topic 1 decision analysis chapter 3

Upload: kent-nice

Post on 02-Mar-2016

133 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

DESCRIPTION

...

TRANSCRIPT

  • Topic 1

    Decision Analysis (Chapter 3)

    Source: Render et al., 2012. Quantitative Analysis Management, 11 editions, Pearson.

  • Learning Objectives

    Students will be able to:

    List the steps of the decision-making process.

    Describe the types of decision-making environments.

    Make decisions under uncertainty.

    Use probability values to make decisions under risk.

  • Chapter Outline 3.1 Introduction

    3.2 The Six Steps in Decision Theory

    3.3 Types of Decision-Making Environments

    3.4 Decision Making under Uncertainty

    3.5 Decision Making under Risk

    3.6 Decision Trees

    3.7 How Probability Values Are Estimated by Bayesian Analysis

    3.8 Utility Theory

  • Introduction

    Decision theory is an analytical and systematic way to tackle problems.

    A good decision is based on logic.

  • The Six Steps in Decision Theory

    1. Clearly define the problem at hand.

    2. List the possible alternatives.

    3. Identify the possible outcomes.

    4. List the payoff or profit of each combination of alternatives and outcomes.

    5. Select one of the mathematical decision theory models.

    6. Apply the model and make your decision.

  • Example: Thompson Lumber Company Case

    John Thompson is the founder and president of Thompson Lumber Company, a profitable firm located in Portland, Oregon.

    The problem that John Thompson identifies is whether to expand his product line by manufacturing and marketing a new product, backyard sheds.

  • Define problem To manufacture or market backyard storage

    sheds

    List alternatives 1. Construct a large new plant

    2. A small plant

    3. No plant at all

    Identify outcomes The market could be favorable or unfavorable

    for storage sheds

    List payoffs List the payoff for each state of nature/decision

    alternative combination

    Select a model Decision tables and/or trees can be used to solve

    the problem

    Apply model and make

    decision

    Solutions can be obtained and a sensitivity

    analysis used to make a decision

    Example: Thompson Lumber Company Case

  • Alternative

    State of Nature

    Favorable

    Market ($)

    Unfavorable

    Market ($)

    Construct a large plant 200,000 -180,000

    Construct a small plant 100,000 -20,000

    Do nothing 0 0

    Example: Thompson Lumber Company Case Decision Table

  • Types of Decision-Making Environments

    Decision making under certainty.

    Decision maker knows with certainty the consequences of every alternative or decision choice.

    Decision making under uncertainty.

    The decision maker does not know the probabilities of the various outcomes.

    Decision making under risk.

    The decision maker knows the probabilities of the various outcomes.

  • Decision Making under certainty:

    Decision makers know within certainty the consequence of every alternative or decision choice.

    E.g.: You have $1000 to invest for a 1-year period. Alternatives are to open a savings or a fixed deposit account paying 3% or 5% interest per year respectively. If both investments are secure and guaranteed, there is a certainty that a fixed deposit will pay a higher return.

  • Decision Making under Uncertainty: Criteria

    Optimistic (Maximax)

    Pessimistic (Maximin)

    Criterion of Realism (Hurwicz)

    Equally likely (Laplace Criterion)

    Minimax Regret (Opportunity Loss or Regret)

  • Alternative

    State of Nature

    Favorable

    Market ($)

    Unfavorable

    Market ($)

    Construct a large plant 200,000 -180,000

    Construct a small plant 100,000 -20,000

    Do nothing 0 0

    Decision Making under Uncertainty

    Example: Thompson Lumber Company Case.

  • Alternative

    State of Nature

    Maximum in

    Row Favorable

    Market ($)

    Unfavorable

    Market ($)

    Construct a large

    plant 200,000 -180,000 200,000

    Construct a small

    plant 100,000 -20,000 100,000

    Do nothing 0 0 0

    Decision Making under Uncertainty: Optimistic (Maximax) Criterion

    Example: Thompson Lumber Company Case

    Optimistic (Maximax)

  • Alternative

    State of Nature

    Minimum in

    Row Favorable

    Market ($)

    Unfavorable

    Market ($)

    Construct a large

    plant 200,000 -180,000 -180,000

    Construct a small

    plant 100,000 -20,000 -20,000

    Do nothing 0 0 0

    Decision Making under Uncertainty: Pessimistic (Maximin) Criterion

    Example: Thompson Lumber Company Case

    Pessimistic (Maximin)

  • Weighted Average = (best in row) + (1- ) (worst in row)

    where: is the coefficient of realism (or the degree of optimism of the decision maker), 0 1.

    Alternative

    State of Nature Weighted

    Average in

    Row

    ( = 0.8)

    Favorable

    Market ($)

    Unfavorable

    Market ($)

    Construct a large

    plant 200,000 -180,000 124,000

    Construct a small

    plant 100,000 -20,000 76,000

    Do nothing 0 0 0

    Decision Making under Uncertainty: Criterion of Realism (Hurwicz) Criterion

    Example: Thompson Lumber Company Case (given = 0.8)

    Criterion of Realism (Hurwicz)

  • Alternative

    State of Nature

    Average in

    Row Favorable

    Market ($)

    Unfavorable

    Market ($)

    Construct a large

    plant 200,000 -180,000 10,000

    Construct a small

    plant 100,000 -20,000 40,000

    Do nothing 0 0 0

    Decision Making under Uncertainty: Equally likely (Laplace) Criterion

    Example: Thompson Lumber Company Case

    Assume all states of nature to be equally likely, choose

    maximum Average.

    Equally likely

    (Laplace)

  • Alternative

    State of Nature

    Favorable Market ($) Unfavorable Market ($)

    Construct a

    large plant 200,000 200,000 = 0 0 (180,000) = 180,000

    Construct a

    small plant 200,000 100,000 = 100,000 0 (20,000) = 20,000

    Do nothing 200,000 0 = 200,000 0 0 = 0

    Step 1: Create an opportunity loss table by subtracting each payoff in the column from the best payoff in the same column.

    Opportunity Loss Optimal payoff Actual payoff

    Decision Making under Uncertainty: Minimax Regret (Opportunity Loss) Criterion

    Example: Thompson Lumber Company Case

  • Alternative

    State of Nature Maximum in

    Row Favorable Market

    ($)

    Unfavorable

    Market ($)

    Construct a large

    plant 0 180,000 180,000

    Construct a

    small plant 100,000 20,000 100,000

    Do nothing 200,000 0 200,000

    Step 2: Choose the minimum alternative out of all the maximum opportunity losses.

    Decision Making under Uncertainty: Minimax Regret (Opportunity Loss) Criterion

    Example: Thompson Lumber Company Case

    Minimax Regret

    (Opportunity Loss)

  • Decision Making under Risk Expected Monetary Value (EMV)

    The probabilities of the states of nature P(S) are known.

    EMV(Alternative) = Payoffs1*P(S1) + Payoffs2*P(S2) ++ Payoffsn*P(Sn)

    Alternative

    State of Nature Expected Monetary Value

    (EMV) Favorable

    Market ($)

    Unfavorable

    Market ($)

    Construct a

    large plant 200,000 180,000

    (200,000)(0.5) +

    (180,000)(0.5) = 10,000

    Construct a

    small plant 100,000 20,000

    (100,000)(0.5) +

    (20,000)(0.5) = 40,000

    Do nothing 0 0 (0)(0.5) + (0)(0.5) = 0

    Probabilities 0.50 0.50

    Example: Thompson Lumber Company Case

  • Alternative

    State of Nature

    Expected Monetary Value

    (EMV) Favorable

    Market, S1 ($)

    Unfavorable

    Market, S2 ($)

    Construct a large plant 200,000 -180,000 10,000

    Construct a small plant 100,000 -20,000 40,000

    Do nothing 0 0 0

    Probabilities 0.50 0.50

    With Perfect

    Information

    Best payoff

    in S1

    200,000

    Best payoff in

    S2

    0

    EVwPI = (200,000)(0.5)

    + (0)(0.5) = 100,000

    Decision Making under Risk Expected Value with Perfect Information (EVwPI)

    Example: Thompson Lumber Company Case

    EVwPI = best Payoffs1*P(S1) + best Payoffs2*P(S2) ++ best Payoffsn*P(Sn)

  • EVPI places an upper bound on what one would pay for additional information.

    EVPI = EVwPI Best EMV

    where:

    EVwPI is Expected Value with Perfect Information.

    Best EMV is expected value without perfect information.

    Decision Making under Risk Expected Value of Perfect Information (EVPI)

  • Decision Making under Risk Expected Value of Perfect Information (EVPI)

    Hence, the EVPI = EVwPI best EMV

    = 100,000 40,000 = $60,000

  • Expected Opportunity Loss (EOL)

    EOL is the cost of not picking the best solution.

    EOL = Expected Regret

  • Thompson Lumber: Payoff Table

    Alternative

    State of Nature

    Favorable Market

    ($)

    Unfavorable

    Market ($)

    Construct a large

    plant 200,000 -180,000

    Construct a small

    plant 100,000 -20,000

    Do nothing 0 0

    Probabilities 0.50 0.50

  • Thompson Lumber: EOL The Opportunity Loss Table

    Alternative

    State of Nature

    Favorable Market ($) Unfavorable Market

    ($)

    Construct a large plant 200,000 200,000 0- (-180,000)

    Construct a small

    plant 200,000 - 100,000 0 (-20,000)

    Do nothing 200,000 - 0 0-0

    Probabilities 0.50 0.50

  • Thompson Lumber: Opportunity Loss Table

    Alternative

    State of Nature

    Favorable Market

    ($)

    Unfavorable

    Market ($)

    Construct a large

    plant 0 180,000

    Construct a small

    plant 100,000 20,000

    Do nothing 200,000 0

    Probabilities 0.50 0.50

  • Thompson Lumber: EOL Solution

    Alternative EOL

    Large Plant (0.50)*$0 +

    (0.50)*($180,000)

    $90,000

    Small Plant (0.50)*($100,000)

    + (0.50)(*$20,000)

    $60,000

    Do Nothing (0.50)*($200,000)

    + (0.50)*($0)

    $100,000

    Note:

    1. The minimum EOL and maximum EMV will suggest the same decision.

    2. The value of EVPI will always equal to the minimum EOL value.

  • Thompson Lumber: Sensitivity Analysis

    Let P = probability of favorable market EMV(Large Plant): = $200,000P + (-$180,000)(1-P) = 380,000P - 180,000 EMV(Small Plant): = $100,000P + (-$20,000)(1-P) = 120,000P - 20,000 EMV(Do Nothing): = $0P + 0(1-P) = 0

  • Thompson Lumber: Sensitivity Analysis (continued)

  • Decision Making with Uncertainty: Using the Decision Trees

    Decision trees are most beneficial when a

    sequence of decisions must be made.

    All information included in a payoff table is

    also included in a decision tree.

  • Five Steps to Decision Tree Analysis

    1. Define the problem.

    2. Structure or draw the decision tree.

    3. Assign probabilities to the states of nature.

    4. Estimate payoffs for each possible combination of alternatives and states of nature.

    5. Solve the problem by computing expected monetary values (EMVs) at each state of nature node.

  • Structure of Decision Trees Trees start from left to right and represent decisions and

    outcomes in sequential order.

    A decision node (indicated by a square ) from which one of several alternatives may be chosen.

    A state-of-nature node (indicated by a circle ) out of which one state of nature will occur.

    Lines or branches connect the decisions nodes and the states of nature.

  • Thompsons Decision Tree

    1

    2

    A Decision

    Node

    A State of

    Nature Node Favorable Market

    Unfavorable Market

    Favorable Market

    Unfavorable Market

    Construct Small Plant

    Step 1: Define the problem

    Lets re-look at John Thompsons decision regarding storage sheds.

    This simple problem can be depicted using a decision tree.

    Step 2: Draw the tree

  • Thompsons Decision Tree

    Step 3: Assign probabilities to the states of nature.

    Step 4: Estimate payoffs.

    1

    2

    A Decision

    Node

    A State of

    Nature Node Favorable (0.5) Market

    Unfavorable (0.5) Market

    Favorable (0.5) Market

    Unfavorable (0.5) Market

    Construct Small Plant

    $200,000

    -$180,000

    $100,000

    -$20,000

    0

    Alternatives

    Outcomes Payoffs

  • Thompsons Decision Tree

    1

    2

    A Decision

    Node

    A State of

    Nature Node Favorable (0.5) Market

    Unfavorable (0.5) Market

    Favorable (0.5) Market

    Unfavorable (0.5) Market

    Construct Small Plant

    $200,000

    -$180,000

    $100,000

    -$20,000

    0

    EMV

    =$40,000

    EMV

    =$10,000

    Step 5: Compute EMVs and make decision.

  • Thompsons Decision: A More Complex Problem

    John Thompson has the opportunity of obtaining a market survey that will give additional information on the probable state of nature. Results of the market survey will likely indicate there is a percent change of a favorable market. Historical data show market surveys accurately predict favorable markets 78 % of the time.

    P(Fav. Mkt | Results Favourable) = 0.78

    Likewise, if the market survey predicts an unfavorable market, there is a 73 % chance of its occurring.

    P(Unfav. Mkt | Results Negative) = 0.73

    Assumed the cost of conduct market survey is $10,000, and is deducted from each payoff under Conduct Market Survey.

  • Thompsons Decision Tree

    Now that we have redefined the problem (Step 1), lets use this additional data and redraw Thompsons decision tree (Step 2).

  • Thompsons Decision Tree Step 3: Assign the new probabilities to the states of nature.

    Step 4: Estimate the payoffs.

    Step 5: Compute the EMVs and make decision.

  • John Thompson Dilemma

    John Thompson is not sure how much value to place on

    market survey. He wants to determine the monetary

    worth of the survey. John Thompson is also interested in

    how sensitive his decision is to changes in the market

    survey results. What should he do?

    Expected Value of Sample Information

    Sensitivity Analysis

  • Expected Value of Sample Information

    o The survey cost $10,000.

    o The expected value of $49,200 (when the survey is used) is based on payoffs after the $10,000 cost was subtracted.

    o The expected value with sample information (EV with SI) is the expected value of using the survey assuming no cost to gather it. Thus, in this example:

    EV with SI = $49,200 + $10,000 (cost) = $59,200.

    o Without the sample information, the best expected value is $40,000. Thus, the expected value would increase by $19,200 if the survey was available free.

  • Expected Value of Sample Information (EVSI)

    Expected value with

    sample information

    + study cost

    Expected value of best decision without sample information

    EVSI ==

    EVSI for Thompson Lumber = $59,200 - $40,000

    = $19,200

    Thompson could pay up to $19,200 for a market study.

    Since it costs only $10,000, the survey is indeed worthwhile.

  • Sensitivity Analysis

    How sensitive are the decisions to changes in the

    probabilities?

    e.g. If the probability of a favorable survey were

    less than the current value (0.45), would the survey

    still be selected? How low would this have to be to

    cause a change in the decision?

    Let p = probability of favorable market

  • Calculations for Thompson Lumber Sensitivity Analysis

    2,400 $104,000

    ($2,400) ($106,400) 1) EMV(node

    + =

    - + =

    p

    ) p ( p 1

    Equating the EMV with the survey to the EMV without the

    survey, we have

    0.36 $104,000

    $37,600 or

    $37,600 $104,000

    $40,000 $2,400 $104,000

    = =

    =

    = +

    p

    p

    p

    Hence, our decision will stay the same as long as the

    probability of favorable survey results, p, is greater than 0.36.

  • Estimating Probability Values with Bayes Theorem

    Management experience or intuition History Existing data Need to be able to revise probabilities based

    upon new data

    Posterior

    probabilities Prior

    probabilities Bayes Theorem

    Information about accuracy

    of sample information.

  • Bayesian Analysis

    The probabilities of a favorable / unfavorable state of nature can be

    obtained by analyzing the Market Survey Reliability in Predicting

    Actual States of Nature.

    STATE OF NATURE

    RESULT OF SURVEY

    FAVORABLE MARKET (FM)

    UNFAVORABLE MARKET (UM)

    Positive (predicts favorable market for product)

    P (survey positive | FM)

    = 0.70

    P (survey positive | UM)

    = 0.20

    Negative (predicts unfavorable market for product)

    P (survey negative | FM)

    = 0.30

    P (survey negative | UM)

    = 0.80

  • Bayesian Analysis (continued): Favorable Survey

    POSTERIOR PROBABILITY

    STATE OF NATURE

    CONDITIONAL PROBABILITY

    P(SURVEY POSITIVE | STATE

    OF NATURE) PRIOR

    PROBABILITY JOINT

    PROBABILITY

    P(STATE OF NATURE | SURVEY

    POSITIVE)

    FM 0.70 X 0.50 = 0.35 0.35/0.45 = 0.78

    UM 0.20 X 0.50 = 0.10 0.10/0.45 = 0.22

    P(survey results positive) = 0.45 1.00

  • Bayesian Analysis (continued): Unfavorable Survey

    POSTERIOR PROBABILITY

    STATE OF NATURE

    CONDITIONAL PROBABILITY

    P(SURVEY NEGATIVE | STATE

    OF NATURE) PRIOR

    PROBABILITY JOINT

    PROBABILITY

    P(STATE OF NATURE | SURVEY

    NEGATIVE)

    FM 0.30 X 0.50 = 0.15 0.15/0.55 = 0.27

    UM 0.80 X 0.50 = 0.40 0.40/0.55 = 0.73

    P(survey results positive) = 0.55 1.00

  • Decision Making Using Utility Theory

    There are many occasions in which people make decisions that would appear to be inconsistent with the EMV criterion.

    E.g.: 1. When people buy insurance, the amount of the premium is greater than the expected payout. 2. A person involved in a law suit may choose to settle out of court rather than go trial even if the expected value of going to trial is greater hat the proposed settlement.

    This is because monetary value is not always a true indicator of the overall value of the result of a decision.

    The overall worth of a particular decision is called utility.

    Rational people make decisions that maximize the expected utility.

  • Decision Making Using Utility Theory Utility assessment assigns the worst outcome a utility of 0,

    and the best outcome, a utility of 1.

    A standard gamble is used to determine utility values.

    When you are indifferent, your utility values are equal.

    Expected utility of alternative 2 = Expected utility of alternative 1

    Utility of other outcome = (p)(utility of best outcome, which is

    1) + (1p)(utility of the worst

    outcome, which is 0)

    Utility of other outcome = (p)(1) + (1p)(0) = p

    Where p is the probability of obtaining the best outcome, and (1p) is the

    probability of obtaining the worst

    outcome.

  • Standard Gamble for Utility Assessment

    Best outcome

    Utility = 1

    Worst outcome

    Utility = 0

    Other outcome

    Utility = ??

    p

    1p

  • Real Estate Example: Utility Theory Jane Dickson wants to construct a utility curve revealing her

    preference for money between $0 and $10,000.

    A utility curve plots the utility value versus the monetary value.

    An investment in a bank will result in $5,000.

    An investment in real estate will result in $0 or $10,000.

    Unless there is an 80% chance of getting $10,000 from the real estate deal, Jane would prefer to have her money in the bank.

    So if p = 0.80, Jane is indifferent between the bank or the real estate investment.

  • Real Estate Example: Solution

    $10,000

    U($10,000) = 1.0

    0

    U(0) = 0

    $5,000

    U($5,000) = p = 0.80

    p= 0.80

    (1 p)= 0.20

    Hence, Janes Utility for $5,000 = U($5,000) = p

    = p*U($10,000) + (1 p)*U($0)

    = (0.8)(1) + (0.2)(0) = 0.8

  • Real Estate Example: Solution

    Utility for $7,000 = 0.90

    Utility for $3,000 = 0.50

    We can assess other utility values in the same way.

    For Jane, let say these are:

    Using the three utilities for different dollar amounts, she can construct a utility curve.

    Note: In setting the value of probability p, one should be aware that utility assessment is completely subjective. It is a value set by the decision maker that cannot be measured on an objective scale.

  • Real Estate Example: Utility Curve

    U ($7,000) = 0.90

    U ($5,000) = 0.80

    U ($3,000) = 0.50

    U ($0) = 0

    1.0

    0.9

    0.8

    0.7

    0.6

    0.5

    0.4

    0.3

    0.2

    0.1

    | | | | | | | | | | |

    $0 $1,000 $3,000 $5,000 $7,000 $10,000

    Monetary Value

    Uti

    lity

    U ($10,000) = 1.0