ibf$–$lecture2$ $ tt2012$ institutions...

35
IBF – Lecture 2 TT2012 Institutions, property rights and agriculture Britain seems to have had much higher agricultural productivity than France, which directly affected living standards and also contributed to industrialisation. A traditional story about why this was true has to do with property rights and the organisation of farming. Progress in France, in this story, was held back by the dominant position of peasant households in cultivating the land, and by archaic, confusing, feudal property rights. The evidence on this is mixed. 1. A useful theoretical framework New Institutional Economics 2. Agriculture industry links 3. Data on agricultural productivity 4. Sources of agricultural productivity improvement 5. Premodern property rights and their problems – scattered strips, open fields, commons 6. Property rights in B & F 7. Did enclosures matter? 8. What else mattered?

Upload: others

Post on 17-Jun-2020

12 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

 Institutions,  property  rights  and  agriculture      Britain  seems  to  have  had  much  higher  agricultural  productivity  than  France,  which  directly  affected  living  standards  and  also  contributed  to  industrialisation.  A  traditional  story  about  why  this  was  true  has  to  do  with  property  rights  and  the  organisation  of  farming.  Progress  in  France,  in  this  story,  was  held  back  by  the  dominant  position  of  peasant  households  in  cultivating  the  land,  and  by  archaic,  confusing,  feudal  property  rights.  The  evidence  on  this  is  mixed.        1.  A  useful  theoretical  framework  -­‐  New  Institutional  Economics    2.  Agriculture  -­‐  industry  links    3.  Data  on  agricultural  productivity      4.  Sources  of  agricultural  productivity  improvement    5.  Pre-­‐modern  property  rights  and  their  problems  –  scattered  strips,  open  fields,  commons    6.  Property  rights  in  B  &  F    7.  Did  enclosures  matter?    8.  What  else  mattered?      

Page 2: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

1.  New  Institutional  Economics      NIE  offers  a  useful  tool  for  thinking  about  many  historical  situations.      We  will  not  be  using  NIE  in  a  very  formal  way,  but  some  discussion  of  definitional  issues  is  useful.      What  are  institutions?      

Many  definitions,  but  all  have  to  do  with  man-­‐made  constraints  that  constrain  or  guide  our  behaviour.      • Rules  of  the  game  (formal  legal  or  informal  norms)  of  a  society  • Formal  or  informal  organisations  like  parliaments,  universities,  firms,  

families  • Beliefs  about  others’  behaviour  or  about  the  world  • Internalised  norms  of  behaviour  • Repeated  regular  behaviour  or  practice,  including  in  organizations  like  

firms    A  recent  definition  by  Greif  (Institutions  and  the  Path  to  the  Modern  Economy,  Ch.  2)  is  very  inclusive:  

 A  system  of  rules,  beliefs,  norms  and  organisations  that  together  generate  a  regularity  of  (social)  behaviour.      They  affect  the  behaviour  of  individuals  but  are  beyond  the  influence  of  the  individual.      Yes,  cultural  or  religious  beliefs  can  be  part  of  an  institution  on  this  definition.  They  affect  what  a  person  believes  about  what  others  will  do,  hence  affecting  her  own  behaviour.  (The  more  so,  if  she  has  internalised  these  norms.)      Greif  takes  a  broad  view.  Legal  rules  don’t  count  for  anything  unless  (people  believe  that)  they  will  be  respected  and  enforced.  And  that  depends  on  understanding  the  behaviour  of  court  officials,  for  example.    

 Organisations    

What  we  might  usually  call  an  institution,  e.g.  a  parliament  or  a  corporation  or  a  university  or  a  church  or  perhaps  a  bank,  is  an  organisation  in  this  terminology.    

 In  Greif’s  scheme,  an  organisation  can  be  part  of  an  institution.      For  example,  a  credit  rating  agency  generates  information  that  affects  our  beliefs  about  whether  a  potential  borrower  will  repay  a  loan  because  it  

Page 3: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

will  affect  their  credit  rating  and  their  future  ability  to  borrow  even  if  we  never  see  them  again.  It  is  thus  part  of  an  institution  that  supports  the  behavioural  regularity  of  borrowers  getting  loans  in  relatively  impersonal  credit  markets  and  paying  them  back.      But  it  is  also  an  institution  itself  because  it  has  a  set  of  norms  and  rules  that  guide  the  behaviour  of  the  people  that  work  in  it,  which  motivate  (or  fail  to  motivate)  them  to  do  their  job  conscientiously,  not  take  bribes,  to  not  maximise  short  term  profits  at  the  expense  of  long  term  reputation,  etc.    

 Discuss  table  from  Greif  below    North’s  scheme    

Has  institutions  as  the  “rules  of  the  game”,  both  formal  legal  rules  and  informal  norms  of  behaviour,  along  with  enforcement  mechanisms.      Organisations  are  the  teams  that  play  the  game.    And  particular  arrangements  like  a  type  of  contracts  are  tactics  used  in  playing  the  game.  

 In  practice  I  will  use  the  term  institution  imprecisely    

Examples:  the  common  law,  sharecropping,  parliament,  generalised  trust,  the  corporation,  serfdom,  …  

 Different  thinkers  make  different  assumptions  about  institutions    

One  contrast  is  what  Greif  calls  agency  vs.  structural  perspectives.      Agency:  people  design  an  institution  to  achieve  a  purpose,  consciously.      Structure:  the  institution  determines  the  people’s  goals  and  beliefs  and  purposes.  (The  older  institutional  economics  tradition  followed  this  line.)    

 A  related  question  is  whether  we  should  adopt  a  functionalist  approach.  That  is,  should  we  assume  that  institutions  exist  in  order  to  achieve  some  particular  end,  and  if  so,  what?      Economists,  perhaps,  tend  toward  functionalism  and  agency.      Possible  functions:    

Promote  efficiency.  If  you  see  a  historical  institution,  it  probably  exists  to  solve  a  problem  in  an  efficient  way.  Scattered  strips  and  

Page 4: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

open  fields  in  medieval  villages.  A  guild  as  a  way  of  solving  collective  action  problems  involving  quality  maintenance  or  training.      Distribute  resources:  historical  institutions  were  probably  set  up  by  one  group  of  people  to  extract  rents  from  others  –  serfdom.  A  guild  as  a  barrier  to  entry.    

 Reduce  uncertainty    Restrain  self-­‐interested  behaviour    Etc.    

More  differences  concern  assumptions  about  degree  of  human  knowledge,  rationality,  and  self-­‐interest.      

There  is  some  notion  of  equilibrium  in  Greif’s  definition    

People  have  beliefs  and  those  turn  out  to  be  justified.      There  could  be  multiple  equilibria,  though.    

 Institutions,  by  definition,  affect  behaviour  and  thus  economic  outcomes.  NIE  economists  think  they  are  the  fundamental  determinants  of  economic  performance.      And  they  may  be  resistant  to  change,  in  which  case  history  is  particularly  important.      

Perhaps  because  interlocking  –  each  institution  makes  sense  in  terms  of  others,  or  alternatively  each  element  of  institutional  system  (in  Greif’s  schema)  fits  together  in  an  internal  equilibrium    Perhaps  because  partly  about  culture/beliefs/norms  that  might  be  slow  to  change    Perhaps  b/c  institutions  serve  interests  of  those  in  power    More  on  institutional  change  later  in  term,  perhaps    

 Some  argue  that  institutions  are  relatively  flexible,  and  reflect  the  needs  of  an  economy  at  the  time.  They  determine  only  the  form  of  things            

Page 5: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

 At  issue  today:  were  peasant  agriculture  and  archaic  property  rights  a  big  impediment  to  industrialisation,  start  of  modern  economic  growth?      

Traditional  view:      large  scale  capitalist  agriculture  highly  progressive,  generates  surplus,  frees  labour  for  other  sectors;  peasant  agriculture  backward,  not  market  oriented,  communal,  extraordinarily  risk  averse,  insists  on  bizarre  inefficiencies  like  open  fields  or  sharecropping,  holds  back  development.      This  view  common  across  the  spectrum  of  ideological  approaches  from  Marxists  to  ardent  liberals.      Perceptions  of  England  and  France  played  a  role  in  generating  this  consensus.      The  peasant  household  we  can  analyse  as  an  institution.      Property  rights  to  the  land  are  another  typical  object  of  institutional  analysis.      Consensus  no  longer  so  clear.    

         

Page 6: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

 

Page 7: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

2.  Contribution  of  the  agricultural  sector  to  industrialisation      Maths  

 With  agriculture  a  big  sector  of  the  economy,  it  is  hard  for  output  per  worker  or  GDP  per  capita  to  be  high  if  it  is  low  in  agriculture.  Fast  growing  industrial  sector  cannot  drag  rest  of  economy  along  at  same  pace.  

 Feed  the  workers  

 In  a  closed  economy,  agricultural  sector  must  feed  industry  and  service  workers.  Needs  to  be  able  to  do  this  without  requiring  a  huge  share  of  labour  force  (and  capital,  other  factors  of  production).  Each  farmer  must  be  able  to  feed  himself  and  a  couple  of  other  workers.  

 Supply  raw  materials  

 Like  flax,  wool,  silk,  vegetable  oils,  leather,  tallow…  (Perhaps  also  oats  etc.  to  feed  horses  employed  in  transport.  For  that  matter,  the  beasts  themselves.)  Fuel  in  the  form  of  wood.    

 Market  for  manufactures  

 Households  in  the  agricultural  sector  can  be  an  important  market  for  the  output  of  the  industrial  and  service  sectors.  In  a  closed  economy  this  is  likely  to  be  important.    

 Release  resources  

 Productivity  growth  in  agriculture  can  release  labour  (or  not  retain  excess  growth  of  labour  force)  for  other  sectors.  It  could  also  provide  capital,  if  profits  in  agriculture  invested  in  other  sectors.      

   These  are  all  different  ways  of  seeing  the  same  problem.  The  food  sold  by  the  agricultural  sector  generates  the  income  with  which  to  purchase  manufactures,  for  example.  Still  it’s  useful  to  think  about  the  problem  from  different  angles.      Failure  to  do  these  things  can  put  a  brake  on  growth  of  industry  and/or  services.            

Page 8: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

 Dualism  

 Traditional  agriculture  sometimes  seen  as  unlike  modern  industry  -­‐-­‐  not  based  on  profit  maximisation,  equation  of  MP’s  to  market  rates  of  return.      Capitalist  hires  labour  until  w/p  =  MPL.  And  no  more.      Peasant  HH  may  care  about  survival  of  HH  as  a  family  agricultural  enterprise.      

Stay  in  agriculture  (“hire  labour”)  so  long  as  APL  >  subsistence.    Or  so  long  as  income  loss  relative  to  urban  wage  less  than  some  threshold.    

 Disequilibrium  in  which  MPL  much  higher  in  industry.      As  labour  transferred,  high  profits  and  (if  reinvested)  rapid  growth  in  industry.          Kindleberger  said  this  was  Europe  post  WWII.    

 A  formal  model  would  be  useful  but  time-­‐consuming  to  analyse.    

Page 9: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

3.  Data  on  agricultural  productivity    Britain:  still  a  consensus  that  something  we  might  call  an  agricultural  revolution  happened,  probably  mostly  before  the  period  we  are  considering.      France:  real  debate  about  whether  traditional  view  of  unchanging  backward  economy  hobbled  by  antiquated  institutions  in  18c  is  valid.  Toutain  thought  there  was  an  agricultural  revolution  in  18c.  Morineau  thought  only  “faux-­‐semblants”  of  one.      How  to  measure  productivity:  output  per  worker,  per  acre,  per  unit  of  capital  and  labour  input,  grain  per  seeds?    Arguably  labour  productivity  is  the  key.      

Only  high  labour  productivity  will  permit  a  small  agricultural  sector  to  support  a  large  industrial/service  sector.    Only  high  labour  productivity  will  permit  high  real  wages  and  standards  of  living.      Ultimately  we  are  interested  in  economic  output  per  person.    

 Other  measures  of  productivity  helpful  in  diagnosing  what  is  going  on.      

Is  labour  productivity  high/low  because  lots/little  capital  per  worker?      Because  lots/little  land  per  worker?      B/c  soil  fertility?      B/c  inefficient  crop  rotations  or  cultivation  techniques?      Etc.    

   

Page 10: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

 Labour  productivity    a.  Allen’s  (EREH  2000)  estimates  of  output  per  agricultural  worker    

   

Note:  England  1500  =  1    

Comments    

Belgium  (Flanders)  not  shown  but  had  highest  productivity  in  middle  ages  when  it  was  the  most  urban  and  advanced  part  of  northern  Europe,  then  long  slow  decline.    

 Britain  looks  ordinary  until  1600,  when  it  takes  off.  There  was  something  of  an  agricultural  revolution  in  Britain,  but  it  preceded  the  IR.  Productivity  growth  slows  in  late  18c.  

 France  looks  like  rest  of  Europe.      

Fairly  stagnant  over  long  run.  A  little  better  than  Italy  or  Spain  post-­‐1600.      Well  behind  NW  Europe  in  18c  and  falling  further  back.      Other  countries  like  Austria-­‐Hungary,  Germany  look  a  lot  like  F,  I.    

 

.5

.5

.5.75

.75

.751

1

11.25

1.25

1.251.5

1.5

1.51500

1500

15001600

1600

16001700

1700

17001800

1800

1800year

year

yearEngland

England

EnglandFrance

France

FranceNetherlands

Netherlands

NetherlandsItaly

Italy

Italy

Page 11: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

Technical  issues    

Estimating  agricultural  LF  very  difficult.    

Rural  population  known,  but  multiple  activities  in  HH  the  norm.  Domestic  production  of  industrial  goods  such  as  handloom  weaving,  for  example.  Role  of  women  and  children.  

 Allen’s  estimates  of  agricultural  population  described  in  previous  lecture:  total  minus  urban  minus  guess  of  rural-­‐nonagricultural  employment.    

 Estimating  output  not  always  easy  either.    

 France  has  agricultural  censuses  (at  least  in  19c)      Britain  and  other  countries  no.      Not  much  data  for  output  estimates.  Deane  &  Cole  used  incomes.      Other  possibilities  based  on  population,  or  based  on  idea  of  a  stable  demand  function  dependent  on  population,  income  p.c.,  and  price  of  food.  Can  infer  fluctuations  in  supply  if  account  for  import/export.      Typical  assumptions:  income  elasticity  .5,  own  price  elasticity  -­‐.6,  cross  price  elasticity  with  manufactures  0.1.  (Allen  09)    Assume  a  functional  form  for  demand  curve  for  food,  use  shift  variables  (population,  wages,  prices  of  other  goods)  to  locate  position  of  curve,  then  read  off  quantity  that  corresponds  to  historical  price  on  that  curve.  Deduct  imports  (or  add  exports)  and  you  have  output.    

   

Page 12: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

b.  Clark’s  estimates  of  labour  and  land  productivity  (1991,  reproduced  in  Simpson  chapter  of  PKO  festschrift).  I  think  based  on  physical  output  estimates.         1851           labour     land        

Britain   100   100  Netherlands   54   94  Ireland   47   78  France   44   82  Germany     42   56  Belgium   37   122  Sweden     37   45  Austria   32   54  Hungary   30   36  Romania   40   51  Russia   29   24  

   Britain  appears  to  retain  a  huge  lead  in  labour  productivity.    

What  do  we  know  about  1800-­‐50  growth  of  Y/L  in  Britain?      Land  productivity  differences  much  smaller.      

Other  countries  may  be  applying  much  more  labour  per  unit  of  land.      That  would  make  sense  if  wages  lower,  rents  higher.    

 France  looks  relatively  average  in  European  perspective.      

Not  much  evidence  of  catch-­‐up  on  Britain.            

Page 13: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

c.  extra.  O’Brien  (EHR  1996)  shares  view  of  early  divergence  b/w  B  &  F,  from  circa  1520.  He  viewed  these  estimates  as  conjectural.  Note  log  scale  means  that  as  curves  drift  apart  the  percentage  difference  increases.  Roughly  2:1  ratio  by  1800,  after  which  more  or  less  parallel  growth.  

 Conjectural  estimates  of  labour  productivity  (O’Brien  1996)  

 

   Estimates  based  on  a  variety  of  sources  and  methods:  Overton,  O’Grada,  Wrigley,  LeRoy-­‐Ladurie…  

   

Grantham  (EREH  97)  reports  new  LF  estimates  for  France  that  make  productivity  growth  appear  much  stronger  throughout  19c.  Comparable  to  Britain.    

 I  think  these  estimates,  which  better  capture  women  and  children  (who  were  leaving  the  ag  LF  over  time),  would  lower  the  initial  level  of  productivity,  and  raise  its  subsequent  growth  rate.        

 Summary:    

British  agricultural  revolution  and  French-­‐British  divergence  early.      France  was  well  behind  and  falling  back  through  18c.  Unclear  if  labour  productivity  stagnant  (Allen)  or  growing  slowly  (O’Brien)  in  France.      In  19c  French  productivity  may  have  been  growing,  keeping  up  with  Britain  though  failing  to  close  gap.    

 

2 l6 PATRICK KARL O ' B R I EN

explanation for Britain's superior record of labour productivity growth(figure i) can be structured into a set of proximate determinants where:output per worker employed in agriculture is related to H/L (hectares ofland cultivated and sown, per worker); and to 0/H (returns, including thecomposition and prices of output as well as physical yields, per hectare).The latter depends in turn upon techniques of production used, K/H (capitalper hectare) and K/L (capital per worker employed) as well as theorganizational efficiency of agriculture.'*

Great Britain

France

Figure i . Conjectural growth rates of labour productivity in British and French

agriculture, IS20-1910Note: The vertical scale is logarithmic.Sources and methods: The source used and methods emulated to construct the output index for Britam, 1520-1700, arccontained in Wrigley, 'Urban growth', pp. 700-1, 720-1. The index for 1700-1850 is from a forthcoming book byMark Overton. Ovenon's output estimates are based on Chartres, 'Marketing of agricultural produce', and Holderness,'Prices, productivity and output'. His input data are derived from Wrigley, 'Urban growth'. The index for 1860-1910is from 6 Grada, 'British agriculture, 1860-1914'. (6 Gr4da's index has been linked to Overton's on the assumptionthat productivity growth 1850-60 was equivalent to the annual average rate for 1860-90). For France, 1520-1700, thesource and methods are from Wrigley, 'Urban growth'; for 1700-1807,1 used Le Roy Ladurie's growth rate for outputbecause French historians have rejected Toutain's estimates for the eighteenth century; see Le Roy Ladurie, 'De lacrise ultime', p. 395. The whole vexed issue of agricultural growth in France is surveyed in Crouzet, Bntam ascendanupp. 47-54. For 1807-1910, the growth rate is calculated from data in Toutain, Le produit de I'agriculture, pp. 128-9,200-1. (See also idem. La production agrkole). Inputs of cultivated land for Britain, I7oo-t85o, are from Allen,'Agriculture during the industrial revolution'; for i85O-t9OO, from O'Brien and Keyder, Economic growth, p . 105. Thecultivated area for France is from Toutain, Le produit de I'agriculture, and O'Brien and Keyder, Economic growth.

Connections between output per worker and returns per hectare can beillustrated with reference to estimates available for 1910, when the area of'unstandardized' hectares of cultivable land per worker employed in primaryproduction in Britain was nearly double that in French agriculture; andwhen returns per hectare cultivated in France were well above British levels.With more human energy at their disposal French farmers obtained highergross and net monetary returns per hectare cultivated.'̂ Since the middle

"' Overton and Campbell, 'Productivity change', provides the best survey of this topic." O'Brien and Prados de la Escosura, 'Agricultural productivity'. Preliminary estimates suggest that

c. 1910 gross returns per hectare cultivated in France may have been 34% above British levels, and netvalue added valued in sterling 82% higher. For the methods involved in these calculations, see O'Brien

Page 14: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

Total  Factor  Productivity    Labour  productivity  can  be  affected  by  various  factors:    

Land-­‐labour  ratio  Capital-­‐labour  ratio  Technological  sophistication  …    It  could  be  perfectly  rational  and  efficient  to  drive  labour  productivity  down  in  order  to  get  high  yields  per  acre,  in  some  circumstances.  Or  alternatively  to  use  lots  of  land  and  have  low  land  productivity,  high  labour  productivity.      An  alternative  measure  of  sophistication  or  level  of  development  of  agriculture  is  total  factor  productivity,  or  TFP.      Can  be  estimated  from  quantities  of  outputs  and  inputs.    

 With  assumption  about  elasticities  /  factor  shares.  

 Or  by  the  “dual  method”,  based  on  prices  of  outputs  and  inputs.    

 With  assumption  about  cost  shares,  perfect  competition,  constant  returns  to  scale  technology.      If  the  prices  of  inputs  rise,  but  output  prices  don’t,  then  farmers  must  be  managing  to  produce  same  output  with  fewer  inputs.      The  difference  between  the  growth  rate  of  output  prices  and  a  weighted  average  of  the  growth  rates  of  costs  equals  TFP  growth.      

The  weights  are  the  shares  of  each  cost  item  in  total  costs.      Advantages:  we  have  more  reason  to  believe  prices  are  representative,  to  the  extent  markets  were  integrated  and  law  of  one  price  holds.  Quantities  need  not  be  same  on  different  farms.    Disadvantages:  one  is  that  market  power  can  drive  a  variable  wedge  between  costs  and  prices.    

   

Page 15: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

TFP:    Hoffman’s  estimates    

Hoffman  (1996,  p.  85)  uses  the  formula    

 

 Here  the  w’s  are  the  costs  of  various  factors  of  production,  such  as  rent  on  an  acre  of  land,  the  cost  of  renting  a  plough  horse  for  an  hour,  the  wage  for  a  labourer  for  an  hour.  And  the  p’s  are  the  prices  of  agricultural  outputs,  like  wheat,  wool,  mutton…    The  ν’s  and  η’s  are  the  share  of  each  factor  of  production  in  total  costs  or  of  each  output  in  total  revenue.    The  second  formulation  pulls  out  rent  so  as  to  highlight  its  role,  adjusts  for  the  fact  that  tax  must  also  be  paid  on  land,  and  subsumes  the  other  costs  and  prices  into  indexes  C  and  P.      s  is  the  share  of  rent  in  total  costs.    

Hoffman  has  a  fairly  large  sample  of  rental  agreements  on  properties  owned  by  the  famous  Cathedral  of  Notre  Dame  in  Paris.  In  many  cases  the  data  are  longitudinal,  meaning  he  observes  the  rent  on  the  same  property  repeatedly  over  a  long  time  span.      He  also  has  data  on  costs  and  prices,  while  he  makes  educated  guesses  about  the  ν’s  and  η’s  from  a  few  scattered  farm  accounts.      

 

!

TFP =w1

"1w2" 2 ...wn

"n

p1#1p2

# 2 ...pm#m = (r + t)s C

P

Page 16: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

Dual  estimates  of  TFP  growth  in  long  run  in  Paris  Basin.    

   

 Hoffman  is  impressed  by  growth.  But  also  by  its  volatility.      Growth  shows  French  agriculture  not  immobile,  contrary  to  stereotypes  about  rural  France  (and  peasant-­‐dominated  agriculture  more  generally).      But  instability  and  war  in  mid/late  16c  (wars  of  religion),  early  17c  (30  Years  War  involvement,  Frondes)  capable  of  driving  it  right  back  down.  The  rapid  growth  of  the  early  16c  is  similarly  the  end  of  a  prolonged  recovery  from  the  100  Years  War,  he  believes.      Some  of  growth  from  late  17c  to  mid  18c  is  overstated  for  technical  reasons.  Caused  by  market  integration  and  a  statistical  mirage.  Still,  cumulative  growth  only  a  few  percent.      But  acceleration  of  late  18c  end  is  real,  he  believes.      The  overall  TFP  growth  rate  over  the  whole  sample  is  0.13%  p.a.      In  the  last  quarter  of  the  18c  it  accelerated  to  0.31%.    

 

790 Hoffman

1.2

In(TFP) set equal to 1 in 1750/74

1.0 .

Before tax adjustment

I 0 A

| 0 AI hv> Alternative shares l

0.7 - Alternative prices

0.6- , , , , , , 1520/24 1550/74 1600/24 1650/74 1700/24 1750/74

1525/49 1575/99 1625/49 1675/99 1725/49 1775/89

FIGURE 3

LN(TFP) FOR ALTERNATIVE PRICES AND SHARES

(ADJUSTED FOR TAXES AND LAND QUALITY)

THE NOTRE DAME PROPERTIES

Productivity trends

What then do the leases reveal? The place to begin is with the evolution of TFP. From equation 2, TFP equals (r + t)sC/P, where r is per hectare rent; t is per hectare taxes; s is the factor share of land; and C and P are the indexes of agricultural costs and prices. We do not know t precisely, but if we ignore taxes for the moment-an oversight soon to be corrected-then the logarithm of TFP will be very nearly equal to sln(r) - In(P/C), which we can average across properties for different periods. We can then chart, at least roughly, the changes in TFP, and we can hone the accuracy of the graph by adjusting In(r) for variations in land quality via the procedure used in Table 1.

Figure 3 plots such an average for 25-year periods. It also charts average values of TFP computed with the alternative factor and product shares and with the alternative prices in the indexes P and C-prices that are averaged over the newly signed lease instead of over the outgoing one. All three curves are corrected for variations in land

Page 17: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

TFP  Grantham  –  19c    

Output  based  (primal)  TFP  growth  estimates.  These  use  the  new  LF  estimates.  And  new  guesses  of  the  capital  stock,  part  of  which  based  on  backward  projection  of  1965  data  on  structures(!).  

 Growth  rates,  %  p.a.   output labour capital TFP 1789-1840 0.77 0.24 0.74 0.45 1815-1870 1.23 0.08 0.72 0.94 1840-1870 0.98 -0.16 0.98 0.81 1870-1890 0.34 -0.17 -0.32 0.54 1890-1914 0.82 -0.59 0.59 0.93 1815-1914 0.95 -0.001 0.05 0.85

   

Sutherland  (JEH  2002)  calculates  TFP  growth  1780-­‐1820  for  samples  around  Le  Mans  and  Rouen.  About  30-­‐40%  increase  in  total.  So  even  faster  than  what  Grantham  calculates  fro  1789-­‐1840.  Somewhat  surprising.  In  any  case  confirms  French  agriculture  not  completely  stagnant.    

   TFP  Britain        

Allen  (cehmb)  is  sceptical  of  existing  estimates.      Primal  estimates  indicate  TFP  growth  rate  of  something  like      

0.3%  p.a.  over  longer  period  from  1700-­‐1850.      But  rising  from  0  –  0.1%  in  18c.  to  0.7%  in  first  half  of  19c.      

 Dual  estimates,  which  he  also  worries  about,  suggest  something  similar.      This  looks  similar  to  France.    

 TFP  growth  appears  to  have  been  positive  but  slow  in  both  B  &  F,  accelerating  in  late  18c  and  early  19c.    

 This  says  nothing  about  levels,  which  could  have  been  higher  in  B.    It  is  not  necessarily  in  conflict  with  our  findings  about  labour  productivity.      

Even  if  levels  of  TFP  were  same,  B  &  F  could  be  at  two  different  points  on  the  efficient  frontier,  with  B  capital-­‐intensive  and  F  labour-­‐intensive,  for  example.      And  TFP  levels  could  be  very  different.    

 

Page 18: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

Yields    

Allen  &  O’Grada  believe  Young’s  yield  data  –  a  measure  of  land  productivity  -­‐  show  that  French  yields  were,  or  at  least  could  be,  as  good  as  British.      On  the  best,  most-­‐English  type  soil  (loam),  Young’s  data  show  French  wheat  yields  of  a  bit  over  20  bushels  per  acre  –  about  same  as  in  Britain.      This  is  consistent  with  interpretation  that  French  agriculture  was  not  still  stuck  in  the  middle  ages,  that  there  had  been  progress,  even  if  F  was  using  much  more  labour  per  acre  to  get  these  yields.      Also  suggests  France  disadvantaged  by  having  a  larger  proportion  of  soils  poorly  suited  to  arable  agriculture.          

   

   

   

102 Allen and 0 Grada

TABLE 2

ESTIMATES OF ENGLISH GRAIN YIELDS, c. 1770 TO c. 1850

(bushels per acre)

Survey Wheat Barley Oats

About 1770 (Young) 23.8 32.1 37.0

Average 1790s 19.1 27.7 27.2

Typical about 1800 21.6 32.0 34.9

1794-1816 (Board of Agnculture) 22.6 32.6 36.1

About 1850 (Caird) 26.7 39.6 46.4

Sources: The "average 1790s" and "typical about 1800" yields are computed from Michael

Turner, "Agricultural Productivity in England in the Eighteenth Century: Evidence from Crop

Yields," Economic History Review, 2nd series, 35 (Nov. 1982), pp. 506-10. The remaining means

are computed from R. C. Allen and Cormac 6 Grdda, "On the Road Again with Arthur Young:

English, Irish and French Agriculture during the Industrial Revolution" (University of British

Columbia, Department of Economics Discussion Paper No. 86-38), appendix tables IA, iB, IC.

the data and a reminder that not too much should be read into

differences of a few bushels. Table 2 is a useful corrective to persistent fears that Young's yields

were too high.26 Discarding the average 1790s return throughout as an

underestimate, we see for wheat that Young's return is 5 percent greater

than the Board of Agriculture average and 10 percent above the 1800

average. For barley, Young's average is lower than the Board of

Agriculture average and almost identical to the 1800 return. For oats,

Young is again a bit higher than the 1800 or Board of Agriculture means,

but the excess is less than for wheat. Given the large standard errors of

all of these numbers, the most reasonable conclusion is that English

grain yields did not change much between the time of Young's tours and the Board of Agriculture reports.

Table 2 also shows that Caird's yields for about 1850 are consistently

higher than the earlier yields for all crops. The implication that yields increased in the first half of the nineteenth century is confirmed by the

Healy-Jones series of wheat yields between 1815 and 1859.27 By its

construction, the Healy-Jones series overstates yields actually reaped,

but it is reliable in establishing the upward trend.

Young's yields also invite comparison with earlier returns. Monastic

accounts record yields for many demesnes in southern England from the

thirteenth to the fifteenth century. These records suggest that wheat and

oats yielded, in round numbers, about 10 bushels per acre, while barley yielded up to 50 percent more.28 Table 2 shows that crop yields had

26For example, Bennett, "British Wheat Yields."

27 Eric L. Jones, Agriculture and the Industrical Revolution (Oxford, 1974), pp. 184-90.

28 Thus, for instance, Titow's, Winchester Yields, pp. 121-35, summary of the yields of 40

manors of the Bishop of Winchester between 1209 and 1349 showed wheat yielding 10.7 bushels per

acre, barley 16.8 bushels, and oats 11.7 bushels. Titow's figures have been divided by 0.9 to

compensate for the tithe. (Titow, Winchester Yields, p. 8.) D. L. Farmer, "Grain Yields on the

Arthur Young on Grain Yields 111

TABLE 4 FRENCH WHEAT YIELDS, 1780s-1850s

(bushels per acre)

Implied by Young's District Young's Own Young's Ours Yield-Seed Ratio Rgcoltes 1815/6 Re6coltes 1850/1

Loam 23.5 22.2 21.6 14.5 21.1

Heath 19.0 17.5 14.4 11.1 15.5

Mountain 18.0 20.2 11.0 10.6 12.6

Stony 18.0 17.3 11.2 8.6 15.9

Chalk 13.5 15.3 7.7 6.8 13.0

Notes and Sources: The districts are Young's. "Young's own" yields are from his summary table in Young, Travels ... [in] France (2nd edn.,

London, 1794), vol. 2, p. 118. We have used the average for "loam, N.E." instead of the average

for all loam districts (25 bushels per acre) since all the other data relating to loam in the table come from the northeast. "Young's Ours" are our averages of Young's data, as computed from the

departmental averages in Allen and 6 Grida, "On the Road Again with Arthur Young: English, Irish and French Agriculture during the French Revolution" (University of British Columbia,

Department of Economics Discussion Paper No. 86-38), appendix table 3. "Implied by Young's

Yield-Seed Ratios" equal his yield ratios-in descending order by district they are 8, 6, 5, 4, 4.5

multiplied by seed rates collected in the agricultural inquiry of the mid-1830s. (Young, Travels ...

in] France, vol. 2, pp. 104-5, 119). These were read off Hugh Clout's map for the departments

where Young recorded yields, in Agriculture in France on the Eve of the Railway Age (London,

1980), p. 112. "Rgcoltes 1815/6" are average yields for 1815 and 1816 from Recoltes des cereales et

des pommes de terre, 1815-1876 for the departments that include the places where Young recorded

yields. "Recoltes 1850/1" are average yields for 1850 and 1851. These averages are calculated from

Allen and 0 Gr~da, "On the Road," appendix table 3.

ratios was a concession to the usual idiom for discussing productivity. Thus, "at Marseilles, the celebrated Abbe Raynal assured me, that he had been informed by many agriculturalists, who well know France, that the whole kingdom does not produce more than 4-1/2 for one of the

seed, on an average. "I To get an overall view of productivity he had to rely on this sort of testimony much more on his third trip. His first two

trips were mainly in northeastern France, where the land was almost

uniformly fertile, so he could reasonably expect that the yields he

sampled were representative of the whole region. His last trip concen- trated on less fertile districts, and he tended to follow the main roads

through river valleys where the land was more productive than in the

districts as a whole. So while he could directly ascertain yields where he

was, he had to rely on the testimony of others for yields in the

hinterlands. And those assessments were given in terms of yield-seed ratios.

In sum, Young gives us two estimates of yields for France-yields per acre and yield-seed ratios. (He retrospectively added yield-seed ratios

for districts where he had not collected them on his first tours.) Table 4

shows the yields per acre of wheat implied by the two methods.

64 Ibid., p. 93.

Page 19: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

Capital/animal  intensity    

Animal  husbandry  was  much  more  important  in  B.      Animals  are  like  capital:  require  sacrifice/investment  to  buy  or  rear,  yield  services  (manure,  traction)  (wool,  milk)  over  long  time,  must  be  maintained  and  eventually  replaced…    Estimates  of  livestock  share  of  agricultural  production  (meat,  dairy,  hides,  wool…)  c.  1850.    E&W   59  Ireland   42  France   32  Spain   26  Portugal   35  Denmark   46  Sweden   47  Norway   51    

Source:  Simpson  chapter  in  PKO  festschrift    (O’Brien  (EHR  96)  cites  late  19c  figures  indicating  75%  of  UK  agr  output  was  animal  products,  vs.  50%  for  F.  )    Animals’  contribution  in  the  form  of  traction  not  reflected  in  this.  

 B  animal  dung  available  as  much  as  two  or  three  times  as  much.      B  draft  power  156  hp  equivalents  per  1000  ha,  vs.  36  in  F.    O’Brien  says  we  cannot  document  it,  but  he  is  convinced  that  this  had  been  the  case  for  a  long,  long  time.  Goes  back  to  lower  population  density  in  Britain  after  Black  Death,  ability  to  devote  more  land  to  fodder.  Plus  climate  slightly  better  for  fodder  crops.      Multiple  self-­‐reinforcing  equilibria.      

Many  livestock  =>  fertiliser  Fertiliser  =>  good  yields  High  yields  =>  less  land  needed  for  grain    Less  grain  land  =>  more  fodder  crops  for  animals    More  animals  =>  more  power  for  ploughing,  other  soil  improvements  =>  good  yields  /  high  productivity  of  labour    High  yields  /  high  productivity  =>  high  incomes  =>  high  consumption  demand  for  meat  and  dairy.    

 

Page 20: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

Summarising  the  productivity  data    

Labour  productivity  is  key.  Britain  seems  to  have  had  an  agricultural  revolution  preceding  the  IR,  with  growth  slowing  down  by  late  18c.      

Levels  very  high  in  European  comparison.    Brit  yields  per  acre  not  extraordinary  in  European  comparison.  Getting  them  with  so  little  labour  is  what  was  impressive.  Animal  husbandry  important  in  this.  

 French  labour  productivity  levels  seem  to  have  been  much  lower  than  British.    

Labour  productivity  growth  rates  may  have  diverged  in  early  modern  period  and  into  18c.  After  that,  hard  to  say  b/c  of  uncertainty  about  LF  estimates.  Possibly  F  kept  up  w/  Britain  in  19c,  without  closing  gap.      

French  yields,  on  good  soil,  perhaps  about  same  as  British  in  late  18c.      

Likely  due  to  higher  input  of  labour,  since  labour  productivity  low.    France  following  path  of  labour  intensification.      Britain  capital/animal  intensification.  

 French  TFP  growth  rates  were  not  zero.  Agriculture  there  did  develop  over  time.      

In  fact,  TFP  growth  (not  necessarily  levels)  apparently  comparable  to  British  rates  of  improvement  both  early  and  late,  if  we  believe  the  numbers.      TFP  levels  may  have  been  considerably  lower  in  France.      Again,  France  behind  but  not  completely  stagnant.    

Page 21: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

4.  Sources  of  productivity  gain    New  crops      

Maize,  potatoes  (New  World  crops)  high  yielding  Fodder  and  nitrogen-­‐fixing  crops,  some  introduced  to  Britain  from  abroad:  sainfoin,  turnips,  swedes,  clover…  Requires  knowledge,  experimentation,  adaptability.    

 Better  crops  (better  breeds)    

Selective  choice  of  seed.  New  breeds  of  livestock  that  matured  faster  or  had  other  good  qualities  developed  through  selective  breeding.  Requires  time,  active  experimentation.  

 Improve  soil  fertility  –  manure,  fertiliser,  nitrogen    

Mineral  or  guano  fertiliser  really  only  after  this  period.    Manure  the  key,  thus  connection  between  animal  husbandry  and  arable.  Nightsoil  maybe,  but  actually  cities  provided  manure  of  horses  and  dairy  cattle.  Nitrogen-­‐fixing  crops  like  legumes,  clover.    

 New  rotations  of  crops,  incl.  convertible  husbandry    

Grain  in  particular  tends  to  exhaust  soil,  depleting  stock  of  key  minerals/nutrients.  =>  you  just  cannot  grow  wheat  on  the  same  soil,  year  after  year.  Rotations  ensure  soil  not  exhausted.    Convertible  husbandry  alternates  arable  with  pasture.    Old,  old  rotation  might  be  alternating  wheat  and  fallow  (either  annual  or  periods  of  several  years).  New  rotation  might  be  something  like  wheat-­‐turnips-­‐barley-­‐clover  or  grass.  Eliminates  fallow.    Required  experimentation,  adaptation  to  local  circumstance.    

 Improve  other  soil  properties      

Drainage  –  requires  significant  investment  of  capital  (ditches,  tiles  to  line  them,  labour  to  dig  them,  etc.)  with  long-­‐run  payoff.  Marling  –  adding  lime  reduces  acidity,  which  I  think  makes  manure  more  effective  as  fertiliser.  Also  can  improve  texture  of  soil.  Deep  ploughing  –  aeration  important  for  heavy,  wet  soils.  Irrigation  –  not  so  relevant  in  Britain,  but  in  many  other  places  vital.  Requires  investment,  hence  funds,  long-­‐run  horizon.      

Page 22: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

More  capital      

Drainage,  water  and  erosion  control  Roads  Buildings    Fences/hedges  Implements  (which  can  be  better  rather  than  just  more)  Livestock  –  which  you  can  think  of  as  capital  b/c  supplies  power  and  fertiliser.  Requires  an  investible  surplus  or  access  to  capital  market,  willingness  to  use  it,  long-­‐run  planning  horizon.  

 Better  organisation      

The  specific  examples  typically  discussed  are  about  scale.      Economies  of  scale  due  to  indivisibilities  of  investments  like  drainage.      

If  you  dig  a  drainage  ditch  next  to  your  strip,  it  will  drain  the  neighbouring  strip  as  well  –  a  positive  externality.  If  your  ditch  empties  into  your  downhill  neighbour’s  land,  you  inundate  it  –  a  negative  externality.    An  efficient  drainage  system  needs  to  take  into  account  an  entire  topographically-­‐defined  area.      To  realise  it  requires  a  big  investment.      Either  coordinate  with  neighbours,  or  internalise  externalities  in  big  farm.    

 Possibility  of  economies  of  scale  due  to  better  organisation  of  labour  through  specialisation  and/or  team  production.    

 Note  how  many  of  these  improvements  require,  or  would  at  least  be  facilitated  by,  complete  individual  control  over  farmland.  Where  ownership  is  joint  or  contested,  or  where  your  rights  to  use  your  land  are  restricted  even  if  ownership  is  clear,  it  can  be  difficult  to  experiment  or  to  introduce  innovations.    

Page 23: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

5.  Pre-­‐modern  property  rights  and  their  problems    An  example  of  NIE  analysis  in  practice    What  we  understand  well:      

Simple  private  property  in  which  farmer  owns  and  controls  his  land,  or  rents  it  from  someone  else  in  the  same  way  as  he  might  hire  other  factors  of  production,  and  seeks  to  maximise  profit.  He  can  use,  improve,  buy/sell  property  as  he  likes.    

 Arguably,  this  sort  of  capitalist  farming  is  what  emerged  early  in  Britain,  starting  as  far  back  as  end  of  Middle  Ages.  Land  ownership  became  relatively  concentrated,  and  landowners  rented  out  large  farms  to  capitalist  tenants  (who  provided  working  capital  –  hence  capitalists)  on  long  term  leases.    

 But  lots  of  interesting  and  apparently  inefficient  arrangements  observed  in  agriculture.  Sharecropping,  for  example,  which  was  important  non-­‐British  contexts,  parts  of  France.  Why?      Organisation  of  typical  medieval  village.    

Lord’s  demesne    Peasant  lands    

 Waste  and/or  common  –  devoted  to  pasture  /  woods  /  wet.  Lord  could  have  rights  here  too.    Arable  –  divided  into  scattered  strips  in  open  fields    

example  of  Neuviller  (disc.  below):  2010  strips  in  263    hectares  of  arable  (out  of  441  total  ha  in  village)  

 Consider  maps  in  Daunton,  Progress  and  Poverty,  ch.  4.  

 Two  problems  with  this  set-­‐up,  which  are  in  principle  separable    

a.  Coordination,  which  arises  from  open  fields  and  scattered  strips    b.  Incentives,  which  arise  (or  don’t)  from  common  property    A  third  problem  is  small  size  of  holdings,  which  might  be  true  even  without  (a)  and  (b).  Small  scale  a  problem  if  indivisibilities  of  investment,  for  example.  

     

Page 24: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

Commons:  property  rights  are  dispersed,  unclear    “Tragedy  of  commons”  

 There  is  an  optimal  rate  of  exploitation  of  a  resource  but  we  aren’t  likely  to  achieve  it  with  common  property.  Each  individual  calculates  only  private  marginal  benefits  and  costs,  taking  everyone  else’s  actions  as  given.      No  private  property  =>  no  market  =>  no  prices  =>  no  proper  incentives.    Result  can  be,  for  example,  overgrazing  of  common  pasture  resulting  in  undernourished  livestock  or  even  ruin  of  the  common  altogether.  Or  deforestation  as  result  of  wood  gathering.  Or  overfishing.      Imagine  that  the  value  of  each  sheep  grazed  on  common  pasture  is  given  by        (120-­‐S),  where  S  is  the  number  of  sheep.      Total  value  of  the  flock  is  S(120-­‐S),  which  is  maximised  when  120-­‐2S=0  or  S=60.      Now  imagine  two  agents,  a  and  b,  with  numbers  of  sheep  Sa  and  Sb.  a  takes  b’s  number  of  sheep  as  given  and  maximises          Sa(120-­‐Sa-­‐Sb),  which  gives  120-­‐2Sa-­‐Sb  =  0  or  Sa=60-­‐Sb/2.    b  does  likewise.      The  Nash  equilibrium  is  where  Sa  =  Sb  =  40.  The  total  flock  is  therefore  80,  when  a  total  of  60  would  have  maximised  its  value.  In  this  sense  the  commons  is  “tragically”  overexploited.      

But  custom  can  regulate,  monitor,  enforce  appropriate  use  of  common  resources.  “Stinting”.      

In  fact  it’s  not  clear  that  tragedies  of  the  commons  occurred  with  any  regularity,  historically.    

 Still,  custom  may  not  promote  or  even  permit  efficient  use  of  resources  by  those  who  value  them  most.  Unclear  whether  private  arrangements  can  circumvent.  

 And  collective  ownership  will  still  complicate  change,  investment.      Hold-­‐up  problem:  one  recalcitrant  or  opportunistic  individual  can  either  block  change  or  seek  to  appropriate  surplus  as  concession  for  his  participation.      

   

Page 25: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

Coordination    

Unfenced  (“open”)  scattered  strips  create  coordination  problems.    Need  convenient  access  to  your  strip,  without  either  trampling  others’  crops  or  walking  all  round  field.      Need  to  turn  ploughing  team  at  end  of  furrow,  same  problem  of  trampling  if  there  are  standing  crops.      Need  to  let  livestock  graze  stubble  and  manure  arable  once  the  harvest  is  in  –  impossible  if  some  crops  still  standing.  Requires  agreement  on  what  will  be  grown  and  when.      Other  possible  problems  such  as  fungus/rot  spreading  –  perhaps  from  crops  on  the  ground  (reaped  but  not  collected)  to  standing  crops?  Weeds.      Many  investments  such  as  drainage  will  benefit  others  as  much  as  you  =>  requires  coordination.      Custom  dictated  that  everyone  with  strips  in  a  certain  field  would  follow  same  rotation  and  would  coordinate  time  of  key  operations.  Even  if  land  was  privately  owned,  its  use  was  not  completely  free.  Property  rights  not  complete.      Agreeing  an  coordinating  a  change  could  be  very  difficult.  Hold-­‐up  problem  again.    

Further  problem  of  scattered  strips:  inefficiency  of  moving  self,  animals,  and  equipment  from  one  place  to  another.    

 Why  did  this  system  exist  in  the  first  place?      

a.  Back  in  the  mists  of  time,  some  communal  ethos  dictated  not  just  that  every  household  have  a  fair,  equal  allotment  of  land,  but  that  they  each  have  the  same  allotment,  hence  a  bit  of  Field  1,  a  bit  of  Field  2,  right  to  the  common  pasture  and  waste…    b.  Common  flock  and  pasture  –  probably  economy  of  scale  due  to  indivisibility.  One  skilled  shepherd  can  manage  quite  a  large  flock,  which  is  quite  a  big  saving  compared  with  each  HH  supervising  its  own  sheep.  But  one  big  flock  requires  one  big  pasture.  Could  explain  at  least  the  commons.    c.  Commons/waste  –  possible  equity  considerations.  Even  the  poorest  with  little  or  no  land  have  equal  access,  certain  minimum  endowment  guaranteed  in  this  way  even  if  for  some  reason  other  land  lost  or  divided  among  too  many  heirs.    

Page 26: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

d.  Scattered  strips  –  debate    i.  McCloskey  says  they  were  inefficient  but  provided  insurance  b/c  all  strips  unlikely  to  do  poorly  in  same  year  if  scattered  across  various  types  of  terrain  in  various  locations  growing  various  things.  Storage  too  expensive  as  a  way  of  providing  insurance.    ii.  Fenoaltea  says  this  kind  of  insurance,  which  actually  makes  everyone  worse  off  on  average  by  reducing  output,  too  expensive  to  be  plausible.  Instead  the  point  was  to  spread  peak  labour  demand  out  in  time.  If  all  your  land  in  one  location  under  one  crop,  harvest  will  all  need  to  happen  at  one  moment.  This  will  exceed  your  HH  labour,  forcing  you  to  turn  to  non-­‐existent  market  and  supervise  non-­‐family  labour,  which  has  little  incentive  to  max  output  for  you.  HH  farm  is  efficient  in  avoiding  this  supervision/transaction  cost  type  of  problem.  So  scattered  strips  were  actually  efficient.  Which  is  why  they  persisted  for  so  long.      Hoffman’s  (1996  book)  discussion  supports  Fenoaltea’s  claim  that  one  couldn’t  necessarily  trust  hired  labour  in  peasant  villages,  nor  assume  strong  communal  bonds  always  at  work.    

 These  are  examples  of  institutional  analysis.      

We  look  at  the  institution,  try  to  understand  the  behavioural  incentives  it  implies  for  individuals,  try  to  see  what  function  it  may  have  served  and  what  problems  it  created.      Sometimes  this  leads  to  some  kind  of  empirical  test.      Greif’s  approach  is  to  use  formal  game  theory  to  model  institutions.  He  says  quantitative  tests  are  not  very  powerful  and  that  we  want  to  construct  an  “analytic  narrative”  supported  by  game  theory  that  describes  the  institution.    

   Since  Young’s  time  it  has  been  alleged  that  this  traditional  system  was  grossly  inefficient.  Enclosure,  private  property,  consolidation,  large  scale  the  key  to  increasing  productivity.      

The  evidence  not  nearly  so  convincing,  as  we  shall  see.      Why  did  such  pre-­‐modern  arrangements  last  so  long?      

Older  wisdom:  because  of  tenacious  resistance  to  change  esp.  in  France.  Political  power  of  smallholders  and  legal  confusion.  Lack  of  enabling  legislation  like  British  parliamentary  enclosure  rules.      

Page 27: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

Newer  wisdom:  because  the  old  arrangements  were  not  very  inefficient,  gains  from  enclosure  were  not  very  large.    

     6.  Property  and  property  rights  in  Britain  and  France    I  cannot  find  figures  for  average  farm  size  in  B  and  F.  There  are  figures  from  1910  which  show  land  labour  ratio  in  B  was  twice  that  in  F.  Not  the  same  as  farm  size,  which  was  much  bigger  in  Britain  from  an  early  date.      Allen  (cehmb)  data  on  Britain  only.    

 Middle  Ages:  demesnes  of  several  hundred  acres,  serf  holdings  ca.  30  acres    1700:  avg  farm  –  including  all  types,  tiny  and  giant,  65  acres    1800:  150  acres  in  South,  100  in  North  

 Daunton  (P&P,  p.62)  from  Mingay    

Distribution  of  land  ca.  1790    Great  owners  (>5k  acres)     20-­‐25%  Greater  squierarchy  (1-­‐6/7k)   25-­‐33  Smaller  owners  (<1k)     42-­‐55      of  whom  small  owner-­‐occupiers   15-­‐20  

 France  by  contrast  perhaps  50%  of  land  worked  by  peasant  households  who  own  or  rent.    

 Why  concentration  in  Britain  more  than  France?      

Recall  Brenner  story  from  Approaches.  Neither  demographic  nor  commercialisation  forces  explain  European  developments  in  Middle  Ages  and  early  modern  period.  Cannot  explain  how  same  situation  produced  different  outcomes,  e.g.  disappearance  of  serfdom  in  West  and  its  strengthening  in  East.      Instead  it  was  political  (even  armed)  conflict  between  classes  that  determined  different  outcomes.      In  Britain  lords  were  successful  in  limiting  the  rights  of  smallholders  to  hereditary  tenure,  commons  rights,  immunity  from  taxation.  This  led  to  consolidation  of  landholdings,  large  estates.  Which  led  to  capitalist  tenant  farming.  Which  led  to  agricultural  productivity  increase.    

Page 28: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

In  France  peasants  were  much  more  successful  in  preserving  their  position.  The  state  became  involved,  seeing  tax  base  in  the  peasantry,  whom  it  supported  against  lords  –  who  were  a  rival  power  anyway.    

   Britain    

Enclosure  =  process  of  consolidating  individual  land  holdings  in  arable  and  eliminating  commons  by  allocating  to  individuals.  Often  associated  with  physically  enclosing  the  new  holdings  for  keeping  animals  in/out,  hence  enclosure.    Allen  (cehmb)  says  about  45%  of  land  in  England  enclosed  already  by  1500.      

By  1700,  only  29%  still  open  fields  or  common.      These  early  enclosures  were  voluntary,  at  least  in  the  sense  that  they  didn’t  rely  on  appeal  to  higher  authority,  official  coercion.  

 In  18-­‐19c  parliamentary  enclosures  become  common.      

Parliamentary  enclosure  rules  allowed  a  majority  of  landownership  to  request  a  mandatory  enclosure.  Since  landownership  concentrated,  might  be  a  small  number  of  individuals  vs.  majority  of  smallholders.    

 These  enclosures  could  be  enforced  against  the  wishes  of  a  minority.    

 Marxist  view    

Enclosures  both  created  a  class  of  landless  labourers,  i.e.  a  proletariat,  and  were  a  source  of  primitive  accumulation  of  capital  –  class  robbery.  The  bourgeoisie,  in  this  view,  were  using  their  control  over  parliament  post  1641  to  push  through  change.    

 Two  aspects:  consolidation  of  scattered  strips  and  enclosing  the  resulting  larger  plots;  and  privatising  the  commons  and  waste.    Debate  about  whether  dividing  up  the  commons  effectively  expropriated  smallholders  and  landless  labourers  for  whom  access  to  the  commons  was  important  to  their  livelihood.  Use  of  commons  and  later  division  of  commons  proportional  to  landholding,  but  in  practice,  supposedly,  use  prior  to  enclosure  was  more  egalitarian,  guaranteed  a  sort  of  minimum  endowment  for  even  the  poorest.  They  lost  this,  if  held  no  other  land,  in  enclosure  process.    

   

Page 29: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

France    

I  don’t  have  data  on  farm  size  or  consolidation,  but  no  one  seems  to  contest  the  claims  that      

peasants  owned  or  otherwise  controlled  much  of  France’s  land    their  holdings  were  typically  small  (in  many  cases  too  small  for  self-­‐sufficiency)    open  fields  and  scattered  strips  predominated    

 However,  there  is  debate  about  whether  this  was  truly  bad  for  productivity  (discussed  below).    And  there  is  debate  about  whether  it  was  the  peasants  who  blocked  consolidation  and  enclosure  in  France.      Hoffman  (1996,  p.  26)  example    

1782  village  of  La  Grande  Paroisse  has  commons  in  form  of  a  large  meadow,  which  is  leased  out  to  provide  income  for  the  village.    The  revenue  went  to  pay  (part  of)  the  village’s  tax  assessment.  This  disproportionately  benefited  the  larger  landowners  who  would  have  been  responsible  for  most  of  the  tax  payments  (which  were  meant  to  be  proportional  to  landholdings).      Smallholders  and  day  labourers  propose  to  continue  leasing  out  the  commons  but  use  revenue  to  pay  a  schoolmaster,  a  vicar,  and  leave  a  bit  left  over  as  income  to  individual  residents.  Villagers  had  no  blind  attachment  to  communal  ownership  and  exploitation  per  se.      They  were  blocked  by  three  prosperous  larger  landholders,  who  were  explicit  about  how  it  would  disadvantage  them.      More  generally,  often  the  case  that  the  well-­‐off  benefited  more  from  the  commons  than  the  small  fry.  Often  the  case  that  landowners  blocked  change,  not  peasants,  even  if  they  (landowners)  claimed  to  be  safeguarding  the  poor.    

 Hoffman  second  example    

Villages  of  Roville  and  Neuviller  in  Lorraine    King’s  intendant  De  la  Galaizière,  local  seigneur  and  landowner,  organises  enclosures  1768-­‐71:      

Page 30: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

consolidate  landholdings,  divide  commons,  enclose,  redraw  access  roads  and  paths…    Also  deals  with  drainage  problem  to  stop  wasteful  defensive  ploughing  of  very  deep  furrows  around  every  strip,  which  end  up  permanently  flooded;  furrows  coordinated  from  one  plot  to  next  to  aid  drainage,  direction  and  link-­‐up  of  furrows  has  to  be  maintained.      In  agreement  with  local  landowners    Highly  successful  –  rents  increase  substantially  after  re-­‐organisation.  Rents  of  a  religious  order  that  held  land  in  the  area  increased  55%  in  aftermath  of  changes  (perhaps  32%  adjusting  for  inflation).      

Classic  dispute  arises  –  villagers  complain  that  they  have  lost  out  from  division  of  commons  where  they  pastured  their  herd.    

 1781  shepherd  leads  flock  through  barriers  and  into  enclosed  field  that  used  to  be  commons.      Court  finds  against,  imposes  fine  on  shepherd  and  village.      But  appeal  to  higher  court  (parlement  of  Nancy)  successful,  judgment  reversed.      This  takes  years  –  lawsuit  still  going  at  time  of  Revolution.  Rhetoric  about  grazing  rights  of  smallholders.  But  in  fact  the  judges  in  the  parlement  were  themselves  seigneurs  and  landowners  with  grazing  rights  on  the  commons  in  (other  villages  in)  this  area!    And  you  have  to  wonder  how  the  villagers  had  the  resources  to  pursue  the  legal  case  so  far  and  long.      

Moreover,  real  obstacle  to  the  enclosures  were  landowners  who  tried  to  hold  up  the  process.    

 De  la  Galaizière  already  in  conflict  with  some  local  landowners,  parlement  of  Nancy.  Has  authorisation  from  King,  but  worries  about  legal  appeals.  Wants  voluntary  agreement  of  everyone.    

 He  has  to  take  most  expenses  on  himself  to  win  agreement.      

Pays  legal  and  surveying  expenses  (about  1/3  of  total  costs)    All  new  roads  made  on  his  land.      

 Purchased  land  of  hold-­‐outs  for  above-­‐market  prices,  effectively  a  bribe.  Biggest  bribe  recipients  were  rich  landowners.    

Page 31: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

 Total  costs  33,000  livres.      Compares  with  increase  in  total  value  of  all  land  in  the  villages  (capitalised  higher  future  rental  income)  of  29,000-­‐76,000  livres.  Anywhere  from  half  to  all  of  the  gain  was  lost  in  the  cost  of  implementation.      De  la  Galaizière  was  a  net  loser  in  all  of  this,  because  he  paid  full  costs  but  got  only  part  of  benefits.  Had  he  not  been  forced  to  pay  the  bribes,  he  would  have  turned  a  profit  even  taking  all  the  legal  and  surveying  expenses  on  himself.  Buying  off  the  opposition  is  what  would  have  killed  off  the  project.      Not  to  worry,  he  was  eventually  compensated  by  the  government.  But  an  example  of  how  the  system  of  land  tenure  could  be  difficult  to  change.  

 Hoffman  does  not  believe  peasant  households  were  steeped  in  some  ancient  communal  ethos,  opposed  to  all  change.  Property  rights  were  contested,  and  change  was  difficult.  But  it  was  the  seigneurs  as  often  as  the  peasants  who  blocked  change.  Hoffman  also  thinks  peasant  households  sometimes  found  ways  around  problems  of  the  land  tenure  system,  such  as  swapping  plots  so  as  to  cultivate  larger  consolidated  areas,  even  if  ownership  didn’t  change.    

 Rosenthal  story  about  irrigation      

Two  sorts  of  problems.    1.  Individuals  have  overly  secure  property  rights  and  can  block  useful  change.  It  may  be  that  the  ability  to  change  property  rights,  rather  than  their  clarity  or  security,  is  the  key  to  progress.      Horwitz’  interpretation  of  American  law  was  that  it  changed  property  rights  to  suit  whatever  was  needed  for  technical  change,  growth,  modernisation.  There  were  no  other  deep  principles  it  upheld.      2.  Conflicting  jurisdiction  claims  make  this  even  harder  to  resolve.    

   The  Revolution    

One  sentence  summary:  did  not  do  anything  to  facilitate  enclosure,  confirming  security  of  individual  property  rights,  confirmed  small  peasant  households  in  ownership  of  a  large  share  of  all  land.      So  French-­‐British  differences  persisted.    

Page 32: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

7.  Did  property  rights,  and  enclosures,  really  matter  so  much?        Evidence  from  Britain  suggests  benefits  of  enclosure  exaggerated.      Evidence  for  efficiency  gain  was  from  increases  in  rental  income  that  came  with  enclosure.      Problems  with  this  claim    

 Young  exaggerated  b/c  he  wanted  to  promote  enclosure.  It  tended  to  benefit  larger  landholders.      This  was  also  true  of  some  French  landowners,  who  sought  justification  for  self-­‐interested  redistributions.      (Presumably  b/c  they  got  a  share  of  commons  proportional  to  their  private  landholdings  in  both  cases.)    

 Rent  can  double  even  if  efficiency  increases  by  much  less,  because  land  is  the  residual  claimant.      

If  wage  and  return  to  capital  don’t  change,  all  of  increased  efficiency  goes  to  land.  That  is  nature  of  rent.      Suppose  rent  is  just  10%  the  value  of  output.  Now  let  output  rise  by  10%  due  to  enclosure,  with  the  entire  increment  goes  to  land.  Rent  doubles,  without  anything  like  doubling  efficiency.    

 Clark  (JEH  98)    Historians  looking  at  well-­‐documented  cases  of  British  enclosures  in  late  18c      

a)  lazy  –  relied  on  little  actual  evidence    b)  failed  to  account  for  generalised  increases  in  all  rents  (irrespective  of  new  enclosure)  in  a  period  of  rising  agricultural  prices    c)  failed  to  account  for  how  change  of  ownership  and/or  cultivation  could  eliminate  tithe  requirement.  Benefits  owner  but  no  efficiency  improvement.    

True  increases  in  rent  much  less  than  doubling.  Clark’s  alternative  data  indicate  much  smaller  increases.    Clark  calculates  that  gains  from  enclosure  (which  was  expensive  b/c  of  building  roads,  fences,  paying  costs  of  commissioners)  were  not  better  

Page 33: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

than  alternative  uses  of  funds.  This  until  mid  1700s,  just  when  last  wave  of  enclosures  starts.    

   Allen  careful  comparison  suggests  little  gain  in  pure  efficiency  from  enclosure.    

Yields  in  bushels  per  acre.      

Open enclosed pct gain Heavy arable district Wheat 19.7 20.2 2.2 Barley 26.5 31.8 20.0 Oats 23.5 33.0 40.4 Beans 18.8 22.2 18.1 Avg. 21.2 24.1 14.7 Light arable district Wheat 20.0 19.7 -1.5 Barley 27.0 29.3 8.5 Oats 26.5 32.5 22.6 Beans 19.9 18.1 -9.0 Avg. 23.4 24.7 5.6 Pasture district Wheat 20.9 21.9 4.8 Barley 28.0 32.2 15.0 Oats 36.9 38.1 3.3 Beans 22.4 23.4 4.5 Avg. 24.7 26.7 8.1

   

For  wheat,  there  is  hardly  any  advantage  at  all.      More  generally,  percentage  improvements  in  yields  are  modest.  The  only  really  striking  one  is  oats  in  the  heavy  arable  district.      This  doesn’t  mean  enclosure  completely  useless,  b/c  it  could  permit  a  more  easy  conversion  to  something  like  convertible  husbandry,  greater  livestock  production,  greater  value  of  output.  It  just  didn’t  directly  increase  yields  of  main  crops  very  much.  A  facilitator  of  productivity  growth  through  structural  change.      

Allen  (2009  book)  also  documents  at  least  some  cases  of  collective  (rather  than  individual)  agricultural  innovation.      

Oxfordshire  villages  as  a  whole  decided  to  experiment  with  sainfoin.  At  first  voluntary,  later  made  compulsory  with  help  of  landlord’s  agent,  who  threatened  non-­‐cooperators  with  making  life  difficult.    

 This  suggests  dispersed  ownership  and  small  scale  not  the  insuperable  obstacle  to  experimentation  and  innovation.      

Page 34: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

   Grantham  and  Hoffman  say  many  alleged  problems  could  be  circumvented  in  France  too.    

for  example  by  exchanging  leased  plots  of  land  so  as  to  have  contiguous  area  for  cultivation.      Land  cultivated  didn’t  have  to  correspond  with  land  owned  or  rented.      With  ownership  not  same  as  cultivation,  small  farm  size  didn’t  have  to  mean  diseconomies  of  small  scale.    

 Grantham  calculates  costs  of  enclosure.  There  was  no  law  making  it  easy  to  override  minority  opponents.      

   8.  What,  then?      What  then  would  be  the  deep  explanation  for  British  advantages?      Many  small  effects  could  have  added  up  to  something  big,  either  by  cumulation  or  interaction.      Capital  (animal)  intense  vs.  labour  intense  form  of  agriculture  seems  to  be  key.  

 This  could  have  to  do  with  population  density  (further  back  in  history,  possibly  to  de-­‐population  of  Britain  post  Black  Death).    And  wool  production  for  woollen  industry.  

 Is  there  some  way  that  peasant  HHs  cannot  or  will  not  make  the  switch  to  animal  husbandry?  Indivisibilities  or  minimum  threshold  investments?  

 And  perhaps  w/  enclosure  too.    

 It’s  not  that  enclosure  magically  increases  productivity  of  particular  activities,  but  that  it  facilitates  switching  activities.      

Perhaps  Smithian  growth  through  greater  specialisation    

Access  to  large  markets  for  particular  products,  including  animal  products,  could  lead  to  move  away  from  subsistence,  specialisation  in  production  for  market.  This  could  lead  to  adoption  of  best  techniques  and  organisation  for  those  particular  specialisations.  (Or,  perhaps,  through  learning  by  doing,  to  better  techniques  for  any  particular  specialisation.)    Access  to  large  markets  driven  by  

Page 35: IBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ Institutions ...users.ox.ac.uk/~pemb3023/ibf_lect2_tt12.pdfIBF$–$Lecture2$ $ TT2012$ $ $ Institutions,propertyrightsandagriculture$ $ $ Britain$seems$to$have$had$much$higher$agricultural$productivity$than$France,$

IBF  –  Lecture  2     TT2012    

 market  integration    transport  infrastructure    urbanisation    incomes  (which  could  be  high  due  to  industry  /  trade)    

We  will  discuss  in  another  lecture  how  Britain  had  advantages  along  these  dimensions.    

 Grantham  (JEH  89)  argues  that  French  farmers  responded  to  market  opportunities.  In  locations  from  which  urban  markets  were  accessible,  they  worked  harder,  invested  more,  switched  crop  mix  towards  marketable  goods.  All  this  raised  productivity,  though  it  did  not  involve  any  revolutionary  change,  completely  new  techniques.    

         Ambiguity  about  how  important  property  rights  were  in  either  Britain  or  France  frustrating.