managerial entrenchment, equity payout and capital structure · ager conflicts over risk level and...

15
Managerial entrenchment, equity payout and capital structure Hao Wang * School of Economics and Management, Tsinghua University, China article info Article history: Received 15 September 2009 Accepted 12 July 2010 Available online 24 July 2010 JEL classification: G32 G33 G35 Keywords: Managerial entrenchment Equity payout Capital structure Bivariate lattice model Security valuation abstract I develop a contingent claims model to examine the impacts of managerial entrenchment on capital structure and security valuation. The analysis shows that managers’ self-interested leverage choices devi- ate significantly from the optimal leverages that maximize firm values, partially explaining the subopti- mal leverage ratios observed empirically (Graham, 2000). Both the extent and sensitivity of the deviations are affected by firm characteristics, debt features and default solutions. The shareholder-man- ager conflicts over risk level and cash payout vary dynamically with a firm’s financial health. Managerial entrenchment does not mitigate the agency problems of debt since managers’ discretionary decisions on milking properties or asset substitution could be driven by incentives to increase their own utility. Ó 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction Since the seminal work of Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton (1974), contingent claims models on the valuation of corporate securities have been used extensively to examine capital structure choice quantitatively. However, this literature has, by and large, ignored a central problem in corporate governance, which is the misalignment of the incentives of managers and shareholders (see Jensen and Meckling (1976), Grossman and Hart (1982) and Jensen (1986), among others). In this paper, I develop a contingent claims model to bridge the two lines of literature to examine in what sense and to what extent managerial entrenchment influence firm policies and security valuation. I consider that partially entrenched managers pursue maximal rent extraction rather than optimal firm value. Shareholders’ lim- ited capability to discipline managers both incentivizes and restricts on managerial value expropriation. The model emphasizes the role managerial agency issues play in determining capital structure and equity payout. In particular, entrenched managers choose leverage not only to minimize bankruptcy risk but also to avoid being removed. As a result, managers assume a minimal amount of debt to deter shareholders from dismissing them. The model allows for quantitative comparisons between mana- gerial leverages and optimal leverages. I show that managers’ self- interested leverage choices deviate significantly from those maxi- mizing firm values. Consistent with the empirical findings in Berger et al. (1997), the stronger the entrenchment of managers, the lower the leverages that they tend to choose. The evidence also supports the notion that entrenchment motives could encourage managers to increase leverage beyond the optimal level to inflate their power against takeover (Harris and Raviv, 1989; Stulz, 1988). The analysis highlights the important role that corporate governance plays on capital structure, suggesting that firms with low leverages but high levels of managerial entrenchment may lift their values by restrict- ing managerial entrenchment power by improving board control (Rosenstein and Wyatt, 1990; Yermack, 1996; Faleye, 2009) and shareholder monitoring (Gillan and Starks, 2000). The deviations of managerial leverages from optimal leverages are significantly affected by firm characteristics, debt features and default solutions. In particular, managerial leverage deviations increase with a firm’s cash payout and risk level. This suggests that in cross-section, small firms are more prone to the negative influ- ence of managerial entrenchment. Issuing debts of long maturities with high coupon rates generates relatively high managerial lever- ages. I present important evidence that when a firm and its credi- tors have equal bargaining strength in default negotiations, the managerial leverages and firm values are optimized. 1 Shared 0378-4266/$ - see front matter Ó 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2010.07.018 * Tel.: +86 10 6279 7482; fax: +86 10 6278 4554. E-mail address: [email protected] 1 Fan and Sundaresan (2000) and Broadie et al. (2007) find that the ex ante firm value is maximized when a firm’s creditors possess the strongest ex post bargaining strength against the firm in default renegotiations when managerial agency issues are ignored. Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Banking & Finance journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf

Upload: duongtram

Post on 29-May-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Banking & Finance

journal homepage: www.elsevier .com/locate / jbf

Managerial entrenchment, equity payout and capital structure

Hao Wang *

School of Economics and Management, Tsinghua University, China

a r t i c l e i n f o

Article history:Received 15 September 2009Accepted 12 July 2010Available online 24 July 2010

JEL classification:G32G33G35

Keywords:Managerial entrenchmentEquity payoutCapital structureBivariate lattice modelSecurity valuation

0378-4266/$ - see front matter � 2010 Elsevier B.V. Adoi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2010.07.018

* Tel.: +86 10 6279 7482; fax: +86 10 6278 4554.E-mail address: [email protected]

a b s t r a c t

I develop a contingent claims model to examine the impacts of managerial entrenchment on capitalstructure and security valuation. The analysis shows that managers’ self-interested leverage choices devi-ate significantly from the optimal leverages that maximize firm values, partially explaining the subopti-mal leverage ratios observed empirically (Graham, 2000). Both the extent and sensitivity of thedeviations are affected by firm characteristics, debt features and default solutions. The shareholder-man-ager conflicts over risk level and cash payout vary dynamically with a firm’s financial health. Managerialentrenchment does not mitigate the agency problems of debt since managers’ discretionary decisions onmilking properties or asset substitution could be driven by incentives to increase their own utility.

� 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction interested leverage choices deviate significantly from those maxi-

Since the seminal work of Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton(1974), contingent claims models on the valuation of corporatesecurities have been used extensively to examine capital structurechoice quantitatively. However, this literature has, by and large,ignored a central problem in corporate governance, which is themisalignment of the incentives of managers and shareholders(see Jensen and Meckling (1976), Grossman and Hart (1982) andJensen (1986), among others). In this paper, I develop a contingentclaims model to bridge the two lines of literature to examine inwhat sense and to what extent managerial entrenchment influencefirm policies and security valuation.

I consider that partially entrenched managers pursue maximalrent extraction rather than optimal firm value. Shareholders’ lim-ited capability to discipline managers both incentivizes andrestricts on managerial value expropriation. The model emphasizesthe role managerial agency issues play in determining capitalstructure and equity payout. In particular, entrenched managerschoose leverage not only to minimize bankruptcy risk but also toavoid being removed. As a result, managers assume a minimalamount of debt to deter shareholders from dismissing them.

The model allows for quantitative comparisons between mana-gerial leverages and optimal leverages. I show that managers’ self-

ll rights reserved.

mizing firm values. Consistent with the empirical findings in Bergeret al. (1997), the stronger the entrenchment of managers, the lowerthe leverages that they tend to choose. The evidence also supportsthe notion that entrenchment motives could encourage managersto increase leverage beyond the optimal level to inflate their poweragainst takeover (Harris and Raviv, 1989; Stulz, 1988). The analysishighlights the important role that corporate governance plays oncapital structure, suggesting that firms with low leverages but highlevels of managerial entrenchment may lift their values by restrict-ing managerial entrenchment power by improving board control(Rosenstein and Wyatt, 1990; Yermack, 1996; Faleye, 2009) andshareholder monitoring (Gillan and Starks, 2000).

The deviations of managerial leverages from optimal leveragesare significantly affected by firm characteristics, debt featuresand default solutions. In particular, managerial leverage deviationsincrease with a firm’s cash payout and risk level. This suggests thatin cross-section, small firms are more prone to the negative influ-ence of managerial entrenchment. Issuing debts of long maturitieswith high coupon rates generates relatively high managerial lever-ages. I present important evidence that when a firm and its credi-tors have equal bargaining strength in default negotiations, themanagerial leverages and firm values are optimized.1 Shared

1 Fan and Sundaresan (2000) and Broadie et al. (2007) find that the ex ante firmalue is maximized when a firm’s creditors possess the strongest ex post bargainingrength against the firm in default renegotiations when managerial agency issues are

vst

ignored.

H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50 37

bargaining power optimally trades off reducing debt costs and liftingshareholders’ capability to discipline managers. Those results yieldapplicable implications for corporate governance and bankruptcyprocess design.

I find that self-interested managers’ preferences regarding oper-ating cash flow and risk level that influence equity payout andfinancing policies change dynamically with a firm’s financialhealth. When a firm is financially healthy, self-interested manag-ers’ preferences for low cash payout and low risk tally with thoseof debtholders, rather than those of shareholders. However, theinterests of managers and shareholders naturally align as a firmapproaches distress. Both managers and shareholders prefer highrisk and high cash payout to increase their own wealth at theexpense of debtholders. Managerial entrenchment does not miti-gate the agency problems of debt, since managerial decisions onmilking properties and asset substitution could be driven by man-agers’ incentives to increase their own utility as well as byattempting to shift wealth from debtholders to shareholders.

From the modeling perspective, this paper stems from the con-tingent claims literature that starts with Black and Scholes (1973)and Merton (1974).2 With a few recent exceptions, those modelsassume that managers make decisions in the best interest of share-holders. My modeling of the interacted managerial agency andshareholder control dynamics is in the same spirit as that of Zwiebel(1996) and Myers (2000). Zwiebel designs a dynamic model in whichself-interested managers voluntarily take on debt to restrict empire-building and thereby prevent takeovers. Myers (2000) valuatesoutside equity by examining the strategic interactions betweenmanagers and shareholders over dividend payments. This paper ex-tends their work by considering asset value uncertainties, tax bene-fits, financial distress and default solutions in a valuation framework.

Anderson and Sundaresan (1996) develop a binomial model tostudy debt security design and capital structure design in the pres-ence of the debtholder–shareholder conflicts. My model moves onestep further to incorporate managerial agency problems and exam-ine jointly the two types of agency issues. In such a setting, share-holders, managers and debtholders all make rational decisions inNash equilibrium to maximize their own interests. Among the con-tingent claims models, Fan and Sundaresan (2000) point out theinadequacy of treating equity payouts as passive residual cashflows. They proxy dividends with periodical asset payouts to inves-tigate the impacts of dividend policy on security valuation. Morel-lec (2004) examines the manager-shareholder conflicts on leveragefocusing on managerial incentives for over-investment. Lambrechtand Myers (2007) develop a real-option model to examine theinfluence of managerial agency issues on investment and disin-vestment with an emphasis on the influence of managerial per-sonal wealth restriction combined with external takeover threat.Recently, Morellec and Smith (2007) and Morellec et al. (2008)study managerial agency conflicts with respect to risk manage-ment and capital structure.

To the best of my knowledge, this is the first paper studyingmanagerial agency issues and security valuation with finite debtmaturity, endogenous payout policy, and endogenous financingpolicy. It facilitates the generation of numerous new resultsregarding corporate policies and managerial entrenchment. Thebinomial lattice model developed combines intuitive simplicitywith powerful flexibility to examine complex and interacted cor-

2 Among others, Leland (1994) endogenizes default barrier and derives ananalytical solution with perpetual debt. Leland and Toft (1996) extend the Lelandmodel to allow for non-perpetual debt. Anderson and Sundaresan (1996) and Fan andSundaresan (2000) investigate the implications of strategic default. Leland (1998) andEricsson (2000) study the effects of asset substitution and hedging policies. Francoisand Morellec (2004) and Broadie et al. (2007) examine the impact of defaulprocedures, and Morellec (2004) gauges the manager-shareholder conflicts throughmanagerial incentives for over-investment.

3 This assumption creates an upper boundary for the agency cost of equity. Theinterests of shareholders and managers could be better aligned by changingmanagers’ remuneration scheme, such as stock option plans (King and Santor2008; Margaritis and Psilaki, 2009). That constitutes an interesting avenue in whichto extend this model in future research, but will not change the basic conclusions inthis paper.

4 Upon no liquidation, the firm continues its operation after retiring debt at itsmaturity. The binomial process ends there for valuation purpose only.

t

porate issues in an equilibrium setting. It allows security valuationto take into account the time-varying and economic state depen-dent interactions of debt and equity agency issues without impos-ing restrictive assumptions. I emphasize analysing the extent towhich the deviations between managerial leverages and optionalleverages are influenced by firm and debt characteristics to provideapplicable implications for corporate governance and bankruptcyprocess design.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 describesthe base case model without strategic default. Comparative staticanalyses are carried out in Section 3. Section 4 examines manage-rial leverages and optimal leverages. Section 5 concludes.

2. The base case model

I introduce the base case model in which strategic default anddebt renegotiations are ruled out. The purpose is to simplify themodel setup and to separate the impacts of managerial agencyissues on corporate policies and security valuation from those ofdebt agency problems. Table 1 summarizes the notations used inthis paper.

2.1. Model setup

Consider a firm of three parties: managers, shareholders anddebtholders. Self-interested and partially entrenched managersoperate the firm and derive private rents as they are in control.To completely separate managers’ interest from that of sharehold-ers, I assume managers hold zero equity of the firm.3 Under therisk-neutral measure Q, the unlevered firm asset value process isexpressed as

dVt

Vt¼ ðr � bÞdt þ rdxt; ð1Þ

where r denotes the risk-free rate, b denotes the operating cashpayout rate, and r denotes the asset return volatility.

There is no information asymmetry in the model, i.e., all threeparties are able to observe the evolution of the firm asset valuecontinuously. The firm raises capital by issuing a coupon-bearingbond that matures at time T. The bond principal and coupon rateare denoted by P and c, respectively. Equity has no prespecifiedmaturity. In valuation, the firm asset value Vt follows a discretebinomial process that ends at debt maturity.4 In the lattice, the as-set value Vt moves either up to uVt with a risk-neutral probability ofp or down to dVt with a risk-neutral probability of 1 � p at time t + 1.The up-move multiple u = er, the down-move multiple d = 1/u = e�r,and the probability of up-move p = (e(r�b)t � d)/(u � d). On eachnode, the firm asset generates an operating cash flow of bVt to payinterest and dividend at t.

The shareholders are able to dismiss the managers and takecontrol at any time. However the takeover will result in an assetloss of /Vt as the firm loses its managerial human capital. The valueof / represents managerial entrenchment power that is primarilydetermined by the managers’ competency and is influenced bycorporate governance. The debtholders are entitled to take overand liquidate the firm if the firm defaults. Upon liquidation, thefirm suffers an unrecoverable asset loss of jVt on top of losing

,

Table 1Notation. This table reports the parameters used in the paper and their benchmarkvalues for the numerical examples.

Notation Definition Benchmarkvalue

The setupV0 Initial unlevered firm asset value 100r Risk-free interest rate 5%b Operating cash flow 2%s Corporate tax rate 20%j Liquidation costs 40%r Asset return volatility 30%T Debt maturity (years) 7h Debtholders’ bargaining power (strategic

default)50%

P Debt principal 60c Coupon rate 6%/ Managerial entrenchment power 2%

ValuationS(Vt) Equity valueB(Vt) Debt valueM(Vt) Managerial rentSM(Vt) Sum of equity value and managerial rentVon(Vt) Ongoing firm value (strategic default)

SðVft Þ Reservation equity value

Vb Default barrier

Valuation without managers

SðVfhÞ Equity value

BðVfhÞ Debt value

VonðVfhÞ Ongoing firm value (strategic default)

38 H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50

managerial human capital /Vt. I will introduce the default condi-tions in the next subsection.

As illustrated in Fig. 1, on each node at time t in the valuationlattice, we observe the following actions:

1. The managers decide whether to pay interest, cP, (interest plusprincipal, (1 + c)P) to the debtholders at time t (T). The manag-ers will not fulfill the debt obligation if they expect the firm todefault at the time.

2. The debtholders will pocket the payment if it satisfies the debtcontract. Otherwise, they take over and liquidate the firmimmediately. Upon liquidation, the debtholders have priorityover the shareholders in claiming the remaining assets of thefirm. Game over.

3. Upon no default, the managers make a dividend offer to theshareholders.

4. If the shareholders are satisfied with the dividend offer, theyaccept the payment and allow the managers to stay in controltill next time t + 1. If they reject the dividend offer, they dismissthe managers and take control.5

All three parties are equally and completely informed and havehomogeneous expectations of what will happen at time t.

2.2. Valuation

The values of debt, equity and managerial rent are denoted byB(Vt), S(Vt) and M(Vt), respectively. The valuation is carried outusing the backward induction method (Cox et al., 1979), and startswith the nodes at debt maturity time T. Equilibrium is obtainedunder the assumption that all three parties act rationally in theirown best interests.

5 Ferris et al. (2009) present evidence that shareholders force dividend payout frommanagers.

2.2.1. At debt maturityAt debt maturity T, the debtholders are entitled to receive the

last coupon cP plus debt principal P. If there is no strategic default,the managers will repay the debtholders the contracted amount ifassets are sufficient to fulfill the debt obligation (VT P (1 + c)P).Otherwise, the firm defaults and is liquidated. Upon liquidation,the debtholders receive the recovered asset value, (1 � j � /)VT.The value of debt at time T is

BðVTÞ ¼ð1þ cÞP; if VT P ð1þ cÞP;1� j� /ð ÞVT ; if VT < ð1þ cÞP:

�ð2Þ

The sum of equity value and managerial rent, denoted by SM, attime T is

SMðVTÞ ¼VT � BðVTÞ þ scP; if VT P ð1þ cÞP;0; if VT < ð1þ cÞP:

�ð3Þ

where s denotes the corporate tax rate and scP represents the taxshield on interest.

Following Myers (2000), I assume that the firm continues itsoperation after time T if there is no default. Then managerial hu-man capital remains valuable to the firm, and dismissing the man-agers will incur an asset loss of /VT. The managers therefore matchtheir offered equity value S(VT) with what the shareholders are ableto obtain if they take over, max(SM(VT) � /VT,0). In equilibrium,the shareholders accept the proposed offer.6 The value of equityat time T is expressed as

SðVTÞ ¼max SMðVTÞ � /VT ;0ð Þ; if VT P ð1þ cÞP;0; if VT < ð1þ cÞP:

�ð4Þ

Upon no default, the managers retain the rest of the firm’s as-sets as their private rent. Upon default, the managers receive noth-ing. The value of managerial rent at time T is

MðVTÞ ¼SMðVTÞ � SðVTÞ; if VT P ð1þ cÞP;0; if VT < ð1þ cÞP:

�ð5Þ

2.2.2. At time t prior to debt maturityThe valuation at each time t prior to debt maturity is analogous

to the valuation at debt maturity, except that it takes into accountthe expected continuation values of securities. To streamline thepresentation, I first discuss how to value B(Vt), S(Vt) and M(Vt) ifdefault does not occur at time t. The introduction of default condi-tions and valuation in default states will follow.

2.2.2.1. Valuation in non-default states. The non-default value ofdebt at time t equals the coupon plus the expected continuationvalue of debt, which is computed by discounting the debt valueson two adjacent nodes at time t + 1 under the risk-neutralprobability measure Q. The value of debt is expressed as

BðVtÞ ¼ cP þ e�rt pB uVtð Þ þ ð1� pÞBðdVtÞð Þ: ð6Þ

The non-default value of SM(Vt) equals the ex-coupon cash flowbVt � (1 � s)cP plus the expected continuation value of SM(Vt) de-rived under the risk-neutral probability measure Q. It is expressedas

SMðVtÞ ¼ bVt � ð1� sÞcP þ e�rt pSM uVtð Þ þ ð1� pÞSMðdVtÞð Þ: ð7Þ

The managers are supposed to pay out all ex-coupon cash flowto the shareholders as dividends. If so the equity value will equalthe ex-coupon cash flow plus the expected continuation value ofequity. The shareholders will take over if the managers fail to

6 The managers can always sweeten the dividend offer to increase S(VT) slightlybove SM(VT) � /VT to ensure that the shareholders will favor accepting the dividendffer.

ao

Fig. 1. Interactions on a node at time t in the base case model. This figure illustrates the interactions among managers, debtholders and shareholders on a node at time t. Afterfirm asset value Vt is realized, the managers decide whether to pay interest to the debtholders. The managers will not fulfill the debt obligation if they expect the firm todefault at the time. The debtholders will pocket the payment if it satisfies the debt contract. Otherwise, they take over and liquidate the firm immediately. Upon liquidation,the debtholders have priority over the shareholders in claiming the remaining assets of the firm. Game over. Upon no default, the managers make a dividend offer to theshareholders. If the shareholders are satisfied with the dividend offer, they accept the payment and allow the managers to stay in control till next time t + 1. If they reject thedividend offer, they dismiss the managers and take control.

H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50 39

pay out a satisfactory amount of dividend. Then the shareholdersend up with the reservation equity value SðVf

t Þ, where Vft denotes

the asset value after the managers are removed. To maximize theirrent value, the managers attempt to pay out the minimal amountof dividend without triggering the termination of their contract.The non-default value of equity at time t equals the lower of thereservation equity value or the ex-coupon cash flow plus the ex-pected continuation equity value. And SðVf

t Þ is lower than the lattersince the firm asset value decreases after the managers are dis-missed. We take SðVf

t Þ as given for the time being. I will describehow to compute SðVf

t Þ in the next subsection. In equilibrium, themanagers make a dividend offer that equates the equity value tothe reservation equity value. The value of equity is expressed as

SðVtÞ ¼min bVt � ð1� sÞcP þ e�rt pS uVtð Þð�

þ ð1� pÞSðdVtÞÞ; S Vft

� ��¼ S Vf

t

� �: ð8Þ

The amount of equity payout varies with asset value Vt. In practice,firms tend to smooth out their cash dividends and to repurchasetheir own shares when they perform well. We could regard theequity payments in this model as a combination of share repur-chases and cash dividends. So they change with a firm’s perfor-mance over time.

The managers retain the rest of the cash flow for their privaterent. The non-default value of managerial rent is expressed as

MðVtÞ ¼ SMðVtÞ � SðVtÞ: ð9Þ

2.2.2.2. Default conditions and valuation in default states. The firmbecomes financially distressed when the ex-coupon cash flow at

time t is negative (bVt � (1 � s)cP < 0), i.e., the firm’s asset valuefalls too low to generate sufficient operating cash flow to pay inter-est. The managers have an incentive to delay the termination of thefirm’s operation since they will lose their firm-specific human cap-ital in liquidation (Lambrecht and Myers, 2007). The shareholderswill raise new capital to pay interest to keep the firm alive as longas they believe saving the firm is worthwhile. The firm defaultswhen the value of equity drops to or below zero (S(Vt) 6 0), wherethe shareholders are no longer interested in keeping the financiallytroubled firm alive. The endogenous default conditions are in factthe same as in Leland (1994), ignoring more realistic but complexdefault and liquidation solutions presented in Broadie et al. (2007).However, this simplification will not change the main implicationsdelivered by the model.

Upon liquidation, the debtholders claim the lower one of theprincipal or the recovered asset value, Bl(Vt) = min (P, (1 � j � /)Vt) where the superscript l denotes liquidation. Given that the firmwill only default when the equity value falls to or below zero, thevalues of equity and managerial rent are 0. Combining the formulasin both non-default and default states, the valuations of debt, equi-ty and managerial rent at time t are summarized as below

BðVtÞ ¼cP þ e�rt pB uVtð Þ þ ð1� pÞB dVtð Þð Þ; if SðVtÞ > 0;

min 1� j� /ð ÞVt ; Pð Þ; if SðVtÞ 6 0;

(ð10Þ

SðVtÞ ¼S Vf

t

� �; if SðVtÞ > 0;

0; if SðVtÞ 6 0;

8<: ð11Þ

MðVtÞ ¼SMðVtÞ � SðVtÞ; if SðVtÞ > 0;

0; if SðVtÞ 6 0:

(ð12Þ

40 H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50

Following the standard valuation method of binomial lattice(Cox et al., 1979), the present values of debt, equity and managerialrent are computed by repeating the valuation at each time t back-ward along the binomial lattice to its starting node at time 0.

2.2.3. Computing reservation equity value SðVft Þ

The reservation equity value SðVft Þ represents the hypothetical

equity value if the shareholders dismiss the managers at time t.For valuation, I assume the shareholders will operate the firm afterthe takeover until debt maturity or default. An alternative way tointerpret this assumption is that the best available managers inthe employment market possess zero entrenchment power. Sup-pose the shareholders take over at time t, and the asset value dropsfrom Vt to (1 � /)Vt, reflecting the loss of managerial human capi-tal. Under the risk-neutral measure Q, the unlevered firm asset va-lue process is expressed as

dVft

Vft

¼ ðr � bÞdt þ rdxt ; ð13Þ

where Vft denotes the unlevered firm asset value after dismissing

the managers. In discrete time, Vft follows a ‘‘new” subgame bino-

mial lattice starting on the node of Vt and ending at debt maturitytime T.

To avoid confusion, I use another subscript h to denote time forthis subgame lattice. The firm-specific up-move multiple u, down-move multiple d, and the risk-neutral probability of up-move p re-main unchanged. Firm asset generates a cash flow of bVf

h at eachtime h except on the starting node Vf

t because cash flow bVt has al-ready realized before the takeover. The valuation of equity in thesubgame lattice is analogous to that of SM(Vt) in the original lattice.

At debt maturity time T, the debtholders are repaid with thecontracted amount (1 + c)P if the firm is able to honor its debt con-tract. Otherwise, the debtholders claim the recovered asset valueð1� jÞVf

T after liquidation. The value of debt at time T is expressedas

B VfT

� �¼

ð1þ cÞP; if VfT P ð1þ cÞP;

1� jð ÞVfT ; if Vf

T < ð1þ cÞP:

(ð14Þ

The value of equity equals the asset value minus the value of debtupon no default and zero upon default:

S VfT

� �¼

VfT � B Vf

T

� �þ scP; if Vf

T P ð1þ cÞP;

0; if VfT < ð1þ cÞP:

8<: ð15Þ

The default conditions are the same as those in the originalmodel, i.e., when the value of equity falls to/below zeroðSðVf

hÞ 6 0Þ, the shareholders are no longer interested in contribut-ing new capital to bail out the financially troubled firm. On eachnode at time h prior to debt maturity, the value of debt in non-default states equals the coupon received at time h plus theexpected continuation value of debt. Upon default, the debtholdersreceive the lower one of the principal or the recovery value. Thevalue of debt at time h is expressed as

B Vfh

� �¼

cP þ e�rt pB uVfh

� �þ ð1� pÞB dVf

h

� �� �; if S Vf

h

� �> 0;

min ð1� jÞVfh; P

� �; if S Vf

h

� �6 0:

8><>:

ð16Þ

7 Default barrier changes dynamically in binomial lattice model with debt of finiteaturity (Broadie et al., 2007). I choose to report the default barrier as the first time

efault occurs in the lattice. The default barrier provides us with at least some idea ofe impacts of entrenchment on firm default probability.

The value of equity equals the ex-coupon cash flow at time h plusthe expected continuation value of equity in non-default states.The default value of equity is 0 in default states. Then we have

S Vfh

� �¼

bVfh � ð1� sÞcP þ e�rt pS uVf

h

� ��þð1� pÞS dVf

h

� ��; if S Vf

h

� �> 0;

0; if S Vfh

� �6 0:

8>>>><>>>>:

ð17Þ

The reservation equity value, S(Vt), is computed by repeatingthe valuation at each time h backward along the subgame latticetill time t. Note that, in equilibrium, the managers will never be re-moved at time t because they can always offer a dividend thatmakes the equity value equal to or slightly higher than the reserva-tion equity value.

3. Comparative statics

I apply the model introduced in the previous section to examinethe impacts of managerial entrenchment on corporate policies andsecurity valuation. The benchmark parameter values are intro-duced in Table 1. I define firm value as the sum of the values ofdebt and equity. Managers possess no entrenchment power when/ = 0.

Table 2 shows that the firm and equity values decrease mono-tonically from 100.93 and 53.55 to 90.20 and 44.28, respectively,as / increases from 0% to 10%. Higher entrenchment power allowsmanagers to extract more value from a firm, i.e., the value of man-agerial rent increases from 0 to 9.20 as managers become more en-trenched. Their selfish actions increase the likelihood of defaultand in turn reduce firm values. This is evidenced by the factthat debt current yield spread increases from 133.25 bps to153.35 bps as / increases. Default barrier, Vb, increases from25.92 to 28.37, confirming that the manager-shareholder conflictsincrease default probability.7 The results suggest that credit riskmodels should take managerial agency issues into consideration(Liao et al., 2009).

Managerial entrenchment reduces not only firm value, but alsooverall economic efficiency. The sum of firm value and managerialrent decreases from 100.93 to 99.40 as managers become more en-trenched. The results suggest that firms with better corporate gov-ernance enjoy relatively higher firm and security values becausecorporate governance helps to restrict managerial entrenchment.This benefits overall social welfare as well.

3.1. Impacts of firm characteristics

Table 3 reports the influence of firm risk level, proxied by assetreturn volatility r, on the relationship between managerialentrenchment and security valuation. Consistent with the findingsin previous research, firm/debt values decrease with business risklevel, whereas equity value increases. Equity value decreases lesswith managerial entrenchment as a firm business risk level in-creases. The equity value decreases by 9.99 as / increases from0% to 10% when r equals 0.1, but decreases by 9.29 when r equals0.9. The negative influence of entrenchment on equity value is mit-igated by the increase in equity value thanks to increased risk level.As / increases from 0% to 10%, debt yield spread increases by0.34 bps and 58.85 bps when r equals 0.1 and 0.9, respectively.The influence of managerial entrenchment on default risk is mag-nified by firm underlying risk level. In cross-section, young andsmall firms tend to have higher risk than mature and large firms,so the security valuations of young and small firms are more

mdth

Table 3The influence of firm risk on the impacts of managerial entrenchment. This table reports the influence of firm risk, r, on the relationships between managerial entrenchment andthe values of firm, equity and managerial rent, debt credit spread, and default barrier. The debt credit spread is defined as current yield minus risk-free rate (cP/B � r). The defaultbarrier is the asset value at which first time default occurs in the lattice.

r / Firm value Debt spread Equity Managerial rent Default barrier

0.1 0.00 103.54 66.40 50.57 0.00 43.170.05 98.53 66.50 45.57 5.00 45.380.10 93.51 66.74 40.58 9.99 47.71

0.3 0.00 100.93 133.25 53.55 0.00 25.920.05 95.67 141.40 48.89 4.65 26.710.10 90.20 153.35 44.28 9.20 28.37

0.5 0.00 99.39 286.51 61.25 0.00 14.960.05 94.08 303.17 56.73 4.50 15.720.10 88.91 318.42 52.26 8.94 16.53

0.7 0.00 99.40 499.97 69.40 0.00 9.260.05 94.26 519.36 64.83 4.56 9.260.10 89.00 545.49 60.31 9.05 9.93

0.9 0.00 99.85 784.21 76.49 0.00 5.610.05 94.74 809.39 71.83 4.66 6.140.10 89.54 843.06 67.20 9.26 6.72

Table 2The impacts of managerial entrenchment on security valuations. This table reports the impacts of managerial entrenchment on firm value, debt credit spread, equity value anddefault barrier. The debt credit spread is defined as current yield minus the risk-free rate, cP/B � r. Since default barrier changes dynamically in a binomial lattice model with debtof finite maturity (Broadie et al., 2007), I report the default barrier as the asset value at which first time default occurs in the lattice. The economic efficiency is measured as thesum of firm value and managerial rent.

Entrenchment/

Firm valueS + B

Debt spreadcP/B � r (bps)

EquityS

Managerial rentM

Economic efficiencyS + B + M

Default barrierVb

0 101.29 132.59 53.87 0.00 101.29 25.160.005 98.28 132.94 50.88 2.98 101.27 25.920.01 95.39 133.31 48.02 5.85 101.24 26.710.015 92.61 133.73 45.27 8.60 101.21 27.530.02 89.94 134.14 42.64 11.23 101.17 28.370.025 87.39 134.54 40.11 13.75 101.14 29.230.03 84.94 135.03 37.69 16.16 101.10 30.120.035 82.57 135.71 35.38 18.46 101.03 31.040.04 80.35 135.92 33.17 20.67 101.02 31.980.045 78.17 136.72 31.06 22.76 100.94 32.960.05 76.14 137.02 29.04 24.77 100.91 33.96

H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50 41

influenced by managerial entrenchment than those of large andmature firms.

The relationship between managerial rent value and firm riskappears to be non-linear. For instance, when / = 10%, managerialrent value decreases from 9.99 to 8.94 as r increases from 0.1 to0.5, then reverts to increase to 9.26 as r further increases to 0.9.The evidence implies that managers should be able to extract morerent from either large and mature firms that tend to have low risklevels or from start-ups that tend to have volatile earnings.

Table 4 shows how the impact of managerial entrenchment onsecurity valuation is affected by capital structure. Debt yieldspreads become more sensitive to the changes in entrenchmentpower the further a firm levers. They increase by 4.75 bps and83.75 bps at P/V0 = 25% and 100%, respectively, when / increasesfrom 0% to 10%. In contrast, equity value becomes less sensitiveto the changes in managerial entrenchment as leverage increases,which is partially explained by the reduced ex-interest cash flowsavailable for managerial rent extraction. Overall, the values offirms of high leverage ratios appear less affected by managerialentrenchment. This is supported by the negative relationshipbetween managerial rent and leverage ratio. For / = 10%, manage-rial rent decreases from 10.00 to 6.30 monotonically as P/V0

increases from 0% to 100%. This finding is consistent with the

well-documented role of debt as a disciplinary tool to restrict man-agerial value expropriation. It further predicts that selfish manag-ers would like to issue zero debt to optimize their own interest inthe absence of internal/external takeover threats (Zwiebel, 1996). Iwill examine managerial financing choices in the absence/presenceof a shareholder takeover threat in the managerial capital structuresection below.

3.2. Impacts of debt features

Table 5 shows that high coupon rates increase firm value but re-duce managerial rent value. When / = 10%, managerial rent valuedrops from 9.25 to 9.03 as the coupon rate increases from 5% to9%. The evidence supports the notion that debt could be used to re-duce managerial value expropriation by paying out free cash flows.A higher coupon rate implies a greater likelihood of default and ahigher bond yield spread. Managerial entrenchment magnifiesthe positive relationship between debt yield spread and couponrate. The debt yield spread difference between c = 5% and 9% is257 bps for / = 0, and increases to 268 bps for / = 10%.

As illustrated in Table 6, the relationship between managerialrent value and debt maturity is subject to leverage ratio. For alow leverage ratio (P/V0 = 20%), the managerial rent value

Table 4The influence of leverage on the impacts of managerial entrenchment. This table reports the influence of leverage, proxied by the ratio of debt principal over the initial asset value(P/V0), on the relationships between managerial entrenchment and the values of firm, equity and managerial rent, debt credit spread, and default barrier. The debt credit spread isdefined as current yield minus risk-free rate (cP/B � r). The default barrier is the asset value at which first time default occurs in the lattice.

Leverage P/V0 (%) / Firm value Debt spread Equity Managerial rent Default barrier

0 0.00 100.00 NaN 100.00 0.00 0.000.05 95.00 NaN 95.00 5.00 0.000.10 90.00 NaN 90.00 10.00 0.00

25 0.00 101.46 78.87 75.54 0.00 13.000.05 96.42 80.69 70.59 4.96 13.400.10 91.34 83.62 65.64 9.89 14.23

50 0.00 100.93 133.25 53.55 0.00 25.920.05 95.67 141.40 48.89 4.65 26.710.10 90.20 153.35 44.28 9.20 28.37

75 0.00 97.96 221.82 35.62 0.00 38.290.05 92.25 240.86 31.51 4.07 40.660.10 86.19 266.84 27.51 7.93 43.17

100 0.00 93.07 341.42 21.76 0.00 51.690.05 86.74 377.51 18.36 3.33 53.260.10 80.00 424.99 15.13 6.30 56.55

Table 5The influence of coupon rate on the impacts of managerial entrenchment. This table reports the influence of debt coupon rate on the relationships between managerialentrenchment and the values of firm, equity and managerial rent, debt credit spread, and default barrier. The debt credit spread is defined as current yield minus risk-free rate (cP/B � r). The default barrier is the asset value at which first time default occurs in the lattice.

Coupon rate (%) / Firm value Debt spread Equity Managerial rent Default barrier

5 0.00 100.50 59.45 55.81 0.00 22.990.05 95.28 66.39 51.14 4.67 24.410.10 89.86 76.74 46.51 9.25 25.92

6 0.00 100.93 133.25 53.55 0.00 25.920.05 95.67 141.40 48.89 4.65 26.710.10 90.20 153.35 44.28 9.20 28.37

7 0.00 101.32 199.75 51.30 0.00 28.370.05 96.00 209.39 46.66 4.63 29.230.10 90.51 222.62 42.08 9.15 31.04

8 0.00 101.66 260.68 49.08 0.00 30.120.05 96.32 271.33 44.46 4.60 31.980.10 90.78 286.16 39.90 9.10 33.96

9 0.00 101.99 316.39 46.87 0.00 32.960.05 96.58 328.65 42.27 4.57 33.960.10 90.99 345.10 37.74 9.03 36.06

Table 6The influence of debt maturity on the impacts of managerial entrenchment. This table reports the influence of debt maturity on the relationships between managerialentrenchment and the values of firm, equity and managerial rent, debt credit spread, and default barrier. The debt credit spread is defined as current yield minus risk-free rate (cP/B � r). The default barrier is the asset value at which first time default occurs in the lattice.

Leverage P/V0 (%) Debt maturity / Firm value Debt spread Equity Managerial rent Default barrier

20 5 0.00 101.01 76.80 80.20 0.00 10.860.05 96.00 77.27 75.21 4.99 11.190.10 90.98 78.16 70.22 9.98 11.88

10 0.00 101.64 69.08 80.56 0.00 9.930.05 96.62 70.73 75.59 4.97 10.540.10 91.56 73.20 70.63 9.92 10.86

20 0.00 102.55 62.31 81.21 0.00 9.350.05 97.50 64.99 76.26 4.94 9.930.10 92.43 68.42 71.32 9.87 10.54

80 5 0.00 95.90 235.20 30.61 0.00 43.170.05 90.07 257.14 26.67 3.90 44.490.10 83.77 288.18 22.87 7.53 47.24

10 0.00 98.81 246.16 34.48 0.00 39.460.05 92.99 267.49 30.45 3.99 41.900.10 86.89 295.19 26.52 7.77 43.17

20 0.00 102.27 241.24 37.51 0.00 37.160.05 96.43 261.16 33.37 4.11 39.460.10 90.37 286.24 29.32 8.02 41.90

42 H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50

H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50 43

decreases from 9.98 to 9.87 as debt maturity increases from 5 to20 years for / = 10%. This could be explained by the model assump-tion that managers have full bargaining strength against share-holders at debt maturity. The more frequently that managerscould exploit shareholders for a rent value that matches theirhuman capital, the higher their rent values. However, for a highleverage ratio (P/V0 = 80%), the managerial rent value increasesfrom 7.53 to 8.02 as debt maturity increases from 5 to 20 yearsfor / = 10%. The evidence indicates that, when managers’ exploita-tion at debt maturity is less of an issue, debt of short maturity ismore effective in terms of restricting managerial entrenchment.In this model, debt maturity could be viewed alternatively as thetenure of managers as well. The longer the debt maturity, the long-er managers could stay in control. And the results suggest that torestrict managerial entrenchment, a firm should avoid keepingthe same management team in control for too long.

00.2

0.40.6

0.81

0.1

0.20.3

0.40.5

88

90

92

94

96

98

100

102

P/VSigma

00.2

0.40.6

0.81

0.10.2

0.30.4

0.5

88

90

92

94

96

98

100

102

P/VSigma

Firm

Val

ueFi

rm V

alue

Fig. 2. Firm, debt, equity and managerial rent values and firm risk. This figure plots the iproxied by the ratio of debt principal over the initial asset value (P/V0).

3.3. Shareholder-manager conflicts over risk and payout

Next I examine the manager-shareholder conflicts over riskchoice and payout level with a firm’s financial health. Fig. 2 illus-trates the impacts of risk level proxied by asset return volatilityr on the values of firm, debt, equity and managerial rent inthe presence of managerial entrenchment. Fig. 2(A) shows thatfirm value decreases with risk level except for extremely highdebt/asset ratios. The result echoes those of previous studies(Merton, 1974; Leland, 1998). Fig. 2(B) and (C) shows that debtvalues are negatively correlated to firm risk, whereas equity valuesrespond positively.

Fig. 2(D) indicates that when a firm is financially healthy with alow debt/asset ratio, the value of managerial rent decreases withrisk level. An increase in risk level leads to a higher likelihood ofdefault upon which managers lose their firm-specific human capi-

00.2

0.40.6

0.81 0.1

0.20.3

0.40.5

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

SigmaP/V

00.2

0.40.6

0.81

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

3

3.5

4

4.5

5

5.5

P/VSigma

Deb

t Val

ueM

anag

eria

l Ren

t

mpacts of firm risk, r, on firm, debt, equity and managerial rent values. Leverage is

44 H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50

tal. The results highlight the shareholder-manager conflict overrisk choice. For a financially healthy firm, shareholders would pre-fer investing in risky projects to boost equity value, but managersfavor safe projects for their own sake. This evidence contradicts thenotion that managers are more aligned to shareholders than todebtholders, i.e., managers’ preference on firm risk level tallieswith that of debtholders when a firm is financially healthy.

The value of managerial rent switches to increase with risk levelas the firm approaches bankruptcy. When the debt/asset ratio ishigh, say P/V = 95%, both the values of managerial rent and equityincrease with r, whereas the debt value decreases. This suggeststhat the relationship between managerial rent and risk levelchanges with a firm’s financial health. Managerial rent behaves likedebt when a firm is financially healthy but resembles equity whenthe firm is close to default where the asset substitution problembecomes economically significant. The preferences of shareholdersand managers over risk choice naturally align, suggesting that

00.2

0.40.6

0.81

0.030.04

0.050.06

0.070.08

0.09

88

90

92

94

96

98

P/VBeta

00.2

0.40.6

0.81 0.03

0.040.05

0.060.07

0.080.090

20

40

60

80

100

BetaP/V

Firm

Val

ueEq

uity

Val

ue

Fig. 3. Firm, debt, equity and managerial rent values and cash payout rate. This figure plorent values. Leverage is proxied by the ratio of debt principal over the initial asset valu

managerial entrenchment does not mitigate the asset substitutionproblem of debt. Asset substitution is conventionally explained asan attempt by managers to transfer wealth from debtholders toshareholders prior to default. My analysis, however, implies thatasset substitution benefits not only shareholders but also manag-ers at the expense of debtholders. Thus, managerial decision aboutasset substitution could be driven by self-interest as well.

Fig. 3 illustrates the impacts of operating cash payout on firm,debt, equity and managerial rent values in the presence of manage-rial entrenchment. Fig. 3(A) shows that the firm value respondsnegatively to cash payout rate b except when the debt/asset ratiois high. Fig. 3(B) and (C) plots that the value of debt (equity)decreases (increases) with payout rate, respectively. Fig. 3(D)shows that when a firm is in good financial health with a lowdebt/asset ratio, the value of managerial rent is negatively corre-lated with payout rate. Managers prefer retaining more money inthe firm to reduce the probability of default and to avoid losing

00.2

0.40.6

0.81

0.030.04

0.050.06

0.070.08

0.09

3.5

4

4.5

5

P/VBeta

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

0.020.04

0.060.08

0.1

3.5

4

4.5

5

P/VBeta

Man

ager

ial R

ent

Man

ager

ial R

ent

ts the impacts of operating cash payout rate, b, on firm, debt, equity and manageriale (P/V0).

H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50 45

their human capital. Thus, ‘‘cash cow” projects appear attractive toshareholders but not to managers, who favor a low cash payoutpolicy to increase the expected value of their rent.

The value of managerial rent turns to increase with cash payoutwhen a firm is close to bankruptcy. When P/V0 = 95%, the value ofmanagerial rent increases as the payout rate rises, whereas thevalue of debt decreases. Managers and shareholders are likely toagree to increase cash payout since doing so benefits both of themat the expense of bondholders. Then managerial decisions on milk-ing properties could be driven by their incentives to increase theirown utility. This constitutes an alternative to the explanation ofthe milking of properties as an attempt by managers to shiftwealth from debtholders to shareholders. Overall, the evidencepresented in this subsection serves as a reminder for caution formaking assumptions on the shareholder-manager conflicts thatmay vary dynamically with a firm’s financial health.

4. Managerial capital structure

The lattice model allows for a direct comparison of managerialdiscretionary leverage choices versus the optimal leverages thatmaximize firm values. I focus on addressing the following ques-tions: (1) What are managers’ leverage choices in the absence/presence of a takeover threat by shareholders? (2) How much domanagerial leverage choices deviate from the optimal leverageratios? (3) To what extent are the deviations affected by firm char-acteristics, debt features and default solutions? To address the lat-ter question, I present in the appendix an extension of the basicmodel that considers alternative default rules.

A firm’s leverage ratio is determined at t = 0, the financing deci-sion time. Shareholders would select ex ante an optimal leverageratio to maximize firm value. That equates to maximizing equityvalue given that debt is fairly priced. Managers choose ex ante a

Fig. 4. Interactions on a node at time t in the strategic default model. This figure illustratet. After firm asset value Vt is realized, the managers make a debt payment to the debtholdhonor the debt contract. The debtholders will accept the payment with no dispute wheamount, the debtholders weigh their options. They will accept the below-contracted-amliquidation, the managers make a dividend offer to the shareholders. The shareholders dekeep the managers in control till next time t + 1. By rejecting, they dismiss the manager

debt amount to maximize their private rent value. The notionalamount of debt is solved numerically to maximize either firmvalue or managerial rent value. Leverage is defined as the ratio ofdebt value over firm value, Leverage = B/(B + S).

In the benchmark, I assume that a firm and its creditors shareequal bargaining strength, i.e., debtholders’ bargaining powerh = 0.5. Fig. 4(A) reports managerial leverage choices in the absenceand presence of shareholders’ takeover threat and optimal lever-ages. The solid line represents the optimal leverage ratios thatincrease with managerial entrenchment power. Managerialentrenchment may have two opposite effects on optimal leverageratios. On one hand, it encourages shareholders to issue more debtto discipline entrenched managers by paying out free cash flows.On the other hand, higher entrenchment power results in higherdebt costs due to increased expected default loss, which in turndiscourages debt financing. The first effect appears to be dominant.The positive relationship between managerial entrenchment andoptimal leverage, however, contradicts the empirical evidence thatfirms with stronger managerial control issue less debt (Berger etal., 1997).

Since financing decisions are a standard responsibility of man-agers, managerial leverage choices provide an explanation of theabnormality. The longdash–shortdash line in Fig. 4(A) shows thatmanagers tend to issue zero debt without shareholders’ takeoverthreat. Issuing zero debt enables them to maximize the value oftheir private rent by avoiding completely losing any value of theirhuman capital in default. This evidence is consistent with the neg-ative relationship between managerial rent and debt amount iden-tified in the comparative statics.

This leads to the following questions: Why do managers issuedebt? Why do not managers reduce existing debt to zero overtime? The answers lie in shareholders’ takeover threat. Considerthat if managers issue zero debt at the financing decision time,

s the interactions among managers, debtholders and shareholders on a node at timeers. The payment may fall short of the contracted amount even if the firm is able to

n it satisfies the debt contract. But when the payment falls short of the contractedount payment to avoid liquidation if it is in their best interest to do so. Upon no

cide whether to accept the dividend offer. By accepting, they pocket the money ands and operate the firm themselves.

46 H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50

shareholders could take control immediately and issue an optimalamount of debt to maximize firm value. Thus, managers have toissue some debt to avoid being removed. In the same vein, manag-ers cannot reduce the existing debt below a certain level becausethat would invite takeover as well. For simplicity, I assume thatthe notional amount of debt is chosen by managers at time t = 0and does not change before maturity.

To avoid being dismissed, managers issue a minimal amount ofdebt to match the firm value to what shareholders are able toachieve by taking control and applying optimal leverage. The long-dash line in Fig. 4(A) represents managerial leverage choices thatsimultaneously maximize their own rent and prevent shareholdersfrom exercising their threat to take over. Their leverage choices de-crease monotonically as entrenchment power increases. Managers’incentives to maximize the value of their private rent make theirleverage choices deviate substantially from the optimal leverages.This is consistent with the empirical findings that firms with stron-ger managerial control tend to use less debt (Berger et al., 1997).The stronger their entrenchment power is, the less debt managersare able to issue without triggering dismissal. As a result, the firmvalues associated with managers’ leverage selections (longdashline in Fig. 4(B)) are increasingly lower than the optimal firm val-ues as managers become more entrenched. Since managerialentrenchment power could be restricted through corporate gover-nance, the analysis suggests that firms with better corporate gov-ernance should have relatively higher leverage ratios. Capitalstructure constitutes an important channel for improving firm va-lue through effective board control and stringent shareholdermonitoring.

00.

20.

40.

60.

8Le

vera

ge R

atio

0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1Entrenchment

0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1Entrenchment

Managers' Leverage without Shareholders' Takeover ThreatManagers' Leverage with Shareholders' Takeover ThreatOptimal Leverage

-0.0

50

0.05

0.1

0.15

Div

iden

d

Managers' Leverage without Shareholders' Takeover ThreatManagers' Leverage with Shareholders' Takeover ThreatOptimal Leverage

Fig. 5. Leverages, firm, equity and managerial rent values for different leverage choices.different leverage choices. The solid lines represent the variable values at the optimalvariable values at the managerial leverage selections in the absence of a takeover thremanagerial leverage selections in the presence of a takeover threat from the shareholde

Little direct evidence exists on the dynamic relationshipbetween payout policy and capital structure (Allen and Michaely,2002). The question of the role of the managerial component inthose policies remains mostly unanswered (Welch, 2004). I applythe model to shed some light on those unanswered questions.The dividend is defined as Dividend(V0) = S(V0) � e�rt(pS(uV0) +(1 � p)S(dV0)). Fig. 4(C) shows that dividends decrease (increase)with managerial entrenchment power at the optimal leverages(managerial leverage choices). Combining the results with thosereported in Fig. 4(A), I find that dividend yields are negatively cor-related to leverage ratios. This is intuitive since issuing more debtreduces net incomes and hence dividends. But their individualrelationships with managerial entrenchment are completelyswitched at the optimal leverages compared to at managerialleverage choices. The evidence highlights the importance of con-trolling for managerial entrenchment in cross-sectional empiricalinvestigations on the interactions between equity payout andfinancing policies. Fig. 4(D) shows that, for entrenched managers,zero leverages produce the highest rent values, followed by theirown leverage choices. The optimal leverages generate the lowestrent values.

To answer questions (2) and (3), I estimate the optimal lever-ages and managers’ leverage choices in the presence of a share-holders takeover threat for different firm characteristics and debtfeatures. Fig. 5 shows that managerial leverages further deviatefrom the optimal leverages as managers become more entrenched.Fig. 5(A) plots the interactions of managerial leverage deviationswith different operating cash payout levels. The result indicatesthat firms with high cash payout rates tend to experience greater

0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1Entrenchment

0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1Entrenchment

9095

100

105

Firm

Val

ue

Managers' Leverage without Shareholders' Takeover ThreatManagers' Leverage with Shareholders' Takeover ThreatOptimal Leverage

02

46

810

Man

ager

ial R

ent

Managers' Leverage without Shareholders' Takeover ThreatManagers' Leverage with Shareholders' Takeover ThreatOptimal Leverage

This figure plots leverage ratios, firm and managerial rent values, and dividends forleverages that maximize firm values. The longdash–shortdash lines represent theat from the shareholders. The longdash lines represent the variable values at thers.

H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50 47

deviations from optimal leverages. Fig. 5(B) shows that the devia-tions increase substantially as firm risk level r increases. As part ofthe value to be renegotiated in defaults that are more likely to takeplace with volatile asset returns, managerial human capital is ofgreater importance to shareholders. In turn, shareholders wouldbe more tolerant of managerial leverage deviations. The results ex-plain why small firms tend to have relatively lower leverage ratiosfrom the entrenchment angle.

The features of debt play a remarkable role in restricting man-agerial deviations from the optimal leverage choices. Fig. 5(C)shows that managerial leverage deviation decreases with debt cou-pon rate. By paying out free cash flows, shareholders discouragemanagerial rent-seeking and make managers issue debt closer tothe optimal amount. Fig. 5(D) indicates that managerial leveragechoices are decreasingly lower than the optimal leverages as debtmaturity increases. With longer debt maturity, managers areforced to issue more debt to avoid being dismissed as the firmcould enjoy more tax savings with debt of longer maturity. To-gether with the fact that short maturity debt better restricts man-agerial entrenchment, this result suggests that issuing debts ofdifferent maturities trades off tax savings versus not only bank-ruptcy loss, but also versus managerial value extraction. Overall,the analysis shows that debt features significantly influence firmleverage ratios when the agency issues between shareholdersand managers are taken into account.

I gauge the impacts of default rules on managerial leveragedeviation by examining three different levels of debtholders’ nego-tiation power: h = 0, 0.5 and 1. I assume that dismissing managersdoes not change a firm’s relative bargaining strength against itsdebtholders. h = 0.5 is the benchmark as the firm and debtholders

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

Leve

rage

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

Leve

rage

Optimal, beta = 0Optimal, beta = 4%

Optimal, C = 5% Managerial, C = 5%Optimal, C = 7% Managerial, C = 7%

Managerial, beta = 0Managerial, beta = 4%

0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1Entrenchment

0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1Entrenchment

Fig. 6. Optimal and managerial leverages with firm characteristics and bond features. Thleverages and the managerial leverage choices in the presence of a takeover threat from

share equal bargaining strength in debt renegotiations. h = 1 im-plies that debtholders possess all bargaining strength and obtainentire liquidation avoidance savings in negotiations. This is techni-cally equivalent to liquidation default since shareholders cannotexploit debtholders in strategic defaults. In practice, it representsthe case that creditors exercise strong power in a workout or nego-tiating restructure plans in bankruptcy court. When h = 0, the firmpossesses all bargaining strength in negotiations. That representsan extreme situation in which debtholders are not well protectedand strategic defaults are maximally encouraged.

Fan and Sundaresan (2000) and Broadie et al. (2007) find that,in the absence of managerial agency issues, optimal leveragesand firm values increase when debtholders possess more bargain-ing strength in debt renegotiations. However, Fig. 6(A) and (B)shows that, at managers’ discretion, leverage ratios and firm valuesare optimized when a firm and its debtholders share equal bargain-ing strength. When a firm holds all bargaining power, it becomestoo costly to issue a large amount of debt because all liquidationavoidance savings go to shareholders and managers in debt rene-gotiations. Strategic defaults are maximally encouraged and occurmore frequently. As a result, debtholders require high premium exante to compensate their high expected losses in defaults(Fig. 6(C)). But when debtholders possess full bargaining strength,shareholders’ power to discipline managerial underleverage is lim-ited. In this case, strategic defaults are maximally discouraged andoccur less frequently. In addition, debt default recovery is rela-tively high. Those two effects jointly make debt financing moreattractive. However, shareholders are forced to be more tolerantof leverage deviations since losing managerial human capital willreduce debt recoveries in defaults and drive up the cost of debt.

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

Leve

rage

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

Leve

rage

Optimal, sigma = 0.1Optimal, sigma = 0.3

Optimal, T = 5 Managerial, T = 5Optimal, T = 15 Managerial, T = 15

Managerial, sigma = 0.1Managerial, sigma = 0.3

0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1Entrenchment

0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1Entrenchment

is figure plots the impacts of firm characteristics and debt features on the optimalthe shareholders.

48 H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50

The leverage ratios and firm values are lower in both situations.Shared bargaining strength best trades off the needs to reduce debtcosts and to lift shareholders’ ability to discipline managers. As aresult, managerial rents are at the lowest level with h = 0.5(Fig. 6(D)).

5. Conclusions

I develop a dynamic valuation model that characterizes equitypayout and capital structure through the agency issues betweenentrenched managers and shareholders who have limited powerto discipline managers. In particular, the entrenched managersundertake financing and payout decisions to maximize their pri-vate rents and simultaneously to prevent shareholders fromremoving them. The model allows for quantitative examinationson the impacts of the agency problems of debt and equity on secu-rity valuation in one setting.

Evidence shows that managers’ preferences on risk choice andcash payout level change according to a firm’s financial health.Their decisions on milking properties/asset substitution could beexplained by managers’ incentives to increase their own utility asopposed to the conventional explanation that they attempt to shiftwealth from debtholders to shareholders. The evidence serves asan important reminder for caution because the shareholder-man-ager conflicts may vary with a firm’s financial health.

Entrenched managers select leverages that are substantiallylower than the optimal leverages. That helps to explain the subop-timal leverage ratios observed empirically (Graham, 2000). Thedeviations of managerial leverage choices from the optimal lever-

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

Man

ager

ial L

ever

age

Cho

ice

Theta = 0 Theta = 0.5 Theta = 1

100

200

300

400

500

Deb

t Cre

dit S

prea

d

Theta = 0 Theta = 0.5 Theta = 1

0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1Entrenchment

0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1Entrenchment

Fig. 7. Impacts of debtholders’ bargaining power. This figure plots the impacts of debtholcredit spreads at the managerial leverage choices. Different debtholders’ bargaining powbargaining power against the firm in debt renegotiations, respectively.

ages are significantly affected by firm characteristics and debt fea-tures. In particular, the deviations increase with operating cashpayout and risk level. Debts of long maturities with high couponshelp to alleviate the inefficiency due to the managerial agency is-sues. Managerial leverage deviations decrease as a firm and itscreditors share equal bargaining strength in debt renegotiations.Those findings provide applicable implications for corporate gover-nance and bankruptcy process design.

Some limitations remain for the model. Managerial entrench-ment is exogenous and is not linked to managers’ competency,board quality or shareholder monitoring. Contractual provisionssuch as executive stock options and golden parachutes are not con-sidered. Information asymmetry is ignored as well. Nonetheless, allconstitute interesting avenues by which to extend this model.

Acknowledgements

The author thanks Ike Mathur (editor), an anonymous referee,Adolfo de Motta, Redouane Elkamhi, Pascal Francois, Stuart Gillan,Kris Jacobs, Eric Jacquier, Roni Michaely, Shenghui Tong, SergeyTsyplakov and seminar participants at McGill University, TsinghuaUniversity, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, University of Zur-ich, University of Lugano, Central University of Finance & Econom-ics, FMA 2006 in Salt Lack City and Five Star Conference 2008 inBeijing for their comments. The author specially thanks Jan Erics-son for his guidance and supervision. The generous financial sup-port from Institute de Finance Mathématique de Montréal (IFM2)and Fonds Québécois de Recherche sur la Société et la Culture isgratefully acknowledged.

9095

100

105

Firm

Val

ue

Theta = 0 Theta = 0.5 Theta = 1

02

46

810

Man

ager

ial R

ent

Theta = 0 Theta = 0.5 Theta = 1

0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1Entrenchment

0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1Entrenchment

ders’ bargaining power on leverage ratios, firm and managerial rent values, and debter values: h = 0, 0.5 and 1, represent that the debtholders possess zero, equal and all

H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50 49

Appendix A. Extended model of strategic default

Strategic default has been deliberately shut off in the base casemodel to eliminate the impacts of the agency issues of debt. In thissection, I relax the restriction to examine simultaneously the man-agerial agency conflicts and ex post debt renegotiations with respectto capital structure and security valuation. Liquidation is morecostly than restructuring due to unrecoverable losses (Altman,1984). A firm may have incentives to default strategically knowingthat its creditors will bear the losses in liquidation. Among others,Anderson and Sundaresan (1996) and Fan and Sundaresan (2000)study security valuation with strategic defaults and debt renegoti-ations but without considering managerial agency issues.

The interactions in the strategic default model are analogous tothose in the base case model, except that negotiations between themanagers and the debtholders take place in strategic defaults. I fol-low Anderson and Sundaresan (1996) to assume zero renegotiationcosts. As illustrated in Fig. 7, on each node of time t, we observe thefollowing actions:

1. The managers make a debt payment to the debtholders. Thepayment may fall short of the contracted amount even if thefirm is able to honor the debt contract.

2. The debtholders will accept the payment with no dispute whenit satisfies the debt contract. But when the payment falls shortof the contracted amount, the debtholders weigh their options.They will accept the below-contracted-amount payment toavoid liquidation if it is in their best interest to do so.

3. Upon no liquidation, the managers make a dividend offer to theshareholders.

4. The shareholders decide whether to accept the dividend offer.By accepting, they pocket the money and keep the managersin control till next time t + 1. By rejecting, they dismiss themanagers and operate the firm themselves.

Appendix B. Valuation in the model of strategic default

The valuation is carried out using backward induction andstarts with the nodes at debt maturity T.

B.1. At debt maturity

Supposing that the firm is liquidated upon default at debt matu-rity T, the debtholders bear an unrecoverable loss of (j + /)VT.Through renegotiation, the debtholders could save part of the liq-uidation loss, depending on their relative bargaining strength,0 6 h 6 1, against the firm. According to the standard results ofNash Equilibrium, the debtholders receive h of the savings from liq-uidation avoidance. To repay the minimal amount to the debthold-ers, the managers choose between honoring the debt contract ordefaulting strategically. Strategic defaults occur when the asset va-lue is sufficiently low to secure the firm a gain in debt renegotia-tion. In equilibrium, the value of debt at time T equals the lowerone of the contracted amount or the negotiated payoff in strategicdefault, which equals the liquidation recovery (1 � j � /)VT plusthe debtholders’ share of the saved liquidation loss, h(j + /)VT.The value of debt can be expressed as

BðVTÞ ¼ min ð1þ cÞP; 1� ð1� hÞðjþ /Þð ÞVTð Þ: ð18Þ

The sum of equity value and managerial rent SM(VT) is ex-pressed as

SMðVTÞ ¼VT � BðVTÞ þ scP; if BðVTÞ ¼ 1þ cð ÞP;VT � BðVTÞ; if BðVTÞ ¼ 1� ð1� hÞðjþ /Þð ÞVT :

�ð19Þ

The value of equity at time T is expressed as

SðVTÞ ¼max SMðVTÞ � /VT ;0ð Þ: ð20Þ

Upon no default, the managers retain the rest of the firm’s assetvalue as their private rents. The value of managerial rent at time Tis

MðVTÞ ¼ SMðVTÞ � SðVTÞ: ð21Þ

B.2. At time t before debt maturity

At every time t, the managers may honor the debt contract. Thevalue of debt then equals the coupon received at time t plus theexpected continuation value of debt. The managers may defaultstrategically. Then the debtholders receive h of the value savedby avoiding liquidation on top of the recovery asset value(1 � j � /)Vt. The value saved by avoiding liquidation equals thedifference between the ongoing firm value Von(Vt) and the liquida-tion recovery value. Since Von(Vt) avoids immediate liquidationcosts and contains future tax benefits, its value is certainly higherthan the recovery asset value. The managers will pay the minimalamount to the debtholders. The latter will accept in equilibrium.The value of debt at time t is:

BðVtÞ ¼mincP þ e�rt pB uVtð Þ þ ð1� pÞB dVtð Þð Þ;

hVonðVtÞ þ 1� hð Þ 1� j� /ð ÞVt

� �; ð22Þ

where the ongoing firm value equals the cash flow generated attime t plus the expected continuation value of the firm:

VonðVtÞ ¼ bVt þ e�rt p B uVtð Þ þ SM uVtð Þð Þðþ ð1� pÞ BðdVtÞ þ SMðdVtÞð Þ

Unlike liquidation, strategic defaults are reversible. The firm de-faults strategically when its asset value is sufficiently low, but hasto resume the normal debt service once its asset value rises abovethe default barrier. Upon no default, the value of SM(Vt) equalsthe ex-coupon cash flow plus the expected continuation value ofSM(Vt). Upon default, the value of SM(Vt) equals the ongoing firmvalue minus the debt value:

SMðVtÞ ¼bVt � ð1� sÞcPþ e�rt pSM uVtð Þ þ ð1� pÞSMðdVtÞð Þ; no default;VonðVtÞ � BðVtÞ; default:

�ð23Þ

Upon no default, the value of equity at time t equals the lowerone of the reservation equity value or the ex-coupon cash flow plusthe expected continuation value of equity, minðbVt � ð1� sÞcPþe�rtðpSðuVtÞ þ ð1� pÞSðdVtÞÞ; SðVf

t ÞÞ. The reservation equity valueis lower for certain because the firm asset value decreases afterthe managers are removed. In equilibrium, the managers makeshareholders’ equity value equal the reservation equity valueSðVf

t Þ:

SðVtÞ ¼ S Vft

� �: ð24Þ

The managers retain the rest for their private rent. The value ofmanagerial rent is expressed as

MðVtÞ ¼ SMðVtÞ � SðVtÞ: ð25Þ

B.2.1. Computing reservation equity value SðVft Þ

Computing the reservation equity value is analogous to that inthe base case model. For simplicity, I omit a detailed introductionand provide the reader with the equations and brief descriptions.At debt maturity time T, the values of debt and equity are ex-pressed as

50 H. Wang / Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (2011) 36–50

B VfT

� �¼min ð1þ cÞP;1� ð1� hÞjVf

T

� �;

S VfT

� �¼

VfT � B Vf

T

� �þ scP; if B Vf

T

� �¼ ð1þ cÞP;

VfT � B Vf

T

� �; if B Vf

T

� �¼ ð1� hÞjVf

T :

8><>:

The up-move multiple u, down-move multiple d, and the risk-neutral probability of p remain unchanged. At every time h beforedebt maturity, the value of debt is expressed as

B Vfh

� �¼min

cP þ e�rt pB uVfh

� �þ ð1� pÞB dVf

h

� �� �;

hVon Vfh

� �þ 1� hð Þ 1� jð ÞVf

h

0B@

1CA;

where the ongoing firm value is expressed as

Von Vfh

� �¼ bVf

h þ e�rt p B uVfh

� �þ S uVf

h

� �� ��þ ð1� pÞ B dVf

h

� �þ S dVf

h

� �� ��:

The value of shareholders’ equity is expressed as

S Vfh

� �¼

bVfh � ð1� sÞcP þ e�rt pS uVf

h

� ��þð1� pÞS dVf

h

� ��; no default;

Von Vfh

� �� B Vf

h

� �; default:

8>>>><>>>>:

References

Allen, F., Michaely, R., 2002. Payout policy. In: Constantinides, G., Harris, M., Stulz, R.(Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Finance, vol. 1. North-Holland,Amsterdam.

Altman, E.I., 1984. A further empirical investigation of the bankruptcy cost question.Journal of Finance 39, 1067–1689.

Anderson, R., Sundaresan, S., 1996. Design and valuation of debt contracts. Reviewof Financial Studies 9, 37–68.

Berger, P., Ofek, E., Yermack, D., 1997. Managerial entrenchment and capitalstructure decisions. Journal of Finance 52, 1411–1438.

Black, F., Scholes, M.S., 1973. The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. Journalof Political Economy 7, 637–654.

Broadie, M., Chernov, M., Sundaresan, S., 2007. Optimal debt and equity values inthe presence of Chapters 7 and 11. Journal of Finance 62, 1341–1377.

Cox, J., Ross, S., Rubinstein, M., 1979. Option pricing: a simplified approach. Journalof Financial Economics 7, 229–263.

Ericsson, J., 2000. Asset substitution, debt pricing, optimal leverage and maturity.Finance 21, 39–69.

Faleye, O., 2009. Classified boards, firm value, and managerial entrenchment.Journal of Financial Economics 14, 399–422.

Fan, H., Sundaresan, S., 2000. Debt valuation, renegotiations and optimal dividendpolicy. Review of Financial Studies 13, 1057–1099.

Ferris, S., Jayaraman, N., Sabherwal, S., 2009. Catering effects in corporate dividendpolicy: the international evidence. Journal of Banking and Finance 33, 1730–1738.

Francois, P., Morellec, E., 2004. Capital structure and asset prices: some effects ofbankruptcy procedures. Journal of Business 77, 387–411.

Gillan, S., Starks, L., 2000. Corporate governance proposals and shareholderactivism: the role of institutional investors. Journal of Financial Economics 57,275–305.

Graham, J., 2000. How big are the tax benefits of debt? Journal of Finance 55, 1901–1941.

Grossman, S., Hart, O., 1982. Corporate financial structure and managerialincentives. In: McCall, J. (Ed.), The Economics of Information and Uncertainty,vol. 1. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

Harris, M., Raviv, A., 1989. The design of securities. Journal of Financial Economics24, 255–287.

Jensen, M., Meckling, W., 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agencycosts, and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305–360.

Jensen, M., 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers.American Economic Review 76, 323–329.

King, M., Santor, E., 2008. Family values: ownership structure, performance andcapital structure of Canadian firms. Journal of Banking and Finance 32, 2423–2432.

Lambrecht, B., Myers, S., 2007. A theory of takeover and disinvestment. Journal ofFinance 62, 809–845.

Leland, H., 1994. Risky debt, bond covenants and optimal capital structure. Journalof Finance 49, 1213–1252.

Leland, H., Toft, K.B., 1996. Optimal capital structure, endogenous bankruptcy andthe term structure of credit spreads. Journal of Finance 51, 987–1019.

Leland, H.E., 1998. Agency costs, risk management, and capital structure. Journal ofFinance 53, 1213–1243.

Liao, H., Chen, T., Lu, C., 2009. Bank credit risk and structural credit models: agencyand information asymmetry perspectives. Journal of Banking and Finance 33,1520–1530.

Margaritis, D., Psilaki, M., 2009. Capital structure, equity ownership and firmperformance. Journal of Banking and Finance 34, 621–632.

Merton, R.C., 1974. On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interestrates. Journal of Finance 29, 449–470.

Morellec, E., 2004. Can managerial discretion explain observed leverage ratios?Review of Financial Studies 17, 257–294.

Morellec, E., Nikolov, B., Schuhoff, N., 2008. Dynamic Capital Structure underManagerial Entrenchment: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. WorkingPaper, Swiss Finance Institute.

Morellec, E., Smith, C., 2007. Agency conflicts and risk management. Review ofFinance 11, 1–23.

Myers, S.C., 2000. Outside equity. Journal of Finance 55, 1005–1037.Rosenstein, S., Wyatt, J., 1990. Outside directors, board independence, and

shareholder wealth. Journal of Financial Economics 26, 175–191.Stulz, R., 1988. Managerial control of voting rights: financing policies and the

market for corporate control. Journal of Financial Economics 20, 25–54.Welch, I., 2004. Capital structure and stock returns. Journal of Political Economy

112, 106–131.Yermack, D., 1996. Higher market valuation of companies with a small board of

directors. Journal of Financial Economics 40, 185–213.Zwiebel, J., 1996. Dynamic capital structure under managerial entrenchment.

American Economic Review 86, 1197–1215.