assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 correct citation: börner j, wunder s,...

42
Working Paper REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian Amazon Assessing costs and livelihood implications Working Paper No. 8 Jan Börner Sven Wunder Sheila Wertz-Kanounnikoff Glenn Hyman Nathália Nascimento

Upload: others

Post on 01-Aug-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

Wor

king

Pape

r

REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian Amazon Assessing costs and livelihood implications

Working Paper No. 8

Jan BörnerSven WunderSheila Wertz-KanounnikoffGlenn HymanNathália Nascimento

Page 2: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

1

REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian Amazon Assessing costs and livelihood implications Working Paper No. 8 CGIAR Research Program on Climate Change, Agriculture and Food Security (CCAFS) Jan Börner Sven Wunder Sheila Wertz-Kanounnikoff Glenn Hyman Nathália Nascimento

Page 3: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

2

Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian Amazon: Assessing costs and livelihood implications. CCAFS Working Paper no. 8. CGIAR Research Program on Climate Change, Agriculture and Food Security (CCAFS). Copenhagen, Denmark. Available online at: www.ccafs.cgiar.org Titles in this Working Paper series aim to disseminate interim climate change, agriculture and food security research and practices and stimulate feedback from the scientific community. Published by the CGIAR Research Program on Climate Change, Agriculture and Food Security (CCAFS). CCAFS Coordinating Unit - Department of Agriculture and Ecology, Faculty of Life Sciences, University of Copenhagen, Rolighedsvej 21, DK-1958 Frederiksberg C, Denmark. Tel: +45 35331046; Email: [email protected] Creative Commons License

This Working Paper is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution – NonCommercial–NoDerivs 3.0 Unported License. Articles appearing in this publication may be freely quoted and reproduced provided the source is acknowledged. No use of this publication may be made for resale or other commercial purposes. © 2011 CGIAR Research Program on Climate Change, Agriculture and Food Security (CCAFS) 2011 CCAFS Working Paper no. 8 The CGIAR Research Program on Climate Change, Agriculture and Food Security (CCAFS) is a strategic partnership of the CGIAR and the Earth System Science Partnership (ESSP). CGIAR is a global research partnership for a food secure future. The program is supported by the Canadian International Development Agency (CIDA), the Danish International Development Agency (DANIDA), the European Union (EU), and the CGIAR Fund, with technical support from the International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD). The views expressed in this document cannot be taken to reflect the official opinions of these agencies, nor the official position of the CGIAR or ESSP. DISCLAIMER: This Working Paper has been prepared as an output for the Pro-Poor Mitigation Theme under the CCAFS program and has not been peer reviewed. This analysis was conducted as part of the Global Comparative Study on REDD, led by the Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR). We gratefully acknowledge the support received from the Norwegian Agency for Development Cooperation, the Australian Agency for International Development, the UK Department for International Development, the European Commission, the Department for International Development Cooperation of Finland, the David and Lucile Packard Foundation, and the Program on Forests. All images remain the sole property of their source and may not be used for any purpose without written permission of the source. The geographic designation employed and the presentation of material in this publication do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of CCAFS concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area or its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries.

Page 4: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

3

Other Related CCAFS Working Papers

This paper was produced in collaboration with Arun Agrawal and Lauren Persha at the University of Michigan for the project Governing Mitigation Trade-offs in Agriculture-Forestry Landscapes. See other related titles: CCAFS Working Paper no. 7. Robinson BE, Holland MB, Naughton-Treves L. 2011. Does secure land tenure save forests? A review of the relationship between land tenure and tropical deforestation. CCAFS Working Paper no. 9. Fox J, Castella J-C, Ziegler AD. 2011. Swidden, Rubber and Carbon: Can REDD+ work for people and the environment in Montane Mainland Southeast Asia? CCAFS Working Paper no. 10. Barbier EB and Tesfaw AT. 2011. Overcoming tenurial constraints to carbon forestry projects in Africa. CCAFS Working Paper no. 11. Cohn A, Bowman M, Zilberman D, O’Neill K. 2011. The Viability of Cattle Ranching Intensification in Brazil as a Strategy to Spare Land and Mitigate Greenhouse Gas Emissions. All papers available online at: www.ccafs.cgiar.org

Page 5: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

4

Abstract

Despite recent reductions, Brazil remains among the top deforesting countries in the world,

and is thus one of the countries where ‘Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Forest

Degradation’ (REDD) initiatives could potentially have the most tangible returns for climate-

change mitigation. Economic incentives, such as payments for environmental services (PES)

represent one option to induce forestland stewards under appropriate property right regimes to

conserve more forests. Yet, for the large part of Amazon deforestation that occurs on non-

designated public lands (terra devoluta) as well as on poorly delimited private land, PES will

not be viable in the short and medium term. REDD will thus also require other tools, notably

improved command-and-control disincentives that enforce existing forest laws more

rigorously. While quite a number of studies have addressed the potential costs of using PES

as a REDD vehicle, cost estimates of control-based REDD strategies are speculative at best.

In this study, we develop a conceptual framework and a spatially explicit model to analyse

regulatory enforcement in the context of the Brazilian Amazon. We validate the model’s

performance based on historical deforestation and enforcement mission data covering the

years 2002-9. Based on an optimal enforcement scenario we analyse the costs of liability

establishment and legal coercion for alternative REDD targets and evaluate local welfare

impacts in terms of land users’ opportunity costs or fine obligations depending on local

compliance.

On the basis of the results, we discuss implications for the introduction of a planned national

PES Program and assess alternative REDD strategies with regard to costs and welfare

implications.

Our findings suggest that spatial patterns deforestation and inspection costs influence

enforcement strategies and thus welfare effects of REDD interventions. Command-and-

control is the most cost-effective REDD instrument from a regulator’s point of view, but

could cost land users over R$ 2.5 billion annually in opportunity costs and fines if the national

REDD target of an 80% reduction in deforestation rates was achieved. PES incentives could

reduce the social costs, but increase budget outlays vis-à-vis a command-and-control

dominated strategy and both legal and institutional challenges have to be overcome to make

Page 6: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

5

PES work at a larger scale. Decision-makers will thus have to innovatively combine on the

ground implementation tools in order to make REDD both financially viable and socially

compatible.

Keywords

Enforcement; PES; incentive; equity.

Page 7: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

6

About the authors

Jan Börner is an agricultural and natural resources economist at the Center for International

Forestry Research (CIFOR) with field and research experience in Latin America, Africa, and

Europe. His work on the analysis of forest conservation policies in the Amazon region is

supported by the Center for International Migration and Development (CIM) and the

Deutsche Gesellschaft für Internationale Zusammenarbeit GmbH (GIZ). [email protected]

Sven Wunder has worked with CIFOR since 2000; first in Indonesia, and since 2004 in

Brazil. He is currently working as Principal Economist, and head of CIFOR´s Brazil office.

He has worked for Danida, IUCN (Quito, Ecuador), and the Center for Development

Research (Denmark). His research deals with payments for environmental services (PES),

deforestation, and forest–poverty linkages.

Sheila Wertz-Kanounnikoff is trained in geography, geo-informatics, and environmental

economics, and a Senior Associate with the Center for International Forestry Research

(CIFOR) based in Maputo, Mozambique. Her current research interests and work focus on

forest and climate policy (REDD+, climate change adaptation), notably payments for

environmental services (PES).

Glenn Hyman is a geographer in CIAT's Decision and Policy Analysis program (DAPA)

specializing in the geographic and natural resources dimensions of agriculture. His regional

interests include Central America, the Andes and the Amazon. His current research involves

matching agricultural technologies to their social and environmental niches and the land-use

dimensions of programs to reduce emissions from deforestation and degradation (REDD+).

Nathália Nascimento is a geographer at the Federal University of Pará, Brazil, focusing on

the management of natural resources and local development in the Amazon. Her research

combines geographical information systems with remote sensing and dynamic land use

modeling.

Page 8: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

7

Acknowledgements

We thank Elizabeth Baron and Edward Guevara for technical support and gratefully

acknowledge the support of Juliana Simoes, Johannes Scholl, and Monika Röper during data

collection. Thanks to Lauren Persha for useful comments to improve the paper.

Page 9: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

8

Contents

1 Introduction .............................................................................................................. 10  2 Conceptual framework ............................................................................................. 13  

The forest and land user’s perspective ..................................................................... 13  The environmental authority’s perspective .............................................................. 14  Optimal enforcement at the forest frontier ............................................................... 16  

3 Data sources and processing .................................................................................... 19  4 Enforcement costs and REDD supply ...................................................................... 22  5 Welfare and equity implications of enforcing REDD .............................................. 26  6 Integrating REDD sticks and carrots ....................................................................... 30  

Pre-existing environmental legislation and forest tenure ......................................... 30  Enforcement costs of PES contracts ........................................................................ 31  Entitlement to PES and distributional fairness ........................................................ 32  

7 Conclusions .............................................................................................................. 33  8 Discussion ................................................................................................................ 36  References .................................................................................................................... 38  

Page 10: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

9

Acronyms

C&C Command-and-control (mechanisms)

IBAMA Brazilian Environmental Protection Agency

PES Payments for Environmental Services

REDD Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Degradation

Page 11: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

10

1 Introduction

Numerous initiatives to Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Degradation (REDD1)

are flowering worldwide, especially in countries with traditionally high deforestation rates,

such as Brazil and Indonesia (Cenamo et al. 2009; Cerbu et al. 2011). Project-type approaches

still dominate most countries’ incipient REDD landscape, but REDD is generally expected to

develop into an intergovernmental mechanism, implemented primarily through national

policy programs (Angelsen et al. 2009).

Broadly speaking, national decision makers can resort to three complementary means to

induce REDD at the local level, namely, incentives, disincentives and enabling measures.

Incentives are understood here as measures designed to encourage forest conservation,

whereas disincentives discourage deforestation and forest degradation. Complementary

enabling measures, such as land-tenure regularization or environmental education, can help

individuals to use forest resources more efficiently, thus preparing the ground for incentives

and disincentives to work effectively.

Incentive mechanisms, such as like payments for environmental services (PES), are usually

based on the principles of conditional cash transfer and often looked to as prime REDD on-

the-ground implementation mechanisms (Blom et al. 2010; Bond et al, 2009). Ferraro and

Kiss (2002) consider PES to be the most direct incentive-based conservation measure, as it

represents a quid pro quo agreement between environmental service users and providers. As a

REDD policy instrument, PES schemes would compensate land users with sufficient control

over their land for the costs of avoiding deforestation. Being conditional on contract

compliance, PES schemes would be enforced by reducing or suspending payments to

unfaithful service providers.

Disincentive-based REDD mechanisms range from taxes, production quotas and standards to

outright deforestation and logging bans, usually enforced through sanctions such as fines,

expropriation or imprisonment. If bans are enforced through (de facto collected) fines, they

1 The now widely adopted official acronym is REDD+, in including other than pure conservation measures, such as carbon stock

enhancement. For expositional reasons, we stick to the term “REDD”. Moreover, our case study focuses primarily on deforestation, which is the prime source of forest-based emissions in the Brazilian Amazon.

Page 12: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

11

come to work much like taxes, representing an additional cost to production. Tax payers, too,

need to be monitored with regard to their economic activities and legally pursued in case of

non-compliance. Disincentive-based policy instruments thus generally involve enforcement

costs. Environmental policy, especially in Latin America, has long been dominated by

disincentive-based regulatory mechanisms, e.g. full or partial bans on deforestation, which

however have proved hard to implement effectively (Seroa da Motta et al. 1996). Below we

refer to these policy instruments as command-and-control (C&C) mechanisms.

For direct payments to be effective REDD policy instruments, individual or collective service

providers must be endowed with the right to exclude others from modifying forest cover on

land under conservation agreements (Wunder 2007). This minimal institutional precondition

for PES generally requires spatially delimited land-tenure rights, as a means to effectively

monitor and enforce PES contracts. However, tropical forest frontiers are often characterized

by uncontrolled immigration waves causing spontaneous settlements with poorly regulated

tenure (Geist and Lambin 2002). Börner et al. (2010) found that 67% of threatened forestlands

in the Brazilian Amazon are subject to ill-defined or non-clarified tenure, thus limiting the

short- and medium-term scope for PES as a REDD vehicle.

At the same time, many REDD candidate countries boast far-reaching environmental

legislation restricting forest use and deforestation through C&C policies. In the Brazilian

Amazon, most private and public tenure categories allow land users to deforest merely up to

20% of their forests2. Illegal deforestation is nonetheless widespread, because regulations are

poorly enforced. According to the latest agricultural census3 in 2006 the aggregated non-forest

land uses on private properties exceeded the 20% limit in 749 out of 760 municipalities.

In the presence of widespread structural limitations for PES and incentive-based policies, and

a record of grossly ineffective C&C implementation, REDD strategies that combine more

effective “stick” enforcement with compensatory “carrots” could appear promising in Brazil,

as elsewhere in the tropics. Indeed, the Brazilian REDD strategy presented at the Kyoto

Protocol’s COP15 (15th Conference of the Parties) in Copenhagen (MMA 2009) stated a clear

commitment to achieving an 80% reduction vis-à-vis historical deforestation rates by 2 The Brazilian Forest Code: Lei Federal nº 4.771/65.

3 www.ibge.gov.br

Page 13: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

12

combining existing C&C measures with a national PES initiative. Nepstad et al. (2009) have

put the price tag of achieving this target at between R$13 and 36 billion4.

However, little thought has so far been given as to how specifically such a policy mix of

sticks and carrots could be designed in order to achieve cost-effectiveness and equity

objectives. This is where we hope to make a contribution with this paper. We quantitatively

assess the potential of C&C in achieving cost-effective and equitable forest conservation

outcomes, and set this into the perspective of PES options. Specifically, we address the

currently weak link between the “optimal enforcement” and the “forest resource

management” literature (Robinson et al. 2010). We do so by developing a spatially explicit

optimal enforcement model to assess the cost-effectiveness and equity impacts of a

disincentive-based REDD policy scenario, and applying it using data on land use and forest

law enforcement in the Brazilian Amazon. Based on the results, we derive the implications for

integrating C&C sticks with PES carrots.

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents our conceptual framework and model

assumptions, and Section 3 documents data sources. Analysis and results are presented in

sections 4 (cost-effectiveness), 5 (welfare) and 6 (integrating C&C and PES). Section 7

provides our main conclusions, while we discuss some of the limitations of our approach and

their implications for our findings in Section 8.

4 2009 average exchange rate: US$1 = R$2

Page 14: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

13

2 Conceptual framework

The forest and land user’s perspective

Deforestation, including in Brazil, often happens because both most land users, and their

corresponding national governments, have a clear economic rationale for harvesting precious

timber resources and increasing their farmland by converting abundant forests (Andersen et

al. 2002; Kaimowitz 2002). Many tropical land users may, nonetheless, have interest in forest

conservation. Indigenous and traditional forest users could be much benefitted if REDD leads

to improved frontier governance and enhanced C&C of deforestation by external migrants and

entrepreneurs encroaching illegally on their land. However, we focus here on the majority of

Amazon land users who, as a baseline, incrementally convert forests to farm- and

pasturelands, even when this deforestation is formally illegal.

Upon deciding whether or not to deforest, land users facing C&C policies are likely to

balance expected profits from illegal forest conversion against the odds of receiving a fine.

Following the classical optimal enforcement model (Becker 1968), the land user’s decision to

deforest d depends on:

⎩⎨⎧

>−

≤−=

0100

:0,1 FprforFprfor

denf

enf

(eq.1)

Where r is the profit obtained per hectare of forest converted to agriculture, penf is the personal

probability of deforestation being detected and effectively sanctioned, and F is the per hectare

fine for illegal deforestation. penf and F are controlled by environmental authorities, and will

be critical in determining land-use decisions, but must be carefully set to represent an

effective disincentive (Robinson et al. 2010). Depending on the available means for legal

coercion, extremely high fines can become ineffective deterrents if offenders chose to default

on them, or do so because they are too poor to pay. Large fines may also encourage wasteful

avoidance behaviour and increase the scope for bribe taking in weak institutional

environments, thus introducing excessive social costs. Also, detection probability must be

Page 15: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

14

high enough for offenses not to be considered as de facto tolerated. In their review of the

enforcement literature, and contrary to Becker’s proposition, Robinson et al. suggest that

effective enforcement normally requires relatively high probabilities and low fines. This is

contrary to Becker’s initial proposition, that optimal enforcement is best achieved by

combining high fine levels and low enforcement probabilities, thus minimizing enforcement

costs.

The environmental authority’s perspective

Environmental authorities in charge of implementing REDD through enhanced forest

conservation on the ground, will typically be up against a powerful agricultural lobby and

many local land users’ interest in continuously expanding the agricultural frontier. In

allocating REDD budgets, welfare impacts on land users and sectoral development constraints

will thus have to be balanced against cost-effectiveness criteria. A key conceptual question

relates to whether the opportunity costs of land users should enter the regulator’s cost-

effectiveness equation (social planner’s accounting). Here we argue that recipient countries

under an international REDD agreement can face budgetary opportunity costs that represent

an incentive to use REDD funds in order to free up resources from the national forest sector

budget for investment in non-forest sectors. Looking at operational cost-effectiveness and

land users’ welfare effects of forest conservation as two separate performance indicators thus

appears justified.

In the context of REDD, environmental cost-effectiveness (i.e., tons of emissions avoided per

unit of currency invested) of a national REDD program could formally be defined as follows:

( )

REDD

i

T

t

I

i

Rtiti

REDD C

BDDE

∑∑ −=

(eq.2)

where t is a period of time horizon T, i is a spatial unit of the intervention area I, D and DR

represent, respectively, deforestation without and with REDD intervention, and B represents

the above-ground biomass carbon content lost per area unit in the form of CO2 during forest

degradation or conversion to other uses. CREDD represents the operational costs of

implementing national REDD policies. D, the baseline deforestation level, is established ex-

ante by assessing historical trends. DR, the de facto realized deforestation, is in principle

established ex post through deforestation monitoring, but here we will model the impacts of

Page 16: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

15

different policy instrument on D. B, the area’s carbon density, is usually determined through

remote sensing analyses and selective field measurements of forest biomass content.

Effective C&C based REDD will incur operational costs in three categories: a) liability

establishment, b) administrative processes, and c) legal coercion.

Liability establishment principally involves the cost of travelling to detected deforestation

patches: more frequent inspections to more deforestation sites raises the probability of

regulators to confront potential offenders, but also increases the costs of field presence.

Variable administrative costs arise from legal processes that result once illegal deforestation

has been officially confirmed. Depending on the type of offense and legal action taken by

presumed offenders, processes can run through various instances. Administrative costs can be

particularly high if enforcement is effective in detecting offenses, but ineffective in following

up with sanctions. Like in the Brazilian case, such an ineffective enforcement scenario tends

to result in high non-compliance levels and consequently high administrative costs.

Coercive action is required if offenders choose to default on fines. The cost of effective

coercive action depends on the available leverage mechanisms. In Brazil, a frequently

employed and effective - though cost-intensive – measure of coercion is confiscation. A

stylized representation of the three C&C cost elements is provided in equation 3, where the

first term represents liability cost establishment: a cost that on average accrues in all locations

with potential deforestation pressure. The second term includes coercion and administrative

follow-up costs in locations, where deforestation actually occurs and liability can be

established, as well as potential fine revenues:

( ) ( ) cPFpTCDDTCpC i

I

ienf

Ci

Rii

LiienfCC +−+=∑

=1&

(eq.3)

With I being the total number of spatial units i in the study area, penf is the probability of i

being visited by an enforcement team, TC represents roundtrip costs to visit i with

superscripts L and C identifying liability establishment and coercion (i.e. confiscation) costs,

respectively. P is the number of deforestation polygons in i and c the administrative cost of

following up on the environmental offense, and F represents fine revenues.

Page 17: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

16

Representing the land user – enforcement agency relationship by way of equations 1 and 3

rests on the assumption that the available enforcement budget is optimally allocated to cover

operational enforcement costs, i.e. the level of effectiveness depends only on penf. In real

world situations, multiple sources of enforcement ineffectiveness exist. For example, cross-

compliance mechanisms, such as restricted credit access for land users that default on fines,

do exist in Brazil, but hinge on effective local institutions that are seldom in place at the forest

margins (Brito and Barreto 2006). Some implications of representing enforcement costs by

way of equation 3 are discussed in section 8.

The disincentive of effective REDD-funded C&C enforcement must result in income, and

thus, welfare losses compared to no additional action. The aggregate direct welfare effect of

enforcement in intervention area I can be written as:

( )( )∑ −−−=I

ienf

Rii

RiiREDD FpDrDDW

(eq.4)

Where the first term represents income losses (uncompensated opportunity costs) for

compliant land users and the second term depicts fine payment costs to non-compliant land

users. That is, forestland users that would have illegally deforested in the absence of enhanced

C&C can choose between two strategies, according to which of them is likely to minimize

welfare losses.

Optimal enforcement at the forest frontier

According to equations 3 and 4, both cost-effectiveness and welfare effects depend on how

well the disincentive is delivered on the ground (here represented by penf, a measure of

enforcement probability).

To determine an optimal penf at a given location in space, consider that regulators typically

face a budget constraint, so that punishing every single offender is seldom an option5. If the

costs of field presence vary in space, a common feature of extensive forest frontiers, an

economically optimal enforcement strategy would thus prioritize nearby over remote

5 This reflects the reality in Brazil and many other Latin-American countries. Theoretically, the prospect of fine revenues could

eventually make enforcement a profitable undertaking.

Page 18: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

17

deforestation polygons. Maximizing deterrence may also imply prioritizing large over small

deforestation offenses6. The regulator’s objective function can thus be described as:

∑∑= =

=I

i

P

pipiv svAREA

i1 1

,max (eq.6)

Subject to:

1,0,1

∈≥∑=

i

I

iii vvTCBUDGET (eq.7)

Where AREA is the total area visit by environmental regulators, s is the size of deforestation

polygon p in spatial unit i, and v a binary choice variable indicating whether a given polygon

is visited by an enforcement team (v=1), or not (v=0). Maximization as a constrained linear

programming problem7 results in a shadow value for each vi. Positive shadow values of

constraints on v (i.e., v ≤ 1) reflect enforcement priority levels among visited i, whereas

negative values indicate how much additional deforestation must occur in a given spatial unit

i for an enforcement visit to become cost-effective. If polygon size and quantity are specified

as expected values for each i, shadow values can be interpreted as economically motivated

enforcement priorities.

6 This also reflects that the enforcement agency’s objective is to maximize total area of inspected deforestation polygons in the

Amazon (IBAMA personal communication, June 2009).

7 With a high number of polygons the imprecision introduced by using a continuous constrained choice variable instead of a binary one is negligible.

Page 19: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

18

Figure 1 Enforcement probabilities as a function of shadow value

0.00

0.20

0.40

0.60

0.80

1.00

1.20

-20 -10 0 10 20 30 40

Perc

entil

e ra

nk s

core

(p e

nf)

Shadow values [km2]

Between 2003 and 2008, the Brazilian Environmental Protection Agency (IBAMA) had an

average annual operational budget of approximately R$ 50 million for the Amazon region

(IBAMA pers. comm. June 2009). In Figure 1, we apply this budget constraint to our spatially

explicit simulation of optimal C&C enforcement in the Brazilian Amazon for a hypothetical

year. For the simulation, polygon sizes (s) in grid cells (i) were set equal to average 2002-9

deforestation levels.

Applying percentile rank scores to the shadow values of the optimal solution, we obtain a

vector of enforcement probabilities with penf below 0.5 for grid cells that were not included in

the optimal solution of the enforcement simulation. Enforcement probabilities are somewhat

stronger correlated with travel costs (ρTC,Penf = -0.7) than with polygon size (ρs,Penf = 0.63).

Validation of the optimal solution by means of a municipal-level comparison with the

location of IBAMA’s de facto enforcement missions during 2002-09 resulted in a 70% match.

Our resulting C&C strategy is responsive rather than preemptive in nature, with field

interventions being planned based on observed deforestation patterns. As such, it represents

quite well the strategy currently pursued by IBAMA, with enforcement teams guided by up-

to-date satellite imagery and maps of past deforestation hotspots.

Page 20: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

19

3 Data sources and processing

Due to widespread Amazon deforestation, Brazil has long topped the list of tropical

deforestation (Hansen et al. 2008). Despite considerable reductions in recent years,

deforestation rates could pick up again once the global economy recovers from the financial

crisis. Today, still more than three quarters of the Brazilian Amazon are covered by forests.

Modelling scenarios, however, suggest that agricultural expansion will have reduced forest

cover by up to 40% in 2050 (Soares-Filho et al. 2006).

The empirical analysis in the following sections covers 4.5 million km2 of the Legal Brazilian

Amazon, drawing on data from a variety of sources (Table 1). An area of approximately 700

thousand square kilometres at the southwestern end of the Legal Brazilian Amazon was

excluded due to incomplete deforestation data. The study area thus comes to represent the

Amazon Biome rather than the formal Legal Amazon.

Table 1 Data sources used in this study

Data type Source

1. Annual deforestation polygons (2002-9) INPE-PRODES (2002-9)*

2. Municipal-level average profits from agricultural activities and

timber extraction (i.e. REDD opportunity costs) Börner et al. 2010

3. Location and size of land-reform settlements, protected areas, and

indigenous territories. IBAMA (provided in 2007)

4. Location and size of protected areas and indigenous territories

IBAMA, at:

http://siscom.ibama.gov.br (accessed in 2009)

5. Costs and locations (districts) of C&C enforcement operations (2003-

2008)

IBAMA records, provided in June

2009

6. Population estimates (Amazon region) IBGE** Agricultural Census 2006

* The Brazilian Space Research Centre’s (INPE) Program for the Calculation of Deforestation in the Amazon:

www.obt.inpe.br/prodes/

** The Brazilian Institute for Geography and Statistics (IBGE)

In order to estimate the travel costs of enforcement missions as a function of travel time, we

used parameters derived from various interviews with IBAMA officials at their headquarters

in Brasilia (September/October 2009) (Table 2).

Page 21: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

20

Table 2 Field presence cost estimates

Quantity/unit R$8/unit R$ per h

Manpower 8 3000 per month 150

Diesel 30 liters 60

Car rental 2 500 per day 125

Helicopter purchase cost - - 4000

Other cost (air travel, housing, etc.) 150

Source: Interviews with IBAMA officials (2009)

Shortest possible travel time by road and waterways was estimated from 524 Amazon

municipal centres to the centre points of 11181 grid cells with a size of 400 km2, using the

Accessibility Analyst software package9 developed by the International Centre for Tropical

Agriculture (CIAT). Travel speed on waterways, unpaved and paved roads was set to 10, 25

and 60 km/h, respectively. Figure 2 shows the results, in terms of travel time from the nearest

urban centre to each grid cell.

8 R$ 1 ~ US$ 0.58 (January 2010)

9 http://webapp.ciat.cgiar.org/access/

Page 22: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

21

Figure 2 Travel time to grid cells from nearest urban center in the Brazilian Amazon

(white areas excluded from the study area)

Using the parameters in Table 4, we can estimate the parameter TC (travel costs per polygon

visit, eq. 4), with the underlying assumption that all polygons falling in to the same grid cell

can be visited at the same cost. Parameter r (per-ha net returns to forest conversion, eq. 1) was

calculated as a municipal-level average using official annual production statistics from IBGE

(for methods and analysis, see Börner et al. 2010). Ds (baseline deforestation, eq. 2) and P

(number of deforestation polygons per grid cell, eq. 4) was estimated from official

deforestation data (see Table 3). Finally, parameter c (administrative cost per identified

offense, eq. 4) was estimated on the basis of an assessment of administrative efficiency by

Micol et al. (2008).

Spatial data processing involved overlays of deforestation with tenure data and zonal statistics

on 100 meter resolution grids, in order to assign each deforestation polygon to a unique grid

cell and tenure category. Tenure categories include land reform settlements (252,142 km2),

Indigenous Territories (970,441 km2), Protected Areas (786,317 km2), not officially delimited

tenure (2,340,727 km2), and others (52,579 km2). Overlapping tenure categories (totalling

67,632 km2 ~ 1.4% of the study area) were analysed separately.

Page 23: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

22

4 Enforcement costs and REDD supply

Assessing the operational cost and effectiveness of enforcing C&C based REDD, using the

model set out in section 2 (equations 2 and 3), requires probability measures for deforestation

patterns in spatial units. Using spatial deforestation data, we derive expected values for annual

deforestation (Dsi) and average deforestation polygon number (Pi) in each of the 11,181 grid

cells in which deforestation occurred during 2002-9. As a result, we applied the model to an

average annual baseline deforestation level of 17,462 km2, i.e. slightly lower than the 19,500

km2 reference scenario of the Brazilian REDD strategy that is based on the period 1996-2005.

Land users’ opportunity costs are estimated over a 10-year planning horizon (Börner et al.

2010) and policy implementation costs and welfare effects must be interpreted as arising from

the provision of a C&C disincentive over the same planning horizon.

Figure 3 depicts the operational costs and compliance effectiveness of four different C&C

implementation scenarios: with and without fine revenues, and with and without fully

clarified land use rights in the undelimited tenure category (see section 3). For each scenario,

we look at operational costs over the full range of avoided deforestation targets, in the sense

that C&C targets are enforced by increasing the level of per-hectare fines. The first scenario

(clarified rights) assumes that field inspections by enforcement teams directly translates into

corresponding enforcement probabilities, i.e. if an enforcement team visits a given grid cell

once in ten years, then land users face a one in ten chance to be effectively fined. In the

second scenario (status quo rights), we assume, more realistically, that field inspections will

only be half as effective in areas with poorly defined tenure status (52.3 % of the study area)

or where deforestation occurs in publicly owned strictly protected areas (7.3%), because in

those cases it will typically be much more difficult to link deforestation to liable land users.

During 2002-9, 68.6% of total forest loss was detected in areas with poorly delimited tenure,

compared to only 1.1% in strictly protected areas.

Page 24: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

23

Figure 3 Operational costs, potential net revenue and effectiveness of enforcing

Brazilian forest laws, as percentage of avoided deforestation

-1,500

-1,000

-500

0

500

1,000

0 20 40 60 80 100

[mill

ion

R$]

C&C effectiveness [%]

Cost  (clarified  rights)Cost  (status   quo  rights)Net  revenue  (clarified  rights)Net  revenue  (status  quo  rights)

Under the clarified rights scenario (grey lines), operational costs are slightly lower than under

the status quo rights (black line) scenario, because a higher number of non-compliant land

users require higher outlays for administrative and coercive action when tenure is unclear. At

80% avoided deforestation, the operational cost difference is R$ 372 versus R$ 392 million,

i.e. roughly R$20 million. Hence, current efforts by the Brazilian government to increasingly

clarify Amazon land tenure could also make C&C implementation more cost-effective, so that

future scenarios come to lie somewhere between the status quo and clarified rights

simulations.

If fines can effectively be collected (dotted-line scenarios), C&C could result in negative costs

(i.e. net revenues for regulators) as soon as avoided deforestation reaches 5-10%. Well-

defined tenure conditions could boost net revenues of regulatory enforcement by R$43

million at the 80% avoided deforestation target. The sharp initial decline in net enforcement

costs is explained through a boost in fine revenues as per-hectare fines increase, while still

affecting a large group of non-compliant land users with low opportunity cost. As compliance

increases, fine revenues level off, but enforcement costs also go down, due to increasing

compliance levels. In the perfect tenure scenario, a 20% reduction in deforestation rates could

be achieved by setting per-hectare fines at R$1370, whereas the 80% effectiveness target

Page 25: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

24

requires a R$3104 fine per hectare of illegally cleared forest. In the more realistic status quo

rights scenario, fine levels must increase to R$2093 and R$5509 to achieve 20% or 80%

conservation effectiveness, respectively. Thus, it is notable that, under perfect conditions,

improved deforestation C&C could more than pay for itself through fine collection. However,

for a variety of reasons (see below), environmental authorities in Brazil have collected only

0.6% of environmental fines applied during 2005-910. Hence, a realistic implementation

scenario will probably come to be closer to the fully drawn than to the dotted lines.

If regulators were interested in maintaining lower fine levels (e.g. out of a recognition that

high fines are less likely to be paid, Section 2), 80% effectiveness could alternatively be

achieved by increasing field presence to compensate for the lower penalties. Under perfect

enforcement, i.e. successfully penalizing every single offense, our model suggests that the

minimum per-hectare fine level must lie at R$2450, less than half the fine level of imperfect

enforcement. Perfect enforcement of the 80% effectiveness target would cost regulators

R$656 million annually, but potentially still come with R$839 million in fine revenues. This

represents, nonetheless, a 40% loss in cost-effectiveness, compared to imperfect enforcement.

Figure 4 shows for the 80% reduced deforestation and status quo rights scenario the spatial

distribution of total operational C&C costs, potential fine revenues, and the net budgetary

outcome of subtracting the two. While fine revenues do compensate for operational costs at

the aggregate level, operational costs are simulated to be higher than fine revenues in over

84% of the grid cells where deforestation was detected during 2002-9. Clusters of grid cells

with very high operational enforcement costs and fine revenues are located primarily in the

states of Pará and Rondônia and, to some extent, in Roraima. Enforcement costs are especially

high in grid cells with a large number of scattered deforestation polygons, rather than few

large ones.

Fine revenues accrue only where the C&C disincentive is not high enough to induce

compliance. High fine revenues thus occur in grid cells that combine high opportunity costs

with large deforested areas and relatively few deforestation patches. Since such locations are

also prioritized by an economically optimal enforcement strategy (see Section 2), little room

exists to further increase compliance here through higher field presence. Even under perfect 10 Tribunal de Contas da União 2009 (accessed in June 2010): www.tcu.gov.br/contasdegoverno

Page 26: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

25

enforcement, landowners are best served here to just pay their fines, as if it was a tax. Higher

fines or equivalently deterrent cross-compliance mechanisms would then be needed to further

reduce deforestation by C&C alone (see discussion in Section 6).

Figure 4 Operational enforcement costs, potential fine revenues and net budgetary

gains (green areas) versus costs (red areas) of an 80% reduction in 2002-9 annual

average deforestation in a scenario with status quo tenure conditions

Page 27: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

26

5 Welfare and equity implications of enforcing REDD

In the absence of compensation mechanisms, more rigid enforcement of conservation

regulations results in two types of welfare effects: non-compliant land users pay fines,

whereas compliant land users suffer opportunity costs (Section 2). Table 3 separates these

effects for the two alternative tenure scenarios, and for high versus low conservation target.

Table 3 Land user annual welfare losses from enforcing forest conservation targets in

the Brazilian Amazon

Scenario Total loss

Million R$

Losses through fines

%

Opportunity costs

%

80% conservation with

status quo use rights

2,850 24 76

80% conservation with

clarified use rights

2,852 25 75

20 % conservation with

status quo use rights

1,585 77 23

20% conservation with

clarified use rights

1,829

83 17

At an elevated 80% conservation target, simulated welfare changes vis-à-vis current levels of

predominantly illegal deforestation are clearly dominated by higher opportunity costs, which

account for three quarters of net changes. Total welfare loss is estimated at R$2,580 annually

under status quo largely unclear use right conditions -- slightly higher so under the clarified

rights scenario, because fines are collected more effectively from non-compliant land users.

According to official IBGE estimates this total welfare loss represents 69% of the average

annual growth in value added from agriculture, forestry, and fisheries in Amazon states (or

20% of the national value added in these sectors) for the period 2002-8.

Since tenure regulation would increase the effectiveness of enforcement missions in areas that

account for the major share of forest loss, fines could then be set at lower levels. With lower

fines, offenses in high opportunity cost areas become profitable, whereas more effective

enforcement in low opportunity cost areas with clarified tenure conditions increases

compliance levels. The latter effect is slightly stronger, which is why opportunity cost related

welfare losses reduce by one percentage point (about R$22 million in absolute terms) under

the clarified use rights scenario.

Page 28: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

27

The patterns of welfare changes in the lower 20% conservation scenario are similar, but the

increase in total welfare loss when moving from the status quo to the clarified tenure scenario

is much more pronounced (R$245 million as opposed to R$2 million). The reason is that

tenure regulation enables fine collection from much larger number of non-compliant land

users. In fact, fine payments dominate welfare losses at the low conservation target by and

83% in the perfect and (77%) in the status quo tenure simulations, respectively, due to the

larger number of fine paying non-compliant land users.

A comparison of welfare outcomes in the 20% versus 80% conservation scenario reveals that

the first 20% of deforestation reduction cause a greater absolute welfare loss than moving the

conservation target all the way up to 80%. This is the result of an optimal enforcement

strategy that prioritizes nearby and large-scale offenses, which typically exhibit higher

opportunity costs. A perfectly reasonable enforcement strategy thus comes to produce an

economically inefficient outcome at the national level, because 20% conservation could have

been achieved at a much smaller economic loss if low opportunity cost areas had been

prioritized (for a discussion of implications for the optimal mix of REDD policy tools, see

Section 6).

To assess equity outcomes, we have to look at the distribution of welfare losses. C&C

induced costs reflect the distribution of deforestation pressures across tenure categories. For

example, the simulated improvement in use right regulation would affect an area of

approximately 2.3 million km2 that comprises almost 55% of all deforestation patches

detected between 2002-9 and caused predominantly by private (often large) landholders and

occupants of public land. Under the 80% conservation target, roughly 68% of the total annual

welfare loss accrues to land users that live in these areas with poorly regulated tenure

conditions. Despite lower fine levels, absolute welfare loss for this tenure category increases

by almost R$42 million in the regulated tenure scenario, whereas it reduces by roughly the

equivalent amount in all other tenure category. Put differently, if the enforcement

effectiveness loss due to unregulated tenure is compensated by higher fine levels, land users

in well-established tenure categories have to face otherwise unnecessary high fine revenues.

The second largest absolute welfare loss in the 80% conservation scenario (19%) accrues to

land reform settlements that comprise almost a quarter of all deforestation patches detected in

the eight-year period. Tenure regulation in combination with lower fixed per-hectare fines

Page 29: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

28

could reduce this burden by R$20 million annually, while maintaining the 80% conservation

target. Protected areas that allow sustainable use account for 6% of the total welfare loss,

whereas indigenous territories and strictly protected areas would face a 3 and 1% share,

respectively.

Figure 5 depicts the spatial distribution of welfare changes for the status quo tenure scenario

of 80% conservation. In absolute terms, high welfare losses seem to occur above all in states

with active deforestation frontiers, such as Pará, Mato Grosso and Rondônia and, to some

extent, in the extreme northern Amazon at the well-connected border to Venezuela. The

picture slightly changes, however, if average welfare loss per offense is considered – an

indicator of individual welfare loss (not shown in Figure 5). In terms of individual welfare

loss, Mato Grosso stands out as the state with the largest number of high negative value grid

cells. The reason is that deforestation in Mato Grosso is generally larger scale than in most

other states, hence, absolute welfare effects are distributed over a smaller number of

deforestation polygons. While the state of Pará boasts 346 grid cells with absolute welfare

losses above the third quartile value, the number of high value grid cells is 42% lower for

average welfare loss. The inverse is true for Mato Grosso, where the number of grid cells with

third quartile level average welfare loss is 37% higher than that of absolute welfare loss cells.

Page 30: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

29

Figure 5 Absolute welfare change as a result of inducing an 80% deforestation target

through C&C measures under status quo right conditions

As expected, the welfare effects of C&C induced forest conservation are thus rather unequally

distributed over space, tenure categories, and individual land users. Land users that have

engaged little in deforestation in the past, such as indigenous and traditional populations,

would face relatively small or no welfare loss through enhanced C&C enforcement, whereas

as opposed to settlers, private landholders, and occupants. Changes in the enforcement

strategy do not seem to substantially alter distributional effects. For example, if each and

every offense was inspected and sanctioned (perfect enforcement), the Gini coefficient of

average (per offense) welfare effects would only fall slightly from 0.48 to 0.4611.

11 Since welfare effects are negative, larger Gini coefficients indicate higher concentration of losses in fewer grid cells.

Page 31: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

30

6 Integrating REDD sticks and carrots

The analyses in sections 4 and 5 suggest that budgetary constraints probably play a minor role

in preventing a policy shift towards more effective enforcement of existing environmental

legislation in the Brazilian Amazon: increased enforcement could widely pay for itself,

provided that fine collection becomes effective. However, an ambitious 80% reduction in

deforestation will cause agribusiness and smallholders to lose out significantly, so that these

groups would become key political economy barriers to REDD. Strong local political

reactions against a 2008 IBAMA crackdown on illegal logging, and national-level

parliamentary strength of the agribusiness lobby foreshadow that REDD is bound to

encounter formidable political resistance. Using PES carrots has thus been suggested as a way

to appease the losers, and thus devise a politically more viable complementary strategy for

REDD on-the-ground implementation. In this section, we discuss three conditioning factors

for the implementation of PES in the Brazilian Amazon.

Pre-existing environmental legislation and forest tenure

In Brazil, REDD is facing an environmental policy context where little deforestation can

occur legally. As mentioned, the Brazilian Forest Code requires the majority of Amazon

properties under private tenure to keep an 80% forest cover. The remaining public tenure

categories typically restrict land use even further. However, since the enforcement of

conservation laws has been lax over many years, illegal deforestation has been widely

tolerated, and land users have come to consider tolerated deforestation an entitlement (May

and Millikan, 2010). Hence, while REDD could de facto reduce emissions substantially, only

a small share would be de jure additional,

A discrepancy between de jure and de facto additionality is a common feature among REDD

candidate countries in Latin America (Armas et al. 2009). Hence, designing an international

compensation mechanism requires carefully balancing the odds of discouraging national

efforts through environmental budget substitution against the risk of losing out on substantial

mitigation opportunities. For the Brazilian case, our welfare analysis above supports the

Page 32: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

31

notion that a politically viable national REDD approach may require budgets for

compensatory measures. Given legal constraints, PES would essentially take the form of a

compliance subsidy, rather than a full-blown compensation of conservation opportunity costs.

As mentioned, most threatened Amazon forests are not held under clear property rights. This

would currently restrict the scope for offering conditional landowner compensations to little

more than a third of threatened forests (Börner et al. 2010). Nevertheless, the federal Terra

Legal12 program and several state-level land survey initiatives are underway, which will

elevate this scope in years to come.

Enforcement costs of PES contracts

In the literature, conservation opportunity costs are often used to roughly estimate required

compensation amounts (Börner et al. 2010, Nepstad et al. 2009, Grieg-Gran 2006). Empirical

assessments of PES schemes suggest that opportunity costs indeed represent the major share

of total implementation costs, but transaction costs could still be significant (Wunder et al.

2008). Implications for PES-based REDD arise from our analysis of C&C with regard to

contract enforcement.

Different from C&C rules, PES contracts can potentially be leveraged through the suspension

of payments, but compliance still requires effective enforcement. To illustrate this, consider

the following variant of equation 1 (Section 2):

⎩⎨⎧

>+−

≤+−=

0)(10)(0

:0,1 PESFprforPESFprfor

denf

enf (eq.8)

where PES depicts a conditional per-hectare compensation. Unless enforcement is perfect (penf

= 1), a PES incentive that equals the land user’s opportunity cost will be insufficient to avoid

deforestation. Moreover, it pays off to receive PES without complying, when detection is only

penalized with termination of payments. Imperfect PES enforcement thus provides an

12 The Terra Legal Program is a pragmatic attempt to regulate occupied public lands that had covered over 10 million hectares of land until the end of 2010: http://portal.mda.gov.br/terralegal/

Page 33: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

32

economic incentive to pocket payments and continue business-as-usual – a potentially high

loss in the overall cost-effectiveness of a national REDD scheme.13

The costs of enforcing PES contracts will depend on the rules regarding liability attribution

and contract coercion. Like in the Mexican national PES program, contracts could potentially

hold landowners liable for any loss in service provision, i.e., suspending payments even for

externally caused damages such as third-party invasion or fires spreading from neighbouring

plots (Muñoz-Piña et al. 2008). Nonetheless, landowners would tend to factor in these risks

and only accept PES contracts with higher per-hectare payments. If fixed per-hectare

payments had to be increased by 10% in the Brazilian Amazon, our spatial analysis suggests

that payment costs could rise by R$687 million annually.

Alternatively, if the liability for externally induced service losses, plus the burden of proof,

would lie with the environmental authority, this would involve widespread field inspections

for liability establishment, similar to C&C. Based on historical Amazon deforestation

patterns, the incremental cost would lie around R$300 million. Correspondingly, if payments

represent only partial subsidies for the costs of complying with underlying regulations, and/or

sanctions include the restitution of past payments, more field presence and administrative

effort would be needed to avoid cheating, thus triggering additional costs. Hence, making PES

a compliance subsidy also compromises some of its attractive simplicity.

Entitlement to PES and distributional fairness

Apart from the implications of pre-existing regulations for the additionality of PES (see

discussion above), the history of land grabbing and unequal access to natural resources in the

Brazilian Amazon somewhat blurs the otherwise straightforward rationale for compensation

payments. Compensation typically presumes entitlement, but past deforestation has not only

been largely illegal, it has also partially taken place under illegitimate land claims. The

perspective of compensation payments to farmers with active deforestation records, thus

understandably raises a perception of entitlement among allegedly good forest stewards, such

as indigenous and traditional population groups.

13 Even elevating the risk to payback of the previously received PES amounts is generally not efficient to discourage cheating: at worst, the non-compliant land user has to return an ‘interest-free loan’. The only way to deter cheating would be to threaten with penalties that exceed PES amounts, in which case PES would become more similar to C&C.

Page 34: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

33

Against this backdrop it would appear politically contentious to introduce PES merely

according to de facto additionality criteria. Just like welfare losses under improved regulatory

enforcement, payments based on a historical reference scenario would then reflect the

underlying distribution of assets and deforestation pressure in favour of large-scale producers

(Börner et al. 2010). Any single stick or carrot approach to REDD in the Brazilian Amazon

would thus ignore historically motivated perceptions of fairness.

Applying PES as a compliance subsidy, as suggested above, could reduce excessive welfare

losses for compliant land users, but fail to be inclusive of good past forest stewards. Yet,

designing an effective Brazilian REDD strategy will also require provisions for leakage into

still relatively well-preserved indigenous lands and extractive reserves. Dwellers in these

public land categories may not qualify for compensation based on their historical

deforestation record. Our assessment of enforcement costs, nevertheless, suggests that

actively involving local people in the protection and management of protected areas may

justify conditional payments also on the grounds of conservation efficiency.

7 Conclusions

Quantitative research on the potential costs and welfare implications of REDD has so far

focused primarily on incentive-based on-the-ground implementation tools, such as PES. Yet,

many REDD candidate countries, most notably Brazil, will have to also rely heavily on C&C

based disincentives, including because the bulk of historical deforestation was illegal but

tolerated, and often a result of land grabbing. In this paper, we presented a simple conceptual

framework for the spatial analysis of the costs and welfare implications of C&C based REDD,

and applied it to the Brazilian Amazon.

Our findings suggest that C&C measures in isolation constitute the most cost-effective REDD

instrument, from an environmental regulator’s point of view. We estimate that an enforcement

strategy to achieve the 80% reduction in forest loss stipulated by the Brazilian REDD strategy

could cost regulators approximately R$392 million in concurrent annual operational expenses

for field presence and administrative follow-up. This cost estimate represents little more than

half of the maximum potential fine revenue that could result from this scenario, provided

these fines can be collected. Realizing this potential fine revenue, however, requires

Page 35: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

34

significant improvements in administrative efficiency and more effective legal mechanisms

for coercive action (Brito and Barreto 2006). Moreover, both enforcement costs and fine

revenues are sensitive to the degree of tenure regularization: improvements in the delimitation

of land claims could potentially boost overall cost-effectiveness by up to 14%.

The cost-effectiveness of C&C enforcement, nonetheless, differs in space. We find that

potential fine revenues exceed enforcement costs only in 16% of the study region. At

disaggregated spatial scales, enforcement costs tend to be higher than fines wherever

deforestation patches are small and scattered, which applies, in particular, to states with

comparatively low population densities like Amazonas, Acre and Amapá. Given that the

current institutional set up requires states to complement federal environmental law

enforcement, an optimal distribution of fine revenues probably involves disproportionally

high transfers to states with low deforestation pressure.

A purely C&C based Brazilian REDD strategy to achieve an 80% reduction in forest loss

would cost land users over R$2.5 billion annually in foregone opportunity costs and paid

fines. This represents more than two thirds of the growth in annual agricultural value added of

the Amazon states. Though the lion’s share of economic loss would accrue to large-scale

producers, losses to smallholders, especially in agricultural reform settlements, could be

substantial. Not surprisingly, a “desire of the public not to enforce the law” has been

identified in the early enforcement literature as a key obstacle to optimal enforcement (Stigler

1970, p. 534). Indeed, outright enforcement of the 80% REDD target could have severe

consequences for the development of regions and sectors that currently depend heavily on a

continuous expansion of the agricultural frontier. PES incentives, in turn, could significantly

reduce the net economic losses for land users, but would increase budget outlays vis-à-vis a

C&C dominated strategy.

Further implications arise for the design of the national PES program currently underway in

Brazil. Even if an international REDD mechanism provided ample resources for direct

conservation payments may remain partially ineffective unless PES contract enforcement was

substantially improved vis-à-vis the status quo of C&C enforcement. The reason is that the

loss of payments as a sanction of non-compliance becomes uncertain under imperfect

enforcement. PES recipients facing a low enforcement probability may thus prefer to continue

forest conversion and receive PES as an additional rent. Small to medium-scale offenders in

Page 36: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

35

remote locations would appear particularly prone to cause this form of loss in cost-

effectiveness, which is specific to incentive-based conservation approaches and potentially

significant in the context of REDD.

The prospect of REDD also raises equity issues in a country, where unequal access to land is

only gradually being tackled by an agricultural land reform and the designation of public land

as indigenous territories or extractive reserves for traditional populations. Combining existing

C&C sticks with PES carrots could increase the political scope for REDD as it could

straighten out otherwise widely unacceptable and unequally distributed welfare gains or losses

of applying any of the two instruments individually. While forest populations without

deforestation record would miss out on PES if payments where distributed according to a

historical reference scenario, leakage provision represents a key argument to compensate

indigenous and traditional populations for co-management efforts.

Institutional barriers to combining C&C with PES on larger scales, however, persist in the

form of unclear or poorly delimited tenure conditions on the majority of threatened forest land

(Börner et al. 2010). Payment schemes may therefore initially remain confined to relatively

well-defined tenure categories, such as agricultural reform settlements (Ezzine-de-Blas et al.

2011). Moreover, pre-existing regulatory policies render deforestation illegal in large parts of

the Amazon, where conditional compensations could possibly be applied only to subsidize

compliance costs.

Hence, an optimal REDD policy mix for the Brazilian Amazon requires balancing at least two

performance measures, cost-effectiveness and distributional equity. Stick policies require

lower budget outlays and are thus more cost-effective than compensatory carrots, yet none of

the two policy instruments alone addresses distributional equity. Only a combination of sticks

and carrots, though not necessarily welfare neutral at the local level, could possibly be

perceived as a politically viable REDD approach by a majority of stakeholders. Accelerating

the process of land tenure delimitation and regularization as well as removing administrative

obstacles to effective enforcement in order to make conditional compensations work at larger

scales thus represent prime REDDiness conditions.

Alternative forms to compensate land users for higher enforcement levels, such as subsidized

credit lines, certification, as well as technology development and dissemination are often

proposed as means to promote sustainable development and thus reduce deforestation through

Page 37: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

36

enablement. These may still play a role, but can backfire by inducing further forest loss unless

they are conditional on avoided deforestation (Angelsen and Kaimowitz 2001). Most PES

alternative are therefore equally demanding in terms of tenure clarity and enforcement, but

also face additional obstacles, such as adoption barriers (technological alternatives), demand

constraints (certification), or limited leverage in case of non-compliance (credit). While

sustainable development in the Amazon may require a much broader set of policy tools,

complementing C&C sticks with REDD funded PES carrots could provide the necessary

underlying incentive structure.

8 Discussion

A number of caveats to our enforcement model and its underlying assumptions merit further

discussion. First, our assumed linear relationship between fines and enforcement probabilities

may produce misleading results, especially for very high fine levels (Section 2; Robinson et

al. 2010). We experiment with very high fine levels only in the sensitivity analyses (e.g., in

Figure 3), so seemingly our key findings with regard to enforcement effectiveness would be

robust if this assumption was relaxed.

Second, the nature of the enforcement-compliance game may change over multi-period

iterations (Heyes 2000). Compliance is the time-bound result of interactions and learning

between land users and environmental authorities. For example, recent inspections may have

higher deterring effects than time-distant ones. We abstract from this by assuming a quasi-

equilibrium state, in which enforcement-compliance learning rounds would already have

taken place, so that the frequency of enforcement visits can be directly translated into

enforcement probability as perceived by land users. Building up effective enforcement could

take several years, and require more investments than the ones considered here, e.g. in

building an effective local and national level institutional infrastructure for C&C enforcement.

Hence, we here somewhat underestimate total C&C investment needs.

Over multiple interaction periods, in addition, land users could learn about the regulators

revealed priorities for preferably inspecting large and non-remote deforestation polygons. In

response, agents could incrementally target smaller-sized and remote areas, to lower detection

probabilities. IBAMA has seen incipient evidence that this may already be happening (pers.

Page 38: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

37

comm. Nov. 2010). Counter-acting this adaptive behaviour of offenders, the authorities would

need to inspect more areas, which would add costs and reduce C&C effectiveness.

Fourth, our approach also assumes that compliance is a binary ‘yes or no’ decision at the

20x20 km grid-cell level (see equation 1), whereas compliance decisions are continuous in

reality. Our model may consequently underestimate non-compliance or overestimate non-

compliance especially where opportunity costs within grid cells are highly heterogeneous.

While increasing the model’s resolution could alleviate the problem, only a full specification

of land users’ net profits in each grid cell would eliminate it.

Fifth, in the absence of adequate empirical observations our analysis ignores that deforestation

in the Brazilian Amazon is the outcome of a pre-existing C&C disincentive. Though allegedly

small due to chronically ineffective enforcement, a pre-existing disincentive would reduce

returns to forest conversion compared to our estimates of opportunity costs. Our approach

may thus slightly underestimate the cost-effectiveness of additional C&C action.

Finally, it is worth restating that fines are used in our model merely as a currency for the size

of the penalty required to induce compliance. However, fines are effective deterrents only

when offenders can successfully be pursued to pay them. In the Brazilian Amazon,

enforcement agents thus increasingly resort to in-situ confiscation of produce and equipment

whenever illegality is obvious. But, confiscation and any other field-based legal follow-up

results in additional enforcement costs. A key implication here is that actual fine revenues of

improved enforcement in the region may be much lower than our estimate of maximum

potential fine revenue. While lower fine revenues would not invalidate our findings regarding

operational C&C costs, welfare impacts, and integration with PES, regulatory enforcement

may ultimately represent a significant cost factor in the national budget.

Page 39: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

38

References

Andersen LE, Granger CWJ, Reis EJ, Weinhold D, Wunder S. 2002. The dynamics of

deforestation and economic growth in the Brazilian Amazon. Cambridge University Press,

Cambridge, UK.

Angelsen A, Brockhaus M, Kanninen M, Sills E, Sunderlin WD, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S.

2009. Realising REDD+: National strategy and policy options. Center for International

Forestry Research (CIFOR), Bogor, Indonesia.

Angelsen A, Kaimowitz D. 2001. Agricultural technologies and tropical deforestation.

CIFOR, CABI Publishing New York, Oxon.

Armas A, Börner J, Tito MR, Cubas LD, Coral ST, Wunder S, Reymond L, Nascimento N.

2009. Pagos por Servicios Ambientales para la conservación de bosques en la amazonía

peruana: Un análisis de viabilidad. SERNANP, Lima, Perú.

Becker G. 1968. Crime and punishment: an economic approach. Journal of Political Economy

76: 169-217.

Blom B, Sunderland T, Murdiyarso D. 2010. Getting REDD to work locally: lessons learned

from integrated conservation and development projects. Environmental Science and Policy

13: 164-172.

Bond I, Grieg-Gran M, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hazlewood P, Wunder S, Angelsen A. 2009.

Incentives to sustain forest ecosystem services: a review and lessons for REDD.

International Institute for Environment and Development, London, with CIFOR, Bogor,

Indonesia, and World Resources Institute, Washington DC, USA.

Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Tito MR, Pereira L, Nascimento N. 2010. Direct

conservation payments in the Brazilian Amazon: scope and equity implications.

Ecological Economics 69: 1272-1282.

Brito B, Barreto P. 2006. A eficácia da aplicação da lei de crimes ambientais pelo Ibama para

proteção de florestas no Pará. Revista de Direito Ambiental 43: 35-65.

Cenamo MC, Pavan MN, Campos MT, Barros AC, Carvalho F. 2009. Casebook of REDD

projects in Latin America. TNC and IDESAM, Manaus, Brazil.

Cerbu, G. A., Swallow, B. M., and Thompson, D. Y. 2011. Locating REDD: A global survey

and analysis of REDD readiness and demonstration activities. Environmental Science & Policy 14, 168-180.

Page 40: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

39

Ezzine-de-Blas D, Börner J, Violato-Espada A-L, Nascimento N, Piketty M-G. 2011. Forest

loss and management in land reform settlements: Implications for REDD governance in

the Brazilian Amazon. Environmental Science & Policy 14: 188-200.

Ferraro PJ, Kiss A. 2002. Direct payments to conserve biodiversity. Science 298: 1718-1719.

Geist HJ, Lambin EF. 2002. Proximate causes and underlying driving forces of tropical

deforestation. BioScience 52: 143-150.

Grieg-Gran M. 2006. The cost of avoiding deforestation. Report prepared for the Stern

Review of the Economics of Climate Change. International Institute for Environment and

Development (IIED), London.

Hansen MC, Stehman SV, Potapov PV, Loveland TR, Townshend JRG, DeFries RS, Pittman

KW, Arunarwati B, Stolle F, Steininger MK, Carroll M, DiMiceli C. 2008. Humid tropical

forest clearing from 2000 to 2005 quantified by using multitemporal and multiresolution

remotely sensed data. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 105: 9439-9444.

Heyes A. 2000. Implementing Environmental Regulation: Enforcement and Compliance.

Journal of Regulatory Economics 17: 107-129.

Kaimowitz D. 2002. Amazon deforestation revisited. Latin American Research Review 37:

221-235.

May PH and Millikan B. 2010. The context of REDD+ in Brazil: drivers, agents, and

institutions. Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR), Bogor, Indonesia.

Micol L, Guimarães S, Mônico I, Santos Rd. 2008. Transparência florestal Mato Grosso:

Análise do desmatamento e da gestao florestal. Instituto Centro de Vida, p 22.

MMA. 2009. The Brazilian REDD Strategy: How the country has achieved major

deforestation reduction in the Amazon. Ministerio do Meio Ambiente

Muñoz-Piña C, Guevara A, Torres JM, Braña J. 2008. Paying for the hydrological services of

Mexico's forests: analysis, negotiations and results. Ecological Economics 65: 725-736.

Nepstad D, Soares-Filho BS, Merry F, Lima A, Moutinho P, Carter J, Bowman M, Cattaneo

A, Rodrigues H, Schwartzman S, McGrath DG, Stickler CM, Lubowski R, Piris-Cabezas

P, Rivero S, Alencar A, Almeida O, Stella O. 2009. The End of Deforestation in the

Brazilian Amazon. Science 326: 1350-1351.

Robinson EJZ, Kumar AM, Albers HJ. 2010. Protecting developing countries' forests:

enforcement in theory and practice. Journal of Natural Resources Policy Research 2: 25-

38.

Seroa da Motta R, Ruitenbeek J. and Huber R. 1996. Uso de instrumentos econômicos na

gestão amiental da América Latina e Caribe: lições e recomendações. IPEA, Rio de

Janeiro.

Page 41: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

40

Soares-Filho BS, Nepstad DC, Curran LM, Cerqueira GC, Garcia RA, Ramos CA, Voll E,

McDonald A, Lefebvre P, Schlesinger P. 2006. Modelling conservation in the Amazon

basin. Nature 440: 520-523.

Stigler GJ. 1970. The optimum enforcement of laws. The Journal of Political Economy 78:

526-536.

Wunder S. 2007. The efficiency of payments for environmental services in tropical

conservation. Conservation Biology 21: 48-58.

Wunder S, Engel S, Pagiola S. 2008. Taking stock: a comparative analysis of payments for

environmental services programs in developed and developing countries. Ecological Economics 65: 834-852.

Page 42: Assessing costs and livelihood implications …...2 Correct citation: Börner J, Wunder S, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S, Hyman G, Nascimento N. 2011. REDD sticks and carrots in the Brazilian

The CGIAR Research Program on Climate Change, Agriculture and Food

Security (CCAFS) is a strategic initiative of the Consultative Group on

International Agricultural Research (CGIAR) and the Earth System Science

Partnership (ESSP), led by the International Center for Tropical Agriculture

(CIAT). CCAFS is the world’s most comprehensive global research program

to examine and address the critical interactions between climate change,

agriculture and food security.

For more information, visit www.ccafs.cgiar.org

Titles in this Working Paper series aim to disseminate interim climate change,

agriculture and food security research and practices and stimulate feedback

from the scientific community.