case2 supply chain risk at unilever.pdf

16
Supply Risk Management at Unilever Managing Spend at Risk 01/2009-5563 This case was written by INSEAD Professors Paul Kleindorfer and Enver Yücesan, in cooperation with the Supply Management Lead Team of Unilever Corporation. The issues raised here are purely for educational purposes and are not intended to illustrate either effective or ineffective management of an administrative situation Copyright © 2009 INSEAD N.B.: TO ORDER COPIES OF INSEAD CASES, SEE DETAILS ON BACK COVER. COPIES MAY NOT BE MADE WITHOUT PERMISSION. Probability Upper limit Annual Spend ‘08 Sept ’07 March ‘08 Probability Upper limit Annual Spend ‘08 Sept ’07 March ‘08 609-006-1 ecch the case for learning Distributed by ecch, UK and USA North America Rest of the world www.ecch.com t +1 781 239 5884 t +44 (0)1234 750903 All rights reserved f +1 781 239 5885 f +44 (0)1234 751125 Printed in UK and USA e [email protected] e [email protected]

Upload: racing-sangers

Post on 19-Nov-2015

47 views

Category:

Documents


4 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Supply Risk Management at

    Unilever

    Managing Spend at Risk

    01/2009-5563

    This case was written by INSEAD Professors Paul Kleindorfer and Enver Ycesan, in cooperation with the Supply

    Management Lead Team of Unilever Corporation. The issues raised here are purely for educational purposes and

    are not intended to illustrate either effective or ineffective management of an administrative situation

    Copyright 2009 INSEAD

    N.B.: TO ORDER COPIES OF INSEAD CASES, SEE DETAILS ON BACK COVER. COPIES MAY NOT BE MADE WITHOUT PERMISSION.

    Pro

    babi

    lity

    Upper limit

    Annual Spend 08

    Sept 07

    March 08

    Pro

    babi

    lity

    Upper limit

    Annual Spend 08

    Sept 07

    March 08

    609-006-1

    ecch the case for learningDistributed by ecch, UK and USA North America Rest of the worldwww.ecch.com t +1 781 239 5884 t +44 (0)1234 750903All rights reserved f +1 781 239 5885 f +44 (0)1234 751125Printed in UK and USA e [email protected] e [email protected]

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 1 01/2009-5563

    The Supply Management Leadership Team (SMLT) at Unilever brought together the heads of key procurement areas such as oils and fats, plastics, cocoa, and milk powder at Unilever. The SMLT was preparing for a special meeting in Zurich in a month to discuss possible changes to its risk management tactics and strategy. The mood among team members was unusually somber. In the past few months, commodity prices had defied all the laws of gravity by jumping to historically high levels. Uwe Schulte, Vice President of Global Supply Management, had asked his team to come up with innovative approaches to commodity procurement that would provide a better understanding, and perhaps some mitigation, of Unilevers exposure to the increased volatility of market prices. The presentations of the risk management proposals by the plastics team was the top agenda item for the meeting, but it was understood that every one of Unilevers major commodity purchases would be subject to a similar review over the next few months. Given the developments of the past few months, the focus was on understanding and managing the risk of large swings in procurement expenditures. How to do this without sacrificing buying performance and a dependable physical supply to Unilevers manufacturing facilities would be the centerpiece of the SMLT meeting and discussion.

    Unilever

    Unilever was a global giant in food and personal care products. Operating in 150 countries with 206,000 employees, its turnover was 39.7 billion euros in 2005. Figure 1 shows the distribution of its activities across different categories and different regions.

    Home Care

    18%

    Spreads

    11%

    Personal Care

    26%

    Savory &

    Dressings

    21%

    Ice Cream and

    Frozen Food

    16%

    Beverages

    8%

    Europe41%

    Americas33%

    Asia/Africa26%

    Figure 1: Distribution of Unilevers Activities Around the World

    Unilever had global brands such as Lipton, Knorr, Lux and Omo that were top brands in their categories, as well as locally strong brands such as Hellmanns, Birds Eye, Carte dOr and Axe. Twelve of these brands achieved annual sales volumes of more than 1 billion euros each.

    609-006-1

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 2 01/2009-5563

    In a press release1, Patrick Cescau, Unilevers CEO, laid out an ambitious agenda:

    We now need to drive harder to build a winning portfolio by extending our leadership positions and our presence in high growth spaces. At the same time, we are improving our consumer marketing and customer development to deliver outstanding execution. Bringing all this together as One Unilever will ensure that we capitalize on both our local roots and global scale. This strategy will enable us to grow ahead of our markets with sustainable margin improvement. I am confident that this will lead to sustainable underlying sales growth of 3-5% and an operating margin in excess of 15% by 2010.

    SMLT

    Unilever was organized upon three pillars: categories, regions, and functions. The Supply Management (SM) organization, which was responsible for global procurement, was part of the Supply Chain Management function. SCMs mission was to build one supply network from shelf to supplier, which leveraged Unilevers scale and delivered competitive solutions to customers and consumers. The organizational structure is depicted in Figure 2. SMLT consisted of the heads of the regions and of key spend categories such as chemicals, food ingredients, and packaging.

    Figure 2: The Supply Management Organization

    1 3 August 2006

    SMLT

    SCLT Sponsor Greg Polcer

    John Rice

    UEx Sponsor

    Globally responsible for SM on behalf of UL

    SCLT

    FOODS Category

    FINANCE Function

    HPC Category

    Reg I ons

    EUROPE

    AMERICAS

    ASIA

    AMET

    David Beauchamp/

    Guenther Buck (O&F)

    Marco Gonalves

    Umesh Shah

    Krish Maharaj

    6 global teams

    7 global teams

    6 global teams

    3 global CoPs

    PACKNET Uwe G Schulte

    VP Packaging Network VP Global SM

    NPI Peter Pick

    VP NPI

    CHEMNET INGNET Henk Sijbring

    VP Chemicals Network/ HPC Category Contact

    Jan-Jelle vd Meer Dir Ingredients Network Foods

    609-006-1

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 3 01/2009-5563

    SM had several guiding principles. With respect to the supply base, it strived to achieve competitive costs, be the innovation partner of choice and a professional business partner. With respect to the downstream supply chain, SM aimed at delivering superior customer service. Under Uwe Schultes leadership, the SMLT also considered efficient risk management part of its mandate, and the new initiative on managing market risk for major commodity groups was a central aspect of this element of SMLTs responsibilities.

    Commodity Characteristics

    SM purchased a wide range of commodities, including food ingredients (such as sugar, powdered milk, cocoa, wheat, and various oils and fats); chemical products (such as lab, caustic soda, and alcohol sulphates); packaging materials (such as plastics, aluminum, and corrugated cardboard); as well as energy (such as electricity and natural gas). The total annual spend under SMs responsibility was several billion euros but the profit consequences of a dependable supply at predictable prices clearly went well beyond the direct impact of its annual spend. Indeed, the sharp rise (Figure 3) and increased volatility (Figure 4) in commodity prices had drawn a lot of attention to SMs activities and further heightened the pressure to improve profitability following a few disappointing quarters for all the major companies in the food industry and the resulting stock market reactions. In the context of this dual pressure, SMLT decided to evaluate alternative risk mitigation strategies for its sizeable commodity procurement business.

    Figure 3: Year-on-Year Change in Commodity Procurement (constant volumes)

    -800

    -600

    -400

    -200

    0

    200

    400

    600

    1999

    2000

    2001

    2002

    2003

    2004

    2005

    2006m

    n

    609-006-1

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 4 01/2009-5563

    Figure 4: Increased Volatility in Commodity Prices

    Risk Management Options

    As a pilot project, SMLT decided to begin with plastics to understand what benefits risk management innovations could provide. As with most major commodities, parallel financial markets were well developed for plastic resins and the recent price volatility had created heightened awareness of the need to limit exposure. Table 1 summarizes some recent market movements in key spend items for selected commodities under SMs responsibility.

    Table 1: Market Characteristics of Selected Commodities

    -40%

    -20%

    0%

    20%

    40%

    60%

    80%

    1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

    Tallow

    Dairy EU

    Dairy NA

    Alkoxylated

    Resins

    LAB/LAS

    O&F

    Cluster

    Maximum historic

    annual price volatility

    Parallel Financial market? Tools available

    Natural Gas EU 30% Limited OTC SwapsDairy ingredients EU 25% NoCocoa 30% LME, OTC Futures + OptionsDairy NA 30% CME, limited Futures+OptionsPAS/AE/LES 25% NoPlastics 25% LME (limited) + OTC Futures + SwapsLAB/LAS 60% OTC SwapsOils & Fats 25% CBOT + OTC Futures

    609-006-1

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 5 01/2009-5563

    Plastics

    Plastics for containers come in many sizes and grades, but the underlying chemical components remain the same, with the basic chemicals (referred to as resins) being high-density polyethylene (HDPE), polypropylene (PP) and polyethylene terephthalate (PET). While SM did not purchase these resins directly, its suppliers of plastic containers did, and they passed on the cost of these resins to SM via the price of the plastic containers it purchased. SM was a major consumer of plastic bottles and lids to package Unilevers products, spending around 400 million euros on plastics in 2006. Price volatility peaked at 25% within the year.

    In spite of a complex supply chain, as depicted in Figure 5, plastics were highly commoditized. As a key commodity, the global over-the-counter plastics trade was quite transparent with well developed parallel financial markets since the price of both PP and HDPE was highly correlated with the price of their raw materials, namely crude oil and natural gas. This suggested that hedging instruments for plastics spend could be either directly in HDPE, PP or PET, or through positions in the underlying raw materials of crude oil and natural gas.

    SM purchased bottles and lids from dedicated suppliers in each of its major sales regions. Bottle blowers closely followed crude oil prices and resulting resin prices before adding their own margins on the product. Due to product volumes, shipping was also quite expensive. SMs strategy for this category was to achieve price stability. Unfortunately, market forecasts were far from accurate. This, in turn, triggered SMs interest in pursuing parallel risk management opportunities, both as a possible source of risk hedging as well as to improve the quality of the information underlying SMs decisions regarding sourcing and contracting for plastics.

    Figure 5: Overlapping HDPE, PP, and PET Supply Chains

    PP and HDPE Chains Overlap

    Ethylene

    Aromatics PTA/DMT

    Naphtha (1t) PP

    Others: L(L)DPE/PVC/MEG/PET

    (polyester) fiber/PETGasoline additives +

    others

    Ethane HDPE20%Natural

    Gas

    Crude oil

    Transport/ fuel

    Propylene

    80%

    Methane95%

    95%

    Reds show competing markets for feedstock use

    Various markets outside the resin market affect resin prices. Crude oil (energy and transportation) is the most prominent affecting both PP and HDPE.

    60%

    0.32t

    0.16t

    0.10t

    609-006-1

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 6 01/2009-5563

    Figure 6 shows the structure and complexity of SMs plastics hedging problem. For a specific region, the problem begins with aggregate end product demand for different bottles and containers, as determined by Unilevers market forecast. These, in turn, imply ex ante demand for different resins (HDPE, PP, PET) in the periods t = 1, , T (think of these as quarters). The basic question confronting the SMLT in terms of hedging strategies was whether to take positions (i.e., buy swaps and other derivative instruments from brokers or directly on the London LIFFE or other exchanges) in crude oil (an indirect hedge) or in the resins themselves. At this juncture SMLT was not interested in changing its physical sourcing of plastics from its direct plastics manufacturers, but only in understanding the cost and value of various hedging strategies.

    Figure 6: Demand for Plastic Bottles

    As an example, Table 2 summarizes demand and mean prices for three demand regions (NE, SE and West) in the North American market for HDPE for the four quarters of 2006 (as forecast at the beginning of 2006). The standard deviation of HDPE demand in each quarter was expected to be about 10% and the standard deviation of the price was expected to be about 25% of mean price, with strong correlation of prices across regional suppliers. During 2006, based on futures contracts trading on 1/1/06, the average price for Brent crude oil was expected to be $65.32 per barrel (with a standard quarterly deviation of $6.17). For the same period, the correlation between crude oil prices and that of resins was around 0.65.

    D1t D2t Dmt .

    HDPEt

    PETt

    PPt

    Crude

    Oil Price

    Market

    Traded Resins

    Final Product

    Demands

    Correlations Correlations

    Resin

    Demands

    609-006-1

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 7 01/2009-5563

    Quarter 1 Quarter 2 Quarter 3 Quarter 4

    Demand-NE 15,557 16,159 14,532 16,858

    Demand-SE 16,550 16,734 14,985 15,485

    Demand-We 19,150 17,810 18,283 18,895

    Price-NE 1,211 1,304 1,405 1,626

    Price-SE 1,309 1,341 1,521 1,517

    Price-We 1,119 1,260 1,378 1,578

    Table 2: 2006 Demand Volumes (metric tons) & Prices ($/ton) Over 4 Quarters

    The challenge for the SMLT was clear enough: Should they engage in risk hedging activity for their plastics resins, possibly including taking positions in crude oil? The analysis presented by the Plastics Team (see Exhibit 2) seemed to suggest that even a small portion of about 1% of total spend on HDPE could lead to significant reductions in maximum expenditures on HDPE in North America (and, by extension, to other plastics resins and other regional markets).

    But there were a number of central issues yet to consider. Was this financial approach to hedging cash flows the right approach for the Unilever Supply Management group? Should the same approach be extended to other resins and, if so, with what benefits? Should the SMLT be the one to implement this approach or should it be done by Unilever Treasury? What controls should be put in place to make sure that the hedging that was done was limited to the specific purpose of improving SMs performance, and not for speculative purposes? What benefits, if any, would information provided by this hedging strategy bring to improving buying performance and contracting with respect to ULs plastics purchases?

    As Uwe Schulte went through the materials for the coming SMLT meeting, he couldnt help but think this was a whole new game as far as supply management was concerned.

    609-006-1

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 8 01/2009-5563

    Appendix 1

    Risk Mitigation Instruments and Supply Portfolios2

    Call and Put Options

    A call option gives the holder the right, but not the obligation, to buy the spot asset on or

    a before a predetermined date (the maturity date) at a certain price (the strike price),

    which is agreed today. Call options come in various flavors. For instance, in American

    options, execution is allowed from a given execution/start date through any time up to

    and including the expiration date. By contrast, a European option can only be exercised

    on the maturity date itself. Figure 8 illustrates the potential payoff from a European call

    option.

    A put option is similarly defined as giving the holder the right, but not the obligation, to

    sell the spot asset on or before the maturity date at the strike price.

    Figure 8: Payoff of a European Option

    SWAPS

    A swap is an agreement whereby a floating (market or spot) price is exchanged for a fixed price over a specified period. A swap buyer pays the fixed leg and receives the floating leg. A swap seller pays the floating leg and receives the fixed leg. Swaps are financial agreements but they essentially assure (for the contracted volume of the swap) that the swap buyer will pay the exact price of the swap for the commodity in question. The effectiveness of swaps is summarized in Figure 9.

    2 For further details on available instruments and risk management strategies, see Aswath Damodaran,

    Strategic Risk Taking, Wharton School Publishing, 2008.

    -

    -

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    12

    0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20Terminal Price

    Pay

    Pro

    Stri

    Price of the Option

    Payoff/Profit

    Probability of

    Terminal Price

    609-006-1

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 9 01/2009-5563

    Figure 9: Using Financial Swaps for Risk Hedging

    The Supply Portfolio Problem

    The central question to be addressed in supply portfolio management (for example for HDPE for ULs North American market) is what mix of supply contracts, options contracts and swaps will provide assured physical supply of needed inputs for its production, together with appropriate financial hedges for the associated cash expenditures for these inputs. Physical supplies can come either from pre-qualified sellers or directly from various spot markets. In supply management for commodities, different grades and specifications for commodities often require prior contracting and procurement relations with pre-qualified suppliers. These alternative situations give rise to various forms of commodity risk management, as shown in Table 3 below.

    UL Spend

    for Plastic

    Resins

    Floating Index

    e.g., for

    Crude Oil

    Crude Oil Swap at Price Ps

    This crude oil Swap gives rise to basis risk as an imperfect hedge against plastic resin price fluctuations

    This Swap is a complete hedge against crude oil price fluctuations

    Suppose

    there is

    correlation

    609-006-1

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 10 01/2009-5563

    Description of Context Instruments used in Optimal Portfolio

    Examples

    Cost and access differences small and only standard commodities are sourced

    Bilateral contracting and financial hedge instruments are defined on a common market and optimized jointly

    Energy

    Commodity metals

    Cost and access differences are large and only standard commodities are sourced

    Bilateral contracting used for most physical procurement, with spot market used for topping up supply, and for financial hedge instruments

    Logistics services (standard air and maritime cargo)

    Fed-cattle (beef), hogs and lamb markets

    Non-standard commodities are sourced, but their prices are highly correlated with those of standard commodities

    Bilateral contracting used for all physical procurement, with financial hedge instruments, defined on correlated standard products, used as an overlay for hedging

    Plastic resins and commodity chemicals

    Table 3: Alternative Contexts for Commodity Risk Management of Supply

    The standard problem of commodity sourcing and hedging for a large buyer like UL can be stated as maximizing expected profits, subject to physical delivery constraints and some risk constraints. The general structure of the Supply Portfolio Problem (SPP) is as follows:

    Supply Portfolio Problem (SPP)

    Maximize Expected Profits (where the decision choices are the amounts to contract for from each available physical and financial contract)

    Subject to:

    Physical delivery constraints (to assure delivery of needed inputs)

    Financial risk constraints (on maximum exposures or on allowable losses from financial instruments used for hedging)

    Constraints defining the instruments themselves (puts, calls, swaps, contract parameters such as minimum take provisions and flexibility bands, etc.)

    609-006-1

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 11 01/2009-5563

    This optimization problem is not solved once and for all but on a continuing basis. At the same time, demand uncertainties are resolved, as well as spot prices and contract prices. To the extent that contracts allow flexibility in execution (e.g., call or put options), these are executed to optimize profits on the day by executing all options that are in the money or needed for physical fulfillment. This problem on the day can sometimes be interesting, but in theory it is straightforward and solved by some computer-based algorithm that picks the best options on the day to execute for both physical coverage and financial return. The more interesting problem, which requires both judgment and computer support, is the medium to long-term, on-going Supply Portfolio Problem (SPP). Various forms of the SPP have been developed for various types of markets, and the details of these differ considerably across these markets. Except in very simple cases, the solution to the SPP must be accomplished using Monte Carlo simulation (together with a simulation optimization engine). We illustrate this below for the plastics problem for UL North America.

    609-006-1

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 12 01/2009-5563

    Appendix 2

    The Initial Risk Management Plan for Plastics

    Jan-Jelle Van der Meer, responsible for procurement of food ingredients for the SMLT, had taken a strong interest in the commodities risk management project and Uwe Schulte had charged him to guide the initial effort on plastics. Van der Meer had a doctorate in chemical engineering and over several months of preparatory work had overseen the development of an analytic framework to guide the Plastics Team. The resulting framework entailed the following analysis process:

    Start with product and market structure and determine the pattern of procurement and correlated markets that could provide risk management hedges.

    Analyze historical data to obtain relevant random variables (demand, price, and correlations) and the associated predicted Spend (total expenses for sourcing and delivering the relevant quantities to production sites).

    For a given pattern of procurement choices, which gives rise to the unhedged probability distribution of Spend, analyze risk management overlays that could (at a cost) reduce right tail spend-at-risk (SaR) exposure.

    Determine the efficient frontier that trades off increased total Spend against decreased right hand tail exposure or SaR.

    As an example of this process, the Plastics Team presented their results for ULs North American expenditures on HDPE. The team used 2006 market data throughout, but they assumed they were at the beginning of 2006 and planning a procurement strategy for that year. Alternative portfolios were evaluated in terms of the total expected spend on HDPE, including the cost of any hedge instruments used. Also of interest were exceedance probabilities for various upper limits (or targets) on total annual spend for HDPE-NA.

    A simple simulation in Crystal Ball was constructed to evaluate various risk hedging strategies for the NA HDPE spend. Below are the results for the fourth quarter of 2006, based on the mean values of price and demand quantities at the beginning of 2006. Table 4 shows the assumptions underlying the simulation (all distributions were tested and found to be well approximated by the log-normal distribution). Table 5 shows the results of using just HDPE call options and Table 6 shows the results of using HDPE call options plus Brent crude oil swaps in the indicated amounts. In each case, both the hedged and unhedged (expected value of) Spend are shown. The unhedged value is simply in the cash outlay for HDPE by UL in the market. The Hedged Spend is this cash outlay for procurement adjusted by the cashflows (positive or negative) resulting from the hedge instruments purchased. A number of other combinations of calls and swaps could also be considered, but these two examples illustrate the general consequences of hedging in this case, which can be summarized as follows.

    Hedging costs money: The expected value of Spend will be greater than if one did not buy hedging instruments because (on average) no financial broker or investor will take the other side of these market instruments without some expectation of profit. Note, for example, in Table 5 below, that the expected cost of the HDPE call options is $360,000. Of course, the large standard deviation of the value of these call options also tells us that they are in the

    609-006-1

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 13 01/2009-5563

    money some of the time (and given their structure, we know that this occurs when the price of HDPE is high and therefore these options help to offset high HDPE prices).

    Hedging cuts off the right hand tail of the spend distribution: Both the standard deviation and the probability that (Spend + Hedging Costs) exceeds a given target threshold will decrease as hedge instruments are purchased. This is, of course, the primary purpose of hedging. Note, for example, in Table 5, that the HDPE call options reduce the probability of exceeding the target spend figure of $100 million from 0.093 to 0.076. They also reduce the probability of exceeding the target spend figure of $110 million from .013 to .006. There are further reductions in the furthest extremes of the spend distribution since it is precisely for these values that the HDPE call options are clearly in the money. (To see these reductions in the extremes, check the distribution of Spend versus Hedged Spend in the Crystal Ball output.)

    The effectiveness of swaps depends on their correlation with the underlying spend: For example, the assumption of 0.65 correlation (not that high!) between crude oil and NA HDPE prices means that crude oil swaps are not that good a hedge for HDPE price volatility in the present case. Indeed it is clear that the crude oil swap hedge here is actually less effective than the HDPE call options alone in reducing the right hand tail of the HDPE Spend distribution (compare 0.76 vs. 0.78 in Tables 4-5 in reducing the exceedance probability for a Target of $100 MM), primarily because these swap options are too expensive relative to their risk hedging benefits (note that buying 50,000 swaps at the indicated swap price has an expected cost of $220,000). Of course, if a more attractive swap price were available, then such swaps could play a role in an efficient hedging strategyhere they clearly do not.

    Mean Std Deviation

    UL Demand for NA HDPE Qtr 4 55,000.00 4,400.00

    Crude Oil Price/Barrel Oct 1 $68.00 $6.00

    HDPE Price ($/ton) Oct 1 $1,594.00 $106.00

    Correlation of Crude with HDPE 0.65

    HDPE Option Price/Ton Oct 1 Calls $28.25

    HDPE Execution Price/Ton Oct 1 Calls $1,650.00

    Crude Oil Futures/Swaps ($/Barrel) $72.50

    Table 4: Assumptions on 4th Quarter HDPE Spend Calculation for UL NA

    609-006-1

  • Copyright 2009 INSEAD 14 01/2009-5563

    Mean Std Dev

    Unhedged Quarterly Spend ($ Million) 87.74 9.23

    Hedged Quarterly Spend ($ Million) 88.10 8.24

    Value of Crude Oil Swaps ($ Million) 0.00 0.00

    Value of HDPE Call Options ($ Million) -0.36 2.25

    Prob{Unhedged Spend > $100 Million} 0.093

    Prob{Hedged Spend > $100 Million} 0.076

    Prob{Unhedged Spend > $110 Million} 0.013

    Prob{Hedged Spend > $110 Million} 0.006

    Table 5: UL HDPE NA 4th Quarter 2006 Spend (as predicted on 1/1/2006) Hedging

    Strategy: 50,000 Call Options in HDPE CMAI NA Spot Underlying

    (Prices per Table 4)

    Mean Std Dev

    Unhedged Quarterly Spend ($ Million) 87.74 9.23

    Hedged Quarterly Spend ($ Million) 88.32 8.25

    Value of Crude Oil Swaps ($ Million) -0.22 0.30

    Value of HDPE Call Options ($ Million) -0.36 2.25

    Prob{Unhedged Spend > $100 Million} 0.093

    Prob{Hedged Spend > $100 Million} 0.078

    Prob{Unhedged Spend > $110 Million} 0.013

    Prob{Hedged Spend > $110 Million} 0.006

    Table 6: UL HDPE NA 4th Quarter 2006 Spend (as predicted on 1/1/2006) Hedging

    Strategy: 50,000 Call Options in HDPE CMAI NA Spot Underlying and 50,000 Crude

    Oil Swaps on NYFE (Prices per Table 4)

    609-006-1

  • To order INSEAD case studies please contact one of the three distributors below:

    ecch, UK and USA Centrale de Cas et de Mdias Pdagogiques

    ecch UK Registered Office: ecch USA Registered Office: www.ecch.com www.ecch.com www.ccmp-publishing.com Tel: +44 (0)1234 750903 Tel: +1 781 239 5884 Tel: 33 (0) 1.49.23.57.25 Fax: +44 (0)1234 751125 Fax: +1 781 239 5885 Fax: 33 (0) 1.49.23.57.41 E-mail: [email protected] E-mail: [email protected] E-mail: [email protected]

    Boulevard de Constance, 77305 Fontainebleau Cedex, France. 1 Ayer Rajah Avenue, Singapore 138676 Tel: 33 (0)1 60 72 40 00 Fax: 33 (0)1 60 74 55 00/01 www.insead.edu Tel: 65 6799 5388 Fax: 65 6799 5399 Printed by INSEAD

    609-006-1