uk v's us healthcare

Upload: anthony-woodhead

Post on 10-Apr-2018

222 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    1/16

    Anthony Woodhead

    Two households, both alike in

    dignity?________________________________________________________________

    The public UK and market based US health systems certainly seem to

    form two opposing houses. Yet, despite much rhetoric against

    socialised medicine and free market competition, managers from each

    system show affection for each others methods in attempts to address

    quality, contain costs and improve the public health of their citizens.

    Ultimately though, views on their relative merits come down to matters

    of context and perspective. The first part of this essay will briefly

    discuss their respective structures and tabulate some key quantifiabledifferences; seeking to analyse reforms which have attempted to

    improve each system; arguing neither is particularly successful in

    containing costs and furthering public health. The second part will turn

    to reflection on the merits of this form of analysis since the systems are

    fundamentally so different.

    Part 1: Comparative analysis of UK and US healthcare

    management.

    Public vs Private: Volume vs Variety

    The UK spends 8.4% of GDP on healthcare, funding is predominately through

    taxation with delivery to all free at the point of consumption. The NHS has grown

    to be Europes largest organisation, employing around 1.4 million people. By

    2006/7 the NHS budget was about 104bn. (Wellards, 2008) The US spends

    15.3% of GDP, the private sector accounts for 54% of total spend with 34% of

    this from private insurers, the remaining 15% coming from out-of-pocket

    expenses. 46% comes from taxation, public spending in absolute terms is very

    similar to the UK. Medicare, a means tested fund for the over 65s is provided

    with 52% of this amount, only 12% is used for Medicaid in supporting the verypoorest. Provision is mainly via private organisations. 70% of the population

    have policies. 13% are covered through Medicare and 12% through Medicaid,

    administered at the state level. 15% have no insurance, this is mainly working

    families in the lowest third income bracket whose employers dont provide plans.

    (Reinhardt, 2005)

    Table 1: Macro difference in US and UK health care

  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    2/16

    Anthony Woodhead

    a-e, m-o OECD, (2009(a)) i Peterson & Burton, (2007)f-g ACP, (2008) p Nolte and McKee, (2008)

    Aging population using new technologies

    Healthcare spending has risen steadily over time but the US rate outpaces the

    UK:

    Graph 1: Change in health expenditure with time(OECD, 2009(b)):

    It misconception that aging and, in the case of the US, increased administration

    costs are the main drivers behind this increasing spend. As the table shows, in

    real terms administration makes up to low a proportion (Garber & Skinner, 2008)

    UnitedStates

    UnitedKingdom

    GDP per capita, 2006 ($)a 45489 35669Health expenditure, 2006 (%, GDP)b 15.3 8.4

    Public Health expenditure, 2006 (%, GDP)c

    7.0 7.3Private Health expenditure,2006 (%, GDP)d 8.3 1.1

    Per Capita health expenditure, 2006 ($)e 6959 2996

    Obesity Rate, 2005 (%)f 32 23

    Administration Costs, 2006 ($ per capita)i 465 172

    Doctors per 1000, 2006d 2.4 2.1

    Acute Hospital Beds per 10,000, 2005d 2.7 2.3

    MRI's per million, 2006d 26.5 5.6

    Male Life Expectancy, 2005 (yrs)m 75.2 77.1

    Female Life Expectancy, 2005 (yrs)n 80.4 81.1

    Deaths per 1000 live birthso 5 6.9

    Reduction in avoidable deaths 19997/98-2002/03 (per 100,000)p

    5.1 27.2

  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    3/16

    Anthony Woodhead

    and aging has much too gradually an impact. Though the retirement of the

    baby-boomers will increase demand it will happen far too slowly to account for

    all the increase. In the US, Reinhardt, (2003, p.30) shows that after modelling for

    factors such as medical care price inflation; greater resource intensity of

    treatments, including the availability of new technology; overall population

    growth; and so on aging will add only 0.5% a year to a forecasted totalexpenditure growth of 8.4%. Gray (2005) discusses studies that indicating similar

    proportions in the UK contrasted with lower overall growth; these also show

    stronger correlation between spend and proximity to death. In the UK 15.7% are

    aged 65+ yet consume 43.7% of resource in the US its 12.3% and 48.8%

    respectively (Blank and Burau, 2007 p.7)

    Critiques could argue much increase is fuelled by supply induced demand;

    proponents of free markets might equally conclude this is just providers

    responding to what is wanted. However as Garber & Skinner (2008 p.7) highlight

    both systems currently experience flat-of-the-curve returns on investment andthe US experiences an even shallower production function, getting even less

    bang for each additional buck. Though numbers of hospital beds and doctors

    are comparable, the US uses more and newer technologies. This is exemplified

    by the fact the US has nearly 5 times as many MRI machines as the UK; this is

    still only half the number of Japan which comes out on top, however the US; is

    consistently at or near the top of all of these measures. Williams fair-innings

    argument controversially proposes that better returns would be had in

    healthcare if the balance of spend was shifted to the young (as cited in Nord,

    2002) and issues concerning how to deal with these rising costs are compounded

    by decreasing population growth:

    Graph 2: Predicted Ratio of inactive elderly (65+) to the labour force(OECD,2009(a))

  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    4/16

    Anthony Woodhead

    Efficiency, cost containment and reform

    Recent UK reform sought to increase healthcare spending bringing it in-line with

    other European countries. In 2002 Blairs third-way policies resulted in the

    purchaser-provider-split; this contestability was marketed as a way of giving

    patients more choice, aiming to increase productivity through a quasi-

    competitive market which in practice it is seldom allowed to fail. Savings remain

    limited, particularly to rural areas, where there is little real choice. (Maynard,

    2005(a))

    Recent US reform has attempted to provide universal coverage but federal

    politics and less centralised presidential governance makes this difficult. Clintons

    tried and failed; at time of writing Obama is struggling to pass watered downreform. (Marmor et. al, 2009) Often more reform occurs at the state level;

    recently Massachusetts extended coverage to all but 2.6% of the population.

    Brennan & Mello (2009) show this was by way of transferring public money from

    an uncompensated care pool into subsidy funding and allowing the uninsured to

    purchase insurance, whilst developing a new federal waiver that brought the

    extra money needed to provide Medicaid rate increases for private hospitals and

    physicians. However, they caution against extending this model to other states

    since there was a much lower proportion of near-poor and nonMedicaid-eligible

    uninsured combined with most insurance through by local non-profit companies.

    Variation between states is massive as Dartmouth Atlas Studies (2006) highlight.

    Health is a service industry; 70% of costs are on salaries, getting value for

    money here is paramount to efficiency however success of pay for performance

    reform has been limited. (Walshe & Smith, 2006) In the UK the consultant

    contract was not signed as it would result in thorough management of clinical

    activity deemed unacceptable to the profession and its trade union and the

    QAF has also resulted in GPs being reimbursed much more without significant

    improvements in health outcomes (Maynard, 2005(a) p.73) In the US also, fee for

    service also dominants and efforts to control this prove particularly difficult

    under private healthcare. Capitation has been instigated with public funds in the

    hope this would help curb private price cost inflation but with little success.

    (Reinhardt, 2005) One mans cost is anothers income; US citizens pay a lot more

    simply because healthcare is more expensive. A study based on tracer diseases

    including diabetes and lung cancer found they used approximately 30% more

    inputs per capita spending roughly 75% more on increased prices. (Anderson et

    al., 2003)

    Both countries have tried to reduce overuse, underuse and misuse through

    assessing new health technologies and implementing evidence based medicine.

    As Banta (2003 p.121) shows, in the US there have been attempts at state levels

    and by large private insurance companies, however, with no effective nationalco-ordination, HTA activities are carried out in many organisations with different

  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    5/16

    Anthony Woodhead

    goals in mind, often using different methods.whereas the UK established NICE

    in 1999. However due to political difficulties faced in overtly rationing health,

    these organisations shy away from it and the elephant-in-the-corner remains

    cost containment. (Fuchs et al., 2007) As NICE (2008 p.9) indicate, statutory

    instruments and directions do not allow (them) to take budgetary impact or

    affordability into account when advising on cost effectiveness. In 2003 itbecame a legal requirement that funding for all positive advice be made

    available within three months of publication. This has led to pressure on PCTs to

    fund new technologies with marginal benefit at the expense of increasing

    funding to more cost effective areas. (Maynard, 2005(a)) Rationing is an

    anathema to private healthcare; however the state of Oregon did attempted to

    explicitly ration public healthcare mathematically. Here to there were also

    problems as patient and government pressure forced managers to move services

    up and down the list by hand. Results were modest; however the amount of

    people without coverage was reduced from 18% to 11%. (Oberlander, 2001)

    Public Health and social networks; bridging the gap between structure

    and agency

    US health problems are amplified by the lack of universal coverage; this alone

    goes a long way in explaining their slightly reduced life expectancy; slightly

    greater infant mortality and much smaller reduction in preventable deaths

    compared with the UK. Public health problems correlate with inequality not

    income. Willkinson & Pickett (2009 p.111) show people in more equal societies

    live longer, a smaller proportion of children die in infancy and health is better

    (see appendix). The social determinants of health have been known about for

    some time. Marmot et al., (1978 p.249) found the lowest grade civil servants had

    a mortality rate three times higher than those in the highest grade; concluding

    "more attention should be paid to the social environments, job design, and the

    consequences of income inequality." Recent US work into social networks by

    Christakis & Fowler (2007 p.376) quantifies the strength of social networks,

    showing for example among married couples, when an alter became obese, the

    spouse was 37% more likely to become obese. Successful public health

    management requires multifaceted approaches at a societal level but this is hard

    to achieve and both systems struggle, the US in particular. (Marmot, 2010)

    Equity equality and path dependant constraints

    Klein argues (2005) once a particular system takes root it can be calculated with

    some certainty as being more costly to change in comparison to any benefits

    that might potentially be gained. Believing that by eschewing private funding the

    NHS deprives itself of potential additional income and by having a fundamentally

    top down approach, which ultimately constrains choice; it is less effective at

    maximising returns when given more money.

    A World Health Report (2000) ranked the US 37 th out of 191 countries, coming

    top for responsiveness, with the UK coming in 26th here and 18th overall. By its

    controversial measures the UK fell short for offering to little choice and the US fornot providing universal coverage. Many US citizens argue they happily pay for

  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    6/16

    Anthony Woodhead

    what they want; they earn more so any net benefit comes at reduced cost to

    them and as early adopters they subsidise others as new technologies eventually

    trickle-down to the less well-off at lower cost. (Reinhardt, 2005) With any

    comparative analysis best comes down to a matter of perspective and reform is

    limited by path dependencies; bringing into question the validity of such an

    approach. The second part of this essay will turn to analysing this.

    Part 2: A Critical Appraisal of Comparative analysis

    By The Numbers

    Since much of my analysis has drawn on health economic arguments it should

    come as no surprise that I ere towards the positivist camp. I believe in the

    scientific method, OXO, where Observation (O), combined with a perturbation (X)

    along with a control allows for analysis of changes and if measured correctly, this

    change can be attributed to the perturbation within know uncertainty proving

    causation. (Pawson and Tilly, 1997)

    Comparative analysis is at the core of hard science and its rigour produces

    some profound findings in healthcare. It has helped show the relative effects of

    aging, discounting it alone as a major cost driver and in the work of Christakis

    and Fowler (2007) allowed for comparison against a theoretical network that

    would arise if distribution were random, proving the large strength of social ties

    in obesity. However there is a problem in comparing only the US and UK by the

    numbers because the US is so often an outlier and an N value of only two often

    proves little. This is evident in Wilson and Pickets graphs; the trend, both

    between and within nations, only becomes apparent though analysing groups ofcountries, or states. (Mills et. al, 2006)

    Through meta-analysts, science looks to build up bodies of evidence and theories

    are only valuable if they provide repeatable results. However with social science

    it is difficult to control for all factors, making attributing causation problematic.

    McLaughlin (2001) argues social constructs based on associations and

    interactions can never be be neutral representations of reality, but are part of

    complex networks of both technology and social relationships. (in Green, 2000,

    p. 454) Difference between Evidence based Medicine and Evidence based

    Management highlight the issue well and Morrell (2007) provides a particularlyinteresting polemic against the narrative of this approach. Since the aim of

    building evidence based on stocks of knowledge can ultimately be traced to

    ideological concepts of positivism, he suggests calls for a paradigm shift from ad

    hoc to coherent research programs and increased systemic reviews of evidence

    based management are fundamentally are intriguing, self-referential paradoxes

    that follow a traditional narrative review format, whilst simultaneously calling

    the value of such research into question.(p.624) He argues that moves towards

    normal science which has a higher degree of paradigmatic consensus and

    where there is less debate over first principles (p.621) are rather a form of

    physics envy which he terms physician envy in the healthcare context. This is

  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    7/16

    Anthony Woodhead

    why I think numbers often seem more descriptive in social science; though

    science argues this is a reductionist form of analysis.

    Context remains king but methods can be mixed.

    As Pawson and Tilly (1997) highlight, the difference in the social sciences isContext + Mechanism = Outcome (CMO). Since it is impossible to control against

    everything, the effect of any management initiative taken from one country and

    introduced to another will always differ simply because the environment differs.

    This has been evident with different US states, binging into question the validity

    of comparing the UK against a nation of nations. (Mills et. al, 2006) The OECD

    caution:

    Adaption can be assisted by learning from other governments but, unless

    countries are very similar indeed, learning will work better at the level of

    system dynamics than at the level of instruments and specific practices.

    (2005, p. 13)

    Hypothesising that comparative analysis is generally more useful in accounting

    for macro level mechanisms. However I feel there argument can also fall down at

    the micro level. The closer evidence based management gets to evidence based

    medicine the more context is controlled. With clinical medicine occasionally we

    know exactly what should be done but are slow to act and even prevented from

    doing so for a variety of contextual reasons discussed in part one. Radical

    relativism argues attempts are ultimately futile, since context and perspective

    are everything. (Hantrais, 1999) I am unwilling to fully concede to this. I feel

    some dynamics of complexity science apply to healthcare management. Socalled butterfly-effects, mean even small changes in context yield large

    difference in outcomes; however results are determinable, to a limited extent, in

    an admittedly extremely complex, non-linear fashion. Hence some macro level

    concepts influence the system greatly allowing broadly predictable outcomes, as

    the OECD highlight. (Gleick, 1987)

    With regard to public health, Tan et al., (2005 p.43) discuss how historically

    public health management was about identifying the cause of a disease usually

    traced back to an acute infection. With advances in our understanding of health

    todays epidemics have fuzzier boundaries being a result of the interplay of

    genetic predisposition, environmental context, and particular life styles.The

    limits this complexity places on management means in the short term it is also

    feasible to introduce a degree of perturbation, measure small changes and

    observe some limited connections. However in the long term management must

    be social in the sense that consensus on broadly acceptable course of action

    must be agreed upon and worked towards.

    Since Willkinson and Picketts (2009) work shows equity having strong correlation

    over a large range of variables in health-outcomes it be what chaos theory terms

    a strange-attractor of health; strange as it cant be fully differentiated, limiting

    predictability. When combined with the work of Christakis and Fowler (2007) thisgives limited insight as to social causes, a small inroad in bridging the macro-

  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    8/16

    Anthony Woodhead

    micro gap. Mason (2006 p.23) believes mixing qualitative methods with

    quantitative structure helps us to think beyond the micro-macro divide, and to

    enhance and extend the logic of qualitative explanationBy meshing or linking

    rather than integrating we can develop multi-nodal dialogic explanations that

    allow the distinctiveness of different methods and approaches to be held in

    creative tension.Though it is positivistic to say so, I feel such approaches havemuch merit.

    However, results are never neutral in the sense that they can be judged from

    differing perspectives. The use of absolute compared to percentage figures also

    gives rises to debate about relative attribution. In absolute terms Americans

    clearly spend more on healthcare than the UK but by thinking about this in

    proportion to their total earnings the difference is reduced. (Mills et. al, 2006)

    Comparative analysis is rarely performed for purely academic reasons; often the

    goal is for convergence toward what is perceived, and presented as best

    evidence based practice. Pollitt (2001 p.491) argues we should distinguishbetween different stages of policy: discourse, decisions, practice and results;

    with each requiring different research strategies; decisions being the most

    straightforward and results is the most difficult. This has been evident in the

    analysis; the political rhetoric is relatively easy to distinguish as were the

    intentions of reform however there was much debate as to best practice and the

    merits of results.

    Conclusion

    Part one indicated how even two fundamentally different systems experienced

    similar problems in managing the health of their citizens. It was found that

    increasing spending on healthcare in both systems was mainly related to our

    increasing ability to consume it, particularly in the latter stages of life. Rationing

    was shown to be difficult in both systems with reform often being a protracted

    affair, yielding limited improvement. It was argued that many reasons the US

    experiences reduced returns on investment was due to the fact their society is

    less equal and coverage is not universal.

    Part two briefly discussed the nature of evidence in social science and the

    difficulties in controlling against context and determining causation. Pollitts

    framework was found to be particularly useful in differentiating between rhetoric,intentions, actions and results and it was decided that whilst it might be possible

    to adopt scientific management in the short term, particularly with evidence

    based practise; in the long term management decisions must be about social

    consensus. It was argued by mixing quantify with qualitative methods the value

    of comparative analysis to policy makers could be increased.

    Ultimately there is merit in comparing two radically different systems, mainly

    because it helps highlight universal problems in managing healthcare, regardless

    of whether the goals are libertarian or egalitarian. However, since health

    correlates much more with equality than cost, I cant help but wonder if this

    analysis has been comparing the wrong divide. It seems somehow fitting to end

  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    9/16

    Anthony Woodhead

    with words from a Conservative Prime Minister: Two nations between whom

    there is no intercourse and no sympathy; who are as ignorant of each others

    habits, thoughts, and feelings, as if they were dwellers in different zones, or

    inhabitants of different planets: the rich and the poor. (Disraeli, 1845)

  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    10/16

    Anthony Woodhead

    Bibliography

    ACP - American College of Physicians (2008) . Achieving a high-performance

    health care system withuniversal access: what the united states can learn fromother countries. Annals of Internal Medicine 2008 January 1;148(1):5575.

    Anderson, G. Reinhardt, U. Hussey, P and Petrosyan, P. (2003) Its the prices,

    stupid: why the united states is so different from other countries. Health Affairs

    22(3):89-105

    Banta, D. (2003) The development of health technology assessment. Health

    Policy 63 121-132

    Brennan, T. and Mello, M. (2009) Incremental health care reform. JAMA.

    301(17):1814-1816

    Blank, R and Burau, V. (2007) Comparative health policy. Palgrave: London

    Christakis, N. and Fowler, J. (2007) The spread of obesity in a large social

    network over 32 years. NEJM 357(4):370-379

    Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care (2006) CMS-FDA collaborative. a report by the

    dartmouth atlas of health care cms-fda collaborative. Available at

    http://www.dartmouthatlas.org [Accessed 8th March 2010]

    Disraeli, B (1845) Sybil or the two nations. London

    Emanuel, E; Fuchs, V; Garber, A (2007) essential elements of a technology and

    outcomes assessment initiative. JAMA. 298(11):1323-1325

    Garber, A and Skinner, J. (2008) Is american health care uniquely inefficient? J

    Econ Perspect; 22(4): 2750.

    Gleick, J. (1987) Chaos: making a new science. Vintage: New York.

    Gray, A. (2005) Population ageing and health care expenditure. Ageing Horizons

    (2)15-20

    Green, J. (2000) Epistemology, evidence and experience: evidence based health

    care in the work of accident alliances, Sociology of Health and Illness 22(4) 453-

    476.

    Hantrais, L. (1999) Contextualization in cross-national comparative research.

    International Journal of Social Research Methodology, 2(2): 93-108

    Klein, R. (2005) The public-private mix in the UK. in the public private mix for

    health pp.43-63 Radcliffe Ltd: Oxfon

    Mason, J (2006) Mixing methods in a qualitatively driven way. Qualitative

    Research 6(9): 9-25

    Maynard, A. (2005(a)) UK healthcare reform: continuity and change In the public

    private mix for health pp. 63-83 Radcliffe Ltd: Oxfon

    Maynard, A. (2005 (b)) Enduring problems in health care delivery. in The public

    private mix for health pp.294- 309 Radcliffe Ltd: Oxfon

    http://www.dartmouthatlas.org/http://www.dartmouthatlas.org/
  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    11/16

    Anthony Woodhead

    Marmor, T. Oberlander, J. and White, J. (2009) The Obama administrations

    options for health care cost control: hope versus reality. Ann Intern Med.

    150:485-489

    Marmot, M. Rose, G. Shipley, M. and Hamilton, P. (1978). Employment grade and

    coronary heart disease in British civil servants. Journal of Epidemiology and

    Community Health 32:244-249

    Marmot, M. (2010) Fair society, healthy lives: the marmot review. Available at

    http://www.ucl.ac.uk/gheg/marmotreview[Downloaded 11th April 2010]

    McLaughlin, J. (2001). EBM and risk - rhetorical resources in the articulation of

    professional identity. Journal of Management in Medicine. 15 (5): 352-363

    Mills, M. Van der Bunt, G. and Bruijn, J. (2006) Comparative research persistent

    problems and promising solutions. International Sociology 21(5): 619631

    Morrell, K. (2007). The narrative of evidence based management: a polemic.

    Journal of Management Studies 45 (3) 613-635

    NICE (2008). National institute for health and clinical excellence: nice response

    to the committee's first report of session 200708 The Stationary Office: London.

    Available online at http://www.parliament.the-stationery-

    office.co.uk/pa/cm200708/cmselect/cmhealth/cmhealth.htm [Downloaded 11th

    January 2010]

    Nolte, E and McKee, M. (2008) Measuring the health of nations: updating an

    earlier analysis. Health Affairs 27(1):5871.

    Nord, E (1992). An alternative to qalys: the saved young life equivalent. BMJ

    305:875-877

    Oberlander, J. Marmor, T. and Jacobs, L. (2001). Rationing medical care: rhetoric

    and reality in the oregon health plan. CMAJ , 164 (11), 1557 1648

    OECD (2005) Modernising government: the way forward. OECD Publishing. ISBN:

    92-64-01049-1

    OECD (2009(a)). Statistics portal. http://stats.oecd.org/viewhtml.aspx?

    queryname=18174&querytype=view&lang=en [Accessed 6th March 2010]

    OECD (2009(b)) Frequently requested data.

    http://www.oecd.org/document/16/0,3343,en_2649_34631_2085200_1_1_1_1,00.

    html [Downloaded 6th March 2010]

    Pawson, R. and Tilley, N. (1997) Realistic evaluation. Sage Publications Ltd:

    London

    Peterson,C and Burton, R. (2007). U.S. health care spending: comparison with

    other OECD countries. Washington DC: Congressional Research Service.

    Pollitt, C. (2001) Clarifying convergence striking similarities and durable

    differences in public management reform. Public Management Review. 3(4): 471-

    492

    Reinhardt, U. (2003) Does the aging of the population really drive the demand

    for health care? Health Affairs 22(6):27:39

    http://www.ucl.ac.uk/gheg/marmotreviewhttp://www.ucl.ac.uk/gheg/marmotreview
  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    12/16

    Anthony Woodhead

    Reinhardt, U. (2005) The mix of public and private payers in the US health

    system. in the public private mix for health pp.83- 117 Radcliffe Ltd: Oxfon

    Tan, J. Wen, J. and Awad, N. (2005) Health care and services delivery systems as

    complex adaptive systems. Communications of the acm. 48(5): 36-44

    Walshe, K & Smith, J. (2006) Healthcare management. Maidenhead: OpenUniversity Press

    Wellards. (2008) Wellards NHS guide 2008. JMH Publishing Ltd, East Sussex

    World Health Report WHO (2000). The world health report 2000 - health

    systems: improving performance. Available at http://www.who.int/whr/2000/en/

    [Downloaded 8th March 2010]

    Willkinson & Pickett (2009). The spirit level: why more equal societies almost

    always do better. London: Allen Lane. Slides available from

    http://equalitytrust.org [Downloaded 8th March 2010]

    NB The Title, unreferenced, is the opening line from William ShakespearesRomeo and Juliet. 1597 and this essay was largely written before Obama,

    thankfully, managed to pass a health care reform bill, but obviously before

    any papers were available analysing its effects.

    Appendix

    HTA- Health Technology Assesment

    NICE- National Institute for Health and Clinical Excellence

    QAF- Quality and Assessments FrameworkOECD-Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

    PCT- Primary Care Trusts

    U.S. state abbreviations:

    Alabama: ALAlaska: AKArizona: AZArkansas: ARCalifornia: CA

    Colorado: COConnecticut: CTDelaware: DEFlorida: FLGeorgia: GAHawaii: HIIdaho: IDIllinois: ILIndiana: INIowa: IAKansas: KSKentucky: KY

    Louisiana: LAMaine: MEMaryland: MDMassachusetts: MAMichigan: MI

    Minnesota: MNMississippi: MSMissouri: MOMontana: MTNebraska: NENevada: NVNew Hampshire: NHNew Jersey: NJNew Mexico: NMNew York: NYNorth Carolina: NCNorth Dakota: ND

    Ohio: OHOklahoma: OKOregon: ORPennsylvania: PASouth Carolina: SC

    South Dakota: SDTennessee: TNTexas: TXUtah: UTVermont: VTVirginia: VAWashington: WAWest Virginia: WVWisconsin: WIWyoming: WY

    Willkinson & Pickett (2009) graphs are created from statistical sources andmethods detailed in full at:

    http://www.who.int/whr/2000/en/http://equalitytrust.org/http://www.who.int/whr/2000/en/http://equalitytrust.org/
  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    13/16

    Anthony Woodhead

    http://www.equalitytrust.org.uk/why/evidence/methods [Accessed 25th March

    2010]

    The site states:

    In our book, for all of our international comparisons, we use the 20:20 ratiomeasure of income inequality from the United Nations Development Programme

    Human Development Indicators, 2003-6. As survey dates vary for different

    countries (from 1992 to 2001), and as the lag time for effects will vary for the

    different outcome we examine, we took the average across the reporting years

    2003-6. For the US comparisons we use the 1999 state-level Gini coefficient

    based on household income produced by the US Census Bureau. Sources:

    United Nations Development Program. Human development report. New York:

    Oxford University Press, 2003, 2004, 2005, 2006.

    US Census Bureau. Gini ratios by state, 1969, 1979, 1989, 1999. Washington,DC: US Census Bureau, 1999 (table S4).

    http://www.equalitytrust.org.uk/why/evidence/methodshttp://www.equalitytrust.org.uk/why/evidence/methods
  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    14/16

    Anthony Woodhead

  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    15/16

    Anthony Woodhead

  • 8/8/2019 UK v's US Healthcare

    16/16

    Anthony Woodhead