international socialism_ the state and capitalism today

Upload: mathiarasu

Post on 14-Apr-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    1/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 1

    The state and capitalism todayIssue:

    Posted: 25 Septembe r 06

    Chris Harman

    From International Socialism,. 2(51): 357, Summer

    1991

    The relation between capital and the state is central to an

    understanding of developments in the world today. It is thrown

    up in a whole series of apparently different discussio ns: on the

    future for the Third World, on the relations betwe en the

    superpowers in the aftermath of the Cold War. on the prospectsfor succ essful econo mic restru cturing in the USSR and Eastern

    Europe, on the repeated rows within the Tory gov ernment over

    European integration, on the significance o f the United States

    war against Iraq. These issues have c reate d conside rable deb ate

    on the left. They hav e been the subject of an intermittent

    discussion among co ntributors to this journal for a dec ade and a

    half, and among the wider left there has been much gre ater

    confusion.1

    The state as simply a superstructure

    The most common v iew of the capitalist state among Marxists is

    to see it simply as a superstructure, as external to the capitalist

    economic system. Capitalism, in this view, consists in the pursuit

    of profits by firms (or, more ac curately speaking, the self

    expansion of capitals) without regard to where they are based

    geographically . The state, by c ontrast, is a geographically based

    political entity, whose bo undaries cut acro ss the operations of

    the individual capitals.

    The state may be a structure that developed historically to

    prov ide the po litical prerequisites for c apitalist productionto

    protect c apitalist property, to po lice the dealings of different

    members of the ruling class with each o ther, to prov ide certain

    services which are essential for the repro duction of the system,

    and to carry thro ugh such reforms as are necessary to make

    other sections o f society accept c apitalist rulebut it is not to be

    identified with the system itself.

    This view of the state claims to be based on the Communist

    Manifesto: The ex ecutive of the modern state is but a c ommittee

    for managing the common affairs of the whole bourgeoisie. But

    its origins do not lie in Marx himself so muc h as in the classical

    economists who preceded him: in the Communist Manifesto

    Marx simply takes their insistence on the need for a minimalist,

    nightwatchman state and draws out its class character.

    Nevertheless it is the view that is to be found in most modern

    academic Marxism. So, for instance, it was to be found on both

    sides of the debate which took place in New Left Review between

    Ralph Miliband and Nicos Poulantzas.2 Miliband argued what

    has been called the instrumental vie w of the state: it was tied to

    http://www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?s=contents&issue=
  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    2/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 2

    the capitalist class because its leading personnel came from the

    same milieu as the owners of priv ate capital.3

    Poulantzas argued that this was to see a merely contingent

    relationship between the state and capitalism, to see the states

    character as depending simply on who manned its top

    structures. He argued what has been called the functional view:

    the state has to fulfil the needs of the society of which it is part;

    since this is a capitalist society it is necessarily a capitalist state.

    The state is, as Poulantzas puts it, a condensate o f class forces,

    and the forces it condenses are capitalist forces.4

    Despite their apparent opposition to each other, both Milibands

    and Poulantzas views can lead to the co nclusion that the

    capitalist state can be used to r eform capitalist society . If it is the

    character of its personnel that guarantees the capitalist nature of

    the state, then changing the personnel could change the

    character o f the state, allowing it to be used for soc ialist

    purposes. If the state is a function of the soc iety o f which it is

    part, then if that society is racked by deep class struggles, these

    would find the ir expression thr ough the state. The c ondensate of

    class forces co uld express bo th ruling class and working class

    pressureswhich perhaps explains why Poulantzas could mov e

    from Maoism to Eurocommunism without any fundamental

    change in his theoretical framework.

    More recently, another v ariant of the view of the state as

    external to capital has emerged on the left. Within academic

    Marxism there is a growing tendency for people to counterpose

    the capitalist system, as a system based upon the drive o f firms

    to ac cumulate, to the sy stem of states within which it has been

    enmeshed historically.5 In a few cases this has led to the

    conclusion that the great wars of the present century hav e not

    resulted from any drive o f capitalism towards war, but rather

    from the clash of ancien regime empires which capitalist

    development is now in the course of dismantling.6

    Nigel Harris comes from a very different traditiona

    revo lutionary traditionto that of ac ademic Marxism. His

    writings have alway s ex pressed an unbridled hatred fo r the state

    and complete co ntempt for those who believe it is possible to

    reform c apitalism. But in his attempt lo come lo terms with the

    internationalisation of capital ov er the last 20 years he has

    turned to an acco unt of the state which belongs to the stale

    simply as superstructure school.

    He argues that the interests of capital are incre asingly

    international interests, not bounded by any national borders.

    Each individual capital grew up within a particular nation states,

    but can now operate within v irtually any state, bending it to its

    will . The part icular state was a nec essary instrument at o ne stage

    of capitalist dev elopmenta superstructure once needed by

    capital acc umulationbut is no longer. Capitalism is led to

    challenge the state which has acco mpanied its growth in the

    past, to act against the arbitrary and corrupt abso lutist stale, tomove to the completion of the bourgeois revo lution in a way

    reminiscent of 1848.7

    Nigel does not mean that the state simply withers away. Far from

    it. The bureaucratic structures of the state remain intact. They

    have interests of their own to preserv e, interests that are tied to

    a particular national geographic area, interests in maintaining

    class peace, interests in attracting capital in competition with

    other states, interests in building up military prowess. And so

    the modern world is characterised not just by an increasing

    volume of trad e in goo ds and c apital, b ut by state boundaries

    which impede that trade in a manne r which is, from a c apitalist

    point of view, irrational. There is bread, but there are also

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    3/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 3

    guns.

    The state as capital

    While mo st o f the left has seen the state and c apital as oppo sed,

    there has been a minority tradition that equates the state with

    capital. Its intellectu al origins go bac k to the insights of Lenin

    and Bukharin in their boo ks on imperialism written at the he ight

    of the First World War.8 They spoke o f the state merging with

    capital, of state monopoly capitalism, or simply of state

    capitalism. It was these insights that Tony Cliff used when he

    developed the only coherent Marxist analysis of Stalins Russia9and various ex -colonial countries.10 But Mike Kidron went

    further and extended the insights into what he c laimed was a

    complete theory of ageing capitalism.11 In Kidrons acco unt

    individual states and individual capitals beco me c ompletely

    congruent with each other: every state acts at the behest of a set

    of nationally based capitals, and every significant capital is

    incorporated in a particular state. If y ou talk about the interests

    of British capitalism, y ou are talking about the intere sts of the

    British state; if you talk about the British state, you are talking

    about the operations of British capitalism. This does not mean

    that there are no exc eptions ruleno c apitals that temporarily

    escape from the control o f national states or no national states

    that temporarily act against the interests of nationally based

    capitals. But these exc eptions, for Kidron, are a hangover fromthe past, relics whic h will disappear with the further

    development of the sy stem. Indeed, the logic is for all elements

    of the superstructure, even trade unions, to bec ome simple

    expressions of the drive of national capital to co mpete with its

    foreign rivals. Certain academic Marxists hold views which in

    some ways parallel Kidrons. These belong to the logic of capital

    or the state as capital schools. For them, the behav iour of the

    state is determined by the logic o f capital accumulation,

    although they tend to see it as the logic o f private capital within

    the individual state rather than of a state capital in competition

    with other state capitals.12

    Problems with both views

    There are problems of analysis and implications for political

    practice assoc iated with both sets of v iews. If the state is simply

    a superstructure, then it is possible to contend that the problems

    that arise in the political sphere and tho se that arise

    economically are separate and distinct from each o ther. The

    struggle against the police or against racism then has nothing to

    do with the class struggle; the blow against the boss ceases to be

    a blow against the bomb.1

    This was the logic which led Bernstein and Kautsky to drop their

    differenc es and to claim that it was possible to fight militarism

    during the First World War without t urning the imperialist war

    into a civ il war. It is the same logic which led Edward Thompson

    in the mid-1980s to talk about military competition betweenstates as exterminism, which had nothing to do with old style

    capitalism and which could be fought by men and women o f

    good will from all classes.

    The implications of the vie w of the state and capital as merging

    completely are just as great.The forms o f oppression maintained

    by the state are see n as flo wing direc tly from the ac cumulation

    needs of capital. There c an be no clash between them. Sexual

    oppression, racial discrimination, the structure of the family,

    bur eaucr atic hierar chies, po litical par ties, even natio nal trade

    union organisation, are all products of the logic of the state as

    capital.14 The consequence of such a view is to dro p any

    distinction between fundamental social clashes which challenge

    the very basis of capitalist rule and less fundamental ones that

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    4/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 4

    can be c ontained by reforms to the existing institutional

    structur e. The result is either ultra-leftist spontaneismas with

    Lotta Continua and then the Italian autonomists in their heyday

    in which the revolution is seen as imminent in each and every

    struggle, since ev ery form of oppression flows from the

    immediate require ments of capital acc umulation. Or it is a

    variant o f refo rmism, which sees the structures e sse ntial to

    capital as being undermined by piecemeal rejection o f each

    particular oppression. The strategic aim beco mes the

    establishment of rainbow coalition alliances between various

    autonomous mov ements, each seen as just as important as any

    other.15The origin of the national state and national capital

    Y ou cannot correc tly grasp the relationship be tween the state

    and capital today unless yo u reject bo th the simple

    superstructure and the state as capital positions. Instead, y ou

    have to understand the co ncrete way s in which capitals and the

    capitalist state necessarily interact in the course of historical

    development. Existing national states did arise out of the

    developing capitalist organisation of pro duction, as

    superstructures. But they feed back into that organisation,

    helping to determine its tempo and direction.

    Marx pointed out in Volume Two of Capital that capital appears

    in three formsas productive capital, as commodity capital and

    as money capital. Every process o f capital accumulation

    involves repeated changes from one form to the other: moneycapital is used to buy means of production, raw materials and

    labour power; these are put together in the production pro cess

    to turn out co mmodities; these commodities are then exchanged

    for money; this money is then used to buy more means of

    production, raw materials and labour power, and so on.

    The forms of capital are continually interacting as one changes

    into the other, so that at any giv en point in time some of the total

    capital will take the form of means of production, some of

    commodities waiting to be sold, and some of money . But there

    can also be a partial separation of these three different forms.

    The organisation of direct production, the selling of

    commodities and the supply of finance can devo lve upon

    different gro ups of capitalists.

    It is this separation which c reates the illusion that capital is anobject that grows in size by some magical proc ess. For it does for

    those capitalists who simply buy and sell commodities, and for

    those capitalists who simply adv ance money and reap interest

    payments in return.

    Each of these forms of capital has had, historic ally, a different

    relationship to the body which has a monopoly of political

    v iolence in any partic ular geo graphic loc alitythe state. Mone y

    capital can (or at least could, in its classical form, when gold was

    the main means of payment) operate regardless of state

    structures. It co uld flourish, as Marx noted, long before the

    development o f capitalism generally . Money lenders in one part

    of the world would make loans to bo rrowers in other parts o f the

    world, re ly ing o n the recipients need for further loans to

    guarantee repayment with interest. So it was that Italian bankerscould finance the French absolute monarchy and south German

    bankers the Spanish abso lute monarchy . Financiers did not nee d

    to be tied to a particular state to flourish prov ided they co uld

    find ways of making sure the state did not actually confiscate

    their wealth.

    Commodity capital could also flourish in all sorts of political

    structuresin slave societies f medieval antiquity, amid the

    battling lordships of the e arly feudal pe rio d, in the c entralised

    absolutist states of late feudalism. Y et the more it developed, the

    more it came to require the protection of state structures it

    could influence. Otherwise those who controlled states co uld

    present obstacles to it: pillaging merchant convoy s on the road,

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    5/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 5

    allowing pirates to intercept seaborne traffic, imposing local

    customs dues that prevented the gro wth of a truly national, let

    alone international, market, imposing price controls that

    restricted the potential for profit making.

    So from quite an early period o nwards, merchants tended to

    encourage the growth o f political structures under their own

    control. A s Braudel tells of the medieval period, there arose:

    ...business rivalries between individuals, between cities and

    betwe en natio ns as a nat ional group o f merchants was calle d.

    Sixteenth century Lyons was dominated by.. .organised rival

    groups, each living as nation... Their presence meant theestablishment of empires, networks and colonies in certain

    areas. Trade circuits and c ommunications were regularly

    dominated by po werful groups who appropriated them and who

    might forbid other gro ups to use them. Such groups are easy to

    find when one starts looking for them, in Europe and eve n

    outside Europe.6

    Productive c apital is necessarily much mo re dependent than

    merchants capital upon state power. It cannot function without,

    on the one hand, a guarantee of its own co ntrol of means of

    production (a guarantee which, in the last resort, relies upon

    armed bodies of men), and, on the other, a labour force which

    has been freed from co ercion by any o ther social group (slave

    owners or feudal lords) and from any control o ver means ofproduction.

    If local state power prevents these c onditions arising, the

    development o f productive capital is stunted: there were

    absolutist states in which finance capital flourished b ut

    productive c apitalism barely too k root, and medieval cities in

    which art isans prod uced c ommodities for the market without

    the separation of workers from the means o f production which

    was required to mov e fro m simple c ommodity pro duc tion to

    capitalist produc tion.17

    When Marx wrote ab out the pr imitiv e ac cumulatio n of capital

    he was not just describing the (very barbaric) means by which

    the early capitalists built up their fortunes. More importantly, he

    was pointing to the social and po litic al me asures which were

    needed to c oncentrate means of production in capitalist hands

    and to free the labour force. The lull development of capitalism

    requires that productive c apital subjugate commodity and

    money capital to itself. Only productive capitalthe ex ploitation

    of workers in the labour proc essguarantees a co ntinually

    growing pool of surplus value and, with it, a source o f ever larger

    profits for capitalists of all sorts.

    If the development of productive c apital, and to a lesser extent

    commodity capital, is entangled with the development o f the

    geographic state, then so is the deve lopment of capitalism as a

    who le even if in the fo rm o f money capital capitalism seems to

    have no need for the state.

    The point is importantmoney c apital often seems to be the

    pure form of capital, the form in which the self expansion of

    value is most v iv idly to be see n. But like the othe r forms of

    capital, it is in reality, as Marx put it, not a thing but a relation,

    a relation which involves the exploitation of people at the point

    of production. And that ex ploitation needs to b e underpinned by

    the political structures of the state.

    Any pro duc tiv e capital gro ws up within the confines of a

    particular territory, alongside other sibling capitals (they are, as

    Marx describes them, warring bro thers). They are mutually

    dependent on each o ther for resourc es, finance and markets.

    And they act to gether to try to shape the soc ial and po litical

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    6/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 6

    conditions in that territory to suit their own purposes.

    This involv es an effort to free labour from the co ntrol of other

    classes, to remov e obstacles to the sales of their products, to

    create an infrastructure (ports, roads, canals, railways) to fit

    their requirements, to establish sets of rules for regulating their

    relations with each o ther (bourgeois property laws) and to

    create an armed power which will protect their property bo th

    from domestic and ex ternal threats. Their efforts to achieve all

    these things will be aided if they can supplant a mass of local

    dialects and languages with a single form of spoken and written

    speech. Their aim, in short, has to be to cr eate a national statepowerand with it a national consciousness and language.

    The national state and different nationally base d capitals grow

    up together, like children in a single family. The development of

    one inevitably shapes the development of the others. This does

    not mean that the structures of the state are an immediate

    product o f the needs of capital. Many of the elements of the pre-

    capitalist state are restructured

    to fit in with the needs of the c apitals that arise within them,

    rather than simply being smashed and replaced. But they are

    actively remolded, so as to function in a very different way than

    previously , a way that co rresponds to the logic of capitalist

    exploitation.

    . Industrial and agrarian capitals were usually not nearly

    powerful enough to shape the who le of the po litical structure.

    But their presence could be a significant counterweight to the

    old baronies, so making it easier for kings to replace the

    decentralised feudalism of the early medieval period with

    absolute monarchies. The mercantilist policies of these

    monarchies then provided the impetus towards a wide

    development of co mmercial capital and a much mo re limited

    development of productiv e capital within the co nfines of each

    state.

    This growing weight of capitalist interests became decisive when

    the absolutist states themselves entered into crisis. In England in

    the 164()s and France in the late 17 80s and early 1 7 90s theywer e able to ensure that the so cial and po litic al c risis was

    resolved by the establishment of unitary national state

    structures that would serve their interests. The only viable

    alternatives to the crisis were those which enco uraged capitalist

    dev elopment (ev en if those, like Cromwe ll in Britain and the

    Jacobins in France, who imposed these alternatives did so in

    opposition to the immediate desires of some powerful capitalist

    interests).

    These national states then became the model for those elsewhere

    who want ed to b reak out o f the b ackwar dness o f dec ay ing

    feudalism or to escape foreign colonial co ntrol. Sometimes this

    was a case of already dev elo ping bourgeo is or pe tty bourgeois

    groups seeking to establish a national state under their owncontrol; on other oc casions intellectuals or army o fficers saw

    their own interests as best advanced by using state power to

    impose capitalist forms of ex ploitation and acc umulation on the

    rest of the po pulation.

    In every case the development of groups of industrial and

    agrarian capitals is inseparable from the transformation of the

    geographic area in which they are based into a national state

    with its o wn language, sy ste m of laws, banking sy ste m and so on.

    Stages in the development of the state and capital

    Classical economics prov ided an acco unt of capitalism in which

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    7/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 7

    the state played a negligible role. It was a theory of pure capital,

    of self expanding capital which took no regard of national

    frontiers. It was this theoretical acco unt which Marx took up in

    Capital and carried through to its logical conclusion, showing

    how c apitalism contained inbuilt co ntradictions ev en when

    considered in the most abstract manner.IS

    But the real, concre te history of capitalism was always v ery

    much intertwined with the history of the state. Classical

    economics was, in fact, an empirical description of o nly o ne,

    historically limited, phase of the sy stem, that of the mid-19th

    century. Things were v ery different when Adam Smith wrote, ashe himself recognised when he co mplained about the dev otion of

    Britains business classes to its empire :

    To found an empire for the sole purpose of raising up a people of

    customers may at first sight appear a project fit only for a nation

    of shop keepers. It is, howev er, a project altogether unfit for a

    nation of shop keepers, but extremely fit for a nation whose

    gov ernment is influenced by shop keepers.

    The growth of British capitalism in the two c enturies befor e

    Smith had, in fact, been very dependent upon sponsorship by

    the state and the economic activities of gov ernments. The

    enclosure acts, the navigation laws, the great state sponsored

    monopolies headed by the East India Company, stateexpenditures on equipping the armed forces, especially the

    navy , all played a v ital part in that growth. A v ery long spell of

    state sponsorship, of mercantilism, was necessary for British

    capitalism to dev elop sufficiently to be able to dominate the

    world on the basis o f the free trade urge d by Smith.

    The Smithian doctrine did not become the practice of British

    capitalism until the 1840s and 1850s (with the repeal of the Corn

    Laws and the removal of India from the control of the East India

    Company) and even then the forc es of the British state still

    played a c entral role in imposing free trade on other parts of the

    world. The Opium Wars are just one example.

    What is mor e, this c lassical phase did not in pr actic e last much

    more than half a century. By the 1880s and 1 890s Britishgov ernments were carving out new colonies in Africa to

    supplement their old o nes in Asia and the West Indies. A nd

    although there were not to be formal measures (tariffs, quotas)

    tying the colonial economies to Britain until the establishment of

    imperial preference in the 1 930s, there were a mass of informal

    links.

    Capitals had established themse lves in Britain through close

    links with the national state. Once established they had then used

    this national base to enco mpass the rest of the world. And when,

    after a few decades, capitals from o ther co untries began to

    challenge their dominating role, they then turned once again to

    their own national stale to establish areas of priv ileged access for

    them.

    The newer centres of c apital accumulation that emerged

    alongside Britain in the 19th century were as dependent upon

    national state support as British capitalism had been previously.

    German, Italian and Yankee capitalists all looked to a national

    state which would use its power to impose protectionist

    measures against outside competition: the rise of indigenous

    capitalist firms in these countries was closely tied to the

    establishment of unitary states prepared to accede to their

    demands (the unification of Italy, the v ictory of the North in the

    Americ an Civ il War, the e stablishment of the Ger man Empire

    under Bismarck).

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    8/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 8

    Capitals aided the cr eation of the unified stateand success in

    the struggle for unification usually gav e an enormous bo ost to

    indigenous capital (eg the tremendous growth o f American

    capitalism in the dec ades after the Civil War and of German

    capitalism after the Franc o-Prussian War).

    Historically, then, capitals have never dev eloped acco rding to

    the anti-statist schemas o f classical economics. They have

    influenced and been influenced by the state structures in which

    they have found themselves. This has left its impact on the

    specific features of the individual capitals.

    Regarded simply as accumulations of wealth, all capitals may

    have the same character, differing only in their size. But each

    individual capital, like eac h individual commodity , has a twofold

    character. A s well as being measurable in terms of ex change

    value, it is also a concr ete use v alue a co ncrete set o f relatio ns

    betwe en indiv iduals and things in the proce ss o f pro duc tio n.

    Each particular capital has its concr ete way s of bringing together

    labour power, raw materials and means of produc tion in the

    production proc ess, of raising finance and getting credit, o f

    establishing networks for distributing and selling its output.

    It inevitably turns for assistance in all of these tasks to other

    loca l capitals and to the state in which it is locate d. Capitals in a

    particular geographical location do not merely compete witheach other; they also c o-operate with each other and with the

    state to establish mechanisms for ac hieving mutual goals. And

    this co-operation inevitably leaves its imprint on the internal

    make up of each cap ital, so that a particular c apital would find it

    very diffic ult to c op e if it were sudde nly to be t or n apart from

    the oilier capitals and the state with which it has co-existed in

    the past.

    The groups of capitals and the state with which they are

    associated form a sy stem in which each affects the others. The

    specific c haracter of each capital is influenced by its interaction

    with the other c apit als and the slate . It re flec ts no t only the

    general drive to expand v alue, to accumulate, but also the

    specific env ironment in which it has grown up. The state and the

    individual capitals are intertwined, with eac h feeding off the

    other . This interactio n takes place in different ways. The legal

    code of the state and the way it raises rev enue, influence, and are

    influenced by, the internal organisation of each capitalthe

    relationship between o wners and managers, acc ounting

    procedures, ev en the ease with which it can recruit and lay off

    labour. They also affect and are affected by the relations between

    capitalsthe extent to which there is a fusion between

    productive capital and merchant capitals (with firms doing their

    own marketing), or between finance capital and productive

    capital (with firms depending on their banks to raise mone y).

    Neither the state no r the particular capitals can easily escape

    this structural interdependence. The particular capitals find it

    easier to o perate within one state rather than another, becausethey may have to pro foundly r estructure both their internal

    organisation and their relations with other c apitals if they mov e

    their operations. The state has to adjust to the needs o f

    particular capitals because it depends on them for the resourc es

    particularly the re venues from tax ationit needs to keep

    going: if it goes against their interests, they can move their liquid

    assets abroad.

    This structural interdependence explains why the capitals that

    grow up in one particular state tend to differ in certain ways to

    those that grow up in other states. For instance, the level of

    monopolisation of British capital tended to be less than that of

    German and American capital in the early y ears of the 20th

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    9/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 9

    century ; the role of the banks tended to be different in pre-First

    World War Britain to their role in Ger many or France; the state

    was muc h mo re impor tant in the formatio n of a skilled lab our

    force in Germany than in Britain in the 19th century; today

    Japanese firms typically raise finance in a rather different way to

    British or A merican firms; the influence o f the state on private

    capital investment is much greater in Japan or France than in

    the US.

    Such structural adjustment of states and capitals to each other is

    necessarily acc ompanied by something else the intermingling

    of their personnel so emphasised by the instrumental view o fthe state. The relationship betwe en the capitals based in a

    particular country and their state is not simply a relationship

    betwe en imper sonal structures. It is a relationship between

    people, between those engaged in ex ploiting the mass o f the

    population and those who control bo dies of armed men.

    Personal contact with the leading personnel of the state is

    something every capitalist aims atjust as ev ery capitalist seeks

    to c ultivate ties of trust and mutual support with certain other

    capitalists

    .

    Relations between the ruler s of the state and the capitalists who

    have ac cumulated wealth within its orbit tend to be much closer

    than cithers relations with outsiders. The fact that the leading

    personnel of the state went to the same schoo ls as the leadingcapitalists, go to the same clubs, and are intermarried with each

    other, is v ery important to the individual capitalists in much the

    same way as are interlocking directorships between firms, their

    suppliers and their bankers. To deny this, as some critics of the

    instrumental account of the state do, is not to take acco unt of

    the fact that both the state and the capitals are concrete

    complexe s of social relationships, in which the character o f the

    leading personnel is o f enormous importance.

    The market models of classical and neo-classical eco nomics

    portray capitals as isolated atoms which engage in blind

    competition with other capitals. In the real world, capitalists

    have always tried to boo st their competitive po sitions by

    establishing alliances with each other and with ambitiouspolitical figuresalliances cemented by money but also by

    intermarriage, old boy networks, mutual socialising.20 Knowing

    the right people is an important complement to adequate finance

    for any successful capitalistindeed, often an indispensable

    precondition for getting that finance.

    The networks of who knows whom hav e grown up within the

    orbit o f particular national states, usually around particular

    major cities. For instance, in the United States in the mid-197 0s

    there was a concentration of co rporate head offices, with most

    of the top 5 00 corpo rations being located in the mid-Atlantic

    and East North Central regions. Despite the gro wth of sunbelt

    industry, only 12 percent of head offices were in the South.21

    Even in multinational corporations, what is sometimes calledthe headquarters effect is at work. As one c ommentator has

    noted:

    Multinationals tend to locate the activities which c reate the

    greatest added value and which give them the greatest

    competitive edge as close as po ssible to their headquarters.22

    The extent of the linkages which have grown up between national

    states and the capitals within their boundaries is shown by the

    difficulties the European Community has in overcoming:

    the refusal by go vernments, utilities and monopoly industries to

    purchase from suppliers outside their own co untries. At stake is

    a market valued at 281 billion, or 10 percent of European

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    10/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 10

    Community ec onomic o utput. It is a bigand sometimes sole

    source of demand for products ranging from turbine generators

    to telephone exc hanges and has long been used by gov ernments

    to promo te national champion industries at the ex pense of

    foreign rivalsFewer than 5 pen cut of all central, regional and

    local public orders go to bidders from other c ountries and many

    are awarded on a non-competitive single tender has is.:^

    The autonomy of the state

    There are cases in which those who c ontrol the state break with

    those who control the capitals within their territory. The Nazisdid confiscate Thy ssens wealth and establish their own Hermann

    Goering Werke as an important co mponent of the German

    economy . Perons first gov ernment in Argentina did seize the

    super-profits of the agrarian capitalists and redirect them into

    state controlled industrial development. Nasser in Egypt and the

    Baathists in Sy ria did dispossess big capital (both indigenous

    and foreign) and transform it into state c apital. Those who

    controlled the state machines of Eastern Europe after the Second

    World War did use the m to impose almost c om plete statificatio n

    of the means of production.

    There are also many cases in which the individual capitals

    behav e in way s detrimental to the inte rests of their state

    moving funds and investment abroad, doing deals with foreigncapitalists that undercut o ther local capitals, ev en selling

    weapons to states fight ing their own. Y et ther e ar e limits to the

    extent to which the state can break free of its capitals, and

    capitals of their state.

    The limiting case for the state is that, ev en if it ov errides the

    interests of particular capitalists, it cannot forget that its own

    revenues and its own ability to defend itself against other states

    depend, at the end of the day, o n the continuation of capital

    accumulation. Thus the Nazis could ex propriate Thyssen, they

    could seize the wealth of Jewish capitalists, they could establish

    the horrific machinery of the death c amps without it providing

    any appreciable benefit to German capital, they c ould ev en insist

    on co ntinuing the war after it was clearly going to be lost and theinterests of German capitalism would have been serv ed by

    attempts at a negotiated peace. But they c ould only do all of

    these things so long as they ensured that capitalist ex ploitation

    took place o n the most favourable terms for c apital (state and

    private) and, therefore, that acc umulation co ntinued. The same

    applies to Pero n, Nasser, the Baathists, the East European

    regimes and so on.

    The limiting case for the indiv idual capital is that though it can,

    with co nsiderable difficulty , uproot itse lf from one national state

    terrain and plant itself in another, it cannot operate for any

    length of time without having some state to do its will. It is too

    vulne rab le to try to operate in a Wild West situatio n in which

    there is no effective state, leaving it prey both to forces be low

    which might disrupt its normal rhythms of explo itat ion and to

    other capitals and their states.

    A b reak, e ithe r o f the state with its capitals o r o f the c apitals with

    their state, is a difficult and risky bu siness. If the state turns on

    private c apital, it can c reate a situation in which people begin to

    challenge not merely private capital but capital accumulation as

    such and, with it, the hierarchies of the state. If a private capital

    breaks with its stale it r isks b eing left to fend a lone in a hostile

    and dangerous world. So there is neither an easy , peaceful road

    to state c apitalism nor an easy shift of industrial capitals from

    one metropolitan centre to another.

    The class character of the state bureaucracy

    Most discussions of the state and capitalism never even to uch

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    11/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 11

    one major questionthe class character of the state bureaucracy

    itself. The assumption is usually that it is simply a passive

    creature o f a capitalist class whose own position is defined by its

    private o wnership of the means of production. Sometimes the

    bur eaucr acy is pr esented as having inter ests o f its own which

    may make marginal encroachments o n the interests of private

    capital, but this is rarely spelt out: it is usually no more than an

    ad hoc assumption thrown in so as to make sense of individual

    events.

    Such a view made a certain sense when Marx was looking at mid-

    19th century British capitalism with its minimal nightwatchmanstate. State expenditure was at very low levels and taxation o nly

    marginally affected the pricing of goods or the level of peoples

    disposable incomes. Howev er, this acco unt of the state can make

    no sense o f the absolutist period which witnessed the rise of

    productive capitalism or of capitalism in the present century .

    In both c ases, the state bureaucracy itself is a very significant

    social layer, state ex penditures play a v ery important part in

    determining the way soc iety dev elops, and state taxation and

    borrowing dec isiv ely influe nce the ge neral structure of pr ices

    and the disposable incomes of the different classes.

    Marx went far beyo nd the view he put forward in the Communist

    Manifesto when, in 187 1, he wrote that the complicated state

    machinerywith its ubiquitous and co mplicated military,bur eaucr atic , c ler ical and judiciary or gans, encoils the liv ing

    society like a boa co nstrictorEvery minor social interest

    engendered by the r elations of soc ial groups was separated from

    society itself, fixed and made independent of it and opposed to it

    in the form of state interest, administered by state priests with

    with ex ac tly deter mine d hie rar chical func tions.

    He emphasised that such a state bureaucracy did not merely live

    off exploitation by separate, private interests, but superimposed

    on them its own ex ploitative activities. The state was not only a

    means of the forcible do mination of the middle class but also a

    means of adding to the direct economic e xploitation a second

    exploitation of the peo ple, by assuring to their [ie the middle

    classsCH) families all the rich plac es in the state ho usehold.The stale bureaucracy arises to assure the domination of the

    existing ruling class, but in the process be comes a parasite

    which is c apable of humb ling under its sway ev en the interests

    of the ruling classes>24

    Under ageing capitalism, the pro portion of the total income o f

    society passing through the hands of the state is usually much

    greater than income going directly to private capital as profits,

    interest and rent. Investment directly undertaken by the state is

    often more than half total investment.25 The state bureaucracy

    directly disposes of a ver y big portion of the fruits of

    exploitation and oversees a great amount of economic ac tivity.

    Its class character is very important to the whole functioning of

    society.

    There is enormous c onfusion among many professed Marxists as

    to what co nstitutes a class. They argue that class depends on

    individual ownership (or non-ownership) of property, and that

    therefore the state bureaucracy c annot be an exploiting class or

    part of an exploiting classhence the claim that the ruling

    stratum in the Eastern states has not in the past been a class,

    although it is conceded that privatisation might now be

    transforming it into 7 one.

    But classes, for Marx himself, were aggregates of people whose

    relationship to material production and ex ploitation forced

    them to act together c ollectively against other aggregates. In an

    unfinished final chapter to v olume thre e of Capital Marx insists

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    12/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 12

    that classes cannot be identified simply by the sources of

    rev enues since this would lead to an infinite division into

    classes, par alleling the infinite fragmentation of interests and

    rank into which the division of soc ial labour splits labourers as

    well as c apitalists and landlo rdsthe latter , eg, into o wners o f

    v ineyard s, farm owners, owners o f forests, mine o wners and

    owners of fisheries.26

    What makes suc h div erse groups co me together into the great

    classes of modern society, he argues elsewhere, is the way in

    which the revenues o f one set of gro ups arise out o f the

    exploitation of those who make up other groups. The socialrelations of production and exploitation divide society into two

    great groupings, one of which ex ploits the other. The historic

    opposition between them forces each to band together against

    the other, to behav e as a class.2

    Feudal lords form a c lass because each depends for his survival

    on the surplus which he forces the serfs to hand ov er to him and

    therefore will unite with other feudal lords against all serfs:

    whe ther he par tic ipates in the explo itat ion of the serfs as an

    individual landowner, as a dignitary in a religious order or as a

    roy al official, is a secondary matter compared to this

    fundamental definition of his class position. For this reason,

    holders o f high office in a state based upo n feudal relations of

    exploitation are part of the feudal ruling class: both their ownexistence and the functions they fulfill in the state depend upon

    them identifying with the prevailing form of exploitation.

    In the same way , under mature capitalism, the directing layer in

    the state bureaucracy is dependent upon successful capitalist

    exploitation and accumulation. It cannot get the rev enues it

    requires if this is not happening. And so it is forced to pro vide

    conditions which will encourage capital accumulation within the

    boundaries o f its state on the o ne hand to make sure that

    resistance to exploitation by the mass of the population is kept

    to a minimum, on the other to enhance the competitiveness of

    nationally based capital as opposed to capital that is based

    abroad.

    Any state b ure auc racy which fails to acc omplish this is go ing to

    see the resourc es it needs for its own privileges and its own

    functioning dry up. Whether it likes it or not, it is com pelled to

    act as an agent of capital accumulation and to identify its own

    interests as national capitalist interests in opposition both to the

    interests of foreign capital and the working class.

    It is this requirement whic h sets the most fundamental limits tin

    the autonomy of the state. Just as the individual capitalist can

    choo se to enter in o ne line of business rather than another, but

    cannot avo id the compulsion to exploit and accumulate in

    whatev er line he go es into , so the state bureaucrac y can move in

    one direction or another, but cannot ignore the needs of national

    capital accumulation without risking its own longer term future.

    Its autonomy co nsists in a limited degree of freedom as to howit enforces the needs of national capital accumulation, not in any

    choice as to whether to enforce these or not.

    The dependence of the state bureaucracy on capitalist

    exploitation is often concealed by the way in which it raises its

    revenuesby tax ation of incomes and ex penditure, by

    gov ernment borrowing or by printing money. All of these

    activities seem, on the surface, to be quite different from

    capitalist ex ploitation at the point o f production. The state

    therefore seems like an independent entity which can raise the

    resources it needs by levy ing funds from any c lass in society.

    But this semblance o f independence disappears when the states

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    13/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 13

    activities are seen in a wider contex t. State rev enues are raised

    by tax ing indiv iduals. But indiv iduals will attempt to reco up

    their loss of purchasing power by struggles at the point of

    productionthe capitalists by try ing to enforce a higher rate o f

    exploitation, the workers by attempting to get wage increases.

    The balance of c lass forces determines the leeway which exists

    for the state to increase its rev enues. These are part of the total

    social surplus valuepart of the total amount by which the value

    of workers output exceeds the co st of reproducing their labour

    power (ie their take home wages).-

    In this sense, state revenues are co mparable to the otherrevenues that ac crue to different sections of capitalto the rents

    accruing to landowners, the interest going to money capital, the

    profits from trade go ing to commo dity c apital and so o n. Just as

    there is continual conflict between the different sections of

    capital over the sizes of these different revenues, so there is

    continual conflict between the state bureaucracy and the rest of

    the capitalist class over the size of its cut from the total surplus

    value.

    The state bureaucracy will, on o ccasions, use its own special

    position, with its monopoly of armed force, to make gains for

    itself at the expense o f others. In response to this, the other

    sections of capital will use their own special positionindustrial

    capital its ability to postpone investment, money capital itsability to move ov erseasto fight back. Yet in all this the

    different sections of capital cannot forget their mutual

    interdependence.

    The state, money capital and commodity capital cannot increase

    their revenues unless surplus value is being generated in the

    domain of production. Productive capital cannot get surplus

    value unless the state e nsures a plent iful supply of free labour

    with suffic ient skills , and pro vides means o f phy sic al de fenc e. I t

    also requires that co mmodity c apital ensures realisation o f the

    surplus value and that money c apital can provide the funds for

    further ex panding production. Commodity capital cannot

    function effectively unless the state lays the basis for the

    oper ation of a stable national market and uses its influence toopen up foreign markets.

    Each element branches out on its own, like nerves in a human

    body , but still canno t escape its dependenc e upon huge

    ganglions where it intertwines with all the others.

    These ganglions, knots where the mass of different capitals are

    entangled with the state bureaucracy they sustain and depend

    upon, are the national capitalist eco nomies.

    Those who run the different elements can act, up to a certain

    point, as if they had complete autonomy . In particular, money

    capital and commodity c apital can act as if they had no

    dependence upon the geographically ro oted means of

    production of industrial capital. In the same way, those who runthe state can act, up to a certain point, as if their rev enues did

    not depend upon successful capitalist exploitation and

    accumulation. This is what happens when reformists, populists

    or ev en fascists get co ntrol of parts of the state structure and use

    them to carry through social change.

    Y et at the end of the day the mutual interdepe ndence of the

    different eleme nts asserts itself in the most dramatic fashion,

    through crisesthe sudden collapse of the sy stem of credit, the

    sudden inability to sell the c ommodities, sudden balance of

    payment crises or e ven the threat of state bankruptcy. The

    autonomy of those who run the state is, in this sense, a bit like

    the autonomy of the banker, the commo dity speculator or the

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    14/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 14

    individual industrialist. Each is able, up to a c ertain point, to ac t

    as if the ov erall drive to ex ploit and accumulate can be ignored.

    The banker can lend without any real consideration of the ability

    of the debtor to pay back. The co mmodity speculator forgets the

    dependence of his profits on co nsumption that can o nly take

    place if there is an expansion of capitalist production. The

    individual entrepreneur can be lulled by temporary success and

    allow his enterprise to lag behind in the drive for further

    investment and innovation. Those who c ommand the state can

    embark on all sorts of ambitious schemes that weaken the ability

    of nationally based capital to c ompete with its rivals elsewhere.But all are eventually forced back into line by the pressures of

    the total system.

    This has v ery important implications for the class po sition o f

    those who direct the bureaucracies o f the state. They may not

    own individual chunks of capital. But they are forced to behave

    as agents of capital accumulation, to beco me, acco rding to

    Marxs definition, part of the capitalist class.

    Marx points out in Capital that with the advanc e of capitalist

    production there takes place a division of function within the

    capitalist class. The owners of c apital tend to play a less direct

    part in the actual organisation of production and ex ploitation,

    leav ing this to highly paid managers. But, insofar as thesemanagers continue to be agents of capital accumulation, they

    remain capitalists. The Austrian Marxist Hilferding developed

    the argument further, pointing to the divisions within a single

    capitalist class between the mass of rentier capitalists, who rely

    on a mor e or less fixed rate of return on their shares, and

    promoter capitalists who gain ex tra surplus value by gathering

    together the capital needed by the giant corporations.29 We can

    add a further distinction, between those who manage the

    accumulation of individual capitals and those who, through the

    state, seek to promo te the dev elopment of the sibling capitals

    operating within an individual statewhat may be called state

    capitalists or political capitalists.

    There are many finance capitalists who are also merchant

    capitalists and productive capitalists. There are many

    entrepreneurial capitalists who are also share owning capitalists.

    In the same way, those who concern themselves with

    accumulation at the nation state level o ften come from the ranks

    of entrepreneurial or shareholding capitalists and will often

    return there at a later date.

    So it is that in Britain the heads of giant private c ompanies hav e

    included individuals who made their careers first by rising to the

    top of nationalised corporations: in two well known cases, those

    of Alf Robens and Richard Marsh, using political succ ess within

    the Labour Party as a stepping stone to running the state

    corpo ral ions and then moving into the private sector. So it is

    that in France the career of Calvet, the head of the giant private

    sector c ar firm Peugeot, has involv ed spells in both public andpriv ate secto r. So it is that in Japan it is normal for people who

    have made careers in public agencies o f accumulation, like the

    powerful Ministry of International Trade and Industry, to mov e

    to top jobs in the private secto r. So it is in Italy that the

    management structure of the key nationalised enterprises, 1RI

    and ENI, has long been intertwined with the political hierarchie s

    of the gov ernmental parties, particularly the largest, the

    Christian Democ rats.

    One account of a notorious Italian financial scandal, by a

    Financial Times journalist, tells:

    To raise money in Italy is to secure a loan from a bank. The

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    15/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 15

    banks, ho wev er, can in turn be heav ily co nditioned by the

    politicians In the early 1 980s/ some three quarters of the

    Italian banking system was owned by the state. And in many

    cases the senior posts are po litically conditioned appointments,

    the accepted spoils of power 0

    In the 1 960s, the Christian Democratic Party move d to

    increase its control of the banking sy stem and the co nstellation

    of public sector corpo rations31 With the formation of centre

    left coalitions there was an intensifying struggle for top pub lic

    sector jobs between the different gov ernmental parties:

    The Christian Democ rats and Socialists have sp lit into factions

    competing as much against each o ther as against the theoretical

    Communist opposition These factions and cliqueshave found

    their new battlegro und in the banks and other appendages of the

    state.i2

    A new b reed o f entr epr ene ur was emerging. Te chnic ally its

    members represented state enterprise and the public sector; but

    in practice they mov ed like financial barracuda, acting

    sometimes on their own behalf, sometimes for their political

    patrons, but unfailingly with money from the public purse

    The fiercest of the b arrac uda was Eugenio Cefis, chairman o f ENI,

    the state oil group. And his hand was behind the most dramatic

    example of this politicisation of industry in 1 968, when ENI

    secretly built up a c on/rolling shareholding in Montedison,

    Italys biggest, and hitherto privately owned, chemical

    concern.^

    Y ears before this the fir st head of ENI, Enric o Mattei, had used

    the funds under his control to dominate the politiciansto the

    extent he was considered the most powerful single figure in

    Italy, ev en setting upwith funds that theoretically belonged to

    the statehis own newspaper, // Giorno.

    Today ENI is estimated to be the fourth biggest industrial

    corpo ration in the world o utside the US.*

    The individual political capitalists do not owe their highlyprivileged position in society to the size of their individual

    holdings of stocks and shares. Political influence and personal

    guile are usually the key. But they hav e in common with

    shareholders and private entrepreneurs an interest in

    maintaining the level of exploitation and accumulation. The

    Financial Times recently noted of France:

    The chairmen of state owned co mpanies are appointed for three

    year terms. The se day s the be st way of ensuring y ou r

    appointment is renewed whatever yo ur po litical friendships

    is to produce profits.

    In behaving like this, the state appointees behave as much like

    capitalistsas living embodiments of capital accumulation at the

    expense o f workersas do priv ate entrepreneurs or

    shareholders.

    Imperialism: the merger of finance

    capital, industrial capital and the state

    We are now in a pos itio n to make sense o f the m erging of the

    state and capital which was so central to the writings on

    imperialism of Lenin and Bukharin. The logic of capitalism lead s

    to the growing conc entration and c entralisation of capitalthe

    replacement of many small capitals by a few large ones. The

    groups of these that operate within any single country are

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    16/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 16

    dependent on each o ther and the national state, laying the basis

    for a new integration of industrial, commerc ial and finance

    capital around the state. Each national state becomes the nodal

    point around which capitals cluster, even when their activities

    lead them to branch o ut from it to penetrate the rest of the

    world.

    But that is not the end of the matter . The mutual

    interdependence of each national state and a few large capitals

    gives rise to a tendency for the boundaries between the state and

    the capitals to break down. The capitals turn increasingly to the

    direct use of personal influence (rather than the indirect use ofmarket pressures) to determine how the state acts, and the state

    bur eaucr acy inc reasingly interferes in the internal manageme nt

    of particular firms.

    The interpenetration of national capitals and the national state

    finds expression in an important change in the way in which

    capitalist competition itself takes place. It is increasingly

    regulated within national boundaries, while assuming the form of

    military, as well as (or even instead of) market competition

    internationally.

    This new dimension of co mpetition does not at all negate the

    dependence of the capitals and the state bureaucracy upon

    capitalist ex ploitation and accumulation. Acquisition of themeans of destruction on the necessary scale to assure success in

    war depends upon t he same driv es as ac quisition of the means of

    production on the necessary scale to assure success in the

    struggle for marketsthe driving down of wages to the c ost of

    reproduction of labour power, the driving up of the productivity

    of labour to the level which prev ails on a world scale (so that

    nothing is lost in translating national concrete labour into

    international abstract labour), and the drive to use the surplus

    for acc umulation.

    The only difference, in this respect, between military and

    economic competition is the form the accumulation takes

    whe ther it is in te rms of an ac cumulation of use v alues that can

    be u sed to pro duc e new go ods or of use v alue s that c an be used

    to wage war. In either c ase the importance of these use v alues to

    those co ntrolling them is determined by c omparison with use

    values e lsewhe re in the sy stem, a c omparison whic h transmutes

    them into exc hange values. As Lenin emphasised, periods of

    peaceful competition prepare the way for periods o f all out war,

    and periods of all out war prepare the way for periods

    ofpeaceful c ompetition.18

    So even in periods of peace the relations between the different

    capitals are not simply depe ndent, as in Marx s model in Capital,

    on their market relations. Conditions are those of an armed

    peace in which the re lative influence of the different states helps

    determine the relative success of the different blocs of capital

    associated with them. And this relative influence depends at the

    end of the day on their ability to acc umulate military hardware:it is this which determines their ability to build empires, acquire

    client states and create alliances.

    I hav e outlined the history o f this phase of capitalist

    dev elopment inExplaining the Crisis and there is no point in

    repeating it here. I tsuffices to say that the trend towards the

    merger o f state and industrythe imperialism of Lenin and

    Bukharinbegan in the late 19th Century. But it did not re ach its

    fullest dev elopment until the 1 930s,when individual private

    capitals seemed incapable of reco vering from eco nomic crisis if

    simply left to their own dev ices. Then for more than40 years the

    march o f statification seemed unstoppable. Everywhere the state

    sector grew remo rselessly, with state control o r ownership of

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    17/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 17

    basic older industrie s like co al, stee l, tr ansport and elec tricity

    generation, and state sponsorship (and sometimes ownership) of

    the most technologically advanced industries.

    The process went furthest, of course, in the bureaucratic state

    capitalisms o f the USSR, Eastern Europe and China. But in

    countries as diverse as Japan and Brazil, Argentina and Italy the

    state exercised an enormous degree o f influence ov er the

    activities of the great c orporations, private or nationalised,

    with peo ple flitt ing from high po sitions inside r uling parties or

    state bureaucracies to the management of the great corpo rations

    and back again. To be a power in the Japanese LiberalDemocrats, the Italian Christian Democrats or the Argentine

    Peronist Movement was to influence the decision makingand

    gain from the rev enuesof industry as we ll as the state. Eve n in

    the most liberal of the Western c apitalisms, that of the US, the

    key role o f the military sec tor gave the state enormous leverage

    and cabinets tended to be to a large extent staffed with

    corpo ration heads. What was good for General Motors was go od

    for the United States, and a Robert McNamara could move from

    helping to run Ford to bo mbing Vietnam and then to try ing, as

    head of the World Bank, to create succ essful capitalisms in the

    Third World.

    The rise of state capitalism was acc ompanied by a decline in the

    proportion of eco nomic transactions that crossed statefrontiers. Each national capitalist complex attempted to

    undertake as wide a range as possible of economic and military

    functions within its own boundaries, each trying to build

    national steel, car, chemical, shipbuilding, electronic, munitions

    and aircraft industries. Trade in manufactures as a proportion of

    world ou tput had risen from an index figur e of 1.0 in 1 900 to 1 .2

    in 1914. It fell back to 1.1 by 1920 and 1.0 in 1930 and then

    slumped to 0.7 in 1940 and 0.6 in 195 0.40

    Merchandise trade was equal to 43.5 percent of Britains national

    product before 191 4. In the 1950 s it was down at 30.4 percent.

    There was a similar decline for other co untries: from 11 .0 to 7 .9

    percent for the US, from 29.5 to 1 8.8 percent for Japan, from

    38.3 to 35.1 percent for Germany, from 28.1 to 25 perc ent forItaly.4 It reac hed its low point after the great slump of the

    193 0s, when all the major powers and many o f the minor o nes

    took the path of military state capitalism.

    For a generatio n, then, trade and financial flows between

    capitalist powers were subordinated to the demands of

    competitive accumulation within national state bo undaries.

    Transactions across state boundaries were dependent upon

    negotiations at the state lev el. The national stale prov ided each

    of the riv al sections of capital with:

    /) A geographic base for acc umulation of means of production

    and destructionie prov ision of trained labour power, priv ileges

    as against other foreign capitals within a certain terrain thro ugh

    subsidies, tariffs, exclusion of foreign produce, cheap stateproduced raw materials etc.

    ii)Military force to protect them against foreign slate capitals

    and to open up new areas o f privileged access.

    iii)

    iii) The orderly regulation o f commercial relations with other

    capitals (through a stable legal sy stem) and the prov ision of

    nationally based currency which can be manipulated against

    other currencies.

    iv)Protection against the sudden harm done to important

    sections of nationally based capital if other sections with which

    they were integrated suddenly c ollapsed.

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    18/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 18

    v )

    Mike Kidrons picture o f a world of self contained, co mpeting

    state capitals is very much an abstraction from this period. Y et

    as an abstraction it misses out v ery important elements of

    concrete reality. For the different phases in the cyc le of capital

    continue to ex ist even in a world o f state capitals, and the need

    to fulfil them leads to divergent pressures within the state-

    industrial complex .

    Thus even a self co ntained state capital can acc umulate more

    quickly if it can gain access to funds, to money capital, outside

    its boundaries. And some state capitals can increase their ownrates of acc umulation if they can invest o utside the national

    stateespecially if this provides privileged access to commodity

    markets. The fact that state diplomacy mediates the flow of

    money capital and commodities does not mean such flows do

    not occur.

    So even where there is a co mplete merger of the state and capital

    the different phases capital goes through create different interest

    groups within the single state capitalist class. Where a co mplete

    merger was never achieved in the first place, there are

    tendencies to wards fission as well as fusion. The different

    elements of capital and the state will be bound together, but will

    also be co ntinually try ing to pull apart.

    The differing pressures o f military and eco nomic c ompetition

    will l ikewise pro duc e a c ombination of div ergent and co nv ergent

    interests: sections of the state apparatus will identify with

    accumulation of military hardware and will succeed in getting

    sections of the industrial structure to make the same

    identification. Other sections of industry will be more interested

    in accumulation directed at market competition and will

    endeavour to win sections of the state bureaucracy to their side.

    The result is that even at the high point of state capitalism

    national planning was very much a my th: what in reality

    occ urred was a continual jockey ing for position between

    different interest gro ups, each using politic al influence to get its

    way . Y et ther e c ould nev er b e a c om plete b reakdo wn of the

    national entity since access lo political influence meant putting

    forward a programme which seemed lo relate to the interests of

    the whole state capital. The divergent particular interests of

    different sec tions of capital and the state were s till bound

    together by a mutual dependence on national accumulation and

    national state po wer.

    Beyond state capitalism

    The patterns of economic activ ity that characterised the period

    of state capitalism began to change during the great boo m of the

    195 0s and 1 960s. The state capitals increasingly traded with

    each otherand as they did so the basis was laid for a new

    internationalisation of production. World trade grew, on

    average, at about twice the rate of world output, until by the

    197 0s trade in manufactures was about the same proportion of

    world ou tput as it had been in 1 900 (and 1 930). And tr ade did

    not contract with the recessions of the mid-197 0s and early

    1980s as it had in the inter-war years. Despite a co ntraction of

    both wor ld output and wo rld trade in 1982 , trade grew faster

    than output throughout the rest of the 1 980s.42 The trade-

    output index so ared up to 1.4 by the mid 1980s4 and total world

    trade grew by 40 perc ent in six y ears.44

    But the bare figures understate the scale o f internationalisation

    in the long boom and after. In the pre-191 4 period a

    considerable amount of trade and a great amount of investment

    had been between colonial powers and their direct or indirect

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    19/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 19

    dependents. In the long boo m the greatest growth in trade was

    betwe en the adv anc ed industrial po wer s themselv es. So wher eas

    about 7 0 percent of Britains trade was with agricultural

    countries before 1 914, in the 1960s more than 7 0 percent was

    with industr ial c ountries.45

    There was a similar shift in the charac ter of inve stment. Whereas

    in 191 3 only 6 percent of British direct ov erseas investment had

    been in industry and trad e, in 195 8-61 20 per ce nt was in

    manufacturing alone.40

    Trade and investment in the long boom were increasinglybetwe en the adv anc ed industrial ec onomies themselv es. And so

    things continued into the 1980s. There had been a flow of trade

    and investment towards Newly Industrialising Countries and

    Eastern Europe (especially Poland and Hungary) in the 1 97 0s. In

    the 1980s the flow v irtually c eased exc ept in the case of the

    handful of countries around the rim of the Pacific (South Kore a,

    Taiwan, Thailand, Singapore, Hong Kong). There was a flow of

    capital from A frica and Latin America back to the advanced

    countries. And even the oil rich Middle Eastern states stagnated

    through that decade.

    What was happe ning was the integration of the e co nomies of the

    advanced world with each other and with the Pacific NICs. The

    behav iour o f muc h of the r est of the wor ld eco nomy became o fless concern to them. What is particularly important is the form

    this integration took. There had, of c ourse, always been trade

    betwe en national c apitalismsthis occ urr ed ev en at the high

    point of 1930 s state capitalism. There had also alway s been a

    mov ement of finance acro ss national bordersthe inability of

    national state gover nments to control such flows was an

    important facto r in leading them in the direc tion of state

    capitalism in the early 1 930s. But the direct organisation of

    production across national boundaries had been very rare

    indeed. Until the 1 950s it was virtually restricted to the

    integration of extractive industries in Third World countries (oil,

    palm oil, coc oa, etc) into the manufacturing needs of companies

    located within colonial powers.47

    The growth of industry through the long boo m, however, broke

    this pattern. The conc entration o f industry through takeovers

    and mergers, o ften under the tutelage of the state, had led to the

    emergence in particular countries of huge firms, able to c hannel

    resources into innovation and productive inve stment on a scale

    undreamt of before. They were not o nly able to dominate their

    national market but to carv e out huge c hunks of the world

    market for themselves, threatening to drive many o f their

    competitors out o f business. These in turn could only surv ive if

    they looked to an international mobilisation of resources, if they

    became multinational, not only whe n it came to trade b ut also

    whe n it c ame to pro duc tio n.

    Multinational firms (eg ITT, Ford, Coca Cola) had ex isted in the

    pre-war period. But they were not generally based uponintegrated international research and production: the British

    subsidiary of a US car firm would generally dev elop and market

    its own models independently of what happened in Detroit. It

    was this that be gan to c hange in the 1960s and 197 0s. The

    successful firms began to be those who operated international

    development, production and marketing strategies. A lready by

    the late 1950 s IBM (bolstered up by huge co ntracts for the US

    military) was able to dominate the new main frame c omputer

    industry world wide, Boeing (again bolstered by US military

    contracts) began to drive riv al national civil aviation firms into

    the ground, Ford and General Motors began in the mid-197 0s to

    talk of the world car, designed acc ording to a single set o f

    blueprint s and assembled fro m com ponents made in a do /en

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    20/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 20

    different countries. Petrochemical production ceased to be

    confined within individual European countries and came to

    involve elaborate pipelines carry ing materials from plant in one

    country to plant in others.

    A new stage of capitalist produc tion, base d upo n multinatio nal

    enterprises, had arrived. This was an o utgrowth of the prev ious,

    state capitalist, stage. Significantly, many of the most successful

    enterprises, whose c ompetitive edge pushed others in a

    multinational direction, were not themselves multinationals but

    very muc h ty pic al pr oduc ts o f the state c apitalist er a. The

    pressure of Japanese firms whose production facilities were stillvery muc h nat ionally based pushed For d and Gener al Motors to

    talk of the world c ar in the late 197 0s; the pressure of the US

    based Boeing for ce d the Euro pean ae rospace firms to pool their

    efforts in the pro duction of the A irbus; the nationally based

    Korean shipbuilding industry sc ooped the poo l, driving its rivals

    elsewhere to massive programmes of closure and cutback.

    But once the process of internationalisation of production was

    under way, there was no stopping it. By the late 1 980s there was

    hardly an industry in which firms in one country did not hav e to

    work out inter national strategies, based upo n buying up,

    merging with or estab lishing strategic alliances with firms in

    other countries.

    In motor s, the Japanese car firms established production

    facilities in the US, turning out more v ehicles than the third

    biggest A mer ican firm, Chrysler; the nationalised Fr enc h firm

    Renault began a series o f acquisitions in the US, beginning with

    the small fourth US car firm American Motors; Volv o too k over

    General Motors heavy truck production in the US; Ford and

    Volkswagen merge d their car pr oduc tion in Brazil; Nissan built

    an assembly plant in north east England to produce hundreds of

    thousands of cars a y ear, while Honda bought a 20 percent stake

    in Rover. In tyres, the French firm Michelin made itself the

    world s biggest produc er by taking over Uniro y al-Goodric h in

    the US in 1988, and Italian firm Pirelli, the worlds sixth b iggest,

    has been attempting to take over the worlds fourth biggest, the

    German Continental.

    In the construction machinery industry, the US firm Caterpillar

    and the Japanese firm Komatsu, the two firms which dominate

    internationally with more than half the world market between

    them, have both forged alliances with smaller firms across the

    globewith Komatsu taking ov er most of the o perations of the

    third largest US firm Dresser, and Caterpillar ex tending a

    manufacturing and design agreeme nt with Mitsubushi.

    GEC in Britain has merged its heav y engineering produc tion with

    the A lsthorn sub sidiary of CGE in France. CGE bought up I TTs

    European operations some y ears ago and has now do ne a deal

    with FIA T of Italy under whic h each gets a large minor ity

    shareholding in the other, while GEC has also jo ined with

    Siemens of Germany to take over the electronic firm Plessey.

    The cost of foreign acquisitions of US companies was 10.9 billion

    dollars in 1985, 24.5 billion in 1986, 40.4 billion in 1987 .

    Japanese firms owned a total o f about 9 b illion dollars worth o f

    US firms in 1987 , British firms about 24 billion dollars wo rth.48

    Total French acquisitions in the US rose from FFr7 6 billion in

    1988 to FFr10 8 billion in 1989.4

    The wave of international takeovers was acc ompanied by a wav e

    of joint ventures and cross-border alliances. The y ears 19 89-90

    saw:

    IBM with Siemens, Texas Instr uments with bot h Kobe Stell and

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    21/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 21

    Hitachi, Motorola with Toshiba , AT&T with bot h Mitsubishi

    Electr ic and NEC, Vo lvo with Renault and perhaps Mitsubishi

    Motors, Pilkingtons with Nippon Sheet Glass, Daimler Benz with

    Pratt & Whitney , and, grandest of all, Daimler Benz s (vague )

    collaboration with the Mitsubishi group.50

    This multinationalisation of produc tion was not co nfined to the

    advanced countries. It affected Third World and Newly

    Industrialising Countrieswhere statification of industry had

    previously tended to go e ven further than in the West.

    Argentina and Brazil were ty pic al. Their industr ial base had beenestablished in the 1940 s, 1950 s and 1960s by the state

    intervening to direct investment into heav y industryoften into

    state owned companies.51 But by the early 197 0s it became

    clear to the more farsighted industrialistswhether in the state

    or private sec torthat they co uld not get the resources and the

    access to the most modern technologies needed to keep up with

    worldwide produc tiv ity lev els unless they found way s of

    breaking thro ugh the co nfines of the natio nal eco nomy . They

    began increasingly to tur n to for eign multinatio nals for lic ensing

    agreements, joint production projects and fundsand they

    began to o per ate as multinationals in other cou ntries.

    A similar process has been at wo rk in Mexico, whe re the state

    and the single Institutionalised Revolutionary Party long play eda dominant role. In the last two decades there has been a big

    expansion of US subsidiaries in the norther n area, just inside

    Mexic os bor der with the US. A firm like Alfa, the largest

    industrial group in Mexico, with 109 subsidiaries spanning

    automotive c omponents, food, petrochemicals and steel, has

    had a growing number of joint operations with foreign firms. Its

    director of finance tells, Three quarters of our non-steel

    bus iness inv olves jo int v enture s. We have the c ulture of jo int

    venture s. Suc h dev elo pme nts hav e led so me le ft wingers to see a

    growth of neo-colonialism undermining national

    independence. But at the same time, some Mexican firms have

    themselves gone multinational, as with the glass maker Vitro

    which has bought two US companies and b ec om e the wo rld s

    leading glass container manufacturer, with its market almostequally split between the US and Mexico.

    The same transition is now beginning to take place in South

    Korea. Industrialisation under state direction built up heavy

    industry controlled by a handful of chaebol conglomerates.

    These were able to break into certain important world markets

    like steel and shipbuilding (where Korea overtook Japan 25

    years after Japan itself had overtake n Britain). But in the mid-

    1980s they saw the need to shift to the mass production of cars,

    electronics and petrochemicalsa step only possible on the

    basis o f a mult inational rather than a mainly national scale o f

    operations. Hy undai motors was 1 0 perce nt owned by

    Mitsubishi of Japan and discussed supply ing small cars for the

    US market with Ford , and Hyundai Electr onics se t up a small

    subsidiary of its own in Californias Silicon V alley and signed a

    deal (which the South Korean gov ernment vetoed) to assemble

    IBM computers. Meanwhile, in petrochemicals, both Samsung

    and Hyundai embarked in 1989-90 on a series of massive

    investments designed at sco oping not just the South Korean

    market, but that of the whole Pac ific basinin the face of bitter

    competition from r ival firms in Taiwan, Thailand, Singapore ,

    Malaysia and Indonesia.

    The pattern of multinationalisation of the advanc ed Western

    countries, the Third World and the NICs is now being repeated in

    the case o f Eastern Europe. As I hav e shown in previous articles,

    the first link ups between enterprise s in the then Eastern Bloc

    and the West were alread y taking place in the late 1 960s.M By

  • 7/27/2019 International Socialism_ the State and Capitalism Today

    22/42

    9/24/13 International Socialism: The state and capitalism today

    www.isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=234 22

    the late 1980s the process had a momentum of its own and was

    one of the factors leading sections of the nomenklatura in

    Eastern Europe to react to the political events of 1989 by

    breaking sharply from the co mmand eco nomy and e mbr ac ing

    talk of the free market. By late 1990 hardly a day went by

    without so me further report o f the sett ing up of joint com panies,

    of takeovers o r of new co -operation agreements between Eastern

    and Western enterp rises.

    The globalisation of finance

    The intemationalisation of finance has proceeded much fasterthan the internationalisation of production. There was always

    some lev el of bank lending acro ss national frontiers. But this

    grew explosive ly in the late 1960 s: foreign currency

    commitments of West European banks increased eightfold

    betwe en 1 968 and 1 97 4; be twe en 1 965 and 1 97 5 the c om bine d

    debt of 7 4 less developed co untries trebled. The crises of the

    mid-197 0s and early 1 980s did not stop the trend: in the course

    of the 1980s the debt o f the less developed c ountries doubled

    again; the United States move d from being a cre ditor nation to

    becoming a massiv e de btor ; by Septemb er 1985 total lending to

    the world banking sy stem totalled 2,347 billion dollars;55 the

    Eurobond market increased 7 0 perc ent in size in the single year

    of 1985, with total issues worth 1 34 billion dollars.

    Parallel with the growth in internatio nal banking went an

    explosive expansion of international currency deals, so that the

    total turnover was 15 0 billion dollars a day by 1984, twice the

    figure five y ears earlier. The expansion of finance ac ross national

    frontiers on this scale made attempts by gov ernments to control

    national banking systems seem increasingly futile. The 1980s

    saw a wav e of deregulation which fed back into the wo rlds

    financial systems enco uraging further cro ss-border flows. As the

    Financial Times noted in the mid-19 80s:

    As deregulatio n and tec hno logic al advanc e pul