the housing price bubble, the monetary policy and the foreclosure crisis in the us

6
This article was downloaded by: [University of Illinois Chicago] On: 16 November 2014, At: 16:21 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Applied Economics Letters Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rael20 The housing price bubble, the monetary policy and the foreclosure crisis in the US John F. McDonald a & Houston H. Stokes b a Heller College of Business , Roosevelt University , Chicago , IL , 60605 , USA b Department of Economics , University of Illinois at Chicago , Chicago , IL , 60607 , USA Published online: 22 May 2013. To cite this article: John F. McDonald & Houston H. Stokes (2013) The housing price bubble, the monetary policy and the foreclosure crisis in the US, Applied Economics Letters, 20:11, 1104-1108, DOI: 10.1080/13504851.2013.791009 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2013.791009 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content. This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http:// www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

Upload: houston-h

Post on 21-Mar-2017

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The housing price bubble, the monetary policy and the foreclosure crisis in the US

This article was downloaded by: [University of Illinois Chicago]On: 16 November 2014, At: 16:21Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House,37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

Applied Economics LettersPublication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rael20

The housing price bubble, the monetary policy and theforeclosure crisis in the USJohn F. McDonald a & Houston H. Stokes ba Heller College of Business , Roosevelt University , Chicago , IL , 60605 , USAb Department of Economics , University of Illinois at Chicago , Chicago , IL , 60607 , USAPublished online: 22 May 2013.

To cite this article: John F. McDonald & Houston H. Stokes (2013) The housing price bubble, the monetary policy and theforeclosure crisis in the US, Applied Economics Letters, 20:11, 1104-1108, DOI: 10.1080/13504851.2013.791009

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2013.791009

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) containedin the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make norepresentations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of theContent. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, andare not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon andshould be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable forany losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoeveror howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use ofthe Content.

This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematicreproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in anyform to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

Page 2: The housing price bubble, the monetary policy and the foreclosure crisis in the US

The housing price bubble, the

monetary policy and the foreclosure

crisis in the US

John F. McDonalda,* and Houston H. Stokesb

aHeller College of Business, Roosevelt University, Chicago, IL 60605, USAbDepartment of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, Chicago, IL60607, USA

This article presents a monthly vector autoregressive (VAR) model ofhousing prices, the federal funds rate, foreclosures, the unemploymentrate and the mortgage interest rate for the United States for the period of2000(1)–2010(8). Impulse response functions show that negative shocks tothe federal funds rate increased housing prices. The interaction effectbetween the foreclosure rate and the housing prices shows that an initialshock to the foreclosure rate produced further increases in the foreclosurerate through a reduction in housing prices.

Keywords: housing bubble; foreclosures; monetary policy; VAR model

JEL Classification: E32; E50

I. Introduction

It is generally agreed that the bursting of the housingprice bubble led to a high increase in the foreclosurerate and severe financial crisis and deep recession inthe United States. A great deal of research is beingdevoted to understand the underlying causes of thevery high increase in the housing prices during theperiod 2000–2006 and the causes and consequencesof the resulting financial crisis and recession. Onefocus of that research agenda is the monetary policyof the Federal Reserve Bank, which held the federalfunds rate at very low levels during 2001–2004 andthen sharply increased this rate during 2004–2006.Was the federal funds rate a cause of the huge increaseand subsequent fall in housing prices? It is clear thatthe huge increase in foreclosures that started in 2006was the fuse that set off the financial crisis, and it islikely that there was an interaction between foreclo-sures and housing prices that made matters worse.Furthermore, the resulting recession produced a highincrease in the unemployment rate that may have

resulted in more foreclosures and housing pricedeclines. The purpose of this article is to examinethese questions by estimating a time-series modelusing monthly data for the critical period of2000–2010.

II. Expected Causes and Consequences

McDonald and Stokes (2013) present the results for atwo-variable vector autoregressive (VAR) model forhousing prices and the federal funds rate in whichnegative shocks in the federal funds equation have apositive effect on housing prices, and positive shocksin housing prices increase the federal funds rate.However, this study left out explicit roles for the fore-closure rate, the mortgage interest rate and the unem-ployment rate. We expect that negative shocks tohousing prices will increase foreclosures and that thepositive shocks to foreclosures will reduce housingprices. In addition, it is possible that the mortgageinterest rate, rather than the federal funds rate, was

*Corresponding author. E-mail: [email protected]

# 2013 Taylor & Francis1104

Applied Economics Letters, 2013Vol. 20, No. 11, 1104–1108, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2013.791009

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

6:21

16

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 3: The housing price bubble, the monetary policy and the foreclosure crisis in the US

the key interest rate during the time in question. Also,the effects of the general economic recession should beincluded in the model. The ability-to-pay theory offoreclosures states that negative shocks to households,such as an increase in unemployment, are prime causesof foreclosures.The VARmethod treats all variables as endogenous

and allows for complex lagged interaction effectsamong the variables. Our earlier study found feedbackfrom housing prices to the federal funds rate, so theVARmethod is used in this study as well. As discussedby Enders (2004, p. 292), identification in the model isachieved by imposing the restriction that contempora-neous ‘innovations’ or ‘shocks’ in the variables in themodel do not have contemporaneous effects on theother variables. In this work, the Choleski decomposi-tion is used to impose this identifying restriction,where the most exogenous variable is assumed to befirst in the variable vector. The Monte Carlo integra-tion approach with 800 draws is used to establish 95%confidence intervals for the effect of random shocks ofthe series once the VAR model is inverted.

III. Data

The study makes use of five monthly time-series vari-ables: the federal funds rate, the S&P/Case-Shillerhome price series for 10 major metropolitan areas,the interest rate on standard 30-year home mortgages,the unemployment rate and the foreclosure rate seriesprovided by Zillow. All the data are from January2000 to August 2010. The federal funds rate for the

Friday closest to the end of the month in question isused. The Zillow foreclosure rate series is a weightedaverage of the current and past 2 months for thepercentage of all homes foreclosed in a given month(with the heaviest weight on the most recent month).Foreclosures include those sold at a sheriff’s sale orforfeited to the bank.Graphs of the five variables (levels and natural log

levels) are shown in Fig. 1, and means and SDs areshown in Table 1.

IV. Empirical Results

This section reports two sets of empirical results. One-way Granger causality tests are reported first. Fiveequations are estimated; each of the five variableswas the dependent variable with eight lags of itselfand the other four variables are on the right-handside of the equation. These results are suggestive, butas noted above, a VAR model is used because feed-back effects among some of the variables are to beexpected. Impulse response functions derived from

Raw and log data

Federal funds rate

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Log federal funds rate

–3

–2

–1

0

1

2

Case–shiller reries

100

120

140

160

180

200

220

240

Log Case–Shiller data

4.6

4.7

4.8

4.9

5.0

5.1

5.2

5.3

5.4

5.5

Mortgage interest rate

4.5

5.0

5.5

6.0

6.5

7.0

7.5

8.0

Log mortgage interest rate

1.5

1.6

1.7

1.8

1.9

2.0

2.1

Foreclosure rate

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.10

0.12

Log foreclosure rate

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 20102000 2002 2004 2006 2008 20102000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

–5.0

–4.5

-4.0

–3.5

–3.0

–2.5

–2.0

Unemployment rate

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

Log unemployment rate

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2.0

2.2

2.4

Fig. 1. Fed funds, C_S index, mortgage rate, foreclosure rate, unemp

Table 1. Variables, means and SDs

Mean SD

ln federal funds rate 0.426 1.241ln mortgage rate 1.802 0.106ln foreclosure rate –3.595 0.772ln unemployment rate 1.743 0.256ln house price index 5.119 0.214

Housing prices, monetary policy and foreclosures 1105

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

6:21

16

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 4: The housing price bubble, the monetary policy and the foreclosure crisis in the US

inverting the VAR model are reported next, and the

existence of feedback effects is confirmed. See Enders

(2004, pp. 264–80) for an introduction to VARmodels

and their transformation to vector moving average

(VMA) equations and impulse response functions.

Doan (2010) discusses the details of the Monte Carlo

procedure used to obtain 95% confidence intervals for

the impulse response functions.The results of the one-way Granger causality tests

are displayed in Table 2. Table 2 contains the F-tests

that result from the exclusion of eight lagged values of

the variables listed in the left-hand column. Note that

exclusion of the lagged values of the dependent vari-

able results in a statistically significant decrease in

explanatory power in the equations for all five vari-

ables. The only off-diagonal elements in Table 2 that

are statistically significant are the effects of lagged

values of the natural log of the federal funds rate on

the natural log of the housing price index, and the

lagged values of the natural log of the housing price

index on the natural log of the federal funds rate.

None of the other 18 effects of lagged values are

statistically significant. Table 2 also reports the SE of

estimate (SEE) and the Durbin–Watson statistic for

each equation. All five Durbin–Watson statistics are

very close to 2.00, results that indicate an absence of

first-order autocorrelation in the error terms of the

estimated equations. While the Granger results indi-

cate the presence or absence of causality, they do not

show the sign of the effect or the timing of the effect.The next set of results displays the impulse response

functions that are derived from the VAR model and

show how each series in the model reacts dynamically

to its own shocks and the shocks from other series.

The five equations of the VAR model are of the form

xit ¼ aþXm

k¼1�iB

kxit þX5

j¼1;j�i

Xm

i¼1�j iB

kxj t þ eit ð1Þ

where m = 8 and B is the lag operator defined such

that Bkxit;xi ;t�k:Using the Cholesky decomposition, exact identifi-

cation for a model with five variables requires diago-

nalizing the VAR error covariance matrix which

allows calculation of a transformed VMA form of

the model that expresses each of the five variables in

the model as a function of their own and the other four

variable shocks. Inspection of these impulse-response

functions provides an insight into the dynamic pat-

terns of the series. The estimated impulse-response

functions can be sensitive to the ordering of the vari-

ables if there are contemporaneous relationships

between the variables because of the necessary identi-

fying restrictions. However, the results reported in this

article are not sensitive to the ordering of the variables.

See Enders (2004, pp. 274–7) for a more detailed dis-

cussion on identifying restrictions and ordering of

variables. Figure 2 plots impulse-response functions

for the period of 20 months. Responses to positive

shocks to lagged values of each variable are discussed

in turn.Shocks to the federal funds rate have statistically

significant mappings that have negative effects on

both the housing price index and the unemployment

rate. The impact on the housing price index replicates

the earlier findings in McDonald and Stokes (2013).

The maximum effect of –0.01 occurs at 10 months.

The negative effect on the unemployment rate in the

first 5 months is not as expected and suggests that

reductions in the federal funds rate during 2001–2004

and in the beginning of 2007 were not effective in

reducing the unemployment rate. Shocks to the mort-

gage interest rate have no effects on any of the other

variables, given that these other variables are included

in the model. This result indicates that the federal

funds rate, rather than the mortgage interest rate,

was the more influential interest rate during this time

period.

Table 2. One-way Granger causality tests: F-statisticsa

Lagged values of thesevariables

ln fed fundsrate

ln mortgagerate

ln foreclosurerate

ln unemploymentrate

ln house priceindex

ln fed funds 8.69* 1.09 1.06 0.71 3.32*ln mortgage 1.11 19.68* 0.16 0.69 0.60ln foreclosure 1.25 0.96 118.80* 1.11 1.85ln unemployment 0.92 0.94 0.82 36.79* 1.76ln house price 2.69* 1.12 1.06 1.10 13 216*SEE 0.210 0.023 0.050 0.023 0.0025Durbin–Watson 2.01 2.06 2.00 2.01 2.05

Notes: aCritical values for F-test are 2.04 (95%) and 2.72 (99%).*Statistically significant at the 98% level or higher.

1106 J. F. McDonald and H. H. Stokes

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

6:21

16

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 5: The housing price bubble, the monetary policy and the foreclosure crisis in the US

Shocks to the foreclosure rate have a negative effect

on the house price index as expected. The effectincreases throughout the 20 months that are charted.Shocks to the unemployment rate have a negative

effect on the federal funds rate. Presumably, this is apolicy response to the unemployment rate, but as

noted above, this policy was not effective. Shocks tothe unemployment rate also have a negative effect on

the house price index as expected. The recession, asmeasured by the unemployment rate, has a negative

impact on the demand for owner-occupied housing.Finally, shocks to the house price index have a positive

impact on the federal funds rate (a policy response)and a negative impact on the foreclosure rate. Both theeffects are as expected. Note that shocks to the fore-

closure rate caused housing prices to fall, and shocksto the housing price caused foreclosures to decrease.

In other words, housing prices and foreclosure ratesmove in opposite directions, and their movements

reinforce each other. As shown in Fig. 1, housingprices began to fall in the summer of 2006 and the

foreclosure rate had already increased in as early as2004, with the rapid increase that began in 2006. It is

reasonable to conclude that the increases in the fore-closure rate and the declines in housing prices werereinforcing each other in the beginning of 2006.An important question to answer is how much of

the variance of a series can be explained by the shocksfrom its own past or shocks from the past of the other

four series in the model. Variance decomposition ofthe log of the housing price series produced the

following results. At low lags, most of the variance iscoming from its own past, e.g. at lag 5 it was 83.59%.However, as the lags increase other variables comeinto play. For example, at lag 10, 8.13% is explainedby the log of the Federal Funds Rate, 31.54% isexplained by the log of the foreclosure rate, 10.39%is explained by the log of the unemployment rate and49.22% by the log of the housing series. By lag 20,these percentages were 22.86%, 46.19%, 2.81% and24.83% respectively, as the effect of the unemploy-ment declines and the log of the Federal Funds Rateand the log of the foreclosure rate increase in impor-tance. Shocks to the log of the mortgage rate explainonly 4.96% of the variance in the house price series atlag 1 and less than 4% thereafter. While this decom-position is most informative, it does not illustrate thesign or the relative magnitude of the effects. To mea-sure this, we turn to Fig. 3 where the cumulativeresponses of the series are shown. The effect of thelog of the federal funds rate turns negative after lag 6and increases. The effect of the log of the foreclosureeffect is always negative. The effect of the log of theunemployment rate is initially negative, peaking at lag7. After that it fades out to zero at lag 14. These resultsconfirm the variance decomposition results.

V. Conclusions

This article has employed the VAR method to exam-ine the relationships among the federal funds rate, the

2 SD bounds set by Monte Carlo integration

Res

pons

es o

f

LO

G_

FF

RL

OG

_M

OR

TI

LO

G_

FO

R_

US

LO

G_

UN

EM

PL

OG

_C

SX

R

LOG_FFR

LOG_FFR

LOG_MORTI

LOG_MORTI

LOG_FOR_US

LOG_FOR_US

LOG_UNEMP

LOG_UNEMP

LOG_CSXR

LOG_CSXR

0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15

0 5 10 15

0 5 10 15

–0.4–0.3–0.2–0.1–0.0

0.10.20.30.4

–0.4–0.3–0.2–0.1–0.0

0.10.20.30.4

–0.4–0.3–0.2–0.1–0.0

0.10.20.30.4

–0.4–0.3–0.2–0.1–0.0

0.10.20.30.4

–0.4–0.3–0.2–0.1–0.0

0.10.20.30.4

–0.03

–0.02

–0.01

0.00

0.01

0.02

0.03

–0.03

–0.02

–0.01

0.00

0.01

0.02

0.03

–0.03

–0.02

–0.01

0.00

0.01

0.02

0.03

–0.03

–0.02

–0.01

0.00

0.01

0.02

0.03

–0.03

–0.02

–0.01

0.00

0.01

0.02

0.03

–0.15

–0.10

–0.05

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

–0.15

–0.10

–0.05

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

–0.15

–0.10

–0.05

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

–0.15

–0.10

–0.05

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

–0.15

–0.10

–0.05

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

–0.06

–0.04

–0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

–0.06

–0.04

–0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

–0.06

–0.04

–0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

–0.06

–0.04

–0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

–0.06

–0.04

–0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

–0.04–0.03–0.02–0.01

0.000.010.020.03

–0.04–0.03–0.02–0.010.000.010.020.03

–0.04–0.03–0.02–0.01

0.000.010.020.03

–0.04–0.03–0.02–0.01

0.000.010.020.03

0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15

0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15

0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15

0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15 0 5 10 15–0.04–0.03–0.02–0.01

0.000.010.020.03

Fig. 2. Impulse response functions log VAR(8) model

Housing prices, monetary policy and foreclosures 1107

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

6:21

16

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 6: The housing price bubble, the monetary policy and the foreclosure crisis in the US

mortgage interest rate, housing prices, the foreclosurerate and the unemployment rate for the United Statesfrom 2000–2010. The results include the following.

l The federal funds rate was a cause of the houseprice index movements, both up and down. Thisresult confirms the earlier result in McDonaldand Stokes (2013). Also, positive shocks to thefederal funds rate were caused prior to reduc-tions in unemployment. This result is not asexpected, but suggests that conventional mone-tary policy was not effective at reducing unem-ployment during 2000–2010.

l The foreclosure rate is a cause of the movementsin the house price index as expected.

l The unemployment rate caused changes in thefederal funds rate (presumably a policyresponse) and also caused movements in thehouse prices as expected.

l The house price index was a cause of the federalfunds rate (presumably another policy response)and a cause of the foreclosure rate.

The basic story that emerges from this investigation isthat very low federal funds rate during 2001–2004 wasa cause of the rapid increase in housing pricesthroughout 2006. Housing prices began to fall rapidly

in the middle of 2006, perhaps, in part, as a result ofthe increase in the federal funds rate during the pre-vious 2 years, and the foreclosure rate began toincrease rapidly at or before the time when housingprices began to fall. Once underway, these trends inforeclosures and housing prices reinforced each other.The economy moved into a deep recession, and theresulting large increase in the unemployment rateadded to the decline in housing prices. In August2010, housing prices remained depressed, unemploy-ment remained high and the foreclosure rate showedno signs of declining. One policy conclusion is that thefederal funds rate should not have been set as such lowrates during 2001–2004. Another is that much moreaggressive policy measures should have been taken tostop the foreclosures.

References

Doan, T. (2010) Rats User’s Manual: Version 8.0, Estima,Evanston, IL.

Enders, W. (2004) Applied Econometric Time Series, 2ndedn, Wiley, New York.

McDonald, J. and Stokes, H. (2013) Monetary policy andthe housing bubble, Journal of Real Estate Financeand Economics, 46, 437–51.

Log federal funds rate

Log mortgage rate

Log foreclosure rate

Log unemployment rate

Log Case–Shiller 10 city series

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19–0.015

–0.010

–0.005

0.000

0.005

0.010

Fig. 3. Plot of responses of log Case-Shiller 10 city series

1108 J. F. McDonald and H. H. Stokes

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

6:21

16

Nov

embe

r 20

14