microeconomics of banking: lecture 10

40
Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Dec. 4, 2015 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Upload: others

Post on 21-Feb-2022

5 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO

Dec. 4, 2015

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Administrative Stuff

▸ HW 4 is due next week.

▸ Final is on Dec. 18.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Review of Last Week

▸ In asymmetric information models, one party (e.g. seller, employee)has relevant information that another party (e.g. buyer, employer)does not know.

▸ In a model with adverse selection, the ”low-quality” type is the onlyone that is traded on the market, since the buyer does not know thetrue type of the object.

▸ One way to mitigate this problem is with a costly signal.

▸ We saw a signaling model of education with ”low” and ”high” typesof workers.

▸ Education could be used as a signal to differentiate betweenworkers, even though it was assumed to have no effect on ability.

▸ A separating equilibrium is an equilibrium where different typeschoose different actions, and therefore can be distinguished fromone another.

▸ A pooling equilibrium is one where different types choose the sameaction, and cannot be distinguished from one another.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Review of Last Week

▸ We saw a model of risk-averse entrepreneur/borrowers with privateinformation about the quality of their projects.

▸ If the project quality θ were not private, then higher-quality projectswould be sold to investors at a higher price.

▸ If the project quality is private, we can have a situation with adverseselection, where only low-quality projects are sold.

▸ Entrepreneurs with high-quality projects can use self-financing as acostly signal to differentiate themselves.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Example of Principal-Agent Problem

▸ There is a single insurance company and a single consumer who isconsidering whether to buy car insurance.

▸ The consumer might get into an accident, causing a random loss of`, where ` ∈ {0,1, ...,L}.

▸ The consumer can choose two levels of ”effort” to drive safely:e ∈ {0,1}. 1 gives a higher disutility to the consumer.

▸ The probability of getting into an accident of loss ` depends on e:π`(e), assumed to be strictly positive for all `, e.

▸ Assume π`(0)π`(1)

is strictly increasing in ` ∈ {0,1, ...,L}.

▸ This means that conditional on accident ` being observed, theprobability that e = 0 was chosen is higher than the probability thate = 1 was chosen.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Example of Principal-Agent Problem

▸ Assume the insurance company is risk-neutral. Therefore, it onlycares about the expected value of its payoff.

▸ Assume the consumer has vN-M utility function u(⋅), which isstrictly increasing and strictly concave.

▸ This implies the consumer is risk-averse, and is always willing toaccept some decrease in average payoff in exchange for a decreasein variance.

▸ Let d(e) denote the disutility of effort. Assume d(1) > d(0).

▸ Consumer’s vN-M utility function is: u(⋅) − d(e)

▸ Assume the consumer’s initial wealth is w , which is large enough topay for insurance.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Insurance Contract

▸ A contract specifies an action in each observable state of the world(i.e. each random outcome that is observable to all parties).

▸ The insurance company can observe the loss `, but not the effort e.Therefore, the contract can only specify actions for values of `.

▸ The contract is a tuple (p,B0,B1, ...,BL), where:

▸ p is the price of the contract, paid by the consumer to theinsurance company in the beginning

▸ B` specifies the payment from the insurance company to theconsumer, if accident ` occurs

▸ Assume that consumers have a reservation utility u that they canget elsewhere (perhaps from a competing insurance company).

▸ We want to find a contract that maximizes the insurance company’sprofits, while still being acceptable to the consumer.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Insurance Contract

▸ We can model this as an extensive-form game:

1. First, the insurance company proposes a contract, which is acollection of L + 1 real numbers (p,B0,B1, ...,BL), to theconsumer.

2. The consumer can accept or reject.3. If the consumer rejects, the insurance company gets a payoff of

0, and the consumer gets his reservation utility u.4. If the consumer accepts, the consumer pays p to the company.5. The consumer then chooses an effort level e = 0 or e = 1.6. Nature chooses the loss level ` ∈ {0,1, ...,L}, where the

probability distribution depends on e.7. The insurance company pays B` to the consumer. Final payoff

is p −B`.8. Consumer’s final payoff is his utility, u(w − p − ` +B`) − d(e).

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Symmetric Information Case (e is observable)

▸ Suppose e is observable. Then e can be specified in the contract.

▸ The insurance company wants to solve the following problem:

maxe,p,B0,...,BL

p −L

∑`=0

π`(e)B` subject to

L

∑`=0

π`(e)u(w − p − ` +B`) − d(e) ≥ u

▸ This problem maximizes over the variables (e,p,B0, ...,BL). We candecompose it into two steps:

▸ Take e as given, and maximize over (p,B0, ...,BL), to get afunction of e.

▸ Maximize this function over e.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Symmetric Information Case (e is observable)

▸ Take e as given.

maxp,B0,...,BL

p −L

∑`=0

π`(e)B` subject to

L

∑`=0

π`(e)u(w − p − ` +B`) − d(e) ≥ u

▸ Lagrangian is:

L(p,B0, ...,BL) = p−L

∑`=0

π`(e)B`−λ [u −L

∑`=0

π`(e)u(w − p − ` +B`) − d(e)]

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

First Order Conditions

▸ First order conditions:

∂L

∂p= 1 − λ [

L

∑`=0

π`(e)u′(w − p − ` +B`)] = 0

∂L

∂B`= −π`(e) + λπ`(e)u

′(w − p − ` +B`) = 0 for ` ∈ {0, ...,L}

∂L

∂λ= u −

L

∑`=0

π`(e)u(w − p − ` +B`) − d(e) = 0

▸ The insurance company will lower the payouts as far as possible, sowe can assume the constraint is binding and λ > 0.

▸ The middle equalities implies u′(w − p − ` +B`) = 1/λ for all `,therefore B` − ` is constant for all `.

▸ This is a classic risk-sharing result:▸ the risk-averse agent will fully insure (receive the same utility

in all states/outcomes)▸ the risk-neutral party will take on risk (receive different utilities

in different states/outcomes)Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Optimal Contract for Symmetric Information

▸ There are many possible optimal contracts, since p can be adjustedto compensate for B`.

▸ One possible optimal contract is: B` = ` for ` = 0, ...,L

▸ For each e, the optimal p is determined by the equationu(w − p(e)) = d(e) + u

▸ Then, the optimal e maximizes the expected profit of the insurancecompany:

p(e) −L

∑`=0

π`(e)`

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Asymmetric Information Case

▸ Suppose e is not observable. The insurance company must designthe contract so that the consumer will voluntarily choose thecompany’s desired e.

▸ This introduces an additional incentive constraint, that the choiceof e is utility-maximizing for the consumer:

maxe,p,B0,...,BL

p −L

∑`=0

π`(e)B` subject to

L

∑`=0

π`(e)u(w − p − ` +B`) − d(e) ≥ u

L

∑`=0

π`(e)u(w −p − `+B`)−d(e) ≥L

∑`=0

π`(e′)u(w −p − `+B`)−d(e

′)

▸ where e ≠ e′.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Optimal Policy for e = 0

▸ In the symmetric information case, the optimal policy given e = 0must satisfy the equality

u(w − p) = d(0) + u for ` = 0, ...,L

▸ Adding the incentive constraint to this problem does not increasethe feasible set, so if a maximizer of the symmetric problem alsosatisfies the incentive constraint, then it is also a maximizer of theasymmetric case.

▸ The incentive constraint for e = 0 is:

L

∑`=0

π`(e)u(w −p − `+B`)−d(e) ≥L

∑`=0

π`(e′)u(w −p − `+B`)−d(e

′)

d(0) ≥ d(1)

▸ which is true by assumption.

▸ The optimal policy for e = 0 is the same as in the symmetric infocase.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Optimal Policy for e = 1

▸ Form the Lagrangian with two constraints (the incentive constraint,and the constraint ensuring e = 1).

▸ It can be shown that both constraints are binding: consumer isindifferent between e = 0 and e = 1

▸ The optimal policy must have the property: ` −B` is strictlyincreasing in `

▸ This no longer provides full insurance. It specifies a deductiblepayment that increases with size of loss

▸ This is necessary to incentivize consumer to choose high effort.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Delegated Monitoring (2.4 in Freixas & Rochet)

▸ When there is asymmetric information, then efficiency can beincreased with monitoring, which can mean:

▸ screening of projects before deciding to lend to them▸ preventing opportunistic behavior of a borrower (e.g. replacing

management who are not performing well)▸ punishing borrowers who fail to meet their contractual

obligations

▸ Specialized firms are likely to be more efficient at monitoring thanindividual lenders. This provides a clear justification for the role offinancial intermediaries.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Delegated Monitoring

▸ This is based on the paper: Diamond (1980), ”FinancialIntermediation and Delegated Monitoring”

▸ There are n identical, risk-neutral firms that are seeking to finance aproject.

▸ Assume the riskless interest rate is R.

▸ Each firm requires an investment of 1, and the cash flow of eachfirm is an i.i.d. random variable y .

▸ All agents agree on the distribution of y , but it is only observed bythe entrepreneur of the firm, but not the lender.

▸ Assume y > 0, and E(y) > R +K , where K > 0 will be defined later.

▸ The entrepreneur can lie and misreport the cash flow of the firm.

▸ How can the lenders and borrowers come to an agreement?

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Approach 1: Optimal Financial Contract

▸ Let’s try to come up with a contract that is incentive-compatible(both sides will make a positive expected payoff by agreeing to it).

▸ A complete contract is a rule that specifies what each party shoulddo, for each observable state of the world.

▸ Here, only the entrepreneur’s chosen repayment z is observable, so acontract specifies the actions of the borrower and lender for everypossible z .

▸ In the absence of outside enforcement, a contract is only useful ifboth sides voluntarily agree to follow its terms.

▸ Therefore, any contract that is actually agreed to must be a Nashequilibrium: the parties have no incentive to deviate from the termsof the contract.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Approach 1: Optimal Financial Contract

▸ Suppose y is the actual cash flow of the firm.

▸ z(y) is a function that specifies what the entrepreneur will repay,given y .

▸ φ(z) is the penalty that is imposed by the lender when theentrepreneur repays z .

▸ An optimal penalty function must satisfy these conditions:

▸ Penalty must be high enough to deter underpayment▸ Penalty must be small to avoid welfare costs

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Approach 1: Optimal Financial Contract

▸ Consider this penalty function: φ∗(z) = max(h − z(y),0), where h isthe contractually agreed level of repayment

▸ The sum of repayment and penalties is always h; therefore, theentrepreneur is indifferent between lying and telling the truth

▸ We’ll assume that the entrepreneur will not lie in this situation.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Approach 1: Optimal Financial Contract

▸ What should h be? Consider this value of h: the lowest value thatprovides lenders with an expected return of R.

▸ h is the smallest value that satisfies

P(y < h)E [y ∣y < h] + P(y ≥ h)h = R

▸ Consider z(y) = min(h, y).

▸ The entrepreneur passes on all the cash flow if y < h; otherwise, herepays h and keeps the rest for himself

▸ This is like a standard credit contract: if the borrower cannot repay,the lenders seize the firm and liquidate the assets

▸ This contract is incentive-compatible for both the lender and theborrower:

▸ the lender’s expected return is equal to R, by the aboveequation

▸ the borrower is indifferent between lying and not lying, asshown previously, so will report the true y

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Approach 1: Optimal Financial Contract

▸ The final specification of the contract is:

▸ The borrower agrees to repay h, which satisfies

P(y < h)E [y ∣y < h] + P(y ≥ h)h = R

▸ If he repays some amount z < h, then the lender will impose apenalty of h − z , otherwise the penalty is zero

▸ This is not socially efficient, since the entrepreneur has to pay apenalty even when he is telling the truth.

▸ Entrepreneurs could be made better off without making lendersworse off, if y were observable.

▸ An alternative solution: Monitoring by lenders

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Approach 2: Contract with Monitoring

▸ Suppose there are m lenders per firm, and that each lender canspend K > 0 to observe y .

▸ Welfare is increased if mK < E [φ∗(z(y))], i.e. if the total cost ofmonitoring is less than the expected amount of penalty.

▸ Monitoring is preferable if m is small, and if the expected penalty ishigh (e.g. if there is a high probability of low returns)

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Approach 3: Delegated Monitoring

▸ If monitoring is delegated to a financial intermediary (FI),monitoring costs can be reduced to K

▸ However, this brings up an additional problem: how can the lenderstrust the FI? There must be an additional level of monitoring

▸ We can combine the two previous approaches: the lenders have anoptimal contract with penalties between themselves and the FI

▸ And, the FI monitors the borrowers.

▸ If the FI deals with a large number of firms with independentreturns, then the probability of low returns goes to 0, by the Law ofLarge Numbers

▸ Then, the expected penalties go to zero as well.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Coalitions of Depositors (Ch. 2.2 in Freixas & Rochet)

▸ This is from Diamond & Dybvig (1983), ”Bank runs, depositinsurance, and liquidity”

▸ One way to think about depository institutions like banks: pools ofliquid assets (e.g. cash).

▸ Individual households need cash due to idiosyncratic shocks (e.g. tofinance consumption).

▸ These households can combine their resources in a coalition, todiversify against risk.

▸ As long as these households’ shocks are not correlated across time,then the total cash reserve needed to satisfy these shocks increasesless slowly than the total number of households.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

The Model

▸ There are three time periods: t = 0,1,2.

▸ There is 1 good.

▸ A continuum of consumers who are identical at t = 0 are endowedwith 1 unit of the good.

▸ At t = 1, the consumers learn what type they are.

▸ Type-1 consumers are called ”early” consumers, and consumeonly in t = 1, with utility u(c1)

▸ Type-2 consumers are called ”late” consumers, and consumeonly in t = 2, with utility u(c2)

▸ Let π1, π2 be the probability of being Type-1 or 2. The expectedutility at t = 0 is

U = π1u(c1) + π2u(c2)

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

The Model

▸ At t = 0, a consumer can choose to consume his endowment, orsave it in two ways:

▸ Store it for 1 period. This is equivalent to a riskless asset witha net return of 1.

▸ Invest amount I in a long-run technology, which gives a netreturn of R > 1 at t = 2, but it can be liquidated early, to givea return of L < 1 in t = 1.

▸ For example, a long-dated certificate of deposit, or a long-termconstruction project.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Optimal Allocation

▸ First, let’s look at the optimal allocation, which maximizes expectedutility at t = 0.

maxc1,c2,I

π1u(c1) + π2u(c2) subject to

π1c1 = 1 − I , π2c2 = RI ⇒ π1c1 + π2c2R

= 1

▸ The first order condition is

u′(c∗1 ) = Ru′(c∗2 )

▸ The marginal rate of substitution between consumption at t = 1,2equals the return on the long-run technology.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Autarky: No Trade Between Agents

▸ Suppose that trade between agents is not allowed.

▸ At t = 0, each agent chooses the amount to store, and the amountto invest I .

▸ Then at t = 1, their type is revealed.

▸ Type-1 agents’ income will be the amount they stored, plus LI(the liquidation value of what was invested in t = 0)

c1 = 1 − I + LI = 1 − I (1 − L)

▸ Type-2 agents’ will continue their storage until t = 2. Then,their income will be the amount they stored, plus RI (thelong-term return on what was invested in t = 0)

c2 = 1 − I + RI = 1 + I (R − 1)

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Autarky: No Trade Between Agents

▸ Type-1 agents’ income will be the amount they stored, plus LI (theliquidation value of what was invested in t = 0)

c1 = 1 − I + LI = 1 − I (1 − L)

▸ Type-2 agents’ will continue their storage until t = 2. Then, theirincome will be the amount they stored, plus RI (the long-termreturn on what was invested in t = 0)

c2 = 1 − I + RI = 1 + I (R − 1)

▸ At t = 0, all investors will maximize expected utility subject to thesetwo constraints.

▸ Note that c1 ≤ 1, with equality if I = 0.

▸ c2 ≤ R, with equality if I = 1.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Autarky: No Trade Between Agents

▸ Note that c1 ≤ 1, with equality if I = 0.

▸ c2 ≤ R, with equality if I = 1. Since both cannot hold, then

π1c1 + π2c2R

< 1

▸ This is inefficient, since some resources are lost due to earlyliquidation.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Introduce a Financial Market for Bonds

▸ Suppose that agents are allowed to trade a riskless bond with otheragents.

▸ We model this by introducing a financial market at t = 1: agentscan trade 1 unit of the good for 1 riskless bond that has price p(endogenously determined), and returns 1 at t = 2.

▸ We will assume agents are price-takers.

▸ Since this is after agents’ types have been revealed, Type 1 agentswill trade with Type 2 agents.

▸ Both Type 1 and Type 2 agents chose the same amount of I , sincetheir type was not yet revealed.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Introduce a Financial Market for Bonds

▸ Both Type 1 and Type 2 agents chose the same amount of I , sincetheir type was not yet revealed.

▸ Type 1 agents will sell bonds at t = 1. They will repay these bondsat t = 2 with the returns of the long-term technology:

c1 = 1 − I + pRI

▸ Type 2 agents will buy bonds at t = 1 with the amount they stored,and get extra consumption at t = 2:

c2 =1 − I

p+ RI =

1

p(1 − I + pRI )

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Introduce a Financial Market for Bonds

▸ Type 1 agents will sell bonds at t = 1. They will repay these bondsat t = 2 with the returns of the long-term technology:

c1 = 1 − I + pRI

▸ Type 2 agents will buy bonds at t = 1 with the amount they stored,and get extra consumption at t = 2:

c2 =1 − I

p+ RI =

1

p(1 − I + pRI )

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Introduce a Financial Market for Bonds

c1 = 1 − I + pRI

c2 =1 − I

p+ RI =

1

p(1 − I + pRI )

▸ Note that c1 and c2 are linear functions of I , and c2 =c1p

.

▸ The only interior equilibrium occurs when p = 1R

.

▸ If p > 1R

, then I = 1 and there is an excess supply of bonds: Type-1agents will sell bonds, but no one will buy them

▸ If p < 1R

, then I = 0 and there is excess demand of bonds: Type-2agents want to buy bonds, but no one will sell them

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Introduce a Financial Market for Bonds

▸ At equilibrium, c1 = 1, c2 = R, I = π2.

▸ This Pareto-dominates the autarky solution since there is noliquidiation, therefore no wasted resources.

▸ However, the first-order condition u′(c∗1 ) = Ru′(c∗2 ) is not satisfied.

▸ Efficiency is acheived when there is perfect insurance: the marginalutility is equalized across all possible states of the world (that is, allpossible random outcomes).

▸ In a complete market (i.e. there is a security corresponding to everyoutcome), risk-averse agents will perfectly insure.

▸ This market, however, is incomplete, since there is no securitycorresponding to the outcome of the liquidity shock (Type 1 vs.Type 2).

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Financial Intermediation

▸ Suppose we know what the optimal allocation (c∗1 , c∗

2 ) is.

▸ Assume there is a financial intermediary that offers this depositcontract:

▸ In exchange for 1 unit at t = 0, the FI will pay either c∗1 att = 1, or c∗2 at t = 2.

▸ Out of the 1 deposited, the FI will store π1c∗

1 , and invest 1−π1c∗

1 inthe long-term technology.

▸ The FI achieves the Pareto-optimal allocation.

▸ Note that this requires that only Type-1 depositors withdraw att = 1; this is true in Nash equilibrium, since Type-2 depositors wouldlower their payoff if they withdrew early.

▸ There is another Nash equilibrium where all Type-2 depositorswithdraw; this is a bank run and will be studied later in the course.

▸ One problem with this model is that the FI cannot coexist with afinancial market.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

What Can Banks Do That Investors Can’t Do ByThemselves?

▸ In the first week, we saw that in a general equilibrium with completemarkets (i.e. a security exists for every possible state of the world),there is no role for banks.

▸ If consumers can directly lend to borrowers, or buy and tradesecurities, then there is no need for a financial intermediary.

▸ If we want to model financial intermediaries correctly, we need tospecify something that individual consumers cannot do bythemselves.

▸ We have seen three models that provide this rationale:▸ A single depositor cannot diversify against liquidity shocks, but

a coalition of many depositors can;▸ If there is asymmetric information between borrowers and

lenders, a coalition of lenders can decrease the cost of capital;▸ If lenders have to monitor borrowers, then a financial

intermediary that deals with many lenders can decrease theaverage cost of monitoring.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Summary of Ch. 2

▸ We’ve seen 3 models where financial intermediaries can providesomething that individual investors cannot do for themselves.

▸ In each of the 3 models, the individual borrower-lender relationshipis inefficient, due to some sort of asymmetric information.

▸ If we assume that coalitions of borrowers or lenders can diversifyaway this inefficiency, then we have a rationale for financialintermediaries.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10

Administrative Stuff

▸ HW 4 is due next week.

▸ Final is on Dec. 18.

Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 10