tying, entry, and competition in investment banking

31
Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking Christian Laux J.W. Goethe-University Frankfurt Uwe Walz J.W. Goethe-University Frankfurt * March 2004 Abstract We analyze the role that tying credit and fee business has for the entry and compe- tition in investment banking. Specialized investment banks that offer only investment banking services earn a rent that induces them not to renege on their promise to offer high quality service. Entering this lucrative market is impossible for firms that (ini- tially) have higher costs of providing services because the higher costs result in higher incentives to shirk. Tying provides additional incentives as the value of risky debt is adversely affected if low quality advice is provided. Tying allows to enter the invest- ment banking business but at the same time leads to stiffer price competition, reducing the profitability of this business. JEL Classification: G21, G24, D49 Keywords: tying, investment banking, universal banking * Address of authors: Christian Laux, Department of Finance, Mertonstr. 17, 60325 Frankfurt, Ger- many, e-mail: laux@finance.uni-frankfurt.de; Uwe Walz, Department of Economics, Schumannstr. 60, 60325 Frankfurt, Germany, e-mail: [email protected]. 1

Upload: samanthafox

Post on 10-Jun-2015

304 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

Christian Laux

J.W. Goethe-University Frankfurt

Uwe Walz

J.W. Goethe-University Frankfurt∗

March 2004

Abstract

We analyze the role that tying credit and fee business has for the entry and compe-

tition in investment banking. Specialized investment banks that offer only investment

banking services earn a rent that induces them not to renege on their promise to offer

high quality service. Entering this lucrative market is impossible for firms that (ini-

tially) have higher costs of providing services because the higher costs result in higher

incentives to shirk. Tying provides additional incentives as the value of risky debt is

adversely affected if low quality advice is provided. Tying allows to enter the invest-

ment banking business but at the same time leads to stiffer price competition, reducing

the profitability of this business.

JEL Classification: G21, G24, D49

Keywords: tying, investment banking, universal banking

∗Address of authors: Christian Laux, Department of Finance, Mertonstr. 17, 60325 Frankfurt, Ger-

many, e-mail: [email protected]; Uwe Walz, Department of Economics, Schumannstr. 60, 60325

Frankfurt, Germany, e-mail: [email protected].

1

Page 2: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

1 Introduction

In the last decade an ongoing process of integration between investment and commercial

banking has been observed in the banking sector of different countries. Most notably, this

has been the case in the US where this process was facilitated by the gradual relaxation of

the legal barriers between the two sectors of the banking industry. Until the mid 1990s the

Glass-Steagall act was the main barrier for combining investment and commercial banking

in the US. Therefore, firms in the world’s main capital market were not able to purchase the

services of commercial and investment banking from a single bank. On the same grounds,

commercial banks were not able to enter the often considered highly profitable investment

banking sector (and vice versa). While the sharp division of the Glass-Steagall act between

the two sectors de facto has been hollowed out already earlier, it took until 2000, until the

US Congress abolished the act entirely.

There is ample empirical evidence that since the 1990s, the degree of tying of fee-related

business of investment banks (underwriting equity and bond issues, M&A etc.) and credit

business of commercial banks has substantially increased (Drucker and Puri (2003)). Em-

pirical studies and stories in the popular press (see, e.g., Cairns et al. (2002)) suggest that

there are two directions. On the one hand, universal banks tend to use their balance sheet

(i.e., their capability to provide loans to firms) to acquire market share in the investment

banking sector: universal banks demand fee business in return for credit. On the other hand,

some clients seem to demand credit in return for fee business.

This leads us to the two main questions of our analysis:

1. Why does tying occur?

2. Who benefits from tying and what are the consequences of it?

The starting point of our analysis is an incentive problem in investment banking. To

provide investment banks with incentives to exert costly effort to provide high quality service,

2

Page 3: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

they have to earn a rent. The rent stems from high fees that are paid for investment

banking services. If an investment bank shirks on the quality of its advice, it stands to

lose its reputation, future business, and rent that goes along with it. The existence of this

incentive problem and the resulting rent make the investment banking business lucrative

and worthwhile for commercial (universal) banks to enter even if they (initially) have higher

costs of providing high quality service. However, the problem is that even if it is worthwhile

for entrants to provide service at the same price as incumbents, it is not possible to enter the

investment banking market. The reason is that the higher costs of providing service increase

incentives to shirk on the quality. Firms foresee that an entrant would shirk on the quality

of advice and therefore not obtain advice from an entrant.

Providing an investment banking client with credit tightens incentives to provide high

quality advice: as the quality of advice affects firm value it also affects the value of risky

debt; shirking on the quality of advice reduces the value of the outstanding debt. A universal

bank can therefore use tied deals to tighten incentives and to enter the investment banking

market. This is the bright side of tied deals. However, there is also a dark side for providers

of investment banking services. With tied deals it is possible to reduce the advisory fee as

debt substitutes for rent in providing incentives. Therefore, competition reduces the rent

to be earned in investment banking in tied deals. A lower bound is set to the rent only by

constraints on how much debt can be provided.

We derive the following empirical implications: (i) Tying is particularly important for

universal banks that have a cost disadvantage over specialized investment banks. (ii) Firms

that obtain tied deals have higher debt levels as a high debt capacity is required for debt

to provide sufficient incentives. (iii) Tying leads to more aggressive pricing, reducing the

profitability of the fee business. (iv) Tying can be used to provide advice when its marginal

profitability is lower than the rent that induces specialized investment banks to provide

high quality advice. (v) Universal banks are more willing to provide risky debt (or credit

3

Page 4: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

lines) if this allows them to sell fee business. (vi) Markets for investment banking services

are segmented with specialized investment banks providing services for which they have a

comparative (cost) advantage to firms with low debt capacity, and universal banks offer tied

deals for ”standard” service provided to firms with high debt capacity.

Our paper is closely related to an extensive literature that analyzes the implications of

commercial banks entering the investment banking business. (See Rajan (1996) for a survey.)

A dominant theme in this literature are information externalities: banks monitor firms to

which they provide credit, which gives them a comparative cost advantage in also providing

information-sensitive fee business. But information spillover can also be a source for potential

conflicts of interest, that are, for example, discussed by Benston (1990), Kroszner and Rajan

(1994), Puri (1994, 1999), and Kanatas and Qi (1998). In our paper there is an incentive

spillover: debt provides incentives to offer high quality advice; this can provide a competitive

advantage even if the costs of producing the service are higher as it aligns incentives.

Kanatas and Qi (2003) show that a universal bank’s incentives to exert underwriting

effort might be low because, if underwriting fails, the bank has a comparative advantage in

providing credit to the firm as it already invested in acquiring information about the client.

In contrast, a specialized investment bank is not able to provide credit if underwriting fails

and has higher incentives to avoid failure. Kanatas and Qi do not address tying. Instead, it

focuses on credit and underwriting as substitutes: credit is used at then prevailing conditions

if underwriting fails, which reduces a universal bank’s incentives. In contrast, we discuss the

situation where credit and investment banking service are both provided simultaneously. In

this case tying (i.e., providing credit or a credit line at fixed terms by the underwriter at the

time or prior to underwriting) increases the universal bank’s incentives.

The recent empirical analysis of Drucker and Puri (2003) can be regarded as an empirical

”complement” to our paper. By using a data set for the 1996-2001 period they analyze the

empirical relevance of tying as well as the manner in which tying occurs. Furthermore, they

4

Page 5: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

analyze the consequences of tying on the parties involved as well as on financing costs. They

clearly show the empirical relevance of tying. The relation between their empirical results

and our analysis is discussed later in this paper.

Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1994) were the first to discuss the implications on reputation

concerns in investment banking. We choose a simpler model of reputation in investment

banking as a starting point to analyze incentives stemming from credit provision as a com-

plement to reputation.

There are also some obvious links between our approach and the literature on tying in the

industrial organization literature. A number of papers in that area provide arguments that

a policy of a incumbent supplier of two complementary products may deter entry by making

the prospects of entry less attractive and certain (see Choi and Stefanidis (2001)).1 In our

paper, tying, just has the opposite effect: it serve as an entry-inducing device. The main

mechanism of our paper, namely that lending acts a bonding mechanism which prevents

shirking is reminiscent to analyses in the labour market literature (see e.g. Lazear (1979)

and Allen et al. (1993)).

The paper is organized as follows. In the next section we outline our main set-up. There

we describe the incentive problem on which our analysis is based. In section three we analyze

the competition among investment banks alone and look into the possibility of entry of a

commercial bank in the absence of tying. The fourth section is devoted to an analysis of

tying and entry of commercial banks in the absence of capacity constraints. The fifth section

introduces upper limits on the provision of risky debt by commercial banks and looks into

the consequences of this on market equilibrium. The sixth section discusses the empirical

implications of our model. In section seven we discuss the robustness and extensions.

1Other papers stress the potential of tying as an entry-deterring device, as well (see e.g. Whinston (1990)

and Carlton/Waldman (2002)).

5

Page 6: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

2 Model

There is an infinite number of periods and three types of players. First, in each period

there is a large number of owners (firms) with access to new projects. To realize their

projects, firms need financing; in addition, they may seek investment banking advice. Second,

investment banks are specialized in advising clients on IPOs, M&As, financing decisions, etc.

(fee-business). Third, commercial banks are specialized in lending (credit business). But

commercial banks might also consider entering the fee-business (universal banks).

All parties are risk neutral and the risk-free rate of return is r.

Owners can seek advice from a specialized investment bank or the investment bank branch

of a universal bank to increase expected profits.

Projects and advice: We consider the simplest setting possible. Each project requires

an investment I and realizes either a high payoff π (success) or a low payoff π (failure),

with π > I > π. The success probability θ depends on the quality of advice provided by

the investment bank. There are only two quality levels, high and low, θ ∈ {θh, θl}, with

θh > θl. θl can be realized without an investment bank. Providing high quality advice is

costly for investment banks while the costs of choosing low quality are normalized to zero.

High quality is not verifiable by a court. Therefore, incentives have to be provided to the

”investment bank” to choose high quality advice. This stylized incentive problem is at the

heart of our analysis.

For convenience it is assumed that investment, advice, and profit realization all occur at

the same time. Therefore, there is no discounting within periods. Projects have a positive

net present value even without advice, i.e., given θl.

Costs of high quality advice: Specialized investment banks’ cost of high quality advice

is denoted by c (per unit of advice). Commercial banks that want to enter investment

banking can produce the same quality of advice. But their costs of giving high quality

6

Page 7: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

advice are initially c̄U and strictly higher than the costs of specialized investment banks,

c. But eventually the costs fall to cU ((1 + r)c > cU ≥ c). The differences in the costs of

producing high quality advice might be due to learning, initial setup cost, specialization, etc.

It is assumed that high quality advice is advantageous for firms even if produced at c̄U , i.e.,

θhπ + (1− θh)π − c̄U > θlπ + (1− θl)π.

Rearranging yields

∆(π − π) > c̄U , (1)

with ∆ ≡ (θh − θl).

Financing: The firm has no funds of its own. It can finance the project with debt and

equity. We do not model the cost of providing credit but assume that these costs are

(much) higher for investment banks than for commercial banks. It is therefore very costly

for investment banks to provide loans. Both types of banks are assumed to have prohibitive

costs of investing equity on their own. However, high-quality advice from an investment

bank enables the firm to raise external equity.

Debt and external equity are competitively priced and the expected repayment equals

the amount raised. Hence, assuming a firm raise B through bank borrowing and E through

issuing equity, the debt repayment obligation D ≤ π is

B = θiD + (1− θi) min{π, D}

and the share α ≤ 1 in the firm’s equity is

E = α[θi(π −D) + (1− θi) max{0, π −D}],

where θi is the equilibrium choice of advice quality that debt holders and equity holders

correctly anticipate. To finance the project, the firm has to raise B + E ≥ I; excess capital,

B + E − I > 0, is paid out to initial owners.

7

Page 8: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

3 No tying: independent financing and investment ad-

vice

The base case of the model is set up such that there is no difference between debt and equity

for the firm if there is no tying. The firm obtains either debt or equity independent of the

quality of advice. That is, there is no inherent advantage of one source of financing over the

other. Of interest are the incentives for providing high quality advice.

Incentives and ”reputation” in investment banking: We first analyze the case where

there are only specialized investment banks. The chosen quality is not contractible and

explicit monetary incentive schemes are not possible. Investment banks’ incentives to provide

high quality advice stem from their reputation. If they do not provide high quality advice,

they put themselves at the danger of not obtaining future business. Hence, it is essential

that investment banks earn a rent that is at stake. To model the equilibrium we assume

Bertrand competition between N investment banks for mandates of M firms. The sequence

of events in each period is as follows:

1. All investment banks simultaneously quote a price p at which they are willing to offer

advice.

2. Firms choose whether and from which investment bank to obtain advice; mandates are

equally distributed if they are indifferent.

3. Investment banks choose whether to provide high or low quality advice for the indi-

vidual projects for which they provide service.

4. ”The market” observes if an investment bank shirks and provides low quality advice.

The assumptions are chosen to carve out the main arguments in the simplest setting

possible. They are stronger than necessary. For example, there might be some ambiguity

8

Page 9: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

about the quality of advice and low quality advice might be detected with a probability

lower than one. Moreover, we can also allow for monetary incentives as long as they do not

eliminate the investment banks’ rent.

We find:

Lemma 1 The following constitutes a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium:

• All investment banks offer advice at price p∗ = (1 + r)c and choose high quality.

• If (θh−θl)(π−π) ≥ (1+r)c, firms seek advice at price p∗ from an investment bank that

has a history of consistently providing high quality advice. If (θh−θl)(π−π) < (1+r)c,

firms carry out the project without advice.

To derive the equilibrium, we show that the strategies are indeed optimal for investment

banks and firms. When deciding on the optimal level of advice investment banks consider

their expected payoffs from either providing low or high quality. Since providing low quality

on one project results in zero demand for advice in the future, it always pays to shirk on all

mandates (or not at all).2 Let m be the number of customers that each investment bank

obtains in equilibrium. (Ignoring integer problems, m = N/M .) With high quality advice,

an investment bank’s total profit is m(p − c) + m(p − c)/r, where the latter term denotes

the present value of the investment bank’s rent from future business. With low quality the

investment bank’s payoff is mp. Hence, for m(p − c) + m(p − c)/r ≥ mp, it is optimal for

the investment bank to provide high quality advice. Rearranging yields

c ≤ p− c

r, (2)

2If instead we assumed that shirking is observed with a positive probability that is increasing in the

number of projects on which the investment bank shirked, the investment bank might consider shirking on

less than all projects for which it provides advice.

9

Page 10: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

Firms only seek advice if they expect investment banks to provide high quality (i.e., (2)

holds) and if the expected increase in profits exceeds the price for advice (i.e., ∆(π−π) ≥ p).

Moreover, they will seek advice from the investment bank that offers high quality advice at

the lowest price.

p∗ = (1 + r)c is the lowest price for which investment banks have an incentive to choose

high quality. Any deviation from p∗ by individual investment banks results in zero demand.

It is immediately clear that it is not optimal for a firm to choose an investment bank that

offers advice at a price exceeding p∗. But it is also not optimal to choose an investment bank

that offers advice at a price below p∗ because this bank will not choose high quality. The

only reason for undercutting in the current period p∗ (which has no direct implications on the

incentive of the bank) is to increase demand to m̄ > m. But higher demand is only sustained

in future periods if the price remains low, jeopardizing incentives because the future rent is

too low. However, obtaining a higher demand only once (and returning to the equilibrium

price p∗ after one period) also jeopardizes incentives because the saving from not offering

high quality in this period exceeds mc if the demand exceeds m, i.e. m̄c > m(p∗−cr

) = mc.

We assume that ∆(π − π) ≥ (1 + r)c. Therefore, firms benefit from obtaining advice at

price p∗ and investment banks have no incentive to shirk on the quality.

Entry of commercial banks A commercial bank enters the market by quoting a price

at which it is willing to offer advice. If customers are indifferent between the entering

commercial bank and the investment banks, the total demand is split evenly between them.

In this section we assume that the entering commercial bank has a cost disadvantage only

in the first period. That is, c̄U > c at the time of entry and cU = c in all future periods. By

showing that even in this extreme case in which the potential entrant has a cost disadvantage

just in one period, allows us to carve out our main argument as clearly as possible.

In order to compete with investment banks, the commercial bank must not charge a

higher price than p∗. If entry is successful, the future rent from doing business is the same

10

Page 11: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

for the investment bank branch of the universal bank as for specialized investment banks, as

cU = c . Entry is profitable for the entrant if

p− c̄U + (p∗ − c)/r = p− c̄U + c > 0. (3)

Note that we implicitly assume that the entrant has to take on his share of the market

in the first period, resulting in total costs mecU in the first period and a rent from future

operations me(p∗ − c)/r, where me is the number of customers for each investment bank

after entry. In particular, it is not possible to service only one customer in the first period

when cost of production are high. This captures the idea that learning, resulting in lower

costs of providing high quality advice, requires sufficiently many customers.

We assume that (3) is satisfied. That is, a commercial bank is willing to offer advice at

the same conditions as investment banks and to invest the higher costs of providing high

quality advice in the first period. However, the commercial bank is unable to enter the

market.

Proposition 1 Assuming that only the rent from future business provides incentives to

choose high quality, entrants will not receive any business and cannot enter the market char-

acterized in Lemma 1.

Proof: A commercial bank cannot enter the market due to its higher costs of producing

high quality advice at the time of entry, which provides the entrant with higher incentives to

shirk. Comparing the cost savings in the case of shirking with future gains when providing

high quality advice yields:

c̄U >p∗ − c

r= c.

Note that again it is not possible to service only one customer in the first period when cost

of production are high, to reduce incentives to shirk, and then service me customers at cost

c in the next period.

11

Page 12: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

4 The role of combining credit and investment banking

business

4.1 A single commercial bank

For a commercial bank it is possible to enter the investment banking business by tying credit

provision and investment banking advice.

Proposition 2 Assuming that the demand for advice is positive at p∗ = (1 + r)c, a com-

mercial bank can enter the market by simultaneously offering to provide investment advice

at price p∗ and credit with a repayment obligation D, where D satisfies

D > π and

c̄U ≤ (θh − θl)(D − π) + c.

Proof: Providing credit changes the entrant’s expected payoff conditional on the quality

of his advice. The expected payoff is p + θlD + (1 − θl)π if he shirks and p − c̄U + θhD +

(1 − θh)π + p∗−cr

if he provides high quality advice. Comparing the two expressions for

p∗ = (1 + r)c reveals that the entrant has an incentive to provide high quality advice if the

inequality in the Proposition holds, thereby enabling the commercial bank to enter.�

By tying credit provision and advice, the universal bank can increase incentives not to

shirk on the quality of its advice. For D > π, the expected debt repayment decreases

by ∆(D − π) if the universal bank provides low quality advice. This provides additional

incentives to offer high quality advice. Firms are indifferent between (a) buying advice from

a specialized investment bank and obtaining financing in the market and (b) buying advice

from a universal bank that also provides it with credit with a repayment obligation D as

characterized in the Proposition.

12

Page 13: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

The analysis generalizes to future periods: tying is necessary whenever the universal

bank has higher costs of producing high quality. Therefore, if cU > c, tying remains to be

necessary for the universal bank even after entry. Because of the higher costs, the universal

bank has higher incentives to shirk on quality and therefore cannot offer investment banking

advice on a stand alone basis.

Despite the higher cost of producing quality advice, it is worthwhile for the commercial

bank to enter the market, because of the rent that can be earned, if

p∗ − c̄U + (p∗ − cU)/r > 0.

Note that we implicitly assume hat the entry of a commercial bank in the fee business is

not foreseen by specialized investment banks. If investment banks know that a commercial

bank will enter the market next period, they will shirk on the quality of advice because the

entry reduces the number of mandates that each can sell in the future. This in turn reduces

the future rent and therefore the investment bank’s advantage of shirking exceeds the future

rent.3

The Proposition establishes that entry in investment banking is possible through tying.

It does not characterize the universal bank’s optimal strategy. In particular, it was assumed

that the universal bank offers investment banking advice at the same price p∗ as specialized

investment banks. If specialized investment banks deviate from this price, they will obtain

zero demand. This is not true for investment bank branches of commercial banks. Of course,

the commercial bank cannot sell services at a higher price than p∗. But it can offer advice

at a price below p∗ in tied deals to obtain a higher share of the investment banking business.

We can thus state:

3Assuming a constant probability of market entry, β, would not change our qualitative results but lead

to an increase in the equilibrium price. In this case the incentive constraint is mc ≤ (1− β)m(p+ − c)/r +

βmi(p+ − c)/r, where mi < m is the future demand for each investment bank after entry. If the probability

of entry, β, increases, the price p+ must increase as well.

13

Page 14: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

Lemma 2 Without any constraint on the amount of debt that the commercial bank can

provide and with only one commercial bank, the commercial bank will use tying and a price

marginally lower than p∗ to monopolize the market.

The Lemma is not meant to be taken literally. Instead, it shows that it is indeed possi-

ble to use tying to obtain a competitive advantage. But in the present context tying does

not result in higher prices. Tying is akin to introducing an additional (superior) incentive

mechanism. Therefore, two questions arise. First, what happens if more than one commer-

cial bank enter the market and there are multiple competitors with access to the incentive

mechanism? Second, when can universal banks and specialized investment banks (that do

not provide credit) coexist? We approach these two issue in the following.

4.2 Multiple competing commercial banks and no ”capacity con-

straint”

If there is no constraint on the amount of debt that each commercial bank can provide, we

can, without loss of generality, restrict attention to two commercial banks.

Lemma 3 Assume that there is no constraint on the amount of debt that each commercial

bank can use in a tied deal.

1. If there is one commercial bank that entered the market first, this bank offers advice at

price being marginally below p = min{c̄U , p∗} in each period after entry, and the second

commercial bank never enters.

2. If both commercial banks want to enter the market simultaneously and c̄U ≤ p∗, both

banks offer advice at price p = c̄U at the time of entry and p = cU thereafter.

3. If both commercial banks want to enter the market simultaneously and c̄U > p∗, both

14

Page 15: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

banks randomize. In the mixed strategy equilibrium banks enter the market with prob-

ability x = 1− ((c̄u − p∗)r)/(p∗ − cu).

In the following we derive the lemma. (1) If one commercial bank has entered the market

it can monopolize the market with a limit-pricing strategy. Investment banks cannot offer

advice at a price below p∗ and the second commercial bank has no incentive to enter the

market at a price below c̄U . Therefore, a price marginally below min{c̄U , p∗} keeps both out

of the market.

(2) When both commercial banks enter the fee business, Bertrand competition leads to

(marginal) cost pricing in all periods.

(3) Given c̄U > p∗, commercial banks have to charge a price below c̄U for advice at the time

of entry. But if both enter, their future rent is zero because of Bertrand competition, making

it not profitable for both to choose a price below c̄U to enter. Hence, they will randomize

between ”entering the market and offering advice at price p∗” and ”not entering”. If only

one offers advice, the continuation game is as characterized in part (1) of the lemma, market

entry is profitable for this bank. If both enter, they will compete prices down and the costs

of entry into the investment banking business (offering advice at a price below the cost of

producing the advice) are not recovered through future rents. Due to randomization it may

happen that neither of the two banks enter, implying that the continuation game is just a

replication of the present period’s situation. The detailed derivation of the mixed strategies

used is delegated to the appendix.

Of course, the setting is rather stylized. But we believe that the main insights generalize:

Tying credit and advice allows commercial banks to enter the market. This is the bright side

of tied deals. However, competition between commercial banks leads commercial banks to

use tied deals in the future as well and to lower prices for advice. This price reduction that

is possible through tied deals reduces the profitability of the investment banking business.

Indeed, it can result in situations where entry in the market results in a loss. This is the

15

Page 16: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

dark side of tying. We will discuss two potential ”remedies” to this dark side of tying in the

next chapter.

5 On the coexistence of tied and non-tied deals

Without any constraint on the maximum amount of debt that a commercial bank can use

in tied deals, it can always ensure that its incentive constraint is fulfilled: by choosing

D = π the commercial bank internalizes the effect of high quality advice. Since we assume

(1 + r)c > cU , the commercial bank is able to capture the entire market by choosing a price

below p∗ = (1+r)c. We will depart from this extreme setting and look into the consequences

of possible constraints on the amount of debt that can be used (either because individual

projects have a debt capacity or because commercial banks have a constraint on how much

risky debt they can lend).

5.1 Constraint on the maximum debt level for individual projects

A high level of risky debt provides incentives to the commercial bank but will go along with

increased costs of financial distress and distorted incentives for the firm. Therefore, it is costly

to finance projects with very high levels of debt. We model these costs as a risk shifting

problem that constrains the amount of debt that can be used in tied deals. We now assume

that there is a second type of project that the firm can choose. The alternative project

realizes a higher payoff in the case of a success, π2 (π2 > π). But it has a lower expected

payoff, due to a lower probability of success. The success probability of the alternative

project is given by qθi (i = h, l), with q < 1. Indeed, we assume that the alternative project

has a negative net present value (even with high quality advice) and that it is not worthwhile

to finance this project (even for an entrant in the investment banking business).

Therefore, the debt level must be low enough not to provide incentives for the firm to

16

Page 17: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

choose project 2, i.e., D must satisfy

θh(π −D) ≥ qθh(π2 −D)

and the maximum debt repayment where the firm still chooses project 1 is given by

D̂ = (π − qπ2)/(1− q). (4)

We assume in the following that risk shifting does not impede debt financing altogether, i.e.

D̂ > π always holds.

D̂ constitutes an upper limit on the debt level that can be used in tied deals. With

such an upper limit we will observe potential market segmentation. Firms for which the

debt capacity is sufficiently high will be natural clients of universal banks providing tied

deals. Firms which have a low D̂ are typically advised by investment banks (and seek equity

financing). We will investigate this market segmentation in more detail now.

5.1.1 Market segments

Projects may now differ in two dimensions, their success probability’s sensitivity to high

quality advice, ∆ ≡ (θh−θl) ∈ (0, 1), and the maximum debt capacity D̂ ∈ (π, π) (stemming

from differences in the risk shifting problem). The number of projects with a given set

of parameters (∆, D̂) remains constant across periods. The characteristics (∆, D̂) of each

project are observed by the market. All types of projects have a positive net present value

even without advice, i.e., with θl. (We assume that there are sufficiently many firms for

which advice is efficient even if produced at high costs, i.e., for which (1) holds.)

If firms expect high quality advice to be provided, they demand advice at price p if

∆(π − π) ≥ p.

Without tying the market price is p∗ = (1 + r)c and specialized investment banks can

service firms for which ∆ is sufficiently high, i.e.,

∆(π − π) ≥ (1 + r)c (5)

17

Page 18: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

Therefore, some firms, with a low expected increase in profitability due to advice, will not

seek advice because of the high price that has to be paid.

Universal banks can offer advice at price p to firms for which (cU , θh, D̂) satisfies

cU ≤ ∆(D̂ − π) + (p− cU)/r. (6)

But firms will only seek advice from commercial banks at a price p ≤ p∗ = (1 + r)c.

Substituting p∗ and rearranging yields

(1 + r)(cU − c)/r ≤ ∆(D̂ − π). (7)

(7) is a necessary condition for universal banks to be able to compete with specialized

investment banks for customers with characteristics (cU , ∆, D̂). The left hand side of the

condition stems from the higher incentive to shirk at price p∗ due to its higher costs of

producing high quality advice. The right hand side resembles the higher incentive to provide

high quality advice with a tied deal for which D = D̂.

Clearly, if cU = c, universal banks can compete with investment banks without using

tied deals, i.e., the investment banking branch can survive on its own. But tied deals allow

commercial banks to undercut the price of specialized investment banks.

Whenever a universal bank has a cost disadvantage over a specialized investment bank

in producing high quality advice, i.e., cU > c, the universal bank has to offer advice through

tied deals. A universal bank’s ability to compete with specialized investment banks depends

on the parameters (cU , ∆, D̂): it decreases in cU , increases in ∆, and increases in D̂.

We can distinguish four market segments.

Segment 1: All combinations of (cU , ∆, D̂) for which (5) and (7) are satisfied. This

market segment will be taken over by the universal bank. It involves fee business from firms

with sufficiently high debt capacity for which the universal bank’s cost disadvantage is not

too high and that has a large impact on profitability.

Segment 2: All (cU , ∆, D̂) for which (7) is satisfied but not (5). This market segment

does not seek advice from specialized investment banks because of the high price required

18

Page 19: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

to induce investment banks to provide high quality. A universal bank can use tied deals

to reduce the price while retaining incentives to provide high quality. Therefore, if a firm’s

debt capacity is sufficiently high, universal banks can provide these firms with advice that

has low impact on profitability (low ∆) provided that the cost of providing this advice is not

too high. This will be ”standard advice with low marginal profitability” but that potentially

makes up a large fraction of the market potential.

As it is likely that individual firms have several occasions where they would use advice

but where advice profitability is low, servicing this market segment will lead to repeated

business at lower price in tied deals.

Segment 3: All (cU , ∆, D̂) for which is satisfied (5) but not (7). In this segment universal

banks cannot compete with specialized investment banks. This segment involves deals for

which the cost difference cU − c (i.e., the comparative advantage of investment banks) is

rather pronounced to firms with low debt capacity. Examples include specialized advice to

start-up firms and IPOs.

Segment 4: All (cU , ∆, D̂) for which (5) and (7) are both not satisfied. This market

segment will not seek (obtain) high quality advice.

We can summarize these findings in the following proposition.

Proposition 3 Competition between investment and universal banks leads to market seg-

mentation.

• Universal banks use tied deals to sell investment banking services for which its cost

disadvantage is not too large to firms with high debt capacity (segment 1 and 2). This

includes advice that is not profitable enough to be demanded from investment banks

(segment 2).

• Investment banks sell service that has a large impact on a client’s profits and for which

their cost advantage is sufficiently large to firms with low debt capacity.

19

Page 20: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

5.1.2 Profitability of the fee business for universal banks

In the absence of any constraints on debt levels in tied deals, entry of more than one com-

mercial bank eliminates all profits (see Lemma (3)). If an upper limit of the debt level

which can profitably provided exists, this extreme result vanishes: commercial banks have

an incentive to enter the investment banking sector since they can, despite competition from

other universal banks, expect positive profits.

The mechanism behind this is the following. Suppose that more than one commercial

bank has entered the market. With a high enough debt capacity of the firm under consid-

eration, universal banks can guarantee incentive compatibility (i.e. ensuring that they will

provide high quality of advice). This is the case if (6) holds for p = cU . Hence, competition

among universal banks will lead to p = cU implying zero profits for this type of banks. In

contrast, if the incentives stemming from debt are not sufficient to induce universal banks

to choose high quality, universal banks earn a rent: p = cU makes it impossible to announce

credibly the provision of high quality advice and p strictly exceeds cU . In a nutshell, a certain

level of future profits has to be sustained to sustain incentives for high quality advice.

That is, for projects/firms for which

∆(D̂ − π) + (p∗ − cU)/r > cU > ∆(D̂ − π) (8)

and (5) hold, competition among several commercial banks and several investment banks

implies that commercial banks outcompete pure investment banks. The equilibrium price is

p = cU + r[cU −∆(D̂ − π)]. (9)

This, in turn, leads to positive profits for commercial banks in the presence of competition

among entering commercial banks.

We can summarize:

Proposition 4 Universal banks make positive profits on mandates with intermediate incen-

tives stemming from the maximum debt in tied deals ((8) holds). For firms with high incen-

20

Page 21: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

tives stemming from the maximum debt level, Bertrand competition results in zero profits for

universal banks as tying alone is sufficient to sustain incentive.

5.2 Constraint on how many risky projects a commercial bank

can finance

Another reason why a universal bank cannot service the whole market is a constraint on how

many risky debt it can provide. If the debt capacity constrains the number of tied deals that a

commercial bank can offer, it might not be optimal to offer advice at a price below p∗. There

are several reason for capacity constraints for risky debt. Most notably, an universal bank’s

costs of providing an increasing number of firms with risky debt are likely to increase due to

diseconomies of scale in bank size, a bank’s cost of financial distress, and regulation. These

costs impose an upper limit on a bank’s capacity for risky debt provision. In a wider sense,

the existence of a capacity constraint can be interpreted as a representation if an upward-

sloping marginal cost curve. The existence of a capacity constraint thereby delineates the

extreme case: marginal costs become infinite at the capacity level.

In order to explore this issue in more detail, suppose that two universal banks have

entered the investment banking market and compete with investment banks. The universal

banks’ costs of providing advice is cU > c. Both universal banks have limited capacity in

the sense that universal bank i (i = 1, 2) is only able to provide N̄i deals. In the third stage

of our game firms will seek advice only if for a given p

∆(π̄ − π) ≥ p (10)

holds. Furthermore, suppose that, e.g., due to differences in ∆ the impact of advice differs

for different firms. This implies that the demand for (high-quality) advice is price-sensitive.

Those firms/projects for which (10) holds for a given price will ask for advice whereas the

remaining ones will not. We denote this price sensitive demand by M(p) with ∂M/∂p < 0

with the demand function denoted by p = M−1.

21

Page 22: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

Hence, we can state:

Lemma 4 i) If M(p∗) ≥ N̄1 + N̄2, then a unique pure strategy equilibrium exists in which

universal banks charge p∗ or slightly lower. The universal banks will receive mandates from 2N

firms, whereas the remaining ones are split among the investment banks at a price pIB = p∗.

ii) If M(p∗) < N̄1 + N̄2 and if a pure-strategy equilibrium exists, the two universal banks

charge p1 = p2 = p̃ ≡ Max(p(N̄1 + N̄2), cU).

A pure-strategy equilibrium exists in this parameter range if N̄i < Ri(N̄j) ≡ argmax(p(Ni+

N̄j)− cU)Ni with j = 1, 2(i 6= j) or if Ni ≥ M̃ ≡ M(cU).

In the former case only the universal banks receive mandates and make positive profits.

For N̄i ≥ M(cU) Bertrand competition prevails implying zero profit levels for the universal

banks.

Proof : See Appendix.

This Lemma implies that for the case of ”small” capacity levels we find coexistence of

investment and universal banks. But even if universal banks are able to service the whole

market, they might make positive profits. Only for very large capacities the conventional

Bertrand result emerges. In our above discussion we have left out the regime of large capaci-

ties, i.e. the one in which (M(cU) > N̄i > R(N̄j)). In this range a mixed-strategy equilibrium

emerges in the pricing game. Endogenizing the capacity game shows, however, that capacity

levels corresponding to the Cournot-result, leading to a pure-strategy equilibrium, emerge

(see Kreps and Scheinkmann (1982)). Therefore, it is for our purposes superfluous to consider

this type of equilibrium.4

We can summarize:

4This is quite intuitive. The Cournot capacities levels emerges from Max Ni(P (Ni+R(Nj))−cU )−C(Ni)

whereby the last term denotes the costs of capacity installation. Hence, due to these costs (which are sunk

in the price game) the Cournot capacity level (N̄Ci = R1(N̄C

j )) are smaller than the capacity level necessary

for a pure-strategy equilibrium (N̄Ci < R(N̄C

i )) a pure-strategy equilibrium results.

22

Page 23: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

Proposition 5 For low enough capacities p = p∗ (or a price slightly below) emerges and

universal and investment banks coexist. For intermediate capacity levels the universal banks

divide the market among themselves, making positive profits. Only for very large capacities

Bertrand competition prevails leading to zero profits.

This reveals that even in the presence of competition among universal banks there is

still room to benefit from the profitable investment banking business. It is quite obvious

that these expected profits attract further market entry which might, however, be prevented

by high costs of entry (i.e., c̄U), build-up costs of capacity, limited resources (e.g., skilled

bankers) etc.

It also becomes obvious that in order to extract the maximum rent in the fee business,

the universal bank wants to use its capacity from the provision of risky debt. Hence, it will

”not” provide firms with risky debt if theses firms do not also purchase fee business from the

commercial bank’s investment banking branch. It will approach those firms first from which

it expects the most promising fee-business (first market segment).

6 Empirical Implications

This section summarizes the empirical implications.

Implication 1: Tying is particularly important for universal banks that have a cost dis-

advantage over specialized investment banks.

Therefore, tying should be associated with the entry of commercial banks. At the time of

entry cost disadvantages are arguably particularly pronounced. Tied deals allow commercial

banks to enter the investment banking market and to compete against specialized investment

banks in the profitable fee-business.

Implication 2: Firms that obtain tied deals have higher debt levels.

23

Page 24: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

A high debt capacity is required for debt to provide sufficient incentives. Therefore,

tied deals are offered to firms with high debt capacity. Drucker and Puri (2003) provide

supporting evidence. They find tying for firms with low credit rating. Ceteris paribus, a low

credit rating results from a high debt level.

Implication 3: Tying leads to more aggressive pricing of the commercial banks, thereby

reducing the profitability of the fee business.

Tying is associated with lower fees or lower interest (on the tied loan). In our framework

lower interest rates and lower fees are perfectly interchangeable. Drucker and Puri (2003)

find that tied deals are associated with lower fees or lower interest.

Our model predicts that universal banks finance projects with ”high debt capacity”.

These are projects/firms with low costs of high debt level (i.e., information insensitive assets,

little risk shifting capabilities, low growth, e.g., hotel business) and projects with high debt

financing for other reasons (e.g., project financing, LBOs).

Implication 4: Tying can be used to provide advice when its marginal profitability is lower

than the rent that induces specialized investment banks to provide high quality advice.

Tying increases the incentive to return to the market more often and eventually undertake

business with the same universal bank. The reason why firms which receive tied deals would

return to the market more often compared to a situation with an absence of tied deals is

that tied deals are cheaper, thereby making them more attractive. Marginal cost of using

investment banking advice decrease with tying. But there is also an incentive to return to

the same universal bank if a long-term loan has been provided which provides the necessary

incentive for providing high-quality advice at lower price. Therefore, tying leads to repeated

business (between the same universal bank and firm).

Implication 5: Universal banks are more willing to provide risky debt (or credit lines) if

this allows them to sell fee business.

24

Page 25: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

Basically, we provide a rationale for the revival of the credit business which serves as a

door opener for fee business. Therefore, our analysis leads us to expect that for commercial

banks the entrance in the investment banking business should be ceteris paribus be associated

with higher debt levels and more provision of riskier debt.

Implication 6: Markets are segmented.

Universal banks use tied deals to sell investment banking services for which its cost

disadvantage is not too large to firms with high debt capacity. This includes advice that is

not profitable enough to be demanded from investment banks. In contrast, investment banks

sell service that has a large impact on a client’s profits and for which their cost advantage is

sufficiently large to firms with low debt capacity.

Robustness considerations and extensions

Monetary incentives We completely abstracted from monetary incentives in investment

banking services and assumed a flat fee. Of course, this assumption is extreme. Investment

banking services are structured to provide the advisor with incentives to exert effort. For

example, when a firm wants to issue bonds, it hires a bank as an underwriter who guarantees

a fixed amount of proceeds that the issuing firm receives when the bonds are sold to investors.

Thereby the underwriter assumes some of the market risk of placing the bond, providing the

underwriter with incentives to provide effort to place the bonds. However, these incentives

may not be sufficient: even when the total amount is guaranteed, there may be external

effects that are not internalized, e.g., negative effects on the borrower’s reputation in the

capital market for future transactions if the underwriter fails to place the borrower’s debt.

In this case, the issuer’s reputation together with a high price paid for services provides

additional incentives to exert effort. Hence, there is still a role for providing incentives

through debt in tied deals even in this situation, where it is relatively easy to implement

25

Page 26: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

explicit monetary incentives. For other types of services this will be more difficult.

More generally, whenever incentive problems in investment banking services are not com-

pletely internalized at zero rent for the investment banks, there can be a benefit to tying.

The large profits earned in investment banking suggest that there is a rent to be earned.

This rent might stem from imperfect competition but also from incentive problems.

Chen and Ritter (2000) find a very high IPO spreads (7%) paid to investment banks in

the United States. They argue that this spread results in a rent for underwriters and analyze

potential justifications. Interestingly, they find that spreads on IPOs in other countries are

much lower, including Japan and Europe, where universal banks dominate.

Negotiating the terms of investment bank services and firms’ demand for tied

deals In the present paper the market interaction was modelled as a take-it-or-leave-it-

price-offer for investment banking services. In a different market model, where firms ne-

gotiate with investment banks and universal banks, the ability of universal banks to offer

tied deals can reduce the profitability of their investment banking business even when their

constraint to provide risky debt is tight. Firms will explicitly seek tied deals to renegotiate

the price for the advice. This is not possible without tying because the firm must always

fear that if the investment bank accepts price cuts, it will do so for other customers as well

to increase the amount of customers, jeopardizing incentives to provide high quality advice.

This problem does not arise with tied deals where incentives are (also) provided through the

debt repayment obligation.

If the terms of investment banking services are negotiated between the bank and the

client, firms’ want investment banks to also use credit because this allows to reduce the price

of fee business. This is indeed a development that has be observed. As Cairns et al. (2001)

argue: ”Still more worrying for investment banks is the fact that some clients now demand

credit in return for M&A and underwriting business” (p 42).

26

Page 27: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

Appendix

Derivation of mixed strategy equilibrium – Lemma 3.3

With c̄U > p∗ an equilibrium in pure strategies does not exist.

In the entry stage game, the two banks decide upon entering the market or not entering.

The payoff of their simultaneous entry game are depicted as follows:

Prob y 1-y

1/2 Enter Don’t Enter

x Enter a,a a+b, 0

1-x Don’t Enter 0, a+b Vt+1, Vt+1

whereby x and y denote the probabilities of the respective players to enter. If both enter the

payoffs are p∗ − c̄U ≡ a < 0. If one bank enters and the other not, the entering firm receives

p∗ − c̄U + (p∗ − cU ≡ a + b. If neither player enters the same game repeats next period itself

with payoff Vt+1.

Since the two players are symmetric it suffices to look at player 1. Player one is indifferent

between playing Enter and Don’t Enter if:

y · a + (1− y) · (a + b) = (1− y) · Vt+1 (11)

The expected payoff in the present period is:

Vt = xya + x(1− y)(a + b) + (1− y)(1− x)Vt+1

Since Vt = Vt+1 and due to symmetry (i.e. x = y) we obtain:

Vt = Vt+1 =x2a + x(1− x)(a + b)

1− (1− x)2(12)

27

Page 28: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

Plugging (12) into 11 yields after some calculations:

x = y = 1 +a

b

Proof of Lemma 4

i) Competition among investment banks will always lead to p∗. Increasing the price to p∗ does

not pay since it will lead to a discrete reduction in mandates while increasing the price only

marginally. Increasing the price above p∗ even leads to a loss of all mandates. Undercutting

below pUB does not alter the number of mandates and is therefore not profitable. Hence

pUB = p∗ − ε and pI = p∗ is the unique pure-strategy equilibrium.

ii) We consider the case of M(p∗) > N̄1 + N̄2. For this case, we look at the equilibrium prices

which result in a pure-strategy equilibrium (step 1). Then, in step 2 we derive necessary and

sufficient conditions for a pure-strategy equilibrium emerge (step 2).

Step 1: We start from the presumption that a pure strategy equilibrium emerges. First,

suppose p1 = p2 > p̃. Hence, undercutting is profitable, since not all capacities are employed.

Second, suppose p1 = p2 < p̃. If p̃ = cU this is not an equilibrium since is involves losses

(no production is hence better). If p̃ = p(N̄1 + N̄2) rationing occurs. Hence, raising prices

unilaterally therefore increases profits. Last, let’s consider pi < pj. Bank i has an incentive

to increase its price as long as it is capacity constraint. i does not have an incentive to

increase the price of it is the monopoly price (p∗). But then, j has an incentive to undercut.

Hence, p1 = p2 = p̃ emerges in the pure-strategy equilibrium.

Step 2: Suppose N̄i ≤ R(N̄j). In the pure-strategy equilibrium with p̃ = p(N̄1 + N̄2) both

sell their entire capacities. Hence, undercutting does not pay. Overbidding by i implies, by

definition of R(N̄j) that p(N̄j +R(N̄j)) > p̃ = p(N̄1+N̄2), which, in turn, implies R(N̄j) < N̄i

thereby violating our initial presumption. Hence, N̄i ≤ R(N̄j) is a sufficient condition for a

pure-strategy equilibrium to emerge. With N̄i > R(N̄j) we get p(N̄j + R(N̄j) > p(N̄i + N̄j)

contradicting together with step 1 the existence of a pure-strategy equilibrium.

28

Page 29: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

With N̄i > M(cU) we are back to the usual Bertrand case implying p1 = p2 = cU . The

remaining statements follow straightforwardly.

29

Page 30: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

References

Allen, S., R.L. Clark, amd A. A. McDermed (1993), Pensions, Bonding, and Lifetime Jobs,

Journal of Human Resources 28, 463-481.

Benston, G. (1990), The Separation of Commercial and Investment Banking: The Glass-

Steagall Act Revisited and Reconsidered, Oxford University Press.

Cairns, A.J., J.A. Davidson, and M.L. Kisilevitz (2002), The Limits of Bank Convergence,

The McKinsey Quarterly, July 2001, 41-51.

Carlton, D.W., and M. Waldman (1998), The Strategic Use of Tying to Preserve and Create

Market Power in Evolving Industries, RAND Journal of Economics 33(2), 194-220.

Chemmanur, T.J., and P. Fulghieri (1994), Investment Bank Reputation, Information Pro-

duction, and Financial Intermediation, Journal of Finance 49(1), 57-79.

Chen, H.-C., and J. Ritter (2000), The Seven Percent Solution, Journal of Finance 55(3),

1105-1131.

Choi, J. P. and C. Stefanidis (2001), Tying, investment, and the dynamic leverage theory,

RAND Journal of Economics 32(1), 52-71.

Drucker, S. and M. Puri (2003), Tying Knots: Lending to win underwriting business,

Stanford University, mimeo.

Kanatas, G., and J. Qi (1998), Underwriting by Commercial Banks: Incentive Conflicts,

Scope Economies, and Project Quality, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 30(1),

119-133.

Kanatas, G., J. Qi (2003), Integration of lending and underwriting: implications of scope

economies, Journal of Finance 58, 1167-1191.

30

Page 31: Tying, Entry, and Competition in Investment Banking

Kreps, D. and J. Scheinkman (1983), Quantity Precommitment and Bertrand Competition

Yield Cournot Outcomes, Bell Journal of Economics 14, 326-337.

Kroszner, R., and R. Rajan (1994), Is the Glas-Steagall Act justified? A study of the

US experience with universal banking before 1933, American Economic Review 84,

810-832.

Lazear, E. (1979), Why is There Mandatory Retirement? Journal of Political Economy

87(6), 1261-84.

Puri, M. (1994), The long-term default performance of bank underwritten security issues,

Journal of Banking and Finance 18, 397-418.

Puri, M. (1999), Commercial banks as underwriters: implications for the going public

process. Journal of Financial Economics 40, 373-401

Whinston, M.D. (1990), Tying, Foreclosure, and Exclusion, American Economic Review

80, 837-859.

31