informal labor markets and macroeconomic fluctuations

40
Informal Labor Markets and Macroeconomic Fluctuations Norbert M. Fiess + Marco Fugazza ° William F. Maloney * November 13, 2006 Abstract: This paper examines the adjustment of developing country labor markets to macroeconomic shocks. It models a two sector labor market: a formal salaried (tradable) sector that may or may not be affected by union or legislation induced wage rigidities, and an unregulated (nontradable) self-employment sector facing liquidity constraints to entry. This is embedded in a standard small economy macro model that permits the derivation of patterns of comovement among relative salaried/self-employed incomes, salaried/self-employed sector sizes and the real exchange rate with respect to different types of shocks in contexts with and without wage rigidities. The paper then explores time series data from Argentina, Brazil, Colombia and Mexico to test for cointegrating relationships corresponding to the patterns predicted by theory. We identify two types of regime. The first corresponds to periods where demand shocks to the nontradable sector offer new opportunities to (informal) entrepreneurs, the informal sector expands “procyclically,” and the exchange rate overshoots toward appreciation in the short run, or remains at its productivity determined levels. The second corresponds to periods of negative shocks to the formal salaried sector in the presence of wage rigidities where the sector plays a more traditional “buffer” role during downturns. JEL: Informality, Labor market dynamics, Self-employment, Real exchange rates. This work partially financed by the Regional Studies Program of the Office of the Chief Economist for Latin America and the Caribbean. It is a substantially reworked version of the previous “Exchange Rate Appreciations, Labor Market Rigidities and Informality” (2002). We are grateful to Rashmi Shankar for early conceptual discussions, to Leonardo Gaspirini for helpful comments, to Norman Loayza and Claudio Montenegro for help with data, and to Gabriel Montes for expert research assistance. Corresponding author: [email protected]. + University of Glasgow ° UNCTAD * Chief Economist Office for Latin America and the Caribbean, The World Bank

Upload: independent

Post on 23-Nov-2023

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Informal Labor Markets and Macroeconomic Fluctuations •

Norbert M. Fiess+

Marco Fugazza°

William F. Maloney∗

November 13, 2006

Abstract: This paper examines the adjustment of developing country labor markets to macroeconomic shocks. It models a two sector labor market: a formal salaried (tradable) sector that may or may not be affected by union or legislation induced wage rigidities, and an unregulated (nontradable) self-employment sector facing liquidity constraints to entry. This is embedded in a standard small economy macro model that permits the derivation of patterns of comovement among relative salaried/self-employed incomes, salaried/self-employed sector sizes and the real exchange rate with respect to different types of shocks in contexts with and without wage rigidities. The paper then explores time series data from Argentina, Brazil, Colombia and Mexico to test for cointegrating relationships corresponding to the patterns predicted by theory. We identify two types of regime. The first corresponds to periods where demand shocks to the nontradable sector offer new opportunities to (informal) entrepreneurs, the informal sector expands “procyclically,” and the exchange rate overshoots toward appreciation in the short run, or remains at its productivity determined levels. The second corresponds to periods of negative shocks to the formal salaried sector in the presence of wage rigidities where the sector plays a more traditional “buffer” role during downturns. JEL: Informality, Labor market dynamics, Self-employment, Real exchange rates.

• This work partially financed by the Regional Studies Program of the Office of the Chief Economist for Latin America and the Caribbean. It is a substantially reworked version of the previous “Exchange Rate Appreciations, Labor Market Rigidities and Informality” (2002). We are grateful to Rashmi Shankar for early conceptual discussions, to Leonardo Gaspirini for helpful comments, to Norman Loayza and Claudio Montenegro for help with data, and to Gabriel Montes for expert research assistance. Corresponding author: [email protected]. + University of Glasgow ° UNCTAD ∗ Chief Economist Office for Latin America and the Caribbean, The World Bank

1

1. Introduction The debate over the role of informal workers -those unprotected by labor

legislation- in the developing country labor market goes back almost half a century. A

prominent stream of the literature has intellectual roots perhaps best distilled in Harris

and Todaro’s (1970) vision of markets segmented by wage setting in the formal sector

that leaves the traditional sector rationed out of modern salaried employment.1 The view

of the informal sector as the inferior segment of a dual labor market, expanding during

downturns to absorb increased unemployment, became highly influential in the

International Labor Organization, its Latin America affiliate, the Latin America Regional

Employment Program (PREALC), and the World Bank.2

However, dating at least from Hart’s (1973) work in Africa, a parallel stream has

stressed the sector’s dynamism and the likely voluntary nature of much of the entry into

informal self-employment, analogous to the mainstream literature such as Jovanovic

(1982), and Evans and Jovanovic (1989), and Evans and Leighton (1989).3 Recent work

has called into question the value of the conditional income comparisons, commonly used

to demonstrate segmentation, both on conceptual and empirical grounds.4 Further, a first

look at time series for Mexico suggests more nuanced cyclical behavior than that of a

shock absorber during downturns. Figure 1 plots the evolution of the relative salaried/

informal self-employed sector sizes and respective earnings and shows that during the

recovery of 1987-1991 both the relative size of the informal self-employed sector relative

to the formal sector, and the relative earnings of the self-employed rise, consistent with a

procyclical expansion of that sector. Since roughly 75% of the informal self-employed

are found in services, transportation or construction, it is plausible that the boom in real

estate and other non-tradable industries across this period created new opportunities for

entrepreneurs who, for whatever reason, chose to be informal.5 That this episode is not a

1 In fact, in Harris and Todaro’s model, the “traditional” sector was the rural sector disposed to migrate. However, it represents perhaps the first analytically worked out view of the dual labor market and remains highly relevant to the debate over the segmented rural sector. 2 For early statements, see Sethuraman (1981), Tokman (1978), Mazumdar (1975), respectively. 3 See for more recent formulations in this vein, de Soto (1989) and Maloney (2004). 4 See Maloney 1999, Pratap and Quintin 2006 5 The self-employed are concentrated in nontradables: Brazil 92%, Colombia 87%, Mexico 83%.

2

statistical anomaly is suggested by Loayza and Rigolini’s (2006) recent finding of pro-

cyclical movement in the informal sector in several of their sample of 42 countries.

However, it is also the case that the subsequent period leading up to the crisis of 1995,

the countercyclical movements envisaged by more traditional segmentation views appear,

manifested as a negative comovement of earnings and labor market sector sizes.

These distinct patterns suggest that the pro- or countercyclicality of the two labor

market sectors may depend on the sectoral origin of the shocks, and the presence of

binding wage rigidities. They also suggest that time series data on these series may offer

potentially useful labor market diagnostics, for instance, in identifying the roots of

expansion of the informal sector across a given period. However, for this to be the case,

we need to understand the drivers of the very large observed movements in relative

wages which in a textbook world, would be forced to equivalence. Three effects in

principle may be at play: barriers to the arbitrage of labor earnings due to barriers to entry

to either sector, barriers to arbitraging of returns to capital of the self-employed which are

generally not separable in labor market surveys from earnings of labor per se, and

changes in the skills composition of the sectoral work forces.

To capture these effects, we begin by constructing a model of developing country

labor markets that is firmly rooted in the established advanced country literature. We

postulate two sectors: a salaried (tradable) sector where workers receive a wage and are

covered by labor legislation or unions; and a nontradable self-employed sector of the kind

postulated by Lucas (1978) with heterogeneity in level of entrepreneurial ability and

where, following Evans and Jovanovic (1989), credit constraints can constitute a barrier

to entry from salaried work. Self-employed workers receive a variable return to invested

capital and their labor which, due to capital adjustment costs arising from credit

constraints, may deviate from long run equilibrium levels.

We locate this labor market in a standard macroeconomic framework (Obstfeld

and Rogoff 1996) that allows us to capture additional information on the sectoral origin

of the shocks through the real exchange rate - a measure of relative prices of tradables

3

and nontradables. This allows us to move beyond simply defining cyclical movements as

a deviation from trend and to characterize the nature of the shocks driving it. Given the

high concentration of the informal self-employed in the nontradables sector, we are able

to derive patterns of comovement between the relative returns and relative sizes of

salaried and self-employed sectors, and the real exchange rate.

Finally, we introduce potential wage rigidities in the salaried tradable sector. As

in the classic Harris-Todaro formulation, formalized in Rauch (1991), the labor market

can become segmented with workers rationed out of salaried/tradable employment and

being forced into the self-employed/nontradables sector where earnings adjust to equate

labor supply and demand. This segmentation gives rise to distinct patterns of

comovement of the three series in response to productivity or demand shocks.

Thus, we provide an integrated model of LDC labor markets that permits

developing a typology of comovements of macroeconomic time series that, once

identified, can help identify the source of shocks and the presence or absence of formal

sector segmenting distortions. The latter offers an alternative to unreliable conditional

income comparisons.6 Empirically, we employ multivariate cointegration techniques to

establish these predicted patterns of comovement and their evolution over the last two

decades in Argentina, Brazil, Colombia and Mexico. These countries all have large

informal self-employed sectors, and have experienced very large movements in levels of

economic activity, the relative sizes of the two labor market sectors, and real exchange

rates.7

We confirm episodes of expansion of informal self-employment consistent with

the traditional segmentation views. However, we also identify episodes consistent with

6 Total returns to Informal self employment and salaried employment incorporate differences in taxes, risk premia, flexibility, etc all of which will lead to incomes not being equated, even in the absence of segmentation. See Maloney (1999). 7 In Mexico from 1988-1995, Argentina 1990-1995, and Brazil beginning in 1992, the exchange rate appreciated, often dramatically, following stabilization policies that fixed the nominal exchange rate, liberalized capital markets, and implemented other reforms.

4

the sectoral expansion being driven by a positive demand shock to the nontradables

sector and “procyclical” behavior of the informal self-employed sector.

2. A Model

We consider the case of a small economy that produces two composite goods,

tradables and nontradables. The salaried sector is assumed to produce tradables (T), the

numeraire, while the production of nontradables is concentrated in the self-employed

sector (N)8. All workers are homogenous when salaried. However, following Lucas

(1978), self-employed sector individuals (j) differ in terms of entrepreneurial capability,

φj distributed uniformly on [0,1]. For simplicity, we also normalize the labor force to

unity so that, provided that the economy is not in a corner solution, the value of

entrepreneurial ability of individual m, who is indifferent between salaried work and self-

employment, also corresponds to the size of the salaried labor force. That is, φm = φ* =

LT where φ* is the ability of the individual who is indifferent between self-employment

and wage work. Thus, we preserve the overall labor supply constraint while building in a

decrease in the marginal entrepreneurial ability as labor shifts toward self-employment.

Tradable output TY is CRS in capital TK and labor LT:

( ) TTTTTTTTT LKALKFAY αα −== 1, . Production of individual j in the self-employed sector

is given by NjjNj kAy αφ= .

Labor is mobile across sectors, but entrepreneurs planning to switch sectors must

accumulate or decumulate their capital before doing so. Because we appear to observe

non-arbitraged wage differentials, we assume that, though capital is mobile both

internationally and across sectors, there are adjustment costs that prevent this from

happening instantaneously. For the self-employed sector, capital markets are not perfect

and, as Evans and Jovanovic (1989) demonstrated for the US, entrepreneurs are often

8 As usually assumed, one unit of tradables can be transformed into a unit of capital at no cost. The reverse is also true. Nontradables can be used only for consumption. Capital can be used for production and then consumed (as a tradable) at the end of the same period.

5

credit constrained. We capture this by assuming that those entering self-employment

must install some capital the period before producing and pay a standard deadweight

installation cost (paid in terms of tradables) of ( )

j

j

kh

I 2

2χ , where Ij represents the change

in capital stock between two successive periods for self-employed individual j and χ is

inversely related to the speed of adjustment. ( )jkh , a linear function of capital

accumulated by the self-employed individual j. We further assume that individuals

willing to leave self-employment must dispose of all the capital they have in place before

they become employed in the salaried sector.9 This specification ensures that the labor

market will not adjust fully in one period and that differentials in net remuneration among

sectors are not instantly arbitraged by labor flows. This permits us to analyze both steady

state movements in relative wages, relative sector sizes and exchange rates, but, also

transitional dynamics.

2.1 The firm

The representative tradable sector firm maximizes

( )[ ]∑∞

=

−−

+ts sTsTsTsTsTsT

ts

ILwLKFAr ,,,,,, ,

11

max , subject to: sss KKI −= +1

where wT,s is the wage (gross) prevailing in the tradables sector at time t=s. The world

interest rate r, expressed in terms of tradables, is assumed to be constant. The first order

conditions are standard:

( ) rkfA TT =' (1) ( ) ( )[ ] TTTTT wkkfkfA =− ' (2)

9 This specification ensures that (de)installation costs are always finite. Further, since marginal costs of capital (de)installation are increasing, capital adjustment will not happen instantaneously.

6

Because r is the world interest rate expressed in terms of tradables, it must correspond to

the marginal product of capital in the salaried/tradable sector. The wage prevailing in the

sector is equal to labor’s marginal productivity. Because both factors do not shift

instantaneously across sectors, these two conditions may fail to hold ex-post in the event

of unanticipated shocks.

In the self-employed sector, individual j maximizes

( )∑∞

=

+ts sjsj

sjsjjsNs

ts

IkhI

kApr

N,

,

2,

,, 211 χ

φ α subject to: sjsjsj kkI ,1,, −= + .

The first order condition is given by

( )sjs

sj khq

I ,,1

χ−

= (3)

( )21

11,1,11 1

21

−−−=− +−

++++ ssjNjsNssss qkAprqqq N

χαφ α (4)

where q denotes the shadow price of installed capital in nontradables and p denotes the

price of nontradables relative to the price of tradables. In other words, p is simply the

inverse of the real exchange rate defined as the relative price of traded goods in terms of

non-traded goods. Equation (3) indicates that investment is positive only for values of q

larger than 1. Equation (4) is a standard investment Euler equation. In the long run, it

must also be true for all self-employed individuals that returns to capital equal the market

rate of interest:

rkpA NjNjN =−1ααφ (4’)

and that the pivotal individual is indifferent between wage work and self-employment:

( ) TNN wkpA N =− αφα **1 .

7

2.2 The Consumer

As is standard, we assume that the economy is inhabited by an infinitely- lived

representative consumer whose demand and asset holdings are identified with aggregate

national counterparts and who maximizes a lifetime utility function of the form

( )( )∑∞

=

− Φ=ts

NTts

t CCuU ,β .

Where TC and NC stand for consumption in the tradables and nontradables sectors.

( )NT CC ,Φ is a linear homogenous function of its arguments and u(.) is isoelastic with

intertemporal substitution elasticity σ. The β element is the standard time-preference

factor which is exogenously given. We assume that the representative consumer owns a

share equal to one of the representative tradable firm and in each entrepreneurial activity,

and receives dividends.10

The representative consumer faces a lifetime budget constraint

( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

−−+

+++=+

+ ∫∑∑∞

=

−∞

=

sN

sNjsjjsNsNsTsT

ts

ts

tsNsTts

ts

Kh

IdkApLw

rQrpCC

rN

,

2,

1

*,,,,,, 2

11

11

11 χ

φφαφ

α

where national financial wealth tTtNtt KKBQ ,, ++= is measured in terms of tradables

and B stands for net aggregate holdings of foreign assets. IN,s represents total investment

and KN,s total capital accumulated in the self-employed sector at date s.

For the general case of a CES utility function11

( )θ

γγ

pCC

N

T

−=

1 (5)

10 It would be equivalent to consider the case where producers directly borrow capital from the representative consumer and the latter is the one who would take the investment decisions as shown in Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996).

8

relative intratemporal consumption depends only on the relative price p and not upon

consumer's spending level where γ indicates the weight of the traded good in the utility

function and θ represents the constant (and strictly positive) elasticity of substitution

between tradable and non-tradable goods.

Moreover,

sN

sT

s

s

sN

sT

CC

pp

CC

,

,1

1,

1,θ

= +

+

+

. (6)

A rise in the relative price of nontradables causes growth in tradables consumption

growth relative to nontradables consumption. 12

Since, by assumption nontradables can only be consumed, in equilibrium

consumption equals production in the self-employed sector. Substitution and the

combination of the Euler equation for tradables consumption with the lifetime budget

constraint of the representative consumer yield an expression for the optimal

consumption of tradables:

( ) ( )

∑∞

=

−−

=

+

−−

+++

=

ts s

tts

ts sN

sNssT

ts

t

tT

PP

r

KhI

IYr

Br

Cθσ

χ

11

211

1,

2,

,

, , (7)

where P is the price index P = θθγγ −−−+ 1/11 ])1([ p ] which is increasing in p.

11 See Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996, pp 226-235) for a full derivation. 12 Note that if σ = θ, tradables consumption remains constant along the perfect foresight paths.

9

2.3 Properties of the Model

Before turning to the dynamics of the economy, we first describe its steady state

equilibrium and assess the impact of permanent productivity and consumption shocks.

We then introduce a wage rigidity in the salaried sector. The results of all exercises are

tabulated in Table 1.

2.3.1 Shocks in the Long Run

Productivity shocks are represented by a permanent variation in the A productivity

scale coefficients and demand shocks by a permanent variation in the γ parameter. In the

following, variables with hats refer to rates of change (xx

x∆

=^

). Log differentiation leads

to the following results, assuming that initial p = 1 and initial γ is equal to one half.

Relative Prices: Differentiating (4’) and aggregating across all j gives

( ) 0ˆˆ1*ˆˆˆ * ==−−++ rkAp NN αφ

Although individual ability remains constant by assumption, 0ˆ =jφ and hence the capital

growth rate is the same for everyone, the labor reallocation after a shock results in a

change in the pivotal individual so that *φ is no longer equal to zero for the labor force

as a whole. By the same logic

TNN wkAp ˆˆ*ˆˆˆ * =+++ αφ

where jkk ˆˆ* = and is given by equation (4’). Defining

T

TTTL Y

Lw=,η , labors’ share in

tradables output, TLT

T Aw ˆ1ˆη

= , and then

NTLT

N AAp ˆˆ1ˆ −

−=

ηα

.

This simply restates the Balassa Samuleson result that, for values of LT

N

ηα−1

close to 1,

the real exchange rate is determined by the relative rates of productivity growth.

10

Relative Sector Size: Demand for tradables and nontradables can be re-written as,

( ) θγγγ

−−+=

11 pZ

CT

and

( )( ) θ

θ

γγγ

−+−

=11

1pZp

CN

,

where ( ) ( )∫ +−+=1

*

~1

φ

α φφα QrdkpALwZ jjjNNTTN .

In order to simplify the analysis we assume that total financial wealth remains constant

across steady states. We assume implicitly that any variation in the total level of physical

capital is fully offset by an equal, but opposite variation in foreign assets holdings. That

is, with international borrowing, a rise in the stock of physical capital for instance, can be

financed by an equal fall in B without affecting the level of total financial wealth13. This

allows us to write

[ ]

Ψ−

−+

−++= *ˆˆ

11ˆ

11ˆˆ

ααϕϕ pALwZ

NN

NseTTLT

where ZLw TT

LT =ϕ ,

( ) ( )Z

dkpA jjjNN

se

N∫−

=

1

*

α φφα

ϕ and ( )

( )

−−−

=Ψ−−

−−

N

N

N

N

N

N

αα

αα

φ

φαα

12

12

*1

*12

.

Changes in nontradables consumption can be written as

( )( )pZC N ˆ1ˆ^^

γθγγ −+−+−=

and changes in total production in the self-employment sector (expressed in units of

tradables) by

[ ] *ˆˆˆ1

1^φ

αΨ−+

−= pApY N

NN .

Since nontradable goods market equilibrium requires that NN YC ˆˆ = , the entrepreneurial

ability of the pivotal worker, and implicitly, the share of the workforce in tradables, can

be written as:

13 See Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996, Chap. 4) for an application.

11

( ) ( )( )[ ] ( )( )

−−+−−−+−++−Ω−= θγθγαϕϕ

ηγφ 11ˆ1111

ˆˆ*ˆ 1 NNseLT

LT

T AA ,

where ( )[ ] 11 1 −+Ψ−=Ω LTse ϕϕ .

Relative Earnings: The change in self-employment production expressed in tradables

units is now:

( ) ( )( )[ ] ( )( )

−−+−−−+−++−Ω+=Ψ−= θγθγαϕϕ

ηγ

ηφ

η11ˆ1111

ˆˆ

ˆ*ˆ

ˆ2

^

NNseLTLT

T

LT

T

LT

TN A

AAApY

where ( ) LTse ϕϕ +Ψ−

Ψ=Ω

12 . The relative change in total production also corresponds to

the relative variation in entrepreneurs’ earnings, wNj, as the latter is a constant proportion

of the former. The change in average self-employment production expressed in terms of

tradables units can be written as:

( )

( ) ( )( )[ ] ( )( )

−−+−−−+−++−Ω+=

−+Ψ−=

θγθγαϕϕη

γη

φφ

φφ

η

11ˆ1111ˆ

ˆˆ

*ˆ*1

**ˆ

ˆ

3

^

NNseLTLT

T

LT

T

LT

TN

AAA

ApYE

where

( ) 01

*1*

3 >+Ψ−

−−Ψ

=ΩLTse ϕϕ

φφ

. It is straightforward to verify that 23 Ω<Ω .

2.3.2 Dynamics

In order to qualify the dynamics of the model in the event of a shock, we linearize

the first order conditions for profit maximization by the self-employed around the steady

12

state. The latter being characterized by 1=q (q denotes the shadow price of installed

capital in nontradables) and, jk we obtain

( )jt

tjtj khq

kkχ

1,1,

−=−+

( ) ( ) ( ) ( )[ ]( )jtjjNtjj

Ntt kkkrqkkh

rqq −−+−

+−=−+ ,1 1111 α

χα .

The equations ∆kj = 0 and ∆qj = 0 characterize the equilibrium dynamics. They are

depicted in a two-equation phase diagram in q and kj that shows the dynamics of the

investment decisions of self-employed individuals (figure 2). The line denoted by SS

indicates the perfect foresight path.

As the steady state level of investment chosen by each individual is not identical,

we expect to observe that a common shock affects heterogeneous individuals differently.

When a shock leads to a contraction of the self-employment sector, for workers whose

entrepreneurial ability falls below the threshold steady state value of φ* (those who

would be better off in the wage work sector), the perfect foresight path leads to zero

capital and zero capital shadow value at steady state, as depicted in figure 3. Should self-

employment expand, new-entrants invest initially ar

rI

χ−

=1

0 - independent of the wage

prevailing in the salaried sector since the initial shadow value of their capital is above 1

(q0=1/r ). Due to heterogeneous entrepreneurial ability, workers will not all move across

sectors in the same period. For instance, in the case of a shock leading to a rise in returns

to self-employment, more able entrepreneurs in the salaried sector would move first. A

detailed analysis is presented in Appendix 2.

The adjustment to the steady state depends on the relative values of σ and θ.

Indeed, CT,t is given by (7) which suggests that the level of tradables consumption along

the saddle path is affected by variations in p in a manner that could either reinforce or

offset the impact of a shock. The impact of a rise in p on consumption is dampened by

13

consumers’ inter-temporal choices if σ >θ , and amplified if σ <θ. If σ >θ, consumption

of nontradables declines slower than consumption of tradables. The opposite occurs if

σ < θ. This implies that migration takes longer in a situation when inter-temporal

substitution prevails over intra-temporal substitution.

2.4 Responses to Productivity and Demand Shocks

In order to define short/medium term properties we need to qualify "on- impact"

effects of various shocks. Short/medium term properties would then reflect variables'

behavior after impact and during the transition towards the new steady state. On impact,

levels of production and consumption must remain constant. Thus any wealth effects

generated by the shock must be offset by an instantaneous change in prices. In order to

simplify the analysis, we assume that changes in wealth occurring on impact reflect only

the shock’s direct effects.14 That is, changes in wealth due to subsequent changes in

prices are accounted for in the long run. This assumption does not affect qualitatively the

properties of the model.

We first assess the impact of permanent productivity and consumption shocks.

We then introduce wage rigidities in the salaried sector. The results of all exercises are

presented in Table 1.

Productivity Shock to the Tradables Sector

In the event of a productivity shock to the tradables sector, 0^

>TA , 0^

=NA and

0^

=γ , both production of the sector as well as returns to capital and labor increase. This

increases demands for both types of goods and causes the exchange rate to appreciate (p

14 Reference equations for determining on-impact effects become:

NN

seTLT AwZ ˆ

^

αϕ

ϕ−

+= and

( )( ) 0ˆ1ˆ^^

=−+−+−= pZC N γθγγ

14

rises) to clear the nontradables market. In addition, along the perfect foresight adjustment

path, some self-employed find it more profitable to move to the salaried sector.15 The

shadow value of their capital falls below 1 and, as it falls towards zero in the long run

they disinvest. However, since capital adjusts with a lag, they cannot migrate until their

capital has been completely dismantled. Tradable firms must also wait for the following

period to adjust their capital. Therefore, on impact only prices adjust16 and average self-

employed earnings follow the initial rise in p. As the economy adjusts, self-employed

earnings fall relative to salaried sector wages17 as does the share of workers in self-

employment.18 Hence, in both the short run and long run, wT / wN increases, LT / LN

increases and, consistent with Balassa-Samuelson, p rises relative to its initial level.

Productivity Shock to the Nontradables Sector

Consistent with standard models, if 0^

=TA , 0^

>NA , and 0^

=γ , in the steady

state, the relative price of nontradables will decrease in proportion to the productivity

shock in nontradables. Both capital intensity and earnings in the self-employed sector

will be left unchanged. However, on impact p rises due to increased demand for

nontradables. It then falls along the transition path. This could be qualified as p

undershooting. Individuals who are already self-employed at the time of the shock and

15 Workers whose sequence of returns from self-employment remains above that of the salaried wage face q>1 and they accumulate more capital. 16 On impact,

( )( ) TLT Ap ˆ1

^

γθγϕ

−+= , which also corresponds to the initial rise in average earnings in the

informal sector. The initial rise in formal wages is equal to TA and remains larger than the rise in self-employed average earnings for reasonable values of ? and ?. 17 Total self-employed production and earnings, measured in tradables units, depends on the sign of

( ) ( )( )[ ][ ]11111ˆ

2 −−−−−−Ω− θγαϕϕη NseLT

LT

TA. It is straightforward to check that the expression

into brackets is always smaller than one. Since LT

TT

Aw

η

ˆˆ = , on average self-employed earnings fall in the

long run relative to workers earnings in the salaried sector for any value of 2Ω and θ. 18 In the steady state the direction of change of the employment share of self-employment depends on the

sign of ( ) ( )( )[ ]1111 −−−+−+ θγαϕϕ NseLT . The expression is unambiguously negative implying

that the share of self-employed workers falls.

15

who, with perfect foresight know that relative prices will continue to fall, do not modify

their capital stock (their shadow value q remains equal to unity), but the increase in

productivity does, in the short run, increase their production and yield higher relative

earnings. This induces migration from the tradables sector and will eventually drive

returns back to the pre-shock level. 19 However, to attract the marginal entrepreneur to

self-employment, relative earnings in this sector will rise. Hence, in both the short and

the long run, wT / wN, , LT / LN and p decrease.

Shift in Preferences toward Nontradables

A shift in preferences, for instance, towards nontradables consumption 0^

=TA ,

0^

=NA and 0^

<γ increases self-employment as well as absolute and relative

consumption of nontradables. On impact, the increased demand for nontradables causes

the exchange rate to appreciate,20 and relative self-employed earnings and the shadow

value of capital increase. This attracts new entrepreneurs to the sector, expanding

nontradables supply and driving the relative price of nontradables, p, back to its initial,

relative productivity-determined level. However, because marginal entrepreneurs are

attracted to the sector, relative self-employment earnings must rise in the steady state.

This represents an important case where both wT / wN and LT / LN fall with an initial

appreciation and then continue to do so as the exchange rate depreciates again back to its

initial level.

Negative Salaried/Tradables Productivity Shock with Salaried Sector Wage Rigidities

Unions or mandatory minimum wages may introduce downward nominal wage

rigidities in the salaried sector that can reverse some of the above findings. As the

derivation of the steady state is complex, detail is deferred to appendix A.1. In the case

19 The sign of ( )( )θγ −− 11 determines the impact on self-employment. It is positive for any positive value of the intra-temporal elasticity of substitution. 20

( )( )∧

−+= γ

γθγ 11^

p and 0^

<γ .

16

where 0^

<TA , 0^

=NA , and 0^

=γ , a negative shock to tradables’ productivity puts

downward pressure on nominal wages in the salaried sector. However, because of

downward wage rigidities, consumption is not affected on impact and hence, there is no

effect on relative prices, p. But the salaried sector will eventually adjust through

quantities and released labor will flow into the non-traded sector increasing its

production, driving down p, and reducing average self-employed earnings. For the

already self-employed, the fall in p observed along the transition path, leads to

disinvestment in capital. However, since there is now rationing in the salaried sector,

migration to the salaried sector is not possible and workers with relatively low

entrepreneurial ability will earn less than what they would in the salaried sector. Hence,

average earnings in the self-employed sector have fallen relative to the salaried sector

while the size of self-employment has increased: we should see wT / wN and LT / LN

moving against each other.21 This is the classic segmentation view: the informal sector

absorbs released labor during downturns to which we also now add that p falls as well.

There are some parameter values which can lead to appreciation and a positive

comovement of the labor market series. However, as detailed in appendix A.1, they are

not very plausible and, while included for completeness they can be disregarded for most

practical purposes.

3. Empirics

The previous section shows that very standard models anchored in the mainstream

literature yield clear hypotheses of comovements among the three series. Two

conclusions are important. First, independent of skill heterogeneity and adjustment costs,

under no conditions can we generate a counter movement of relative sector sizes and

earnings in the absence of a wage rigidity: observed counter movements imply

21 As long as wages in the salaried workers do not adjust, average earnings in self-employment unambiguously fall with respect to the former. Then, along the transition towards steady state, average earnings in the self-employed sector have fallen relative to the salaried sector while the size of self-employment has increased. As mentioned in the previous section, this is also true in the new steady state if appendix A.1, condition (1) is satisfied.

17

segmentation and if we detect them empirically, this is evidence of labor market

distortions. Second, in all cases, the short run labor market dynamics move in the same

direction as the steady state and only in the case of a shock to preferences for

nontradables does the exchange rate overshoot in the short-run.

We explore the patterns of comovement between relative sector sizes, relative

earnings and the real exchange rate for Argentina, Mexico, Brazil and Colombia using

the multivariate Johansen (1988) approach. (see appendix A.3). Although cointegration is

sometimes given the economic interpretation of capturing “long run” relations, as

Granger (1991) and Hakkio and Rush argue (1991) at core it is a statistical relationship

existing among non-stationary series that can occur at any frequency or span. 22 In our

case, relative sector sizes, earnings and the real exchange rate are plausibly I(1) and they

always appear to be so in the analysis.23 Since overshooting or undershooting (as found in

the case of a productivity shock or a demand shock respectively to the nontradables

sector) can take a number of years to return to long run equilibrium, our short/medium

runs can, in fact, represent quite persistent phenomena that will be identified by the

cointegration relationship as well.

3.1 Data

We use quarterly data for Mexico, Brazil and Colombia and semi-annual data for

Argentina (see Appendix A.4 for data definitions and details) to generate the earnings

ratio of salaried over self-employed workers, wT / wN , and the ratio of the absolute size of

the salaried over the self-employed sector, LT / LN . To the degree possible, we try to be

consistent across surveys and in spirit be close to the ILO definitions: we treat the male

population that reports being employed in firms of greater than 6 workers as salaried

22 See Hakkio and Rush (1991) Cointegration: How long is the long-run?: "Clearly, the length of the 'long-run' may vary between problems, that is, for some issues the long- run may be a matter of decades while for others a matter of months." 23 Theoretically, however, it is legitimate to include an I(0) variable in the cointegrating relationship, although we would expect at least one cointegrating vector to emerge that captures simply the stationary series. In practice, these series were never stationary across our sample and the problem was moot.

18

(tradable) workers. Own-account workers or heads of firms employing fewer than 5

employees paying no social security contributions and excluding professionals and

technicians, constitute the informal self-employed (nontradable) sector. Real exchange

rates, p, were taken from International Financial Statistics. The series are plotted in

Figure 1 with the exchange rate inverted for greater graphical clarity (an upward

movement here and here alone is a depreciation).

Three issues merit note. First, even if remuneration is equalized in both sectors,

we do not observe non-monetary remuneration (independence, benefits foregone, taxes

avoided, implicit returns to capital, etc.) and hence we may observe a wedge in observed

returns even in equilibrium. We assume that these non-monetary components are a

constant fraction of monetary earnings and hence that changes in relative monetary

earnings are a good proxy for relative changes in total remuneration. Second, variations

in definitions and the composition of payment can cause substantial differences in ratios

of relative earnings across countries. As a final caveat, we do not model or study those

salaried workers who are uncovered by labor legislation and hence are informal. While

this group is substantially smaller than the informal self-employed, its particular cyclical

behavior deserves independent study in another paper.

3.2 Results

We begin by estimating separate VAR models for Argentina, Mexico, Brazil and

Colombia. We include a constant, lags for p, wT / wN and LT/LN as well as time dummies

in the cointegration space. These specifications prove sufficient to produce random

errors. The model specifications for the three models are presented in Tables A.1-A.3 in

the AppendixA.4 along with tests for long-run exclusion, stationarity and weak-

exogeneity. All variables appear to be non-stationary and the diagnostics on the residuals

of the system point towards the absence of autocorrelation, and normality. Sensitivity

analysis for different lag lengths and with and without dummies further indicated

robustness of the findings. Trace tests (λ trace) indicate one significant cointegrating vector

for all three models (Table A.2). Normalizing the cointegration vectors on the 1st

19

element, yields the estimates for the β s (Table 3) in a cointegration vector that can be

read as:

LT/LN + ßW wT / wN + ßp p + ßC = 0

Thus, the signs on the first three parameters (beginning with the normalized coefficient

on LT/LN) correspond directly to those in table 1. Hence, a finding of a positive

coefficient on relative earnings implies an integrated labor market, while a negative

coefficient indicates a segmented market.

The theoretical model suggests that different shocks, or differing degrees of

salaried sector rigidities, should lead to different regimes and hence different

cointegration vectors across subsamples. To identify potential shifts in the degree of

labor market segmentation, and for an indication of potential break dates we plot rolling

correlation coefficient of the two labor variables (figures 4). We then test for specific

cointegrating vectors across separate periods for our full model specification.

For both Argentina and Colombia, our correlation analysis suggests the only

significant comovements between the two labor market variables to be negative with

incipient but never statistically significant shifts toward the positive. This, combined

with the relatively limited degrees of freedom in these cases led us to abandon search for

regime change and we report only the full sample result in table 2. However, both

Mexico and Brazil do suggest periods where the correlations flip signs and significantly

so suggesting that in some moments the market is behaving in a more integrated fashion,

and sometimes in a more segmented fashion. In Mexico, for example, the period around

the crisis, roughly 1993 to 1997 shows a negative and significant correlation. However,

on either side of the crisis, the boom prior to 1991 and after the recovery around 1999 and

2004, we identify periods of statistically significant positive correlation. As Brazil also

exhibits both patterns with statistical significance, we proceed for these two countries to a

subsample investigation and estimate cointegrating vectors for respective sub periods.

20

Our results provide strong evidence for two types of regimes. First, in Brazil

during 1994-97 and in Mexico in the periods 1987-91 and 1998-04, we find a positive

comovement of the two labor series. This suggests an integrated market and a positive

demand shock to the nontradables sector. Traditionally, Mexican and Brazilian minimum

wages are not especially binding, and in these samples, both economies were going

through something of a boom. 24 In the two Mexican cases, the appreciation of the

exchange rate suggests that we are not yet in the long run. In the Brazilian case, the

coefficient on the real exchange rate is statistically insignificant suggesting that we have

reached the long run equilibrium where markets have adjusted to erode the short term

overshooting.

In a second regime, Argentina, Brazil in the periods 1983-89 and 1998-02,

Colombia, and Mexico during 1992-96, all correspond to the case of a negative shock to

the formal/traded sector in the presence of wage rigidities. In this sense, we find the

classic informal/non-tradable sector adjusting to take in labor no longer absorbed in the

formal sector. This is historically plausible. Across these periods, all four countries

experienced deep recessions where wages may not have been able to adjust sufficiently to

prevent segmentation. In addition, Colombia’s minimum wage was the most binding in

Latin America while Argentina, although not showing especially high minimum wages,

nonetheless has been considered to have a quite rigid labor market.

4. Conclusion:

This paper has offered an integrated view of the developing country labor market

and its behavior across macroeconomic fluctuations. We model a two sector labor

market in a Rogoff-Obstfeld small economy model to include heterogeneous

entrepreneurial ability and credit constraints to entering informal self-employment. This

allows us to generate a set of hypotheses about the comovement of relative sector sizes

and earnings and sectoral shocks as captured by the real exchange rate.

24 See Maloney and Nunez (2004)

21

These patterns of comovement are then tested in a cointegration framework and

offer provocative results. First, the informal self-employed and formal salaried sectors

often appear as one integrated labor market, rather than segmented or dual labor markets

as customarily envisaged: numerous periods show strong comovement between

relativesector sizes and earnings. This suggests that a large component of the informal

sector should not be viewed as somehow inferior or queuing for formal sector

employment. However, it is also the case that rigidities in the formal salaried sector can

become binding, as appears to be most dramatically the case in Colombia, and lead to

patterns consistent with the traditional segmentation hypothesis of adjustment. These

distinct patterns suggest that the pro or countercyclicality of the sectors may depend on

the sectoral origin of the shocks, and the presence of binding wage rigidities.

22

References: Balassa, B. 1964. “Trade Prospects for Developing Countries.” Yale University. Economic Growth Center. Publications 382, New Haven. Blanchard, O. and N. Kyotaki (1987), “ Monopolistic Competition and the Effects of Aggregate Demand, American Economic Review 77:4 p 647-666. Cheung, Y.-W. and K.S. Lai. 1993. “Finite sample sizes of Johansen’s likelihood ratio tests for cointegration.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 55, 3, 313-328. de Soto, H. 1989. The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World. Harper Row, New York. Evans, D.C. and B. Jovanovic. 1989. “An Estimated Model of Entrepreneurial Choice under Liquidity Constraints.” Journal of Political Economy 97:4 pp 808-826. Evans, D.C. and L. S. Leighton. 1989. “Some Empirical Aspects of Entrepreneurship.” American Economic Review, 79(3), 519-535. Fiess, N. M. Fugazza and W. Maloney (2002) “Exchange Rate Appreciations, Labor Market Rigidities, and Informality” World Bank Policy Working Paper 2771. Granger, C. (1991): Developments in the study of cointegrated variables, in R. F. Engle and C.W.J. Granger (Eds.): Long-run economic relationships. Readings in Cointegration, Oxford University press., p. 65. Hakkio, C.S. and Rush, M. (1991): Cointegration: How short is the long-run?, Journal of International Money and Finance, 10, 571-581. Hamilton, J., J-F. Thisse and Yves Zenou. 1998. “Wage Competition with Heterogenous Workers and Firms.” Centre for Economic Policy Research. Discussion Paper Series (U.K.); No. 2141:1-22, May 1999. Hansen, Henrik and Søren Johansen (1999) “Some Tests for Parameter Cnstancy in Cointegrated VAR-models. Econometrics Journal 2:306-333. Harris, John R. and Michael P. Todaro (1970), “Migration, Unemployment and Development: A Two–Sector Analysis.” American Economic Review 60(1):126-42. Hart, K. 1973. “Informal Income Opportunities and Urban Employment in Ghana.” Journal of Modern African Studies, 11(1), 61-69. Johansen, S. 1988. “Statistical Analysis of Cointegrating Vectors.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control (Netherlands); 12:231-54 June-September 1988.

23

Johansen, S. and K. Juselius. 1992. “Testing structural hypothesis in a multivariate cointegration analysis of PPP and UIP for UK.” Journal of Econometrics, 53, 169-209. Johansen, S. and K. Juselius. 1994. “Identification of the long-run and short-run structure. An application of the ISLM model.” Journal of Econometrics, 63, 7-36. Loayza, N. and J. Rigolini (2006) “Informality Trends and Cycles” mimeo, World Bank Lucas, Jr, R. E. 1978. “On the size distribution of business firms.” Bell Journal of Economics, 2, 508-523. Maloney, W.F. 2004. “Informality Revisited.” World Development 32(7) 1159-1178 Maloney, W.F. 1999. “Does Informality Imply Segmentation in Urban Labor markets? Evidence from Sectoral Transitions in Mexico.” The World Bank Economic Review 13:2 275-302. _______ 1998. “The Structure of Labor Markets in Developing Countries: Time Series Evidence on Competing Views,” IBRD Working Paper 1940, Latin America and the Caribbean Region, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Unit, World Bank, Washington, D.C. Processed. Maloney, W. F. and J. Nuñez (2004) “Measuring the Impact of Minimum Wages: Evidence from Latin America” In James J. Heckman and Carmen Pagés Law and Employment, Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean, University of Chicago Press. Mazumdar, D. (1975) “The Urban Informal Sector” Working Paper 211, World Bank, Washington, DC. Obstfeld, M. and K. Rogoff. 1996. “Foundations of Internationa l Macroeconomics.” Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Boston. Pratap, S. and E. Quintin (forthcoming) “Are Labor markets Segmented in Developing Countries? A Semiparametric Approach.” European Economic Review. Rauch, J. E. (1991) “Modelling the Informal Sector Formally” Journal of Development Economics 35:35-47. Sethuraman, S.V. 1981 The Urban Informal Sector in Developing Countries. Geneva:International Labor Office Taylor, L. 1979. “Macro Models for Developing Countries.” New York. Tokman, V. E. (1978) “An Exploration into the Nature of the Informal-Formal Sector Relationships.” World Development 6(9/10):1065-1075.

24

25

Table 1: Predicted Patterns of Comovement among Relative Earnings, Relative

Sector Sizes, and the Real Exchange Rate Short /

Medium Run ∆ ( wT / wN ) ∆( LT / LN ) ∆p

∆AT > 0 > 0 > 0 > 0

∆AN > 0 < 0 < 0

< 0

(undersh.)

Flexible Wage

∆γ< 0 < 0 < 0 0 >

(oversh.)

Wage Rigidities ∆AT < 0 > 0 < 0 < 0

Long Run

∆AT > 0 > 0 > 0 > 0

∆AN > 0 < 0 < 0 < 0

Flexible Wage

∆γ< 0 < 0 < 0 0

Wage Rigidities ∆AT < 0 > 0 < 0 < 0

26

Table 2: Cointegration Coefficients Among Relative Sector Sizes, Relative Earnings, and the Real Exchange Rate Argentina Brazil Colombia Mexico

Sample Full Full 1983-89 1994-97 1998-02 Full Full 1987-91 1992-04 1998-04

Variables

LT/LN 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000

WT/WN -2.336

(-7.087)

1.135

(1.761)

-0.067

(-2.297)

2.432

(16.7)

-0.623

(3.833)

-8.831

(-9.801)

-0.845

(-5.116)

6.894

(-3.461)

-3.792

(-6.626)

2.701

(2.739)

p -0.376

(-4.16)

-1.685

(-4.603)

-0.224

(-4.07)

0.009

(0.045)

-0.008

(0.29)

-0.270

(-2.160)

0.415

(5.772)

4.490

(4.030)

-0.227

(-2.334)

0.493

(6.846)

Const. 3.300

(-8.42)

-0.071

(-0.418)

1.330

(41.7)

0.443

(17.1)

0.831

(20.9)

2.792

(2.792)

-1.262

(-3.870)

-16.148

(-3.622)

1.425

(3.559)

-1.423

(-4.279)

Regime

(From Table 1)

∆AT < 0

rigidities

Mixed ∆AT < 0

rigidities

∆γ< 0

LR

∆AT < 0

rigidities

∆AT < 0

rigidities

Mixed ∆γ< 0

SR

∆AT < 0

rigidities

∆γ< 0

SR

Note: Cointegration vectors between relative tradable/nontradables (Formal/Informal Self-employment) size measured in employment, relative tradable/nontradable earnings, and the real exchange rate. Vector presented as LT/LN + ßW wT / wN + ßp p + ßC = 0. (t-statistics in parentheses).

27

Figure 1: Relative Sector Shares and Earnings, Real Exchange Rate

Argentina, Brazil, Colombia and Mexico

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

1.619

85

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

1

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2

2.2

Unconditioned Earnings F SE Real exchange rateFormal/SE

Argentina

Rel

ativ

e ea

rnin

gsR

eal e

xcha

nge

rate

For

mal

/ SE

Source: Own estimates based on EPH (Encuesta Permanente de Hogares) and IFS.

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

1983

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

4

4.5

5

Unconditioned Earnings F/SE Real exchange rate Formal/SE

Brazil

Rel

ativ

e ea

rnin

gsR

eal e

xcha

nge

rate

For

mal

/ SE

Source: Own estimates based on PME (Pesquisa Mensal de Emprego) and IPEA.

28

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

1.2

1.4

1.6

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

1.0

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2.0

2.2

2.4

Unconditioned Earnings F/SE Real exchange rate Formal/SE

Colombia

Rel

ativ

e ea

rnin

gsR

eal e

xcha

nge

rate

Form

al /

SE

Source: Own estimates based on ENH (Encuesta Nacional de Hogares) and IFS.

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1.0

1.1

1.2

1.3

1.4

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

1.0

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2.0

2.2

2.4

2.6

Unconditioned Earnings F/SE Real exchange rate Formal/SE

Mexico

Rel

ativ

e ea

rnin

gsR

eal e

xcha

nge

rate

Form

al /

SE

Source: Own estimates based on ENEU (Encuesta Nacional de Empleo Urbano) and IFS.

Notes: Wage F/SE captures the relative earnings of the formal salaried vs informal self employed sector. Formal/SE captures the relative size of these sectors as a ratio of employed population.

29

Figure 2: Self-employment and gradual capital adjustment

<<< < <

>> > > ∆kj=0

∆q=0

kj

q

jk

>

SS

Figure 3: Capital decumulation for migrating self-employed

∆kj=0

∆q=0

kj

q

jk

<<<

<<

<

<'jk

SS ’

30

Figure 4: Rolling Correlation between relative sector size and relative wages

Note: 16 period rolling window, dashed lines represent 10% level of significance (0.426). Values above (below) 0.426 (-0.426) indicate significant positive (negative) comovement of relative sector size and relative wages.

Argentina

-1

-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002

Brazil

-1

-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003

Colombia

-1

-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004

Mexico

-1

-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004

31

Appendix A.1: Details on Negative Tradables Productivity Shock with Salaried Sector Wage Rigidities

Unions or mandatory minimum wages may introduce downward nominal wage rigidities in the salaried sector that can reverse many of the findings above.

A negative shock to productivity in the tradables sector translates into nominal wage downward pressures in the salaried sector. Nominal wage downward rigidities, if persistent, would lead to a non-optimal and thus unstable equilibrium. In order to obtain a possibly stable equilibrium, we assume that nominal wages are adjusted to satisfy the first order conditions of firms operating in the tradables sector. However, we assume that wage variations represent the last element of adjustment. That is, labor movements are precluded after wages have been adjusted. As a consequence, the pivotal individual could end up in a situation where belonging to either one or the other sector does make a difference. This is a case of segmentation where the nontradables sector behaves in part as a residual sector.

As both capital and labor are assumed not to move instantaneously, two adjustment scenarios are possible. In the first scenario, capital would move first, then labor and finally wages. In that scenario, capital adjustment is a two-step process. Capital first adjusts to meet (1) in a context of constant salaried labor force. It further adjusts to meet (1) considering labor variation obtained by solving (2) with constant wage. Wages adjust in a final stage to satisfy (2). In the second scenario, labor would move first, then capital and finally wages. In that scenario, capital adjustment is one-step process. Capital adjusts to meet (1) after salaried labor has changed to meet (2) with constant capital and wage. Wages adjust to meet (2) after labor and capital adjusted. We can expect results to be qualitatively similar, as we expect factors of production adjustments to be identically signed in both scenarios.

Taking for instance the case of a Cobb-Douglas production function, salaried

labor outflow25 in the first scenario corresponds to ( )

( ) 0*ˆ1

ˆˆ <=−

= φηη LTLT

TT

AL ,

( )( )

01

ˆ1 <−

+=LTLT

TLTT

AKηη

η) and 0ˆ

ˆ <=LT

TAwη

.

Equilibrium of the demand and supply conditions in the nontradables sector

( )( )( )

( )( ) pACN

seLTLT

TseLTLTN ˆ1

11

1

ˆ2

^

−+−

−+

−Ψ−−= γθγ

αϕ

ηηϕϕη

and

( )LTLT

T

N

NN

ApYηηα

α−

Ψ−−

=1

ˆˆ

1

^

give 25 In that case, labor demand in the salaried sector at period s can be expressed as

( )sT

sT

sTLTsT K

w

AL

LT

,

/1

,

,,

η

−= .

32

( )( ) ( ) ( )( )

( ) ( )( )

−+−+−

Ψ−+−−−

=γγθαϕα

ϕϕηαηη 11

1211

ˆˆ

NseN

seLTLTN

LTLT

TAp

and

( )( )

( ) ( )( ) ( )( )

−Ψ−−+−+−

Ψ−+−−

=*1

*11

121

ˆ^

φφ

γγθαϕαϕϕη

ηη NseN

seLTLT

LTLT

TN

ApYE

The sign of both real exchange rate and average earnings depends upon the sign and magnitude of expression ( ) ( )( )γγθαϕα −+−+− 11 NseN

. This expression is increasing with θ, the elasticity of substitution. For θ=1 (preferences are Cobb-Douglas) for instance, the expression is equal to

seϕ−1 . In that case, both the real exchange rate and average self-employed earnings are decreasing unambiguously. A sufficient condition for the real exchange rate to depreciate is ( )

( )( )θ

γαϕ

−>−−

111

N

se . Unless Nα and θ are both very

close to zero and γ very close to one the condition is likely to be always satisfied. However, the sufficient condition for both the relative price of nontradables and average earnings to be decreasing is more restrictive, namely θ ≤ 1. Average earnings in the self-employment sector could rise despite the fall in p because in the context of an expansion of the sector the contribution per unit of entrepreneurial ability is higher for less able workers. This is a feature of the model essentially due to the fact that ability enters in a linear manner in the production function of self-employed workers. As far as relative earnings are concerned, self-employed workers would become on average worst off with respect to salaried workers if

( ) ( )( ) ( )( )

( )LTNseN

seLTLT ηφ

φγγθαϕα

ϕϕη−>

−Ψ−−+−+−

Ψ−+−1

*1*

1112 (1)

for θ =1 we must have that

( )( )

( )LTse

LTLT ηφ

φϕ

ϕη−>

+−

−1

*1*

12

This condition is likely to be satisfied for any plausible set of parameters values.

In the second scenario, we obtain ( )

( ) 0*ˆ1

ˆˆ <=

−= φ

η LT

TT

AL ,

( )0

1

ˆ<

−=

LTLT

TT

AK

ηη

) and

ˆ <=LT

TAwη

.

The real exchange rate and average self-employed earnings vary according to

33

( )( ) ( )( )

( ) ( )( )

−+−+−Ψ−+−

−=

γγθαϕαϕηϕα

ηη 1111

1

ˆˆ

NseN

seLTLTN

LTLT

TAp

and

( )( )

( )( ) ( )( )

−Ψ−−+−+−

Ψ−+−

=*1

*11

11

ˆ^

φφη

γγθαϕαϕηϕ

ηη LTNseN

seLTLT

LTLT

TN

ApYE

Conditions presented in the case of the first scenario also apply to the second scenario. When conditions presented above are satisfied, as labor migrates towards the self-employed sector, production rises, the real exchange rate depreciates, and average earnings in the self-employed sector fall. Moreover, as workers cannot migrate back to the salaried sector, those whose entrepreneurial ability is relatively low earn less than what they would get in the salaried sector. For those workers “trapped” in the self-employed sector earnings performance has worsened relative to those employed in the salaried sector as earnings in the salaried sector are preserved by institutional rigidities. The two labor force series move against each other. Critically, the same result would hold in the case where indexation of wages to past inflation forces salaried sector wages above equilibrium: we should see relative sector sizes and incomes move against each other. Appendix A.2: Migration Timing

Because we assume that the self-employed individual, who is willing to move to the wage-work sector, has to disinstall the capital she borrowed before moving, migration occurs whenever,

( )( )

( )( )

( )( ) ∑

+=

+=

++−

−−≤

−−

++−−

1,,

,

2,

,,

1,

,

2,

,,,,

2,

,,

11

2

211

2

tssT

ts

tntj

tjtNjtnt

tssn

sj

sjsNjsns

ts

tntj

tjtNjtnt

wr

rkkh

kkAp

rkkh

IkAp

rrk

kh

IkAp

N

NN

χφ

χφ

χφ

α

αα

Labor could adjust within the first period following the shock. However, because individuals are non homogenous when producing in the self-employed sector, the optimal time for leaving the latter may differ across workers.

The Left Hand Side of the above expression is increasing with entrepreneurial ability. Namely, more able individuals earn more than less able ones. Then the opportunity cost of migrating to the salaried sector at time t, without considering the direct migration costs corresponding to capital disinstallation, is increasing in the level of entrepreneurial capability. The last term of the RHS, which represents the present value of labor earnings in the salaried sector is identical for all individuals at time t. However, the first term of the RHS is likely to be different. The sign of the partial derivative of the latter with respect to φ j is given by

34

( )( )

( )

+

−+

−−

2

22

121

j

jN

N ka

aka

αχ

If the above expression appears to be positive, that would imply that the cost of migrating to the salaried sector at time is increasing with the level of entrepreneurial capability. If this is the case, then the total cost of migration is unambiguously increasing with φ j . As a consequence we may expect more able entrepreneurs to postpone their migration towards the wage sector with respect to less able ones.

In the case of a shock leading to an expansion of the self-employed sector, migration can occur within the first period following the shock, even though capital accumulation may take more than a period because of installation costs. Individuals migrate at the end of period s whenever

( )( )( ) ∑∑

+=

−∞

+=

−+

++≥

−−

++

1,

1,,

,

2,

,,

21,

, 11

211

0 tssT

ts

tstTsn

sj

sjsNjsns

tstj

tT wr

wrkkh

IkAp

rh

kw N

χφχ α

Following arguments similar to those presented above, we can infer that more able entrepreneurs will leave the salaried sector first, in order to "cash in" the expected earnings differential the soonest.

Appendix A.3: Details of Johansen Cointegration Procedure

The Johansen procedure allows us to test for cointegration in a multivariate system. Starting from an unrestricted vector autoregressive model (VAR), the hypothesis of cointegration is formulated as a hypothesis of reduced rank of the long run impact matrix Π (Johansen, 1988, Johansen and Juselius, 1990). The VAR is generated by the vector zt, which defines the potential endogenous variables of the model, in our case, the three series. Taking first differences of the variables, the VAR can be transformed into an error correction model

∆ Γ ∆ Γ ∆ Π Σz z z z D INt t k t k t k t t t= + + + + +− − − = −1 1 1 1 0... , ~ ( , )ψ ε ε

where the estimates of )1,...,1(),...( 1 −=−−−−=Γ kiAAI ii describe the short run dynamics to changes in zt and Π = − − − −( ... )I A Ai1 captures the long run adjustments and D contains deterministic terms.

Cointegration occurs in the case of reduced rank of Π . If the rank is reduced (r<n) it is possible to factorize Π into Π ( ' )= αβ where α denotes the adjustment coefficients and β the cointegration vectors. The cointegration vectors β have the property that β ' zt is stationary even though zt itself is non-stationary. If the rank is reduced it is also possible to interpret the VAR in first differences as a vector error correction model and to obtain estimates of α and β via the reduced rank regression. Since the rank of Π is equal to the number of independent cointegration vectors and the rank of Π is also equal

35

to the number of non-zero eigenvalues, the test of cointegration thus amounts to a test for the number of non-zero eigenvalues. The trace statistics, λ trace, is a non-standard distributed likelihood-ratio test, which is commonly used to determine the number of cointegration vectors, (Johansen, 1988). The trace statistic tests the null hypothesis that there are at most r cointegration vectors:

H0: iλ =0, for i = r+1,..n where only the first r eigenvalues, λ , are non-zero against the unrestricted hypothesis that n.26

26 The null hypothesis of at most r cointegration vectors implies that there are n-r unit roots and,

theoretically, n-r zero eigenvalues. This is because the hypothesis of cointegration is formulated as the reduced rank of 'αβ=Π and the full rank of ⊥⊥ Γβα ' , where α and β are n × r matrices and ⊥α and

⊥β are n× (n-r) matrices orthogonal to α and β . This allows us then to distinguish between r +cointegrating I(0) relations and n-r non-cointegrating I(1) relations.

36

Appendix A.3 Details on Data

Country Survey Time Coverage and Frequency

Spatial Coverage Sample Definition of Formal Sector All who declared:

Definition of S.E. Sector All who declared:

Brazil Pesquisa Mensal de Emprego - PME (Monthly Employment Survey)

From first quarter of 1983 to fourth quarter of 2002 Each quarter is represented by the last month of that quarter.

6 major metropolitan regions (covering 25% of the national labor market): Paulo, Rio de Janeiro, Belo Horizonte, Porto Alegre, Recife and Salvador.

Males above 15 years old

- to be working or to have a work during the survey's week - to be employees in their work - to have a work-card (carteira de trabalho) - to have NOT a work-card and to be working in some activity related to the public sector

- to be working or to have a work during the survey's week - to be employers - to be self employed

Mexico Encuesta Nacional de Empleo Urbano –ENEU (National Survey of Urban Employment)

From first quarter of 1987 to fourth quarter of 2004

16 major urban areas, covering 60% of urban population

Males between 11 and 99 years

- to be employees of firms with more than 5 employees(*) with social benefits - to be owners of firms with more than 5 employees - to be commission workers with social benefits

- to be owners of firms with 5 or less employees - to be self employed - to be commission workers without benefits

Argentina Encuesta Permanente de Hogares – EPH (Permanent Employment Survey)

From second wave of 1985 to first wave of 2003 (two waves per year, one in May, one in October)

Gran Buenos Aires Males between 12 and 75 years

- to be working during the survey's period - to be employees in their work - to have a pension plan in their current employment

- to be working or to have a work during the survey's week - to be self employed - to be employers in firms with 5 or less workers (**)

Colombia Encuesta Nacional de Hogares – ENH (National Household Survey)

From first quarter of 1985 to second quarter of 2004

7 major metropolitan areas (Barranquilla, Bucaramanga, Bogota, Manizales, Medellin, Cali, and Pasto)

Males between 11 and 99 years with less than 12 years of education(***)

Not possible to identify Formal Salaried, just Salaried: - those who declared to be working for a private firm or for the Government

- to be employers - to be self employed

(*) Due to a modification in the questionnaire (1994), a firm is considered to be small if it has 6 or less workers for all periods before to third quarter of 1994. (**)Employers in big firms were dropped to avoid unnecessary pro-cyclicality in formal wages. These individuals account for a reduced number so the sector sizes are not affected after dropping them (e.g. in 2003 I, 2.7% of the formal workers were employers in big firms) (***)All observations with incomplete monetary income declarations are dropped from the sample

37

Appendix A.4: Model Specification Tests for the VAR models: Table A.1: Tests for Long-Run Exclusion, Stationarity and Weak Exogeneity

Test for Long-Run Exclusion: LR-Test ( )(2 rχ )

Test for Stationarity: LR-Test ( )(2 rp −χ )

Test for Weak-Exogeneity: LR-Test ( )(2 rχ )

Model Specification: r 1 2 1 2 1 2 dgf 1 2 3 2 1 2 )5(2χ 3.84 5.99 7.81 5.99 3.84 5.99 Mexico nT/nN 16.97 18.67 37.96 2.74 0.57 1.92 Lag length: 4 WT/WN 10.54 12.11 38.52 3.28 12.06 12.49 Dummies : P 26.06 27.82 35.22 2.87 21.22 22.03 1995 Q1 Constant 12.6 14.4 (Peso Crisis) Brazil nT/nN 10.27 12.97 15.05 5.85 17.34 23.6 Lag Length: 3 WT/WN 4.23 12.94 16.3 3.19 1.69 6.89 Dummies: P 13 13.3 14.8 6.3 0.13 3.1 1994 Q2, 1991 Q1 Constant 12 12 (Currency conversion from Cruzerio Real to Real; Real Devaluation) Colombia nT/nN 21.58 23.38 28.18 2.91 2.83 3 Lag Length: 2 WT/WN 11.25 13.13 27.76 2.5 3.33 5.48 No dummies P 12.81 15.27 28.96 4.1 24.83 25.95 Constant 20.6 23.1 Argentina nT/nN 8.78 13.24 31.54 5.32 18.33 24.01 Lag Length: 4 WT/WN 27.01 33.06 23.8 2.98 0.34 6.84 Dummies P 10.23 11.62 32.07 5.88 1.34 2.2 1991:1; 2002:1 Constant 9.45 12.73

38

Table A.2: Multivariate Statistics (Residual Analysis)

México: Brazil Colombia Information Criteria: SC -21.09 -15.81 -13.37 HQ -21.81 -16.52 -13.85 Autocorrelation Ljung-Box: 2χ (114) = 126.3, p-val. = 0.05 2χ (150) = 159, p-val.= 0.18 2χ (99) = 129.5, p-value = 0.02 LM(1) 2χ (9) = 8.1, p-value = 0.53 2χ (9) = 4.52, p-value = 0.87 2χ (9) = 7.6, p –value = 0.58 LM(4) 2χ (9) = 17.2, p-value = 0.05 2χ (9) = 13.1, p-value = 0.16 2χ (9) = 7.9, p –value = 0.54

Normality 2χ (6) = 9.94, p-value = 0.13 2χ (6) = 16.4, p-value = 0.01 2χ (6) = 31.5, p-value = 0.00

Table A.3: Univariate Test Statistics (Residual Analysis)

Mexico Brazil Colombia nT/nN WT/WN p nT/nN WT/WN p nT/nN WT/WN p Skewness -0.066 -0.446 0.718 -0.168 -0.574 0.567 0.2750 -0.1402 -0.014

Kurtosis 2.345 3.785 3.940 2.682 4.118 4.765 5.8000 4.3100 3.8161 ARCH 0.941 5.077 2.307 1.850 5.473 2.005 4.3170 2.7780 3.3060 Normality 0.830 4.061 5.884 0.482 5.983 9.846 19.6240 7.6740 4.4030 R2 0.290 0.470 0.765 0.291 0.217 0.461 0.4050 0.3840 0.4110

39

Table A.4 Argentina Mexico Brazil Colombia Null Hypothesis

Alternative Hypothesis

Lag: 4 With Constant

Lag: 3 With Constant

Lag: 3 With Constant

Lag: 2 With Constant

95% Critical Value

90% Critical Value

λ trace test r = 0 r > 0 36.65* 59.85* 51.06* 36.45* 35.10 31.88 r ≤ 1 r > 1 11.38 13.32 19.54 6.43 20.17 17.79 r ≤ 2 r > 2 0.53 5.71 5.36 1.69 9.10 7.50

*Rejection at the 5% level of significance27

Table A.5 : Adjustment Coefficients

Argentina Brazil Colombia Mexico

Sample

Variables

full full 1983-94 1994-‘97 1998-02 full 1987-04 1987-91 1992-97 1998-04

∆ LT/LN -0.356

(-4.211)

-0.048

(-5.715)

-0.609

(-2.743)

-0.265

(-1.710)

-0.810

(-6.795)

-0.213

(-1.750)

-0.061

(-1.294)

-0.002

(-0.188)

0.062

(0.667)

-0.124

(-0.706)

∆ WT/WN -0.238

(-2.407)

-0.010

(-0.457)

-0.131

(-0.223)

0.190

(0.779)

-0.164

(-0.520)

-0.057

(-1.961)

-0.166

(-5.236)

0.003

(0.228)

-0.096

(-6.608)

0.094

(1.858)

∆ p 0.040

(0.369)

-0.014

(-0.509)

-1.269

(-3.055)

-0.332

(-6.233)

-0.841

(-0.873)

-0.088

(-6.009)

0.269

(3.718)

-0.055

(-4.537)

-0.583

(-2.096)

0.721

(2.977)

Note: ∆ indicates a variable in first differences. t statistics in parentheses.

27 The Reinsel-Ahn small sample corrected critical value at the 10% level is 43.13 for Mexico, 39.53 for Brazil and 36.32 for Colombia).