corporategovernanceandcreditaccessinbrazil: the sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a...

20
Corporate Governance and Credit Access in Brazil: The Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a Natural Experiment Bruno Funchal* and Danilo Soares Monte-Mor ABSTRACT Manuscript Type: Empirical Research Question/Issue: This study seeks to examine the effect of changes in corporate governance levels on the choice of rmsdebt nancing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment. Research Findings/Insights: Our empirical method uses an experimental design in which we control for observed and unob- served rm heterogeneity via a difference-in-differences estimator. We show that rms subjected to this new regulation, which raised governance requirements, observed a positive effect on their access to the credit market, increasing their total debt signi- cantly, via long-term and private debt, and reducing the cost of debt, indicating that SOX produced economic gains in this aspect. Theoretical/Academic Implications: The main contribution of the present paper is to measure the corporate governance effects on rmsdebt nancing policies, isolated from other contemporaneous events. Furthermore, we develop a simple theoretical model to help in the understanding of the main sources of SOXs effects. Finally, the natural experimental approach deals with the endogenous relation between corporate governance and rmschoices on debt nancing, and presents an alternative to instrumental variables techniques. Practitioner/Policy Implications: This paper offers insights to policymakers of emerging economies interested in the development of the credit market. Using laws and regulations like the Sarbanes-Oxley Act, we show that it is possible to improve rmsgovernance, with a positive impact on rmsability to access credit. Keywords: Corporate Governance, Credit, Experiment INTRODUCTION F rictions in credit markets hinder companies from raising funds to nance investment projects with positive net present value. On the micro level, these nancial constraints reduce the chance of rmsgrowth and survival (Aghion, Angeletos, Banerjee, & Manova, 2005; Musso & Schiavo, 2008). On the macro level, the economic development literature has established a connection between credit market development and economic growth (e.g., King & Levine, 1993; Levine, Loyaza, & Beck, 2000). The empirical evidence suggests that institutions help the development of nancial markets (e.g., Araujo, Ferreira, & Funchal, 2012; Coelho, De Mello, & Funchal, 2012; Djankov, McLiesh, & Shleifer, 2007; La Porta, Lopez-de Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1997 La Porta, Lopez-de Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1997 and 1998). After the failures of Enron, WorldCom, Adelphia and others, there was a great deal of discussion among academics, politi- cians and the press regarding a special type of institution: corpo- rate governance. 1 In the United States these huge bankruptcies spurred legislative reform, chiey the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (henceforth SOX), to improve governance schemes. In addition, the debate in the media pointed to increasing attention of corpo- rations on governance issues. 2 In this paper, we focus on the ef- fect of corporate governance on rmsaccess to debt nancing. Unlike most studies that focus on other types of agency prob- lems, like the manager compensation literature (Berle & Means, 1932; Fama, 1980; Jensen & Meckling, 1976; among others) or the ownership concentration literature (e.g., Demsetz, 1983; Demsetz & Lehn, 1985; Zingales, 1994), we shed some light on the benets that improvements in corporate governance have on the reduction of information asymmetry between companies and lenders. The problem of accessing credit markets is more severe in developing countries (e.g., Araujo et al., 2012; La Porta et al., 1997). Poorly designed institutions that deepen the asymmet- ric information problems explain their current situation. Therefore, from a policy perspective it is crucial to understand, theoretically and empirically, how improvements in gover- nance schemes affect rmsdebt nancing, especially for com- panies located in developing countries. To conduct our study we use the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment as it imposed an exogenous shock at the corporate governance level. Also, we focus on the effect on *Address for correspondence: Bruno Funchal, FUCAPE Business School, Fernando Ferrari Av. 1358, Boa Vista, Vitória, ES, Vitoria, 29075-010, Espirito Santo, Brazil; 55 27 40094402; E-mail: [email protected] © 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd doi:10.1111/corg.12151 1 Corporate Governance: An International Review , 2016, ••(••): ••–••

Upload: others

Post on 15-Jul-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

1

Corporate Governance: An International Review, 2016, ••(••): ••–••

Corporate Governance and Credit Access in Brazil:The Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a Natural Experiment

Bruno Funchal* and Danilo Soares Monte-Mor

ABSTRACT

Manuscript Type: EmpiricalResearch Question/Issue: This study seeks to examine the effect of changes in corporate governance levels on the choice offirms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment.Research Findings/Insights: Our empirical method uses an experimental design in which we control for observed and unob-served firm heterogeneity via a difference-in-differences estimator. We show that firms subjected to this new regulation, whichraised governance requirements, observed a positive effect on their access to the credit market, increasing their total debt signifi-cantly, via long-term and private debt, and reducing the cost of debt, indicating that SOX produced economic gains in this aspect.Theoretical/Academic Implications: Themain contribution of the present paper is tomeasure the corporate governance effectson firms’ debt financing policies, isolated from other contemporaneous events. Furthermore, we develop a simple theoreticalmodel to help in the understanding of the main sources of SOX’s effects. Finally, the natural experimental approach deals withthe endogenous relation between corporate governance and firms’ choices on debt financing, and presents an alternative toinstrumental variables techniques.Practitioner/Policy Implications: This paper offers insights to policymakers of emerging economies interested in thedevelopment of the credit market. Using laws and regulations like the Sarbanes-Oxley Act, we show that it is possible toimprove firms’ governance, with a positive impact on firms’ ability to access credit.

Keywords: Corporate Governance, Credit, Experiment

INTRODUCTION

Frictions in credit markets hinder companies from raisingfunds to finance investment projects with positive net

present value. On the micro level, these financial constraintsreduce the chance of firms’ growth and survival (Aghion,Angeletos, Banerjee, & Manova, 2005; Musso & Schiavo,2008). On the macro level, the economic developmentliterature has established a connection between credit marketdevelopment and economic growth (e.g., King & Levine,1993; Levine, Loyaza, & Beck, 2000). The empirical evidencesuggests that institutions help the development of financialmarkets (e.g., Araujo, Ferreira, & Funchal, 2012; Coelho, DeMello, & Funchal, 2012; Djankov, McLiesh, & Shleifer, 2007;La Porta, Lopez-de Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1997 La Porta,Lopez-de Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1997 and 1998).After the failures of Enron, WorldCom, Adelphia and others,

there was a great deal of discussion among academics, politi-cians and the press regarding a special type of institution: corpo-rate governance.1 In the United States these huge bankruptcies

*Address for correspondence: Bruno Funchal, FUCAPE Business School, FernandoFerrari Av. 1358, Boa Vista, Vitória, ES, Vitoria, 29075-010, Espirito Santo, Brazil; 55 2740094402; E-mail: [email protected]

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltddoi:10.1111/corg.12151

spurred legislative reform, chiefly the Sarbanes-Oxley Act(henceforth SOX), to improve governance schemes. In addition,the debate in the media pointed to increasing attention of corpo-rations on governance issues.2 In this paper, we focus on the ef-fect of corporate governance on firms’ access to debt financing.Unlike most studies that focus on other types of agency prob-

lems, like the manager compensation literature (Berle &Means,1932; Fama, 1980; Jensen & Meckling, 1976; among others) orthe ownership concentration literature (e.g., Demsetz, 1983;Demsetz & Lehn, 1985; Zingales, 1994), we shed some light onthe benefits that improvements in corporate governance haveon the reduction of information asymmetry between companiesand lenders.The problem of accessing credit markets is more severe in

developing countries (e.g., Araujo et al., 2012; La Porta et al.,1997). Poorly designed institutions that deepen the asymmet-ric information problems explain their current situation.Therefore, froma policy perspective it is crucial to understand,theoretically and empirically, how improvements in gover-nance schemes affect firms’ debt financing, especially for com-panies located in developing countries.To conduct our study we use the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a

natural experiment as it imposed an exogenous shock at thecorporate governance level. Also, we focus on the effect on

Page 2: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

2 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Brazilian companies. We do this for two reasons: first, wewant to shed some light on the effect of changes in governanceon a relevant emerging economy; second, Brazil is the devel-oping economy with the most cross-listed companies in USequity markets (therefore, subject to SOX regulation) and theuse of Brazilian companies provides us better tools for ouridentification strategy.Leuz (2007) points out that the main problem in assessing

the effects of SOX is the difficulty of finding a control groupof firms not affected and comparable to firms affected bySOX. This shortcoming makes it difficult to remove market-wide effects that are unrelated to SOX. In addition, Coates(2007) states that existing studies of SOX are confounded bythe presence of contemporaneous economic and legal events,as the legislation was enacted amidst sharp financial and eco-nomic changes.To deal with this problem, several authors use cross-listed

companies to shed some light on the effects of SOX (e.g.,Berger, Feng, & Wong, 2005; Li, Pincus, & Rego, 2008; Litvak,2007; Smith, 2007). Berger et al. (2005 compare returns ofcross-listed foreign companies to returns of US issuers.According to Litvak (2007), this allows evaluation of cross-sectional variation in reactions based on home-country char-acteristics, but does not allow assessment of overall investorreaction to SOX, because of the lack of a control group ofcompanies to which SOX does not apply. Smith (2007) adoptsan event study approach to test the impacts of SOX and Litvak(2007) applies a natural experiment approach, controlling forcontemporaneous events using a control group.To isolate the effect of SOX on debt financing policy from

other shocks, we have to find treatment and control groupsthat are subject to the same shocks, except for SOX implemen-tation. To do this, we use the difference-in-differences ap-proach, which accounts for unobservable time effects. Underthis approach, the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (SOX) is our naturalexperiment used to test the effect of changes in the level ofcorporate governance on the terms of debt, as the law causesan exogenous shock to governance requirements to all USpublic companies and to non-US firms with American depos-itary receipts (ADRs) listed at levels 2 and 3, and does notapply to foreign companies not listed or listed with ADRlevels 1 or 144A. Brazil is a good choice in this respect. LargeBrazilian firms extensively use American depositary share(ADS) programs,3 implying that part of our sample is subjectto SOX regulation.Our main results suggest that the average interest rate of

companies subject to the Sarbanes-Oxley Act dropped afterthe law came into force, consistent with an expected reductionin moral hazard costs due to gains in corporate governance.We estimate a reduction in the cost of newly issued debtvarying from 7 percent to 11 percent relative to matched firmsnot subject to SOX regulation, most of which comes from debtcontracts issued in Brazil. As a consequence, we find anincrease in the total amount of debt around 15 percent, consis-tent with a positive shift in the supply curve of credit. Thisincrease in the amount of debt is driven mainly by long-termdebt and private loans. Analyzing debt according to matu-rities, we find an increase of 23.9 percent in long-term credit,while on the other hand, we find a decrease of 9 percent inshort-term credit. This indicates an increase in the averagedebt maturities. Concerning the source of credit, public and

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

private loans, we found an increase between 12 and 20 percentfor private debt and a reduction between 2 and 4 percent forpublic debt.Together, these results suggest that the Sarbanes-Oxley

Act had a positive impact on the terms of credit, loweringthe cost and increasing the amount, consistent with a posi-tive shift in the credit supply curve. Since SOX broughtbetter information, manager punishment and monitoring,creditors could expect better corporate governance due toa reduction in managers’ moral hazard action. This reduc-tion of asymmetric information cost increased the probabil-ity of success of investment projects. This effect reduced therisk of lending, motivating creditors to supply more creditwith better terms.In addition to these average effects on the treated group, we

investigate the heterogeneous effect from the gains on gover-nance. The only heterogeneity comes from the source of credit.Companies with lower levels of cash holdings (our proxy forprobability of solvency) and monitoring benefit more frompublic and private loans respectively.Our results also show an increase in long-term private debt

contracts, such as term loans, in the post-SOX year, whichcorroborates the findings that SOX led to debt with longermaturity. Since borrowers’ financial health could changesignificantly over a long period, this result suggests that im-proved governance allowed private lenders to take on riskierdebt contracts. With improvements in firms’ governanceschemes, the risk of default declined, which explains boththe shift in the supply curve of debt and the shift of debt fromshort term to long term.Our paper belongs to a group of studies that examine the

effect of asymmetric information related to corporate gover-nance on firms’ financing policy and the terms of credit. In abroad way, Barath, Pasquariello, and Wu (2009) evaluate ifinformation asymmetry drives decisions on capital structure.Concerning asymmetric information in corporate governance,Anderson, Mansi, and Reeb (2004) analyze the effect of boardsize and independence on the cost of debt. Concerningaccounting system and accounting quality, Armstrong, Guay,and Weber (2010) show that the accounting system plays twoimportant roles in reducing the agency costs that arise in thedebt contracting process. Biddle andHilary (2006) provide ev-idence of the relation between accounting quality and accessto debt markets. Finally, Cremers, Nair, and Wei (2007) andQiu and Yiu (2009) study the relationship between corporatecontrol and the cost of debt.Further, our results bring new evidence of a specific benefit

of SOX, as we are exploring the gains of firms in the terms ofcredit. Much research has been carried out regarding the neteffects of SOX (e.g., Engel, Hayes, & Wang, 2007; Kamar,Karaca-Mandic, & Talley, 2005; Leuz, Triantis, & Wang, 2008;Piotroski & Srinivasan, 2008; Sneller & Langendijk, 2007;among others).Relating SOX and debt, Andrade, Bernille, and Hood (2014)

point to a potential relationship between reliability ofcorporate reporting and cost of debt. The authors found adecrease in the cost of debt, provided by increased corporatetransparency perceived by investors. Carter (2013) argues thatan increase in firms’ financial reporting transparency inducedby SOXpromoted a reduction in the information asymmetry be-tweenmanagers and investors, increasing firms’ debt financing.

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

Page 3: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

3CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CREDITACCESS

Costello andWittenberg-Moerman (2011) study the trade-off be-tween financial reporting quality and the use of financialcovenants.Our paper is closely related to Andrade et al. (2014) and

Carter (2013). In this study, we contribute to the literature byanalyzing the existence of a specific benefit of SOX, isolatedfrom other contemporaneous events, on the terms of debtfinance. Furthermore, this natural experimental approach getsaround the concern that corporate governance and debt areendogenous,4 and presents an alternative to instrumentalvariables techniques.An important issue to be considered here is how steady

the cross-listing decision is, as it may influence our identifi-cation strategy. Because of the significant increase in costsbrought about by SOX, the listing decision is endogenousto the regulation and therefore companies can go dark afterSOX, biasing our estimation. Leuz et al. (2008) documenteda significant increase in the going dark decision, and attrib-uted it to the Sarbanes-Oxley Act. However, Marosi andMassoud (2008) argue that foreign firms find delistingextremely difficult (they “can check in, but they can’t checkout”).5

Brazil is also a good choice in this respect. None of theBrazilian firms cross-listed through level 2 or 3 ADR delistedin the post-SOXperiod,which contributes to our identificationstrategy by reducing the survivor bias problem. An estimationusing countries with delisting tends to be biased in the direc-tion of the average remaining firms, ignoring the fact thatthe event was the reason for the delisting decision. Hostak,Karaoglu, Lys, and Yang (2013) show that the delistingdecision is positively associated with firms having poor gov-ernance. They argue that deregistration wasmotivated to pro-tect the control rents of managers or controlling shareholders.Brazilian firms have a particularly large benefit from

issuing bonds in the US market, as they face extremely highinterest rates6 due to poor legal enforcement7 and creditors’protection in Brazil. For example, in 2002, the year that SOXwas implemented, the Brazilian ratio of private credit toGDP was 0.35, while the average of OECD countries was1.02 and of Latin America and Caribbean countries it was0.44. Moreover, the Brazilian interest rate (49 percent) ismore than four times larger than the average interest ratein Latin American countries (11 percent) and more than 12times larger than the average for OECD countries (3.87percent).8 Therefore, even with the addition of the SOXcosts, the cross-listed credit market “outside option”inhibits their decision to go dark.In summary, understanding the benefits of improvements in

corporate governance schemes ondebt capacity is important, atthe micro level, to enable firms to enhance their financialcapacity and, at the macro level, for countries to promote theircredit market development and growth, crucial to emergingeconomies.The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. The

next section describes the relation between the Sarbanes-Oxley Act and corporate governance. The third sectiondescribes the empirical design. The fourth section presentsthe database and the main descriptive statistics, and the mainresults on the effect of corporate governance on firms’ debtfinancing are presented in the fifth section. The final sectionpresents the conclusions.

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

THE SARBANES-OXLEYACTANDCORPORATE GOVERNANCE

The Sarbanes-Oxley Act, officially called the Public CompanyAccounting Reform and Investor Protection Act, forcedchanges that affected executive compensation and fraudpunishment, required stronger board and shareholder moni-toring, established a new audit committee, heightened thepotential liability of senior executives, and put in place manyother rules to reduce information asymmetry (see Holmstrom& Kaplan, 2003).To be more precise, one provision related to executive

payments requires the CEO and CFO to give back any profitsfrom bonuses and stock options during the 12-month periodthat follows a financial report that is subsequently restateddue to misconduct. This provision increases their risk of sell-ing a large amount of stock or options in any one year whilestill in office, inducing more conservative behavior until theyare no longer in those positions before selling equity orexercising options. Also, this requirement acts as a deterrentto negligent or deliberate misreporting.Shareholder-related provisions also enhance financial

disclosure. SOX requires more detailed disclosure of off-bal-ance-sheet financing and special purpose entities, whichshould make it more difficult for companies to manipulatetheir financial statements in a way that boosts the currentstock price. The Act also includes several provisions designedto improve board monitoring. These focus largely on increas-ing the power, responsibility, and independence of the auditcommittee. SOX requires that the audit committee choosethe outside auditor and that the committee consist entirely ofdirectors with no other financial relationship with the com-pany. Such changes in monitoring practices increase thechances ofmisconduct being identified, reducing the expectedgains from moral hazard actions.Finally, the law increases the responsibility of the CEO,

CFO, and board for financial reporting and the criminalpenalties for misreporting. This issue clearly increases theircost of misconduct, probably inducing less opportunisticbehavior. Table 1 summarizes the set of mandates of SOX.To sumup, the requirements imposed by SOX induce an im-

provement in the corporate governance system, as they re-duce the potential gains to managers and increase theirchances of being caught and the cost of misconduct.

The Sarbanes-Oxley Act and Cross-Listed CompaniesAlthough the new law was enacted to address domestic USproblems, it applies to all “issuers”, including foreign compa-nies listed on the US stock market. In addition, the provisionsconcerning auditor oversight and independence apply to allaccounting firms, including non-US ones. The application ofSOX to foreign private issuers produced strong reactions fromforeign executives and national regulators (Berger et al., 2005).Given the frequent conflicts between legal and regulatory re-gimes, the extraterritorial application of Sarbanes-Oxley hasproduced challenging areas of interpretation and implementa-tion for the SEC and the companies subject to its provisions.Additionally to the previous section, we describe a

summary of new requirements, with limited relief, forforeign issuers:

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

Page 4: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

TABLE 1Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002: Summary of Provisions

Sections Topics

101–109 PCAOB’s creation, oversight, funding, and tasks302, 401–406, 408–409, 906 New disclosure rules, including control systems and officer certifications201–209, 303 Regulation of public company auditors and auditor-client relationship301, 304, 306, 407 Corporate governance for listed firms (audit committee rules, ban on officer loans)501 Regulation of securities analysts305, 601–604, 1103, 1105 SEC funding and powers802, 807, 902–905, 1102, 1104, 1106 Criminal penalties806, 1107 Whistleblower protections308, 803–804 Miscellaneous (time limits for securities fraud, bankruptcy, fair funds)

Source: Coates (2007)

4 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

• Audit committee: In response to conflicts between the USaudit committee rules and local legal requirements andcorporate governance standards outside the US, the rulesallow some exemptions for cross-listed companies. Thetwo most important areas of relief are: an expanded defini-tion of permitted members of an audit committee; andalternative structures established under foreign law thatprovide an exemption from the audit committee’s over-sight and independence requirements.

• Prohibition on loans to executives: The Actmakes it illegalfor any issuer, including through any subsidiary, to extendor maintain credit, in the form of a personal loan to or forany director or executive officer. However, for foreignprivate issuers, it allows extensions of credit maintainedby the issuer on the date of its enactment, as long as thereis no material modification to any term of such extensionof credit after the Act’s date.

• Code of ethics for senior financial officers: The SEC hasadopted disclosure rules demanding each company todisclose in its annual report whether or not, and the reason,the company has adopted a written code of ethics applica-ble to the CEO, CFO, and controller or principal accountingofficer. For cross-listed firms, the SEC has suggested thatissuers disclose waivers on Form 6-K, but does not requireit, and at a minimum such disclosure is required in annualreports on Form 20-F.

SOX, Corporate Governance, and DebtAs shown above, SOX is associated with firms’ governance.How does the governance induced by SOX connect withincentives around debt policy? Sections 302 and 404 deal withinternal controls. Section 302 requires managers of all publicfirms filing under Sections 13(a) or 15(d) of the SecuritiesExchange Act to test and report on the quality of the internalcontrols. Section 404 requires publicly traded firms to publishan audited report concerning the effectiveness of the firm’sinternal controls of financial reporting. Also, firms are re-quired to disclose in the Section 404 report anymaterial weak-ness in internal controls over financial reporting. The effect ofboth sections on firms’ debt terms is intuitive. Consider, forexample, a companywith weak internal control over financial

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

reporting. It leads to a poor precision of financial reportingnumbers. In this case, lenders have less reliable informationto assess default risk, which leads them to charge a highercost of debt. Therefore, with regulation that strengthensinternal controls we can expect a reduction in the interestrate charged to companies and in consequence an increasein the amount of debt.The effect of Sections 101–109 and 901–906 are straightfor-

ward. Punishment has no effect if the chance of being caughtis low or nil. Sections 101–109 work to improve disclosureand the chance of discovering the manager misbehavior, and901–906 work to increase punishment. For example, Section906 requires CEOs and CFOs to provide certifications to theSEC as exhibits to each periodic report containing financialstatements filed with the SEC pursuant to Sections 13(a) or15(d) of the Exchange Act. The certifications must declare thatthe report fully complies with such sections and that theinformation contained in the periodic report fairly presentsthe financial condition and results of operations of the com-pany. CEOs and CFOs must provide the certifications witheach annual report on Form 20-F (and amendments theretothat include financial statements). Submission of a false certifi-cation is subject to criminal penalties.A higher expected penalty induces a higher effort ex ante,

increasing the chance of firms’ success, and therefore thechance of lenders being repaid. This reduces the debt contractrisk, and therefore induces lower interest rates.

A Simple ModelIn this section, we try to elucidate the channels that linkchanges produced by SOX and the terms of credit. Severalclassic papers model the effect of information asymmetry onfirms’ financing policy.One of the seminal papers on the subject, Leland and Pyle

(1977), develops a model with information asymmetry onthe quality of the project to be financed. The informationasymmetry explains the capital structure and the level of debt,as equity financing serves as a signal for good projects. In thispaper, we are interested in another type of asymmetric infor-mation, the moral hazard that comes from the borrowers’behavior.

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

Page 5: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

FIGURE 1Manager’s Output Tree

5CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CREDITACCESS

Ourmodel is closely connectedwithDiamond (1991) andDi-amond andVerrecchia (1991. Both studies dealwith borrowers’moral hazard. Diamond (1991) shows that debt financingfrom banks has a positive effect on alleviation of moralhazard due to bankmonitoring. This result shows that mon-itoring serves to screen borrowers, and the demand formonitoring will tend to be higher for companies withoutreputation that want to establish a good track record.Diamond and Verrecchia (1991), on the other hand, analyzethe effect of information asymmetry on cost of capital. Theauthors show that disclosure improves liquidity of a firm’ssecurities, and this reduces its cost of capital. Our paperintroduces monitoring and disclosure in the model tomeasure their effect on manager/borrower behavior andtheir impact on the terms of debt.To analyze the potential effect of the law, let us consider

an asymmetric information problemwith regard to the levelof effort and fraud that managers of debt-financed firmschoose when they pursue projects. In this model, we ignorethe moral hazard between managers and owners, since ourfocus is on the borrower-lender relationship and its effect oncost of credit. Since lenders do not observe the effort andfraud variables, they are not able to know whether aborrowing firm has chosen the optimal effort level. Themanagers can allocate their time to effort (e) to pursue theproject’s success or fraud (f) to divert gains of the projectto themselves by some means. Thus, their time is dividedbetween effort and fraud, which is equal to the time spentin the firm α (α = e + f ). A manager ’s decision regardingeffort and fraud affect the chance of being caught and thesuccess of the firm’s investment. We assume that the proba-bility of success of the investment project increases with themanager ’s effort level. In precise terms, we assume that theprobability of the firm being solvent (psolv(e) ) is differentia-ble, strictly increasing, and strictly concave in the effortvariable e, such that:

lime→0

p′solv eð Þ ¼ ∞;

meaning that it is efficient for the firm to choose a posi-tive effort level and that psolv(e)<1 for the insolvency stateis always possible. Also, since there is a chance of amanager being caught, we assume that this probability in-creases with the manager ’s fraud level ( f ) and the moni-toring level (M). In precise terms, the probability of themanager being caught (q( f,M) ) is differentiable andstrictly increasing on the fraud level ( f ) and monitoringvariable (M), and that q( f,M) < 1 for fraud not discoveredis always possible.The manager ’s gains from fraud are a positive func-

tion of the level of fraud G( f ) and its cost C( f ) is thepunishment imposed by the legislation. Figure 1 illus-trates the dynamics of this problem. The figure repre-sents the manager ’s expected return as a function ofhis choice between fraud and effort. The firm can suc-ceed and be solvent, providing a return of V. After thepayment to creditors F (debt face value), the amountthat remains for the manager is V � F. If the managercommits fraud and is not caught, he adds the gains fromfraud (V�F+ FraudGains), whereas if he is caught, he

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

receives a punishment (Cf ). The firm can go into bank-ruptcy, providing a return of zero for managers and vfor creditors (where v < F). If the manager commitsfraud and is not caught, his gains come only from fraud(like personal benefits obtained during the managementperiod, it can be pecuniary or non-pecuniary), whereasif he is caught, the punishment (Cf ) is applied.Thus, from the manager’s perspective and, for simplicity,

assuming risk neutrality, he chooses the level of effort andfraud to maximize his expected wealth:9

maxf ;e

E Wð Þ ¼ p eð Þ q f ;Mð Þ �Cf� �þ 1� q f ;Mð Þð Þ V � Fþ G fð Þð Þ� �þ

1� p eð Þð Þ q f ;Mð Þ �Cf� �þ 1� q f ;Mð Þð Þ G fð Þð Þ� �

s:t:α ¼ eþ f

The problem can be simplified and rewritten as:

maxf

E Wð Þ ¼ p α� fð Þ 1� q f ;Mð Þð Þ V � Fð Þþ 1� q f ;Mð Þð ÞG fð Þ � q f ;Mð ÞCf

Themanager commits fraud until his marginal gain is equalto the marginal cost. The optimal level of fraud is a function ofgains from solvency, gains from fraud, level of monitoring,level of punishment, etc. Thus, we can write the optimalchoice of fraud as:

f � ¼ f V � F; α;G �ð Þ;M;Cf� �

:

Notice that the Sarbanes-Oxley Act directly affects the lasttwo exogenous variables (M and Cf). So, the question thatwe address is: How can an increase in the levels of monitoring(M) and punishment for fraud (Cf) affect the manager’s deci-sion on fraud and effort on the firm’s projects? To see the ef-fect, we take the manager’s expected wealth and divide itinto three parts:

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

Page 6: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

6 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

(1) Benefit from solvency:

p α� fð Þ 1� q f ;Mð Þð Þ V � Fð Þ (1)

(2) Benefit from not being caught:

1� q f ;Mð Þð ÞG fð Þ (2)

(3) Cost of fraud:

q f ;Mð ÞCf (3)

Suppose that the monitoring level increases from M to M′.In this case, for a higher monitoring level, the level of fraud(f) has a stronger effect on the probability of being caught(since ∂q f ;Mð Þ

∂M > 0Þ, reducing the marginal benefits from fraud(equations (1) and (2), respectively). In addition, it increasesthe marginal cost of fraud, as it increases the expected cost(3). Therefore, since a higher level of monitoring reduces themarginal benefit from fraud and increases its marginal cost,the optimal level falls from f* to f**.We can apply the same idea for the punishment level Cf. Let

us suppose an increase in Cf, whereC′f > Cf : In this case, there

is no change in the benefit (1 and 2), but the marginal cost offraud (3) rises. Therefore, because the marginal cost increases,the optimal level falls from f* to f**, where f* > f**. Therefore,since we observe a fall in the fraud level, more time will beexpended on the firm’s projects (since α = e + f), reducing themoral hazard problem.

Proposition 1. An increase in the monitoring level (M) reducesthe moral hazard problem.

Proposition 2. An increase in the cost of fraud (Cf ) reduces themoral hazard problem.

With a reduction in the fraud level (f), the time allocated (ef-fort) by the manager to the firm’s project increases (e), makingthe solvent state of naturemore likely (it increases its chance ofsuccess p(e)) and insolvency is less likely. This effect reducesthe risk of lending by creditors, making the terms of credit bet-ter to the firm and, as a consequence, motivating the firm’sdebt financing.To see the effect on interest rates and the amount of credit,

consider that the borrowing firm has a project that requirescapital, I, which the firmmust raise externally. The firm prom-ises to repay creditors the face value of a debt contract F,where F = I(1 + r) and r is the interest rate charged by thelender. However, if the firm is insolvent, the repayment isthe firm’s value of liquidation. Thus, the project can return avalue, v, where the firm is solvent if v ≥ F and insolvent if v< F. Two states are possible in the future, one if the firm is sol-vent and the other if it is not. The solvency and insolvencystates return to the firm vsolv and vins, respectively, wherevsolv ≥ F > vins. The probability of solvency is p(e); the proba-bility of insolvency is (1 – p(e)). This implies that the expectedvalue of the project is E(v) = p(e)vsolv + (1 – p(e))vins.Because the creditmarket is competitive, F is the largest sum

that creditors can demand to fund the project, given the

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

probabilities of solvency and insolvency and the firm’s valuein the insolvency state of nature. The risk-free interest rate isassumed to be zero, and, therefore, the borrowing firm’s inter-est rate is a function only of the riskiness of its project.Creditors that lend I should expect to receive I in return, as

the market is competitive. This expectation can be written asfollows:

I ¼ p eð ÞFþ 1� p eð Þð Þvins;

and

F ¼ I 1þ rð Þ ¼ I � 1� p eð Þð Þvinsp eð Þ :

The firm’s interest rate is defined by r = (F/I) – 1,which is anincreasing function of the debt contract’s face value F; this isthe value that the firm is required to repay in the solvencystate. To simplify, suppose that the investment is normalizedto one. Denoting by vuins the per-unit-of-investment (I = 1)counterparts of vins, we also have:

r ¼ 1� p eð Þð Þp eð Þ 1� vuins

� �:

Therefore, the more the creditor expects to receive in the in-solvency state, due to higher probability of success, the less itwill require the firm to repay in the solvency state, reducingthe interest rate.

Proposition 3. An increase in the probability of success p(e)reduces the interest rate.

As consequence, lower interest rates motivate the firm’sdebt financing.

Proposition 4. An increase in the probability of success p(e)increases the firm’s debt financing.

From Propositions 1–2, we develop the following hypothe-ses to be tested:

Hypothesis 1a. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act increased firms’ debtfinancing.

Hypothesis 2b. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act reduced the interest ratein debt contracts.

EMPIRICAL DESIGN

In this section, we describe our experiment and the difference-in-differences method used in the paper.

The Sarbanes-Oxley Act as an ExperimentThe basic idea of exploiting the implementation of SOX regu-lation is that it provides a way to identify the effect of changesin corporate governance on firms’ debt financing policies. Theproblem of dealingwith the relation between corporate gover-nance and the level of debt financing is their endogenous

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

Page 7: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

7CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CREDITACCESS

relation. To approach this issue, our identification strategy re-quires the governance level to be variable enough to allowcomparison across firms. Also, the variation of the corporategovernance level needs to be exogenous and independent offirms’ financing policies. SOX represents an exogenous shockon the corporate governance level that is independent offirms’ financing policies.Several studies use the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as an identifica-

tion strategy. For example, Litvak (2007) compares returns tocross-listed companies subject to SOX (cross-listed at level 2or 3) to returns of matching non-cross-listed companies fromthe same industry and country and similar in size. Carter(2013) uses Canadian firms to examine the effect of SOX onlong-term debt ratios. Costello and Wittenberg-Moerman(2011) rely on SOX’s internal control reports to measure finan-cial reporting quality. They analyze howmaterial internal con-trol weakness affects the use of financial covenants.The major problem concerning the use of SOX as an experi-

ment is the fact that it is difficult to disentangle its effects fromother shocks occurring simultaneously in the financial andeconomic fields. The legislation was enacted amidst sharp fi-nancial, economic and political changes. To isolate the effectof SOX on debt financing from the other shocks, we have tofind treatment and control groups that are subject to the sameshocks, except for the SOX implementation. The cross-listingsituation allows us to screen groups. Companies that haveADR level 2 or 3 programs require the US depositary bankto register the ADRs representing the issuer’s securities underthe Securities Act by filling out Form F-6, following SOX rules.If a company has a class of securities registered under theExchange Act, it is required to file periodic reports with theSEC. Form 20-F is the annual reporting form used by foreignprivate issuers. The only difference between levels 2 and 3 isthat the latter program allows the issuer to raise capitalthrough a public offering of ADRs in the US in addition tothe creation of a trading market for the issuer’s equity securi-ties. On the other hand, level 1 programs do not involve thelisting of the ADRs on a US stock exchange, being tradedthrough the over-the-counter market, and therefore, it is notrequired to register the securities under the Exchange Actand the issuer is not subject to SOX. In addition, foreignprivate issuers can raise capital by issuing ADRs pursuant toRule 144A, which provides an exemption from the registra-tion requirements of the Securities Act for securities issued incompliance with the rule. Due to this exemption, the foreignprivate issuerwill not become subject to the periodic reportingrequirements of the Exchange Act and of SOX.Since the law provides an exogenous shock on governance

requirements to all non-US firms issuing level 2 or 3 ADRs(treatment group), and it does not apply to foreign companiesnot listed or listed with ADR levels 1 or 144A, the existence ofcross-listed firms presents a natural experiment.Finally, we have to consider in the model the cross-listing

decision, as it may influence our identification strategy. Thelisting decision is endogenous to changes in regulation andtherefore it can produce a bias in our estimation. With theadoption of SOX, the costs of cross-listing increased, inducingfirms to “go dark” (see Leuz et al., 2008). Using data onBrazilian firms, we can avoid this estimation problem as theyextensively use ADS programs – implying that part of oursample is subject to SOX regulation – and none of the cross-

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

listed firms in the ADR level 2 or 3 program delisted in thepost-SOX period, which allows our identification strategy.

Difference-in-differences EstimatorsWe want to test whether firms altered their decision on debtfinancing policy after SOX took effect. Our objective is todevelop an identification strategy that represents a “random”experiment, that is, any Brazilian publicly traded firm had apositive chance to be regulated by SOX. As we are interestedin quantifying the impact of changes in the corporategovernance level on terms of credit, we need to carefullyidentify a group containing firms that are virtually similar tothose that suffered a change in their corporate governance,except for the fact that they did not suffer this shock. That is,we need to pin down the counterfactual firm financing policyin the period of SOX because it would represent the financingpolicy of the firmswithout the changes in the corporate gover-nance level.Thematching estimator is closer to the idea of a randomized

experiment. This procedure isolates treated observations – inthis case firms subject to SOX – and then, from the untreatedobservations, searches for controls that best match the treatedobservations in several dimensions, called covariates, i.e.,their characteristics are the closest to the treated ones.Instead of representing amodel that tries to fully explain the

endogenous variable, the specification focuses on ensuringthat variables can both influence the selection into treatmentand that observed outcomes are appropriately accounted forin the estimation. While there are several theories to justifythe inclusion of debt determinants, we only include in ourestimations covariates that can make a reasonable case forsimultaneity in the treatment outcome relation. It is com-monly accepted that the covariates capture a lot of otherwiseunobserved firm heterogeneity. Therefore, in matching, theset of counterfactuals are represented by thematched controls,or in other words, we assume that the treated group wouldhave behaved the same as the control group if those firmshad not been treated. The matches are made in the pre-treatment period, to ensure that both groups of observationshave identical distributions along the covariates chosen.In this paper we use the nearest-neighbor matching initially

suggested by Abadie and Imbens (2006), with bias correctionfor average treatment effect. As Abadie and Imbens (2006,2011) propose in their studies, the implementation of bias cor-rection removes the conditional bias of matching asymptoti-cally such that the resulting estimator is consistent. Withoutbias correction, the matching estimators include a conditionalbias term, usually when few continuous variable are used formatching or when one does not have the exact match fordiscrete variables in a small sample. As a result, matching es-timators may not be consistent. Nearest-neighbor matchingestimation allows matching each treated firm with one ormore control firms, for categorical and continuous variables.In our estimation, we use the nearest-neighbor matching withreplacement and three matches per observation, reducing theexpected variance of the treatment effect estimator.10 Finally,since we want to implement a matching difference-in-differences estimator, we model the outcomes in differencedform, which represents the time difference (the first differ-ence), comparing both groups, which represents the group-

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

Page 8: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

8 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

difference (the second difference). Therefore, we are compar-ing the changes in terms of debt financing across the groups.Since the Sarbanes-Oxley Act was enacted in 2002, we

compare how the outcomes behaved from pre-SOX topost-SOX between both treatment and matched controlgroups. We considered three period variations: from 2001to 2003; from 2001 to 2003 and 2004; and from 2001 to2003, 2004, and 2005. To be more precise, our variable ofinterest is the variation Δy from 2001 to 2003. To capturelong-run effects and also to increase the number of observa-tions, we first add variation from 2001 to 2004 and thenvariation from 2001 to 2005. We expect a significant differ-ence in outcomes between groups, with lower tendency ofinterest rate and higher tendency of amount of credit forthe treatment groups compared to its counterfactual.In addition to the matching estimator, we also run an

OLS regression. We do this for two reasons: first, this en-ables us to capture the heterogeneous effect of SOX on debtpolicy behavior using interactions between variables thatwe cannot do with matching; second, this allows us tocheck the robustness of our results to changes in the empir-ical method.Thus, our second estimation method is a difference-in-

differences panel model with fixed effects, which comparesthe outcomes in the treatment group before and after thechange in regulationwith outcomes in the control groupwhilecontrolling for time-invariant heterogeneity (ownershipstructures, for example). Unlike the matching estimator, thedifference-in-differences panel model does not work withvariables in difference. Thus, we use data from 2001 to 2009in our estimation and we include a set of year dummies toaccount for all common shocks (pure time series) and there-fore macroeconomic or political shocks that affect all Braziliancompanies are controlled by this set of dummies, as well ascontrol variables to account for firms’ heterogeneities.However, it is fair to argue that since ADR issuers have

access to the US financial markets, the difference of termsof credit for both groups of companies (with and withoutADRs) could be driven by the Brazilian macroeconomic mo-ment. Because of this, the treatment group consisted of Bra-zilian firms with ADRs listed at levels 2 and 3, and thecontrol group consisted of Brazilian companies with level1 or 144A ADRs. In summary, the identifying variationwas the difference (at the firm level) between treatmentand control groups, before and after adoption of the law.More specifically, we measured the effect of the law by esti-mating the following model:

yit ¼ αi þ δt þ β1DIDit þ β2DIDit�CHit þ β3DIDit�Monitit

þ∑jϕjX

jit þ εit

(4)

where yit is the credit variable (amount, source, price, etc.)for firm i in year t. The right-hand side of the equation in-cludes a full set of firm dummies (αi), which control for allpure cross-section invariant unobserved heterogeneity,and a full set of year dummies (δt) that control for all com-mon macroeconomic shocks. The diff-in-diff variable(DID) is a dummy variable that assumes a value of 1 for

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

companies cross-listed at level 2 and 3 and after SOX wasenacted, and zero otherwise. The parameter associated withthe difference-in-differences variable, β1, is our main coeffi-cient of interest. Also, we added the cash holdings variable(CH), a proxy for the probability of solvency. Acharya,Davydenko, and Strebulaev (2012) argue that cash-richfirms should have lower probability of default and lowercredit spreads, other things equal. As Propositions 3 and 4show, we expect that a higher probability of solvency in-duces lower cost of debt and larger amounts of debt, andthe effect of SOX should be weaker for companies with bet-ter solvency situation. The parameter that captures this het-erogeneous effect is β2.Additionally, following Propositions 3 and 4, we expect a

heterogeneous effect of SOX on firms with different pre-SOXlevels of monitoring. We use the monitoring cost variable(Monit) to interact with the DID variable, and the parameterβ3 estimates this heterogeneous effect. To measure the moni-toring cost, we use the sub-indexes of Brazilian CorporateGovernance Index of 2002, which measure disclosure andboard composition and functioning.11 We believe that firmswith more disclosure allow creditors/investors to access theiraccounting and financial information more easily, reducingthe monitoring cost. In addition, better board compositionand functioningmay exert an initial monitoring effect on com-panies’ management, reducing the creditors’ monitoring costas well.12

Among the list of remaining variables used as controls, wehave:

(i) total assets, to control for effects of scale;(ii) cash holdings, as firms with different levels of cash hold-

ings have different repayment capacity;(iii) accruedprofit, to capture the contemporaneous profitability;(iv) fixed assets, as it can be used as collateral in debt con-

tracts, and;(v) equity, as it helps to measure how distressed companies are.

DATA AND DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

Our data come from two distinct sources, “Capital IQ” and“Economatica”. The first source has information on the firms’debt contracts, such as type of debt, principal, spread, index,and maturity. We use this database to measure the real interestrate paid by the companies and maturity. Data on balance-sheetinformation on publicly traded Brazilian firms comes from thesecond source. Both data sets cover the period from 2001 to 2009.

Debt Contracts DatabaseOur database concerning debt contracts is from Capital IQ –Standard and Poor’s. Capital IQ reports the stock debt con-tracts that each company holds per year. This database has atotal of 30,937 observations of debt contracts from 291 firms,for a period that runs from 2001 to 2009. However, severalcontracts have some missing information. We dropped con-tracts if: the contract does not have information on interest ratespread (9,889 observations); the information is duplicated(2,831 observations); and the contract does not have informa-tion on principal (5,541 observations). Finally, some of thepublicly traded Brazilian companies took credit from the

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

Page 9: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

9CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CREDITACCESS

National Bank for Economic and Social Development(BNDES) at subsidized rates (TJLP, or long-term interest rate,plus a modest spread). This type of credit is closely related topolitical decisions, and because of such characteristics, we alsodropped all companies that use this type of credit (717 firm-year observations and 5,436 contracts). The remaining samplehas 4,429 contract observations, and 890 firm-year observa-tions. For cost of debt, we also discard 206 firm-year observa-tions leaving 684 firm-year observations, 226firms overall and22 firms with ADR level 2 or 3.Each contract has information about its type, interest rate

index, interest rate spread, date of issue, principal amount,maturity, and others. Concerning the price of debt contracts,they have their own coupon rate characteristics. The couponrate can be fixed or floating and in the latter case, it iscomposed of the interest rate index and spread. Thus, forfloating rates, they can be indexed by: Libor, CDI (InterbankDeposit Certificates), TJLP (government subsidized rate), Selic

TABLDescriptive Statistics

This table presents descriptive statistics and median tests of ourimmediately before the Sarbanes-Oxley Act took effect. Our sam“Economatica”. The first source has information on firms’ debt cofirms comes from the second source and is scaled by total assetstreatment group (cross-listedfirms at levels 2 and 3) and 257 firmspecifically subject to theAct (cross-listedfirms at levels 1 and 4) oA presents descriptive statistics considering all firms. Panel B prtreatment firms and firms matched with same characteristics asmedian test was used. See Appendix A for variable definitions.

Panel A: Descriptive statistics

Mean Std. dev.

Total credit 0.30 0.42Cost of credit 4.67 5.93Maturity 4.12 3.21Firm size 3131 4382Cash holdings 0.12 0.21Equity 0.43 0.22PPE 0.40 0.25Accrued profit -0.09 0.32Panel B: Mann-Whitney median tests

Treatment Non-treatment

Total credit 0.22 0.12Cost of credit 1.46 3.41Maturity 3.50 4.00Firm size 8329 728Cash holdings 0.05 0.03Equity 0.43 0.35PPE 0.51 0.40Accrued profit 0.00 0.00

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

(Central Bank benchmark rate), IGP-M (Brazilian generalmarket price index), CPI (US inflation rate), and others.13

Our challenge here is to make the price of debt comparablein order to aggregate it to calculate an average of ex-ante realinterest rates faced by each firm each year.14 To do this, wehave to follow the specific characteristics of debt contractsissued inside Brazil or outside the country. Brazil has com-pound interest rates, and because of this for all contractsindexed by a Brazilian indexwe compounded the interest rateindex with the spread, deflating by the expected IGP-M. Forcontracts with foreign indexes, mainly Libor andCPI,we usedthe linear interest rates, deflating by the expected CPI.Having the real interest rate of each debt contract, the next

step is to calculate the average real interest rate paid by eachcompany each year. To do this we use the share of the princi-pal of each debt contract to the total amount of debt issued bythe firm in the specific year to define the weight of each con-tract in the firm’s average interest rate. We decided not to

E 2and Median Tests

covariates and terms of credit (differenced) for the yearple is identified by merging firms listed in “Capital IQ” andntracts. Balance-sheet information of publicly traded Brazilian. For this specific year, we have 34 firms composing ours composing our non-treatment group (firms that are either notr not subject to anyUS regulation at all (noADR firms)). Panelesents median tests comparing treatment firms with non-firms in treatment group (control group). The Mann-Whitney

Median Q1 Q3

0.23 0.08 0.383.72 0.99 7.563.50 1.93 5.201059 320 33740.06 0.02 0.160.42 0.25 0.600.39 0.20 0.580.00 -0.03 0.00

P-value Treatment Control P-value

0.24 0.22 0.34 0.670.04 1.46 3.50 0.150.98 3.50 4.00 0.970.00 8329 6074 0.110.00 0.05 0.07 0.830.00 0.43 0.48 0.060.00 0.51 0.61 0.830.00 0.00 0.00 0.77

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

Page 10: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

10 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

aggregate debt contracts issued within and outside Brazilfor two reasons: first, we want to investigate if the impacton interest rates depends on the place that the contractwas issued; second, these contracts are issue in differentcurrencies and therefore present an exchange rate risk. Ifwe aggregated these contracts, firms could simply migratefrom one to another and the change in interest rate couldbe due to differences in exchange rate instead of changesbrought about by SOX.

Firms’ Balance Sheet DatabaseFirms accounting data comes from the Economatica database.We used year-end information on amount of debt (total, shortterm, and long term), public and private debt, total assets,cash holdings, accrued profit, fixed assets, and equity. Theamount of debt variables are the variables of interest, whilethe other accounting/financial variables are used in the fixedeffects panel model as controls and in the matching procedureas covariates.

FIGURE 3Cost of the Newly Issued Credit Before and After SOX

FIGURE 2Total Credit to Assets Ratio Before and After SOX

Descriptive StatisticsTo proceed with our empirical tests, we use data merged fromthe Capital IQ andEconomatica databases. Our final sample iscomposed of observations of 291 Brazilian companies, where34 had ADS (level 2 and 3 cross-listed firms),15 from 2001 to2009, disregarding observations from financial institutions,as their financing policies differ greatly from those of firmsfrom others sectors. We call this subsample of 34 firms thatuse theADS program the treatment group, as these firmsweresubject to the changes brought about by SOX. The remainingfirms either are not listed outside Brazil or are listed at ADRlevels 1 or 144A, called the untreated group.Now we present the descriptive statistics, concerning our

covariates and credit variables. We removed all observationsthat appear to be misreported (such as negative numbers forcredit or zero assets). To keep firm size from influencing theaccounting variables (amount of credit, cash holdings, equity,fixed assets, and accrued profits), we use the variables dividedby total assets.Panel A of Table 2 presents the descriptive statistics for the

whole sample and for the year immediately before theSarbanes-Oxley Act took effect. Panel B presents the medianvalues of our covariates and terms of credit (differenced) againfor the year immediately before the Sarbanes-Oxley Act tookeffect. For this specific year, we have 34 firms composing ourtreatment group and 257 firms that are not specifically subjectto the Act. From this group of 257 companies, 18 firms arecross-listed firms at levels 1 and 144A, and the remainder(239) are not cross-listed at any level. Panel B compares thetreatment group with all publicly traded firms not affectedby SOX, representing the untreated group. Notice that forthe pre-SOX period, both groups have similar medians forthe amount of credit, unlike that observed for the covariates,which present a significant difference between the treatmentand non-treatmentmedians. The treated firms are bigger, withhigher cash holdings, equity, and fixed assets. However, po-tential similarities were not expected, as we are not runninga truly random experiment.

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

The benefit brought by the matching estimators is to controlfor these distributional differences, which can affect both theselection in the treatment group and the post-SOX outcomes.We perform again the same Mann-Whitney median test butin comparison with the control group, identified by thematching procedure from Abadie and Imbens (2006). In thiscase, if two observations of the opposite treatment group areequally close to that being matched, we allowed both to beused. Observe in Panel B that there is no highly significant sta-tistical difference between the control and the treatment groupfor all the covariates. Apart from equity, which is significant at10 percent, no others are statistically different.To illustrate the potential impact of SOX implementation,

we compare the evolution of the credit-assets ratio betweenfirms in the treatment group against the control group.Figure 2 shows a strong increase in the amount of total creditafter SOX became effective only for the treatment group. Theannual mean of total credit to assets ratio increased from0.66 to 0.82 for the treatment group, while it remained almostthe same for the control group, which means a variation of 24percent for the treatment group. The results are qualitativelythe same for long-term and short-term credit-to-assets ratio.As illustrated in Figure 3, the annual average cost of newly

issued credit presents dynamics consistent with that related

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

Page 11: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

11CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CREDITACCESS

with amount of total credit. The figure shows a strong de-crease in the cost of newly issued credit after SOX became ef-fective only for the treatment group. The annual average realcost of newly issued credit decreased from 2.45 percent to1.16 percent for the treatment group while it rose from 4.05percent to 4.25 percent for the control group, which meansvariations of approximately �53 percent and 5 percent forthe treatment and control groups, respectively.To sumup, the descriptive statistics show that after Sarbanes-

Oxley there was a strong increase in credit for the treatmentgroup, unlike the control group, where it remained stable oreven dropped. In terms of cost of newly issued credit, the de-scriptive statistics show that after Sarbanes-Oxley there was astrong decrease in the cost of credit for the treatment group, un-like the control group, which experienced a small decrease.The difference in the terms of credit behavior between

treated and control groups gives us a nice picture to illustratethe potential effect of SOX. However, we cannot forget thatsuch result could be driven by other factors that can influencethe assignment in the experiment and the post-SOX outcome.To estimate SOX’s impact controlling for these facts, in thenext section we present our results using the difference-in-differences estimators.

RESULTS

We now examine the firms’ debt financing policy behaviorusing information on the amount of credit–assets ratio (total,long-term, and short-term credit) and its cost, comparingtreated and control firms, before and after the Sarbanes-Oxley

TABLMatching Difference-in-Differen

This table presents the results of average change in total amountassets comparing treated and control firms from 2001 (pre-SOX y2003–2005. Thematching estimationmeasures the difference-in-dtreated firms are defined as those that are subject to SOX (firmssubset of non-treated firms selected as the closest match (three fiindustry sector, total assets (in logs), and cash holdings, equity, fiis the Abadie and Imbens average treatment effect for the treateconsistent errors were used. See Appendix A for variable defini

2001 × 2003

Coefficient P-Value

Panel A: Dependent variable: Difference of total credit scaledMatching estimator (ATT) 0.159 0.027Number of observations 135

Panel B: Dependent variable: Difference of short-term credit sMatching estimator (ATT) -0.043 0.289Number of observations 135

Panel C: Dependent variable: Difference of long-term credit sMatching estimator (ATT) 0.202 0.003Number of observations 135

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

implementation. Tables 3, 4 present the results for the variablecredit–assets ratio, for matching and panel regressionrespectively.Panels A, B, and C of Table 3 report the SOX effect estima-

tion via the matching procedure for total amount of credit–assets ratio, short-term credit–assets ratio and long-termcredit–assets ratio, respectively. For each credit variable wecompare treated and control firms from 2001 (pre-SOX year)to three different post-SOX periods: 2003, 2003–2004, and2003–2005. We found significant results of SOX implementa-tion for all credit variables and periods of analysis. Focusingon the estimation that considers the post-SOX period from2003 to 2005, we observed an increase of 15 percent on thetotal credit–assets ratio and 23.9 percent on long-term credit–assets ratio. Also, we found a decrease of 9 percent in theshort-term credit–assets ratio.The results of estimation using diff-in-diff in the panel

regression are reported in Table 4. Panels A, B, and C presentthe SOX effect for total amount of credit, short-term credit andlong-term credit, respectively. In this case, we use only compa-nies with ADRs but not subject to the Act (cross-listed firms atlevels 1 and 144A) as a control group. By not including firmsthat trade only in Brazil (non-ADR firms) in the control group,we intend to mitigate problems concerning unobservablecharacteristics among cross-listed and domestic firms likeaccess to different credit markets.Like our previous result, we found a positive and significant

effect of SOX on treated firms compared with our controlfirms for total and long-term credit variables. The difference-in-differences point estimator is equal to 0.56 for total credit–assets ratio. This increase comes from the long-term credit as

E 3ces Model: Amount of Credit

of credit, long-term credit, and short-term credit scaled by totalear) to three different post-SOX periods: 2003, 2003–2004, andifferences between the two groups of firms over the years. Thethat are cross-listed at levels 2 or 3). The control firms are therms at most) to the treated firms based on the covariates:xed assets, and accrued profit (scaled by total assets). The ATTd biased corrected matching estimator. Heteroskedasticity-tions.

2001 × 2003-2004 2001 × 2003-2005

Coefficient P-Value Coefficient P-Value

by total assets0.092 0.052 0.149 0.000

290 435

caled by total assets-0.133 0.000 -0.090 0.000

290 435

caled by total assets0.225 0.000 0.239 0.000

290 435

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

Page 12: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

TABLE 4Difference-in-Differences Model: Amount of Credit

This table presents the results of average change in total amount of credit, long-term credit, and short-term credit scaled by totalassets from 2001 (pre-SOX year) to 2009 comparing treated and control firms. The Diff-in-Diff estimation measures thedifference-in-differences between the two groups of firms over the years. The treated firms are defined as those that are subjectto SOX (firms that are cross-listed at levels 2 or 3). The control firms are those that are not specifically subject to the Act (cross-listed firms at levels 1 and 144A). Accrued profit, PPE, and Equity are expressed in million Brazilian Reais. Cash holding isexpressed in thousand Brazilian Reais and Firm size in logs. Heteroskedasticity-consistent errors are used. See Appendix A forvariable definitions.

Coefficient P-Value Coefficient P-Value

Panel A: Dependent variable: Total credit scaled by total assetsDiff-in-diff estimator 0.180 0.046 0.556 0.074Cash holdings * DID -0.039 0.523Cash holdings 0.160 0.066Monitoring * DID -0.093 0.194Firm size -0.048 0.400Accrued profit 0.067 0.092PPE 0.048 0.000Equity -0.050 0.002Number of observations 252 174

Panel B: Dependent variable: Short-term credit scaled by total assetsDiff-in-diff estimator -0.039 0.250 -0.091 0.442Cash holdings * DID 0.036 0.124Cash holdings -0.025 0.343Monitoring * DID 0.004 0.892Firm size -0.026 0.203Accrued profit 0.006 0.561PPE 0.000 0.946Equity 0.000 0.878Number of observations 252 174

Panel C: Dependent variable: Long-term credit scaled by total assetsDiff-in-diff estimator 0.220 0.013 0.647 0.044Cash holdings * DID -0.075 0.309Cash holdings 0.185 0.059Monitoring * DID -0.098 0.187Firm size -0.022 0.683Accrued profit 0.061 0.108PPE 0.048 0.000Equity -0.049 0.003Number of observations 252 174

12 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

the estimated effect is 0.65, significant at 5 percent. The short-term credit presents no statistical significance. Notice that re-sults from regression without control variables provide coeffi-cients closer to those from matching estimation.The increase in the long-term debt after SOX is possibly

explained by the Brazilian institutional environment and com-panies’ poor governance. It is well documented that before2005, the Brazilian Bankruptcy Law was inefficient and didnot guarantee proper protection of creditors (see Araujo &Funchal, 2005; Araujo et al., 2012). In economic environmentswhere lenders face such risk, short-term debt is used to

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

minimize this problem. With improvements in firms’ gover-nance schemes, the risk of default declines (see Proposition 4),which explains both the shift in the supply curve of debt andthe shift of debt from short term to long term.Still in Table 4, the panel regression allows us to explore

other effects on the terms of credit. In addition to the main re-sults of SOX, we tested the effect of cash holdings on firms’debt and the heterogeneous effect of SOX for different levelsof monitoring costs as stated in the theoretical model. In linewith Proposition 4, which states a positive relation betweenprobability of solvency and credit financing, cash holdings

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

Page 13: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

13CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CREDITACCESS

(our proxy for probability of solvency) has a positive impacton the total and long-term credit–assets ratio. Also, we inves-tigate a consequence that follows from Proposition 1. Proposi-tion 1 states that higher monitoring level reduces the moralhazard problem. Thus, we expect companies with higherpre-SOX level of monitoring to benefit less from the improve-ment in their governance. The coefficient of the variable thatinteracts monitoring and the diff-in-diff shows that, althoughthe point estimator is negative, in harmony with the theory,it is not statistically significant. Therefore, we cannot say thereis a heterogeneous effect that depends on the pre-SOX level ofmonitoring.The next step is the analysis of price of credit. Here we use

the data on debt contracts and, as described in the previoussection, we measure the real interest rate paid by each firmeach year. We call this variable the cost of newly issued credit.For this variable, we do our analysis screening debt contractsinto two distinct groups: debt contracts issued inside Brazil(fixed rate contracts and floating rate contracts indexed byCDI, IGP-M, and Selic) and outside Brazil (floating rate con-tracts indexed by Libor and CPI).Table 5 presents the results of matching estimators. The esti-

mation shows, for all three periods of analysis, that the treat-ment group had a statistically significant reduction in the costof newly issued credit compared with the control group. TheATT points to a reduction in the cost of newly issued debt vary-ing from 7 percent to 11 percent. This result means that the in-terest rate paid by companies subject to SOX is statisticallylower compared to the matched companies after SOX took ef-fect. Most of this effect comes from debt issued in Brazil, and

TABLMatching Difference-in-Differences M

This table presents the results of average change in cost of newlcredit indexed by national indexes comparing treated and contrpost-SOX periods: 2003, 2003–2004, and 2003–2005. The matchinbetween the two groups of firms over the years. The treated firmthat are cross-listed at levels 2 or 3). The control firms are the sub(three firms at most) to the treated firms based on the covariatesholdings, equity, fixed assets, and accrued profit (scaled by totaltreatment effect for the treated biased corrected matching estimaSee Appendix A for variable definitions.

2001 × 2003

Coefficient P-Value

Panel A: Dependent variable: Difference of the cost of creditMatching estimator (ATT) -7.429 0.000Number of observations 51

Panel B: Dependent variable: Difference of the cost of credit iMatching estimator (ATT) 0.766 0.478Number of observations 14

Panel C: Dependent variable: Difference of the cost of credit iMatching estimator (ATT) -8.151 0.000Number of observations 47

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

we found weak evidence on debt contracts indexed by Libor.The result concerning debt contracts indexed by Libor is notsurprising. This type of debt is issued by global banks and issubject to more rigorous analysis than carried out by localbanks. So it is possible that the debt is less risky than contractsissued within Brazil, and therefore less affected by SOX.A similar, but economically and statistically weaker ef-

fect, was found through the diff-in-diff panel regression,presented in Table 6. Panel A shows that there is no signifi-cant change in the cost of newly issued credit for contractsissued outside Brazil. However, Panel B shows that thedifference-in-differences coefficient for the cost of newly is-sued credit for contracts issued in Brazil shows a drop insuch cost, presenting a reduction of 2.79 percent for thetreated firms compared to the control firms.We also investigate the effect of cash holdings on the cost of

credit. Aligned to Proposition 3, which posits a negative rela-tion between probability of solvency and the cost of credit,cash holdings (our proxy of probability of solvency) has a neg-ative impact on the cost of credit indexed by national indexes.We could not perform the same test for monitoring level dueto the significant loss of observations.In sum, all the results concerning the improvement in gover-

nance are in line with theory. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act had apositive impact on terms of credit, lowering cost and increas-ing amount, consistent with a positive shift in the supplycurve of credit. Since SOX brought better information, man-ager punishment, and monitoring, creditors could expect bet-ter corporate governance due to a reduction in managers’moral hazard action (see Propositions 1 and 2). This reduction

E 5odel: Cost of Newly Issued Credit

y issued total credit, credit indexed by Libor, andol firms from 2001 (pre-SOX year) to three differentg estimation measures the difference-in-differencess are defined as those that are subject to SOX (firmsset of non-treated firms selected as the closest match: industry sector, total assets (in logs), and cashassets). ATT is the Abadie and Imbens averagetor. Heteroskedasticity-consistent errors are used.

2001 × 2003-2004 2001 × 2003-2005

Coefficient P-Value Coefficient P-Value

-11.742 0.000 -11.356 0.00090 137

ndexed by Libor-0.498 0.580 -7.841 0.00018 28

ndexed by national indexes-14.298 0.000 -15.625 0.00083 121

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

Page 14: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

TABLE 6Difference-in-Differences Model: Cost of Credit for Newly Issued Contracts

This table presents the results of average change in the cost of newly issued credit for contracts indexed by Libor and nationalindexes from 2001 (pre-SOX year) to 2009, comparing treated and control firms. The Diff-in-diff estimation measures thedifference-in-differences between the two groups of firms over the years. The treated firms are defined as those that are subjectto SOX (firms that are cross-listed at levels 2 or 3). The control firms are those that are either not specifically subject to the Act(cross-listed firms at levels 1 and 4) or not subject to any US regulation at all (no ADRs). Accrued profit, PPE and Equity areexpressed in million Brazilian Reais. Cash holding is expressed in thousand Brazilian Reais and Firm size in logs.Heteroskedasticity-consistent errors are used. See Appendix A for variable definitions.

Coefficient P-Value Coefficient P-Value

Panel A: Dependent variable: Cost of credit for contracts indexed by LiborDiff-in-diff estimator -0.253 0.871 0.797 0.655Cash holdings * DID -0.512 0.781Cash holdings -1.010 0.639Firm size 0.193 0.796Accrued profit -0.493 0.344PPE 0.103 0.768Equity 0.345 0.506Number of observations 180 130

Panel B: Dependent variable: Cost of credit for contracts indexed by national indexesDiff-in-diff estimator -1.909 0.127 -2.793 0.073Cash holdings * DID 1.367 0.130Cash holdings -1.767 0.041Firm size -0.378 0.629Accrued profit -0.552 0.216PPE -0.032 0.758Equity 0.055 0.743Number of observations 684 631

14 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

in asymmetric information cost increased the probability ofsuccess of investment projects, diminishing the chance offailure. This effect reduced the risk of lending, motivatingcreditors to supplymore credit with better terms (see Proposi-tions 3 and 4).Given the similarity between firms that compose both

groups, this evidence suggests the Sarbanes-Oxley Actreally did affect firms’ debt financing policy choices. Inorder to verify that this result was not driven by someunobservable characteristics that could cause an increasein the amount of credit, we performed a placebo test thatreplicates our matching estimators in the pre-reform period,from 1999 to 2001. We were not able to perform the sametest for the cost of debt because our contract database beginsin 2001.The results of the placebo test are presented in Table 7.

Panels A, B, and C present the matching difference-in-differences estimation for the period before SOX. For all threecases, the treated and control firms have virtually the samedebt financing behavior. The ATT differences have no statisti-cal significance for total, short-term, and long-term credit.Therefore, we can conclude there was no difference in theterms of credit across the two groups of firms in the pre-treatment period. This result provides more evidence thatthe improvement in corporate governance schemes via SOX

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

had a positive effect on the terms of credit and on firms’ debtfinancing policies.Notice that our results add to the understanding of a spe-

cific benefit of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act. Like Carter (2013)and Andrade et al. (2014), we found a positive effect of SOXon terms of credit. Our model shows that the effect of SOXcomes from a reduction in the information asymmetry be-tween borrowers and lenders, mainly through three channels:disclosure, monitoring, and manager punishment. However,earlier papers in this literature point to the high costs intro-duced by SOX and its final effect on firms’ returns. Eldridgeand Kealey (2005) examine the cost of the new internal controlaudit required by SOX. Analyzing stock returns, Zhang (2007)concludes that SOX and its provisions imposed significantnet costs on firms. Li et al. (2008) and Litvak (2007) show thatthe costs of SOX compliance exceed its benefits, reducing thenet benefits of cross-listings. What none of these papers didwas analyze through which channels SOX contributed posi-tively or negatively to cross-listed companies. With this in-formation, it would be possible to enhance its benefits andmanage its costs.Finally, we also tried to shed some light on the main sources

of funding, private versus public debt, affected by Sarbanes-Oxley Act. Diamond (1991) argues that debt financing frombanks has a positive effect on alleviation of moral hazard

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

Page 15: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

TABLE 7Matching Difference-in-Differences Model: Placebo Test for Amount of Credit

This table presents the placebo test results of average change in total amount of credit, long-term credit, and short-term creditscaled by total assets from 1999 to 2001, comparing treated and control firms. The matching estimationmeasures the difference-in-differences between the two groups of firms over the years. The treated firms are defined as those that are subject to SOX(firms that are cross-listed at levels 2 or 3). The control firms are the subset of non-treated firms selected as the closest match(three firms atmost) to the treated firms based on the covariates: industry sector, total assets (in logs), and cash holdings, equity,fixed assets and accrued profit (scaled by total assets). TheATTis theAbadie and Imbens average treatment effect for the treatedbiased corrected matching estimator. Heteroskedasticity-consistent errors are used. See Appendix A for variable definitions.

Coefficient Robust standard error P-Value

Panel A: Dependent variable: Difference of total credit scaled by total assetsMatching estimator (ATT) 0.02 0.08 0.78Number of observations: 140

Panel B: Dependent variable: Difference of short-term credit scaled by total assetsMatching estimator (ATT) -0.09 0.06 0.15Number of observations: 140

Panel C: Dependent variable: Difference of long-term credit scaled by total assetsMatching Estimator (ATT) 0.11 0.07 0.11Number of observations: 140

15CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CREDITACCESS

due to bank monitoring. Dhaliwal, Hogan, Trezevant, andWilkins (2011) present empirical evidence in that regard. Thatsaid, improvements in disclosure and monitoring might sub-stitute the need for private debt as a monitoring mechanism,inducing more public debt.Panels A and B of Table 8 report the SOX effect estimation via

matching procedure for public and private credit, respectively.Both types of credit present statistically significant changes, but

TABLMatching Difference-in-Differences Mod

This table presents the results of average change in total amountreated and control firms from 2001 (pre-SOX year) to three diffmatching estimation measures the difference-in-differences betware defined as those that are subject to SOX (firms that are cross-treated firms selected as the closest match (three firms atmost) toassets (in logs), and cash holdings, equity, fixed assets and accruImbens average treatment effect for the treated biased correctedused. See Appendix A for variable definitions.

2001 × 2003Coefficient

Panel A: Dependent variable: Difference of total public credittotal assetsMatching estimator (ATT) -0.041Number of observations 135Panel B: Dependent variable: Difference of total private creditotal assetsMatching estimator (ATT) 0.200Number of observations 135

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

in opposite directions. For the private credit–assets ratio, wefound an increase between 0.12 and 0.20. For the public credit–assets ratio, however, we found a negative effect between 0.02and 0.04. A similar result holds for the diff-in-diff panel regres-sion presented in Table 9, pointing to a significant increase inprivate debt, but non-significant decrease in public debt.The positive effect of SOX on private credit and its negative

effect on public debt go against the conventional wisdom of

E 8el: Amount of Public and Private Credit

t of public and private credit scaled by total assets comparingerent post-SOX periods: 2003, 2003–2004, and 2003–2005. Theeen the two groups of firms over the years. The treated firmslisted at levels 2 or 3). The control firms are the subset of non-the treated firms based on the covariates: industry sector, totaled profit (scaled by total assets). The ATT is the Abadie andmatching estimator. Heteroskedasticity-consistent errors are

2001 × 2003-2004 2001 × 2003-2005P-Value Coefficient P-Value Coefficient P-Value

scaled by

0.080 -0.029 0.036 -0.021 0.027290 435

t scaled by

0.004 0.121 0.013 0.170 0.000290 435

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

Page 16: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

TABLE 9Difference-in-Differences Model: Amount of Public and Private Credit

This table presents the results of average change in total amount of public and private credit scaled by total assets from 2001(pre-SOX year) to 2009, comparing treated and control firms. The Diff-in-diff estimation measures the difference-in-differencesbetween the two groups of firms over the years. The treated firms are defined as those that are subject to SOX (firms that arecross-listed on levels 2 or 3). The controlfirms are those companies that are not specifically subject to theAct (cross-listedfirms atlevels 1 and 144A). Accrued profit, PPE and Equity are expressed in million Brazilian Reais. Cash holding is expressed inthousand Brazilian Reais and Firm size in logs. Heteroskedasticity-consistent errors are used. See Appendix A for variabledefinitions.

Coefficient P-Value Coefficient P-Value

Panel A: Dependent variable: Total public credit scaled by total assetsDiff-in-diff estimator 0.017 0.420 -0.095 0.300Cash holdings * DID -0.013 0.036Cash holdings 0.013 0.108Monitoring * DID 0.025 0.252Firm size 0.013 0.462Accrued profit -0.014 0.022PPE 0.000 0.677Equity 0.001 0.458Number of observations 252 174

Panel B: Dependent variable: Total private credit scaled by total assetsDiff-in-diff estimator 0.163 0.072 0.651 0.020Cash holdings * DID -0.027 0.673Cash holdings 0.147 0.096Monitoring * DID -0.118 0.074Firm size -0.061 0.211Accrued profit 0.080 0.025PPE 0.048 0.000Equity -0.051 0.002Number of observations 252 174

16 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

bank loans as a substitute formonitoring and, therefore, bettergovernance. In general, we expect firmswith poor governanceto take more private debt as banks have the monitoring tech-nology (e.g., Diamond, 1991). In fact, it is in line with the coef-ficient of the monitoring interacted with diff-in-diff, showingthat the improvements in governance had less effect on pri-vate loans for firms with better monitoring. However, it wasnatural to expect a substitution of private debt for public debtinduced by SOX. Our results point in the other direction: aprivate debt increase after the shock on corporate governanceintroduced by SOX.We believe that this result is strongly driven by the Brazilian

institutional environment. In the period of analysis, Brazil hada bankruptcy law providing very low protection to creditors(see Araujo et al., 2012). According to Diamond (2004), ineconomic environments where lenders often fail to seek thebankruptcy courts to enforce their rights after a borrowerdefaults, short-term private debt can be an effectiveway to solvethe lender passivity problem. In Brazil, before the New Bank-ruptcy Law – effective in June 2005 – lenders were not part ofthe reorganization procedure and, in case of liquidation, they re-covered less than 1 percent of their credit. The consequence wasthat credit concentrated in short-term private credit (see Araujo

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

et al., 2012). Other studies, including Berlin and Loeys (1988)andMyers (1977), focus on the relation between increased mon-itoring and increased leverage-related costs (agency cost of debtand bankruptcy costs). Since reorganization is costly, these au-thors argue that private debt may help firms to avoid attendantcosts and formal default by providing more flexibility forrescheduling debt contracts. These results should be evenmore pronounced in developing countries where institutionsare poorly designed and face legal enforcement problems.Additionally, we find a heterogeneous effect of SOX on the

treated firms concerning monitoring and cash holding levels.Firmswith highermonitoring are less likely to engage in under-investment compared to companies subject to poorer monitor-ing, because monitoring committees (compensation and/ornomination and/or audit committee and/or permanent over-sight board) supervise management’s decisions. Therefore,suchfirms aremore likely to have higher proportions of privatedebt and find a limited need for the benefits of governanceimprovement on private debt.In line with such an argument, our results suggest that

companieswith poorermonitoring levels benefitedmore fromprivate debt after SOX came into effect. Concerning cash hold-ings, we find that riskier companies (lower level of cash

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

Page 17: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

TABLE 10Number of Newly Issued Private Debt Contracts Before and After SOX

This table presents a comparison between the number of newly issued short-term and long-term private debt contracts from2001 (pre-SOX year) to 2003 (post-SOX year). Our database concerning debt contracts is from Capital IQ – Standard and Poor’s.We dropped contracts if: the contract does not have information on interest rate spread; the information is duplicated; and thecontract does not have information on principal. Finally, some of the publicly traded Brazilian companies took credit from theNational Bank for Economic and Social Development (BNDES) at subsidized rates (TJLP, or long-term interest rate, plus amodest spread). This type of credit is closely related to political decisions, and because of such characteristics, we also droppedall companies that use this type of credit. In the end, we obtained 685 debt contracts considering the pre- and post-SOX years.For the pre-SOX year, we have 34 firms composing our treatment group (cross-listed firms at levels 2 and 3) and 248 firmscomposing our non-treatment group (firms that are either not specifically subject to the Act (cross-listed firms at levels 1 and 4)or not subject to any US regulation at all (no ADR firms)). Panels A and B present the number of newly issued short-term andlong-term contracts comparing treatment and non-treatment groups, respectively.

Type of contract Before SOX After SOXTreatment Non-treatment Treatment Non-treatment

Panel A: Number of newly issued short-term contracts before and after SOXCommercial paper 0 2 1 0Revolving credit 3 20 12 25

Panel B: Number of newly issued long-term contracts before and after SOXBonds and notes 13 32 23 31Capital lease 0 3 0 3Term loans 39 155 93 191Other borrowings 5 11 12 11

17CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CREDITACCESS

holdings) benefitted more from public debt. Since cash hold-ings allow financially constrained firms to hedge against fu-ture income shortfalls (Acharya, Almeida, & Campello, 2007)and such companies are more likely to benefit more frompub-lic debt under improved governance.These results are potentially consistent with other find-

ings in the paper, such as the shift away from short-termdebt. Table 10 presents further analyses about the type ofprivate debt issued after SOX, by comparing the numberof newly issued short-term and long-term private debtcontracts from 2001 (pre-SOX year) to 2003 (post-SOX year).The results show an increase in long-term private debtcontracts, such as term loans, in the post-SOX year. Thenumber of term loan contracts for the treated and non-treated firms increased 138 percent (from 39 to 93 contracts)and 23 percent (from 155 to 191) respectively, aligned withthe findings that SOX leads tomore private debt with longermaturity. Since borrowers’ financial health could changesignificantly over a long period, this result suggests thatimproved governance allowed private lenders to take onriskier debt contracts. With improvements in firms’ gover-nance schemes, the risk of default declines (see Proposition 4),which explains both the shift in the supply curve of debt andthe shift of debt from short term to long term.

CONCLUDING REMARKS

This paper studies the effect of changes in corporategovernance level on firms’ debt financing policies in arelevant emerging economy. In particular, this study

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

tests whether firms subject to a positive shock regardingcorporate governance – brought about by the Sarbanes-Oxley Act – experienced a more pronounced increasein their debt and reduction in its cost than similar firmsthat were not subject to the new corporate governancelevel imposed by SOX.Our empirical approach aims at replicating an experimental

design using the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as an experiment inwhichwe control for observed and unobserved firm heteroge-neity via the difference-in-differences estimator. To implementthis experiment, we use two sets of firms: one that wasaffected by SOX (treatment group) and another group thatwas not affected by SOX (control group). To reduce theconcerns about selection bias, we match firms under SOXrequirements (treatment), with control firms that were notsubject to the new regulation.Our main results show that the firms affected by the

Sarbanes-Oxley Act increased their total credit–assets ratioby approximately 15 percent more than similar firms thatwere not affected by SOX. This increase was driven by long-term and private credit. Also, we found a significant reductionin the interest rate charged to firms. This improvement interms of credit (increase in amount and reduction in price) isconsistent with an increase in the supply of credit, which isconsistent with an expected reduction in moral hazard costsdue to the gains in corporate governance.The results also show an increase in long-maturity loans in

the post-SOX year, which corroborates other findings in thepaper that indicate that SOX led to debt with longer maturity.Since borrowers’ financial health could change significantlyover a long period, this result suggests that improved

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

Page 18: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

18 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

governance allowed private lenders to take on riskier debtcontracts. With improvements in firms’ governance schemes,the risk of default declined (see Proposition 4), which explainsboth the shift in the supply curve of debt and the shift of debtfrom short term to long term.In addition to the main results for SOX, we tested the ef-

fect of cash holdings on firms’ debt and the heterogeneouseffect of SOX for different levels of monitoring costs, asstated in the theoretical model. The only heterogeneitycame from the source of credit. Companies with lower levelsof cash holdings (our proxy for probability of solvency) andmonitoring benefited more from public and private loans, re-spectively. Our results contribute to the literature in threeways. First, we study effects of governance on the relation be-tween managers and creditors; second, we evidence benefitsof improvements in corporate governance schemes on firms’terms of credit in a relevant emerging economy; finally, ourempirical strategy allows us to analyze the effect of changesin corporate governance levels on firms’ debt policies con-sidering a more appropriate design to deal with endogeneityproblems.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

Wewould like to thank Daniel Gottlieb, Moshe Cohen, NelsonCamanho, Vinícius Carrasco, Fabio Moraes, Ricardo Leal andFernando Galdi for helpful comments, alongwith seminar par-ticipants of the 2011 Brazilian Meeting of Economics, the 2012European Meeting of the Econometric Society in Malaga, andthe 2012 Brazilian Meeting of Finance. We are also indebtedto both anonymous referees and the associate editor ChrisFlorackis, whose comments greatly contributed to strengthenthis paper. Bruno Funchal acknowledges financial supportfrom CNPq (National Council for Scientific and TechnologicalDevelopment) and FAPES (Espírito Santo Foundation for Re-search Support).

NOTES

1. See, for example, “After 10 Years, Corporate Oversight Is StillDismal” (The New York Times, January 26, 2003).

2. See, for example, “After High-Profile Corporate Busts, GovernanceConsulting Booms” (The Washington Post, December 27, 2002).

3. According to JP Morgan (www.adr.com), in July 2008 Brazil wasamong the top three countries with firms cross-listed the US, justbehind the UK and Japan.

4. Intuitively, better corporate governance schemes decrease informa-tion asymmetry, alleviating themoral hazard problem and improv-ing the terms of credit. On the other hand, debt can work as adisciplinary mechanism, inducing managers to better allocate freecash flows, increase self-effort, etc. (see Jensen & Meckling, 1976;Zwiebel, 1995; Innes, 1990; Aghion and Bolton, 1992)

5. We chose a sample in which none of the cross-listed firmsdelisted in the post-SOX period. Brazilian firms have this feature.

6. According to theWorld BankWDI database, Brazil has been one ofthe leading countries in interest rate spreadduring the last 10 years.

7. According toDurnev andKim (2005, only Colombia ranks aboveBrazil in terms of legal enforcement.

8. All the values refer to the 1997--2002 period. Source: World De-velopment Indicators (2004).

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

9. The assumption ofmangers’ risk neutrality helps to derive a sim-ple solution without loss of generality.

10. To check robustness we also did the matching with two matchesper observation. The results remain the same.

11. See Leal and Carvalhal-da-Silva (2007.12. The measure of disclosure and board composition and function-

ing are results of binary answers -- 0 for bad or 1 for good – for 12attributes. Both dimensions of governance, disclosure and boardcomposition and functioning, have six attributes. The higher thescore, the better is the company governance. The variable wasconstructed using public sources related to all Brazilian publiccompanies. See Table 1 in Leal and Carvalhal-da-Silva (2007 formore details.

13. More than 90 percent of all contracts are indexed by CDI, Selic,TJLP, IGP-M, and Libor.

14. Ex-ante real interest rate is deflated by the expected inflation atthe moment of debt issuance.

15. Information on Brazilian firms that are traded on NYSE andNASDAQ is obtained from www.adr.com.

REFERENCES

Abadie, A. & Imbens, G. 2006. Large sample properties of matchingestimators for average treatment effects, Econometrica, 74: 235–67.

Abadie, A. & Imbens, G. 2011. Biased-corrected matching estimatorsfor average treatment effect, Journal of Business Economics andStatistics, 29: 12–6.

Acharya, V., Almeida, H., & Campello, M. 2007. Is cash negativedebt? A hedging perspective on corporate financial policies, Jour-nal of Financial Intermediation, 16: 515–54.

Acharya, V., Davydenko, S., & Strebulaev, I. 2012. Cash holdings andcredit risk, The Review of Financial Studies, 25: 3572–609.

Aghion, P., Angeletos, G., Banerjee, A., &Manova, K. 2005.Volatilityand growth: Credit constraints and productivity-enhancing in-vestment. NBER working paper no. 11349.

Aghion, P. & Bolton, P. 1992. An incomplete contracts approach to fi-nancial contracting, Review of Economic Studies, 59: 473–494.

Anderson, R., Mansi, S., & Reeb, D. 2004. Board characteristics, ac-counting report integrity, and the cost of debt, Journal of Account-ing and Economics, 37: 315–42.

Andrade, S., Bernille, G., & Hood, F. M., III. 2014. SOX, corporatetransparency and the cost of debt, Journal of Banking & Finance,38: 145–65.

Araujo, A., Ferreira, R., & Funchal, B. 2012. The Brazilian bankruptcylaw experience, Journal of Corporate Finance, 18: 994–1004.

Araujo, A. & Funchal, B. 2005. Bankruptcy law in Latin America: pastand future, Journal Economia – The Journal of the Latin Americanand Caribbean Economic Association, 6(1): 146–216.

Armstrong, C., Guay, W., & Weber, J. 2010. The role of informationand financial reporting in corporate governance and contracting,Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50: 179–234.

Barath, S., Pasquariello, P., &Wu, G. 2009. Does asymmetric informationdrive capital structure decisions? The Review of Financial Studies, 22:3212–43.

Berger, P. G., Feng, L., & Wong, M. H. F. 2005. The impact ofSarbanes-Oxley on cross-listed companies. Working Paper,University of Chicago Graduate School of Business.

Berle, A. & Means, G. 1932. The modern corporation and privateproperty. New York: Macmillan.

Berlin, M. & Loeys, J. 1988. Bond covenants and delegatedmonitoring,The Journal of Finance, 43: 397–412.

Biddle, G. & Hilary, G. 2006. Accounting quality and firm-levelcapital investment, The Accounting Review, 81: 963–82.

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

Page 19: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

Arkansas.

19CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CREDITACCESS

Carter, K. 2013. Capital structure, earnings management, andSarbanes-Oxley: Evidence fromCanadian andU.S. firms,Account-ing Horizons, 27: 301–18.

Coates, J. C. 2007. The goals and promise of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act,Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21: 91–116.

Coelho, C., de Mello, J. M., & Funchal, B. 2012. The Brazilian payrolllending experiment,Review of Economics and Statistics, 94: 925–34.

Costello, A. &Wittenberg-Moerman, R. 2011. The impact of financialreporting quality on debt contracting: Evidence from internal con-trol weakness reports, Journal of Accounting Research, 49: 97–136.

Cremers, K. J., Nair, V., &Wei, C. 2007. Governance mechanisms andbond prices, The Review of Financial Studies, 20: 1358–88.

Demsetz, H. 1983. The structure of ownership and the theory of thefirm, Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 375–90.

Demsetz, H. & Lehn, K. 1985. The structure of corporate ownership:Causes and consequences, Journal of Political Economy, 93: 1155–77.

Dhaliwal, D., Hogan, C., Trezevant, R., & Wilkins, M. 2011. Internalcontrol disclosures, monitoring, and the cost of debt, The Account-ing Review, 86: 1131–56.

Diamond, D. W. 1991. Monitoring and reputation: The choice be-tween bank loans and directly placed debt, Journal of PoliticalEconomy, 99: 689–721.

Diamond, D. W. 2004. Committing to commit: Short-term debt whenenforcement is costly, The Journal of Finance, 59: 1447–79.

Diamond, D. W. & Verrecchia, R. 1991. Disclosure, liquidity and thecost of capital, The Journal of Finance, 46: 1325–59.

Djankov, S., McLiesh, C., & Shleifer, A. 2007. Private credit in 129countries, Journal Financial Economics, 84: 299–329.

Durnev, A. &Kim, E. H. 2005. To steal or not to steal: Firm attributes, le-gal environment, and valuation, The Journal of Finance, 60: 1461–93.

Eldridge, S. W. & Kealey, B. T. 2005. SOX costs: Auditor attestationunder Section 404. Working Paper, University of Nebraska.

Engel, E., Hayes, R., & Wang, X. 2007. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act andfirms’ going-private decisions, Journal of Accounting and Econom-ics, 44: 116–45.

Fama, E. 1980. Agency problems and the theory of the firm, Journalof Political Economy, 88: 288–307.

Holmstrom, B. & Kaplan, S. N. 2003. The state of U.S. Corporate gov-ernance: What’s right and what’s wrong? Journal of Applied Cor-porate Finance, 15: 8–20.

Hostak, P., Karaoglu, E., Lys, T., & Yang, Y. 2013. An examination of theimpact of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act on the attractiveness of US capitalmarkets for foreign firms, Review of Accounting Studies, 18: 522–59.

Innes, R. 1990. Limited liabilities and incentive contracting with exante action choices, Journal of Economic Theory, 52: 45–67.

Jensen, M. & Meckling, W. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial be-havior, agency cost and ownership structure, Journal of FinancialEconomics, 3: 305–60.

Kamar, E., Karaca-Mandic, P., & Talley, E. 2005. Going-private deci-sions and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002: A crosscountry analy-sis. Public Law Research Paper no. 901769, University of Berkeley.

King, R. & Levine, R. 1993. Finance and growth: Schumpeter mightbe right, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108: 717–37.

la Porta, R., Lopez-de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., &Vishny, R.W. 1997. Le-gal determinants of external finance, The Journal of Finance, 52:1131–50.

la Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. 1998.Law and finance, Journal of Political Economy, 106: 1113–55.

Leal, R. & Carvalhal-da-Silva, A. L. 2007. Corporate governance andvalue in Brazil (and in Chile). In A. Chong and F. Lopez-de-Silanes(Eds.), Investor protection and corporate governance – Firm-levelevidence across Latin America: 213–287. Stanford, CA: StanfordUniversity Press.

Leland, H. & Pyle, D.. 1977. Informational asymmetries, financial struc-ture and financial intermediation, The Journal of Finance, 32: 371–87.

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

Leuz, C. 2007. Was the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 really this costly?A discussion of evidence from event returns and going-private de-cisions, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 44: 146–65.

Leuz, C., Triantis, A. J., & Wang, T. Y. 2008. Why do firms go dark?Causes and economic consequences of voluntary SECderegistrations,Journal of Accounting and Economics, 45: 181–208.

Levine, R., Loyaza, N., & Beck, T. 2000. Financial intermediation andgrowth: Causality and causes, Journal of Monetary Economics, 46:31–77.

Li, H., Pincus, M., & Rego, S. O. 2008. Market reaction to eventssurrounding the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, Journal of Law andEconomics, 51: 111–34.

Litvak, K. 2007. The effect of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act on non-UScompanies cross-listed in the US, Journal of Corporate Fi-nance, 13: 195–228.

Marosi, A. & Massoud, N. 2008. “You can enter but you cannotleave…”: U.S. security markets and foreign firms, The JournalFinance, 63: 2477–506.

Musso, P. & Schiavo, S. 2008. The impact of financial constraints onfirm survival and growth, Journal of Evolutionary Economics,18: 135–49.

Myers, S. 1977. Determinants of corporate debt policies, Journal ofFinancial Economics, 5: 147–75.

Piotroski, P. & Srinivasan, S. 2008. Regulation and bonding: TheSarbanes-Oxley Act and the flow of international listings, Journalof Accounting Research, 46: 383–425.

Qiu, G. & Yiu, F. 2009. The market for corporate control and the costof debt, Journal of Financial Economics, 93: 505–24.

Smith, G. P. 2007. A look at the impact of Sarbanes-Oxley on cross-listed firms. Working paper, Arizona State University West.

Sneller, L. & Langendijk, H. 2007. Sarbanes Oxley Section 404 costs ofcompliance: A case study, Corporate Governance: An Interna-tional Review, 15: 101–11.

Zhang, I. X. 2007. Economic consequences of the Sarbanes-Oxley Actof 2002, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 44: 74–115.

Zingales, L. 1994. The value of the voting right: A study of the MilanStock Exchange experience, The Review of Financial Studies, 7:125–48.

Zwiebel, J. 1995. Block investment and partial benefits of corporatecontrol, Review of Economic Studies, LXII: 161–85.

Bruno Funchal is Professor of Economics and Finance atFUCAPE Business School. He holds a PhD in Economics fromGetúlio Vargas Foundation (2006). Hewas a Post-Doctoral fel-low at the National Institute of Pure and Applied Mathemat-ics (IMPA) and visiting researcher at Wharton School,University of Pennsylvania. His research interests cover areassuch as bankruptcy law, credit markets, corporate gover-nance, general equilibrium and applied microeconomics. Hehas published in top academic journals, such as The Reviewof Economics and Statistics, Economics Letters and Journal of Cor-porate Finance.

Danilo Monte-Mor is a professor of Econometrics andFinance at FUCAPE Business School. He received his PhD inManagement and Accounting from FUCAPE Business Schooland his MA in Economics from Federal University of EspíritoSanto. His research focuses on accounting-based valuationmodels as well as corporate governance. He was a visitingscholar at the Accounting Department of the University of

Volume •• Number •• •• 2016

Page 20: CorporateGovernanceandCreditAccessinBrazil: The Sarbanes ... · firms’ debt financing in a relevant emerging economy, taking advantage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as a natural experiment

APPENDIX: VARIABLES DESCRIPTION

Panel A: Information about firms’ debt contractsPrincipal Amount of loans, expressed in thousand Brazilian Reais.Spread Spread paid above the referred index, expressed in percent.Type of debt Type of loans: term loans, capital lease, bonds and notes, etc.Real interestrate

Firm’s debt interest rate expressed in percent. Brazil uses compounded interest rates, and becauseof this we compounded the interest rate index with the spread, deflating by the expected IGP-M forall contracts indexed by the Brazilian index. For contracts with foreign indexes, mainly Libor and CPI,we used the linear interest rates, deflating by the expected CPI.

Maturity Maturity of the bond, expressed in years.Total credit Total amount of debt, scaled by total assets.Cost of credit Cost of newly issued credit, expressed in percent and estimated as the weight-average interest rate,

where the share of the principal of each debt contract to the total amount of debt issued by the firm inthe specific year is used to define the weight of each contract in the firm average interest rate.

Panel B: Balance-sheet informationFirm size Total assets, expressed in thousand Brazilian Reais.Cash holdings Cash and short term investment, scaled by total assets.PPE Fixed assets, scaled by total assets.Accrued profit Operating earnings, scaled by total assets.Equity Book value, scaled by total assets.Panel C: Index (expressed in percent)IGP-M Brazilian inflation rateCPI US inflation rateTJLP Government subsidized rateCDI Interbank deposit certificatesLIBOR London interbank offered rateSELIC Brazilian Central Bank benchmark ratePanel D: Information about monitoring indexMonitoring Average between two indicators that proxy for board composition and disclosure. The board dimension

is based on a set of six questions that specify whether the chairman of the board and the CEO are the sameperson, if companies use committees, if the board is made up of a majority of outside directors and fit theIBGC’s (Brazilian Institute of Corporate Governance) recommended board size of five to nine members,if directors serve consecutive one-year terms, and if companies have a minority shareholder-mandatedfiscal board. The disclosure dimension is based on a set of six questions that deals with company sanctionsagainst governance, related party transactions, malpractice, auditors, compensation disclosure, andaccounting practices.

20 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

© 2015 John Wiley & Sons LtdVolume •• Number •• •• 2016