sugar and structural change in the cuban economy

20
World Development, Vol. 17, No. 10, pp. 1627-1646,1989. 0305-750X/89 $3.00 + 0.00 Printed in Great Britain. 0 1989 Pergamon Press plc Sugar and Structural Change in the Cuban Economy JORGE F. PGREZ-L6PEZ* US Department of Labor Summary. - Diversification of the economy away from sugar was high among the economic priorities of the Cuban revolutionary government in power since 1959. This essay explores whether sugar’s role in the structure of the economy has in fact changed significantly in the last 25 years or so by examining three aspects of structural change: specialization in production, export concentration, and effects of changes in world sugar market prices on economic growth. The analysis suggests that policies of the revolutionary government have had a marginal impact in reducing sugar’s role. Plans to increase sugar production and exports through the end of the century virtually assure that sugar will continue to play a predominant role in the economy. 1. INTRODUCTION Among the critical structural problems of the economy of prerevolutionary Cuba were the heavy concentration on the production and export of a single commodity - sugar - and the consequent vulnerability of the economy to exogenous shocks arising from changes in the world market price for that commodity. Diversi- fication of the agricultural and industrial sectors of the economy away from sugar was high among the economic priorities of the revolutionary government in power since 1959. To what extent have these structural problems been alleviated, or resolved, by economic policies of the revolu- tionary regime? Assessing long-term structural changes of the Cuban economy is more difficult than meets the eye. For one thing, the statistical base has significant gaps. Reliable macroeconomic data for prerevolutionary Cuba are only available beginning with the late 1940s when the Banco National de Cuba was established and began to publish such statistics. More recently, there is a gap in macroeconomic (and other) statistics for some of the early years of the revolution (e.g., 1960-61). Second, macroeconomic data available for prerevolutionary and revolutionary Cuba are largely not comparable. And third, the extraordi- narily high prices the Soviet Union pays for Cuban sugar distort trade statistics, biasing esti- mates of the importance of sugar exports within the total export basket. lems noted above, this paper nevertheless ex- plores whether sugar’s role in the structure of the Cuban economy has changed significantly in the last 25 years or so. The paper begins with a brief review of economic development strategies of the revolutionary regime, with special emphasis on the role devolved to the sugar industry. It then examines three aspects of the structural change issue - specialization in production, export concentration, and effect of changes in world sugar market prices on economic growth - in an effort to determine whether there. have been significant changes since 1959. The paper closes with some tentative conclusions regarding the extent to which the role of sugar in the Cuban economy has changed as a result of the policies of the revolutionary government. 2. SUGAR IN REVOLUTIONARY CUBA’S DEVELOPMENT STRATEGIES Economic development strategies of the re- volutionary government have contributed to shaping the role of the sugar industry in the Cuban economy. Typical of the love-hate rela- tionship Cuban leaders have traditionally en- joyed vis-a-vis the sugar industry, the role assigned to this industry in development policies of the revolutionary government has ranged from Mindful of the serious methodological prob- *Bureau of International Labor Affairs. This paper presents only the personal views of the author. 1627

Upload: jorge-f-perez-lopez

Post on 01-Sep-2016

214 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

World Development, Vol. 17, No. 10, pp. 1627-1646,1989. 0305-750X/89 $3.00 + 0.00 Printed in Great Britain. 0 1989 Pergamon Press plc

Sugar and Structural Change in the Cuban Economy

JORGE F. PGREZ-L6PEZ* US Department of Labor

Summary. - Diversification of the economy away from sugar was high among the economic priorities of the Cuban revolutionary government in power since 1959. This essay explores whether sugar’s role in the structure of the economy has in fact changed significantly in the last 25 years or so by examining three aspects of structural change: specialization in production, export concentration, and effects of changes in world sugar market prices on economic growth. The analysis suggests that policies of the revolutionary government have had a marginal impact in reducing sugar’s role. Plans to increase sugar production and exports through the end of the century virtually assure that sugar will continue to play a predominant role in the economy.

1. INTRODUCTION

Among the critical structural problems of the economy of prerevolutionary Cuba were the heavy concentration on the production and export of a single commodity - sugar - and the consequent vulnerability of the economy to exogenous shocks arising from changes in the world market price for that commodity. Diversi- fication of the agricultural and industrial sectors of the economy away from sugar was high among the economic priorities of the revolutionary government in power since 1959. To what extent have these structural problems been alleviated, or resolved, by economic policies of the revolu- tionary regime?

Assessing long-term structural changes of the Cuban economy is more difficult than meets the eye. For one thing, the statistical base has significant gaps. Reliable macroeconomic data for prerevolutionary Cuba are only available beginning with the late 1940s when the Banco National de Cuba was established and began to publish such statistics. More recently, there is a gap in macroeconomic (and other) statistics for some of the early years of the revolution (e.g., 1960-61). Second, macroeconomic data available for prerevolutionary and revolutionary Cuba are largely not comparable. And third, the extraordi- narily high prices the Soviet Union pays for Cuban sugar distort trade statistics, biasing esti- mates of the importance of sugar exports within the total export basket.

lems noted above, this paper nevertheless ex- plores whether sugar’s role in the structure of the Cuban economy has changed significantly in the last 25 years or so. The paper begins with a brief review of economic development strategies of the revolutionary regime, with special emphasis on the role devolved to the sugar industry. It then examines three aspects of the structural change issue - specialization in production, export concentration, and effect of changes in world sugar market prices on economic growth - in an effort to determine whether there. have been significant changes since 1959. The paper closes with some tentative conclusions regarding the extent to which the role of sugar in the Cuban economy has changed as a result of the policies of the revolutionary government.

2. SUGAR IN REVOLUTIONARY CUBA’S

DEVELOPMENT STRATEGIES

Economic development strategies of the re- volutionary government have contributed to shaping the role of the sugar industry in the Cuban economy. Typical of the love-hate rela- tionship Cuban leaders have traditionally en- joyed vis-a-vis the sugar industry, the role assigned to this industry in development policies of the revolutionary government has ranged from

Mindful of the serious methodological prob- *Bureau of International Labor Affairs. This paper presents only the personal views of the author.

1627

Page 2: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

1628 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

neglect to being singled out as the key sector in (1961, pp. 39-40) had indicated that Cuba had an agriculture-led growth strategy. short-term plans to develop a transportation

equipment industry that would produce tractors,

(a) The industrialization drive trucks, internal combustion engines, etc.; after 1965, according to Guevara, Cuba would pro-

The development strategy crafted during 1960 duce passenger automobiles.

and 1961 by Cuban officials, with the assistance of experts from abroad, stressed agricultural diversification and rapid industrialization.’ These

(b) The return to sugar

policies were popular not only because of the large employment gains which were projected,

Overwhelmed by a balance-of-payments crisis,

but also because they played on the deeply- the abject failure of the agricultural diversi-

ingrained sucrophobia of a large portion of the fication/industrialization drive, and declining

population, which had increasingly grown to sugar production, the Cuban government in

associate the sugar industry with the ills of the 1963 shifted gears and redefined its development

economy: unemployment, monoculture, instabil- strategy to give agriculture - and specifically

ity, external dependence. It has been suggested sugar - a central role.’ Under this new strategy,

(Ritter, 1974, pp. 133-134) that another reason agriculture was tapped as the leading sector of

for the strategy of turning away from sugar was the economy. The intention was to expand sugar

the poor world market price situation and pros- production and exports in order to raise additio-

pects; a bumper crop in Cuba in 1961 (see Table nal revenue to finance imports of capital goods;

l), coupled with high production in Western these capital goods, in turn, would be employed

Europe, had driven down world market prices, a in the domestic production of a range of inter-

common outcome whenever Cuban production mediate and final consumer goods theretofore

was high. being imported (Brunner, 1977, pp. 3839).

Consistent with the agricultural diversification Consistent with the new strategy, an ambitious

drive, large sugar cane estates were cleared and plan for the sugar industry for the period 1965-70

replanted with other crops - rice, fruits, veget- was drawn up. This “Prospective Plan for the

ables (Boorstein, 1968, pp. 185, 201, 205). In Sugar Industry” foresaw substantial expansion in

1961 alone, cooperatives diverted 13,000 cabal- the area devoted to sugar cane cultivation,

ferias (nearly 175,000 hectares) from sugar cane planting of improved sugar cane varieties, in-

to the cultivation of beans, peanuts, rice, cotton, creases in the area under irrigation, mechaniza-

tubers, etc., and to pasture land (Aguirre, 1961, tion of harvesting, modernization of sugar mills,

p. 24). Total sugar cane area under cultivation etc. The objective was to produce 10 million tons

fell by 25% between 1958 and 1963 (Mesa-Lago, of sugar in 1970 - compared to a historical high

1971, p. 283). By 1962, nine sugar mills, with production of 7.2 million tons in 1952 - and for

combined grinding capacity of 15,000 tons per annual production to remain at the 10 million-

day, had been dismantled (CERP, 1965a, p. 89), level during 1971-75 and then to rise to about 12 million tons3

a reduction of about 2.7% in grinding capacity estimated at 561,000 tons per day in 1958 (Cuba

At the early stages of implementation of the sugar “Prospective Plan,” several Cuban eco-

Economica, 1959, pp. 91-93). Retrospectively, nomists (Herrera, 1965; Regalado, 1965; Bor- the Central Planning Board (Junta Central de rego Diaz, 1965) publicly discussed potential Planificacion, JUCEPLAN) has admitted that bottlenecks in sugar agricultural and industrial investment in the sugar industrial sector (e.g., for activities that could jeopardize attainment of the maintenance and repairs of sugar mills) during this period fell well below acceptable levels (“El

10 million ton target in 1970 and, more impor- tantly, the ability to produce at that level of

desarrollo industrial,” 1966, p. 148). output in subsequent years. With regard to the Industrialization plans bordered on the idyllic. impact of the sugar push on the rest of the

In August 1961, Minister of Industries Guevara economy, a Cuban economist (Borrego Diaz, (1971, p. 148) spoke of plans to make Cuba the 1966, p. 166) noted in 1966 that almost 70% of most highly industrialized country in Latin total planned investment for 1965-70 was to be America relative to its population, diversify the targeted on the sugar industry, draining the rest economy, and reduce the dependence on sugar of the economy of investment resources. Retro- exports from the then-current 80% of the value spective analyses have dealt in considerable of exports to 60%, an optimistic view shared by detail with the reasons behind the failure of the Cuban technicians and foreign advisors (e.g., sugar plan to meet its quantitative targets in Boti, 1961; Kale&i, 1976). Earlier, Guevara every year after 1965 - and especially the much-

Page 3: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

SUGAR AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE

Table 1. Cuban sugar production, consumption, and net exports (thousand tons)

Year Production Consumption Net

exports

Net exports as a % of

production*

1950 1951 1952

5558 5759 7225 5159 4890 4528 4740

247 292 303 258 206 206 313 304 242 331

5261 5441

94.6

106.7

94.5 69.3

106.9

92.1

86.4 102.6 113.8

93.6 97.4 83.0 96.1 94.8

5516

5131

4226 4644

3521

5394 5307 5631 4952 5635 6414

1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970

5672

5315

5784 5964

5534

5862 6767 4815 3821 4590 6082 4867 6236

348 376

682

373 456

636

402 492 542 630

4176 91.0 5316 87.4 4435 91.1 5683 91.1 4613 86.8 4799 86.7

7559 5950 4688 5383

619 616 471 464 522 499 532 519 552 519 530 552 649 678 728 887

6906

4140 4797

5511

5491 5744 5764 6238 7231 7269 6191 7071 7648 6792 7017 7209

88.3

91.3

89.1 92.7

92.6

89.4 93.7

1971

1976

1972 1973

1977

1974 1975

6151 6953

6427

89.7 94.4 93.2 91.0 89.2 95.1 91.0 90.2 91.3

1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985

7662

6805 7926 8040 7460 7783 7889

*A net export/production ratio exceeding 100% means that stocks are drawn down. Source: Compiled from data in IS0 (1985) and earlier issues.

publicized 10 million ton target set for 1970 (see Table 1) - and the misallocation of resources that occurred as a result of the single-minded pursuit of a 10 million ton zafra in 1970.4

giant, barn-busting zafras, but rather on stable and more efficient production, with gradual increases in output (Petushkov, 1975, pp. 32-34; Charadan Lopez, 1982, pp. 143-248). Significant efforts have been made to increase industrial yields, reduce fuel consumption by sugar mills, broaden the scope of mechanization in cutting and loading of sugar cane, improve on the timeliness of sugar export deliveries, etc. Efforts to rationalize the sugar industry probably have been influenced by Cuba’s formal accession into the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance

(c) Deepening reliance on sugar

In the aftermath of the 1970 zafra and the severe economic dislocations that occurred, poli- cies toward the sugar industry have undergone significant change. The emphasis is no longer on

Page 4: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

1630 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

(CMEA) in 1972. Since then, Cuba has been assigned the role of sugar supplier within the CMEA division of labor, a factor which has tended to work against diversification and may be a long-run obstacle to the country’s indus- trialization (Brezinski, 1986, p. 302).

In July 1981, Cuba and its three primary markets within CMEA - the Soviet Union, Bulgaria and the German Democratic Republic - signed a “General Agreement on the Integral Development of Sugar Production” (also known as the CMEA Sugar Program) which formalized Cuba’s role as the primary supplier of sugar to CMEA (Contreras, 1982, pp. 19-20; Diaz- Vgzquez, 1985, pp. 73-74; Ferrer 1981, p. 2; ValdCs, 1984, p. 141). Pursuant to this program and other bilateral arrangements, Cuba receives preferential price treatment for sugar exports to CMEA markets and assistance (credits, technical aid) for the development of the sugar industry, its byproducts, and agricultural equipment manu- facturing. Reportedly, CMEA assistance for sugar investments was projected at $635 million during 1981-85 and $540 million during 198690 (UNIDO, 1986, p. 25). The sugar agreement with CMEA, and a similar pact signed at the same time dealing with the citrus industry, “consecrated” Cuba’s role as a purveyor of agricultural commodities within the socialist divi- sion of labor (Ferrer, 1981, p. 2).

During the five-year plan 1976-80, Cuba undertook a massive effort to modernize and expand sugar industrial capacity. More than 40 mills were modernized and two new mills were put into operation in 1980, the first new mills built in the country in more than 50 years (Castro, 1980b, p. 42). Sugar output rose steadily through 1979, when 7.8 million tons were pro- duced (Table l), the second-largest zufra on record, but fell sharply in 1980 (to about 6.8 million tons) when sugar cane was hard hit by an epidemic of roya (cane rust) which affected yields (Mesa-Lago, 1982, pp. 124-125). Thus, the output goal of s8.5 million tons of sugar in 1980 was not met.

For the period 1981-85, Cuba’s development plan called for the start-up of construction of at least seven new sugar mills, expansion of 23 mills, and renovation of 18 others; sugar output was expected to average about 2&25% above the 7.1 million tons per annum achieved during 1976-80 (Lineamientos, 1980, pp. 79-80). For 1985, output was projected at 8.2-8.5 million tons, roughly the same level projected earlier for 1980, but not achieved. Actual production in 1985 was about 7.9 million tons (Table l), 4-7% below projections. In the first half of the 198Os, Cuba was not able to meet its sugar export

targets and in fact had to turn to the world market to purchase significant volumes of sugar for reexport to fulfill supply commitments to socialist nations.5

The current 1986-90 plan again foresees heavy investments in the sugar industry, including completion of several sugar mills already under construction and expansion and modernization of existing mills to support an increase in output of 15% compared to the average production of 7.8 million tons per annum achieved during 1981-85 (Lineamientos, 1986, pp. 7>74). In 1990, sugar production is expected to reach 11 million tons, rising to 1514 million tons by the year 2000 (“Conferencia,” 1981, p. 2).

In the face of worldwide oversupply of sugar and generally weak international market prices, Cuba justifies the expansion of sugar production as follows (“Otra batalla,” 1979, p. 20):

It may appear paradoxical that at a time [early 19791 when the price of raw sugar in the world market barely covers production costs, a country would build four new sugar mills. Severed from fluctuations in the world market, Cuban sugar has guaranteed demand in the Soviet Union and all other socialist countries. Moreover, this industry which continues to be the most important in the nation, is also the most economical one. It is a noble industry which can generate even the electricity it consumes and from whose derivatives can be obtained paper, particle board, alcohol, cattle feed, among others.

More recently, President Castro (1985, p. 20) has stressed the special conditions in trade with the socialist nations which justify Cuba’s expansion of its sugar industry:

Cuba’s situation is different because we have an enormous market in the socialist countries. All our sugar is already sold. The sugar we will produce in the next five-year period, as well as in the next 15 years, has already been sold to the socialist coun- tries. When the Cuban revolution triumphed, these countries [the socialist countries] had plans to increase their sugar output. They moderated their expansionary plans, directed investments to other areas of their economies, and reserved an important part of their markets for Cuban sugar exports. Cuba has already sold to the socialist countries all the sugar it can produce - above its world market quota - in the next 15 years. Thus we are expanding sugar production and even building new sugar mills.

Finally, former Foreign Trade Minister Marcel0 Fernandez has argued in strong terms (Oramas, 1986, p. 7) that expansion of the sugar industry is the proper policy for Cuba to follow:

Our growing possibility to export sugar to CMEA [Council for Mutual Economic Assistance] coun-

Page 5: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

SUGAR AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE 1631

tries and the need to regain our historical participa- tion levels in the world market leads us to the conclusion that Cuba is perhaps the only sugar- exporting developing country that can, and should, increase sugar production even in the current depressed conditions of the world sugar market.

3. SUGAR AND THE STRUCTURE OF THE CUBAN ECONOMY

Through the first half of the 18th century, sugar production in Cuba was relegated to small- scale enterprises and was secondary in import- ance to other economic activities such as tobacco, forestry, livestock, and shipbuilding (Marrero, 1984, pp. 135-272; Moreno Fraginals, 1978, Vol. 1, pp. 15-102). In the second half of the century, however, growing demand for sugar from Europe, coupled with very limited growth in output from traditional sugar suppliers - pri- marily small Caribbean nations - led to very high international sugar prices and stimulated the expansion of the Cuban industry. By the end of the century, Cuba was firmly established as a world-class sugar producer and exporter. So rapid was the expansion of the sugar industry that by the mid-18OOs, Cuba was responsible for nearly 40% of world sugar production from sugar cane and 30% of total sugar production (Moreno Fraginals, 1978, Vol. 3, p. 37). Cuban sugar exports grew very rapidly - from about 5,000 tons in 1760 to about 500,000 tons in the 1860s (Moreno Fraginals, 1978, Vol. 3, pp. 43-44) - and firmly established the sugar industry as the premier earner of foreign exchange.

(a) Sugar specialization

During the period 1949-58, the sugar sector (agriculture and industry) accounted for 2829% of Cuban gross national product (GNP).6 Although there is some evidence that sugar’s share of GNP was following a downward trend - for example, it was 25% in 1957-58, two years in which sugar output and exports were quite high (Table 1) - it is clear that prerevolutionary Cuba’s economy was severely skewed toward sugar production and suffered from the economic ills associated with monoculture.

Reviewing the statistical record, Carmelo Mesa-Lag0 (1986, p. 301; 1981, p. 57) concludes that revolutionary Cuba has had little success in reducing the role of sugar in the economy. He points out that sugar’s combined industrial/ agricultural share of the global social product (GSP) has hovered around one-tenth, with only a

slight tendency to decline; sugar’s shares of GSP were almost identical in 1962 and 1981, 11.4% and 11.5%, respectively. (For more recent years, sugar’s combined industrial/agricultural shares of GSP are: 1982,11.0%; 1983,9.9%; 1984, 10.3%; and 1985, 10.1% .‘) Based on these data and others, Mesa-Lag0 (1986, p. 299; 1981, p. 64) concludes that Cuba continues to have a mono- culture economy and that sugar monoculture may have been more pronounced in the late 1970s than in prerevolutionary Cuba.

Using the same basic statistical record and his own estimates of Cuban economic performance, Claes Brundenius (1984, p. 67) draws diametri- cally opposite conclusions. Although Brundenius concedes that changes in the structure of produc- tion were modest during the 1960s he argues that they accelerated during the 1970s. In his view, the relative importance of sugar in the Cuban economy has fallen sharply - according to his estimates, the share of Cuban gross domestic product (GDP) accounted for by sugar (agricul- tural and industrial activities combined) fell from 14.0% in 1970 to 7.9% in 1981. How to reconcile these two contradictory views?

Strictly speaking, it is not possible to trace the changes over time in Cuba’s structure of produc- tion - and in the relative importance of sugar within the Cuban economy - because the appropriate data are not available.* Cuban mac- roeconomic statistics for the prerevolutionary period were based on the System of National Accounts (SNA), the accounting system used by Western economies to measure economic activ- ity. In the early 1960s however, Cuba shifted to another accounting system, the Material Product System (MPS), used by centrally planned econo- mies. Through 1959, then, the available measure of overall Cuban economic activity is gross national product (GNP), while after 1962 the available measure is global social product (GSP). (Official statistics on macroeconomic activity for 1960 and 1961- under either system - have not been published.) GNP and GSP differ not only with respect to which sectors of the economy are covered (GSP excludes so-called nonproductive services sectors, such as education, housing, etc., which are included in GNP) but also with respect to the very concept of economic activity being measured: GSP includes the value of intermedi- ate outputs, while GNP measures only value added.

In addition to the problem of lacking a consistent base (i.e., GNP or GSP for both prerevolutionary and revolutionary periods) against which to gauge the development of sectors within the economy, there are other statistical problems which frustrate attempts to

Page 6: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

1632 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

determine secular shifts in Cuba’s production structure. In fact, a case could be made that the data limitations are so severe that it is not possible to measure with precision changes in the structure of Cuban production even for short time spans within the revolutionary period.

First, macroeconomic data for revolutionary Cuba reflect a mixture of sector data at constant and current prices. For some sectors (e.g., agriculture and industry, except for new pro- ducts), internal prices were fixed in the early 1960s and therefore output of these sectors has been reported primarily at constant prices. For other sectors (e.g., trade, transportation), however, output has been measured at current prices. Thus, measures of the composition of output by sector tend to be distorted, with agriculture’s and industry’s shares probably understating the importance of these sectors relative to others.

A second major problem is that, over time, the methodology used by Cuban statisticians to value output has changed, so that consistent time series on the value of output for sectors of the eco- nomy, and for the economy at large, are not available. For example, the output valuation method in use during the period 1962-72 was “complete circulation” (circulucidn completu), roughly equivalent to the so-called gross turnover method, which is affected by double counting. Since 1977, the output valuation method in use for most sectors - but not for agriculture, which remains under circulacibn completa - is “enter- prise exit” (a salida de empress), equivalent to the so-called enterprise method, which avoids double counting. The third problem is that the price reforms of 1981 (a wholesale price reform in January, followed by a retail price reform in December) introduce further discontinuities in the macroeconomic data as historical series based on the new price structure have not been published.

Notwithstanding the macroeconomic data limi- tations, Mesa-Lagos contention that sugar con- tinues to be one of the mainstays of the Cuban economy seems to be borne out by the available data. Whether the argument is posed in terms of the contribution of sugar to gross value of output generated by industry (which would control for the problem of overvaluation of output of certain sectors, e.g., trade, which report data valued at current prices) or of the contribution of sugar (agriculture and industry) to GSP at current prices, the results are quite similar.

In either case, the data suggest that the sugar industry continues to be a very important compo- nent of Cuba’s economy: within industry, sugar trails only the food, and the beverages and tobac-

co industries in terms of contribution to gross output at producer prices (Table 2). Although sugar agriculture outweighs all other nonsugar agricultural activities combined in terms of con- tribution to the gross value of output (livestock is the largest contributor to agricultural output, however), by 1985 sugar and nonsugar agricul- ture’s shares were virtually identical, suggesting a decline in the relative importance of sugar cultivation within agriculture. However, if the same comparison is made in terms of gross value of output at constant prices of 1965 - available from Cuban official statistics for the agricultural sector, with some gaps, but not at all for industry - a different picture emerges. The constant- price data (Table 3) suggest that sugar gained in importance within agriculture during the 1970s and 1980s compared to the 1960s. Over the period 1971-85, sugar’s share of agricultural output .remained remarkably stable at around 37%; sugar’s contribution to agricultural output peaked in 1977 at 41.1% and by 1985 it had declined by about five percentage points. As noted earlier, in the 1980s sugar industrial and agricultural activities combined accounted for about 10% of total GSP (at current prices), about the same share they have held during the entire revolutionary period.

Statistics on investment in sugar production activities and on area devoted to sugar cane cultivation also support the view that sugar continues to be one of the mainstays of the economy of contemporary Cuba. Regarding in- vestment, a pattern of heavy outlays in sugar- related activities - both industrial and agricultu- ral - is apparent. Disaggregated investment data are only available since 1975. During the period 1975-85, the sugar industrial sector was the largest recipient of investment resources, averag- ing around 20% of total industrial investment (Table 4). In 1985, nearly 25% of the value of investments in the industrial sector were sugar industry related. Similarly, investments in sugar cane agriculture have also been high, taking about one-third of total agricultural investment.

As can be observed from Table 5, area under sugar cane cultivation tended to increase through the 1970s and 1980s. (Unfortunately, systematic statistics are not available on total land under cultivation or on land devoted to other crops. It is, therefore, not possible to make relative com- parisons of land devoted to cultivation of sugar cane and of other crops.) In 1985, over 1.757 million hectares of land were devoted to sugar cane. This is slightly above the previous historical high of 1.752 million hectares under cultivation in 1982 and substantially above the area devoted to sugar cane cultivation during the prerevolution-

Page 7: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

SUGAR AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE 1633

Table 2. Distribution of gross industrial output*, by branches of the industrial sector (percentages)

1975 1980 1981 1982 1984 1985

Industry

Electricity Fuels Ferrous mining

& metallurgy Nonferrous mining

& metallurgy Nonelectrical machinery Electronics Metal products Chemicals Paper and cellulose Printing Wood products Construction materials Glass & ceramics Textiles Apparel Leather Sugar Food Fishine Bevergges & tobacco Others

100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0

2.1 3.4 4.8 4.8 4.6 3.9 6.3 5.2 5.4 5.3 4.6 4.5

0.9 0.9

0.9 1.1 4.6 6.5 2.3 1.7 1.6 1.7 9.7 8.0 1.2 1.2 1.3 1.4 2.0 1.9 4.1 4.0 0.5 0.5 2.1 1.7 4.3 4.9 2.7 2.1 9.3 9.3

19.2 19.5 1.3 1.6

20.2 19.7 3.3 3.7

1.1

1.4 5.8 1.1 1.5 6.6 1.4 0.9 1.4 3.9 0.3 1.7 2.1 1.6

15.0 19.6 2.2

18.0 4.3

1.2 1.1

1.3 1.2 6.4 7.5 0.9 1.2 1.6 1.7 5.5 5.8 1.4 1.5 0.9 0.9 1.3 1.4 3.5 3.3 0.4 0.4 1.6 1.6 1.9 1.9 1.6 1.4

14.7 14.7 19.6 19.3 2.4 2.6

19.8 19.3 4.1 4.4

1.2

1.2 7.8 1.2 1.6 6.2 1.6 0.9 1.3 3.3 0.4 1.8 2.0 1.4

13.9 18.8 2.6

19.9 4.5

*At producer prices. Source: 1984-85: Anuario (1985). DD. 110-111. 1975, 1981-82: Anuario (1984), p. 90. 1980: Anuario (1982), p. 97. _ ’ ”

ary period: the area devoted to sugar cane cultivation was nearly 20% higher in 1985 than during the prerevolutionary record-high crop year 1952.

Brundenius’ contention that the role of sugar in the Cuban economy has fallen sharply is based on his estimates of the value of output of the sugar sector and of the gross domestic product (GDP). The methodology he uses appears to introduce a severe downward bias to sugar’s share of GDP.

As discussed above, Cuban official statistics indicate that in 1957-58, sugar accounted for about 25% of Cuban GNP. However, based on Brundenius’ estimates of the value of production of the sugar sector and of GDP (Brundenius, 1984, pp. 39, 147), sugar’s share of GDP in 1958 is 12.8%) about one-half the share obtained from the official data.’ Sugar’s share of GDP based on his estimates is 12.7% for 1959, 12.4% for 1960 and 13.7% for 1961. At least for these early years, Brundenius’ estimates of the value of sugar output and of GDP tend to impart a severe downward bias to sugar’s share.

It is more difficult to assess whether his estimates for later periods are afflicted by the same biases as there are no comparable official statistics against which to gauge them. Brunde- nius uses three different methodologies for esti- mating the value of output of the sugar sector and GDP for the time periods 194fS-61, 1961-68 and 1968-80. As noted above, sugar’s share of GDP based on the estimating methodology he used for the period 1946-61 is 13.7%, but it is 12.6% based on the methodology he used for 1961-68. It appears, then, that the methodology used for the more recent periods (1961-68 and 1968-80) continues to impart a downward bias to sugar’s share of GDP.

(b) Sugar export concentration

The export orientation of the Cuban sugar industry has persisted through contemporary times. As is clear from data in Table 1, over the period 1950-85, Cuba exported, on average, over 90% of its physical output of sugar. In the most

Page 8: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

1634 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 3. Gross value of output of agriculture and of sugar cane production (million pesos)

Year

At current prices At constant prices

Sugar CanelAg Sugar CanelAg Agriculture cane (%) Agriculture cane (%)

1962 940.6 283.8 30.2 1963 904.2 235.1 26.0 1964 958.5 265.5 27.7 1965 1074.0 367.1 34.2 1966 1041.9 268.6 25.8 1967 1111.9 352.9 31.7 1968 1352.4 394.2 29.1 1206.4 474.0 39.3 1969 1289.2 406.3 31.5 1970 1182.4 559.2 45.5 1971 1091.6 471.0 43.1 1972 1151.5 457.5 39.7 1973 1206.6 482.1 40.0 1974 1258.4 480.2 38.1 1975 1537.7 553.6 36.0 1399.6 513.4 36.7 1976 1673.9 596.3 35.6 1448.6 511.7 35.7 1977 1747.9 684.2 39.1 1502.3 583.6 38.8 1978 1849.5 745.0 40.3 1591.3 654.3 41.1 1979 1962.2 744.2 37.9 1611.9 634.4 39.4 1980 2168.6 758.6 35.0 1587.6 610.6 38.5 1981 3498.9 1144.3 32.7 1791.8 701.3 39.1 1982 3393.3 1056.1 31.1 1692.6 654.5 38.7 1983 3361 .O 970.3 28.9 1675.1 633.1 37.8 1984 3566.1 1003.3 28.1 1750.6 643.7 37.1 1985 3693.7 1008.8 27.3 1726.4 607.1 35.2

Sources: 198&85: Anuario (1985), 112, 279. 197g80: Anuario (1984), 90, 186. 1975-77: pp. pp. Anuario (1978), 50,64. 1968-74: Anuario (1974), 35. 1968 (constant price): Anuario (1977), pp. p. p. 62. 1967: Anuario (1972), pp. 30, 62. 1962-66: Boletin (1970), pp. 30, 32.

recent decade, for example, 92% of sugar output was exported.

Historically, the Cuban economy has de- pended on sugar for the lion’s share of its export earnings. In the 20th century, for example, the average shares of the value of sugar exports relative to the value of total exports, based on official data, are:”

1900-09: 55.9% 1910-19: 78.6% 192@29: 85.2% 1930-39: 77.3% 194@49: 81.4% 195&59: 81.4% 196069: 83.3% 197&79: 82.2%.

For the first half of the 1980s sugar’s share of the value of total exports is 76.7%) and 74.1% for 1985.” President Castro (1980a, p. 3) described the role of the sugar industry in Cuba’s external sector as follows at a gathering of sugar workers in October 1980:

[T]he sugar industry is the largest generator of foreign exchange, of soft currency as well as of freely convertible currency. The sugar industry is the great producer of foreign exchange, the pro- ducer of the resources the country needs in order to finance operation of the rest of the economy and the services sector. It is true that other sectors of the economy are growing, true that mining, tobacco, and fishing all contribute to the economy, and industry is contributing more, but nothing can be compared with the thousands of million pesos in foreign exchange contributed by the sugar industry.

Concentrating on the record through the 1970s several analysts outside Cuba (e.g., Leo- Grande, 1979, pp. 8-9; Mesa-Lago, 1986, p. 301 and 1981, pp. 82-83; Packenham, 1986, p. 63; Rota, 1989, p. 103) have argued that Cuba’s dependency on sugar exports has continued unabated during the revolutionary period. The view that revolutionary Cuba has enjoyed very modest success in diversifying its export basket is confirmed by statistical measures published by

Page 9: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

SUGAR AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE

Table 4. Distribution of investment, by branches of the industrial sector (percentages)

1635

1975 1980 1981 1982 1984 1985

Industry

Electricity Fuels Ferrous mining

& metallurgy Nonferrous mining

& metallurgy Nonelectrical machinery Electronics Metal products Chemicals Paper and cellulose Printing Wood products Construction materials Glass & ceramics Textiles Apparel Leather Sugar Food Fishing Beverages & tobacco Others

100.0 loo.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0

8.3 12.3 9.9 13.5 19.0 15.7 1.3 3.5 5.2 6.3 6.7 5.9

4.3 1.5 0.9 1.8 3.0 4.3

1.4 16.6 14.7 11.6 12.4 13.3 8.1 11.4 9.6 11.1 7.3 6.6 0.6 2.1 1.7 1.2 0.9 0.9 1.3 0.8 0.8 1.2 1.3 1.9 8.5 2.6 2.5 3.0 2.6 4.1

0.5 5.6 10.4 3.7 2.0 1.4 0.5 0.4 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.1

5.3 0.5 0.3 0.3 0.5 0.2

8.2 8.0 5.3 5.7 7.3 5.9 0.1 1.2 1.1 1.0 0.6 0.8 0.4 10.6 7.1 7.3 2.9 2.3 0.4 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.4 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.6 0.6 0.4

20.6 13.7 17.8 20.7 20.1 23.8 5.3 5.9 5.0 4.6 4.7 3.5

22.8 1.7 1.6 1.5 1.9 2.3 1.2 0.8 1.0 1.5 3.0 3.1 0.8 0.4 4.4 3.1 2.9 3.0

Source: 1984-85: Anuario (1985), p. 206. 1975, 1981-82: Anuario (1984), p. 122. 1980: Anuario (1982), p. 136.

the United Nations Conference on Trade and

Development (UNCTAD) for developed and de-

veloping nations.

UNCTAD’s indexes of export concentration, a variant of the concentration index developed by Hirschman, l2 measure the relative concentration in the export structure of a country; index values range from zero to one, with the latter indicating maximum concentration. Table 6 reproduces UNCTAD’s export concentration indexes for Cuba and other Latin American nations for 1960, 1966, 1970, 1975 and 1983. The countries are listed in order of decreasing value of the concen- tration index in 1983. Cuba’s export concentra- tion indexes not only tend to be very high in absolute terms (higher than 0.771 for each of the five years reported in Table 6) but also were the highest for Latin America as a whole, with the exception of Suriname and Bolivia in 1960 and Uruguay in 1966. Thus, Cuba and oil-exporting Venezuela tended to be the Latin American countries whose export structures were most highly concentrated. At the other extreme, Brazil, Argentina, Peru and Mexico (before oil exports became significant) tended to have the most diversified export structures. (For 1983, the

most recent year for which these measures are available, the highest export concentration index reported by UNCTAD is 0.978 for Nauru; the lowest is 0.079 for Yugoslavia.)

Analysts who have suggested that Cuban sugar export dependency continues to be high have been taken to task by Brundenius (1984, pp. 62- 63) for failing to consider that the value of sugar exports is distorted by fluctuations in the world sugar market price and, more importantly, by the very high price the Soviet Union pays for Cuban sugar, two factors he claims tend to overstate sugar’s contribution to the value of exports. (This criticism is also applicable to the work of economists in Cuba. For example, two recent studies by economists associated with the Cuban government (Diaz-Vbquez, 1981, pp. 141-142; ValdCs, 1984, p. 132) also rely on raw value of exports data to make the point that Cuba’s export basket consists of a very limited number of products.) Brundenius (1984, p. 75) has made estimates of the value of Cuban sugar exports “at constant prices” which suggest substantially lower sugar export shares after 1974 than obtained from the official data: 73.7% compared to 87.2% from official trade data in 1974; 73.5

Page 10: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

1636 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 5. Land under sugar cane cultivation (in thousand hectares)

Year*t Area under cultivation

1952 1,425 1953 1.605 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958

1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985

11541 1,444 1.346 1,323 1,583

1,417 1,535 1.504 1;436 1,389 1.421 1,450 1,507 1,533 1,630 1,640 1,685 1,659 1.725 1,752 1,743 1,750 1,757

*Data for 1952-58 are given in source in caballerias; the conversion from caballerias to hectares has been made using 1 caballeria = 13.42 hectares. tData for 1952-58 refer to land under sugar cane culti- vation and available for each of the zafras; for 1968-85, the data refer to sugar cane plantings as of 31 December of the reporting year.- - Source: 1978-85: Anuario (1985). p. 284. 1968-77: Anuario (1977), p. 67. 1952-58: ‘&ba Econ6mica y Financiera (1959), p. 115.

versus 88.2% in 1978; 70.0 versus 89.2% in 1980. The methodology he used to estimate Cuban exports at constant prices is not spelled out, however.

Elsewhere, relying on raw Cuban export statis- tics, Brundenius and Zimbalist (1985a, p. 41) have made the point that in the 198Os, sugar’s share of the value of exports has dropped significantly - to 79.1% in 1981, 77.1% in 1982, and 73.8% in 1983. More recently, Zimbalist and Eckstein (1987, p. 16) have made a similar argument noting that sugar’s share of the value of exports fell to 75.7% during 1983-84. The declin- ing trend, in these authors’ view, is evidence of substantial export diversification during the 1980s. However, not taken into account by these

analysts is that part of the reduction in sugar’s export share results from the anomalous situation whereby Cuban reexports of Soviet oil recently became a significant source of export revenue.13 If the official export data are adjusted to elimi- nate oil reexports (Table 7), sugar’s average export share during 1981-85 rises from 76.5% to 83.2%.

The very high prices the Soviet Union pays for certain Cuban imports such as sugar and nickel - reportedly, the contract price for Cuban sugar sales to the Soviet Union in 1985 was around 45 cents/pound, compared to a world market price of just above four cents/pound (ECLAC, 1986, p. 18) - which combine elements of trade and aid, and Cuba’s reexports of Soviet oil tend to distort official trade statistics and limit their usefulness in exploring secular changes in the composition of the export basket. Conceptually, adjusting the trade data to remove the impact of oil reexports - not an indigenous product - is a straightforward procedure (see Table 7). It is much more difficult to adjust the data to factor out the aid element from the very high prices the Soviet Union pays for Cuban imports. Doing so requires decomposing the price at which Cuba sells products (sugar, nickel) to the Soviet Union into two components: (1) a “normal” price at which the products are traded; and (2) the aid the Soviet Union grants to Cuba via price premiums. (In what follows, nickel sales to the Soviet Union are not considered.)

Adjusting Cuban trade statistics to account for very high prices of sugar sales to the Soviet Union is tantamount to eliminating from the official trade statistics the price subsidies granted Cuba by the Soviet Union. Let the difference between the price the Soviet Union pays for Cuban sugar and the alternative price at which Cuba could have sold its sugar to other pur- chasers (the “opportunity price”) be the subsidy margin. Then, the subsidy Cuba receives over a given time period can be calculated as the subsidy margin times the volume of exports to the Soviet Union. The thorny question is, at which price could Cuba have sold to other purchasers the sugar it sold to the Soviet Union?

Elsewhere (PCrez-Lbpez, 1988) I have re- viewed in considerable detail the sugar price subsidy issue and estimated a range of possible values of the Soviet sugar subsidy to Cuba using several “opportunity prices”: (1) the world mar- ket price; (2) the US import price; (3) preferen- tial prices in the United States and the European Economic Community (EEC); (4) the price at which Cuba sold sugar to selected market econo- mies (Canada, Japan, Spain) pursuant to con- tracts; and (5) the price at which the Soviet

Page 11: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

SUGAR AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE 1637

Table 6. Export concentration indexes

1960 1966 1970 1975 1983

Cuba Venezuela Suriname Ecuador Mexico Colombia El Salvador Bolivia Guyana Jamaica Belize Grenada Dominican Republic Costa Rica Nicaragua Honduras Chile Paraguay Panama Guatemala Uruguay Peru Argentina Haiti Brazil

0.766 0.864* 0.725 0.702 0.821 0.754 0.644 0.650t 0.272 0.243 0.743 0.664 0.712 0.500 0.7958 0.73811 0.543 0.554 0.560 0.536 0.492 0.466

0.541 0.609 0.460 0.511 0.6548 0.3180 0.561C 0.694 0.4451 0.293§ 0.300

0.580

0.598 0.462 0.517’ 0.531 0.74711 0.34511 0.592 0.496 0.91711 0.83211 0.322

0.40611 0.463

0.771 0.659 0.728 0.495 0.116 0.622 0.472 0.542 0.582 0.460 0.524 0.610 0.519 0.398 0.275 0.431 0.754 0.231 0.568 0.332 0.409 0.350 0.222 0.386 0.335

0.871 0.688 0.491 0.564 0.174 0.530$ 0.448$ 0.444

0.509$ 0.770 0.565 0.563 0.337$ 0.313$ 0.358$ 0.547$ 0.272 0.492 0.306 0.271$ 0.287 0.164 0.280$ 0.237-J

0.733 0.611 0.543 0.532 0.516 0.488 0.488 0.483 0.472 0.462 0.431 0.431 0.430 0.379 0.375 0.372 0.350 0.338 0.316 0.280 0.271 0.237 0.212 0.201 0.133

‘1965. t1964. $1976. $1962. 111968. Source: UNCLAD (1985) and earlier issues.

Table 7. Sugar export shares based on total exports and on nonfuel exports (million pesos and percentages)

Sugar as a % of:

Total Fuels Nonfuel Sugar Total Nonfuel Year exports exports exports exports exports exports

1975 2952.2 2.7 2949.5 2655.9 90.0 90.1 1977 2918.4 67.1 2851.3 2438.3 83.6 85.5 1978 3440.1 46.0 3394.1 2981.1 86.7 87.8 1979 3499.2 56.0 3443.2 3011.4 86.1 87.5 1980 3966.7 168.4 3798.3 3327.3 83.8 87.6 1981 4223.8 178.9 4044.9 3346.2 79.2 82.7 1982 4933.2 338.3 4594.9 3813.1 77.3 83.0 1983 5534.9 586.6 4948.3 4102.2 74.1 82.9 1984 5476.5 573.9 4902.6 4130.6 75.4 84.3 1985 5983.0 619.7 5363.3 4462.6 74.6 83.2

Source: Anuario (1985) and earlier issues.

Page 12: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

1638 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Union purchased sugar from other developing countries (e.g., Brazil, the Philippines). In gene- ral, the subsidy margins - and therefore the level of Soviet subsidization - are largest when the world market price is used as the opportunity price, and lowest when preferential prices in either the United States or the EEC are used.

To illustrate the effect of the Soviet sugar price subsidies on the trade statistics, Table 8 presents sets of estimates of sugar’s share of total Cuban nonfuel exports derived from official trade statis- tics adjusted to extract the subsidies. These hypothetical estimates are subject to numerous caveats and should be treated merely as illustra- tive. For comparative purposes, column 1 of Table 8 presents sugar’s share of nonfuel exports

as computed from the actual official trade data. Columns 2-7 contain estimates of sugar’s share based on adjusted trade data, where the adjust- ment has been to assume that the sugar sold to the Soviet Union in each year was traded at some hypothetical price different from the actual price. Conversions of the hypothetical price (or unit value - UV) from dollars or rubles to pesos have been made at the official exchange rates. Column 2, for example, presents estimates of sugar’s share assuming that Cuban sugar exports to the Soviet Union during each year were made at world market prices. Columns 4 and 5 do the same under the assumption that sales were effected at the prices the United States and the EEC paid to preferred exporters.

Table 8. Sugar exports as a share of nonfuel exports (percentages)

Based on alternative valuations of sugar sales to Soviet Union

us Preferential Cuban Soviet World import prices export import

Year Actual price UV US EEC UV’ UV

1962 82.8 80.8 84.7 85.8 84.8 1963 86.8 87.9 87.1 87.8 86.6 1964 85.9 85.6 86.2 86.5 85.6 1965 85.8 79.6 85.6 86.5 85.5 1966 84.3 78.1 84.0 85.2 84.1 1967 71.1 60.2 71.4 73.5 70.5 1968 76.8 69.0 77.3 78.7 75.2 1969 75.6 72.4 76.2 77.2 74.4 1970 76.9 73.0 78.1 79.5 75.2 1971 76.4 75.0 77.3 78.5 75.5 1972 72.8 73.5 74.1 74.9 73.3 1973 75.4 73.9 72.8 74.2 71.3 1974 86.5 88.5 86.5 88.4 84.2 1975 90.0 88.7 89.2 88.2 89.0 1976 88.1 82.1 82.6 81.2 82.1 1977 85.5 73.0 73.9 65.9 68.4 1978 87.8 73.3 73.3 74.9 76.0 1979 87.5 75.6 74.9 74.5 77.6 1980 87.6 84.3 82.3 84.6 82.7 1981 82.7 77.0 77.9 78.1 77.8 1982 83.0 68.9 72.6 74.3 73.0 1983 82.9 67.3 71.1 75.4 73.2 1984 84.3 63.3 70.4 76.7 73.5 1985 83.2 55.3 65.6 74.1 71.3

75.2 73.1 73.1 86.4 90.6 84.8 76.7 73.0 74.9 83.2 76.7 69.0 66.2 63.2 54.6

72.5 73.5 86.5 93.2 82.7 72.4 73.6 78.0 81.0 80.3 70.6 67.6 56.1 53.9

*Exports to Canada, Spain and Japan. Sources: Actual - Based on official trade data from Anuario (1985) and earlier issues adjusted to extract sales of fuel exports (see Table 7). Alternative valuations - Based on official trade data adjusted to extract sates of fuel exports and Soviet sugar price subsidies cal- culated on the basis of hypothetical prices. See explanations in text and subsidy estimates in Perez-Mpez (1988).

Page 13: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

SUGAR AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE 1639

The estimates of sugar’s share of nonfuel exports in Table 8 are quite close for the period 1962-75 regardless of which alternative price is used to value sugar exports to the Soviet Union. In fact, for some years (e.g., 1963, 1974), sugar shares derived using the world market price or the US or EEC preferential prices to value exports to the Soviet Union are higher than those derived from actual data. This is the case because actual prices in Cuban-Soviet sugar sales in those years were below prices in other markets. Over this period, the estimates in Table 8 suggest that there was a dip in sugar’s export share toward the end of the 1960s but by the mid-1970s Cuba’s dependence on sugar for export revenues was probably at its peak.

After 1976, the year when a new pricing mechanism for Cuban sugar sales to the Soviet Union began to operate - a method that set a very high floor price, annually indexed pro- portionally to increases in the prices of Soviet exports to Cuba relative to the prices they commanded in 197514 - and Soviet aid to Cuba via sugar price subsidies began to escalate, estimates of sugar’s share of exports differ significantly depending on which hypothetical price is used. These differences are most acute for the 1980s: while the official data (i.e., including the subsidies) show sugar’s share of exports at above 80% for 1981-85 (column l), this share would have been around 67% had Cuba sold its exports to the Soviet Union at prevailing world market prices (column 2). Using the world market price as the hypothetical sales price, the Soviet Union transferred the equiva- lent of 11.6 billion pesos in subsidies to Cuba during 1981-85, roughly 58% of the actual value of total sugar exports over this period. However, if the US preferential price is used as the hypothetical price for exports to the Soviet Union, sugar’s estimated share of exports for 1981-85 is nearly 76% (column 4), and the Soviet sugar subsidy 7.4 billion pesos or 37% of the value of sugar exports.

Even if the official trade data are adjusted to extract Soviet sugar price subsidies, the statistical record is quite clear that sugar continues to play a predominant role in the Cuban export basket. Using the US preferential price as the hypotheti- cal price at which to value exports to the Soviet Union - there is some logic in using this method as presumably it yields estimates comparable with those for prerevolutionary Cuba, a period when Cuba sold the bulk of its sugar exports to the United States at US preferential prices - data in Table 8 suggest that sugar’s share of the value of exports in revolutionary Cuba has tended to behave cyclically, varying annually

within the range of 7489%. Sugar’s share of the value of exports was over four-fifths in 196266, dipped in 1967-73 to about three-quarters, re- covered in 1974-76, and dropped again to the three-quarters range after 1977 (with the excep- tion of 1980).

(c) Sugar prices and economic performance

International commodity markets are charac- terized by price volatility. Swings in world mar- ket prices can have a severe impact on export revenues, and on economic performance, of countries specializing in commodity exports.

Cuba’s efforts to stabilize sugar world produc- tion and prices began in earnest in the 1920s. In 1926, Cuba unilaterally reduced sugar production to try to prop up world market prices and the following year convened the first international meeting of sugar exporters with the same pur- pose. Cuba was a key participant in the 1929 Brussels Conference, which resulted in a four- year agreement aimed at stabilizing international sugar prices, as well as in each of the Intematio- nal Sugar Agreements which have been in effect since the early 1930s.15

As is clear from data in Table 9, over the period 1955-81 sugar showed by far the highest degree of price volatility among all major com- modities - an average annual change in world market price (absolute value) of nearly 42%, with the change in price in a given year fluctuat- ing 19% relative to a three-year moving average and 30% relative to a five-year moving average. To some extent, the volatility of international sugar prices is the result of actions by sugar- producing countries to insulate themselves from world market price fluctuations - by entering into long-term contractual commitments at fixed prices - that exacerbate price swings in the world market. As more sugar is sold through long-term contracts (typically preferential price agreements), the world market becomes more of a residual market, exposed to wild price swings. l6

Moreover, it has been suggested that Cuban trade with the Soviet Union and socialist nations has tended to add to world sugar price volatility because the latter countries have reexported substantial amounts of Cuban sugar. Reportedly, during the 1966-70 period, socialist countries (CMEA members plus the People’s Republic of China) reexported to the world market about 52% of the sugar they imported from Cuba pursuant to long-term contracts. These resales increased the availability of sugar in the world market, contributed to lower world market prices, and affected Cuba’s ability to generate

Page 14: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 9. Indices of fluctuations in world market commodity prices, in 1981 constant dollars* (percent changes)

Commodity

Deviations from Annual moving average average

3-year 5-year change

Petroleum 6.3 9.4 17.7 Coffee 7.1 12.1 17.8 Cocoa 10.2 16.8 25.3 Tea 4.8 6.2 9.7 Sugar 18.8 30.3 41.6 Beef 5.9 7.2 11.8 Bananas 3.4 5.9 7.0 Oranges 6.6 8.5 15.4 Rice 7.0 14.1 16.6 Wheat 4.5 7.9 10.2 Maize 4.6 6.9 9.5 Grain sorghum 4.2 5.9 8.7 Palm oil 7.7 10.7 13.9 Coconut oil 11.5 16.4 20.3 Groundnut oil 7.3 10.8 14.2 Soybeans 6.0 8.3 10.8 Copra 11.8 18.4 22.8 Groundnuts 6.0 9.6 12.6 Soybean meal 7.5 10.8 13.2 Cotton 4.7 6.8 10.1 Jute 6.9 9.2 15.6 Rubber 7.9 12.1 16.3 Tobacco 6.1 5.8 10.8 Logs (lauan) 6.6 8.9 14.0 Copper 9.1 15.3 18.5 Tin 5.3 8.1 10.4 Nickel 2.6 4.6 7.1 Aluminum 2.4 4.6 6.2 Lead 9.2 14.7 18.8 Zinc 8.4 14.4 17.8 Iron ore 4.1 5.7 8.4 Bauxite 3.7 5.6 8.0 Manganese ore 4.0 7.2 10.3 Phosphate rock 6.7 13.8 17.4

*Indices calculated on the basis of annual price data in 1981 constant dollars for 1955-81. Annual average change is the average of the absolute value of annual percentage changes. Source: Computed by the Commodity Studies and Projections Division, Economic Analysis and Projections Department, The World Bank, as reported in Fry (1985)! p. 11

hard currency from world market sales (Smith, 1984, p. 369). There are indications that the Soviets have been active in the world sugar market in more recent periods as well (Fowler, 1974, 63-64).

A recent econometric study of Cuban sugar trade (Tan, 1986: v-vi) has estimated the long- run elasticity of world sugar price with respect to Cuba’s export share to be about -0.7 in this historical period. That is, a 1% increase in Cuba’s share of the world market induces a 0.7%

decline in the world sugar price in nominal terms. Should Cuba succeed in its ambitious plans to increase sugar production over the rest of the century, and demand for sugar from socialist nations fail to keep pace, substantial quantities of Cuban sugar are likely to gravitate toward the world market and put downward pressure on world prices to the detriment of all exporting countries using the world market. One analyst (Turns, 1987, p. 177) has questioned whether the Soviet Union can absorb increasing quantities of

Page 15: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

SUGAR AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE 1641

Cuban sugar exports implied by Cuba’s ambi- Table 10. Destination of Cuban sugar exports (per-

tious production plans. centages based on physical quantity of exports)

To be sure, Cuba has traditionally sold the bulk of its sugar exports under preferential arrangements - first, to the United States, and currently to the Soviet Union and socialist nations - at more stable and higher prices than the world market price. Nevertheless, the level of sugar prices in the world market influences Cuban economic performance. This is so be- cause, over certain time periods, preferential prices received by Cuba have borne some rela- tionship to world market prices. Moreover, in addition to sales pursuant to preferential arrangements, Cuba has traditionally disposed of substantial quantities of sugar in the world market (Eckstein, 1980, p. 264). In 1985, the most recent year for which data are available, 24.4% of Cuban sugar exports went to other than socialist countries, presumably at world market prices, compared to 42.1% a year earlier (Table 10). In contemporary Cuba, sugar sales on the world market have gained in strategic signifi- cance since they generate convertible currency - which Cuba can not typically obtain from its socialist trading partners - necessary to finance the import of goods and services from market economies and service hard currency debt.17

Thus, while preferential arrangements have insulated the Cuban economy from the vagaries of the world sugar market, the insulation has not been by any means total. As Vice President Carlos Rafael Rodriguez expressed in 1977 (Col- lar Fraguela, 1977, p. 31):

United States

Socialist countries*

Rest of the world

1950 1951 1952

54.6 45.4 48.4 51.6

1953 1954 195.5 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1%2 1%3

53.2 45.9 57.0 55.5 52.1 52.5 57.5 59.3 34.6

0.1 0.2

10.4 5.0 7.3 4.5 5.5

40.5 75.2 72.9

46.8 54.0 42.8 34.1 42.9 40.2 38.0 35.2 24.9 24.8

1964 1965

59.1 63.7

1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971

67.9 73.5 69.2 69.4 59.9 69.5 60.8 56.5 63.0

27.1 40.9 36.3 32.1 26.5 30.8 30.6 40.1 30.5

1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979

39.2 43.5

60.4 71.2

Our preferential agreements with the Soviet Union and other socialist nations members of CMEA regarding prices eliminate the unequal exchange relation which affects developing country exporters of raw materials, and permit us to plan, with certainty, our steady development.

But Cuba can not escape totally the uncertainties of the capitalist market, still an important destina- tion of our sugar exports and a key source of technology which we can not renounce. As a result, although a fall in [world market] sugar prices cannot ruin us, as it could during the times of foreign domination, negative conditions in the world mar- ket, such as we are experiencing now, affect deeply our foreign earnings, over 30% of which originate from capitalist markets.

1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985

76.0 64.7 56.3 57.5 47.3 65.5 80.1 76.2 57.9 75.6

37.0 39.6 28.8 24.0 35.3 43.7 42.5 52.7 34.5 19.9 23.8 42.1 24.4

*Albania, Bulgaria, People’s Republic of China, Czechoslovakia, German Democratic Republic, Hungary, Mongolia, North Korea, Poland, Romania, Soviet Union, Vietnam and Yugoslavia. Source: Computed from data in IS0 (1985) and earlier issues.

The adverse impact of low world sugar market prices on Cuban economic performance, and the beneficial impact of high prices, have been noted by numerous officials and analysts. The mechan- ism through which changes in international sugar prices affect Cuban economic performance may be as follows: changes in sugar export prices affect export revenue, which in turn affects the

ability to import necessary intermediate goods (and thus production in the short term) as well as capital goods (and future production); export revenue in excess of import needs finances consumption from abroad in earlier periods (in the form of repayment of export credits) and enhances the ability to finance future consump- tion from abroad, by improving credit worthiness and the ability to obtain additional export credits (Mesa-Lag0 and Ptrez-Mpez, 1985c, p. 59; Rodriguez, 1982, p. 115).

Page 16: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

1642 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Because of the very limited basket of hard currency exports, Cuba’s ability to generate hard currency revenues to operate the segment of the economy which depends on imports from capital- ist countries is closely associated with internatio- nal sugar prices. It has been observed that the makeup of Cuba’s import basket is sensitive to world sugar market prices; when world market prices are high (e.g., 1974) and hard currency from sugar sales is available, Cuba tends to increase its share of imports from capitalist countries, while the opposite is the case when world market prices are low (Smith, 1984, p. 369; Carciofi, 1983, p. 217).

Speaking in September 1976 - at a time when world market sugar prices had softened, after a period when they had reached record-high levels - President Castro (1976, p. 2) said:

It is sad that the time when we are making the greatest efforts to undertake these steps forward in the political, state [organization] and social fields should coincide with an unfavorable economic situation. These problems are mainly caused by the fact that there has been an extraordinary drop in the market price of sugar. . These price fluctuations on the world market are really hair raising. And such things as the price of sugar are truly beyond the control of our revolution.

In a report issued to Western creditors in mid- 1982, the Cuban National Bank (Banco Nacio- nal, 1982, p. 34) gave the following explanation for the economic problems which had precipi- tated the need to request a renegotiation of the hard currency debt:

The most important factor continues to be the behavior of sugar prices. Its typical cycle - in the absence of an effective international agreement - affects foreign exchange planning and, consequent- ly, that of foreign expenditures. . At times price declines at short notice have been so severe that not even conservative estimates of price trends have been able to discount their effects. . [A] sudden price drop in the latter months of 1975, just before the plan was implemented, made a quick adjust- ment necessary, with a four-cent reduction in the planned price. This logically led to a revision of national economic plans. Moreover, the unpredicta- bility of the change had a negative effect on the balance of trade during the initial years of the plan period.

Referring to the same period, Dominguez (1978,

P. 148) made the foliowing assessment: _

The extraordinary increase in the world price of sugar [during the first half of the 197Os] became a powerful stimulant to the Cuban economy, dramati- cally improving terms of trade. . Cuba launched the first sustained period of real growth in per capita income in revolutionary history. Capitalist sugar-

price inflation at last rescued the Cuban economy in the early 1970s. The decline of the world price of sugar in 1975 ended the bonanza: Cuban annual economic-growth rates for the second half of the decade are expected to slow down by 40%, com- pared to the 1971-75 period, under the 1976-80 five-year plan. But it is plain that the sustained increase of the world price of sugar from 1968 to 1974 had rescued the Cuban economy.

Finally, a study of industrialization in Cuba by the United Nations Industrial Development

Organization (UNIDO, 1986, pp. 3-4) states:

The Cuban economy experienced deceleration when the price of suiar degan descent from the $0.65 high of November 1974 and collapsed to about $0:08 a pound in mid-1976. The price of this key component of Cuba’s export soared in 1980, but fell by almost 70% in the early 1980s. The change in sugar prices largely attests to the change in econo- mic conditions. . Despite advances in economic diversification, sugar continues to remain the back- bone of the Cuban economy.

A study which attempted to estimate Cuban GDP/capita in dollars using the physical indica- tors approach (Mesa-Lag0 and Perez-L6pez, 1985a and 1985b) noted that this technique may not be suitable to economies such as Cuba which depend heavily on a single export commodity subject to highly volatile price behavior. Thus, estimates of Cuban GDP/capita in dollars based on the behavior of consumption-oriented, rela- tively stable, physical indicators failed to reflect the impact on the economy of external shocks, such as a drop in world sugar market prices which occurred in 1976-78. In support of this view, a simple correlation between the absolute levels of international sugar prices and GSP at current prices (GSP at constant prices was not available) over the period 1962-81 yielded a coefficient of 0.68, and with a one-year time lag the coefficient was 0.76, suggesting that there was a significant statistical relationship between world sugar mar- ket prices and GSP (Mesa-Lag0 and PCrez- L6pez, 1985c, p. 59). Criticisms of this test arguing, for instance, that it is invalid because of a time trend in both variables (Brundenius and Zimbalist, 1985b, p. 129) have been rebutted by demonstrating that the world sugar market price does not exhibit a clear time trend (Mesa-Lag0 and PCrez-L6pez, 1985d, p. 79).

Dominguez (1989) observes that, for the first time in revolutionary history, the Cuban eco- nomy was able to grow during the first half of the 1980s despite very low world sugar market prices. He attributes the change in the historical rela- tionship between world sugar market prices and domestic economic performance to the generos- ity of the Soviet Union. Not only did the Soviet

Page 17: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

SUGAR AND STRUCWRAL CHANGE 1643

Union transfer massive amounts of resources to Cuba during this period via sugar price subsidies - which assured Cuba’s ability to maintain adequate levels of imported goods from the Soviet Union and socialist countries - but it also provided Cuba with an alternative hard currency export commodity - oil - which made up for hard currency shortfalls associated with low world market sugar prices. Indeed, during the period 198%35, oil reexports were Cuba’s princi- pal hard currency export earner, generating almost twice the level of hard currency revenue attributable to sugar exports (Banco National, 1985, p. 31). The sharp drop in the world market price of oil, which began in late 1985, has adversely affected Cuba’s ability to obtain hard currency revenue from reexports of this com- modity and again enhanced sugar’s importance as a generator of hard currency.

4. CONCLUSION

Management of the Cuban economy by the revolutionary government over the last 25 years appears to have had a marginal impact in changing the structure of the economy to reduce the role played by sugar. Although precise measurement and comparisons with prerevolu- tionary Cuba are not feasible for a host of methodological reasons, the record suggests that

sugar production (industry plus agriculture) con- tinued to be one of the key sectors of the economy and the backbone of the export eco- nomy.

Moreover, Cuba’s plans to increase sugar production and exports through the end of the century virtually assure that sugar will continue to play a predominant role in the economy over this time horizon. Unlike other sugar-exporting countries which have made serious efforts to restructure their economies, Cuba has cast its lot with sugar. Cuban officials speak of the impera- tive to increase sugar production not only to meet the anticipated increased needs to socialist coun- tries, but also to regain “historical participation levels” in the world market.

It does appear that by virtue of arrangements with the Soviet Union that guarantee very high prices for sugar exports regardless of the be- havior of world market price, Cuba has been able to stabilize sugar export revenue in soft currency and ameliorate the severity of economic cycles associated with swings in world market sugar prices. However, because efforts to diversify the hard currency export basket have not been

wholly successful, the economy continues to depend on sugar sales to nonsocialist countries - typically at world market prices or at prices related to world market prices - to generate hard currency and therefore remains vulnerable to volatile world market prices.

NOTES

1. For a description of development strategies dur- ing this period see, e.g., Guevara (1971), pp. 431-434; “El desarrollo industrial” (1966), p. 147; Mesa-Lag0 (1971), pp. 295-296; Nolff (1964a), p. 32 and (1964b). pp. 326-335; Ritter (1974), pp. 129-159; and Volkov (1977), pp. 55-63.

2. E.g., Boorstein (1968), pp. 181-225; Dominguez (1971), pp. 67-69; Mesa-Lag0 (1971), p. 297; and Rodriguez (1981), pp. 136138.

3. Although the detailed plan has not been made public, several very useful reconstructions by scholars are available, e.g., Brunner (1977), pp. 4&76; Mesa- Lago (1971), p. 299; and Rota (1976). pp. 8-12.

4. E.g., Brunner (1977), pp. 77-137; Mesa-Lag0 (1971), pp. 301-311; and Rota (1976), pp. 8-12.

5. According to official data, Cuban sugar imports amounted to $101 million in 1984 and $100 million in 1985 (in hard currency). See Banco National (19851, p. 35. Since the averagk’world market price was &o&d 5.2 cents/pound in 1984, and 3 cents/pound in 1985, Cuban sugar purchases for reexport w&e probably in

the neighborhood of 800,000 tons in 1984 and 1.2 million tons in 1985. Reportedly (Feuer, 1987, p. 72), anticipating a poor 1986 crop, Cuba brought 500,000 tons of sugar in the world market in July 1985 for delivery to the Soviet Union.

6. Mesa-Lag0 (1971), p. 278; Rota and Hernandez (1972), p. 68. Based on official estimates of Cuban macroeconomic performance published by the Banco National de Cuba.

7. Calculated from data in Anuario (1985), pp. 106, 111. 112.

8. The discussion on Cuban macroeconomic statis- tics relies heavily on Mesa-Lag0 and Ptrez-Lbpez (1985a).

9. It is unlikely that differences between GDP and GNP would account for the very significant shifts in sugar’s importance in the economy posited by Brunde- nius, but this can not be asserted with certainty since data on the two measures are not available. While GDP is a measure of “domestic income,” i.e., the income arising in a given geographic area, GNP measures

Page 18: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

1644 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

“national income,” i.e., domestic income plus income earned abroad by the work and property of residents minus the income earned in the country by the work and property of foreign residents. See, e.g., Kendrick (1972) pp. 33-34.

10. These data were presented in Mesa-Lag0 and Perez-Lopez (1985d), pp. 73-74.

11. Calculated from data in Anuario (1985), pp. 376, 432-433.

12. Hirschman (1980), especially Chapter 6. It should be noted that Hirschman’s contribution was aimed at measuring the geographic concentration of exports and imports, while the UNCTAD indexes appear to mea- sure commodity concentration. Commodity concentra- tion and geographic concentration indexes are dis- cussed in Michaely (1958).

13. On this point see Perez-Lopez (1987).

14. For descriptions of this pricing mechanism see, e.g., Castro (1976) p. 3 and (1981) p. 3; ECLA

(1982), p. 194; Rodriguez (1982) p. 121 and (1984), p. 126; and Sanchez Garcia-Calzadilla (1982), p. 80.

15. Cuba’s participation in international efforts to stabilize sugar prices are documented in, e.g., CERP (1965b), pp. 325-357, 496-512; Silva Ledn (1975); Torras (1977); and Lazo (1984), pp. 46-49.

16. Fry (1985), pp. 9-10. As Fry points out, in a free market in which 15% of total world output is traded, a 4% increase in world output from trend coinciding with a 4% drop in consumption would increase the volume of sugar in the world market by 50% and probably result in weak prices.

17. It should be noted that not all Cuban sales to nonsocialist countries are necessarily transacted at world market prices. For example, in 1963, Spain began to purchase Cuban sugar through long-term contracts at fixed prices. This practice was stopped in 1979 (Recarte, 1980, p. 183). The most recent Cuban statistical yearbook (Anuario, 1985, p. 470) contains statistics on the price of Cuban sugar sold to nonsocial- ist countries via contracts through 1982.

REFERENCES

Aguirre, S., “El primer aniversario de las cooperativas caneras,” Cuba Socialista, Vol. 1, No. 3 (November 1961) pp. 17-27.

Anuario Esradistico de Cuba (Havana: ComitC Estatal de Estadfsticas, 1972-85). Early volumes were pub- lished by the Junta Central de Planificacion.

Banco National de Cuba, Economic Report (Havana: 1985).

Banco National de Cuba, Economic Report (Havana: 1982).

Boletin Estadistico de Cuba (Havana: Junta Central de Planificacion, 1964-71).

Boorstein, E., The Economic Transformation of Cuba (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1968).

Borrego, Diaz, O., “La tarea economica: el problema fundamental,” Cuba Socialista, Vol. 6, No. 62 (October 1966), pp. 161-174.

Borrego Diaz, O., “Problemas que plantea a la industria una zafra de 10 millones de toneladas de azticar,” Cuba Socialista, Vol. 5, No. 44 (April 1965) pp. l&30.

Boti, R., “El plan de desarrollo econdmico de 1962,” Cuba Socialista, Vol. 1, no. 4 (December 1961), pp. 1932.

Brezinski, H., “Economic relations between European and the less developed CMEA countries,” in US Congress, Joint Economic Committee, East Euro- pean Economies: Slow Growth in the 198Os, Vol. 2 (Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office, 1986).

Brundenius, C., Revolutionary Cuba: The Challenge of Growth with Eauity (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1984). _ ’ ~

Brundenius, C., and A. Zimbalist, “Recent studies on Cuban economic growth: A review,” Comparative

Economic Studies, Vol. 27, No. 1 (Spring 1985a), pp. 21-45.

Brundenius, C., and A. Zimbalist, “Cuban economic growth one more time: A response to imbroglios,” Comparative Economic Review, Vol. 27, No. 4 (Fall 1985b), pp. 115131.

Brunner, H., Cuban Sugar Policy from 1963 to 1970 (Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1977).

Carciofi, R., “Cuba in the seventies,” in G. White, er al., (Ed.), Revolutionary Socialist Development in the Third World (Lexington, KY: University of Ken- tucky Press, 1983).

Castro, F., Nuestra Lucha es la de America Latina y el Tercer Mundo (Havana, 1985). Interview given to the Mexican newspaper El Dia on 8 June 1985.

Castro, F., “Discurso en el acto de clausura de1 II Conzreso de 10s CDR. el 24 de octubre de 1981,” CraGma (26 October 1981), pp. 2-5.

Castro, F., “Discurso en el acto de clausura de1 XVI Congreso de1 Sindicato Azucarero, el 30 de octubre de 1980,” Granma (1 November 1980a), pp. 24.

Castro, F., “Informe Central al II Congreso de1 Partido Comunista de Cuba,” Bohemia, Vol. 72, No. 52 (26 December 1980b), pp. 34-67.

Castro, F., “Discurso en el XVI aniversario de 10s Comites de Defensa de la Revolution, el 28 de septiembre de 1976,” Granma (30 September 1976), pp. 2-4.

Charadan Lopez, F., La industria azucarera en Cuba (Havana: Editorial de Ciencias Sociales, 1982).

Collar Fraguela, J., “En defensa de nuestros recursos naturales: VI Reunion de GEPLACEA,” CubaAru- car (April-June 1977), pp. 28-42.

“Conferencia de Diocles Torralba en informaci6n

Page 19: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

SUGAR AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE 1645

pdblica,” Grunma (4 December 1981), p. 2. plan 1961-5 for the Cuban economy,” in M. Kalecki

Cdntreras, R., “Cuba- un mayor impulsb al azticar,” ATAC. Vol. 41. No. 1 (Januarv-Februarv 1982). DD.

(Ed.) Essays on Developing Economies (London: Harvester Press, 1976).

19-20.’ \ ’ ,,. L

Kendrick, J. W., Economic Accounts and Their Uses Cuba Econ6mica y Financiera, Anuario Azucarero de (New York: McGraw Hill, 1972).

Cuba 1958 (Havana: 1959). Lazo, R., “LPor quC no se firm6 el nuevo convenio?,” Cuban Economic Research Project (CERP), Cuba: Bohemia, Vol. 75, No. 32 (10 August 1984), pp. 46-

Agriculture and Planning (Coral Gables, FL: Univer- 49. sity of Miami Press, 1965a). LeoGrande, W. M., “Cuban dependency: A compari-

Cuban Economic Research Proiect (CERP). A Studv son of pre-revolutionary and post-revolutionary in- on Cuba (Coral Gables, FL: University of Miami Press, 1965b).

“El desarrollo industrial de Cuba,” Cuba Socialista, Vol. 6, No. 56 (April 1966), pp. 128-183.

Diaz-VLauez. J. A., Cuba v el CAME (Havana:

Dominguez, J. I., To Make a World Safe for Revolution

Editoriil de Ciencias Sociaies, 1985). \ Diaz-VBzquez, J. A., “Cuba: integracibn econ6mica

(Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard Univer-

socialista y especializaci6n de la producci&,” Eco- nomia y Desarrollo, No. 63 (July-August 1981),

sity Press, 1989).

pp. 132-165.

Dominguez, J. I., Cuba: Order and Revolution (Cam- bridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard Universitv

ternational economic -relatiohs,” Cuban S&dies/ Estudios Cubanos, Vol. 9, No. 2 (July 1979). pp. l- 28.

Lineamientos econdmicos y sociales para el quinquenio (1986-1990) (Havana: Editora Politica, 1986).

Lineamientos econdmicos y sociales para el quintjuenio 1981-1985 (Havana: Editora Politica. 1980).

Marrero, L., ‘Cuba: Economia y Sociedad, vol. 10 (Madrid: Editorial Playor, 1984).

An eq;ity trade-off for grow&“-in J. Hartley add Mesa-Lago, C., “Cuba’s centrally planned economy:

S. A. Morley (Eds.), Latin American Political Economy: Financial Crisis and Political Change (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1986).

Mesa-Lago, C., “The economy: Caution. fruaalitv and

and ;developm&t,”

Press, 1978). _

Latin American Rese&h Re- Domineuez. J. I.. “Sectoral clashes in Cuban oolitics

view, Vol. 6, No. 3 (Fall 1971), pp. 61-87. Eckstein, S., “Capitalist constraints on Cuban socialist

development,” Comparative Politics, Vol. 12, No. 3 (1980), pp. 253-274.

resilient ideology,” in J. I. bominguez (Ed.), i‘uba:

Sage Publications, 1982). ” ~ Internal and International Affairs (Beverlv Hills. CA:

d Mesa-Lago, C., The Economy of Socialist Cuba: A

Two Decade Apprufial (Albuquerque, NM: Univer- sity of New Mdxico Press, 1981):

Economic Commission for Latin America (ECLA), Economic Survey of Latin America 1982 (New York: United Nations, 1982).

Economic Commission for Latin America (ECLA), Economic Survey of Latin America 1980 (New York: United Nations, 1980).

Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC), Estudio Econdmico de Am&i- co Latina 1985: Cuba, LUL.39OlAdd.18 (Santiago: Naciones Unidas, 1986).

Ferrer, M., “Cuba: principal abastecedor azucarero de1 CAME,” Grunma (13 August 1981), p. 2.

Feuer, C. H., “The performance of the Cuban sugar industry, 1981-85,” World Development, Vol. i5, No. 1 (Januarv 1987). DD. 67-81.

Fowler, k., “Russian a&i& on sugar emerge,” The New York Times (29 November 1974), pp. 63-64.

Fry, J., Sugar: Aspects of a Complex Commodity Market (Washington, Dd: The Wdrld Bank, 1985j.

Guevara, E., Obra Revolucionaria (Mtxico: Editorial Era, 1971).

Guevara, E., “La industrializaci6n de Cuba,” in Universidad Popular, Economia y Planificacidn (Havana: 1961).

Herrera, R., “Problemas que plantea a la agricultura una zafra de 10 millones de toneladas,” Cuba Socialista, Vol. 5, No. 43 (March 1%5), pp. l-23.

Hirschman, A. O., National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade (Berkeley, CA: University of Califor- nia Press, 1980).

International Sugar Organization (ISO), Sugar Year Book (London: ISO, 194-5).

Kalecki, M., “Hypothetical outline of the five-year

Mesa-Lago, C., “Economic policies and growth,” in Carmelo Mesa-Lag0 (Ed.), Revolutionary Change in Cuba (Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1971).

Mesa-Lago, C., and J. F. PCrez-Mpez, Study of Cuba’s Material Product System, Its Conversion to the System of National Accounts, and Estimation of Gross Domestic Product per Capita and Growth Rates (Washington, DC: The World Bank, 1985a).

Mesa-Lago, C., and J. F. PCrez-L6pez, “Estimating Cuban gross domestic product per capita in dollars using physical indicators,” Social Indicators Re- search, Vol. 16 (1985b), pp. 275-300.

Mesa-Lago, C., and J. F. PCrez-Mpcz, “Imbroglios on the Cuban economy: A reply to Brundenius and Zimbalist,” Comparative Economic Studies, Vol. 27, No. 1 (Spring 1985c), pp. 47-83.

Mesa-Lago, C., and J. F. Perez-Mpez, “The endless Cuban economy saga: A terminal rebuttal,” Compa- rative Economic Studies, Vol. 27, No. 4 (Winter 1985d), pp. 67-82.

Michaely, M., “Concentration of exports and imports: An international comparison,” The Economic Jour- nal, Vol. 68, No. 272 (1958). pp. 722-736.

Moreno Fraginals, M., El ‘Zngenio-(Havana: Editorial de Ciencias Sociales, 1978).

Nolff, M., “El desarrollo industrial de Cuba,” Pano- ruma Econdmico (Santiago), Vol. 17, No. 241 (May 1964a), pp. 32-35.

Nolff, M., “Industry,” in D. Seers (Ed.), Cuba: The Economic and Social Revolution (Chapel Hill, NC: Universitv of North Carolina Press. 1964b).

Oramas, L.; “ Cuba puede y debe expahdir su produc- ci6n,” Grunma (20 October 1986), p. 7.

Page 20: Sugar and structural change in the Cuban economy

1646 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

“Otra batalla en Las GuBsimas,” Cuba Znternacional (February 1979), pp. 20-21.

Packenham, R. A., “Capitalist dependency and social- ist dependency: The case of Cuba,” Journal of Inter- american Studies and World Affairs, Vol. 28, No. 1 (Spring 1986), pp. 59-92.

PCrez-Lbpez, J. F., “Cuban-Soviet sugar trade: Price and subsidy issues,” Bulletin of Latin American Research, Vol. 7, No. 1 (1988). pp. 123-147.

Perez-Mpez, J. F., “Cuban oil reexports: Significance and prospects,” Energy Journal, Vol. 8, No. 1 (1987), pp. 1-16.

Petushkov. I.. “Desarrollo integral de la industria azucarera de Cuba,” Am&& Latina (Moscow), No. 1 (1975), pp. 2%44.

Recarte, A., Cuba: Economia y Poder (1959-1980) (Madrid: Alianza Editorial, 1980).

Regalado, A., “Los pequetios agricultores y el plan azucarero para 1970,” Cuba Socialista, Vol. 5, No. 48 (August 1965), pp. 36-50.

Ritter, A. R. M., The Economic Development of Revolutionary Cuba: Strategy and Performance (New York: Praeger, 1974).

Rota, S., “Cuba’s international economic relations in the late 198Os,” in S. G. Rota (Ed.), Socialist Cuba: Past Interpretations and Future Challenges (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1989). -

Rota. S.. Cuban Economic Policv and Ideoloav: The Ten Million Ton Harvest (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications, 1976).

Rota, S., and R. E. HernBndez, “Structural economic problems, ” in J. Suchlicki (Ed.), Cuba, Castro and Revolution (Coral Gables. FL: University of Miami Press, i972j.

Rodriguez, J. L., DOS Ensayos sobre la Economia Cubana (Havana: Editorial de Ciencias Sociales, 1984).

Rodriguez, J. L., “La economia cubana entre 1976 y 1980: resultados y perspectivas,” Economiu y Desar- rolfo, No. 66 (March-April, 1982), pp. lOS149.

Rodriguez, J. L., “La economia de Cuba Socialista,” Economia y Desarrollo, No. 61 (March-April 1981), pp. 112-148.

SBnchez Garcia-Calzadilla, M., “La participacibn de Cuba en la integracibn socialista,” Rev&a Estudbti- ca, Vol. 5, No. 9 (December 1982), pp. 59-87.

Silva Leon, A., Cuba y el Mercado lnternacional Azucarero (Havana: Editorial de Ciencias Sociales, 1975).

Smith, J. T., “Sugar dependency in Cuba: Capitalism versus socialism,” in M. A. Seligson (Ed.), The Gap Between the Rich and the Poor (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1984).

Tan, C. S., Cuba-USSR Sugar Trade (Washington, DC: The World Bank. 1986).

Torras, J., “El Convenio’ International Azucarero de 1953,” ATAC, Vol. 36, No. 3 (May-June 1977), pp. 3539. (Article oriainallv anneared in 1953.)

Turits, R.., “Trade, debt, in6 ihe Cuban economy,” World Development, Vol. 15, No. 1 (January 1987), pp. 16%180.

United Nations Conference on Trade and Develop- ment (UNCLAD), Handbook of International Trade and Development Statistics: 1985 Annual Supplement (New York: United Nations, 1985).

United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO), Cuba, Industrial Development Review Series. UNIDO/IS.615 (New York: United Nations. 1986).

Valdts, M. T., “La evoluci6n de la produccibn azucarera de Cuba y su papel en las relaciones econ6micas externas,” Temas de Economla Mundial, No. 10 (1984), pp. 117-149.

Volkov, S., “Acerca de la elecci6n de la estructura econbmica national: la experiencia de Cuba,” AmPrica Latina (Moscow), No. 2 (1977), pp. 5572.

Zimbalist, A., and S. Eckstein, “Patterns of Cuban development: The first twenty-five years,” World Development, Vol. 15, No. 1 (January 1987), pp. 5-