei, 2007, ‘Internationalisation, Innovation and Productivity: How Do Firms

Differ in Italy?’, The World Economy, 156-176. Coe, D. and E. Helpman, 1995, ‘International R&D Spillovers’, European Economic Review, 39, 859-

887. Cohen, W.M. and R.C. Levin, 1989, ‘Empirical Studies of innovation and Market Structure’ in

Schamalensee, R. and R.D. Willig (Eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization 2, 1059-1107. Cohen, W. M. and S. Klepper, 1994, ‘Firm size and the nature of innovation within industries: the case of

process and product R&D’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 788 (2) 232-243. Criscuolo, C., J. Haskel and M. Slaughter, 2005, ‘Global Engagement and the Innovation Activities of

Firms’, NBER WP no. 11479.

26

Dodgson, M., 1994, Technological Collaboration and Innovation, The Handbook of Industrial Innovation,

Elgar, Aldershot, UK. Evenson, R. and L. Westphal, 1995, ‘Technological Change and Technology Strategy’, in T.N. Srinivasan

and J. Behrman, eds., Handbook of Development Economics, v.3, North Holland. Freel, M., 2000, ‘External Linkages and Product Innovation in Small Manufacturing Firms’,

Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 12, 245-266. Griliches, Z., 1979, ‘Issues in Assessing the Contribution of R&D to Productivity Growth’, Bell Journal

of Economics (10), 92-116. Griliches, Z., 1990, ‘Patent Statistics as Economic Indicators: A Survey’ Journal of Economic

Literature28 (4), 1661-1707. Grossman, G. and E. Helpman, 1991, ‘Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy’, Cambridge, MA,

MIT Press. Herguera, I. and S. Lutz, 2003, ‘The Effects of Subsidies to Product Innovation on International

Competition’ Economics of Innovation and New Technology 12(5), 465-480. Hitt, M., R. Hoskisson and H. Kim, 1997, ‘International Diversification: Effects on Innovation and Firm

Performance in Product-Diversified Firms’, Academy of Management Journal, 40 (4), 767-798. Kafouros, M., P. Buckley, J. Sharp and C. Wang, 2008, ‘The Role of Internationalization in Explaining

Innovation Performance’, Technovation, 28, 63-74. Karlsson, C. and O. Olsson, 1998, ‘Product Innovation in Small and Large Enterprises’, Small Business

Economics, 10, 31-46. Keeble, D., C. Lawson, H. Smith, B. Moore and F. Wilkinson, 1998, ‘Internationalisation Processes,

Networking and Local Embeddedness in Technology-Intensive Small Firms’, Small Business Economics, 11, 327-342.

Kotabe, M., S. Srinivasan and P. Aulakh, 2002, ‘Multinationality and Firm Performance: the Moderating

Role of R&D and Marketing Capabilities’, Journal of International Business Studies, 33, 79-97. Love, J.H. and S. Roper, 1999, ‘The Determinants of Innovation: R&D, Technology Transfer and

Networking Effects’ Review of Industrial Organization 15, 43-64. Mansfield, E., 1968, ‘The Economics of Technological Change’, Norton, New York. Marlin, S. and J.T. Scott, 2000, ‘The nature of innovation market failure and the design of public support

for private innovation’ Research Policy29, 437-447. Morone, P. and G. Testa, 2005, ‘What Makes Small and Medium Enterprises Competitive’ DSEMS

University of Foggia WP n. 18 Pack, H. and L. Westphal, 1986, ‘Industrial Strategy and Technical Change: Theory Versus Reality’,

Journal of Development Economics, 22, 87-128. Piergiovanni, R., E. Santarelli and M. Vivarelli, 1997, ‘From which Source do Small Firms Derive their

Innovative Inputs? Some Evidence from Italian Industry’, Review of Industrial Organization, 12, 243-258.

27

Reganati, F., 2004, ‘I processi di internazionalizzazione delle PMI" in Le piccole e medie imprese nell'economia italiana - Rapporto 2004’ - Realizzato a cura dell'Istituto Guglielmo Tagliacarne Edizione FrancoAngeli - Unioncamere

Rivera-Batiz, L. and P. Romer, 1991, ‘ Economic Integration and Endogenous Growth’, Quarterly Journal

of Economics, 106(2), 531-556. Rogers, M., 2004, ‘Networks, Firm Size and Innovation’, Small Business Economics, 22, 141-153. Romer, P.M., 1990, “Endogenous technological change”, Journal of Political Economy, 98 (5), 71-102. Rothwell, R. and M. Dodgson, 1991, ‘External Linkages and Innovation in Small and Medium-sized

Enterprises’, R&D Management, 21, 125-137. Rothwell, R. and Dodgson, M., 1994, ‘Innovation and Size of Firm’, in Dodgson, M. and Rothwell, R.

(eds.), The Handbook of Industrial Innovation, Cheltenham, UK, Edward Elgar. Santos, J., Y. Doz and P. Williamson, 2004, ‘Is Your Innovation Process Global?’, MIT Sloan

Management Review, 31-37. Schmookler, J., 1966, ‘Invention and Economic Growth’, Harvard University Press. Symeonidis, G., 1996, ‘Innovation, Firm Size and Market Structure: Schumpeterian Hypotheses and

Some New Themes’, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 161, OECD Publishing.

Spence, M., 1984, ‘Cost reduction, competition, and industry performance’, Econometrica, 52 (1), 368-

402. Stock, G.N., N.P. Greis and W.A. Fischer, 2002, ‘Firm size and dynamic technological innovation’

Technovation 22, 537-549. Teece, D., 1996, ‘Firm organisation, industrial structure and technological innovation’ Journal of

Economic Behaviour and Organisation 31, 193–224. Vitali, G., 1995, ‘Accordi tecnologici e processo di internazionalizzazione dell'industria italiana", in A.

La Bella, M. Raffa, G. Zollo (eds), Leve strategiche nei mercati integrati, Etas Libri. Wagner, J., 2006, ‘Exports, Foreign Direct Investment, and productivity: Evidence from German Firm

Level Data’, University of Luneburg, Working Paper Series in Economics no. 25. Welch, L.S. and R.K. Luostarinen, 1988, ‘Internationalization: evolution of a concept’, Journal of General

Management, 14 No.2, 36-64. Westhead, P., and Storey, D. J., 1995, ‘Links Between Higher Education Institutions and High

Technology Firms’, Omega, International Journal of Management Science, 23, 345-360. Zeng, J., 2001, ‘Innovative vs. imitative R&D and economic growth’ Journal of Development Economics

64, 499-528.