institutional investor collective engagements: non

69
1 Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non-Activist Cooperation vs Activist Wolf Packs Gaia Balp * & Giovanni Strampelli ** ABSTRACT This Article sets out the first comprehensive analytical framework for non-activist shareholder cooperation, showing that coordinated engagement by non-activist institutions can be a promising lever by which to foster a more effective and viable corporate governance role for non-activist institutional investors and provide an alternative to activist-driven ownership involvement. After considering the diverging incentives structures of activist and non-activist investors and showing how they are reshaped in a context where investors collaborate in the engagement process, this Article shows how non-activist driven collective engagements are beneficial in several respects. Specifically, collective engagements favor the redistribution of engagement costs and, therefore, increase the net return earned by each institutional investor involved. In doing so, they also lower the free-rider problem, which generally affects institutional shareholders’ behavior. Moreover, the presence of a third-party entity coordinating the engagement initiatives can work as an effective tool for reducing potential regulatory risks, mainly concerning 13D group disclosures and Regulation FD. Against this background, this Article concludes that, in order to promote non-activist collective engagement initiatives, there is the need for the SEC to provide greater clarity concerning the circumstances under which engaging collectively through an enabling organization will not, as a rule, be regarded as control-seeking or acting in concert, and will not trigger group filing obligations under Section 13 of the Securities and Exchange Act. In addition, the SEC should explicitly recognize the role of such coordinating entities¾that adopt predefined frameworks governing the process of engagement and establish rules of conduct for participating investors¾in promoting collective engagement initiatives in line with the applicable regulatory framework. * Associate Professor of Business Law, Bocconi University, Milan. ** Full Professor of Business Law, Bocconi University, Milan. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Upload: others

Post on 05-May-2022

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

1

Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non-Activist Cooperation vs Activist Wolf Packs

Gaia Balp* & Giovanni Strampelli**

ABSTRACT

This Article sets out the first comprehensive analytical framework for non-activist shareholder cooperation, showing that coordinated engagement by non-activist institutions can be a promising lever by which to foster a more effective and viable corporate governance role for non-activist institutional investors and provide an alternative to activist-driven ownership involvement. After considering the diverging incentives structures of activist and non-activist investors and showing how they are reshaped in a context where investors collaborate in the engagement process, this Article shows how non-activist driven collective engagements are beneficial in several respects. Specifically, collective engagements favor the redistribution of engagement costs and, therefore, increase the net return earned by each institutional investor involved. In doing so, they also lower the free-rider problem, which generally affects institutional shareholders’ behavior. Moreover, the presence of a third-party entity coordinating the engagement initiatives can work as an effective tool for reducing potential regulatory risks, mainly concerning 13D group disclosures and Regulation FD. Against this background, this Article concludes that, in order to promote non-activist collective engagement initiatives, there is the need for the SEC to provide greater clarity concerning the circumstances under which engaging collectively through an enabling organization will not, as a rule, be regarded as control-seeking or acting in concert, and will not trigger group filing obligations under Section 13 of the Securities and Exchange Act. In addition, the SEC should explicitly recognize the role of such coordinating entities¾that adopt predefined frameworks governing the process of engagement and establish rules of conduct for participating investors¾in promoting collective engagement initiatives in line with the applicable regulatory framework.

* Associate Professor of Business Law, Bocconi University, Milan. ** Full Professor of Business Law, Bocconi University, Milan.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 2: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

2

I. INTRODUCTION .................................................................................................................... 3

II. SETTING THE SCENE ........................................................................................................... 8

A. Activist vs Non-Activist Institutional Investors............................................................. 8

B. Activism vs Engagement ............................................................................................ 11

III. DIVERGING INCENTIVE STRUCTURES ............................................................................... 17

A. Non-Activist Institutional Investors ........................................................................... 17

1. Collective Action Problems and Limited Benefits ................................................. 18

2. Cost Issues ............................................................................................................ 21

3. Reputational Incentives .......................................................................................... 23

B. Activist Institutional Investors ................................................................................... 25

1. Portfolio Concentration and “Two Twenty-Like” Rules ......................................... 25

2. The Absence of Business Ties With Investee Companies ....................................... 26

3. The Corporate Governance Limits of Hedge Fund Activism ................................. 27

IV. RECONSIDERING INCENTIVE STRUCTURES IN THE CONTEXT OF COLLECTIVE

ENGAGEMENT ................................................................................................................ 29

A. Activist-Driven Forms of Shareholder Cooperation .................................................. 30

1. Wolf Packs ............................................................................................................ 30

2. Non-Activist Institutions Teaming Up With Activists ............................................ 34

B. Different Forms of Non-Activist Collective Engagements .......................................... 35

1. Collective Engagements in Stewardship Codes ...................................................... 35

2. Investor Forums .................................................................................................... 38

3. Associations Representing Institutional Investors ................................................. 41

C. The Benefits of Non-Activist Collective Engagements ................................................ 45

1. Cost Sharing and Limiting Collective Action Problems ...................................... 45

2. Alleviating Regulatory Risks ............................................................................... 49

3. Enhancing Expertise ........................................................................................... 51

4. Reinforcing Reputational Incentives ................................................................... 53

V. IMPLICATIONS .................................................................................................................. 55

A. Smoothing the 13D Filing Obligation Hurdle ............................................................. 56

B. Limiting the Risk of Regulation FD Infringements ..................................................... 64

C. Recognizing the Facilitator Role of a Coordinating Entity ........................................ 65

VI. CONCLUSIONS ................................................................................................................. 68

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 3: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

3

I. INTRODUCTION

In a world where the agency ownership model of publicly traded shares is largely

predominant and the ownership of publicly listed corporations is increasingly institutionalized,

active institutional shareholders are considered key to firms’ corporate governance. The case

for institutional oversight is that “product, capital, labor, and corporate control market

constraints on managerial discretion are imperfect, corporate managers need to be watched by

someone, and the institutions are the only watchers available”.1 From the public policy

standpoint, institutional investors’ active ownership is believed to serve the efficient allocation

of capital to the most promising business ventures as well as informed corporate monitoring, so

as to ensure that the best possible use is made of the capital provided.2 Ownership engagement

by institutions is therefore regarded as essential to value creation, economic growth, and the

fostering of a well-functioning market economy.3

Ever since the late 1980s, many have viewed institutional investors as the potential sharp-

eyed natural champions of corporate monitoring and stewardship.4 Institutions holding large

blocks, more power and greater access to company information, along with the requisite skills,

behave differently‒so it is argued‒from dispersed individual investors and play a more active

corporate governance role. They reduce agency costs associated with the separation of

ownership and control and ultimately promote shareholder welfare. It is then asserted that

institutional shareholders monitor investments by voting and engaging informally through

dialogue with portfolio companies and support enhanced directors’ accountability; when

needed, they lever formal shareholder rights and run campaigns to challenge the board’s

authority.

By the end of the 1990s, however, supporters of institutional active ownership had to

acknowledge that only a small number of U.S. institutional investors, mostly public pension

plans, were actually active shareholders, and that institutions’ spending on governance efforts

1 Bernard S. Black, Agents Watching Agents: The Promise of Institutional Investor Voice, 39 UCLA L. REV.

811, 815 (1992). 2 See Serdar Çelik & Mats Isaksson, Institutional Investors and Ownership Engagement, 2013/2 OECD J.: FIN.

MKT. TRENDS 93, 104 (2014). 3 Id. See also INT’L CORP. GOV. NETWORK, GLOBAL STEWARDSHIP PRINCIPLES, https://www.icgn.org/

(conceiving of stewardship as part of a responsible investment approach owed by money managers to end-investors, aimed at preserving and enhancing long-term value and “overall financial market stability and economic growth”) [hereinafter, ICGN GSP].

4 See, e.g., Black, supra note 1; Ronald J. Gilson & Reinier Kraakman, Reinventing the Outside Director: An Agenda for Institutional Investors, 43 STAN. L. REV. 863 (1991).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 4: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

4

was very limited.5 Moreover, empirical evidence seemed not to convincingly support any

relationship between activism and company performance.6 Overall, shareholder activism,

conceived of “as proactive efforts to change firm behavior or governance rules”,7 proved to be

quite limited, and the skeptical view of the institutional investor as the shareholders' champion

appeared to be justified.8 Simply put, monitoring costs were considered likely to outweigh the

potential benefits of playing an active role.9 Collective action problems arising out of

institutions’ fractional ownership combined with regulatory impediments to communication

with fellow shareholders in disincentivizing shareholders’ joint action. The resulting mismatch

between private cost-bearing and collective gain-sharing with free-riding passive investors

frustrated the possibility of then playing an active role in corporate governance.10 Some

institutions’ pro-manager conflicts of interest, as well as shareholder-unfriendly corporate law

rules which generally favored entrenched boards, also contributed to passivity.11 Overall, with

rare exceptions, institutions appeared to be as rationally apathetic as individual shareholders.12

Since then, however, the features of shareholder activism have evolved and forces capable

of overcoming such disincentives have arisen. First, pension funds and other categories of

traditional institutions have increasingly left space for alternative institutional investors, such

as private equity firms and, particularly, hedge funds with more significant equity positions in

a limited number of individual companies and strong incentives for proactive, strategic

governance and performance intervention.13 Starting from the second half of the 2000s, hedge

5 Bernard S. Black, Shareholder Activism and Corporate Governance in the United States 459-465, in 3 THE

NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW (Peter Newman ed., 1998), https://ssrn.com/abstract=45100.

6 Id. 7 Id. 8 See Edward B. Rock, The Logic and (Uncertain) Significance of Institutional Shareholder Activism, 79 GEO.

L.J. 445 (1991). 9 See Jill E. Fisch, Relationship Investing: Will It Happen? Will It Work?, 55 OHIO ST. L.J. 1009 (1994). 10 See Stephen M. Bainbridge, Shareholder Activism and Institutional Investors 12-14 (Sept. 2005), UCLA

School of Law, Law & Econ. Research Paper No. 05-20, https://ssrn.com/abstract=796227. 11 See Black, supra note 1, at 822-827 (referring (i) to the cumulative chilling effect of blockholder filing

requirements under section 13(d) of the Securities and Exchange Act and related SEC rules, company poison pills, the SEC’s proxy rules and the shareholder proposal 14a-8 Rule, and (ii) to bank and insurers’ extensive dealings with corporate managers, managerial control over corporate pension funds, and public pensions funds’ responsiveness to political pressure).

12 See Bainbridge, supra note 10. 13 See Stuart L. Gillan & Laura T. Starks, The Evolution of Shareholder Activism in the United States, 19 J. OF

APPLIED CORP. FIN. 55, 55 (2007); Harwell Wells, A Long View of Shareholder Power: From the Antebellum Corporation to the Twenty-First Century, 67 FLA. L. REV. 1033, 1097 (2015); William W. Bratton & Joseph A. McCahery, Introduction to Institutional Investor Activism: Hedge Funds and Private Equity, Economics and Regulation, in INSTITUTIONAL INVESTOR ACTIVISM: HEDGE FUNDS AND PRIVATE EQUITY, ECONOMICS AND

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 5: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

5

funds have grown into prominent players in corporate monitoring and have boosted shareholder

activism at an unprecedented rate.14

Second, although it attracted much less attention than the rise of hedge funds, both

practitioners and scholars¾albeit still a limited number¾point to shareholder collective

initiatives as another means by which to voice concerns about corporate governance and

performance in a more effective and cost-saving manner.

Where individual blockholdings are small, weight matters. This means that collective action

can obviously be by far more convincing than independent conduct in pressurizing the board of

directors, holding the management accountable and assembling non-trivial voting power.15 In

addition, shareholder collective engagement initiatives can help to share costs, overcome

collective action problems and alleviate regulatory risks. 16

Against this backdrop, the form of coordinated intervention that has received most

consideration from corporate governance scholars and practitioners, and even lawmakers, is

possibly that of so-called wolf packs formed by like-minded activist hedge funds with the aim

of bringing about significant corporate changes at targeted companies.17

One further form of shareholder cooperation frequently in the spotlight is that which involves

non-activist institutions teaming up with activist shareholders, mostly following support-

seeking publicity via the press. Hedge funds that act as specialized “governance intermediaries”

by monitoring company performance and actively submitting proposals for business strategy

have proven to be a powerful driver for activating the reactive response from mainstream non-

activist institutions: “activists gain their power not because of their equity stakes, which are not

controlling, but because of their capacity to present convincing plans to institutional

REGULATION 2 (William W. Bratton & Joseph A. McCahery eds., 2015); U. Penn., Inst. for Law & Econ. Research Paper No. 16-12, https://ssrn.com/abstract=2785587.

14 See Thomas W. Briggs, Corporate Governance and the New Hedge Fund Activism: An Empirical Analysis, 32 J. CORP. L. 681, 682-684 (2007).

15 See, e.g., Bernard S. Black, Shareholder Passivity Reexamined, 89 MICH. L. REV. 520, 523-24 (1990) (however highlighting legal obstacles to shareholder coordination); Stuart L. Gillan & Laura T. Starks, Corporate Governance Proposals and Shareholder Activism: The Role of Institutional Investors, 57 J. FIN. ECON. 275, 276 and 303 (2000) (finding that shareholder proposals sponsored by coordinated groups—investor associations or investment groups—were able to garner substantially more voting support than proposals sponsored by individuals); Tim C. Opler & Jonathan Sokobin, Does Coordinated Institutional Activism Work? An Analysis of the Activities of the Council of Institutional Investors 5 (Dice Center for Res. in Fin. Econ., Working Papers Series 95-5) (1995), https://ssrn.com/abstract=46880 (showing that coordinated engagements facilitated by the Council of Institutional Investors (CII) positively impact target firms’ performance, “consistent with the view that coordinated monitoring and ‘quiet’ governance activism by institutional investors is effective”).

16 See infra Part IV.C. 17 See infra part IV.A.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 6: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

6

shareholders, who ultimately will decide whether the activists' proposed plan should be

followed”.18

However, these are not the examples of shareholder coordination to which this Article seeks

to draw attention. In order to fill a gap within the existing legal scholarship, drawing on

empirical and anecdotal evidence of the relevance of such an alternative shareholder

cooperation model that does not mean to achieve or influence corporate control,19 we analyze

a non-activist-driven approach to collective engagement, which is based on the coordination

function performed by a third-party enabling entity.20

Over the last few years, representative organizations, such as, to some extent, the Council of

Institutional Investors in the U.S., and even more so the Institutional Investors’ Forum in the

UK, Eumedion in the Netherlands, Assogestioni in Italy, and many more, have emerged as a

cost-saving and efficient tool for supporting institutions’ active stewardship collectively and

“mak[ing] the case for long-term investment approaches.”21 Organizations that provide affiliate

institutions with corporate governance services and actively lobby to consolidate investors’

votes and encourage dialogue with corporations have proven to be effective in stimulating the

collective involvement of institutional shareholders with investee companies in spite of their

weak individual incentives and the free-rider disincentive. Since the engagement strategies,

programs and agendas promoted are chiefly based on the constructive discussion of key issues

with portfolio companies to convey investors’ shared views without asking for significant

corporate changes nor intervening in the details of the management decision-making, the

coordinating organizations typically adopt a non-confrontational and collaborative stance.

Institutional investor organizations are a collective monitoring tool aimed at minimizing

institutions’ stewardship costs, hence reducing corporate agency costs and enhancing the

collective voice of investors. Thus, coordinating organizations promote an institutional

investor-driven model of non-activist, relationship-building corporate monitoring and oversight

that is fundamentally different from that adopted by activist hedge funds and wolf packs.22

18 Gilson & Gordon, supra note 35, 867, 897-8. 19 See infra, Part IV.C.1. 20 See infra, Part III.C. 21 FIN. CONDUCT AUTHORITY & FIN. REPORTING COUNCIL, BUILDING A REGULATORY FRAMEWORK FOR

EFFECTIVE STEWARDSHIP 5 Discussion Paper DP19/1 (2019), https://www.fca.org.uk/publications/discussion-papers/dp19-1-building-a-regulatory-framework-effective-stewardship.

22 See generally Sharon Hannes, Super Hedge Fund, 40 DEL. J. CORP. L. 163, 186 (2015).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 7: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

7

The importance of promoting the corporate-governance role of coordinated non-activist

shareholders is further underscored when the re-concentration of U.S. corporate ownership and

the concentration of the asset management industry is taken into account. There is little doubt,

in fact, that corporate ownership, asset and asset industry concentration render institutions’

stewardship inescapable. This is even more so the case if it is considered that, over time, the

increases in both institutional ownership and ownership concentration have prompted

regulatory action aimed at enhancing institutions’ “responsibilities” in performing the corporate

governance functions associated with share ownership.23 Furthermore, the promotion of cost-

effective pathways for institutions’ collective monitoring can also help to activate passively

managed funds with particularly weak financial incentives for being active and attentive

owners, and to counteract the potential for “unthinking and automated approach to governance

that is unlikely to be in the company’s best interest”.24

Against this backdrop, this Article seeks to provide a comprehensive analytical framework

for non-activist shareholder cooperation by extending the perspective for analysis beyond

hedge-fund wolf packs and activist-driven teaming up. It aims to demonstrate that coordinated

engagement by non-activist institutions can be a promising lever by which to foster a more

convincing and viable corporate governance role for non-activist institutional investors and

provide an alternative to activist-driven ownership involvement.

With a view to illustrating how collective engagement can be key in making non-activist

institutional investor stewardship more effective and can provide an actual alternative to hedge

fund-driven activism, this Article proceeds as follows. Part II sets the scene by drawing some

relevant distinctions. In order to examine the issue of collaboration between non-activist

institutions, it is first necessary to draw a clear distinction between activist and non-activist

shareholders, as well as the non-overlapping notions of activism and engagement. Based on

these distinctions, Part III examines the diverging incentives structures underlying activist and

non-activist investors’ ownership within a context of solo-engagement. Part IV reconsiders

those incentives structures in a context where investors collaborate in the engagement process.

First, we provide an overview of the different types of shareholder coordination that take place

in the practice. Taking account of the recommendations made by a growing body of soft

regulation—chiefly stewardship codes and principles—we highlight the distinction between

activist-driven and non-activist-driven forms of shareholder collaboration. Second, we contend

23 See infra Part III.A.3. 24 See Dorothy Shapiro Lund, The Case Against Passive Shareholder Voting, 43 J. CORP. L. 493, 510 (2018).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 8: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

8

that hedge-fund wolf packs and the activist-driven receptive teaming up phenomenon need to

be kept distinct from the non-activist collective engagements that are recommended by the

stewardship principles adopted in several countries.25 This is because these forms of

shareholder collaboration substantially differ in terms of the potential up- and downsides of

their operation. We then analyze the potential benefits of collective engagements and how they

can stimulate institutions’ active ownership. Part V examines the regulatory framework

applicable to the various types of shareholder collaboration, showing that they need to be kept

separate also from the regulatory standpoint. Crucially, we contend that, if collective

engagement is to be incentivized to promote non-activist stewardship as an actual alternative to

activist-driven share ownership, it is necessary to clarify the grey areas still remaining within

the relevant regulatory framework. In particular, regulators should acknowledge the facilitating

role played by third-party coordinating entities and provide greater clarity concerning the

circumstances in which collective engagement through an enabling organization will not, as a

rule, be regarded as control-seeking or concerted action and will not trigger group filing

requirements under Section 13 of the Securities and Exchange Act. Part VI concludes.

II. SETTING THE SCENE

Before examining institutional shareholder collaboration and its role in corporate

governance, it is first necessary to set the conceptual framework and the definitions that are

relevant for the purposes of this Article. Within the debate on shareholder activism, the very

notion of activism is usually used to refer to any kind of ownership engagement by institutional

investors, irrespective of its specific character or degree, which may vary, and investor

characteristics. However, there are significant differences between being, or not being, an active

shareholder, which mainly depend on the business model of the relevant investor. Thus, the

undifferentiated use of the term “activism” may be misleading. Accordingly, some distinctions

must be drawn for the purposes of the following analysis.

A. Activist vs Non-Activist Institutional Investors

25 See generally Jennifer G. Hill, Good Activist/Bad Activist: The Rise of International Stewardship Codes, 41

SEATTLE U. L. REV. 497 (2018).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 9: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

9

As early as 1994, Briggs clearly stated his position concerning the concept of shareholder

activism, noting that “[a]ctive investors … are not "typical" institutional investors”.26 The latter

were, in fact, essentially passive shareholders. Briggs drew the attention to “several kinds of

private investment funds commonly known as hedge, risk arbitrage, value investment or vulture

funds” for whom

“‘[A]ctivism" does not mean putting a resolution on management's proxy card

asking shareholders to vote to end discriminatory employment practices or redeem

a poison pill. For these investors, activism means securing board representation

with a view to fundamentally changing a company's policies, dismissing

management or taking over a company’”.27

Traditional institutional investors, such as public and private pension plans, actively

managed mutual funds and insurance companies, could not reasonably be expected to be truly

activist shareholders. Portfolio diversification and fragmentation predicted that these

institutions would be likely to dedicate attention to “process and structure issues”, rather than

company-specific concerns.28 They would not exert day-to-day control over individual investee

companies, and would be even less likely to engage in company-specific “micro-

management”.29 Institutions would engage with portfolio companies chiefly concerning general

issues such as antitakeover devices, plurality voting, the composition and structure of the board

of directors, director elections and compensation.30

In fact, the issue at the very roots of the large differences in the quality and quantity of

ownership involvement with portfolio companies is the varying features and choices that define

institutional investors’ business models.31 Çelik and Isaksson identify seven factors, each of

which must be further distinguished based on a set of options available to the institution, which

taken together shape the institution’s business model and determine its likely attitude towards

ownership engagement.32 These factors include: the purpose of the institution (for profit or not

for profit); its liability structure, in terms of whether or not an institution is under a profit

26 Thomas W. Briggs, Shareholder Activism and Insurgency under the New Proxy Rules, 50 BUS. LAW. 99,

147 (1994). 27 Id. at 101-102. 28 See Marcel Kahan & Edward B. Rock, Index Funds and Corporate Governance: Let Shareholders be

Shareholders 4-5, 34-35 (NYU L. Econ. Res. Paper No. 18-39) (2019), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3295098 29 Black, supra note 1, at 818. 30 Id. See also Kahan & Rock, supra note 28, at 35. 31 See Çelik & Isaksson, supra note 2, at 93. 32 Id. at 105, table 1.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 10: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

10

maximizing obligation towards its owners; the investment strategy (ranging from passive

indexing to active fundamental, up to purely quantitative active strategies); the portfolio

structure (whether concentrated or diversified); the fee structure (ranging from performance

through flat fees, to no fees); and an institution’s possible political or social objectives. The

applicable regulatory framework also contributes to shaping an institution’s behavior as an

owner, depending on whether any requirements, or limitations, are set as regards an institution’s

engagement with investee companies, e.g. voting and voting disclosure requirements, or voting

prohibitions.33

Along the same lines, Kahan and Rock attribute the diverging features of hedge fund and

traditional institutions’ activism to the differences between the underlying business models, the

resulting incentive structures and the set of regulatory and political constraints, as well as

conflicts of interests which are largely typical for traditional institutions.34 Also according to

Gilson and Gordon, the business models, and the resulting incentives structures, explain why

traditional institutions usually adopt a passive, or at best a reactive, stance towards engagement

with portfolio companies.35 Furthermore, Bebchuk, Cohen and Hirst consider that the structural

incentive problem that negatively affects stewardship by actively managed mutual funds and

index funds with a significant share of the market for managed investments is likely to

undermine the effectiveness of any principle or guideline put forward by stewardship codes.36

Following this line of reasoning, it is clear that engagement remains a costly endeavor, which

cannot easily be aligned with traditional investors’ prevailing business models—which are

primarily based on asset diversification and, as a consequence, portfolio fragmentation—and

the corresponding incentive structures. The inadequate incentives hypothesis points to a number

of factors that characterize the industry structure as the primary explanation for traditional

institutions’ reduced levels of engagement.37 These factors include: the highly competitive

structure of the market for money managers, which puts pressure on lowering costs; rational

33 Id. at 111, table 2. 34 See Marcel Kahan & Edward B. Rock, Hedge Funds in Corporate Governance and Corporate Control, 155

U. PA. L. REV. 1021, 1060-70 (2007). 35 Ronald J. Gilson & Jeffrey N. Gordon, The Agency Costs of Agency Capitalism. Activist Investors and the

Revaluation of Governance Rights, 113 COLUM. L. REV. 863, 867; Paul H. Edelman, Randall S. Thomas & Robert B. Thompson, Shareholder Voting in an Age of Intermediary Capitalism, 87 S. CAL. L. REV. 1359, 1408 and 1415-1417 (2014).

36 See Lucian A. Bebchuk, Alma Cohen & Scott Hirst, The Agency Problems of Institutional Investors, 31 J. OF ECON. PERSPECTIVES, 89, 108 (2017).

37 Edward Rock, Institutional Investors in Corporate Governance, in THE OXFORD HANDBOOK OF CORPORATE LAW AND GOVERNANCE 373-4 (Jeffrey N. Gordon & Wolf-Georg Ringe eds., 2018).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 11: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

11

apathy and the free rider problem; the institutions’ revenue model which, being typically a

percentage of assets under management, encourages increases in funds’ size and complexity;

the perverse incentives of asset managers based on a fund’s relative performance, which

improves where underweighted portfolio companies perform badly; the enduring belief that

involvement in corporate governance reduces resources that could be better employed in

selecting investments in order to increase the fund’s relative performance—and portfolio

managers’ compensation; and finally the various conflicts of interests facing asset managers.38

Hence, based on their strongly diverging incentives, activist shareholders should be kept

distinct from non-activist shareholders. Such a distinction, which draws on investors’ natural

attitudes towards share ownership, as shaped by the business model adopted, is useful in order

to explain the determining features and different patterns of shareholder collaboration and to

analyze how they impact the corporate governance role of institutional investors. For the

purposes of this Article, we shall therefore refer to fundamentally “activist” and “non-activist”

institutions as meaning, respectively, investors with high incentives for strategic, proactive, and

costly, company-specific governance and performance intervention (as exemplified by

alternative institutions such as activist hedge funds and private equity funds), and on the other

hand investors with weak incentives for activism other than low-cost engagement, such as most

traditional institutions with active or passive investment strategies.

B. Activism vs Engagement

In keeping with the broadening of the gap between the actual behavior of activist and non-

activist institutional shareholders as owners, the rise of hedge fund activism has contributed to

somehow shifting the original meaning of the notion of shareholder activism towards a more

strategic and often confrontational kind of governance and performance engagement. Hedge

fund activism typically embraces “any actual or overtly threatened proxy contest or any other

concerted and direct attempt to change the fundamental strategic direction of any solvent […]

public corporation other than a mutual fund”.39 Based on costly fundamental and company-

specific analysis, activists seek specific targets for investment, typically picking the stocks of

underperforming companies, with a view to bringing about a significant change in corporate

governance practices, business plans and operations, capital structure or strategic direction. In

functional terms, the activist takes up a significant but non-controlling equity position in the

38 Id. 39 Briggs, supra note 14, at 695.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 12: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

12

target company and starts to step up pressure—from persuasion behind the scenes through to

proxy contests—to bring about the particular changes advocated. Activists seek to benefit from

the improved stock price performance returns that usually follow responsive changes by

company management.40

By contrast, the promise of traditional non-activist institutional shareholder initiatives was

originally conceived of as lying with voting and voicing their views, the latter involving

primarily informal shareholder monitoring efforts, as well as, on a residual basis, reacting to

unresponsiveness to investors’ demands.41 Over the last decade, the stewardship efforts of

traditional institutions have increasingly focused on dialogue with portfolio companies, which

in many cases occurs privately. A survey of large institutional investors—chiefly U.S.,

continental European and UK asset managers, mutual funds and pension funds—has found that

the use of private discussions with management or members of the board of directors is

widespread, which supports the view that “investors try to engage firms behind the scenes

through direct negotiations, and take public measures (e.g., shareholder proposals, public

criticism) only if these private interventions fail”.42 In effect, discussions with the management

have been found to be the mostly frequently used channel for engagement, followed by voting

against the management.43 Alongside the ability to voice their views when dissatisfied with a

firm’s governance, respondent institutions reported that they also use, on a complementarily

basis, exit, or the threat thereof, as a disciplinary governance mechanism.44 By contrast, the

submission of shareholder proposals as a corporate governance mechanism was reported to be

used far less frequently, as also were the initiation of legal action against, and the public

criticism of, portfolio companies.45

40 See Brian R. Cheffins & John Armour, The Past, Present, and Future of Shareholder Activism by Hedge

Funds, 37 J. Corp. L. 51, 57 (2011); Bebchuk et al., supra note 36, at 104-05 (explaining that activists’ incentives to spend on stewardship depend on the likeliness of inducing large governance-generated value increases); William W. Bratton, Hedge Funds and Governance Targets, 95 GEO. L.J. 1375, 1379 (2007).

41 Black, supra note 1, at 817; see also supra notes 29-30 and accompanying text. Non-activist investors’ voice has also taken the form of shareholder proposals which, in spite of being precatory, have proven to prompt management to effect the changes sought. See Yonca Eritmur, Fabrizio Ferri & Stephen R. Stubben, Board of directors’ responsiveness to shareholders: Evidence from shareholder proposals, 16 J. CORP. FIN. 53, 58-59 (2010).

42 Joseph A. McCahery, Zacharias Sautner & Laura T. Starks, Behind the Scenes: The Corporate Governance Preferences of Institutional Investors, 71 J. OF FIN. 2905, 2912 (2016).

43 Id. at 2911-13. 44 Id. at 2913, 2918-20. 45 Id.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 13: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

13

In line with the findings that non-activist institutional investors’ preferences focus on

dialogue, scholars emphasize that “[i]ncreasingly, the insider-shareholder dynamic in the

modern corporation is collaborative, not competitive”, with institutional investors being at the

forefront of such “constructivist” trend offering “a new source of well-resourced and

sophisticated knowledge from outside the corporation” which complements that of insiders.46

According to McCahery et al., institutions’ engagement is primarily triggered by inadequate

corporate governance and excessive compensation, as well as disagreement with long-run

strategic issues—e.g. large diversifying mergers or acquisitions.47 On the other hand,

dissatisfaction with company performance does not seem to be a key driver of shareholder

engagement.48 Hence, mainstream institutions’ ownership engagement is mostly about exerting

a monitoring function and providing portfolio companies with valuable informational inputs.49

Therefore, when compared to situations involving more aggressive activism in which “hedge

funds can often shape a firm’s business policy unilaterally”,50 terms such as shareholder

engagement, or, as a broader category, stewardship—which have grown popular with the rise

of best practice codes and principles for institutional investors—appear to be capable of

capturing the actual meaning, and the extent, of non-activist investors’ behavior as owners

much better than the term activism. As compared to activism, the milder terms “engagement”

and “stewardship” point towards a kind of active—but non-activist—ownership the approach

of which to portfolio companies is by far less adversarial, more collaborative, and primarily

based on mutual understanding. At the same time, engagement and stewardship obviously

assume investee companies to be attentive and responsive to investors’ concerns.51

Initially, the concepts of engagement and stewardship may perhaps have been more familiar

with the European context, where pioneering pieces of soft regulation developed and took hold

more readily than in the United States. Those concepts were first established in a systematic

way thanks to the UK Stewardship Code published by the Financial Reporting Council in July

46 Jill. E. Fisch & Simone M. Sepe, Shareholder Collaboration 3, 5 (Eur. Corp. Gov. Inst. (ECGI) Law

Working Paper No. 415/2018) (July 25, 2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3227113 (emphasis in original). 47 McCahery et al., supra note 42, at 2924. 48 Id. 49 See Fisch & Sepe, supra note 46, at 14-5. 50 Id. at 11. 51 See, e.g., ICGN GSP, at 22.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 14: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

14

2010.52 Based on the premises that responsibility for stewardship of publicly listed companies

is shared between the board, which oversees its management, and investors, who hold the board

accountable for its responsibilities, in its current version the Code explains that stewardship is

more than just voting:

“Stewardship activities include monitoring and engaging with companies on matters such

as strategy, performance, risk, capital structure, and corporate governance, including

culture and remuneration. Engagement is purposeful dialogue with companies on these

matters as well as on issues that are the immediate subject of votes at general meetings”.53

The Code states that effective monitoring is an essential component of stewardship

(Principle 3), and that institutional investors should establish clear guidelines on when and how

they will escalate their stewardship activities, regardless of whether an active or passive

investment policy is followed (Principle 4). While initial discussions concerning investors’

concerns should take place on a confidential basis, if companies do not respond constructively,

then institutional investors should consider whether, e.g., to hold additional meetings with

management specifically in order to: discuss concerns; express concerns through the company’s

advisers; meet with the chairman or other board members; intervene jointly with other

institutions on particular issues; make a public statement in advance of general meetings; submit

resolutions and speak at general meetings; and requisition a general meeting, in some cases

proposing changes to board membership.54

Similarly, in the Stewardship Code drafted in 2017 by the European Fund and Asset

Management Association (hereinafter, EFAMA)—a revision of its 2011 Code of External

Governance—the concept of stewardship covers the monitoring of, voting the shares of, and

engagement with, investee companies. Stewardship is defined as

“engagement, i.e. the monitoring of and interaction, with investee companies, as well as

exercising voting rights attached to shares. Engagement can be on matters such as:

business strategy and its execution; risk management; environmental and social concerns;

corporate governance issues such as board composition and the election of independent

directors, together with executive remuneration; compliance, culture and ethics; and

52 FIN. REP. COUNCIL (FRC), THE UK STEWARDSHIP CODE (July 2010),

https://www.frc.org.uk/getattachment/e223e152-5515-4cdc-a951-da33e093eb28/UK-Stewardship-Code-July-2010.pdf.

53 FIN. REP. COUNCIL (FRC), THE UK STEWARDSHIP CODE (Sept. 2012), https://www.frc.org.uk/getattachment/d67933f9-ca38-4233-b603-3d24b2f62c5f/UK-Stewardship-Code-(September-2012).pdf., Guidance to Principle 1 [hereinafter UK Stewardship Code 2012].

54 Id., Guidance to Principle 4.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 15: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

15

performance and capital structure. Asset managers have a duty to act in the best interests

of their clients as they are entrusted with their money.”55

EFAMA Principles are intended to enhance the quality of dialogue with companies, and “do

not constitute an obligation to micro-manage or intervene in the day-to-day affairs of investee

companies or preclude a decision to sell a holding where that is the most effective response to

such concerns.”56

Even European legislation has explicitly embraced the concept of engagement. Directive

(EU) 2017/828 of 17 May 2017 amended Directive 2007/36/EC—the so-called Shareholders’

Rights Directive (hereinafter, SRD II)—precisely “as regards the encouragement of long-term

shareholder engagement”.57 Based on “clear evidence” of the inadequacy of the current level

of institutional monitoring of, and engagement with, portfolio companies, and the excessive

focus on short-term returns, the SRD II is aimed at encouraging long-term shareholder

engagement.58 According to the SRD II, “effective and sustainable shareholder engagement is

one of the cornerstones of the corporate governance model of listed companies”.59 Hence,

Article 3(g) of the SRD II requires Member States to ensure (on a comply-or-explain basis) that

institutional investors and asset managers “develop and publicly disclose an engagement

policy” describing

“how they monitor investee companies on relevant matters, including strategy, financial

and non-financial performance and risk, capital structure, social and environmental

impact and corporate governance, conduct dialogues with investee companies, exercise

voting rights and other rights attached to shares, cooperate with other shareholders,

communicate with relevant stakeholders of the investee companies and manage actual

and potential conflicts of interests in relation to their engagement.”60

While it is rooted in Europe, in recent years the need for non-activist institutional investors’

engagement has gained momentum also in the United States, where it is conceived of as the

55 EUR. FUND AND ASSET MANAG’NT ASS’N (EFAMA), STEWARDSHIP CODE. PRINCIPLES FOR ASSET

MANAGERS’ MONITORING OF, VOTING IN, ENGAGEMENT WITH INVESTEE COMPANIES (2018), https://www.efama.org/Publications/Public/Corporate_Governance/EFAMA%20Stewardship%20Code.pdf.

56 Id. at 5. 57 Directive (EU) 2017/828 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 17 May 2017 amending Directive

2007/36/EC as regards the encouragement of long-term shareholder engagement, 2017 O.J. (L 132), 1 [hereinafter, SRD II].

58 See Recitals 2 and 3 of SRD II. 59 See Recital 14 of SRD II. 60 Article 3(g) (1)(a) of SRD II.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 16: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

16

missing middle-ground approach within the polarized board-versus-shareholder debate, and,

alongside voting, as “another legitimate mechanism for influencing management and

potentially bringing about change”.61 Indeed, successful engagement can bring about changes

at portfolio companies as “the result of a consensus process”.62

The same collaborative tone shapes the relationship between institutional shareholders and

corporations in at least four different¾fairly new¾sets of corporate governance and

stewardship principles, as well as similar initiatives, which recommend non-activist

institutional investor engagement in line with the model initially set out by the UK Stewardship

Code.

First, Martin Lipton’s “New Paradigm” to corporate governance provides “a synthesis of the

corporate governance codes applicable in a number of markets and various efforts underway to

articulate a new corporate governance framework”. 63 The New Paradigm was proposed in 2016

under the auspices of the International Business Council of the World Economic Forum with

the aim of achieving “sustainable long-term investment and growth” and countering short-

termism in managing and investing in businesses. Subsequent updates provide guidance on the

practice of engagement and stewardship, suggesting, inter alia, that investors “should raise

critical issues to companies as early as possible in a constructive and proactive way, and seek

to engage in a dialogue before submitting a shareholder proposal. Public battles and proxy

contests have real costs and should be viewed as a last resort where constructive engagement

has failed”.64

Second, the Commonsense Principles of Corporate Governance, drafted by representatives

of some of America’s largest corporations and institutional investors, also underscore the

importance of a company’s engagement with shareholders and receiving feedback concerning

matters that are relevant to long-term shareholder value, and recommend that the CEO should

61 Matthew J. Mallow & Jasmin Sethi, Engagement: The Missing Middle Approach in the Bebchuck-Strine

Debate, 12 NYU J. L. & BUS. 385, 392 (2016). See also Fisch & Sepe, supra note 46, at 19-20. 62 Id. at 20. 63 See Martin Lipton et al., The New Paradigm. A Roadmap for an Implicit Corporate Governance Partnership

Between Corporations and Investors to Achieve Sustainable Long-Term Investment and Growth 6 (2016), http://www.wlrk.com/docs/thenewparadigm.pdf.

64 Martin Lipton et al., Some Thoughts for Boards of Directors in 2019 (Including The New Paradigm: A Roadmap for an Implicit Corporate Governance Partnership Between Corporations and Investors to Achieve Sustainable Long-Term Investment and Growth) 18 (2018), http://www.wlrk.com/webdocs/wlrknew/WLRKMemos/WLRK/WLRK.26288.18.pdf

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 17: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

17

actively engage with corporate governance and key shareholder issues when meeting with

shareholders.65 The Principles also recommend that

“Asset managers should actively engage, as appropriate, based on the issues, with the

management and board of the company, both to convey the asset manager’s point of view

and to understand the company’s perspective. Ideally, such engagement will occur early

in the process to facilitate alignment on resolution of issues where possible and avoid

unnecessary disruption. Asset managers should give due consideration to the company’s

rationale for its positions, including its perspective on certain governance issues where

the company might take a novel or unconventional approach.”66

Finally, further groups have also adopted analogous self-regulatory and non-binding

initiatives. The Investor Stewardship Group (hereinafter, ISG) published its Framework for

U.S. Stewardship and Governance, which came into effect in January 2018, recommending that

institutional investors address and attempt to resolve differences with companies in a

constructive and pragmatic manner.67 The Business Roundtable published its Principles of

Corporate Governance in 2016, likewise emphasizing the importance of constructive

engagement with long-term shareholders.68

III. DIVERGING INCENTIVE STRUCTURES If the actual behavior of activist and non-activist institutional shareholders as owners is so

radically different, this is largely due to their diverging incentives structure, which

fundamentally contributes to shaping investors’ conduct. Once again, those differing economic

incentives can be illustrated by examining more closely the opposition between non-activist

and activist institutional investors.

A. Non-Activist Institutional Investors

65 The Commonsense Principles of Corporate Governance 2.0 are hosted on the Columbia Law School

Millstein Center webpage, https://millstein.law.columbia.edu/content/commonsense-principles-20. 66 See Commonsense Principles of Corporate Governance 2.0, VIII(a). 67 See Stewardship Principle E, https://isgframework.org/. 68 BUS. ROUNDTABLE, PRINCIPLES OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE, 26 (2016),

https://s3.amazonaws.com/brt.org/Principles-of-Corporate-Governance-2016.pdf.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 18: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

18

The long-standing collective action and limited benefits problems, alongside conflicts of

interest,69 are the main obstacles to active ownership by mainstream institutional investors.

Nevertheless, as the conduct of some leading fund managers seems to suggest, reputational

concerns can prompt fund managers to increase their investments in stewardship and play a

more active monitoring role in relation to investee companies.

1. Collective Action Problems and Limited Benefits

As is known, portfolio diversification only allows investors to take limited advantage of

successful individual stewardship efforts with investee companies.70 Since stakes held in

individual companies account for a minimal part of the fund’s portfolio and, even more so, the

overall assets managed by the fund manager, the benefits potentially deriving from active

engagement will affect fund performance in a way that is necessarily very limited.71 By contrast,

engagement-related costs can be fairly high and will not be shared with fellow passive

shareholders, which will nonetheless take advantage of the company’s improved

performance.72 Costly to produce as they are, and subject to a form of “non-rivalrous

consumption”, “the gains resulting from institutional activism are a species of public goods.”73

Moreover, engagement-related costs cannot be passed on to end-investors, since investment

managers are precluded by regulation from charging stewardship expenses to their funds, or

from tying fees to increases in the value of their portfolios.74 Hence, sensitivity to the free-rider

problem is high, particularly in contexts where competition for investor capital is high, as is the

69 See, e.g., John D. Morley, Too Big to Be Activist, 1 S. CAL. L. REV. (forthcoming) (May 7, 2019),

https://ssrn.com/abstract=3225555. 70 See generally McCahery et al., supra note 42, at 2921; Lucian A. Bebchuk & Scott Hirst, Index Funds and

the Future of Corporate Governance: Theory, Evidence, and Policy 17-19 (Eur. Corp. Gov. Inst. Working Paper No. 433/2018 (2018), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3282794.

71 See Rock, supra note 38, at 373. Whether corporate governance improvements will actually improve the firm’s value remains however questionable: see J.B. Heaton, All You Need is Passive A Response to Professors Fisch, Hamdani, and Davidoff Solomon (July 7, 2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3209614 (stating that “corporate governance initiatives have little effect on financial performance”).

72 Stewardship-related expenses escalate proportionately to the measures adopted. See Nickolay Gantchev, The Costs of Shareholder Activism: Evidence from a Sequential Decision Model, 107 J. OF FIN. ECON., 610-631 (2013).

73 Bainbridge, supra note 10, at 14. 74 Bebchuk, Cohen & Hirst, supra note 40, at 108. But see for an alternative view Simone Alvaro, Marco

Maugeri & Giovanni Strampelli, Institutional Investors, Corporate Governance and Stewardship Codes: Problems and Perspectives 60 (CONSOB Legal Research Papers No. 19) (2019), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3393780; Hannes, supra note 22, at 201.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 19: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

19

case within the asset management industry,75 where fund managers compete to attract assets

under management based on performance relative to alternative investment opportunities.76

As specifically regards passive index funds (i.e. index fund and exchange traded funds-

ETFs), some argue that these prefer to free-ride on stewardship initiatives performed by other

(active) fund managers. Indeed, since index fund portfolios are typically much larger than those

held on average by actively managed mutual funds, “any investment in improving governance

at a single portfolio company will be even less likely to impact the fund's overall

performance.”77 Due to the very low fees that index funds charge, “the increased revenue they

receive—through increased fee revenue—will be only a tiny fraction of the expected value

increase from governance improvements.”78 In addition, governance interventions seem

especially costly for index funds because passively managed funds are not informed traders:

they “do not generate information about firm performance as a byproduct of trading and thus

must expend additional resources to identify underperforming firms and evaluate interventions

proposed by other investors”.79

However, this line of argumentation is controversial since other scholars contend that, in

order to reduce the comparative advantage that competing actively managed funds enjoy vis-à-

vis passive funds on account of their ability to trade, passive funds need to exert their voice to

improve the corporate governance and performance of investee companies and to prevent asset

outflow.80 Because passive investors are, by definition, quasi-permanent shareholders that

cannot exit underperforming companies, or adjust their relative weight in their portfolio, they

should naturally be incentivized to monitor managers, use their votes and further stewardship

75 John C. IV Coates & R. Glenn Hubbard, Competition in the Mutual Fund Industry: Evidence and

Implications for Policy, 33 J. CORP. L. 151 (2007). 76 See Bebchuk, Cohen & Hirst, supra note 40, at 98; Black, supra note 5, at 9. 77 Bebchuk & Hirst, supra note 70, at 17; Shapiro Lund, supra note 24, at 511. 78 Bebchuk & Hirst, supra note 70, at 18. 79 Shapiro Lund, supra note 24, at 497 and 511-12. 80 See Jill E. Fisch, Assaf Hamdani & Steven Davidoff Solomon, Passive Investors, 14-6 (Eur. Corp. Gov. Inst.

(ECGI) Law Working Paper No. 414/2018) (2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3192069; Kahan & Rock, supra note 28, at 26-29. But see Heaton, supra note 71, at 17.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 20: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

20

tools to improve the company’s performance.81 Owing to the large size of their portfolios,

passive fund managers can exploit economies of scale deriving from “identifying governance

ʽbest practicesʼ that are likely to reduce the risk of underperformance” to be “deployed across

a broad range of portfolio companies” at a relatively low cost.82

Evidence concerning how passive investment strategies impact fund managers’ incentives

to engage actively with portfolio companies is mixed. Some findings suggest that, where

passive institutions make their voice heard, this is associated with significant corporate

governance improvements. In particular, index fund influence has been found to support greater

board independence, favor the removal of takeover defenses—such as classified boards—and

promote more equal voting rights by opposing dual-class share structures.83 However, findings

that a greater proportion of passive investors in the shareholder base is associated with more

value-destroying mergers and acquisitions suggest on the other hand that passive investors are

less likely to monitor managers.84

The free-rider disincentive can not only affect truly passive funds which mimic a given

market index, but also so-called “closet index” funds. Closet index funds adopt formally active

investment strategies for portfolio holdings that, however, more or less duplicate some defined

market benchmark; these are, in other words, funds that “charge for active management, but

deliver investments that mostly overlap with the holdings of a much cheaper passive index

fund.”85 In fact, for a closet indexer, “a desire to improve relative performance would provide

no incentives to move stewardship decisions toward optimality for any of the portfolio

companies where the company’s weighting in the investment fund’s portfolio is approximately

81 See Ian Appel et al., Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners, 121 J. FIN. ECON. 111, 113–14 (2016); see also

HORTENSE BIOY ET AL., MORNINGSTAR, PASSIVE FUND PROVIDERS TAKE AN ACTIVE APPROACH TO INVESTMENT STEWARDSHIP 3 (2017), http://www.morningstar.com/content/dam/morningstar-corporate/pdfs/Research/Morningstar-Passive-Active-Stewardship.pdf; Nan Qin & Di Wang, Are Passive Investors a Challenge to Corporate Governance? 3 (2018) (unpublished manuscript) (on file with author); Zohar Goshen & Sharon Hannes, The Death of Corporate Law 39 (Eur. Corp. Gov. Inst. Working Paper No. 402/2018) (2018), http://www.ecgi.global/sites/default/files/working_papers/documents/finalgoshenhannes.pdf; Leo Strine, Jr., Can We Do Better by Ordinary Investors? A Pragmatic Reaction to the Dueling Ideological Mythologists of Corporate Law, 114 COLUM. L. REV. 449, 478 (2014).

82 Fisch, Hamdani & Davidoff Solomon, supra note 80, at 15 and 17. 83 See Appel et al., supra note 81, at 114. 84 Cornelius Schmidt & Rüdiger Fahlenbrach, Do Exogenous Changes in Passive Institutional Ownership Affect

Corporate Governance and Firm Value?, 124 J. FIN. ECON. 285, 298-300 (2017). 85 K. J. Martijn Cremerst & Quinn Curtis, Do Mutual Fund Investors Get What They Pay for: Securities Law

and Closet Index Funds, 11 VA. L. & BUS. REV. 31 (2016).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 21: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

21

equal to its weighting in the index; improving the value of those portfolio companies would not

enhance performance relative to the index”.86

At the same time, competitive pressure to improve performance relative to peers can

disincentivize investing in engagement also for actively managed funds. Indeed, they may

rationally prefer to invest in fundamental analysis of portfolio companies in order to search for

the best selling opportunities, rather than to initiate engagement. In fact, unlike a successful

engagement effort, a successful trade will produce a private gain for the fund.87 More generally,

unless some specific companies are overweighed in the fund’s portfolio compared to competing

funds’ portfolios, or in the index tracked by passive competitors, an actively managed fund has

little incentive to take any active stewardship initiatives, since free riding peers with

comparatively greater stakes would benefit from the improved value in those companies more

than the active fund.88 In addition, “to the extent that funds depart from an index, but still

compete with managers of similar funds, a fund’s relative performance improves when

“underweighted” companies in their portfolio [relative to the index] perform badly”.89

2. Cost Issues

Portfolio diversification discourages active ownership also due to cost considerations.

Identifying relevant corporate governance pitfalls would require a potentially active owner to

closely monitor any of its portfolio companies. However, portfolio companies are most often

simply too many in number in order to realistically allow fund managers to operate such

screening effectively. Arguably, due to their limited size, dedicated in-house stewardship teams

built up at major asset managers are not capable of dedicating the same degree of attention to

86 Lucian A. Bebchuk & Scott Hirst, Are Active Mutual Funds More Active Owners than Index Funds? HARV.

L. SCH. F. ON CORP. GOV. & FIN. REG. (Oct. 3, 2018), https://corpgov.law.harvard.edu/2018/10/03/are-active-mutual-funds-more-active-owners-than-index-funds/.

87 See Gilson & Gordon, supra note 35, at 890. 88 See Bebchuk, Cohen & Hirst, supra note 40, at 98-99 (explaining that “the extent to which improving the

value of the corporation would improve fund performance will depend on the extent to which the corporation is overweight in the portfolio”. In fact, “ any increase in the value of the portfolio company will be substantially shared by rival funds that track the index at least partly. Indeed, the increase in value of the portfolio company will worsen the performance of the investment fund relative to rival funds that are more overweight with respect to the portfolio company. Thus, even for companies that are overweight within the portfolio of the investment fund relative to the index, the impact of the desire to improve relative performance would be diluted by the presence of the company in the benchmark index and in the portfolios of rival funds.”). See also McCahery et al., supra note 58, at 2915.

89 Rock, supra note 38, at 373.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 22: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

22

all portfolio companies.90 In fact, although they are expanding,91 stewardship teams are still too

small even at the leading fund managers. For example, at Blackrock¾the world’s largest asset

manager¾, the stewardship team is made up of around forty people, who are tasked with

monitoring corporate governance issues at around 17,000 companies and voting in around

17,000 shareholder meetings each year.92 Therefore, even for major asset managers’

stewardship teams, “[s]imply voting the shares, without even considering how to vote them, is

an enormous task.”93

As a consequence, stewardship teams most often draw up nearly identical voting guidelines,

which they normally tend to follow fairly closely.94 These voting patterns may also be a

consequence of the fact that asset managers largely rely on proxy advisory firms which adopt

standardized in-house voting policies, or assist clients in drafting their own voting policies, in

both instances according to mainstream corporate governance principles and practices.95 True,

institutions do not seem to follow proxy advisors’ voting recommendations blindly at all times,

and this is the case especially at larger institutions with in-house stewardship teams and stronger

90 See Bebchuk, Cohen & Hirst, supra note 40, at 98-99; Shapiro Lund, supra note 24, at 516. 91 Bioy et al., supra note 81, at 19. For instance, in 2018 Vanguard created a new European stewardship team to

include at least five members. See also Chris Flood, Vanguard Creates New European Stewardship Team, FIN. TIMES (Feb. 17, 2018), https://www.ft.com/content/5dbd7d56-1256-11e8-940e-08320fc2a277.

92 BLACKROCK, INVESTMENT STEWARDSHIP: PROTECTING OUR CLIENTS’ ASSETS FOR THE LONG-TERM 5, 13, and 17 (2019), https://www.blackrock.com/corporate/literature/publication/blk-profile-of-blackrock-investment-stewardship-team-work.pdf.

93 Rock, supra note 38, at 370 (emphasis omitted); see also Bebchuk, Cohen & Hirst, supra note 40, at 100; Bebchuk & Hirst, supra note 70, at 31-34; Asaf Eckstein, Great Expectations: The Peril of an Expectations Gap in Proxy Advisory Firm Regulation, 40 DEL. J. CORP. L. 77, 93 n.118 (2015); John C. Coates, IV, The Future of Corporate Governance Part I: The Problem of Twelve, 14 (Sept. 20, 2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3247337.

94 See, e.g., VANGUARD’S PROXY VOTING GUIDELINES, VANGUARD, https://about.vanguard.com/investment-stewardship/policies-and-guidelines/# [https://perma.cc/2D42-LCYP] (“[T]he guidelines . . . provide a rigorous framework for assessing each proposal. . . . each proposal must be evaluated on its merits, based on the particular facts and circumstances as presented.”); see also STATE ST. GLOB. ADVISORS, ANNUAL STEWARDSHIP REPORT 2017 YEAR END 12 (2018), https://www.ssga.com/investmenttopics/environmental-social-governance/2018/07/annual-stewardship-report-2017.pdf [https://perma.cc/DT23-ZSP8] (declaring that State Street adheres strictly to adopted voting policy and all its voting and engagement activities are centralized within the asset stewardship team irrespective of investment strategy or geographic region).

95 See recently James R. Copland, David F. Larcker & Brian Tayan, The Big Thumb on the Scale: An Overview of the Proxy Advisory Industry 7 (Rock Ctr. for Corp. Governance at Stan. U. Closer Look Series: Topics, Issues and Controversies in Corporate Governance No. CGRP-72; Stan. U. Graduate Sch. of Bus., Research Paper No. 18-27) (2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3188174.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 23: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

23

reputational incentives to be active.96 Nevertheless, adhering to a low-cost box-ticking approach

to voting is consistent with the need to keep fees low.97

This is especially so for passive index fund managers. As they charge very low fees and

can, therefore, capture only a tiny fraction of the expected revenues originated by stewardship

initiatives, stewardship-related costs have a significant impact on passive funds’ fee structure.98

As one of us has already noted, this prediction seems to be confirmed by available data and

evidence suggesting that passive index funds can have a positive impact on corporate

governance issues for which low-cost interventions are required, such as voting according to

pre-defined policies at annual meetings.99 By contrast, passive investors are deemed to be

generally passive owners “when it comes to high-cost governance activities such as monitoring

of M&A, the choice of board members, or the accumulation of titles that often happen outside

of annual general meetings and require continuous monitoring.”100

3. Reputational Incentives

While collective action and cost issues can significantly discourage non-activist institutional

investors from engaging with investee companies, especially when engagement comes with

higher costs, there is growing reputational and regulatory pressure for leading fund

managers¾mainly the largest passive fund managers101¾to be active monitors.102

First, reputational concerns that leading fund managers should play an active monitoring role

are fueled by regulatory pressure to exercise voting rights in keeping with mutual fund fiduciary

duties to end-investors.103 The SEC has adopted a disclosure-based regulatory strategy that has

96 See, e.g., Rock, supra note 38, at 370-71. 97 See Shapiro Lund, supra note 24, at 495 (noting that passive investors tend to approve any shareholder

proposal that meets pre-determined qualifications); see also Rana Foroohar, Investors Pass the Buck on Governance, FIN. TIMES (Oct. 29, 2017), https://www.ft.com/content/f2510d5a-b961-11e7-8c12-5661783e5589; Attracta Mooney & Robin Wigglesworth, Passive Fund Managers Face Showdown in US Gun Debate, FIN. TIMES (Mar. 2, 2018), https://www.ft.com/content/517fbbb6-1d4c-11e8-956a-43db76e69936.

98 See Bebchuk & Hirst, supra note 70, at 18-19. 99 See generally Giovanni Strampelli, Are Passive Index Funds Active Owners? Corporate Governance

Consequences of Passive Investing, 55 SAN DIEGO L. REV. 803, 823 (2018). 100 Schmidt & Fahlenbach, supra note 84, at 287. 101 See infra, notes 104-105 and accompanying text. 102 See Bioy et al., supra note 81, at 3; Kahan & Rock, supra note 28, at 32. 103 See MORNINGSTAR, PASSIVE FUND PROVIDERS TAKE AN ACTIVE APPROACH TO INVESTMENT STEWARDSHIP

3 (2017) http://www.morningstar.com/content/dam/morningstar-corporate/pdfs/Research/Morningstar-Passive-Active-Stewardship.pdf; Fisch, Hamdani & Davidoff Solomon, supra note 80, at 30.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 24: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

24

prompted (albeit without imposing a duty) institutional investors to vote all portfolio shares.104

Second, it is also credible that creating the appearance of governance expertise will help funds

managers to win over clients, especially among institutional investors.105 Moreover, fund

managers may see corporate engagement “as a branding or marketing tool that provides them

with another dimension on which to compete for assets.”106

In line with the underlying assumption that the three leading passive fund managers “are

simply too-big-to-be-passive,”107 the conduct of the Big Three appears to confirm this

prediction. Indeed, they frequently reiterate that they participate in the governance of investee

companies, e.g. in open letters sent to the CEOs of world’s largest companies.108 As Kahan and

104 Voting by mutual and public pension funds was fueled by regulatory action taken to enhance fiduciary

obligations applicable to voting proxies (see Sec. & Exch. Comm'n, Disclosure of Proxy Voting Policies and Proxy Voting Records by Registered Management Investment Companies, 68 Fed. Reg. 6564 (Feb. 7, 2003); Id., Proxy Voting by Investment Advisers, 68 Fed. Reg. 6586 (Feb. 7, 2003)) and by Department of Labor interpretative guidelines concerning the standards under sections 402, 403 and 404 of Title I of the Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) (see Interpretative Bulletin relating to written statements of investment policy, including proxy voting policy or guidelines, 59 Fed. Reg. 38.863 (July 29, 1994) (29 CFR 2509.94–2)). Those rulings were largely (mis-)interpreted as requiring addressees to vote every proxy (see e.g. Rock, supra note 38, at 374-78; Shapiro Lund, supra note 24, at 526-28). Further SEC material explicitly recognized that votes based upon the recommendations of an independent third party can serve investment advisers to fulfill their fiduciary obligation under Rule 206(4)-6, and was further interpreted as requesting investment advisers to vote on all matters: see the SEC’s no-action letters to Egan-Jones Proxy Services (May 27, 2004), https://www.sec.gov/divisions/investment/noaction/egan052704.htm, and to ISS (Sept. 15, 2004), https://www.sec.gov/divisions/investment/noaction/iss091504.htm. In order to tackle these unintended consequences, in 2014, the SEC Divisions of Corporate Finance and Investment Management released new guidance regarding the responsibilities of investment advisers concerning proxy voting: see Sec. & Exch. Comm'n, Staff Legal Bulletin No. 20 (IM/CF), Proxy Voting: Proxy Voting Responsibilities of Investment Advisers and Availability of Exemptions from the Proxy Rules for Proxy Advisory Firms (June 30, 2014), http://www.sec.gov/interps/legal/cfslb20.htm#_ftn1. Similarly, the Department of Labor revised its guidance in 2008 and 2016: see Dep’t of Labor, Interpretative Bulletin relating to the exercise of shareholder rights, 73 Fed. Reg. 61.732 (Oct. 17, 2008) (clarifying that proxies should be voted as part of the process of managing the plan’s investment in company stock unless the time and costs associated with voting proxies in respect to certain types of proposals or issuers may not be in the plan’s best interest). IB 2008-2 was later withdrawn and replaced by Interpretive Bulletin 2016-1, which reinstates the language of Interpretive Bulletin 94-2 with certain modifications: see Dep’t of Labor, Interpretative Bulletin relating to the exercise of shareholder rights, 81 Fed. Reg. 95.879 (Dec. 29, 2016).

105 Shapiro Lund, supra note 24, at 527. See also Jennifer Thompson, Pension funds raise concern over index manager stewardship, FIN. TIMES (June 23, 2019), https://www.ft.com/content/f75459e3-3a6d-383e-843b-6c7141e8442e (noting that “[a]t a time of fierce competition between passive managers . . . the quality of stewardship will become a way for them to stand out”).

106 Fisch, Hamdani & Davidoff Solomon, supra note 80, at 13; Kahan & Rock, supra note 28, at 31. 107 Luca Enriques & Alessandro Romano, Institutional Investor Voting Behavior: A Network Theory Perspective

14 (Eur. Corp. Governance Inst. Working Paper No. 393/2018) (2018), https://ecgi.global/sites/default/files/working_papers/documents/finalenriquesromano.pdf [https://perma.cc/K4KR-8GCH]. See also John Gapper, Index fund managers are too big for comfort, FIN. TIMES (Dec. 12, 2018), https://www.ft.com/content/ad8c8a12-fd5f-11e8-aebf-99e208d3e521.

108 See LARRY FINKS’S ANNUAL LETTER TO CEOS. A SENSE OF PURPOSE, https://www.BlackRock.com/corporate/investor-relations/larry-fink-ceo-letter (last visited, Feb. 19, 2019) (stating that, in managing its index funds, “BlackRock cannot express its disapproval by selling the company’s securities as long as that company remains in the relevant index. As a result, our responsibility to engage and vote is more important than ever.”). For similar remarks on the part of State Street CEO see CYRUS TARAPOREVALA, State

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 25: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

25

Rock note, leading passive investors “have strong reputational interests to be perceived, by

investors, regulators, and politicians, as responsible actors who are a force for the good.”109 In

addition, the considerable attention paid by some leading institutional investors to ESG matters

could help to attract clients that are especially attentive to socially responsible investing.110

B. Activist Institutional Investors

Unlike traditional institutions, activist investors, and especially hedge funds, conceive of

activism not as a tool for remedying a particular corporate flaw (according to an ex post

perspective), but rather as a strategic ex ante lever by which to increase returns on investment.

As Kahan and Rock summarized, activism by traditional institutions is aimed at achieving

small, systemic changes, entails low costs and is incidental and ex post.111 On the contrary,

hedge fund activism aims at achieving significant changes at individual companies, entails

higher costs, and is strategic and ex ante, in that “[a]ctivists first identify a problematic

company, then decide whether intervention can improve matters. If activists conclude that an

intervention is warranted, they buy a stake in order to intervene.”112. Hedge funds’ usual

investment strategies and the applicable regulatory regime are such that they weaken some of

the disincentives that reduce the readiness of mainstream institutional investors to engage with

portfolio companies.

1. Portfolio Concentration and “Two Twenty-Like” Rules

Hedge funds can hold under-diversified portfolios since they are exclusively intended for

professional investors and, therefore, are not subject to the prudential regulatory framework

which typically applies to mutual funds and other categories of traditional institutions in order

Street’s letter to board members 2019, HARV. L. SCH. F. ON CORP. GOVERNANCE & FIN. REG. (Feb. 4, 2019), https://corpgov.law.harvard.edu/2019/02/04/state-street-and-corporate-culture-engagement/.

109 Kahan & Rock, supra note 28, at 28-32. 110 Id. at 30. 111 Kahan & Rock, supra note 34, at 1069. See also Alvaro et al., supra note 74, at 39. 112 Rock, supra note 38, at 382. See also Cheffins & Armour, supra note 40, at 56-58 (defining mainstream

institutional investors’ activism as “defensive” in nature, as opposed to hedge funds’ “offensive” activism, the former relying on pre-existing stakes in the company and the latter being based upon ad hoc stake-building).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 26: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

26

to protect unskilled end-investors.113 Higher levels of portfolio concentration allow hedge funds

to be committed to more actively engaging with investee companies as compared with

traditional diversified institutions since, by holding higher stakes, they can reap higher benefits

associated with improved corporate performance following successful intervention. First,

improvements in a single target’s performance have a greater effect on the fund’s overall returns

than is the case for diversified portfolios.114 Second, portfolio concentration reduces the

likeliness that the activist may be faced with free-riding from competitors that hold a position

in the same company.115 Third, portfolio concentration allows greater resources to be dedicated

to the monitoring of, and engagement with, individual investee companies.116

Hedge funds’ fee structures also provide a strong incentive towards active engagement as

well. In fact, despite criticism, “two twenty-like” fund manager compensation structures are

widespread in the hedge fund industry, where “[t]he "two" refers to an annual management fee

of two percent of the capital that investors have committed to the fund. The "twenty" refers to

a twenty percent share of the future profits of the fund”.117 The upside potential of performance

fees, which are now usually charged on profits above the hurdle performance levels that the

fund manager has agreed to with the investor, provides a potent financial incentive for activism,

since “[i]f the fund does well, the managers share in the treasure. If the fund does badly,

however, the manager can walk away.”118 Capturing 20 per cent of the value increase of the

position in the target is “an order of magnitude more than the percentage of any value increase

that a mutual fund manager would be able to capture”.119

113 See generally Wulf A. Kaal & Dale A. Oesterle, The History of Hedge Fund Regulation in the United States,

in HANDBOOK ON HEDGE FUNDS (Ohio State Public Law Working Paper No. 326 & Univ. of St. Thomas (Minn.) Legal Stud. Res. Paper No. 16-05) (2016), https://papers.ssm.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=2714974.

114 Bebchuk, Cohen & Hirst, supra note 40, at 105. 115 Id. 116 Id. 117 Victor Fleischer, Two and Twenty: Taxing Partnership Profits in Private Equity Funds, 83 N.Y.U. L. REV.

1, 3 (2008). But see Robin Wigglesworth, DE Shaw to revert to ‘3 and 30’ model as cost pressures bite, FIN. TIMES (Apr. 19, 2019), https://www.ft.com/content/fe2799b4-6252-11e9-b285-3acd5d43599e (noting that “only 3 per cent now charge a 2 per cent management fee, and 16 per cent take a fifth of profits . . . The average is now just 1.45 per cent and 16.9 per cent respectively”). Although, due to growing pressure from low- or zero-fee passive funds and to performance not always adequate, two-and-twenty rules appear to be declining, hedge funds’ fee models still remain expensive, with average management fees of around 1,5 per cent and performance fees rarely lower than 15 per cent. See Chris Flood, Hedge fund fee model morphs from ‘two and 20’ to ‘one or 30’, FIN. TIMES (Apr. 1, 2019), https://www.ft.com/content/7e4e2cdc-8c2a-34d4-a7e2-60c9db9e2a2d (citing JPMORGAN CHASE & CO, 2019 INSTITUTIONAL INVESTOR SURVEY 11, https://www.jpmorgan.com/country/HK/en/prime-services/institutional-investor-survey-2019?source=cib_ps_li_Aiinvestor0319).

118 Id. See also Bebchuk, Cohen & Hirst, supra note 40, at 104; Rock, supra note 38, at 382. 119 Bebchuk, Cohen & Hirst, supra note 40, at 104.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 27: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

27

2. The Absence of Business Ties with Investee Companies

Unlike non-activist institutions, most hedge funds do not sell money management services

to portfolio companies or, more generally, have no business ties with the public corporations in

which they invest, and do not hold horizontal shareholdings in a vast number of issuers.120

Hence, they are less subject to the conflicts of interest that are associated with the desire to

attract business from investee companies and, as a consequence, with bias toward non-

adversarial, if not overtly manager-friendly, ownership behavior.121 As Morley notes, normally

activist hedge funds are not run by large investment managers¾e.g. BlackRock, Vanguard,

Fidelity¾since these managers are simply too big to be activists.122 Specifically, since the

largest investment managers run different business lines, an activist initiative promoted by one

of their fund managers could harm the clients of other funds managed by the same investment

conglomerate.123

3. The Corporate Governance Limits of Hedge Fund Activism

However, hedge fund activism also suffers from limitations that can weaken its potentially

beneficial corporate-governance effects. First of all, activist intervention mostly occurs in

relation to underperforming targets, which means that intervention is worth the costs in terms

of the expected returns.124 Therefore, companies that do not match activists’ stock picking will

not usually become involved in any of the corporate changes on the activist’s usual playbook.125

Second, and more broadly, there is still a question as to whether the effects of hedge fund

activism are actually positive or negative. Those who view activists as valuable corporate

monitors that can benefit all shareholders underscore the fact that no evidence has been found

to suggest that activist intervention, including investment-limiting and adversarial intervention,

is followed by any short-term gains in performance at the price of long-term performance.126

120 Rock, supra note 38, at 382. 121 See Bebchuk, Cohen & Hirst, supra note 40, at 105-06; Bebchuk & Hirst, supra note 70, at 22-25. 122 Morley, supra note 69, at 1. 123 Id. 124 Bebchuk, Cohen & Hirst, supra note 40, at 106. 125 See Strampelli, supra note 99, at 839. 126 See Lucian A. Bebchuk, Alon Brav & Wei Jiang, The Long-Term Effects of Hedge Fund Activism, 115

COLUM. L. REV. 1085 (2015).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 28: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

28

Supporters of hedge fund activism further highlight the fact that operating performance

increases at targeted firms;127 and that innovation output (as measured by patent counts and

citations) also increases.128 Moreover, activism is claimed to induce industry peers that are not

targeted to respond proactively to the threat of possible activist intervention by implementing

policy changes that mimic those made by targeted firms.129 Finally, it is asserted that activist

investment-limiting proposals effectively curb the management's bias towards inefficient

expansion and empire building.130

However, further evidence supports the view “that the substantial private gains hedge funds

realize through activism come at the expense of long-term firm value, rather than from the

activists' ability to hold managers more accountable”.131 Activism is also believed to have a

perverse deterrent effect on the long-term focus of the management, since it distorts the ex-ante

incentives of managers and other stakeholders to invest optimally in the firm.132 Moreover,

activists are unlikely to have superior knowledge, skills or expertise at running the business, as

compared to the firm’s management.133 In addition, in favoring riskier projects or an increase

in financial leverage, hedge fund activism is argued to increase corporate risk-taking and to

heighten the risk of wealth-transfers from creditors to shareholders.134 Finally, hedge fund

representation in the board of directors has been associated with an increase in informed trading

127 See Matthew R. Denes, Jonathan M. Karpoff & Victoria B. McWilliams, Thirty years of shareholder

activism: A survey of empirical research, 44 J. CORP. FIN. 405, 411 (2017). 128 Alon Brav et al., How does hedge fund activism reshape corporate innovation? (July 3, 2017), J. OF FIN.

ECON. (2018) (forthcoming), https://ssrn.com/abstract=2409404. 129 See Nickolay Gantchev, Oleg Gredil & Chotibhak Jotikasthira, Governance under the Gun: Spillover Effects

of Hedge Fund Activism (EUR. CORP. GOV. INST. (ECGI) Working Paper No. 562/2018) (May 2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=2356544.

130 See Nickolay Gantchev, Merih Sevilir & Anil Shivdasani, Activism and Empire Building (Eur. Corp. Gov. Inst. (ECGI) Finance Working Paper No. 575/2018) (Sept. 8, 2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3062998.

131 Martijn Cremers, Saura Masconale & Simone M. Sepe, Activist Hedge Funds and the Corporation, 94 WASH. U. L. REV. 261 (2016); Martijn Cremers, Erasmo Giambona, Simone M. Sepe & Ye Wang, Hedge Fund Activism, Firm Valuation and Stock Returns (June 16, 2018), http://ssm.com/abstract=2693231; Ed deHaan, David F. Larcker & Charles McClure, Long-Term Economic Consequences of Hedge Fund Activist Interventions (Eur. Corp. Governance Inst. (ECGI) Finance Working Paper No. 577/2018) (Oct. 3, 2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3260095.

132 Cremers et al, supra note 131, 278; John C. Jr. Coffee & Darius Palia, The Wolf at the Door: The Impact of Hedge Fund Activism on Corporate Governance, 41 J. CORP. L. 545, 593 and 605 (2016).

133 See Leo E. Jr. Strine, Who Bleeds When the Wolves Bite: A Flesh-and-Blood Perspective on Hedge Fund Activism and Our Strange Corporate Governance System, 126 YALE L. J. 1870, 1953-1954 (2017); Alon Brav, Wei Jiang, Frank Partnoy & Randall Thomas, Hedge Fund Activism, Corporate Governance, and Firm Performance, 63 J. FIN. 1729, 1755 (2008).

134 See April Klein & Emanuel Zur, The impact of hedge fund activism on the target firm's existing bondholders, 24 REV. FIN. STUD. 1735 (2011); Sandeep Dahiya, Issam Hallak & Thomas Matthys, Targeted by an Activist Hedge Fund, Do the Lenders Care? (June 4, 2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3191072. But see Brav et al., supra note 133, at 1732.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 29: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

29

in the corporation’s stock, suggesting that activist board representation imposes new agency

costs.135

IV. RECONSIDERING INCENTIVE STRUCTURES IN THE CONTEXT OF COLLECTIVE ENGAGEMENT

The previous analysis of institutional investors’ incentive structures implicitly relies on the

assumption that investors conduct their engagement initiatives individually. In fact, it is

generally assumed that institutional investors act in a solo-engagement context where free

riding problems and cost issues are particularly acute.

It is undeniable that some engagements may best be conducted privately by a

single¾activist or non-activist¾institutional investor.136 However, there is a growing body of

anecdotal evidence and academic studies to suggest that coordinated engagements by

institutional investors are becoming increasingly widespread and can have a positive impact on

investee companies, especially with regard to corporate governance issues.137

While wolf packs have received comparatively greater consideration within the literature,

increasing attention is being paid to non-activist shareholders’ collective engagement

initiatives. For example, according to Dimson et al., collective engagement initiatives are

“effective in successfully achieving the stated engagement goals and subsequently improving

target performance”.138 Doidge et al. note that coordinated actions can help to overcome free-

rider problems affecting institutional investors.139 Similarly, Crane et al. maintain that

coordinated initiatives can improve institutional shareholders’ voice.140

However, while highlighting the potential benefits of shareholder collective action,

available empirical studies present some limitations. First, the distinction between activist-

driven and non-activist-driven engagement is not always clear. Second, and more importantly,

135 See John C. Coffee Jr. et al., Activist Directors and Agency Costs: What Happens When an Activist Director

Goes on the Board? (Colum. Bus. School Research Paper No. 18-15) (Jan. 12, 2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3100995.

136 SeeElroy Dimson, Oğuzhan Karakaş & Xi Li, Coordinated Engagements 9 (July 1, 2018). https://ssrn.com/abstract=3209072.

137 See, e.g., id. 27-28; Elroy Dimson, Oğuzhan Karakaş & Xi Li; Active Ownership, 28 REV. FIN. STUD. 3225, 3240-3242 (2015); Craig Doidge et al., Collective Action and Governance Activism (Aug. 30, 2017), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2635662; Tanja Artiga González & Paul Calluzzo, Clustered Shareholder Activism, 27 CORP. GOVERN. INT. REV. 210 (2019).

138 Dimson et al., supra note 137, at 3. 139 Doidge et al., supra note 137, at 25-28. 140 Alan D. Crane, Andrew Koch & Sebastien Michenaud, Institutional Investor Cliques and Governance (June

22, 2017) J. FIN. ECON. (forthcoming), https://ssrn.com/abstract=2841444.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 30: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

30

they do not provide an unambiguous definition of shareholder cooperation. Indeed, institutional

investors can be associated with each other in a number of ways. As is noted by Enriques and

Romano, formal, geographical, employee, and co-ownership ties can exist among institutional

investors.141 Also proxy advisors142 and hedge fund activists143 can act as connections among

institutions. Although informal connections among institutional investors can “contribute to

shaping institutional investors’ incentives to vote ‘actively’”,144 as far as coordinated

engagement initiatives are concerned formal connections prove to be more significant, since

only ex-ante formalized cooperation allows institutional investors to share costs and can help

to overcome potential free-rider problems.145

Hence, as this Article mainly points towards solutions that seek to stimulate collective

engagement initiatives by institutional investor, we do not consider informal shareholder

connections. Accordingly, we focus on coordinated initiatives that imply the decision by

participants to engage alongside other institutional investors in order to meet a shared goal.

A. Activist-Driven Forms of Shareholder Cooperation

The distinction between activist-driven and non-activist-driven engagements is sometimes

blurred. To begin with, there appears to be no clear distinction between so-called wolf packs

and the different, although equally activist-driven, phenomenon of the receptive teaming up by

non-activist institutional investors with an activist. Second, also non-activist-driven collective

engagement comes in different shapes. In this Part, we provide an overview of these different

forms of shareholder collaboration with the aim of highlighting the fundamental differences,

thus laying the premises for a discussion both of the benefits of collective engagements vis-à-

vis activist, or activist-driven, types of shareholder collaboration as well as their policy

implications.

1. Wolf Packs

141 Enriques & Romano, supra note 107, at 244. 142 See Ryan Bubb & Emiliano Catan, The Party Structure of Mutual Funds (Apr. 16, 2018) (unpublished

manuscript), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3124039). 143 Gilson & Gordon, supra note 35, at 897-8. 144 Enriques & Romano, supra note 107, at 223. See also Bubb & Catan, supra note 142, at 7-18; Crane et al.,

supra note 140, at 7-13. 145 See infra, Part IV.C.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 31: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

31

The form of shareholder collaboration that relies on wolf pack formation has been found to

be “the most profitable type of engagement, reflecting the high probability of achieving

successful outcomes”.146 While it has been pointed to as an explanation for the recent spike in

hedge fund activism,147 the wolf pack tactic has been reported since at least 2005 as a form of

pseudo-cooperation between mutually supportive hedge funds “interested in the same prey but

who are careful not to form a Schedule 13D group”.148 Avoiding formal coordination between

the members of the pack means preventing their stakes from being aggregated under section

13(d) of the Securities Exchange Act, followed by their notification as a joint stake, which

would trigger earlier disclosure obligations regarding potential changes in corporate control,

including the “purposes of the transaction” and any plans or proposals involving material

corporate transactions relating to the issuer.149

Based on parallel—though formally uncoordinated—action, the wolf pack exploits the

voting power held collectively by its members to enable relatively small blockholders to gain

significant influence, thereby increasing the prospects of success of an activist campaign.150

Importantly, focusing on trading in the target’s stocks around individual 13D filings, the process

by which the wolf pack is formed involves a markedly speculative stance. Participation in the

pack is thus likely to be premised on trading-profits incentives. Such a characterization of the

wolf pack tactic holds despite some ambiguity surrounding the particular mechanism by which

wolf packs are formed as well as the very definition of a wolf pack; in actual fact, two competing

views have been conceptualized in this regard, although they are not necessarily mutually

exclusive.

Some take the view that wolf packs are formed spontaneously as a result of independent

activity by their members based on investors’ understanding of the lead activist’s playbook, as

can be inferred from its trading. It is considered that no direct communication between the

players need take place; reputational concerns are key in leading smaller investors who compete

for investor capital to purchase the target’s stock following a 13D filing and to join the

146 Marco Becht et al., Returns to Hedge Fund Activism: An International Study, 30 REV. FIN. STUD. 2933,

2936 (2017). 147 See Coffee & Palia, supra note 132, at 549-50. 148 Briggs, supra note 14, at 698. 149 17 C.F.R. § 240.13d-5 (b)(1) (2018) (“When two or more persons agree to act together for the purpose of

acquiring, holding, voting or disposing of equity securities of an issuer, the group formed thereby shall be deemed to have acquired beneficial ownership, for purposes of sections 13(d) and (g) of the Act, as of the date of such agreement, of all equity securities of that issuer beneficially owned by any such persons.”)

150 See Alon Brav, Amil Dasgupta & Richmond Mathews, Wolf Pack Activism 2-3 (Eur. Corp. Gov. Inst. (ECGI) Finance Working Paper No. 501/2017) (Mar. 1, 2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=2529230.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 32: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

32

campaign triggered by the larger, better-informed lead activist.151 Mindful that a significant

degree of participation in the campaign is necessary in order for it to be successful, and that

only a successful campaign will increase the reputation of the institutions participating in the

campaign, small institutions are apparently motivated to join the lead activist implicitly in order

to increase their perceived skills and reputation and to attract additional capital inflow.152

Admittedly however, trading profits resulting from private pre-filing tips from the lead activist

may increase followers’ incentives to buy the target stock prior to the 13D filing by the lead

activist. Therefore, informed trading may complement the spontaneous reputation-driven

mechanism by which the pack is formed.153

However, the data seem to more strongly support the view that wolf packs are “a loose

network of activist investors that act in a parallel fashion but deliberately avoid forming a

‘group’ under section 13(d)(3) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934”.154 Accordingly, wolf

packs are formed intentionally, and are motivated by low-risk informed trading occurring prior

to 13D filings. While buying up the target’s stock at lower prices until it reaches 5% threshold

ownership level, thus triggering the 13D filing obligation‒and, usually, up to no more than 10%

during the following ten-day window set by section 13d(1) for the filing155‒the lead activist is

argued to encourage other investors to join it by positively tipping them off about its upcoming

campaign prior to the filing in exchange for wolf pack member support.156 Circumventing the

application of 13D group disclosures allows the pack to accumulate fairly significant stakes in

the target while “escap[ing] old corporate defenses (most notably the poison pill) and …

reap[ing] high profits at seemingly low risk”.157 In effect, ungrouped holders of stock in the

target remain undetected for the purposes of Regulation 13D, provided that no investor

151 Id. at 4-5, and 7 (finding an average abnormal turnover “of over 30% of the activist's typical stake” over the

ten-day period following 13D flings). 152 Id. at 5-6. 153 Id. at 29. 154 Coffee & Palia, supra note 132, at 562. 155 17 C.F.R. § 240. 13d-1(a). See Coffee & Palia, supra note 132, at 563 (explaining that crossing the 10%

threshold would subject the activist to section 16(B) of the Exchange Act, which “may force it to surrender any “short swing” profit to the corporation on shares acquired in excess of 10%”); see also Lucian A. Bebchuk, Robert J. Jr. Jackson & Wei Jiang, Pre-Disclosure Accumulations by Activist Investors: Evidence and Policy, 39 J. CORP. L. 1, 4-5 (2013).

156 See Yu Ting Forester Wong, Wolves at the Door: A Closer Look at Hedge Fund Activism, 2 and 4 (Colum. Bus. School Research Paper No. 16-11, Oct. 2, 2016), https://ssrn.com/abstract=2721413 (conceptualizing the “coordinated effort” hypothesis for wolf pack formation).

157 See Coffee & Palia, supra note 132, at 549.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 33: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

33

participating in the coalition individually crosses the 5% ownership level, thus triggering the

13D filing obligation.

The intentional nature of wolf pack formation is inferred from data concerning trading

volume and the appreciation of the stocks targeted during the period of time close to the public

announcement of the campaign. Trading volume is found to increase abnormally prior to the

public announcement of the campaign and then to drop sharply immediately after the 13D filing

by the lead activist, with most of the stock appreciation occurring during the ten-day window.158

This suggests that many other investors buy the target’s stock during the ten-day window.159

The wolf pack members “most likely have been informed by those filing the Schedule 13D of

their intentions. The inference then seems obvious: tipping and informed trading appears to

characterize both the formation of the ʽwolf packʼ and transactions during the window period

preceding the filing of the Schedule 13D”.160 In enlisting other investors in the formation of the

pack by tipping them off, the 13D-filing activist relies on the expected increase in stock returns

that usually follows the public announcement of the campaign as a way of compensating them

for their support. In effect, investors “who learn of the incipient Schedule 13D filing face a

nearly riskless opportunity for profitable trading if they act quickly, as the Schedule 13D filing

usually moves the market upwards”.161

Further empirical research has found evidence that is consistent with the notion that wolf

pack formation is intentional. Specifically, share turnover is found to be about 325% of the

normal trading volume on the day the 13D filer crosses the 5% threshold, whereby the bulk of

158 See Bebchuk et al., supra note 155, at 23-24 (finding that stock purchases by 13D-filer activist hedge funds

are “disproportionately concentrated on the day on which the investor crosses the five-percent threshold and, to a lesser extent, the immediately following day”.); Coffee & Palia, supra note 132, at 565.

159 Coffee & Palia, supra note 132, at 565. See also Choonsik Lee, Activism of Blockholder Investors: Who Drives the Purchases of the Target Shares before Schedule 13D Filing? 4-5 (Jan. 2015), http://www.fmaconferences.org/Orlando/Papers/Activism_of_Blockholder_Investors_2015FMA.pdf. But see Alon Brav, J.B. Heaton & Jonathan Zandberg, Failed Anti-Activist Legislation: The Curious Case of the Brokaw Act, 11 J. BUS. ENTREPRENEURSHIP & L. 329, 345-47 (2018) (contending that activists’ 13D filings often occur well before the ten-day window closes, and that “the anomalous pattern of abnormal volume disappears . . . when trading data are centered on the date the reporting threshold is crossed rather than the filing date.” While not excluding that some tipping or wolf pack formation may take place after the crossing of the 5% threshold, they note that

the number of additional shares purchased by the elusive pack is economically small . . . unless much of the trading on the trigger date is by investors forming a wolf pack. It is also likely that an important part of the trading on the threshold day is by investors other than the hedge fund activist. Such trading can arise either because of leaked information about the activist’s intent to cross the 5% threshold or because activists choose to trade precisely when they anticipate or observe uninformed selling.

160 Coffee & Palia, supra note 132, at 565. 161 Id. at 565.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 34: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

34

the trading volume is attributable to trades by investors other than the lead activist.162 That

finding ranks against the view that wolf pack are formed spontaneously, since synchronicity in

block building by many investors cannot be fully explained by any sudden changes in market

conditions. In addition, wolf packs are found to be more likely to occur in better-defended

companies: this, in turn, consistent with the notion that wolf packs are used to circumvent

securities takeover defenses.163

2. Non-Activist Institutions Teaming Up With Activists

Having accepted that both the practice and the definition of wolf packs is characterized by

informed trading based on tipping, it is necessary to consider another type of activist-driven

uncoordinated shareholder collaboration, which differs from that underlying wolf packs. In

effect, it is increasingly the case that‒chiefly in the context of proxy fights164‒actively managed

mutual funds, pension funds and index investors share the views of an activist whom they

consider to be a credible actor,165 and are willing to support its campaign, either privately or

publicly, and to vote in line with it at the shareholders’ meeting. Ultimately, receptively teaming

up with an activist “seems to be developing into a broader market trend”.166

This form of shareholder collaboration is not restricted to activist players alone or, at least,

to actively managed funds motivated by trading profits, but also involves passive investors.

Since passively managed investors can hardly be expected to be in a position that allows them

to exploit trading‒either after or before 13D filings‒voting support provided by them to an

activist’s campaign cannot be assumed to be motivated by the prospects of profits associated

with trading in the target’s stocks during the period of time close to the announcement of the

campaign. It can hence be assumed that implicit, spontaneous support by passive investors is

162 Id. See also Bebchuk et al., supra note 155 , 23-4. 163 See Wong, supra note 156, at 5-6 (finding wolf pack campaigns to be 6% more likely to achieve at least part

of the activist’s objectives, and 9% more likely to obtain board seats in the target; also, wolf packs are associated with an 8.3% higher buy and hold abnormal return over the duration of the campaign).

164 See, e.g., Alon Brav et al., Picking Friends Before Picking (Proxy) Fights: How Mutual Fund Voting Shapes Proxy Contests (Eur. Corp. Gov. Inst. (ECGI) Fin. Working Paper 601/2019) (March 1, 2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3101473.

165 See ACTIVIST INSIGHT-SCHULTE ROTH & ZABEL, THE ACTIVIST INSIGHT ANNUAL REVIEW 2018 6 https://www.activistinsight.com/resources/reports/(. See also C.N.V. Krishnan, Frank Partnoy, Randall S. Thomas, The second wave of hedge fund activism: The importance of reputation, clout, and expertise, 40 J. CORP. FIN. 296, 297 (2016) (pointing at reputation, clout and expertise built up by top hedge funds as a consequence of being successful in difficult interventions as factors further driving success).

166 Wolf-Georg Ringe, Shareholder Activism: a Renaissance, in THE OXFORD HANDBOOK OF CORPORATE LAW AND GOVERNANCE 5, 20 (Jeffrey N. Gordon & Wolf-Georg Ringe eds., 2015).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 35: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

35

provided in the basis of pre-existing stakes held by them in the target. Institutions the decide to

vote in line with the activist at the target’s shareholder meeting as a result of the activist’s ability

to convince fellow shareholders of its allegedly superior value-enhancing entrepreneurial

views, as compared to those of the target’s management.167 Under the model of shareholder

collaboration considered here, there is no need for any direct communication between the

activist and its potential followers.168 After building up its stake, the activist exerts pressure on

the target publicly, e.g. by means of open letters to the board of directors and to all shareholders

explaining its prospects in terms of the changes advocated along with the reasons for those

changes‒whether regarding the firm’s corporate governance, policies, strategy, etc. Where the

activists’ views align with those of mainstream fellow investors, the latter may decide to lend

support to the campaign and to back the activist’s proposals, which obviously increases the

likelihood of success. In fact, the activist succeeds in its campaign “by coming public, not so

subtly suggesting a willingness to scuffle, and by reaching an accommodation with the target's

management that involves the hedge fund gaining board seats”169‒which often occurs by means

of a settlement concluded “well before the ballot box”.170

B. Different Forms of Non-Activist Collective Engagements

Turning to non-activist-driven forms of collective shareholder action, this Part provides an

overview of the practice of non-activist shareholder cooperation, taking account of the

recommendations contained in stewardship codes aimed at promoting collective engagement

by institutional investors.

1. Collective Engagements in Stewardship Codes

Stewardship codes recommend that institutional investors as stock owners collaborate,

where appropriate, on the grounds that (individual and) collective engagement with portfolio

167 See, e.g., Randall S. Thomas, The Evolving Role of Institutional Investors in Corporate Governance and

Corporate Litigation, 61 VAND. L. REV. 299, 312 (2008); Kahan & Rock, supra note 28, at 33-34 However, activist-driven teaming up cannot be regarded as a functional substitute for non-activist collective engagements (infra, Sec. B). The former can only occur where the views of mainstream institutions converge with those of the activist: which may happen occasionally, but is certainly not always the case. In fact, in line with the differing business models and incentives structure characterizing different investor types, their views often diverge. Therefore, institutions’ teaming up with an activist may be thought of as being complimentary to non-activist driven engagements.

168 See Kahan & Rock, supra note 28, at 40. 169 Strine, supra note 133, at 1902. 170 Id. at 1904.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 36: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

36

companies is part and parcel of a money manager’s duty to act in the best interests of its clients,

with a view to maintaining and enhancing long-term value and “with the aim of preserving or

adding value to the clients’ assets.”171

In Europe, a common reference to collective engagement is contained in the EFAMA

Stewardship Code. In its current version, EFAMA Principle 4 recommends that asset managers

“should consider acting with other investors, where appropriate”. Emphasizing that shareholder

collaboration may sometimes be “the most effective manner in which to engage”, the Guidance

to Principle 4 illustrates that collective action with individual investee companies may in

particular be appropriate “at times of significant corporate or wider economic stress, or when

the risks posed threaten to destroy significant value or the ability of the company to continue in

operation”. In addition, the Code also welcomes ongoing collective engagements concerning

policy issues.

As the very wording of Principle 4 makes clear, the EFAMA Code heavily borrows from

the UK Stewardship Code, Principle 5 of which is re-stated almost verbatim by the EFAMA.

The UK Code also states that institutions’ policies on collective engagement “should indicate

their readiness to work with other investors through formal and informal groups when this is

necessary to achieve their objectives and ensure companies are aware of concerns”, along with

the circumstances under which they would consider participating in collective engagement.172

Not surprisingly, given its precedence, the UK model for collective stewardship has also

inspired a number of similar initiatives at Member State level. Examples include the 2018 Dutch

Stewardship Code, drafted by Eumedion,173 which emphasizes the potential upsides of

shareholder cooperation and joint initiatives, noting that collective discussion with investee

companies may sometimes generate “a wider and deeper range of analysis compared to a one-

to-one meeting”, especially where issues of common interest are concerned. It also suggests

that collective engagement may be beneficial to both investee companies and investors,

“because both the board and investors get familiar with each other’s views and perspectives and

171 EFAMA STEWARDSHIP CODE, Background, 3; ICGN GSP, Preamble, 5. 172 See FIN. REP. COUNCIL, PROPOSED REVISIONS TO THE UK STEWARDSHIP CODE - ANNEX A REVISED UK

STEWARDSHIP CODE, Guidance to Sec. 4, Provision 20, https://www.frc.org.uk/consultation-list/2019/consulting-on-a-revised-uk-stewardship-code. [hereinafter: PROPOSED REVISIONS TO THE UK STEWARDSHIP CODE]

173 Eumedion is an independent foundation, managed by representatives of participants, representing the interests of dutch and international institutional investors in the field of corporate governance and sustainability performance; it is currently participated by about 60 institutional investors and umbrella organizations collectively managing more than € 5.000 billion in assets. See https://www.eumedion.nl/en/abouteumedion.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 37: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

37

engagement is made more cost effective”.174 The cost consideration is thus explicitly mentioned

as a factor in favor of shareholder collaboration.

While also recommending that institutions’ engagement policies also describe “how they

will act collectively with other investors in order to achieve greater effect and impact”, the

Danish Stewardship code emphasizes that shareholder collaboration that does not occur in

relation to the acquisition of shares or other kinds of stake accumulation in the relevant

company is not ad odds with the European regulatory framework for takeover bids, including

in particular the provisions on concerted action.175 Therefore, the Danish code suggests that the

rules on concerted action, specifically the risk of triggering a mandatory bid, should not in

principle discourage shareholder collaboration or be used as an excuse to avoid collective

engagement.

Closely following EFAMA, also the Italian Stewardship Principles acknowledge that the

collective one “may be the most effective method of engagement”.176 Over the years,

Assogestioni has been increasingly taking on an active role in providing operational support to

its affiliates.177 As has been shown by the Italian model, by catalyzing investors’ stewardship,

investor associations can play an active role within the framework for stewardship, and can turn

into a cost-saving vehicle for collective engagement.178

Similarly, the Global Stewardship Principles (hereinafter, GSP) adopted by the Corporate

Governance Network in 2016 acknowledge the proactive role that can potentially be played by

investor associations. Guidance 4.5 to ICGN GSP 4 illustrates that investors should “be

prepared to form or join investor associations to promote collective engagement”, noting that

the aim of collaborating with (both domestic and overseas) investors is “to leverage the voice

of minority investors and exert influence, where required, with investee companies.”179

Identical recommendations in relation to investor associations are also set out in the guidance

to Stewardship Principle 5 drafted by the Canadian Coalition for Good Governance (hereinafter,

174 DUTCH STEWARDSHIP CODE, Guidance to Principle 4, https://ecgi.global/node/6972 (June 20, 2018) 175 DANISH STEWARDSHIP CODE, Comments to Principle 4, https://ecgi.global/code/danish-stewardship-code-

2016 (Nov. 2016). 176 ITALIAN STEWARDSHIP PRINCIPLES, Recommendations to principle 4, https://ecgi.global/code/italian-

stewardship-principles-2016 (2016). 177 See generally Strampelli, How to Enhance Directors' Independence at Controlled Companies, 44 J. CORP. L.

103, 134-135 (2018). 178 See infra Part IV.B.3. 179 ICGN GSP, Guidance 4.5 to Principle 4.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 38: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

38

CCGG)180, an organization formed and run by a wide range of institutions investing in the

Canadian capital market, which currently includes pension funds, mutual funds and third party

money managers managing a total of almost $4 trillion in assets. Finally, collective engagement

is mentioned as a beneficial tool also in the Japanese Stewardship Code, revised in 2017, as

well as the 2016 Singapore and Taiwan Codes, and the 2016 Hong Kong Stewardship

Principles.181

The relevance of collective engagement is clearly highlighted also by the stewardship

principles recently adopted in the United States. Specifically, the investor-led Investor

Stewardship Group (ISG) provides a framework of basic investment stewardship (and corporate

governance) standards for U.S. institutional investor conduct, which took effect on January 1,

2018. Principle F states that institutional investors “should work together, where appropriate,

to encourage the adoption and implementation of the Corporate Governance and Stewardship

principles.”182 As the Guidance to that principle explains, collaboration not only relates to

institutions’ efforts “to ensure that the framework continues to represent their common views

on corporate governance best practices”;183 it also, and more importantly, entails “addressing

common concerns related to corporate governance practices, public policy and/or shareholder

rights by participating, for example, in discussions as members of industry organizations or

associations.”184 Here, too, the role of investor associations in coordinating collective

stewardship is explicitly acknowledged.

180 See CANADIAN COAL’N FOR GOOD GOVERNANCE, STEWARDSHIP PRINCIPLES (2017), https://www.ccgg.ca/. 181 See THE COUNCIL OF EXPERTS ON THE STEWARDSHIP CODE, PRINCIPLES FOR RESPONSIBLE INSTITUTIONAL

INVESTORS (“Japan’s Stewardship Code” - To promote sustainable growth of companies through investment and dialogue) (2017), Guidance 4.4 to Principle 4; SINGAPORE STEWARDSHIP PRINCIPLES WORKING GROUP, SINGAPORE STEWARDSHIP PRINCIPLES FOR RESPONSIBLE INVESTORS (2016), Guidance to Principle 7; TAIWAN STOCK EXCHANGE, STEWARDSHIP PRINCIPLES FOR INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORS (2016), Guideline 4.3 to Principle 4; HONG KONG SECURITIES AND FUTURES COMMISSION, PRINCIPLES OF RESPONSIBLE OWNERSHIP (2016), Principle 5. All Stewardship Codes mentioned above are available at https://ecgi.global/code/stewardship-principles-institutional-investors.

182 See INV’R STEWARDSHIP GROUP, STEWARDSHIP FRAMEWORK FOR INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORS, Principle F, https://isgframework.org/stewardship-principles/ (hereinafter ISG principles). The ISG, formed in January 2017, currently includes “some of the largest U.S.-based institutional investors and global asset managers, along with several of their international counterparts. The members include more than 60 U.S. and international institutional investors with combined assets in excess of US$31 trillion in the U.S. equity market.” (https://isgframework.org/, last visited Jan. 25, 2019). See also Hill, supra note 25, at 522-23 (noting that “ISG's new stewardship principles are more tentative and ambiguous than the U.K. Stewardship Code”, as institutional investors’ “collaboration appears to be directed at encouraging the adoption and implementation of corporate governance/stewardship principles, rather than engaging in collective activism per se”.

183 Id., F1. 184 Id., F2.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 39: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

39

2. Investor Forums

Although stewardship principles and guidelines do sometimes mention specific tools for

collective engagement, such as coordination by investor associations,185 those principles and

guidelines are not prescriptive and feature a highly flexible approach. It is left to investors to

decide when and how, based on their differing investment strategies and the interests they may

share with other investors, it is appropriate to exert active ownership collectively. As a

consequence, different pathways for collective engagement have developed.

In some countries, investor collaboration is supported by organizations that specifically seek

to facilitate coordination between institutions when engaging with portfolio companies. One

prominent example is the UK Investor Forum, a “member-founded not-for-profit organization”

which includes many UK and third-country institutional investors.186 Following the explicit

recommendations set out in the UK equity markets review carried out by Professor John Kay

and promoted by the UK Government,187 the Investor Forum was established in 2014 with the

specific purpose of promoting collective engagement by institutional investors.188 The Investor

Forum has its own team of corporate governance and financial experts.189 At present, there are

forty-three institutional investors in the Investor Forum, of which fourteen are international,

accounting for around 30% of FTSE All Share market capitalization.190 Between 2015 and

2018, the Forum assessed forty-two collective engagement initiatives and engaged with twenty-

three companies.191 In 2018, the range of participants in collective engagement initiatives varies

between six and twenty, representing company market capitalization of between 7% and

22%.192

185 See supra, notes 176-180 and accompanying text. 186 See https://www.investorforum.org.uk. 187 See THE KAY REVIEW OF UK EQUITY MARKETS AND LONG-TERM DECISION MAKING 51–53 (2012),

https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/253454/bis-12-917-kay-review-of-equity-markets-final-report.pdf [https://perma.cc/8AJG-3U4D] [hereinafter, KAY REVIEW]. Such recommendation followed the one already made in Sir David Walker’s corporate governance review: see A REVIEW OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN UK BANKS AND OTHER FINANCIAL INDUSTRY ENTITIES. FINAL RECOMMENDATIONS (2009), https://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/+/www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/walker_review_261109.pdf [hereinafer, WALKER REVIEW].

188 ROGER. M BARKER & IRIS H.-Y. CHIU, CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT, 175 (2017).

189 See generally INV’R FORUM, REVIEW 2018 (2019), https://www.investorforum.org.uk/. [hereinafter, INV’R FORUM REVIEW]

190 Membership Summary, INV. F. (Oct. 1, 2018), https://www.investorforum.org.uk/membership-summary/ [https://perma.cc/C6T7-VH52].

191 INV’R FORUM REVIEWsupra note 189, at 3. 192 Id. at 6.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 40: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

40

In line with the recommendations of the Kay Review, the Investor Forum takes a flexible

approach.193 Crucially, collective engagements occurring under the auspices of the Investor

Forum must follow the specific formal procedures outlined by the Forum in its collective

engagement framework, which was put in place inter alia “to prevent inadvertent violation of

legal or regulatory requirements” and, thus, to reduce member institutions’ disincentives to

participate.194 According to that framework, “[m]embers retain full voting and other investment

rights in respect of their shareholdings” and are free to “choose[] to participate in an

[e]ngagement involving a [c]ompany in which [they are shareholders or] to opt out of an

[e]ngagement at any time.”195 As regards the steps that must be followed within the procedures

set out by the Forum, both affiliated institutional investors and portfolio companies can propose

an engagement.196 The Forum’s Executive evaluates the proposal and, once it has determined

that the proposal is consistent with the Forum’s engagement framework, the team engages in

consultation with the major shareholders of the company to determine the level of member

support for the proposed engagement.197 The Forum then only proceeds with the engagement

if the proposal attracts an adequate level of support.198

Similarly, in Japan, the Institutional Collective Engagement Forum was established in 2017

as a response to recommendations concerning collective engagement incorporated into the

Japanese Stewardship Code, according to which “[I]n addition to institutional investors

engaging with investee companies independently, it would be beneficial for them to engage

with investee companies in collaboration with other institutional investors (collective

engagement) as necessary”.199

In line with the UK model, the Japanese Collective Engagement Forum seeks to “help

institutional investors conduct sound and appropriate stewardship activities, especially in

collective shareholder engagements in which multiple institutional investors work together in

an aim to hold constructive dialogues with listed companies in Japan.200 To this end, the Forum

193 See KAY REVIEW, supra note 187, at 51. 194 INV’R FORUM, COLLECTIVE ENGAGEMENT FRAMEWORK. SUMMARY (2016) 2,

https://www.investorforum.org.uk/wp-content/uploads/2018/08/Collective-Engagement-Framework-Summary.pdf [hereinfater, the “INV’R FORUM, FRAMEWORK”]. See also infra Part. IV.C.

195 Id. at 3. 196 Id. at 5. 197 Id. 198 See id. 199 Japan’s Stewardship Code, Guidance 4-4. 200 https://www.iicef.jp/en/.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 41: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

41

“will promote/organize Institutional Investors Collective Engagement Program, which

coordinates collective engagement events and activities with listed companies, in collaboration

with multiple institutional investors.”201 According to the Program, investors meet to discuss

engagement agendas before contacting the companies and form a common view concerning

each engagement agenda. The Forum, acting as a coordinator, conveys participants’ shared

views to targeted companies by sending summary letters, including the names of participating

institutions, with a view “to shar[ing] their awareness and understanding of the issues the

companies are facing”202 and inviting comments from the companies concerned. In addition,

the Forum asks companies to set up meetings for face-to-face discussions where needed in order

to exchange views, and to facilitate dialogue by moderating investor-issuer meetings. Since

investors participating in the Program are “those who conduct passive investment, such as index

investment”,203 the Forum is specifically aimed at supporting investors that follow a long-term,

‘buy and hold’ investment strategy and that may have weak incentives to engage. Hence, the

Forum operates in such a way as to reduce engagement-associated costs and to counter any

cost-related disincentives to active stewardship.

3. Associations Representing Institutional Investors

Efforts to support coordinated engagement are sometimes made by institutional investor

associations, with varying degrees of intensity and in different forms—from providing member

institutions with forums for discussion, through to more organized coordination initiatives,

usually in relation to upcoming shareholder meetings.

Looser forms of support for shareholder collaboration may be exemplified by the model

provided by the Canadian Coalition for Good Governance (CCGG). Despite not being focused

on collective engagements and not playing a role as specialized as that of UK and Japanese

Forums, the CCGG offers members the possibility to utilize the organization “to distribute

governance-related information to other Members, on the Hub, an online discussion forum

where Members can share their views on governance issues and/or post links to relevant articles

and resources”.204

201 Id. 202 Id. 203 Id.. 204 See CANADIAN COAL’N FOR GOOD GOVERNANCE, BENEFITS OF MEMBERSHIP IN THE CANADIAN COALITION

FOR GOOD GOVERNANCE, https://www.ccgg.ca/site/ccgg/assets/pdf/benefits_of_membership_in_ccgg_-_the_hub.pdf.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 42: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

42

As specifically regards environmental, social and governance issues, a tool similar to that

provided by the CCGG is available for signatories to the Principles for Responsible

Investment—a set of international principles drafted by a group of the world’s largest

institutional investors, acting in partnership with the United Nations Environment Programme

Finance Initiative and the United Nations Global Compact. The PRI were launched in 2006 to

encourage the use of responsible investment to enhance returns and to better manage risks; the

initiative currently has more than 1,800 signatories internationally.205 The “Collaboration

Platform” available to PRI signatories is “a unique private forum that allows signatories to pool

resources, share information and enhance their influence on ESG issues”.206 The platform

enables signatories, for instance, to send invitations to sign joint letters to companies as well as

to request for support in relation to upcoming shareholder resolutions. In addition, it also offers

opportunities to join investor-company engagements concerning particular ESG issues,

alongside the support services provided by the PRI.207 The PRI 2018 annual report states that

333 posts (7.4% up on 2017) and 282 shareholder resolutions (a 21% increase on 2017) were

added to the collaboration platform in 2018, and that 22% of signatories had been active on the

platform; 65% of signatories reported having actively engaged with investee companies via

individual or collaborative engagements.208

More institutionalized support for collective engagement is provided by some other

investor associations. As mentioned above, one such example is that provided by Assogestioni,

the Italian non-profit Investment Management Association, which represents most of the Italian

and foreign asset managers operating in Italy. The role played by Assogestioni in collective

engagement is closely intertwined with the Italian regulatory framework for director elections

at listed companies, which is based on the so-called slate voting system. Based on the

mandatory adoption of that system, the Italian regime is intended to ensure that at least one of

the seats on the board is reserved for minorities, provided that minority shareholders actually

submit a slate of nominees to be voted on at the shareholders’ meeting.209 Minority shareholders

205 https://www.unpri.org/about-the-pri. 206 https://www.unpri.org/esg-issues/explore-the-pri-collaboration-platform. 207 Id. 208 PRINCIPLES FOR RESP. INV., ANNUAL REPORT 2018, 13-14,

https://d8g8t13e9vf2o.cloudfront.net/Uploads/g/f/c/priannualreport_605237.pdf. 209 See Decreto Legislativo 24 febbraio 1998, n. 58, Art. 147-ter (It.) (Consolidated Law on Finance), available

in English at http://www.consob.it/web/consob-and-its-activities/laws-and-regulations/documenti/english/laws/fr_decree58_1998.htm (stating that shareholders holding a minimum threshold of shares—set by the Italian Supervisory Authority and currently varying between 0.5% and 4.5%—can present lists of candidates for election to the board. At least one member must be elected from the minority

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 43: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

43

are thus offered a way of gaining access to the boardroom and obtaining a direct insight into

the company’s affairs. The activation of this pathway requires a willingness to submit a slate of

director nominees to be voted on according to the applicable rules, and to bear the (non-

negligible) cost associated with this. Since the introduction of the this system, Assogestioni has

played a central role in selecting candidates and submitting minority slates.

In doing so, Assogestioni adopts a formalized procedure. In particular, candidates are

selected in accordance with the “principles for the selection of candidates for corporate bodies

of listed companies” drawn up by the Assogestioni Corporate Governance Committee, which

is composed of members of the Association’s Board and representatives of member

companies.210 Candidates for election as minority representatives to the corporate bodies of

investee issuers are selected by the Investment Managers’ Committee—which is comprised

solely of representatives of Italian or foreign institutional investors—with the assistance of an

independent advisor. This advisor is charged with both maintaining a database of possible

candidates and submitting to the Investment Managers’ Committee a shortlist of those that

appear to best meet with the requirements for each corporate office.211 In addition, the selection

principles drawn up by the Assogestioni Corporate Governance Committee require that

candidates must have adequate professionalism, integrity, and independence and, to avoid

possible conflicts of interest, that the legal representatives of investment management

companies and—unless at least one year has elapsed since the relevant appointments were

relinquished—anyone who has served in a senior management or executive role in an

investment management company may not be selected as a candidate.212

slate, having obtained the largest number of votes, and this person must not be linked in any way, even indirectly, to the shareholders who presented or voted on the list which received the largest number of votes). According to Consob, the Italian Supervisory Authority, 96—out of 242—listed companies’ boards currently include at least one minority-appointed director: see COMMISSIONE NAZIONALE PER LE SOCIETÀ E LA BORSA (CONSOB), REPORT ON CORPORATE GOVERNANCE OF ITALIAN LISTED COMPANIES, 15 (2017), http://www.consob.it/web/consob-and-its-activities/report-on-corporate-governance. Moreover, several bylaws, especially of larger corporations, have actually made room for two or three minority-appointed directors, and the average number of directors appointed by the minority is approximately two: Piergaetano Marchetti, Gianfranco Siciliano & Marco Ventoruzzo, Disclosing Directors 7 ( Eur. Corporate Gov. Inst. (ECGI) Law Working Paper No. 420/2018) (2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3264763.

210 See ASSOGESTIONI, PROTOCOL OF DUTIES AND RESPONSIBILITIES OF THE CORPORATE GOVERNANCE COMMITTEE AND THE INVESTMENT MANAGERS’ COMMITTEE 20–21 (2017), http://www.assogestioni.it/index.cfm/3,139,12309/protfunzccg_cge_dic_2017.pdf [hereinafter “ASSOGESTIONI PROTOCOL”].

211 Id. at 24–25 (specifying that “[e]ven when minority slates are presented for elections to boards, the Committee members undertake no obligation in regard to the exercise of voting rights during general meetings”).

212 Id. at 28–29 (also stating that persons who hold a senior management or executive role in investment management companies may not be selected as candidates for company boards).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 44: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

44

In the Netherlands, Assogestioni’s equivalent, Eumedion, also seeks to facilitate

cooperation amongst its members. The association does so, amongst other things, by

“encouraging joint consultations between institutional investors, listed companies and their

representative organisations”, and providing services in the field of corporate governance to its

members.213 In particular, through its Investment Committee, Eumedion plays a facilitating role

for investor collaboration with regard to upcoming shareholders meetings, in that it

“draws up a summary of the AGMs and sends this AGM schedule to all Eumedion

members; this schedule contains a proposal stating which member(s) wish to attend a

certain AGM. The person going to an AGM makes a (preliminary) analysis of the items

on the agenda and forwards this to the members. Members can decide on the basis of the

AGM schedule and analysis whether to give a proxy to the person attending the AGM.

… If required, the person attending the AGM can consult in advance on the items on the

agenda for the AGM with other members attending the AGM. … A member can decide

on the basis of the analysis of the items on the agenda for the AGM to give the person

going to the AGM a proxy to vote in favour or against an item on the agenda, depending

on the discussion during the AGM.”214

Thus, Eumedion provides a kind of “consultation platform” for its members, although does

not provide any analysis of its own concerning the items on the agenda, or issue any voting

recommendation, and also does not receive proxies or vote on behalf of its members.215 As is

also explained, the objective of the joining of forces in the Eumedion investment committee is

to enable “the exchange of information in order to arrive at a stance with regard to subjects

related to corporate governance”, and not to form a coalition to exercise member voting rights

at the shareholders meeting.216

Also the U.S. Council of Institutional investors (CII) sometimes acts as “a facilitator of

interactions among members and asset management industry players”.217 Specifically, the CII

hosts occasional "engagement exchanges" where corporate and investor members can meet

213 EUMEDION, MISSION, https://www.eumedion.nl/en/abouteumedion#what-does-eumedion-do. 214 EUMEDION, CORPORATE GOVERNANCE MANUAL 50 (2008),

https://www.eumedion.nl/en/public/knowledgenetwork/manual/2008-manual-corporate-governance.pdf. 215 Id. 216 Id. at 51 (explaining that “Eumedion members may naturally pursue the same course of action because

they share the same opinion, but this does not mean that they are acting in concert.”). 217 Enriques & Romano, supra note 107, at 245.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 45: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

45

one-on-one or in small groups to discuss particular issues of concern.218 In addition, the CII

annually publishes the “Focus List” of underperforming companies with the aim of attracting

members’ attention to such companies so as to “compel company managers to step up efforts

to improve performance.”219 However, it does not perform a coordinating function for affiliated

investors similar to that of its foreign equivalent counterpart institutions.220 The action

encouraged by the publication of the Focus List does not require consultation among investors,

and usually does not result in collective engagements by members.221

C. The Benefits of Non-Activist Collective Engagements

While the impact of wolf pack activism on targeted firms has been investigated in a number

of studies, both theoretical and empirical,222 the potential benefits of non-activist collective

engagements are as yet underexplored. This Part illustrates how different forms of non-activist

investors’ cooperation can help to lower costs, and make engagement more effective and safer.

1. Cost Sharing and Limiting Collective Action Problems

Available empirical evidence-albeit still limited-consistently shows that collective

engagements are more successful than solo-initiatives. In fact, so the argument goes,

coordination between several institutional investors increases the potential influence of

engagement activities “via louder voice and larger power”.223 The pioneering study by Gillan

and Starks dealing with the corporate governance role of institutional investors shows that

“proposals sponsored by institutions or through coordinated activities receive significantly

more favorable votes than those sponsored by independent individuals or religious

218 https://www.cii.org/engagement. 219 Gary L. Caton et al., The Effectiveness of Institutional Activism, 57 FIN. ANALYSTS 21, 21 (2001). See also

Andrew J. Ward et al., Under the spotlight: institutional investors and firm responses to the Council of Institutional Investors’ Annual Focus List, 7 STRATEGIC ORG. 107 (2009) (showing that “institutional investors respond to this negative third-party signal by reducing their holdings in firms that received this public repudiation” and that “targeted firms with more independent boards respond by increasing the intensity of incentives of the CEO, thus signaling their responsiveness to investor concerns”).

220 See Andrew F. Tuch, Proxy Advisor Influence, 99 B. U. L. REV. 1459, 1486-7 (2019). 221 Wei-Ling Song & Samuel H. Szewczyk, Does Coordinated Institutional Investor Activism Reverse the

Fortunes of Underperforming Firms?, 38 J. FIN. QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS 317, 318 (2003). 222 See supra Part IV.A.1. 223 Dimson et al., supra note 137, at 9.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 46: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

46

organizations”.224 More recently, Dodge and others have found that collective engagement

initiatives promoted by the Canadian Coalition for Good Governance (CCGG) has a notable

rate of success.225 Specifically, CCGG-led engagements increase the likelihood that targeted

investee companies will adopt governance reforms (e.g. majority voting, say-on-pay advisory

votes, shareholder-aligned compensation policies) requested by institutional investors.226 Along

the same lines, Dimson and others show that coordinated engagements have a fairly high rate

of success, especially when the investor leading the initiative is located in the same geographic

region as the targeted firm.227

While, of course, the greater likelihood of success of collective engagements proves to be

an effective incentive,228 it does not help to exhaustively explain why institutional investors

should be willing to become involved in such initiatives. To clarify this point, it is essential to

consider how collective engagement initiatives can promote more active conduct by

institutional investors by favoring the redistribution of the engagement costs among the

institutional investors that carry out engagement activities collectively229, thereby increasing

the net return earned by each institutional investor involved.230 Moreover, in doing so, collective

engagement initiatives also lower the free-rider problem that significantly contributes to the

institutional investors’ “rational reticence”.231

Indeed, while according to conventional wisdom each investor maximizes its wealth by

declining to participate in collective initiatives and by free-riding on other investors’ efforts,232

there is an apparent economic incentive to join forces, irrespective of whether particular

investors might nonetheless prefer to free-ride. Since fund managers are remunerated by a fee

that is usually a percentage (1%-2%) of the assets under management, they are naturally

224 Gillan & Starks, supra note 15, at 277. 225 Doidge et al., supra note 137 at 14. 226 Id. at 17-24. 227 Dimson et al., supra note 137, at 23-26. 228 Tanja Artiga González & Paul Calluzzo, supra note 137, at 212 (noting that “greater costs would increase

the incentive for activists to pool their resources through clustering”). 229 See OECD, THE ROLE OF INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORS IN PROMOTING GOOD CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 38

(2011), https://www.oecd.org/daf/ca/49081553.pdf [https://perma.cc/9RZD-9377] (“The ability for institutional investors to co-operate is fundamental to resolving the free rider problems . . . .”).

230 Artiga González & Calluzzo, supra note 228, at 212; Doidge et al., supra note 137, at 7. 231 Gilson & Gordon, supra note 35, 888–902; Kahan & Rock, supra note 34, 1048–57; Rock, supra note 8,

453–64. See also Paul Davies, Shareholders in the United Kingdom 16 (Eur. Corp. Gov. Inst. (ECGI) Law Working Paper No. 280/2015) (Jan, 2015), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2557680

232 Id. at 15-16.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 47: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

47

interested in any actions in relation to an investee company that is likely to increase the value

of assets under management, since this implies higher fees in monetary terms.233

A simple example can help to reinforce the point. First, where an engagement intervention

is expected to result in an increase in the returns of assets under management of $ 1,000,000

and implies costs of $ 15,000, an investor charging a fee equal to 2 per cent of assets under

management will earn an additional fee of $ 20,000, and thus a net gain of $ 5,000. While such

initiative will be per se profitable even if it is taken individually, profits would be higher for

our investor if the same initiative were to be carried out collectively. For example, if the $

15,000 costs were to be shared among (say) 10 investors, our investor would earn a net profit

of $ 18,500.234

Second, collective engagement may prompt investors to engage in initiatives that would not

be profitable if pursued individually. For example, where engagement is expected to result in

an increase of the returns of assets under management of $ 1,000,000 and has a cost of $ 30,000,

an investor charging a fee equal to 2 per cent of assets under management would not engage,

as it would suffer a net loss of $ 10,000. Conversely, if the same initiative were to be carried

out by a number of investors¾say 10¾that share the costs, it would become profitable for our

investor as it would earn a net profit of $ 17,000.

However, a coordinating entity is required in order to make the collective engagement

mechanism actually work.

First, a coordinating entity can reduce free-riding problems by lowering the risk that

engagement costs are borne by a limited number of investors, while benefits are shared by all

other investors who are shareholders in the same investee company. For example, with the aim

of favoring the sharing of engagement-related benefits and costs among investors, in order to

allocate costs in proportion with the "size" of associated asset managers, Assogestioni's bylaws

state that each member must pay a fee comprised of a fixed amount and a variable amount,

which is established by dividing the remaining portion of the budget amongst all members in

proportion with the assets collected and/or managed at the end of the previous year.235 As is

233 Kahan & Rock, supra note 28, at 15-29. 234 Even if we assume that collective engagement comes with higher costs due to the fee to be paid to the

coordinating entity, a clear economic incentive to engage collectively remains. Where, referred to the example in the text above, such fee is $ 10.000¾and overall engagement costs are $ 25.000¾our investor would still earn a net profit of $ 17.500.

235 See ASSOGESTIONI BYLAWS 34 (2016), http://www.assogestioni.it/index.cfm/3,813,11301 /statuto-marzo-2016.pdf.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 48: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

48

reported by Dodge and others,236 the CCGG adopts a more complex cost-sharing mechanism,

which favors cost allocation among affiliated investors by providing for increased fees in line

with the size (in terms of assets under management) of the institution, with a cap above a certain

threshold.237 Along the same lines, a similar solution is advanced by Sharon Hannes, who

argues that the crucial issue of the funding of collective engagements coordinated by a

specialized task force (called “Super Hedge Fund”) should follow a two-tier structure aimed at:

i) placing the greatest burden on those that have invested in the specific target company

identified by the task force, based on a pro-rata mechanism that takes account of the size of

investors’ holdings;238 ii) sharing the lower tier¾unrelated to specific engagement

initiatives¾minimal funding serving the pre-engagement activities of the task force among all

investors involved in the task force. 239

If it is considered that “the most important factor by far in determining how much a fund

advisor stands to gain from being informed is the size of the holdings”,240 cost-sharing

mechanisms that allocate costs among participating investors proportionately with the size of

their stakes could also help to alleviate another potential disincentive against joining collective

initiatives. In fact, where engagement costs are allocated equally amongst participating

investors, irrespective of the size of their holdings, investors with an overweighting of the shares

of the target companies in their portfolio will earn more than investors that have underweighted

those shares in their portfolio, and can hence improve their relative performance, attracting

236 Doidge et al., supra note 137, at 28. 237 See CANADIAN COAL’N FOR GOOD GOVERNANCE, 2017 ANNUAL REPORT 26 (2018),

https://www.ccgg.ca/annual-report/ (“Annual Member fees are based on total assets under management (AUM). The annual fee for Members with total AUM below $1.5 billion is $2,500. As total AUM increases above $1.5 billion, the fee escalates on a straight-line basis by $1,500 for every $1 billion to a maximum annual fee of $44,000. An affiliate of a Member paying the maximum annual fee of $44,000 is eligible to become a Member for an annual fee of $2,500 irrespective of that affiliate’s total AUM”).

238 See Hannes, supra note 22, at 183 (noting that “[t]his capital call to the direct investors of the target forges the link that is missing today between the institutional long-term shareholders of the target of the activism and the agent that executes the activism”).

239 Id. at 182-83 (explaining that “Tier-one funding would be quite minimal and used to support the task force before it engages in activism ... However, once the task force begins to zero in on a target, it would become entitled to call for additional and much more substantial tier-two funding … to cover major possible expenses such as proxy fight costs, litigation, and public and investors relations campaigns. Most importantly, the source of funding for the two tiers would differ as follows: the low-tier-one funding would be provided by all institutional investors that have signed an agreement with the task force. [By contrast,] funding called for after the task force has zeroed in on a target would … be borne solely by the institutional investors that invest in the specific potential corporate target and pro-rata to their holdings in the target.” (footnotes omitted)).

240 Kahan & Rock, supra note 28, at 21.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 49: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

49

clients from other institutional investors.241 By contrast, a size-related allocation of engagement

costs among participating investors can level out the relative performances of investors

involved in the collective initiatives, and therefore reduce stake size-related disincentives.

Second, a third-party coordinating entity can facilitate the circulation of information and

agreement among institutional investors.242 Such a facilitating role is especially important in

order to save costs and time when the investors involved in collective initiatives have different

geographic and cultural backgrounds. In fact, absent such an entity, cooperation between

investors would appear to be ineffective and excessively expensive. In particular, without an

entity playing a coordinating role, “to achieve agreement among many investors from diverse

geographic and cultural backgrounds may prolong the process. The delayed action may reduce

the effectiveness of engagements on issues that are time sensitive”.243

2. Alleviating Regulatory Risks The presence of a third-party coordinating entity can also help to reduce potential

disincentives against joint collective engagement initiatives posed by regulatory hurdles and

also to lessen compliance costs.244 Although the chilling effect of regulatory hurdles on

collective engagement cannot be completely eliminated, there are ways in which cross-

jurisdictional regulatory concerns can be effectively kept under control. Chiefly, a third-party

entity taking on an active coordination function (which function will be most effectively

performed where it is based on specific formal procedures and safeguards) can work as an

effective tool to reduce the risk of concerted action, group formation, or the selective disclosure

of relevant information in breach of Regulation FD-or the Market Abuse Regulation in the

EU.245 Indeed, practical experience with some existing organizations seems to be encouraging.

241 Id. at 23 (illustrating that since “it is relative performance, rather than absolute performance, that affects

fund flows . . . attracting future fund flows generates no incentives for a portfolio managers to cast an informed vote to increase the value of stock in which a fund is underweight relative to competing funds or the benchmark”).

242 The coordinating entity could help investors interested in joining collective initiatives to reach an agreement by creating confidence that “costs of intervention will be spread across a number of institutions”. See Davies, supra note 231, at 10.

243 Dimson et al., supra note 137, at 10. See also Jean-Pascal Gond & Valeria Piani, Enabling Institutional Investors’ Collective Action: The Role of the Principles for Responsible Investment Initiative, 52 BUS.& SOCIETY 64, 72 (2013).

244 Dimson et al., supra note 137, at 10. See infra Part V.A. 245 See, for a similar view, id. at 10.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 50: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

50

The most illustrative example of this is UK Investor Forum, whose framework for collective

engagements was designed with a view to preventing “inadvertent violation of legal or

regulatory requirements” imposed by multiple jurisdictions involved in cross-border investment

decisions.

As regards concerted action or group formation, the framework requires members wishing

to participate in an engagement to “agree that they will not … form a concert party in respect

of the relevant Company, including by requisitioning or threatening to requisition the

consideration of a board control-seeking proposal or seeking to obtain control of the relevant

Company, or otherwise form a group that could trigger regulatory reporting or other regulatory

requirements.”246 To that end, any engaging member will need to confirm its adherence to the

Forum’s no-concert party and no-group undertaking, as well as its code of conduct;

additionally, the Forum’s executives will carry out appropriate monitoring to ensure

consistency with the Forum’s principles and code of conduct, ask members to withdraw from

an engagement (or expel them if necessary) “if their behaviour compromises the Forum’s

activities”, and ensure liaison with the UK Takeover Panel, seeking specialist advice whenever

required.247

As far as inside information is concerned, the Forum is committed to “actively seek to avoid

obtaining inside information from Companies and Members without its prior consent” and to

“actively seek to avoid passing on any inside information that it may receive to Members

without their prior consent”, while also applying certain procedures aimed at identifying and

quarantining inside information, where such information may possibly have been received or

generated by the Forum.248

In addition, since members are subjected to confidentiality obligations during an

engagement, communications between the Forum’s Executive and the members involved are

based on a bilateral model, and communication with the issuer is conducted by the Forum’s

Executive itself, it is clear that coordination by the Forum (or similar organizations) relies on

the organization’s leadership in heading the dialogue as a means of avoiding direct action by

member institutions, as well as direct communications between participating members and

between companies and the engaging members.249 In fact, to develop the engagement strategy,

246 See INV’R FORUM, FRAMEWORK, supra note 194, at 4. 247 Id. 248 Id. at 3. 249 Id. at 6.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 51: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

51

the Forum provides members with a description of the range of views expressed by them with

the Executive, thus allowing mutual oversight by investors; however, the Forum refrains from

both exercising any advisory function and from seeking “to form an agreement between

Members, in particular in relation to their investment or voting decisions”.250

Overall, under a formalized model similar to that put forward by the UK Investor Forum,

the particular engagement follows a course that ensures as far as possible that its strategy and

outcomes cannot be regarded, with hindsight, as being either premised on intentional, let alone

agreed, group formation or concerted action, or built on the exploitation of inside information.

3. Enhancing Expertise Collective initiatives involving a large number of investors can also improve the

effectiveness of the engagement “by borrowing expertise from investors in the group who are

more knowledgeable about an issue or target company”.251 This assumption is in line with

empirical evidence showing that, as far as ESG-related engagements promoted by the PRI are

concerned, success rates of collective initiatives are increased by around one-third “when there

is a lead investor who heads the dialogue, especially when that investor is located in the same

geographic region as the targeted firm” and is therefore supposed to have a superior knowledge

of the local economic and regulatory context. 252

While, of course, even engagement initiatives coordinated by one of the participating

institutional investors that takes the lead within the group of investors can prove to be

successful, the facilitating role played by a third-party coordinating entity seems to be crucial

also in this respect. First, absent such an entity, collective action problems can prevent leading

investors-which are theoretically capable of enhancing the group’s expertise-from undertaking

collective engagements. While the lead investor bears a considerable costs burden to gather the

necessary information, potential benefits of the engagement efforts, such as improved firm

performance and a higher stock price, are shared among all stakeholders.253

In addition, although they are deemed to have adequate knowledge and resources to perform

a coordination function, even the biggest international institutional investors -in terms of assets

under management-might not be able to provide case-specific expertise. First, those leading

250 Id. 251 Dimson et al., supra note 137, at 9. 252 Id. at 5, 22. 253 Id.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 52: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

52

actors may not add to expertise where the engagement initiatives take place outside their

country of origin as they might not have adequate knowledge about the foreign regulatory and

business context or the investee company to which the engagement relates. Given the

considerable number of portfolio companies, the stewardship teams at leading institutional

investors are not capable of dedicating the same degree of attention to all portfolio companies

or preparing detailed reports for each one.254 Second, the major institutional investors, and

especially passive investors holding stakes in thousands of companies, draw up standardized

voting guidelines which they normally tend to follow fairly closely. Therefore, leading

investors are generally unwilling to go beyond their standardized guidelines and to make

significant investments in any company-specific analyses that may be required by engagement

in more complex situations, such as proxy contests or M&A and related-party transactions.255

Against this background, an adequately organized third-party coordinating entity employing

high-skilled professionals256 can play a key role in providing institutional investors that intend

to cooperate with the necessary expertise. For example, such enabling institutions can help to

identify issues of interest to heterogeneous investors as well as investors that may potentially

be interested in joining the collective engagement,257 or to develop an engagement strategy that

meets with the expectations of all investors concerned.258 Moreover, the third-party

coordinating entity can keep member institutional investors informed concerning issues

relevant to engagement. For example, the Canadian Coalition for Good Governance aims to

provide its members with updated information concerning corporate governance developments

by publishing a range of materials-including best practice guidance, policies and principles,

and research studies-and hosting educational initiatives on governance topics on a continuing

basis.259 In addition, the Canadian Coalition for Good Governance also provides members with

a detailed analysis of the governance practices of each listed company that is involved in the

Coalition’s engagement program.260

254 See generally Strampelli, supra note 99, at 820; Bebchuk & Hirst, supra note 70, at 31-35. 255 See e.g. Bebchuk & Hirst, supra note 70, at 36 (note 83). 256 For example, all members of the UK Investor Forum’s teams have a strong financial background and past

working experiences in the financial services and investment sector. See INV’R FORUM, Team, https://www.investorforum.org.uk/about/meet-the-team/.

257 See Gond & Piani, supra note 243, at 72-73. 258 INV’R FORUM, FRAMEWORK, supra note 194, at 6. 259 CANADIAN COAL’N FOR GOOD GOVERNANCE, supra note 237, at 4. 260 Id. at 5.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 53: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

53

In this respect, as the activity of the UK Investor Forum or the Canadian Coalition for Good

Governance indicates, it must be borne in mind that such institutions are able to empower

collective engagement initiatives by providing expertise concerning relevant issues related to

the engagement and company-specific information as they manage a limited number of

engagements, usually concerning issues that go beyond the routine matters usually covered by

the voting and engagement policies adopted by most of leading institutional investors. While

such investors engage with a huge number of investee companies,261 in the first 4 years of its

life the UK Investor Forum evaluated 42 UK company engagements and engaged in 23

engagement initiatives.262 Similarly, the Canadian Coalition for Good Governance usually

engages with the boards of approximately 45 to 50 companies every year.263 Therefore, it is

apparent that such third-party coordinating entities will have more skilled human resources to

dedicate to each engagement and, in doing so, can help to overcome problems posed by the

small size of leading institutional investors’ investment stewardship teams.

Therefore, as one of us has already noted, coordinated engagement cannot¾and does not

seek to¾radically modify non-activist institutional investor engagement practices. Arguably,

third-party enabling entities can help to promote more proactive engagement with non-routine

issues, such as proxy contests or M&A and related-party transactions.264 By contrast, given also

the size of existing enabling entities, investors are likely to “continue to adopt standardized

voting policies and to rely largely on proxy advisory services for routine matters.”265

4. Reinforcing Reputational Incentives

261 For example, BlackRock-the world’s largest asset manger-reports about 2.000 engagements in 2018, even

though most engagements were qualified as “basic” and generally amounted to one single conversation concerning a routine matter. See BLACKROCK, INVESTMENT STEWARDSHIP REPORT: 2018 VOTING AND ENGAGEMENT REPORT 3 (2018), https://www.blackrock.com/corporate/literature/publication/blk-voting-and-engagment-statistics-annual-report-2018.pdf.

262 INV’R FORUM REVIEW, supra note 189, at 3. 263 CANADIAN COAL’N FOR GOOD GOVERNANCE, supra note 237, at 5. 264 Strampelli, supra note 99, at 845. See also Davies, supra note 231, at 10 (arguing that “[n]on-routine

intervention by shareholders in the management of investee companies thus requires the construction of a coalition of institutions to be effective”).

265 Id.; Kahan & Rock, supra note 28, at 38; Hannes, supra note 22, at 179 (noting that, as for pension funds, “[t]hey do not have to delve into the business activities of any single company in order to conduct such activism . . . In other words, this is an inexpensive type of activism, and it does not cost much to develop the agenda or manifest it, nor does it need to be tailored to the business challenges and failures facing any single corporation”). But see Tuch, supra note 220, at 1504 (contending that the empowerment of coordinating entities aimed at promoting institutional investors’ collective initiatives could limit proxy advisors’ influence in the United States).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 54: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

54

Since it is widely acknowledged that reputational concerns can prompt leading fund

managers to play an active monitoring role over their investee companies,266 it must be also

noted that collective engagements are, to some extents, able to reinforce such a reputational

mechanism. In fact, it can plausibly be argued that institutional investors could be incentivized

to join collective initiatives where these prove to be successful or to be viewed positively by

end clients.267

This intuition is backed up by the model designed by Brav and others showing that

“reputational rents can be achieved only by participating in a successful activism campaign”,

while “[t]here are never rents for remaining inactive, even when activism fails.” 268 In addition,

this line of reasoning is also supported by anecdotal evidence.269 In particular, although the

benefits of collective engagement for passive investors are, in theory, more limited due to the

presence of internal stewardship teams, as well as the fact that each portfolio company has a

lower relative weight, collective engagement can also incentivize passive index fund managers

to engage in costlier engagement activities. For example, BlackRock carefully emphasizes in

its proxy voting guidelines for European securities that “under the umbrella of the Collective

Engagement Framework of the Investor Forum [BlackRock participates] in collaborative

engagements with other shareholders where concerns have been identified by a number of

investors.”270

In addition, actions could be taken both by the coordinating entity itself and by regulators

to enhance the incentivizing power of collective engagements.

Fist, as is suggested by Hannes, the coordinating entity could stipulate that a minimal

number of adhering investors is a necessary condition for initiating engagement initiatives,

thereby limiting the potential chilling effect of conflicts of interest affecting institutional

investors that do significant business with investee companies, and which are therefore not

willing to gain a reputation for being troublemakers.271 In fact, such an approach already

characterizes the operations of the UK Investor Forum, since the Forum only initiates an

266 See supra Part III.A.3. 267 See Hannes, supra note 22, at 189 (noting that “[i]nstitutional investors that choose to opt out of a scheme

that seems socially beneficial would suffer reputational loss”). 268 Brav, Dasgupta & Mathews, supra note 150, at 20. 269 Strampelli, supra note 99, at 848. 270 BLACKROCK, PROXY VOTING GUIDELINES FOR EUROPEAN, MIDDLE EASTERN AND AFRICAN SECURITIES 2

(2019), https://www.blackrock.com/corporate/about-us/investment-stewardship#principles-and-guidelines. 271 Hannes, supra note 22, at 187 (highlighting that such “provision would ease the reputational concern of

potentially conflicted institutional investors”).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 55: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

55

engagement when there is the “reasonable prospect of securing sufficient support among the

company’s largest shareholders”.272

Second, the incentivizing role of collective engagement could be further strengthened by

the broader disclosure of collective engagement initiatives. In particular, where a third-party

entity acts as the coordinator, it could disclose the identity of any institutional investors that

join each engagement initiative. Currently, coordinating entities usually publish only a list of

affiliated institutional investors, without specifying the specific engagements of each member.

Given that some institutional investors would prefer to keep their involvement in collective

engagement initiatives confidential, a flexible approach would be one under which the identity

of the investors involved in specific engagement initiatives would only be disclosed with the

consent of the investors themselves. Moreover, to avoid any potential unintended consequences

of such an enhanced disclosure, the list of the investors joining a specific engagement should

only be published once the engagement initiative in question has been concluded.

In addition, to enhance the reputational incentive, as suggested in the new draft version of

the UK Stewardship Code, investors could be required to disclose "whether or not they

participate in collaborative engagement with other investors and/or other market participants”

and to provide additional information, including “their objective(s) for collaborative

engagements in which they plan to participate or have already done so”; “the number of

collaborative engagements they have participated in during the previous year”; and “an

assessment of the effectiveness of the collaborative engagements they have participated”.273

V. IMPLICATIONS

As described in Part IV, one distinction that can be made in relation to shareholder

collaboration is whether collaboration is driven by activist or non-activist institutions.

As they are promoted by activist shareholders that generate profit by implementing major

changes in their portfolio public companies, wolf-packs clearly seek to gain control of corporate

boards to influence corporate decision making. Specifically, “activist investors’ purchases of a

large stake in a public company are direct to “lobby the company's management to implement

changes that the investors believe would increase shareholder value”.274

272 See INV’R FORUM, FRAMEWORK, supra note 194, at 5. 273 PROPOSED REVISIONS TO THE UK STEWARDSHIP CODE, supra note 172, at 17. 274 Carmen X. W. Lu, Unpacking Wolf Packs, 125 YALE L. J. 773, 774 (2016).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 56: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

56

On the other hand, stewardship codes, principles and guidelines that offer guidance on how

investors should exert active ownership and interact with portfolio companies, explicitly make

it clear that “[e]ngagement by active and index-tracking investors differs from the approach

taken by activist investors who purchase large numbers of shares in a company and may try to

obtain seats on the company's board with the goal of effecting a major change in the

company”.275 Based on the assumption that investments are focused on a horizon longer than

that which is usual for activists, stewardship codes underscore the need that traditional

institutions—whether actively managed or index-tracking funds—should conceive of

engagement as a tool for building constructive relationships with investee companies, based

chiefly on mutual understanding.276 Hence, investor engagement is generally regarded as being

premised on pre-existing stakes and being focused on longer-term relationships with investee

companies. Therefore, the nature of an engagement-based form of shareholder cooperation that

is explicitly supported by virtually any stewardship code is very different from that of wolf

packs.

Accordingly, these different types of shareholder collaboration should be kept distinct also

as regards the applicable regulatory framework. In particular, non-activist driven collective

engagements should not be reined in by the rules on group formation that are relevant to

blockholder disclosure requirements and the rules imposed on inside information.

A. Smoothing the 13D Filing Obligation Hurdle

From the regulatory standpoint, the debate concerning wolf-packs largely focuses on the

circumvention of 13D-filing obligations by wolf-pack members as a group. The rationale of

blockholder disclosure under section 13(d) is “focused on informing investors about purchases

of large blocks of shares acquired in a short period of time by individuals [or groups] who could

then influence or change control of the issuing company.”277 In essence, 13D disclosures

provide investors with an early warning concerning potential shifts in corporate control.

Delaying disclosures by avoiding formal coordination while exploiting tipping regarding an

275 EFAMA Stewardship Code, Background, at 4. 276 Id. at 3-4. See also WALKER REVIEW, supra note 187, 72. 277 Kristin Giglia, A Little Letter, A Big Difference: An Empirical Inquiry Into Possible Misuse of Schedule

13G/13D Filings, 116 COLUM. L. REV., 105, 110 (2016); Hill, supra note 25, at 523.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 57: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

57

upcoming activist campaign may well be lawful under both insider trading rules278 and section

13(d)(3) of the Exchange Act. However, wolf pack tactics could potentially facilitate creeping

control acquisitions. Moreover, trading on asymmetric information over the ten-day window is

regarded as “com[ing] at the expense of selling shareholders”, since it allows for wealth

transfers in favor of the activists.279 In general terms, the passing of “material non-public

information to a select few”, which seems to be inherent in the wolf pack tactic, feeds a

perception of unfairness.280

By contrast, collective engagement by non-activist institutions does not call for the same

degree of regulatory concern as the conscious parallelism of the wolf pack. In the first place,

the very notion of collective engagement—as conceived of within the context of stewardship

codes and principles—makes it clear that collective action is not about seeking control or

exerting decisive influence over the firms’ management, but basically about performing active

monitoring. Engagement-related coordination will not seek to bring about major corporate

changes, unless such changes result from a “consensus process” with the issuer. That feature

explains why, as a rule, collective engagement levers pre-existing equity stakes in order to

develop longer-term foundational corporate relations. This is particularly evident where passive

index-tracking investors are involved, who simply cannot trade their stocks unless changes in

the benchmark index occur. Consequently, since “any promising involvement by shareholders

will require more than acting in concert for one vote,”281 stewardship is not meant to be

occasional but implies an ongoing activity aimed at disciplining corporate managers. By

contrast, coordinated activist intervention, such as that underlying wolf packs, more easily falls

into the category of what has been termed “an ad hoc, one-period affair”.282

Furthermore, as experience with Assogestioni concerning corporate elections in Italy

shows,283 even where board representation is sought, coordinated collective engagements do

278 See Strine, supra note 133, at 1897 (explaining that “so long as they are not disclosing nonpublic

information which they obtained as a result of an insider's breach of duty, hedge funds are normally free to tip third parties about their own plans or intentions without running afoul of Rule 10b-5.").

279 See Coffee & Palia, supra note 132, at 597. 280 Id. at 600. 281 See Manuel A. Utset, Disciplining Managers: Shareholder Cooperation in the Shadow of Shareholder

Competition, 44 EMORY L. J. 71, 76 (1995). 282 Id. 283 See Matteo Erede, Governing Corporations with Concentrated Ownership Structure: An Empirical Analysis

of Hedge Fund Activism in Italy and Germany, and Its Evolution, 10 EUR. CO. & FIN. L. REV. 328, 371 (2013). See also Massimo Belcredi et al., Board Elections and Shareholder Activism: The Italian Experiment, in BOARDS AND SHAREHOLDERS IN EUROPEAN LISTED COMPANIES: FACTS, CONTEXT AND POST-CRISIS REFORMS 414 (Massimo Belcredi & Guido Ferrarini eds., 2013); Luigi Zingales, Italy Leads in Protecting Minority Investors,

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 58: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

58

not depart from the constructivist approach fostered by stewardship principles internationally

and are not aimed at gaining control of the board. The number of nominees included in the lists

of director nominees submitted according to the procedure adopted by Assogestioni

corresponds to fewer than half of the seats on the board.284 In addition, only nominees who meet

with specified independence requirements are included in the lists.285 In keeping with the

predominantly monitoring role that is to be performed by minority-appointed directors, director

nominees are required to declare that, if elected, they will act in full independence and exercise

autonomous judgment in the pursuit of the company’s interests.286 This approach is very

different from that characterizing activist intervention,287 where hedge fund executives are

frequently appointed288 and board representation mostly serves as a toehold which can be

exploited to promote, if not to force through, wider-ranging objectives.289 Such objectives may

be “related to business strategies, balance sheet actions (such as returning cash to shareholders

through dividends or share repurchase) and divestitures or other M&A actions (such as

encouraging a sale of the target company or opposing a merger) by target companies”.290

All in all, engaging collectively does not in itself mean that the collaborating shareholders

are motivated by the purpose of bringing about the effect, “of changing or influencing the

control of the issuer” (or a willingness to do so).291 Therefore, the collaborating investors should

not, in principle, be required to switch from a 13G to a 13D filing and be treated as a group.292

FIN. TIMES (Apr. 13, 2008), https://www.ft.com/content/357c40c4-094d-11dd-81bf-0000779f2ac (a vote for a list sponsored by Assogestioni is not “a vote against the management but a vote to ensure truly independent board members and avoid the representation of other opportunistic minority shareholders, who might have other goals in mind”).

284 ASSOGESTIONI PROTOCOL, supra note 210, at 25. See also Coffee & Palia, supra note 132, at 560, n. 57 (noting that “The goal of the short slate rule also was to encourage ‘constructive engagement’ through minority board representation...”).

285 ASSOGESTIONI PROTOCOL, supra note 210, at 25 and 28 (stating that appointed directors “do not entertain and have not entertained, whether directly or indirectly, relationships which may affect their independence of judgment with the company for which they are nominated for a corporate office, or with the persons or entities who nominate them, or with persons or entities related to said company or to the nominators”).

286 Id. at 29. 287 See Matteo Erede, supra note 283, at 370. 288 See generally Matthew D. Cain et al., How Corporate Governance Is Made: The Case of the Golden Leash,

164 U. PA. L. REV. 649 (2016). 289 Coffee & Palia, supra note 132, n. 57. 290 Sullivan & Cromwell, 2016 U.S. Shareholder Activism Review and Analysis 15 (Nov. 28, 2016),

https://www.sullcrom.com/siteFiles/Publications/SC_Publication_2016_U.S._Shareholder_Activism_Review_and_Analysis.pdf .

291 See 17 C.F.R. § 240.13d-1 (b) (2017). 292 See Hill, supra note 25, at 523 (noting that some regulators “have attempted the difficult task of

differentiating between "good" and "bad" collective activism, with the aim of encouraging the former and deterring the latter”). See e.g. AUSTL. SECS. & INV. COMM'N REGULATORY GUIDE COLLECTIVE ACTIONS BY

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 59: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

59

Yet, it cannot be denied that the current regulatory framework for blockholder filings

remains a roadblock that can thwart engagements by non-activist investors. For example, as

Bebchuk and Hirst point out, to avoid taking on Schedule 13D filer status, the three leading

passive investors “refrain entirely from communications about particular individuals who they

believe should be added to or removed from the board in the vast number of situations in which

one or more of the Big Three had positions of 5% or more in portfolio companies.”293

Uncertainty as regards the continuing eligibility to file (individually or jointly) on Schedule

13G cannot be ruled out completely within the context of collective engagement activities, since

the determination as to whether beneficial ownership of equity securities has been acquired or

is held for the purpose of or with the effect of changing or influencing corporate control “is

based upon all the relevant facts and circumstances”.294

Given that “a control purpose reflects the state of mind of a filing person”,295 the SEC’s

view of the types of activity that could reveal a controlling purpose is a broad one. Indeed, the

Commission’s interpretations in this area are ambiguous and inconclusive; thus, investors

routinely filing on Schedule 13G may not without some reason be wary that participating in a

collective engagement could result in the loss of their passive investor status.

In fact, regarding eligibility to use Schedule 13G under Exchange Act Rule 13d-1(b) or 13d-

1(c), the SEC has illustrated that “[t]he subject matter of the shareholder’s discussions with the

issuer’s management may be dispositive in making this determination, although the context in

which the discussions occur is also highly relevant.”296 According to the examples provided by

the Commission,

Generally, engagement with an issuer’s management on executive compensation and

social or public interest issues (such as environmental policies), without more, would not

INVESTORS 4 (2015), http://download.asic.gov.au/ media/3273670/rgl28-published-23-june-2015.pdf (“there is a difference between investors expressing views and promoting appropriate discipline in entity decision making and investors effectively taking control of entity decision making. Regulatory support for collective action by investors must recognise that the takeover and substantial holding provisions place limits on cooperation between investors to avoid control over an entity being acquired inappropriately”).

293 Bebchuk & Hirst, supra note 70, at 47-48. See also BLACKROCK, THE INVESTMENT STEWARDSHIP ECOSYSTEM 5, 13, 17 (2018), https://www.blackrock.com/corporate/literature/whitepaper/viewpoint-investment-stewardship-ecosystem-july-2018.pdf ( “BlackRock has never sought a seat on a public company board as part of its stewardship activities”).

294 See SEC’S & EXCHANGE COMM’N, Exchange Act Sections 13(d) and 13(g) and Regulation 13D-G Beneficial Ownership Reporting, Compliance and Disclosure Interpretations, Question 103.11 (July 14, 2016), https://www.sec.gov/divisions/corpfin/guidance/reg13d-interp.htm.

295 Amendments to Beneficial Ownership Reporting Requirements, Exchange Act Release No. 34-39538, 63 Fed. Reg. 2854 (Mar 31,1998), www.sec.gov./rules/final/34-39538.txt.

296 See supra, note 294.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 60: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

60

preclude a shareholder from filing on Schedule 13G so long as such engagement is not

undertaken with the purpose or effect of changing or influencing control of the issuer and

the shareholder is otherwise eligible to file on Schedule 13G.297

In its adopting release, the SEC also stated that a shareholder’s proposal or soliciting activity

relating to such topics would not generally cause a loss of Schedule 13G eligibility. Moreover,

Engagement on corporate governance topics, such as removal of staggered boards,

majority voting standards in director elections, and elimination of poison pill plans,

without more, generally would not disqualify an otherwise eligible shareholder from

filing on Schedule 13G if the discussion is being undertaken by the shareholder as part of

a broad effort to promote its view of good corporate governance practices for all of its

portfolio companies, rather than to facilitate a specific change in control in a particular

company.298

On the contrary,

Schedule 13G would be unavailable if a shareholder engages with the issuer’s

management on matters that specifically call for the sale of the issuer to another company,

the sale of a significant amount of the issuer’s assets, the restructuring of the issuer, or a

contested election of directors.299

As is apparent from the above, engaging with a company could entail entering a grey area

as regards the judgment over whether the investors concerned are pursuing the goal of changing

or influencing corporate control. That is especially the case when “putting forward or

supporting proposals to sell or restructure the portfolio company, proposing governance

changes that make it easier to replace the managers of the portfolio company, or engaging with

the portfolio company to propose or facilitate the appointment of particular individuals as

directors.”300

Against this backdrop, it is quite clear that cost considerations associated with the prospect

of a possible switch from a 13G to a 13D filing can discourage collective engagements. As has

been summarized in relation to the major index fund managers,

297 Id. 298 Id. 299 Id. 300 See Bebchuk & Hirst, supra note 70, at 26.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 61: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

61

Schedule 13D filings must be made much more frequently than Schedule 13G filings and

are much more extensive. Schedule 13D must be filed within ten days after every

acquisition and subsequent change in holdings, compared to once-per-year for Schedule

13G. Schedule 13D filings also require particularized disclosure of each acquisition,

entity-by-entity, compared to disclosure of aggregated positions for Schedule 13G.

Schedules 13D and 13G apply not just to the index funds managed by the index fund

manager but to all the investments they manage, including active funds, and separate

client accounts. This increases the differential in compliance costs exponentially: given

the frequency of trades in all of these portfolios, making the extensive disclosure for every

single change in position that Schedule 13D requires would be incredibly costly and time

consuming.301

13D filings not only restrict an investors’ ability to trade following the initial filing; they

also “may cause the target firm to become hostile to the blockholder and restrict access to

management and thus a source of information”; they are “typically accompanied by credit

downgrades…, higher bank loan spreads, and shorter bank loan maturities”; finally, a 13D filing

“signals that the blockholder believes that the target is underperforming and intervention is

warranted. Thus, if she subsequently fails to intervene and firm performance does not improve,

she loses reputation among her own end investors”.302 Those additional effects of 13D

disclosures are in sharp contrast with any engagement-only intention that an investor might

have. Still, U.S. disclosure rules “are believed to chill concerted action by institutional

investors, making them wary to cooperate with their peers and engage with portfolio

companies.”303

In addition, a chilling effect on institutions’ willingness to coordinate for engagement

purposes may be further enhanced by the way in which U.S. courts have handled group

disclosures, given that “[c]onventional wisdom holds that courts are more willing than the

statutory language suggests to find that shareholders are acting as a “group.””304

301 Id. at 26-27 (pointing at the costs of a switch to 13G filings as an incentive towards “deferential stewardship”

for index fund managers). See also Tuch, supra note 220, at 1497. 302 Alex Edmans, Vivian W. Fang & Emanuel Zur, The Effect of Liquidity on Governance, 26 REV. FIN. STUD.

1443, 1449 ( 2013). 303 Tuch, supra note 220, at 1498. 304 Id. at 1497. See also Colleen D. Ball, Regulations 14A and 13D: Impediments to Pension Fund Participation

in Corporate Governance, 1991 WIS. L. REV. 175, 176 (1991).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 62: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

62

If non-activist collective engagements are to be seriously supported, legal concerns raised

by the current legislation regarding Schedule 13G eligibility should be removed by clarifying

under which conditions, as a general rule, collaboration between like-minded investors exerting

stewardship functions will not be associated with an influence or control-seeking purpose, and

will not trigger the obligation to switch to 13D reporting.305

In designing a safer regime for collective engagement initiatives promoted by non-activist

investors that do not seek to gain influence over the corporation’s control, some insights can be

drawn from the European regulatory framework, where institutions that engage collectively

could be regarded as parties “acting in concert”, thereby the mandatory bid rule where their

aggregate stakes exceed the relevant threshold.306

Following calls concerning the importance of ensuring “that there are no regulatory

impediments, real or imagined, to the development of effective dialogue” and the need to

provide for a safe harbour for collective engagements,307 the European Securities and Markets

Authority (ESMA) has identified a “White List” of activities shareholders may wish to engage

in with a view to exercising good corporate governance, but without seeking to acquire or

exercise control over the company.308 Specifically, although “national competent authorities,

when determining whether cooperating shareholders are acting in concert, decide each case on

the basis of its own particular facts”,309 the ESMA states that “[w]hen shareholders cooperate

to engage in any activity included on the White List . . . that cooperation, in and of itself, will

not lead to a conclusion that the shareholders are acting in concert.”310

305 For a similar¾but only sketched¾proposal see Hannes, supra note 22, at 200, 203 (arguing that “the SEC

should clarify that the indirect cooperation between those who sign the agreement with the task force does not amount to holding their securities together and that the member institutional investors would still be considered passive investors”).

306 See BARKER & CHIU, supra note 188, at 174; Davies, supra note 231, at 13-14. 307 WALKER REVIEW, supra note 187, at 85-86. See also FIN. CONDUCT AUTH. & FIN. REPORTING COUNCIL,

BUILDING A REGULATORY FRAMEWORK FOR EFFECTIVE STEWARDSHIP 14 Discussion Paper DP19/1 (Jan. 2019), https://www.fca.org.uk/publication/discussion/dp19-01.pdf (claiming that firms “need to be able to demonstrate to their internal compliance functions that they are not ‘acting in concert’ when engaging on a collective basis with a subset of the company’s investors”).

308 EUR. SEC. & MARKETS AUTH., INFORMATION ON SHAREHOLDER COOPERATION AND ACTING IN CONCERT UNDER THE TAKEOVER BIDS DIRECTIVE. 1ST UPDATE 4 (2014), https://www.esma.europa.eu/sites/default/files/library/2015/11/2014-677.pdf

309 EUR. SEC. & MARKETS AUTH., INFORMATION ON SHAREHOLDER COOPERATION AND ACTING IN CONCERT UNDER THE TAKEOVER BIDS DIRECTIVE 4 (2019), https://www.esma.europa.eu/document/information-shareholder-cooperation-and-acting-in-concert-under-takeover-bids-directive-0.

310 Id. See also Davies, supra note 231, at 14 (stressing that “[s]imply proposing or supporting change of executive directors (or of managerial policy) does not necessarily amount to board control, in the absence of evidence of a wish to exert continuing control of the board.”).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 63: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

63

The White List’s activities include, among others, “making representations to the

company’s board about company policies, practices or particular actions that the company

might consider taking”, “agreeing to vote the same way on a particular resolution put to a

general meeting”, such as proposals relating to directors’ remuneration or ESG issues.311

Moreover, even though it is not included in the White List, the ESMA also provides guidance

on shareholder cooperation in relation to the appointment of board members. According to the

ESMA, when determining whether or not shareholder cooperation in relation to board

appointments will lead to the shareholders being regarded as persons acting in concert, a

number of factors must be considered, including “the number of proposed board members being

voted for pursuant to a shareholders’ voting agreement”; “whether the shareholders have

cooperated in relation to the appointment of board members on more than one occasion”;

“whether the appointment of the proposed board member(s) will lead to a shift in the balance

of power on the board.”312

In line with the ESMA’s statement, the Italian experience with minority-appointed directors

clearly suggests that, under an explicit model for formal coordination led by third-party

organizations and involving the adoption of adequate procedures and safeguards, investors

seeking to appoint some non-executive independent directors on the board as a lever by which

to improve corporate governance should not be considered to be control-seeking. As mentioned

above, when managing the submission of short slates for the appointments of independent

directors, Assogestioni relies on formalized procedures which enhance the active management

role that is to be played by the association’s internal committees throughout the process while

keeping member institutional investors in a fundamentally reception-only position313. Thus, the

Italian case is of particular interest since it shows that¾despite the rules on acting in concert

set at the EU-level, which are particularly attentive to board elections involving a possible

aggregation of the stakes of those acting in concert, which may trigger a mandatory

bid¾collective engagements nonetheless may very well disassociate itself from any control-

seeking intent and instead remain within the limits of active monitoring and stewardship.

Hence, several lessons can be learned from the European experience. First, it confirms that

there is no clear-cut solution for avoiding 13D-related concerns for institutional investors.314

311 Id. at 5-6. 312 Id. at 7. 313 See supra Part IV.B.3. 314 Namely, a clear-cut solution based on the distinction between activist and non-activist institutional investors

aimed at excluding the latter from the scope of 13D disclosures is not advisable, since there appears to be a not

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 64: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

64

Second, based on the ESMA’s approach, the SEC could adopt a similar view to provide a safe

harbor for collective engagement initiatives that do not seek to gain control of the company.315

In particular, the SEC should consider providing a¾white¾list of engagement-related

activities that, in themselves, are considered to fall beyond the scope of section 13D, unless it

is demonstrated on the basis of a case-specific analysis of all relevant circumstances that such

activities have control-seeking purposes.

B. Limiting the Risk of Regulation FD Infringements

As mentioned above,316 one further potential hurdle for investor engagement with portfolio

companies is associated with Regulation FD, which concerns the selective disclosure of

material non-public information to certain specified persons.317 Specifically, any dialogues

between an issuer and selected investors occurring within the engagement process could

possibly (either inadvertently or not) result in the selective communication of price-sensitive

information, such as advance warnings of earnings results, before such information is disclosed

to the public. Since shareholders are explicitly included within its scope, Regulation FD has an

impact on board-shareholder engagement.318 In particular, due to the obligation to not trade on

material non-public information, institutional investors deploying active investment strategies

might be disincentivized to engage directly with portfolio companies.

However, concerns related to Regulation FD within the context of engagement should be

largely scaled down. 319 First, investors are unlikely to discuss topics that are more likely to be

negligible tendency of some non-activist institutional investors to adopt activist tactics that are more likely to have an influence over the control of investee companies. See e.g. Justin Baer & Dawn Lim, Mutual Fund Managers Try a New Role: Activist Investor, WALL ST. J. (Dec. 30, 2018), https://www.wsj.com/articles/mutualfundmanagerstryanewroleactivistinvestor11546174800; LAZARD, REVIEW OF SHAREHOLDER ACTIVISM –1Q 2019 1, 12-13 (2019), https://www.lazard.com/perspective/lazards-quarterly-review-of-shareholder-activism-q1-2019/ (reporting e.g. that “Wellington Management switched its 13G filing to a 13D and publicly opposed Bristol-Myers Squibb’s $74bn acquisition of Celgene”).

315 See, for a similar view, Bebchuk & Hirst, supra note 70, at 57 (suggesting that U.S. “[p]olicy makers should facilitate such pooling by making it clear that the shared use of such resources would not create a group for the purposes of Section 13(d)”).

316 See supra Part. IV.C.2. 317 Regulation FD, 17 C.F.R. § 243.100 (2017). 318 See Joseph W. Yockey, On the Role and Regulation of Private Negotiations in Governance, 61 S.C. L.

REV. 171, 206 (2009). 319 See, e.g., Lisa M. Fairfax, Mandating Board-Shareholder Engagement?, 2013 U. ILL. L. REV. 821, 834-

836 (2013); Edward B. Rock, Shareholder Eugenics in the Public Corporation, 97 CORNELL L. REV. 849, 871, 898 (2012); Eugene Soltes, What Can Managers Privately Disclose to Investors, 36 YALE J. REG. BULLETTIN 148, 149 (2018-2019). See also BUSINESS ROUNDTABLE, PRINCIPLES OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 25 (2016), http://businessroundtable.org/corporate-governance.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 65: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

65

classified as material. In fact, investors are mostly concerned with issues—such as “succession

planning, executive compensation, director nominating criteria, governance philosophies, and

general board oversight (including of accounting, internal controls, risk, auditing and other

related matters)”320—that do not usually fall within the scope of Reg FD.321 Second, advance

arrangements are usually made to ensure that investors do not receive any material non-public

information through contact with directors, so as to avoid trading prohibitions under insider

trading law.322

That said, it is worth noting that regulatory risks associated with board-shareholder dialogue

are minimized to a greater extent within a context of collective engagement. Arguably, if

various investors are involved jointly in the dialogue, cross-control among investors could help

to reduce the likelihood of infringing Regulation FD, since the disclosure of material nonpublic

information during contacts with the company would limit the ability of all participating

investors to trade in the company’s securities. Moreover, as the above-mentioned example of

the UK Investor Forum clearly shows, 323 this is especially the case where a third-party entity

takes on the coordination of collective engagements and adopts formalized procedures capable

of substantially preventing investors from receiving of material non-public information.

C. Recognizing the Facilitator Role of a Coordinating Entity

320 See THE SHAREHOLDER-DIRECTOR EXCHANGE, INTRODUCTION AND SDX PROTOCOL 13 (2014),

http://www.sdxprotocol.com/what-is-the-sdx-protocol/. 321 See Fairfax, supra note 319, 836 (citing STEPHEN DAVIS & STEPHEN ALOGNA, MILLSTEIN CENTER FOR

CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND PERFORMANCE, TALKING GOVERNANCE: BOARD-SHAREHOLDER COMMUNICATIONS ON EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION 10 (2008)). According to the SEC, material information mostly concerns topics such as earnings information; mergers, acquisitions, tender offers, joint ventures, or changes in assets; new products or discoveries, or developments regarding customers or suppliers; changes in control or in management; change in auditors or auditor notification that the issuer may no longer rely on an auditor’s audit report; events regarding the issuer’s securities; and bankruptcies or receiverships. See SEC, WRITTEN STATEMENT CONCERNING REGULATION FAIR DISCLOSURE (May 17, 2001), www.sec.gov/news/testimony/051701wssec.htm#P7817603.

322 See F. William McNabb III, Getting to Know You: The Case for Significant Shareholder Engagement, HARV. L. SCH. F. ON CORP. GOVERNANCE & FIN. REG. (June 24, 2015), https://corpgov.law.harvard.edu/2015/06/24/getting-to-know-you-the-case-for-significant-shareholder-engagement/ (“[L]arge shareholders are not looking for inside information on strategy or future expectations. What they’re looking for is the chance to provide the perspective of a long-term investor. Companies individually have to decide how to best manage that risk, but it shouldn’t be by shutting out the shareholders completely.”). With reference to the European context, see UK STEWARDSHIP CODE 2012, supra note 53, at 7.

323 See supra, Part IV.C.2.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 66: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

66

Coordinated engagements by traditional asset managers may occur in different ways. As

has been shown above, the relevant factor common to any such form of intervention is the

enabling role played by a representative third-party entity.324

Support provided by such entities can be categorized based on whether the action carried

out by the organization is light-touch or more significantly institutionalized. While some such

organizations provide for loose forms of support to members, but do not themselves take on a

truly active stance (as is the case, for instance, with those that merely run of platforms enabling

the investors to exchange views concerning specific portfolio companies), other entities operate

as real drivers of engagement. These organizations proactively stimulate collective action by

performing a propositional and monitoring function concerning the initiation, management and

overview of specified engagement initiatives within a formalized procedural framework. In

some cases, they also perform a scouting function to select director nominees regarding whom

members could potentially arrive at a consensus. Of course, other arrangements fall between

the two extremes.

To a greater or lesser extent, all forms of support provided by third-party entities facilitate

and promote collective engagement as they reduce institutional investors’ costs and enhance

their aggregate voice, ultimately fostering management accountability. In general terms, the

enabling effect of such entities results from their very operation, which may consist in

“triggering the initiative for collective action; … (providing for) mobilizing structures that allow potentially

interested investors to network and to identify partners in engaging the collective action; … (reducing)

incentives to free-riding in engaging the reputation of investors …; and providing a monitoring context and

an administrative structure that bear a significant a significant amount of the coordination cost ….”325

However, it seems to be apparent that this enabling effect is likely to depend on the extent

to which the deployment of collective initiatives follows specific procedural patterns outlined

and monitored by the organization and is proactively supported by it. For collective action by

traditional asset managers and asset owners to be effectively subsidized, organizations should

therefore both adopt a more active role in supporting the engagement process and also take the

procedural steps required to create an organizational structure and context that is capable of

effectively fostering and supporting the engagement initiatives within a formalized framework.

324 See supra Part IV.B. 325 Jean-Pascal Gond & Valeria Piani, Organizing the collective action of institutional investors: Three case

studies from the principles for responsible investment initiative 53 in INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORS’ POWER TO CHANGE CORPORATE BEHAVIOR: INTERNATIONAL PERSPECTIVES (2014), https://doi.org/10.1108/S2043-9059(2013)0000005010.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 67: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

67

The adoption of formalized safeguards and procedures not only enhances the enabling effect

of third-party organizations with regard to collective engagements. Even more crucially, an

enhanced degree of formalization within the engagement process allows third-party entities to

perform a truly facilitating function: the procedures adopted can, in fact, effectively counteract

the regulatory disincentives against collective action described above. Organizations that

actively perform a coordination function based on specified procedures and safeguards can

provide a safer environment that reduces the risk that any investors wishing to participate in a

collective engagement initiative may be viewed as seeking to influence the company’s

management, thus becoming subject to heightened regulatory requirements, including the filing

of a long-form Schedule 13G instead of a short-form Schedule 13G.

Constraints on shareholder collaboration imposed by 13D disclosures are considered to

account as an explanation for the comparatively limited role played by trade groups, such as

investor associations, in fostering collective engagements in the United States.326 However, a

complementary explanation for this limited role of trade groups may be found in the fact that

the existing U.S. organizations do not yet appear to have embraced the proactive, organized

approach adopted by certain entities such as the UK Investor Forum in Europe. The more third-

party organizations act as a filter between the investors and the company with which they

engage, the more they require members participating in an engagement initiative to comply

with requirements and procedures set out in advance, and the more they perform a monitoring

function over the process and the conduct of participating members, the greater the degree of

assurance they will provide. As a result, investors wishing to take part in a collective initiative

may reasonably do so without breaching the relevant provisions and being exposed to the

related consequences. Indeed, as mentioned above, the drafting of a framework for collective

engagements by the UK Investor Forum specifically took account of the need to prevent

“inadvertent violation of legal or regulatory requirements” imposed by multiple jurisdictions

involved in cross-border investment decisions.327

If third-party coordinating entities are believed to actually promote the more effective

involvement of institutions with portfolio companies, investors should be encouraged to

participate in such entities. To this end, the SEC should explicitly recognize the role of those

coordinating entities in promoting collective engagement initiatives in line with the applicable

regulatory framework.

326 Tuch, supra note 220, at 1480. 327 See supra Part. IV.B.2.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 68: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

68

Therefore, in designing safe harbors for collective engagements that do not seek to influence

or control investee companies,328 the SEC should accept that¾unless a control-seeking purpose

can be inferred from the relevant circumstances of the case ¾collective engagement will not

be relevant under Section 13D where the institutional investors participating in the initiative

have explicitly committed not to form a control-seeking group and have appointed a third party

to monitor compliance with the agreement according to predefined frameworks governing the

process of engagement and establishing rules of conduct for participating investors.

In addition, to enhance the regulatory relevance of coordinating entities by limiting conflicts

of interests and distorting incentives, the SEC or, perhaps, stewardship principles could

recommend that, where the engagement process is managed and overseen by the facilitating

entity and not by the investors themselves (as is advisable in order to minimize the risk of

forming a group), independence requirements could apply to the coordinating entity’s

executives who actually lead the initiative. This would be particularly advisable if some

executives of the coordinating entity are former representatives of the institutions participating

in the engagement or potential target companies. For example, it could be stipulated that a

member of the coordinating entity’s team should avoid participating in engagement initiatives

involving any investors with whom she/he has had business relations during the previous 12

months. Such additional requirements would reasonably promote independent monitoring

throughout the collective engagement process.

VI. CONCLUSIONS

Looking beyond hedge-fund wolf packs and activist-driven teaming up, this Article sets out

the first comprehensive analytical framework for non-activist shareholder cooperation, showing

that coordinated engagement by non-activist institutions can be a promising lever by which to

foster a more effective and viable corporate governance role for non-activist institutional

investors and provide an alternative to activist-driven ownership involvement.

After considering the diverging incentives structures of activist and non-activist investors

and showing how they are reshaped within a context in which investors collaborate in the

engagement process, this Article illustrates that non-activist driven collective engagements are

beneficial in several respects. First, collective engagement favors the redistribution of

engagement costs and, therefore, increases the net return earned by each institutional investor

328 See supra Part V.A.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989

Page 69: Institutional Investor Collective Engagements: Non

69

involved. In doing so, it also lowers the free-rider problem generally affecting institutional

shareholders’ behavior. Second, the presence of a third-party entity that coordinates the

engagement initiatives can work as an effective tool for reducing potential regulatory risks,

mainly concerning 13D group disclosures and Regulation FD. Third, collective engagements

can exploit the expertise of more skilled investors who participate in the initiative or of the

third-party coordinating entity. Finally, collective engagement initiatives can enhance

reputational incentives for being active owners, as institutional investors may be incentivized

to join collective initiatives where these prove to be successful or are viewed positively by end

clients.

Against this background, this Article concludes that, to promote non-activist stewardship as

an actual alternative to activist-driven share ownership, collective engagement initiatives

should he incentivized by clarifying the remaining grey areas within the relevant regulatory

framework. In particular, there is the need for the SEC to provide greater clarity concerning the

circumstances in which collective engagement through an enabling organization will not, as a

rule, be regarded as control-seeking or concerted action and will not trigger group filing

obligations under Section 13D of the Securities and Exchange Act. In addition, the SEC should

explicitly recognize the role of such coordinating entities¾ that adopt predefined frameworks

governing the process of engagement and establish rules of conduct for participating

investors¾in promoting collective engagement initiatives in line with the applicable regulatory

framework. Thus, the CII or similar institutions could play a more significant role in promoting

effective institutional investors stewardship, following the patterns of counterparty institutions

in other countries.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3449989