paper itseurope 2009 final

Upload: lcastejon

Post on 06-Apr-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    1/29

    WHY IT IS IMPOSSIBLE THAT THE LADDER OF INVESTMENT

    ACTUALLY WORKS

    September 2009

    Fernando Herrera-Gonzlez

    Luis Castejn-Martn

    Abstract

    The ladder of investment is a regulatory approach that has been used by European

    National Regulatory Authorities (NRAs), in order to foster infrastructure competition

    among operators. According to its proponents, by forcing incumbent operators to open

    several levels of access to their network in such a way that alternative operators may

    climb up the ladder, they will eventually deploy their own access network and

    infrastructure competition will be achieved.

    This regulatory approach seems to have failed, as can be seen in the lack of advance to

    the last rung of the ladder, the deployment of an alternative infrastructure.

    In this paper, it is argued that the ladder of investment can not possibly attain the above

    results, by using the methodology of the Austrian School of Economics. Three

    arguments are developed: 1) Impossibility of establishing prices outside the free market;

    2) Impossibility of defining relevant point of access outside the discovery market

    process; 3) Misconception of the investment decisions

    Keywords

    Regulation, ladder of investment, investment incentives, theory of price control,

    entrepreneurship, market process

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    2/29

    1. Introduction

    The deployment of an alternative fixed infrastructure to that of the incumbent has

    possibly been the main concern of governments and telecommunications regulatorssince the opening of the sector to competition.

    According to their logic, deregulation of the sector will only be possible when there is

    an important degree of facility-based competition. Otherwise, alternative operators and

    competition have to rely on the incumbent facilities and regulation is necessary. If full

    deregulation were accomplished from the beginning, several negative effects would

    occur, as raise of prices or foreclosure risks.

    In summary, to attain the benefits of competition in the telecommunication sector it is

    necessary to have an alternative infrastructure to that of the incumbent. The question is

    how alternative operators may be able to deploy it in an open market, because the

    duplication of the incumbent network is risky and involves high sunk costs, if made at

    one time.

    The ladder of investment approach provides new entrants with a smooth path for

    investments, which allows them to progressively deploy their networks. Lowering in

    this way their risk, the probability of deployment is bigger.

    The concept was originally proposed in (Cave, 2004). The idea is to force incumbent

    operators to open several levels of access to their network (the rungs of the ladder) in

    such a way that alternative operators may climb up the ladder, using more of his own

    infrastructure, and thus decreasing their reliance on the wholesale products of the

    incumbent operator. The final result would be the deployment of their own access

    network by the alternative operator, once he has captured the appropriate number of

    costumers to profit from the economies of scale of that investment.

    Regulators oblige incumbent operators to provide wholesale access products in several

    points of their infrastructure. These points require different levels of investment, from

    the lowest requirement (for example, resale) to the largest (unbundling). Thus, new

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    3/29

    entrants may start using the incumbent network on the access points requiring the

    lowest investments, and then proceed up the ladder, as they build a mass of costumers.

    For example, an operator may start providing broadband services by simply resaling

    under its own brand those of the incumbents. As it acquires costumers, it gets revenues

    that may allow it to further its investments up to the next access point or rung,

    deploying its own infrastructure closer to the customer premises, which results in higher

    product differentiation and variety, and in less dependence on the incumbents network.

    Supposedly, the process goes on, until a point comes where the operator finds attractive

    to deploy its own facilities, and to severe their dependence of the incumbent.

    This gradual climb is only possible if NRAs regulate prices of the various access

    products in a consistent way, and if the right number of rungs is defined to allow for

    smooth transitions between each successive rung. Neither of these problems seems to be

    easily solved, as the literature points out (Cave, 2006) (Cave, 2004).

    In this paper, the methodology of the Austrian School of Economics will be applied to

    assess if the ladder of investment approach can possibly work. That is, if the ladder of

    investment regulation may attain the objective of facilities-based competition, as their

    proponents pretend. The rest of the paper is structured in the following way. In the

    second section, the Austrian School of Economics is briefly introduced: its

    methodology is explained and the description of the market as a process, one of the

    main features of Austrian economics, is depicted.

    The third section will deal with the question at stake, that is, if it is really possible that

    the ladder of investment attains its goal. The argumentation follows the Austrianeconomics methodology, and revolves around two basic issues: establishment of prices

    and production structure outside the free market, and how both issues affect the

    investment decisions of operators.

    In the fourth section, we will discuss an analysis made for the Spanish market. This

    analysis concludes that the ladder of investment has attained its goal. Because this

    conclusion is contrary to the results of the theoretical analysis (and to that of other

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    4/29

    empirical studies), it deserves a more detailed appraisal, even if the review of historical

    evidence is at odds with the methodology of the Austrian school of economics.

    Fifth section concludes and closes the paper.

    2. The Methodology of the Austrian School of Economics

    In this section, the Austrian School of Economics is introduced, and features of its

    methodology are described. After that, focus is made on describing the market as a

    process, outlining the main differences with the mainstream economics. Once made the

    description, a general categorization of the effects of regulation in the market processwill be presented. This introductory explanation is deemed necessary to understand how

    the ladder of investment affects the market.

    Introducing Austrian Economics

    This paper is built on economic theory developed by the Austrian School of Economics

    as opposed to the neoclassical school, which constitutes the current economic

    mainstream1. In the past, other schools has been successively considered mainstream,only to be abandoned when they proved wrong.

    The Austrian School of Economics has its origins with the Viennese economist C.

    Menger (1814-1921). Its specific foundation is dated to 1871, with the publication of

    Mengers Grundstze der volkswirtschaftlehre (Principles of economy).

    Most relevant contributors to this tradition include L. von Mises (1881-1973), J. A.Schumpeter (1883-1950), F. A. Hayek (1899-1992, Economics Nobel Prize in 1974),

    and M. N. Rothbard (1926-1995).

    Methodology

    1 For a detailed analysis of the important differences between both approaches, see Murphy (2007).

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    5/29

    The methodology used by the Austrian School of Economics is praxeology, or the study

    of human action. Two features are characteristic of this methodology: individualism and

    subjectivism.

    Methodological individualism means that the starting point for economic analysis is

    human action: all economic phenomena are the result of actions and interactions of

    individuals whose doings generate all outcomes observed in the market. As a

    consequence, there are no natural laws in the market.

    An individual acts by choosing among several alternatives of action. Methodological

    subjectivism implies that these selections are made according to an individuals scale of

    preferences. A human acts by allocating his or her resources to the satisfaction of more

    urgent needs. This scale is different for each individual and changes with time.

    Moreover, it is subjective and cannot be measured nor apprehended by outside

    observers. Finally, these preferences cannot be measured in absolute terms; they have an

    ordinal, rather than a cardinal, hierarchy.

    The Austrian School of Economics starts from the axiom that humans act (i.e., they

    have purposeful behaviour) and do so to satisfy ends according to a given scale of

    values. From here and through logical reasoning, laws governing the economy can be

    deduced.

    Because of its logical foundations, praxeology is similar to logic and mathematics. Its

    statements and propositions are not derived from experience. They are a priori. They

    may be illustrated historically, but they are never verified or falsified experimentally.

    For its part, economic history cannot teach any general rule, principle, or law. There is

    no way to abstract a posteriori from historical experience any theories concerning

    human conduct and policies. Because of this, there is no need of real cases to apply

    praxeology to a concrete economic problem. That is, no case supporting the results of

    the analysis would further justify its conclusion, and no case contradicting it would

    serve to falsify its reasoning.

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    6/29

    It is important to note that all theorems developed according to praxeology are true

    regardless of specific circumstances2, unless there is some mistake in the logical

    reasoning that underlies them.

    The market as a process

    Austrian economists understand the market as a dynamic process of discovery generated

    by entrepreneurs (Hayek, 2002). (Kirzner, 1985) summarises this view around four key

    concepts.

    - Competition: understood as rivalrous activities of market players, not as perfect

    competition equilibrium, as mainstream economists do.

    - Knowledge and discovery: the competitive process does not only mobilize

    existing knowledge, but also generate awareness of opportunities whose very

    existence was known to no one at all.

    - Profit and incentives: Profits are not understood as the mere subtraction of

    known costs from known revenues, but as the incentives to locate gaps between

    costs and revenues. In other word, profits are a sign that resources are more

    valuable in other uses than in the current ones.

    - Market prices: in each moment, they are the (disequilibrium) exchange ratios

    worked out between market participants; they provide information to

    entrepreneurs on the current valuation of commodities, and, thus, on the

    opportunities of profits.

    In the real world of uncertainty, the discovery market process is carried out by

    entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurs are constantly looking for new opportunities of profits,

    that is, of gaps between current prices of resources and expected prices of them; this is

    done by market calculation, by means of which they are able to make estimates that can

    guide their ex ante decisions.

    2 See Mises (1949/1998a), chapter 39.

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    7/29

    It is important to note that the market process is not instantaneous; on the contrary, it

    takes time to profit from the identified opportunities.

    When an entrepreneur detects an opportunity of profits, he has first to acquire the

    resources at the current price (invest in resources) and only after a variable lapse of

    time, depending on the complexity of the productive process, he will be able to sell

    those resources in the new form. Only at that time, will he be able to know if he was

    right or wrong in his market calculation: he who was right will attain profits; he who

    was not, will suffer losses.

    Effects of regulation on the market process

    Government regulation drastically alters opportunities for entrepreneurial gain, and

    influences the prices emerging from entrepreneurial competition. However, perils arise

    out of the impact that regulation have on the discovery process, which unregulated

    markets tend to generate. Kirzner identifies four categories of impact on the discovery

    process (Kirzner, 1985)

    The undiscovered discovery process

    Regulators may not correctly address the market course in the absence of regulation.

    The unsimulated discovery process

    Regulators have no incentives in profit seeking, so it is very unlikely that they are able

    to discover opportunities for social betterment that the market process has not already

    discovered. Regulation process can not simulate market process.

    The stifled discovery process

    Regulation may inhibit, discourage or hamper desirable discovery processes which the

    market might have generated, activities not yet foreseen by anyone. For example, price

    ceilings not only restrict supply from known sources, but also inhibit the discovery of

    wholly unknown sources.

    The wholly superfluous discovery process

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    8/29

    Regulation may create opportunities for new, but not necessarily desirable, market

    discovery processes which would not be relevant in an unregulated market. Regulation

    constraints introduce profit opportunities that otherwise have been absent. Such

    consequences may be wholly undesired by authorities.

    In brief, the competitive-entrepreneurial process, being a process of discovery of the

    as yet unknown, can hardly be predicted in any but the broadest terms. The imposition

    of regulatory constraints necessarily results in a pattern of consequences different from

    and, most plausibly, distinctly less desirable than what would have occurred in the

    unregulated market.

    3. Can the ladder of investment work?

    In this section, it will be proved that the ladder of investment approach cannot possibly

    attain the stated objective of getting other operator to deploy their own access. Three

    arguments will be developed. Firstly, it will be shown that it is impossible to establish

    meaningful prices from outside the market. Any price not resulting from the market

    process will distort the investment decisions of entrepreneurs, because it is not

    providing the right information about the value of resources. It is likely that, in these

    circumstances, resources are misdirected and a sector bubble may be generated.

    Secondly, the question of how to define point of access to the incumbent network will

    be tackled. As before, there is no possibility of such a definition outside the discovery

    market process. Of course, it is possible to define points of access, but they will be

    technical points of access, and not economic points of access, because they are

    defined according to a concrete technical structure of the service, and not to the real

    demand of the market. Once again, this may possibly lead to bubbles and mal-

    investment. Besides, the impossibility of defining prices outside the market is

    exacerbated, because prices for each of the points of access are supposed to be

    consistent among them, in order for the ladder of investment to work.

    Finally, the investment decision will be described, showing that the ladder of

    investment not only does not easy investment in new networks by alternative operators,

    but on the contrary, it makes considerably more difficult such deployment. The key

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    9/29

    issue is to understand that entrepreneurs make investments only if the expected increase

    in revenues is above the amount of needed outlays.

    3.1 Prices outside of the free market

    In the first place, it will be argued that it is impossible to establish prices outside the

    free market. All prices defined from external institutions are necessarily arbitrary and do

    not convey any useful information for taking investment decisions. On the contrary,

    they severely distort this signal and cause mal-investment to be made.

    In the unhampered market, the price is established by the interplay of buyers and sellers.

    This price depends on the preferences of buyers and on the available stock. The pricemay vary with time, as preferences or stock are altered.

    In the market, sellers and buyers exchange goods (typically, goods for money). The

    exchange takes place only if both parties value more that which they receive than that

    which they deliver. It is not possible to know which is their valuation of the good

    received; the only magnitude an observer may apprehend is the ratio of exchange, i.e,

    the price at which the exchange took place.

    In words of the Nobel laureate James Buchanan (Buchanan, 1999, chapter 6):

    Only prices have objective, empirical content; neither the marginal

    evaluations of the demanders nor the marginal costs of the suppliers (the

    marginal evaluations of foregone alternatives) can be employed as a basis for

    determining prices. The reason is that these are both brought into equality with

    prices by behavioural adjustments on both sides of the market. Prices are not

    brought into equality with some objectively determinable and empirically

    measurable phenomena, on either the demand or the supply side of the market.

    However, services defined in the ladder of investment approach are not offered in the

    market (there is no free market for these products). Before any access obligation, all

    exchanges are internal; there is no price for the good, and no way for the firm or for

    anyone else to determine a price for it. In any case, proponents of the ladder of

    investment deem necessary to define prices for each of the rungs of the ladder.

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    10/29

    According to (Cave, 2006), access pricing may be used to establish the different prices.

    This methodology (as summarised in (Armstrong, 2002)) relies heavily on the notion of

    costs as something given or objective3.

    According to the Austrian School of Economics, the cost is the loss, prospective or

    realized, to the person making the decision, of the opportunity of using those things in

    the alternative courses of action

    Cost is that which the decision-taker sacrifices or gives up when he makes a

    choice. It consists in his own evaluation of the enjoyment or utility that he

    anticipates having to forego as a result of selection among alternative courses of

    action. (Buchanan, 1999).

    Thus, in that view, costs are subjective, they exist only in the mind of the decision-

    maker, and cannot be measured by someone other than the decision-maker, because

    there is no way that subjective experience can be directly observed.

    Even if it could be accepted that prices can be calculated from one or other group of

    costs, these are in turn unobservable, except for the entrepreneur making the decision,

    who is the only one able to apprehend the costs that his decision poses on him.

    (Buchanan, 1999) explains that this false objectification of costs may have resulted

    from the extension of the perfect knowledge assumption of competitive equilibrium

    theory to the analysis of non-equilibrium choices, whether made in a market or a non-

    market process.

    And he concludes: The implications of all this for modern welfare economics could

    scarcely be underestimated. My argument suggests that almost all of this subdiscipline

    has been based on simple methodological confusion. It has converted predictive

    propositions into allocative norms which have then been used to make policy

    proposals.

    3

    (Armstrong, 2002) builds its results on the normative results of the perfect competition model. This ideahas been extensive and widely criticized by Austrian School economists, and all those arguments shouldbe brought up here. For example, see (Hayek, 1948).

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    11/29

    In summary, prices are the only objective magnitude; only prices can be apprehended by

    an outside observer. It is prices that define costs, and not the other way around. Once a

    price for a good is observed in the market, providers have to adjust their offer to that

    price, and consequently their costs, if they want to survive in the market place. Costs are

    not observable either, because they are subjective to the decision-maker. Of course, unit

    counts may be carried out, but these are not true costs, just accounting figures 4.

    Any price established outside of the market place is, in conclusion, arbitrary. Proofs of

    this arbitrariness are pervasive. For example, in the discussions about the recent EC

    Recommendation on mobile termination rates, there were more than 50 contributors5.

    The analysis of the contributions to the public consultation shows the wide divergence

    of approaches to determine termination rates.

    More conclusively, the EC recognizes this fact in the paragraph 2 of the

    Recommendation6, when it states:

    Although some form of cost orientation is generally provided for in most

    Member States, a divergence between price control measures prevails across the

    Member States. In addition to a significant variety in the chosen costing tools,

    there are also different practices in implementing those tools.

    This divergence of approaches is not exclusive of termination rates, but extends to the

    implementation of any price regulation, and not only in telecoms but in any other

    economic sector.

    4 In this respect, see (Mises, 1998a), p. 346. Cost accounting is therefore not an arithmetical processwhich can be established and examined by an indifferent umpire. It does not operate with uniquely

    determined magnitudes which can be found out in an objective way. Its essential items are the result of an

    understanding of future conditions, necessarily always colored by the entrepreneur's opinion about the

    future state of the market. Attempts to establish cost accounts on an "impartial" basis are doomed to

    failure.5 Seehttp://ec.europa.eu/information_society/policy/ecomm/library/public_consult/termination_rates/index_en.htm6

    European Commission: COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION of 7.5.2009 on the RegulatoryTreatment of Fixed and Mobile Termination Rates in the EU. C(2009) 3359.

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    12/29

    Ladder of investment proponents also reflect this arbitrariness in their proposals. For

    example, in (Cave, 2006) there is a lengthy discussion: If a price-based approach is

    chosen, this can rely upon the well-understood theory of option pricing (). It may

    seem that an access charging regime based on long run incremental cost (LRIC) plus

    common cost, using the appropriate asset-specific cost of capital, would then send the

    correct make or buy signals to other operators.() Precise estimates of the option

    value of delaying investment until uncertainties have been resolved can be made ().

    The key factors for applying the approach to telecommunications include the degree of

    demand uncertainty and the expected change in input and output prices. () The

    product of the calculation is the mark-up on LRIC associated with pricing the option.

    Dixit and Pindyck estimated it as 100%, but a recent paper by Dobbs (2004), taking

    account of other factors influencing output prices, suggests that a mark-up of 550% is

    more likely. () This estimate can then be built into a dynamic access pricing regime

    consistent with incentives to invest

    Even if the proposed methodology and all other component were accepted without

    discussion, there is still a mark-up associated with pricing the option that can oscillate

    between 5% and 100%!.

    Both theoretical analysis and empirical evidence seem to show the same result: the only

    fair, non arbitrary, price in the market is the one at which both buyer and seller freely

    choose to make the interchange7, and prices established outside the market are arbitrary.

    Because of this, these prices do not contain sensible information for entrepreneurs, and

    contribute to distort the market process.

    In the case of the ladder of investment, prices below market prices would surely giveplace to instances of the stifled market process and wholly superfluous market process.

    Prices too low for wholesale services will produce lower profits (if at all) and thus will

    repel entrepreneurs willing to enter the market; this will probably led to stifled

    innovation due to lack of incentives.

    7 Vance L.M.: The Myth of the Just Price, 31 March 2008, available inhttp://www.mises.org/story/2918

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    13/29

    On the other side, those prices will raise profits in retail, attracting more entrepreneurs

    that would be the case in the free market and creating a wholly superfluous market

    process, not demanded by consumers. Entrepreneurs will wrongly think that there is an

    opportunity of investment, more investments will be carried out and a bubble will be

    produced, that is, an economic growth that is not based on costumers preferences, and

    is not sustainable.

    3.2 Identification of points of access

    The other relevant element of the ladder of investment approach is the definition of the

    rungs of the ladder, that it, points where access to the incumbent network is forced.

    In the free market, it cannot be discarded that wholesale services would be offered by

    the incumbent. Individual value scales" determine "the quantity of goods produced, the

    prices of consumers' goods, the prices of productive factors, the interest rate, profits

    and losses." Not only that, but "given a stock of land and labour factors, given

    existing capital goods inherited from the past, given individual time preferences (and,

    more broadly, technological knowledge), the capital goods structure and total

    production is determined." (Rothbard, 1993), chapter 9, p. 624.

    Thus, the market process, starting from the individual preferences of each customer,

    determines not only goods and prices but also the structure of production for those

    goods (given available resources). As already explained, this process is carried out by

    entrepreneurs, using market calculation on the known prices.

    In order to accomplish this calculation, explicit markets are needed, that provide

    information about current prices of the resources involved. "For, without an external

    market for wage rates, rents, and interest, there would be no rational way for

    entrepreneurs to allocate factors in accordance with the wishes of the consumers."

    (Rothbard, 1993), chapter 9, p. 608.

    This poses limits to the vertical integration of enterprises: a firm can effectively have

    vertical integration of several processes, only if there is a real market for each of the

    intermediate products that provide the firm with an explicit price, that, in turn, allows it

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    14/29

    to perform market calculation: "For every capital good, there must be a definite market

    in which firms buy and sell that good." Otherwise, without the price, the firm will not be

    able to allocate factors and resources from one stage to another. (Rothbard, 1993),

    Chapter 9, paragraph 3.E: "Vertical Integration and the Size of the Firm," p. 609-616.

    There are some instances of wholesale services provided spontaneously by incumbents.

    For example, Telefnica started offering bitstream national services in 2000 with

    commercial conditions. Only later, in 2007, was this service regulated.

    In summary, in the free market, economical points of access would appear, in the

    sense that they would be driven by costumer preferences, possibly due to the limits of

    vertical integration described.

    However, according to the ladder of investment approach, it is necessary to define those

    points without regard to the market preferences. Market preferences have to be

    substituted then by other criteria (for example, replicability of the asset (Cave, 2006))

    and that takes us back to the realm of arbitrariness. No longer are market preferences

    defining the capital structure, but arguable, non objective, criteria.

    The structure of production established by the unhampered market was the best (so far)

    for serving the customers. If, in this situation, the government decides to forcibly alter

    this structure of production by, say, splitting one activity into two, the resulting

    productive structure will be worse for their purpose8. The point of access so defined

    may be termed as technical point of access, as opposed to economical.

    In order to define points of access with the ladder of investment approach, it isnecessary to define a chain of production for the provision of the retail service. Once

    this is known, points of access to that chain may be identified. In the case of broadband

    services, this is done in (Cave, 2006), p. 230-231. The proposed set of activities is the

    following:

    - access to the customer via a copper loop or shared loop;

    - DSLAMs located at the local exchange;

    8 For an explanation of the consequences of this splitting in the concrete case of BT and functionalseparation, see (Herrera-Gonzlez, 2008).

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    15/29

    - ATM backhaul;

    - access to an IP network;

    - access to the world wide web via transit or peering services;

    - retailing functions (marketing, billing, helplines, etc.).

    This identification is arbitrary, as could be expected after the previous theoretical

    analysis. This is recognized by the author (see (Cave, 2006), footnote 16).

    There are other problems caused by this approach. The proposed chain of production is

    one technical solution for the provision of broadband services using a legacy copper

    network. It is arguably the more widely used solution at this moment in time, and it may

    even be regarded as the most efficient solution at present. But by no means is the only

    possible solution, neither at present nor for the future, especially if innovation is

    allowed.

    With the static approach, it is usual to consider that technology does not change. If it is

    assumed that technology will not change, and regulatory steps are taken with that

    hypothesis in mind (i.e, points of access are defined according to a given technical

    solution), it is very likely that technology will effectively not evolve. Alternative

    operators will rely on the regulatory rungs for their own deployments and will in fact

    replicate the technical solution chosen by the incumbent, instead of looking for

    alternatives. In that way, dependence of the incumbent network increases, contrarily to

    the purpose of the ladder of investment approach. Thus, the regulatory definition of

    rungs of the ladder of investment tends to freeze the chain of production, leaving it as

    that definition was assuming, in a self-fulfilling prophecy..

    The process does not even stop here. Following (Mises, 1998a) p.742), It is important

    to realize that what those benefited by these measures consider an advantage for

    themselves lasts only for a limited time. In the long run the privilege accorded to a

    definite class of producers loses its power to create specific gains. The privileged

    branch attracts newcomers, and their competition tends to eliminate the specific gains

    derived from the privilege.

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    16/29

    Once the regulatory possibilities of competition are exhausted (for example, all

    operators are in the best rung), the only way ahead for alternative operators is to ask for

    further rungs in the ladder9. The demanded rungs will of course depend on the specific

    business model chosen by each operator10. So, the incumbent operator will be obliged to

    open more and more rungs for these customized ladders of investments. This is clearly

    seen in Spain, where specific operators are now demanding wholesale services like

    naked DSL and shared access without telephony service. The first is demanded by

    operators who chose VoIP to provide voice services over the unbundled local loop,

    where the second is demanded by those who opted for indirect access services.

    Finally, a thought should be given to the consistence of the prices of the rungs. In the

    previous section, it was concluded that any price defined outside of the market is

    arbitrary. The ladder of investment approach requires defining prices for all of the

    offered rungs. In the case that there are inconsistencies, all operators will tend to the

    best rung, that which allow more profitability, and will not move ceteris paribus.

    Is it possible to assure consistence among prices of the rungs? In the free market, the

    factor prices tend to the discounted value of the marginal product they are able to

    produce. On the other side, the wholesale services included in the ladder of investment

    may be regarded as highly specific factors, because they can only be used to provide a

    concrete retail services (i.e, broadband access to Internet). Because of this, all prices of

    the wholesale services in the ladder would basically depend on the retail price and on

    the prices of the factors that have to be incorporated to the process as a consequence of

    climbing up a rung11.

    In turn, the concrete factors depend on the subjective decisions of entrepreneurs and cannot be apprehended by any outside institution. There is no unique way of climbing

    from a rung to other rung. That logically implies that there is no objective way of

    determining the factors to be used, and whose price should consequently be discounted

    in order to achieve consistence among prices. In brief, to the general arbitrariness of

    9 In the words of Mises: Thus the eagerness of the law's pet children to acquire privileges is insatiable.They continue to ask for new privileges because the old ones lose their power.10 This is rightly identified as a problem in (Cave, 2004), but it is not addressed: Competitors are likely

    to have different business models, and seek various access points. They will also have an interest indenying their rivals the access points they seek.11 See (Rothbard, 1993), chapter 7: Production: General pricing of the factors.

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    17/29

    defining prices outside the market, it is joined the specific arbitrariness of determining

    which factors are to be removed/added from one rung, and their costing. It can be safely

    concluded that it is impossible that prices of the different rungs of the ladder are

    consistent among them.

    As a sample of this arbitrariness, it is interesting to refer to the margin squeeze tests that

    are proposed in order to achieve this consistence. In (Cave, 2004), it is stated that the

    formulation of these tests begs many questions about the range of products over which

    the test should be conducted, the methodology for measuring costs, the firm whose costs

    are relevant to the test (firm A, firm B or some hypothetical efficient retailer) and the

    period over which costs should be calculated. (p.21). The discussion on margin

    squeeze tests is of course a prolongation of the general discussion on methodologies to

    establish prices outside the market, already illustrated.

    The mere definition of the rungs in the ladder of investment approach will likely give

    place to instances of the unsimulated market process, the stifled market process and the

    wholly superfluous market process.

    As said, the rungs of the ladder of investment have to be defined outside the market, and

    its definition implies a certain model of production. However, the only way to identify

    the model of production that better satisfies the consumers preferences in each moment

    is the market process. As the government is not guided by profits, it cannot simulate this

    process, and its election will surely be not the best from the economical point of view,

    even if it is from the technical point of view. Moreover, the government cannot react to

    adapt the model of production to changes in demand preferences.

    The a priori definition of a production model and of the wholesale services will stifle

    the innovation of entrepreneurs. They will see as better alternative to rely in the

    incumbent network and replicate its architecture instead of looking for other solutions to

    serve the market. So, the regulatory defined production model will tend to stay and so

    will the rungs.

    In fact, a wholly superfluous market process will be created, as entrepreneurs startlooking for new rungs in the ladder of investment and new wholesale services that allow

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    18/29

    them to grasp more profit according to their chosen business models. Innovation will

    thus be driven from the search of alternative network solutions, to the search of new

    uses of the incumbent network.

    3.3 Distortion of the investment decisions

    Both the identification of access points and the determination of the corresponding

    prices are arbitrary when made outside the market process. It has already been shown

    that these decisions distort the discovery market process in several ways. In this sub-

    section, it will be described how the ladder of investment distorts the investment

    decisions of entrepreneurs, causing precisely the opposite effect to that pursued by the

    government, that is, it hinders the deployment of alternative access networks.

    In order to prove so, it is first necessary to understand how do prospective investors take

    the decision to invest. In actual life, the existing stock of capital goods is always the

    result of an accidental historical process, consisting of a succession of unforeseen

    changes, and they will never be reproduced in exactly the same form. They were only

    produced in this particular form because certain kinds of equipment happened to be

    available as the result of past history. (Hayek, 1941)

    Any asset becomes an ex-post error as market conditions change. If investors would

    have had the information they got days, months or years after their investment, they

    would have invested in other assets or, at least, would have deployed their assets in

    other ways. For example, if at the moment of deploying copper to provide voice

    services, there would have existed wireless technologies for its provision, it is likely that

    no deployment of copper wire would have happened.

    In the same vein, if operators would have known that citizens would demand broadband

    services in the future, they would probably have chosen another technology instead of

    copper wire as access technology. But, in the moment they got that information, it was

    too late, and copper wire became an ex-post mistake.

    However, the adaptation of the production infrastructure to the new situation is not

    automatic. It requires an explicit decision of the entrepreneurs, and it depends not only

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    19/29

    of the relative obsolescence of the current assets, but, most importantly, on the

    incremental profits that the new investment is able to accrue.

    The adoption of new techniques is limited by the usefulness of already given capital-

    goods structure. (...) The fact that investment in a new technique is unprofitable means

    that the use of capital in the new process at the cost of scrapping the old equipment is a

    waste from the point of view of satisfying consumer wants. (Rothbard, 1993)

    Applied to the ladder of investment approach, this means that, the decision of an

    operator to progress from one rung to the next one is not automatic. Most importantly,

    the operator, when taking this decision, will not consider the absolute level of profits

    after the investment (i.e. the climb to the next rung), but only the incremental profits itwill get.

    For example, suppose that in rung A the operator is obtaining XA Euros of profit, and

    that it estimates that it may obtain XB Euros in rung B. The decision to invest is NOT

    based on XB, but only in the increment XB XA. Only if that increment justifies the

    investment, it will be accomplished. Otherwise, the situation will remain. This fact

    logically implies that any operator is less likely to progress from one rung to another,than to directly start in the second rung. In the first case, the operator only sees XB XA,

    but in the second it sees the full XB.

    Only if there is high degree in the re-use of investments to reach one rung, allowing for

    a lesser investment, is this conclusion reverted. This degree of re-use may be relevant

    when progressing between wholesale services of the incumbent operator, but it is

    clearly not relevant when climbing to the own access network rung.

    Let us focus on the specific case of the last rung of the ladder of investment, according

    to ERG. It consists of passing from the use of Unbundled Local Loop (ULL) to its own

    infrastructure. As just described, in order to take this decision, alternative operators will

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    20/29

    take into consideration the following items (roughly): current Average Revenue per

    User (ARPU), expected ARPU and current recurrent cost12.

    In their own infrastructure there are no recurrent costs. The current cost is the ULL

    regulated price. The decision will be based on the following magnitude (the higher, the

    more likely the investment): ARPUExpected (ARPUCurrent PriceULL). According to

    European Commission, the average price for ULL in the EU is 10,88 Euros per month

    (fully unbundled LL), being 11,43 in Spain13. This means that the key issue for this

    decision is the expected increase in the ARPU, which, in turn, depends on the services

    for which costumers are willing to pay, of those that can be offered on the new

    infrastructure, but could not be offered with the current one.

    With ULL, alternative operators can provide telephony, broadband access services and

    TV. These are the services that are currently demanded by end users; demand

    uncertainty for services requiring higher speeds is great at this moment, even if there are

    talks of HDTV. So, the prospects of increasing the ARPU with investment in new

    infrastructure (like optical fibre) are currently dim for alternative operators. In these

    circumstances, there is no possibility of progressing to the last rung of the ladder.

    Compare this situation with that of an operator who is no present in any rung in the

    ladder of investment. For this operator, the decision on investment depends only and

    completely on the expected ARPU. Of course, this ARPU will include that derived of

    new services (like HDTV), but it will also include the current ARPU obtained by an

    operator using ULL. If there is an increase in the expected ARPU (due, for example, to

    positive prospects for new services), it is easier that a new entrant deploy infrastructure,

    than that an operator using ULL do it.

    It is interesting to analyse how the price of the ULL affects the investment decision of

    operators using ULL. Recall that this decision depends on the magnitude ARPUExpected

    12 Note that this analysis is ceteris paribus to isolate cause and effect. In concrete, the number ofcostumers is left untouched. It is not possible to praxeologically infer any effect on the number ofcostumers from a change in the used rung of the ladder of investment.13 European Commission: Progress Report on the Single European Electronic Communications Market

    (14th Report)(COM(2009)140 final). Available athttp://ec.europa.eu/information_society/policy/ecomm/library/communications_reports/annualreports/14th/index_en.htm

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    21/29

    (ARPUCurrent PriceULL) and the higher the increase, the higher the probability of

    investment. It is immediate to show that PriceULL has a positive impact on the

    magnitude, and, the higher PriceULL, the higher the probability of investment.

    However, NRAs in Europe seem to go in the contrary direction. This price is decreasing

    in the EU, as shown in the graphic14.

    Once again, this regulatory behaviour is contrary to the goal pursued. But it has other

    effects. Let analyze the investment decision process in order to progress among

    intermediate rungs of the ladder, i.e., those between wholesale services of the

    incumbent. For example, from bitstream services to ULL services.

    Recall that the decision depends positively on the difference XB XA being XB and XAthe profits respectively obtained at rung B and rung A. In the case under analysis, the

    difference may be formulated as (ARPUExpected PriceULL) (ARPUCurrent

    PriceBitstream), equivalent to (ARPUExpected ARPUCurrent) + (PriceBitstream - PriceULL).

    However, in this case there is a clear increment in ARPU, because it is not possible to

    provide TV with commercial quality using bitstream services. Moreover, the lower the

    14 European Commission: Progress Report on the Single European Electronic Communications Market(14th Report)

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    22/29

    PriceULL, the higher the magnitude, and the higher the probability of investment.

    Finally, it should not be forgotten that investment to progress between two rungs on the

    incumbent network is considerably lower than to deploy a new infrastructure. This

    explains why operators tend to flock on the ULL rung of the ladder of investment, but

    do not progress from here.

    Note that NRAs, with their decisions, are steering operators to the ULL rung of the

    ladder of investment. And, it is precisely for the operators in this rung for which more

    difficult is to find viable an investment in new infrastructures, as shown before.

    In summary, the theoretical analysis shows that the ladder of investment approach

    hinders the deployment of alternative access infrastructures, instead of easing it, as its

    proponents defend. It is contrary to the goal it admittedly pursues.

    4. Does the ladder of investment work?

    In this section, it will be discussed if, according to historical evidence, it can be said that

    the ladder of investment is working. The analysis will focus on the case of broadband

    access services on the Spanish market. In this regard, at least, two papers have been

    published stating that the ladder of investment is working for this market15. As this

    seems contrary to the conclusion just deducted, those analyses deserve a detailed

    review.

    4.1 Empirical analysis under Austrian School of Economics methodology

    It should be noted that, as explained in section 2, the Austrian methodology does not

    rely on empirical or historical evidence for its conclusions, but on logical reasoning.

    According to the Austrian school, economics is a science in the same sense that

    mathematics and logic are sciences. Its claims are based on logical deduction from

    indisputable axioms, and may be illustrated historically, but never verified or falsified

    experimentally. In the same way, we do not ask for experimental verification that a

    straight line is the shortest distance between two points on a two-dimensional plane.

    15 See (Lpez & Vives, 2008), (Lpez, 2009).

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    23/29

    Thus, the conclusions achieved in the precedent section are true (provided there are no

    flaws in the logic reasoning), with independence of the results of the historical evidence.

    If this evidence shows that the ladder of investment has not worked in the past, it could

    be due to exogenous causes not related to the regulatory implementation. In the same

    vein, if the historical evidence showed that the ladder of investment has worked in the

    past, it does not imply that it will work in the future, not even that the results observed

    were due to the regulatory implementation. Historical phenomena are too complex to

    allow the isolation of a concrete cause for a given event.

    In brief, the historical analysis now proposed does not change in any direction the

    theoretical results already developed.

    4.2 Review of the empirical analysis for the Spanish market

    As is usually the case, empirical research in this area throws contradictory results. There

    are several studies that seem to conclude that entry regulation discourages infrastructure

    investment, both for incumbents16 and for new entrants17. This seems in line with the

    theoretical conclusion of this paper.

    Being the ladder of investment one concrete form of entry regulation, the same should

    be expected for broadband services in Spain. However, the conclusion reached in

    (Lpez & Vives, 2008) and (Lpez, 2009) seems to be the contrary.

    Those conclusions are based on historical data of the Spanish market. The authors

    analyse the evolution of wholesale services between 2001 and 2008, distinguishing

    16 See (Baake & Kamecke, 2007), (Kotakorpi, 2006)17 See (Friederiszick et al., 2008), (Waverman et al., 2007)

    34,85%

    42,39%

    27,16% 30,66%

    23,36%

    60,65%

    26,94%37,99%

    23,11%

    14,17%

    42,62% 41,33%

    25,19%

    34,02%35,57%

    0%

    10%

    %30%

    40%

    50%

    60%

    70%

    80%

    90%

    100%

    2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 IIQ 2008 IIIQ 2008

    20

    Resale+Bitstream access shared access Full ULL

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    24/29

    between resale+bitstream, shared access and ULL. They analyse the data in relative

    terms, with the results shown in the graphic below18.

    From this data, they conclude:

    En conclusin, aparentemente parece confirmarse la teora de la escalera de inversin

    en el sector espaol, al menos hasta el punto de presencia que se corresponde con la

    desagregacin de bucles locales. Sin embargo, todava falta por saber si los operadores

    alternativos darn el paso final de acceder directamente al hogar del consumidor

    desplegando su propia red mediante el uso de tecnologas alternativas. (Lpez &

    Vives, 2008), p.10

    Existe competencia basada en infraestructuras en Espaa? La desagregacin del

    bucle supone una inversin considerable en infraestructuras, podemos por tanto

    considerar tanto el cable como la desagregacin de bucles locales competencia basada

    en infraestructuras. (Lpez & Vives, 2008), p.11

    Por un lado tenemos que el proceso de la escalera de la inversin hasta el bucle local

    se ha cumplido en Espaa, y para ello ha sido fundamental la regulacin del sector que

    ha incentivado el despliegue de redes. (Lpez, 2009), p.3.

    It is surprising to note that alternative accesses are not analysed in any of the papers.

    Taking into account that the admitted purpose of the ladder of investment is to facilitate

    alternative operators the deployment of their own access network, it is difficult to see

    how conclusions about its efficacy can be reached without that information.

    In fact, their conclusion is that the ladder of investment up to the local loop has been

    accomplished in Spain. But this conclusion misses the point, because the goal of the

    ladder of investment is not that, but the deployment of alternative accesses. And itcannot be inferred from the fact that it has worked up to the ULL, that it will keep

    working to the last rung. In fact, none of the operators involved in ULL in Spain has

    made any progress to the last mile, after 8 years of ladder of investment.

    18 Source: The ladder of investment in Spain Slides- ngel L.Lpez, 17 March 2009. Available atwww.nerec.es. Last accessed: 21 August 2009.

    http://www.nerec.es/http://www.nerec.es/
  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    25/29

    The only alternative infrastructures for fixed access in Spain are those deployed by

    cable operators. None of these operators have used any of the wholesale services

    provided under the ladder of investment regulation.

    All these results are consistent with the theoretical analysis of the previous section. On

    one side, alternative operators tend to flock around one of the intermediate rungs,

    without progress to the last rung. In this case, they seem to flock around ULL services.

    On the other side, investment in alternative infrastructures is more likely to come from

    operators that are not using ladder of investment services. In the case of Spain, they

    come from cable operators.

    Besides, the authors make no analysis proving that the cause of this accomplishment is

    the regulation of ladder of investment. It is just stated in the paper. A more rigorous

    causal analysis would be necessary in order to reach that conclusion, but this is absent

    from any of the papers. Thus, even if it were accepted that the ladder of investment is

    working (in a perfunctory way), it would still be needed to prove that it is due to the

    related regulation and no other cause.

    In order to do so, it would be interesting to analyse the evolution of wholesale services

    in light of the regulated prices of the different rungs. Specifically, it would be necessary

    to analyse if the relative increases of ULL and shared access with respect to bitstream

    are correlated in time with changes in difference of the regulated prices of both services.

    In that case, the evolution of access should be traced not to the ladder of investment

    approach per se, but to the changes in relative attractiveness of wholesale prices. The

    theoretical analysis has shown that there is a strong influence of that difference whendeciding to move from one rung to the next one of the incumbent network. In other

    words, if the climbing of the ladder is due to changes in prices, the efficacy of the ladder

    of investment is falsified19. Unfortunately, nothing has been done in this regard.

    19 Of course, ladder of investment proponents will argue that the original prices were wrong, and only

    after the change could the ladder work. It has already been shown that it is impossible to have the pricesright in any case. Besides, even if this argument is accepted, why is then necessary to keep reducingthem?

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    26/29

    Finally, the authors state that the unbundling of the loop supposes a significant

    investment in infrastructures, thus we can consider both cable and unbundling of local

    loops as infrastructure-based competition. If this statement is accepted, then of course

    the ladder of investment has achieved its purpose in Spain.

    The statement is, however, wrong. The amount of investments that ULL requires has

    nothing to do with it being or not an alternative infrastructure. ULL-based operators

    keep relying on the incumbent network, with independence of the investment required.

    Thus, it is fallacious to state that cable and ULL constitute infrastructure-based

    competition. In Spain, the real infrastructure competition is between cable operators and

    incumbent. And this competition has nothing to do with the ladder of investment.

    In summary, there is no historical evidence showing that the ladder of investment is

    working in Spain, in spite of the analysed papers. Nor there is evidence that the

    evolution of wholesale access is due to the ladder of investment regulation.

    On the contrary, the historical evidence in Spain seems consistent with the theoretical

    analysis developed previously: alternative operators tend to flock around ULL services,

    without investing in alternative infrastructures. This investment has only come from

    cable operators, which have never used wholesale services of the ladder of investment.

    5. Conclusions

    Since the opening of the telecommunications market for competition, European

    governments have sought the deployment of an alternative access infrastructure. This is

    the only way in which they see that effective competition can be achieved, as

    competition will not rely anymore on the incumbent network. Surprisingly, they do not

    seem to consider mobile networks as an alternative infrastructure, even if these

    networks would seem capable to cater for the needs of most users.

    In any case, it is not for the economic analyst to wonder about the goals of the

    government, but only to analyse if the proposed means are able to attain those goals. As

    already said, European governments, led by the European Commission, have

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    27/29

    implemented the ladder of investment approach in order to achieve the deployment of

    an alternative fixed access network.

    It has been proven that the referred approach can not possibly attain that goal, but, on

    the contrary, it hinders it. In the first place, it is impossible to establish a price outside

    the market; prices set by the government will distort the investment decisions of

    entrepreneurs, causing them to direct resources to wrong places.

    In the second place, it is also impossible to establish relevant points of access outside

    the market process: the rungs defined are thus arbitrary. Even if they are reasonable

    from a technical point of view, this does not imply that there is a need for them in the

    market. This definition will probably freeze innovation in the productive process and

    will cause that all operators opt for the regulated production process.

    Thirdly, as the decision to progress between rungs depends on the incremental profit,

    not on the absolute level of the same, it is more difficult for an operator already present

    in the ladder of investment to deploy its own access network, than it is for a whole new

    entrant. However, the current regulation is driving prospective alternative operators to

    the ULL rung, making it very unlikely that there is any deployment of alternative access

    networks.

    Even if the analysis of historical evidence is irrelevant for the methodology used in this

    paper, a couple of papers on the Spanish market were reviewed, as they seemed to

    conclude that the ladder of investment has worked in Spain. However, the empirical

    evidence presented in those papers did not prove so. On the contrary, it was consistent

    with the theoretical analysis presented, as it showed that the only alternativeinfrastructures had been deployed by the cable operators (which do not use any ladder

    of investment service) and that no ladder of investment-based operator has deployed any

    access.

    In summary, the ladder of investment approach fails to achieve its goal. The theoretical

    analysis unambiguously shows this conclusion, and the presented empirical evidence

    seems consistent with the result. Given these conclusions, it would be desirable thatEuropean regulators and European Commission stopped pursuing this approach, not

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    28/29

    only for the legacy copper network, but most importantly, for the new optical fibre

    networks.

    6. References

    Armstrong, M. (2002). The theory of access pricing and interconnection. In M.

    Cave, S. Majumdar, & I. Vogelsang (Eds.), Handbook of telecommunications

    economics, Vol. 1. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Baake P. & Kamecke U. (2007). New networks, competition and regulation. Berlin,

    Germany: German Institute for Economic Research

    Buchanan, J. M. (1999): Cost and Choice, Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund.

    Cave M., Vogelsang I. (2003). How access pricing and entry interact.

    Telecommunications Policy, 27, 717-727.

    Cave, M. (2004). Remedies for broadband services. Journal of Network Industries,

    2349.

    Cave M. (2006). Encouraging infrastructure competition via the ladder of

    investment. Telecommunications Policy, 30, 233-237

    Friederiszick, H. W., Grajek, M. and Rller, L.-H. (2007). Analysing the

    Relationship Between Regulation and Investment in the Telecom Sector. ESMT

    White Paper.

    Hayek F.A. (1941). The pure theory of capitalism. Chicago: The University of

    Chicago Press.

    Hayek F.A. (1948). The meaning of competition. In F.A. Hayek, Individualism and

    economic order, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Hayek F.A. (2002). Competition as a discovery procedure. The Quarterly Journal of

    Austrian Economics, 5 (3), 9-23.

    Herrera-Gonzlez, F. (2008). Europes internet troubles: The history continues,

    Mises Daily, [News Bulletin]. URL http://mises.org/story/2851

  • 8/3/2019 Paper ITSEurope 2009 Final

    29/29

    Kirzner I.M. (1985). The Perils of Regulation: A Market Process Approach. In R.M.

    Ebeling (1991), Austrian Economics: A Reader, Hillsdale, MI: Hillsdale College

    Press, 618-654.

    Kirzner, I. M. (1973). Competition and Entrepreneurship. Chicago: ChicagoUniversity Press.

    Kotakorpi, K. (2006). Access price regulation, investment and entry in

    telecommunications. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24, 1013-

    1020.

    Lpez A.L. & Vives X. (2008). Inversin en banda ancha: Competencia en

    infraestructuras y competencia en servicios. Economistas, Espaa 2007: Un

    balance.

    Lpez A.L. (2009).Despliegue de redes de telecomunicaciones y difusin de banda

    ancha.Economistas, Espaa 2008.

    Mises, L. von (1998a). Human action: A treatise on economics (The Scholars

    Edition). Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute. Murphy, R.P. (2007). Austrian vs. neoclassical analytics, [Speech at Ludwig von

    Mises Institute]. URL http://mises.org/Controls/Media/MediaPlayer.aspx?Id=3263

    Raisman, G. (1990). Capitalism. Ottawa, IL: Jameson Books.

    Rothbard, M. N. (1993): Man, economy, and state. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises

    Institute.

    Waverman, L., Meschi, M., Reillier, B., & Dasgupta, K. (2007). Access regulation

    and infrastructure investment in the telecommunications sector: An empirical

    investigation. Study for ETNO.