hoover digest, 2013, no. 3, summer

Upload: hoover-institution

Post on 03-Apr-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    1/200

    T H E H O O V E R I N S T I T U T I O N S TA N F O R D U N I V E R S I T Y

    R E S E A R C H A N D O P I N I O N

    O N P U B L I C P O L I C Y

    2 0 1 3 N O 3 S U M M E R

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    2/200

    T H E H O O V E R I N S T I T U T I O N

    S TA N F O R D U N I V E R S I T Y

    R E S E A R C H A N D O P I N I O N

    O N P U B L I C P O L I C Y

    2 0 1 3 N O . 3 S U M M E R

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    3/200

    The Hoover Digestoffers informative writing on politics, economics, and

    history by the scholars and researchers of the Hoover Institution, the publicpolicy research center at Stanford University.

    The opinions expressed in the Hoover Digestare those of the authors and

    do not necessarily reflect the opinions of the Hoover Institution, Stanford

    University, or their supporters.

    The Hoover Digest (ISSN 1088-5161) is published quarterly by the Hoover

    Institution on War, Revolution and Peace, Stanford University, Stanford

    CA 94305-6010. Periodicals Postage Paid at Palo Alto CA and additional

    mailing offices. POSTMASTER: Send address changes to the Hoover

    Digest,Hoover Press, Stanford University, Stanford CA 94305-6010. 2013 by the Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University

    Contact InformationWe welcome your comments and suggestions at digesteditor@stanford.

    edu and invite you to browse the Hoover Institution website at www.

    hoover.org. For reprint requests, write to this e-mail address or send a fax

    to 650.723.8626. The Hoover Digestpublishes the work of the scholars and

    researchers affiliated with the Hoover Institution and thus does not accept

    unsolicited manuscripts.

    Subscription InformationThe Hoover Digest is available by subscription for $25 a year to U.S.

    addresses (international rates higher). To subscribe, send an e-mail to

    [email protected] write to

    Hoover DigestSubscription FulfillmentP.O. Box 37005Chicago, IL 60637

    You may also contact our subscription agents by phone at 877.705.1878

    (toll free in U.S. and Canada) or 773.753.3347 (international) or by fax at

    877.705.1879 (U.S. and Canada) or 773.753.0811 (international).

    On the CoverA racecar streaking past the finishline is both an iconic image of sum-mer and a reminder of the story of

    American automaking. Indianapolis

    once ranked second only to Detroitin cars produced for the growingcontingent of American drivers.The Indianapolis Motor Speedwayin this poster was a place whereearly engines, suspensions, brakes,tireseven rearview mirrorswere tested for the driving public. Even today,car builders and innovators jostle for position on the Brickyard just as driversdo. See story, page 196.

    Hoover DigestResearch and Opin ion on Publ ic Po l icy

    . www.hooverdigest.org

    HOOVER DIGEST

    Editor

    Managing Editor

    .

    Institutional Editor

    Managing Editor,Hoover Institution Press

    HOOVER INSTITUTION

    .

    Chairman, Board of Overseers

    .

    .

    Vice Chairmen,Board of Overseers

    Tad and Dianne Taube

    Director

    .

    Deputy Director,Davies Family Senior Fellow

    Senior Associate Directors

    .

    Counselors to the Director

    ASSOCIATE DIRECTORS

    .

    ASSISTANT DIRECTORS

    .

    .

    visit theHOOVER INSTITUTION

    online atwww.hoover.org

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    4/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3

    ContentsHOOVER D IGEST 2013 NO . 3 S UM MER

    THE ECONOMY

    9 How to Ignite Economic Growth (Its Not a Mystery)Start with a sound budget, then challenge everything thats hold-

    ing the economy back. By . , . ,

    . , . , . , and

    . .

    15 Cloudy, with a Chance of ErrorMonthly job numbers offer only the haziest economic predictions.

    By .

    18 Skip the Short RunWe need to swear off this endless tinkering. By . .

    23 Contrived InequalityA lot of wealthy people deserve their success. Is it asking too much

    of the government to recognize that? Maybe so. By . .

    27 We Need to Cut Spending. Heres HowThe careful budget that Paul Ryan and others in the House have pro-

    posed would ease the economy into a better place. By .

    and . .

    TAXAT ION

    32 Alternative Maximum TaxLets settle on a top number for everybody. By . .

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    5/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3

    POL IT ICS

    36 The Missing ModeratesPlenty of moderates still existbut theyre forced to choose be-

    tween a couple of political parties that rarely serve them well. By

    . .

    50 The GOP Can Win Back Asian-AmericansAn opportunity that the party of opportunity must seize. By

    . .

    53 The Quiet AmericansA half-century-old Supreme Court ruling is costing rural voters their

    voiceand control over their own destinies. By .

    HEALTH CARE

    61 Consumer ChoiceIt Works!

    In the private marketplace, millions already choose just the healthinsurance they want. Government-run exchange schemes, however,

    will get everything all wrong. By . .

    64 Promises, PromisesObamaCare makes Americans certain promises. We already know

    that at least four of them are false. By . .

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    6/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3

    REGULAT ION

    68 Protect Me NotA lot of workplace protections protect workers right out of a job.

    By . .

    EDUCAT ION

    74 No Bright Mind Left BehindResearch by Hoover fellow . shows how institu-

    tions of higher learning can attract the many qualified, deserving stu-

    dents that the admissions process now overlooks. By .

    IMMIGRAT ION

    79 On the Border, New RealitiesRecession helped slow the river of illegal immigration. Demography

    and a stronger Mexican economy may keep it from rising again. By

    . .

    83 A Price on CitizenshipClashes over immigration policy can be settled with one simple, hu-

    mane reform: selling the right to citizenship. By . and

    .

    I RAQ

    87 Ten Years OnSaddam Hussein is long gone, but a peaceful, democratic Iraq re-

    mains a long way off. By .

    91 Why We Went to WarDisappointment with how the wars in Afghanistan and Iraq turned

    out is no excuse for rewriting the record. By .

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    7/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3

    AFGHAN ISTAN

    98 A Time to Reflect, a Time to ActIn Afghanistan, an Army colonel explains what he learned during his

    year at Hoover. By . c.

    RUSS IA

    108Women of the GulagVoices so indomitable that even Stalin failed to silence them. By

    .

    I ND IA

    116 India UnchainedWhats keeping India from taking on Chinaand the world? By

    .

    FORE IGN POL ICY

    120 Nuclear Arms: No Time for ComplacencyNonproliferation efforts must intensify, step by careful step. By

    . , . , . , and

    .

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    8/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3

    NAT IONAL SECUR ITY

    126 Drones SightedThe targeted-killing program gets a ray or two of sunshine. By

    . .

    131 A Proxy Air ForceBest known for precisely targeted attacks on terrorists, drones are

    now being given much broader missions. By .

    RACE

    136 Gifted HandsWith a mother who refuses to let him fail, a young black man grows

    up to be a neurosurgeon. By .

    I NTERV IEWS

    140 Calming the Political WatersHoover fellow talks about the subtle power of

    constitutional conservatism. By .

    148 An Endless StruggleScholars Bernard Lewis and Norman Podhoretz ponder the

    Arab spring and the chilly season to come. An interview with

    .

    H ISTORY AND CULTURE

    159 Margaret and RonThe unlikely friendship that changed the world. By .

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    9/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3

    163 Gambling on AggressionThe cold, warlike calculations of 1914 find an echo in todays North

    Korea. Tomorrow it could be China. By .

    HOOVER ARCH IVES

    168 The Battle of Rockefeller CenterIn the Manhattan fresco he painted during the Depression,

    saw a masterpiece. His patrons, however, saw Red. By

    . .

    190 On the Cover

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    10/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 9

    THE ECONOMY

    How to IgniteEconomic Growth(Its Not a Mystery)Start with a sound budget, then challenge everything thats holding

    the economy back. By George P. Shultz, Gary S. Becker, Michael J.

    Boskin, John F. Cogan, Allan H. Meltzer, and John B. Taylor.

    Washington has become a city of tactics, obsessed with finger pointing,

    fear mongering, and political spin. These maneuversdesigned for tem-

    porary political or personal gainhave produced incoherent policies and

    left the nations pressing problems unaddressed.

    The country needs a long-term strategy to achieve its common goals

    of personal freedom, noninflationary prosperity, broad-based economic

    opportunity and mobility, and national security. With a good strategy as a

    foundation, sound economic policies will follow.

    A good strategy must be based on principles of the free-enterprise system

    in which individuals are allowed to pursue their aspirations with govern-

    ments role limited to protecting property rights, setting predictable and

    transparent marketplace rules, and providing a safety net, infrastructure,

    defense, and other functions if the market falls short. Many current gov-

    ernment policies are going well beyond such limits, as shown by excessive

    spending and taxes, growing debt, interventionist monetary policy, and bur-

    densome regulations that have slowed economic growth and job creation.

    The obvious place to begin applying strategic thinking is to the bud-

    getthe primary vehicle for setting priorities. Yet, in recent years, the

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    11/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 310

    budget process has completely broken down, replaced by disorderly man-

    agement by crisis.

    RESTORING THE BALANCE

    We need to go back to an old-fashioned regular budget order. The presi-

    dent needs to submit a budget that contains a strategic plan and brings

    the budget into balance. The House and Senate then need to pass a bud-

    get resolution that sets spending in line with revenues. The congressional

    committees responsible for appropriations and entitlements must then

    produce legislation required to achieve the budget plan, bill by bill.

    Appropriations legislation should focus on the coming fiscal year andthe next, not on ten-year, multitrillion-dollar totals that the current Con-

    gress cant control and the public cant understand. Annual appropriations

    should concentrate on supporting the basic role of the federal govern-

    ment, leaving major support for infrastructure and education to the states.

    Recent promising actions by local governments to allow more choice in

    K12 education should be encouraged. The defense budget must be based

    on a national-security strategy, not on across-the-board cuts, ad hoc for-mulas that simply target defense spending as a share of GDP, or continu-

    ing resolutions that put national security at risk.

    Entitlement legislation should focus on humanely controlling the

    growth of Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid, thereby saving them

    from destruction. Currently, each of these programs is projected to grow

    much faster than national income and the revenue to fund it, and their

    unfunded liabilities are several times greater than the national debt.

    GEORGEP. SHULTZis the Thomas W. and Susan B. Ford Distinguished Fel-

    low at the Hoover Institution, the chairman of Hoovers Shultz-Stephenson

    Task Force on Energy Policy, and a member of Hoovers Working Group on

    Economic Policy. GARYS. BECKER is the Rose-Marie and Jack R. Anderson

    Senior Fellow at Hoover and a member of the Working Group on Economic

    Policy and Shultz-Stephenson Task Force on Energy Policy. He is also the

    University Professor of Economics and Sociology at the University of Chicago.

    He was awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1992.

    MICHAELJ. BOSKINis a senior fellow at Hoover, a member of Hoovers Shultz-

    Stephenson Task Force on Energy Policy and Working Group on Economic

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    12/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 11

    Medicaids growing costs, as the Ravitch-Volcker task force report

    recently noted, have severely impaired the ability to finance essential state

    government functions. A sensible reform strategy enacted now would

    therefore help the economy grow, raise living standards, improve govern-ment services, and avoid abrupt and unpredictable changes that harm

    individuals and the economy.

    Appropriations bills should focus on the coming fiscal year and the next,

    not on ten-year totals that Congress cant control and the public cant

    understand.

    The key to reform is recognition that real inflation-adjusted payments

    per recipient in these programs are projected to rise sharply. While life

    spans are increasing and the baby-boom generation is retiring, the main

    problem is this rapid growth of payments per beneficiary.

    In the case of Social Security, a typical twenty-five-year-old worker

    today will get a monthly benefit 50 percent higher after adjusting for infla-tion than the amount paid to todays typical retiree. To solve this problem,

    the indexing formula originally adopted in 1977 should be modified for

    future retirees so their inflation-adjusted benefits are the same as those

    received by todays retirees. It is absurd to claim that slowing the growth of

    benefits for those retiring in the distant future is somehow a cut.

    For Medicare and Medicaid, the reform goal must be to reduce their

    immense cost growth in a humane way. The explosive trends are mainly

    Policy, and the T. M. Friedman Professor of Economics at Stanford University.

    JOHNF. COGANis the Leonard and Shirley Ely Senior Fellow at Hoover and a

    member of the Shultz-Stephenson Task Force on Energy Policy, Working Group

    on Health Care Policy, and Working Group on Economic Policy. ALLANH.

    MELTZERis a distinguished visiting fellow at Hoover and a professor of politi-

    cal economy at Carnegie Mellon University.JOHNB. TAYLORis the George P.

    Shultz Senior Fellow in Economics at Hoover, the chairman of the Working

    Group on Economic Policy and a member of the Shultz-Stephenson Task Force

    on Energy Policy, and the Mary and Robert Raymond Professor of Economics

    at Stanford University.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    13/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 312

    due to improper incentives created by poor government policies. The fed-

    eral governments attempts to impose price controls on hospitals, doctors,

    and other health care providers make the problem worse. Price controls

    cause the supply of health care providers to shrink, as these controls havedone in every other market in which they have been imposed. The declin-

    ing supply amid rising demand produces shortages and reduced access to

    health care.

    Its absurd to claim that slowing the growth of benefits for retirees of

    the distant future amounts to a cut.

    Medicare and Medicaid reforms should be part of a larger effort to

    improve the private health care system. The best strategy is to allow

    consumers to have more skin in the game, provide high-quality readily

    accessible information, and permit competition among health plans and

    insurers.

    Introducing more co-payments that reflect some of the opportunity

    costs of health care resources will provide the proper incentives and mod-erate demand. More-informed decision-making will lead to lower insur-

    ance premiums and thus more disposable income for Medicare recipients,

    and higher wages for workers with employer-sponsored health plans.

    Government can play an important role in making accurate informa-

    tion more widely available, both by funding its dissemination and by pro-

    tecting health care institutions and individuals who provide it. If they are

    to be wise and effective consumers of health care, people need to knowwhat works and what doesnt, who works best and who doesnt, and what

    prices will be.

    The federal government can encourage competition in a number of

    ways: by making out-of-pocket health care spending tax-deductible and

    thereby in line with the tax treatment of health insurance premiums; by

    providing insurance subsidies through which people can shop among

    alternative insurance programs; by expanding the availability of healthsavings accounts; and by permitting individuals to purchase health insur-

    ance in other states. Insurance companies and health care provider groups

    long ago captured state legislatures and insurance regulators, creating

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    14/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 13

    anticompetitive barriers to entry and thousands of state mandates to pro-

    vide insurance coverage and procedures.

    The ideal strategy for Medicaid reform would allow states flexibility in

    designing and administering their programs in exchange for a level of fed-eral funding that grows in line with population plus inflation. The federal

    government should take immediate steps to allow states greater discretion

    to reform their programs to curtail costs and maintain coverage.

    F IXING INCENTIVES

    Sound entitlement reform will have other beneficial effects. The work dis-

    incentives now built into our large and growing federal transfer programsimpede economic growth. These work disincentives affect all recipients:

    younger workers, senior citizens, healthy workers, and those with dis-

    abilities. Social Security, for example, contains significant disincentives

    for older people to work. To reduce these disincentives, the government

    could introduce a paid up concept so that a person continuing to work

    after his or her retirement age would not be subject to either employer or

    employee payroll taxes.

    If they are to be wise and effective consumers of health care, people need

    to know what works.

    Franklin Roosevelt rightly called welfare a subtle destroyer of the Ameri-

    can spirit. In 2011, the latest year in which data are available, thirty-eight

    million working-age households (i.e., with no member age sixty-five andolder), representing 42 percent of working-age households, received benefits

    from at least one federal welfare-entitlement program. Among these thirty-

    eight million households, the average effective tax rate on additional earn-

    ingsa rate that includes the loss of welfare benefits as earnings increase

    ranges from 36 percent to over 50 percent, depending on whether the

    additional income causes a family to lose Medicaid eligibility.

    By discouraging work and human capital investments, these high effec-tive tax rates on such a large segment of the American working-age popu-

    lation harm economic growth and reduce employment. Thus, a broad

    reform strategy should include a complete overhaul of the entitlement

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    15/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 314

    system, with reduced work disincentives and improved targeting on per-

    sons who are unable to help themselves.

    At the end of World War II, strategic economic thinking enabled the

    United States to lead the world by encouraging free enterprise and pro-moting a rules-based system for trade and finance. The result was an

    unprecedented period of prosperity, which by the 1980s had spread across

    the globe, dramatically improving living standards.

    Strategic thinking today will produce policies that bolster economic

    growth, employment, and American geopolitical leadership. As other

    countries again emulate our economic and political system, their prosper-

    ity will be to our mutual benefit.Reprinted by permission of the Wall Street Journal. 2013 Dow Jones & Co. All rights reserved.

    New from the Hoover Press is Entitlement Spending: Our

    Coming Fiscal Tsunami,by David Koitz. To order, call

    800.935.2882 or visit www.hooverpress.org.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    16/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 15

    THE ECONOMY

    Cloudy, with a Chanceof ErrorMonthly job numbers offer only the haziest economic predictions. By

    Edward Paul Lazear.

    On the first Friday of the month, when the latest employment numbers

    come out amid much business-media fanfare, the numbers will be parsed

    for what they tell us about the economy and where it is headed. The jobs

    numbers do contain some valuable information, but they mean much less

    than is often assumedbecause, as the Department of Labor cautions,theyre estimates. They are subject to significant revision, they are volatile,

    and they tell us very little about the direction of the labor market.

    The jobs day information comes from two different sources of data pro-

    vided by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Household data are used to estimate

    the size of the labor force and the unemployment rate, and the widely reported

    job creation numbers come from data supplied by employers. It is possible,

    however, to obtain job-creation numbers by analyzing the household data.Often there is a disparity between the employer-based numbers and the

    job-creation numbers that come from household data. In more than half

    the months from 1996 to the present, the household and establishment job-

    creation figures differed by more than 50 percent. For example, in a month

    when the employer-based number is 200,000 additional jobs, it would be

    typical to find the household numbers reporting only 100,000 new jobs.

    EDWARDPAULLAZEARis the Morris Arnold and Nona Jean Cox Senior Fellow

    at the Hoover Institution and the Jack Steele Parker Professor of Human Resources

    Management and Economics at Stanford Universitys Graduate School of Business.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    17/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 316

    Over longer periods, however, there is significant agreement between

    the two data sources. The annual employment levels from the household

    survey are very closely related to annual employment levels from the

    employer-establishment survey.It is widely accepted that the employer-based establishment data are

    better for the purposes of estimating job creation than are the household

    data. Unfortunately, even the establishment data are less than accurate, at

    least when first announced.

    The accuracy of job-creation numbers goes up considerably during more

    normal times, when job growth is positive.

    Each month, the Bureau of Labor Statistics reports employment and the

    change in employment since the previous month. There are subsequent

    revisions, one and two months after the first announcement, until the num-

    ber becomes final, sometimes up to two years later. The error in any given

    month tends to be very large, which means that its reliability is low.

    For instance, the average number of jobs created per month duringthe 19962012 period was 78,000. But in the typical month, the initial

    estimate missed the final number by 73,000 in one direction or the other.

    This means that the average error in the initial report is almost as large as

    average job creation itself.

    The quarterly numbers are somewhat better, but not by much. The

    picture improves again for annual job growth, with the typical error being

    about half as large as the average job change itself.In some months, the error is enormous. For example, the initial report

    released in January 2011 stated that 130,712,000 Americans were work-

    ing in December 2010. Two months later, that number was revised down-

    ward to 130,260,000a difference of 452,000. When the final numbers

    came in, the actual overstatement turned out to be 366,000. Thats worth

    keeping in mind at a time when much excitement can be stirred up by a

    monthly jobs fluctuation in the tens of thousands.The December 2010 example is by no means the worst case. In late

    2009, the difference between initial reports and revisions was well over

    one million. For the entire period studied, the initial estimates of job cre-

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    18/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 17

    ation deviated from final estimates by at least 50 percent in almost one in

    every four months.

    Over the very long run, the reported numbers look better. Although

    there is significant error in any given month, the overstatements of jobgrowth in some months tend to offset understatements of job growth in

    other months. The preliminary data would have yielded job growth of

    about 17 million between 1996 and 2012. The actual job growth was 16

    million, an error of about 6.5 percent.

    Accuracy goes up considerably during more normal times when job

    growth is positive (about two-thirds of the time). Then, the average error is

    only about one-third as large as the average number of jobs created duringthis period. This still implies that true job growth is missed by 68,000 in

    one direction or the other during the typical positive-job-growth month.

    Trying to deduce anything about the direction of the jobs market by

    referring to such wobbly numbers is essentially guesswork. Indeed, in any

    given month, about 70 percent of what happens to job growth in the

    following year has nothing to do with changes that occurred in that par-

    ticular month. In almost one-fourth of cases, the job growth in any givenmonth does not even move in the same direction as the job change in the

    twelve months that follow. Using even the entire previous quarters job

    growth provides no better signal of where the labor market is headed.

    Employment numbers have value, especially when considered over

    long periods, such as a full year. Jobs day chatter is irresistible but almost

    without content. Monthly jobs numbers are imperfect portraits of the

    recent past and very poor predictors of the labor markets future.Reprinted by permission of the Wall Street Journal. 2013 Dow Jones & Co. All rights reserved.

    New from the Hoover Press is Bankruptcy, NotBailout: A

    Special Chapter 14,edited by Kenneth E. Scott and John

    B. Taylor. To order, call 800.935.2882 or visit www.

    hooverpress.org.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    19/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 318

    THE ECONOMY

    Skip the Short RunWe need to swear off this endless tinkering. By Michael J. Boskin.

    President Obamas most recent prescription for economic growthmore

    government stimulus spending, new social programs, higher taxes onupper-income earners, subsidies for some industries and increased regula-

    tion for all of themis likely to have the same anemic results as in his first

    administration.

    Recall that the $825 billion stimulus program did little economic good,

    at a cost of hundreds of thousands of dollars per job, even based on the

    administrations own inflated job estimates. Cash for Clunkers cost $3

    billion merely to shift car sales forward a few months. The Public-Private

    Investment Program for Legacy Assets (PPIP) to buy toxic assets from the

    banks to speed lending generated just 3 percent of the $1 trillion that the

    program planners anticipated.

    And now? Obama proposes universal preschool ($25 billion per year),

    Fix It First repairs to roads and bridges, plus an infrastructure bank ($50

    billion), Project Rebuild, refurbishing private properties in cities ($15

    billion), endless green-energy subsidies, and a big hike in the minimum

    wage. The president and Senate Democrats also demand that half the

    spending cuts under sequestration be replaced with higher taxes.

    These proposals are ill-considered. The evidence sadly suggests that the

    initial improvement in childrens cognitive skills from Head Start quickly

    MICHAELJ. BOSKINis a senior fellow at the Hoover Institution, a member ofHoovers Shultz-Stephenson Task Force on Energy Policy and Working Group on

    Economic Policy, and the T. M. Friedman Professor of Economics at Stanford

    University.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    20/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 19

    evaporates. Higher minimum wages increase unemployment among low-

    skilled workers. A dozen recent studies in peer-reviewed journals, includ-

    ing one by the presidents former chief economic adviser, Christina Romer,

    document the negative effects of higher taxes on the economy.As for adventures in industrial policy, former Obama economic adviser

    Larry Summers wrote a memo in 2009 about the impending $527 million

    loan guarantee to Solyndra and other recipients of government largess.

    The government is a crappy v.c. [venture capitalist], he wrote. In 2010,

    Harvard economist Edward Glaeser concluded in the New York Timesthat

    infrastructure is poor stimulus because it is impossible to spend quickly

    and wisely. Federal infrastructure spending should be dealt with in regu-lar appropriations.

    Will more spending today stimulate the economy? Standard Keynesian

    models that claim a quick boost from higher government spending show

    the effect quickly turns negative. So the spending needs to be repeated

    over and over, like a drug, to keep this hypothetical positive effect going.

    Japan tried that to little effect, starting in the 1990s. It now has the highest

    debt-to-GDP ratio among the countries of the Organization for Econom-ic Cooperation and Development (OECD)and that debt is a prime

    cause, as well as effect, of Japans enduring stagnation.

    Models that claim a quick boost from government spending show the

    effect quickly turns negative. So the spending needs to be repeated over

    and over, like a drug.

    The United States is heading in this wrong direction. Even if the $110

    billion in annual sequestration cuts were allowed to stand, the Congres-

    sional Budget Office projects that annual federal spending will increase

    by $2.4 trillion to $5.9 trillion in a decade. The higher debt implied by

    this spending will eventually crowd out investment, as holdings of gov-

    ernment debt replace capital in private portfolios. Lower tangible capitalformation means lower real wages in the future.

    Since World War II, OECD countries that stabilized their budgets

    without recession averaged $5 to $6 of actual spending cuts per dollar of

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    21/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 320

    tax increases. Examples include the Netherlands in the mid-1990s and

    Sweden in the mid-2000s. In a paper last year for the Stanford Institute

    for Economic Policy Research, Hoover senior fellows John Cogan and

    John Taylor, along with Volker Wieland and Maik Wolters of FrankfurtsGoethe University, show that a reduction in federal spending over several

    years amounting to 3 percent of GDPbringing noninterest spending

    down to pre-financial-crisis levelswill increase short-term GDP.

    Why? Because expectations of lower future taxes and debt, and there-

    fore higher incomes, increase private spending. The United States reduced

    spending as a share of GDP by 5 percent from the mid-1980s to the mid-

    1990s. Canada reduced its spending as share of GDP by 8 percent in themid-1990s and 2000s. In both cases, the reductions reinforced a period

    of strong growth.

    Illustrationb

    y

    TaylorJones

    for

    the

    HooverDigest.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    22/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 21

    An economically balanced deficit-reduction program today would

    mean $5 of actual, not hypothetical, spending cuts per dollar of tax

    increases. The fiscal-cliff deal reached on January 1 instead was scored at

    $1 of spending cuts for every $40 of tax hikes.Keynesian economists urge a delay on spending cuts on the grounds

    that they will hurt the struggling economy. Yet at just one-quarter of 1

    percent of GDP this year, $43 billion of this years sequester cuts in an

    economy with a GDP of more than $16 trillion is unlikely to be a major

    macroeconomic event.

    Continued delay now leaves a long boom as the only time to control

    spending. There was some success in doing this in the mid-1990s under

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    23/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 322

    President Clinton and a Republican Congress. More commonly the oppo-

    site occurs: a boom brings a surge in tax revenues and politicians are eager

    to spread the spending far and wide.

    Infrastructure is poor stimulus because it is impossible to spend quickly

    and wisely.

    In any case, the demand by Obama and Senate Democrats that any

    dollar of spending cuts in budget agreements (to fund the government for

    the rest of the fiscal year and when the debt limit again approaches) be

    matched by an additional dollar of tax hikes is economically unbalancedin the extreme. Those who are attempting to gradually slow the growth of

    federal spending while minimizing tax hikes have sound economics on

    their side.

    This essay is based on the authors testimony before the U.S. Congress Joint Economic Committee.

    Reprinted by permission of the Wall Street Journal. 2013 Dow Jones & Co. All rights reserved.

    Available from the Hoover Press is Pension Wise:

    Confronting Employer Pension UnderfundingAnd Sparing

    Taxpayers the Next Bailout, by Charles Blahous. To order,

    call 800.935.2882 or visit www.hooverpress.org.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    24/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 23

    THE ECONOMY

    Contrived InequalityA lot of wealthy people deserve their success. Is it asking too much

    of the government to recognize that? Maybe so. By Gary S. Becker.

    The media and many intellectuals criticize the widening inequality in

    countries as different as the United States, China, and Brazil. Yet people

    everywhere generally accept, and usually admire, differences in incomes

    and wealth that they believe result from abilities and hard work, and where

    the work done by the wealthy is considered socially valuable. For example,

    the great wealth of Steve Jobs or Bill Gates is little criticized because of

    their brilliant accomplishments that added a lot to social value. On theother hand, people object when high incomes and wealth are considered

    undeserved. The distinction between deserved and undeserved wealth is

    crucial to acceptance of or hostility to inequality.

    Government policies that favor some people and discriminate against

    others are the biggest source of contrived inequality. For example, much

    of the wealth of Russian oligarchs came from government favors when

    Russia privatized industries after the collapse of communism. Laterthe government consolidated ownership in natural resources and other

    industries, adding to the favoritism. Similar government help propelled

    the Mexican telecommunications giant Carlos Slim to become the

    wealthiest person in the world.

    GARYS. BECKERis the Rose-Marie and Jack R. Anderson Senior Fellow at the

    Hoover Institution and a member of Hoovers Working Group on EconomicPolicy and Shultz-Stephenson Task Force on Energy Policy. He is also the Uni-

    versity Professor of Economics and Sociology at the University of Chicago. He was

    awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1992.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    25/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 324

    Until fairly recently, all countries simply handed telephone ser-

    vices, radio and television channels, and mineral and energy rights to

    politically powerful companies. Economists pointed out that this was

    granting enormous wealth to these companies without getting muchin return. Their writings and other pressures finally forced the United

    States and many other countries (but not all) to auction off such valu-

    able, scarce property. Protected industries also benefit from tariffs on

    goods like sugar and ethanol, and subsidies to oil and other industries.

    These artificially raise the incomes of capital and workers employed in

    those industries.

    The labor market offers other examples. Chinas sharp restrictions onrural migrants obtaining residency in cities has contributed greatly to

    Chinas rapid growth in inequality during the past two decades. Mini-

    mum-wage laws raise the incomes of low-skilled workers who can find

    jobs but lower the incomes of equally productive workers who are priced

    out of a job.

    Steve Jobs and Bill Gates get a pass: though immensely wealthy, theyre

    brilliant and their work has added a lot to social value.

    I could give many other examples of government creation of undeserved

    inequality, but governments are not the only source of such disparities.

    Unions raise the wages of workers in unionized sectors while lowering the

    wages of equally productive workers who are forced out of these sectors

    and into lower-paying jobs elsewhere. At the same time, unions artificiallyreduce inequality by suppressing the earnings of more-productive union

    members, so that the net effect of unions on inequality is not clear. One

    blatant example of unions suppressing earnings of more-productive mem-

    bers is the union opposition to merit pay for good teachers, even though

    good teachers have large positive effects on their students.

    Private monopolies and cartels tend to raise the wealth of businessmen

    and workers who gain from higher prices created by monopolies. Theburden of these higher prices is borne by consumers, other businesses, and

    the workers who must exit monopolized industries because of the cuts in

    output that create the higher prices.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    26/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 25

    Differences in education and other human capital are the cause of

    much of the earnings inequality within rich countries such as the United

    States and Japan. Higher education over the past thirty years has wid-

    ened earnings inequality greatly, sharply increasing the earnings of col-lege graduates and those with even higher skills. Most people do not

    object to higher incomes for skilled workers, but they do object that

    many young men and women with the talent to benefit from higher

    education are prevented from doing so. These students families and

    schools fail to prepare them for college or they lack the family resources

    to pay for a college education.

    Along with everything else, higher education also widens earnings

    inequality.

    The effects on children of broken families and uninterested parents are

    considerable, yet much more can still be done to remedy the inequali-

    ties in college opportunity. Schools attended by poorer children can be

    improved by increasing competition among schools, by paying very goodteachers much more than average teachers, and by getting rid of the bad

    and indifferent teachers. Student loans might be made more effective

    by making the amount to be repaid contingentup to a pointon the

    incomes of those repaying the loans. This would reduce the loan burden

    on those who turn out to earn relatively little.

    The huge earnings and great wealth accumulation of some members

    of the financial sector are often viewed with suspicion because the earn-ings are considered more due to luck than abilities. This suspicion is not

    universal; the billionaire Warren Buffett, the second-wealthiest person in

    America, is much admired even though he made his enormous fortune

    from investments in companies. The vast wealth of some hedge-fund

    managers, on the other hand, is often criticized. Usually overlooked is the

    role of these funds and other investors in arbitraging prices and returns

    in different sectors. Hostility to high earnings in the financial sector hasgreatly increased during the past few years because of the role banks and

    other financial institutions played (along with governments and other cul-

    prits) in the financial crisis that so damaged the world economy.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    27/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 326

    Since Rousseau, many intellectuals have been opposed to inequality per

    se. Most people, however, distinguish deserving from undeserving inequal-

    ity. Clearly, much of the income and wealth inequality in any country

    would be considered deserving because it results from greater abilities anddedication. Governments are expected to reduce obstacles to deserving

    wealth. Unfortunately, they create many of the undeserved sources of

    inequality themselves.

    Reprinted from the Becker-Posner Blog (www.becker-posner-blog.com).

    Available from the Hoover Press is The Taylor Rule and

    the Transformation of Monetary Policy,edited by Evan F.

    Koenig, Robert Leeson, and George A. Kahn.

    To order,

    call 800.935.2882 or visit www.hooverpress.org.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    28/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 27

    THE ECONOMY

    We Need to CutSpending. Heres HowThe careful budget that Paul Ryan and others in the House have

    proposed would ease the economy into a better place. By John F.Coganand John B. Taylor.

    In March the House of Representatives approved its Budget Committee

    plan, which would bring federal finances into balance by 2023. The plan

    would do so by gradually slowing the growth in federal spending without

    raising taxes. Still, the plan was denounced by naysayers who asserted thatit would harm the economic recovery and that any spending reductions

    should be put off until later. This thinking is just as wrong now as it was

    in the 1970s.

    According to our research, the spending restraint and balanced-budget

    parts of the House Budget Committee plan would boost the economy

    immediately. With the Budget Committees proposed tax reform includ-

    ed, the immediate impact would be even larger. The entire plan wouldraise gross domestic product by 1 percentage point in 2014, equivalent

    JOHNF. COGANis the Leonard and Shirley Ely Senior Fellow at the Hoover

    Institution and a member of Hoovers Shultz-Stephenson Task Force on En-

    ergy Policy, Working Group on Health Care Policy, and Working Group on

    Economic Policy.JOHNB. TAYLORis the George P. Shultz Senior Fellow in

    Economics at the Hoover Institution, the chairman of Hoovers Working Groupon Economic Policy and a member of Hoovers Shultz-Stephenson Task Force

    on Energy Policy, and the Mary and Robert Raymond Professor of Economics

    at Stanford University.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    29/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 328

    to about a $1,500 increase for each U.S. household. Ten years from now,

    at the end of the official budget horizon, we estimate that the entire plan

    would raise GDP by 3 percentage points, or more than $4,000 for each

    U.S. household.Our assessment is based on a modern macroeconomic model (devel-

    oped with Volker Wieland of the University of Frankfurt and Maik

    Wolters of the University of Kiel) whose features include the recog-

    nition that the resources to finance government expenditures arent

    freethey withdraw resources from the private economy. The model

    provides for other essential attributes of the economythat consum-

    ers, businesses, and workers respond to incentives, and they are influ-enced by their expectation of future economic conditions when mak-

    ing decisions today. None of these features is provided for in old-style

    Keynesian models.

    The budget plan would raise gross domestic product by 1 percentage

    point in 2014, equivalent to a $1,500 increase for each U.S. household.

    The House budget plan would keep total federal outlays at their

    current level for two years. Thereafter, spending would rise each year,

    but more slowly than if present policies continue. By 2023, federal

    expenditures would decline to 19.1 percent of GDP from 22.2 percent

    today.

    Since the Congressional Budget Office projects that revenues will

    equal 19.1 percent of GDP in 2023, the House plan would balance thebudget that year. Also by 2023, the publicly held federal debt relative

    to GDP would decline to 55 percent from its current high level of 76

    percent.

    The House budget is hardly austere: the federal spending claim on

    GDP would still be considerably higher than it was in fiscal 2000 (18.2

    percent) and only slightly below its claim on GDP in 2007 (19.7 percent).

    The reductions in the growth rate of spending would be achieved pri-marily through entitlement reforms. The Affordable Care Act would be

    repealed. Medicaid and food-stamp administration would be turned over

    to the states. Medicare would be fundamentally reformed. Anti-fraud mea- Illustrationb

    yTaylorJones

    forthe

    HooverDigest.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    30/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 29

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    31/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 330

    sures would be applied to federal disability programs. Among the major

    entitlement programs, only Social Security would remain unchanged; this

    is a deficiency in the plan. As for discretionary spending, the House bud-

    get plan would provide for only slight reductions from the levels that areset by the budget sequester.

    The long-run economic gains from restraining government spending

    would not, despite what critics claim, harm the economy in the short run.

    Instead, the economy would start to grow right away. Why?

    First, the lower level of future government spending avoids the

    necessity of sharply raising taxes. The expectation that tax rates wont

    need to rise provides incentives for higher investment and employ-ment today.

    Second, since the expectation of lower future taxes has the effect of

    raising peoples estimation of future disposable income, consumption

    increases today. This change comes thanks to Milton Friedmans famous

    permanent income hypothesis that the behavior of consumers reflects

    what they expect to earn over a long period. According to our macro-

    economic model, the higher level of consumption induced by the Housebudgets effect on consumer expectations is large enough to offset the

    reduced growth of government spending.

    Third, the new budgets reduction in the growth of government spend-

    ing is gradual. That allows private businesses to adjust efficiently without

    disruptions.

    The expectation that tax rates will stay put provides incentives for higher

    investment and employment today.

    Our macroeconomic model probably underestimates the positive

    impact of the House budget plan. The model doesnt account for the

    greater economic certainty that results from preventing the national debt

    from soaring to dangerously high levels and from stabilizing the federal

    tax burden. Nor does the model account for beneficial changes in mon-etary policy that could accompany enactment of the budget plan. Lower

    deficits and national debt would reduce pressure on the Federal Reserve to

    continue buying long-term Treasury bonds.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    32/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 31

    The U.S. economy has been experiencing its slowest recovery from a

    deep recession in modern history. Tragically, fewer people are working

    as a percentage of the working-age population than when the recovery

    beganand economic growth was only 1.6 percent last year. The largefederal budget deficitsby increasing uncertainty and delaying private

    spendingare an important cause of this lackluster economic perfor-

    mance.

    For too long, policy makers have been misguided by models that lend

    support to bigger government or to the politically convenient objective of

    delaying any reduction in spending. It is better to recognize the flaws in

    this approach and get on with the sensible budget reforms the country sosorely needs.

    Reprinted by permission of the Wall Street Journal. 2013 Dow Jones & Co. All rights reserved.

    New from the Hoover Press is Government Policies

    and the Delayed Economic Recovery, edited by Lee E.

    Ohanian, John B. Taylor, and Ian J. Wright. To order, call

    800.935.2882 or visit www.hooverpress.org.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    33/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 332

    TAXAT ION

    AlternativeMaximum TaxLets settle on a top number for everybody. By John H. Cochrane.

    They keep coming back, like the villains in a good zombie movie, chant-

    ing more taxes, more taxes. Long ago, Congress passed the alternative

    minimum tax, or AMTa simple flat rate to ensure that in an insanely

    complex tax code, no one escapes paying something. Now we need an

    alternative maximumtax as a simple, rough-and-ready way to limit the tax

    zombies economic damage. Call it the AMaxT.Lets start a national conversation: how much is the most anyone should

    have to pay? When do taxes indisputably start to harm the economy and

    produce less revenuewhen government takes 50 percent of peoples

    income? 60 percent? 70 percent?

    I like half, but the principle matters more than the number. Once the

    country settles on a number, each of us gets to add up everything we pay

    to government at every level: federal income taxes, yes, but also payroll(Social Security, Medicare, etc.) taxes; state, city, and county taxes; estate

    taxes; property taxes; sales taxes; payroll taxes and unemployment insur-

    ance for nannies, household workers, or other employees; excise taxes;

    real-estate transfer taxes; and so on and on, right down to your vehicle

    stickers and those annoying extra taxes on your airline tickets.

    JOHNH. COCHRANEis a senior fellow at the Hoover Institution and the AQR

    Capital Management Distinguished Service Professor of Finance at the University

    of Chicagos Booth School of Business.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    34/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 33

    On April 15, once this total hits the alternative maximum tax, youve

    done your bit and federal income taxes can take no more.

    The zombies howl that the top federal tax bracket is still only 40

    percent. Surely the rich can contribute a bit more? They forget that theeconomic damage of taxes comes from the total tax bite, not just the fed-

    eral income tax.

    When do taxes indisputably start to harm the economy and produce less

    revenuewhen government takes 50% of peoples income? 60%? 70%?

    Marginal taxes are a purer measure of economic damage. If youearn one more dollar, how much do you get to keep? Marginal rates

    are higher than average rates in a progressive system: if the govern-

    ment takes 100 percent of income above $100,000, then somebody

    earning $150,000 pays a 33 percent average tax rate but has no incen-

    tive to work at all after he reaches $100,000. Ideally, we would limit

    marginal rates, but this is not practical in a simple backstop like the

    AMaxT.American governments also like to hide taxing and spending by passing

    mandates and regulations, forcing people and businesses to spend on their

    behalf. Ideally, we would limit this economic damage as well, but this is

    also not practical in an alternative maximum tax.

    However, both considerations mean that the true economic damage

    will be higher than the AMaxT rate, so we should leave some headroom

    in setting that rate.Every cent of corporate taxes comes out of some persons pocket, in

    higher prices, lower wages, or lower returns to investors. For example,

    even the tax zombies dont dream that we stick it to the big oil compa-

    nies by charging gas taxes. To limit this damage, every single cent of tax

    that government assesses, at all levels, should be assigned to somebody

    and count against that persons alternative maximum tax. It is easiest to

    assign all corporate taxes to shareholders. When corporations send you theannual 1099 dividend form, they also report all taxes paid by your shares,

    which count against your AMaxT. Some taxes could similarly be assigned

    to workers and reported on W-2 forms.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    35/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 334

    Yes, there are details to work out. People get big tax bills in some years,

    such as when they pay estate taxes. Incomes fluctuate. Smart tax lawyers

    could game the system.

    This isnt hard to fix. For example, we could use an average of severalyears income or, better yet, scale the AMaxT limit to consumption rather

    than income.

    Liberals might object to a maximum tax. In setting the maximum level

    of taxation, shouldnt we consider the nice roads, free schooling, police,

    national defense, thoughtful regulation, and other benefits and services?

    This is a valid consideration if one argues about whats fair. But I

    propose the AMaxT entirely to limit the economic damage of taxation, agoal you must consider even if you think its fair to take every cent of a

    rich persons income.

    To limit economic damage, benefits are irrelevant. Suppose that the

    government levies a 100 percent income tax, but it is so good at providing

    services that each of us gets back twice the value of what we put in. Good

    deal? Yes. Functioning economy? No. Each person gets services whether

    they do or dont pay taxes. But with a 100 percent income tax, nobodyworks, nobody pays any taxes, and nobody actually gets any services.

    How many people are really being taxed at outrageous rates? I dont

    know. The U.S. tax system is so complex, with so many layers of taxing

    authority, that nobody really knows. Still, an alternative maximum tax is

    a win-win bet.

    The disincentive effects of heavy taxation settle in gradually.

    If there really are few people who pay an extraordinarily high percent-

    age of their income, then liberals shouldnt object. They wont lose any

    revenue and will enjoy snickering I told you so. If it turns out that there

    are lots of people being so taxed, then we will sharply reduce the unin-

    tended, multiplicative effect of taxation, and we will measure that fact. A

    canary in the coal mine is as valuable chirping as choking.The disincentive effects of heavy taxation settle in gradually. For the

    first year or two, all people can do is hire smarter lawyers and work a little

    less hard. It takes years for businesses to retrench, close, never get started,

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    36/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 35

    or fail to expand; for people and companies to move abroad; for students

    to give up investing in an expensive MBA or medical school or engineer-

    ing degree; for people to stay put rather than follow lucrative opportuni-

    ties; or to retire early. All this shows up slowly and gradually drags downan economy and its tax revenues.

    So the AMaxT is most important for the backstop promise it makes to

    young people and entrepreneurs. Yes, start a company, go to school, work

    hard, invest, hire people. We guarantee you that no matter what happens,

    no matter how loud the zombies chant, no matter what clever revenue

    enhancers they come up with, you will get to keep some reasonable frac-

    tion of what you earn. Go for it.Reprinted by permission of the Wall Street Journal. 2013 Dow Jones & Co. All rights reserved.

    Available from the Hoover Press is The Flat Tax,

    updated and revised edition, by Robert E. Hall and Alvin

    Rabushka. To order, call 800.935.2882 or visit www.

    hooverpress.org.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    37/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 336

    POLIT ICS

    The Missing ModeratesPlenty of moderates still existbut theyre forced to choose between

    a couple of political parties that rarely serve them well. By Morris P.

    Fiorina.

    In 2000 the Republicans won the electoral Triple Crown, capturing the

    presidency (despite losing the popular vote), the House of Representa-

    tives, and the Senate (with Vice President Dick Cheney as tie-breaker)

    for the first time since the election of Dwight Eisenhower forty-eight

    years earlier. In 2002 they increased their congressional majorities,

    an unusual feat in an off-year election, and in 2004 voters re-electedPresident George W. Bush and added slightly to Republican congres-

    sional majorities. The six years of unified party control produced by

    these three elections was the longest period of unified government the

    United States had experienced since the Kennedy-Johnson administra-

    tions in the 1960s.

    Political scientists refer to U.S. electoral history in the second half of

    the twentieth century as the era of divided government. Between the1952 and 2000 elections Republicans held the presidency for twenty-

    eight years, but Democrats organized the Senate for thirty-six years and

    Democratic majorities ran the House for forty-two years. The result was a

    long period when divided party control generally prevailed. In only eight

    years (195254, 197680, 199294) did one party control the presidency

    and both chambers of Congress. (Divided control also characterized elec-

    tions in the states during this period.)

    MORRISP. FIORINAis a senior fellow at the Hoover Institution and the Wendt

    Family Professor of Political Science at Stanford University.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    38/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 37

    The apparent break with previous history in the early 2000s was the

    stuff of Republican dreams and Democratic nightmares. Had Karl Rove

    succeeded in his announced goal of creating a long-term Republican

    majority? For Rove the real prize, as Nicholas Lemann wrote in the NewYorkerin 2003, would be a Republican majority that would be as solid as,

    say, the Democratic coalition that Franklin Roosevelt createda majority

    that would last for a generation.

    Such ambition soon faded, as the presidents approval ratings plunged

    in the wake of Hurricane Katrina, the misbegotten nomination of Har-

    riet Miers to the Supreme Court, the Dubai ports debacle, Social Secu-

    rity private accounts, and the war in Iraq. In 2006, the new Republicanmajority suffered a thumpin, in President Bushs words, losing thirty

    seats in the House and six in the Senate, ceding control of both cham-

    bers of Congress to the Democrats. Divided government returned.

    In 2008 the Republicans experienced another thumpin : Barack

    Obama won a decisive victory over John McCain, and the Democrats

    enlarged their congressional majorities. For a short period afterward

    speculation that 2008 was a transformative election ran rampant. Inearly 2009 James Carville published a book titled 40 More Years: How the

    Democrats Will Rule the Next Generation. But in 2010 the Democrats suf-

    fered a shellacking, as President Obama put it, losing sixty-three seats in

    the House (the largest midterm loss since 1938), six Senate seats, six state

    houses, and nearly seven hundred state legislative seats. (Carvilles book,

    incidentally, was discounted by 60 percent on Amazon.com.)

    Clearly, generations are not what they used to be. Since that brief peri-od of unified Republican government in the early 2000s the country has

    entered a period of almost unprecedented electoral instability.

    How common or unusual is this period? It turns out that the country

    had seen nothing like it since the nineteenth century, when the five elec-

    tions of the 188694 period produced five distinct patterns of institu-

    tional control. Had the Republicans captured the Senate in 2012, or had

    control of the two chambers of Congress flipped, or had Mitt Romneybeen elected with Republicans in control of either chamber, the elections

    of 200612 would have tied the historical record for majority instability.

    As it stands, the current period holds second place in American history.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    39/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 338

    It is important to recognize that this pattern of unstable institutional

    control stands in contrast to the macro-stability of the American elector-

    ate. That is, control of our institutions is not vacillating between the par-

    ties because voters are manic, dramatically changing their party preferenc-es from one election to the next. Nor are they flighty and uncommitted,

    voting on a whim now for Democrats then for Republicans. Despite some

    gradual demographic shifts, the characteristics of the American electorate

    have changed little in the past generation; the way the parties represent

    them, on the other hand, has changed a great deal.

    THE AMERICAN VOTER, THEN AND NOWFor some sixty years political scientists have been asking Americans, Gen-

    erally speaking, do you think of yourself as a Republican, a Democrat, an

    independent, or what? The Democrats lost their national majority dur-

    ing the tumult of the 1960s, and at the same time more came to identify

    as independents. But since the Reagan years, partisanship has been gener-

    ally stable, with 3540 percent of the population adopting the indepen-

    dent label, a slightly lower proportion the Democratic label, and abouta quarter of the electorate the Republican label. Three decades of data

    undermine pundits claims that the country is half Republican red and

    half Democratic blue.

    Voters arent manically changing their party preferences from one

    election to the next.

    Sociologists have been querying Americans about ideology for almost as

    long, asking people to classify themselves on a scale ranging from extreme-

    ly liberal to extremely conservative. There have been no dramatic shifts for

    more than a generation. The liberal label traditionally carries less popular

    support than the conservative one; only about a quarter of the electorate

    adopts it. Moderate is usually the plurality choice, with conservative trail-

    ing by a bit. There is no indication in the data that the middle is waningand the extremes waxing. The picture is one of stability.

    Pundits often combine conservatives and moderates and pronounce

    the United States to be a center-right nation. Its probably an accurate

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    40/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 39

    characterization relative to other advanced democracies, but there are two

    problems with this interpretation.

    First, there is no logical reason why moderates should always coalesce

    with conservatives to form a three-fourths majority. If conservatives movefar enough to the right, moderates could find themselves closer to liberals

    and coalesce with them to form a two-thirds center-left majority.

    Second, as an empirical matter, ordinary Americans do not use these

    abstract terms in the same way partisan intellectuals do. Self-classified lib-

    erals tend to have liberal views on specific policy issues, but self-classi-

    fied conservatives are much more heterogeneous; many, even majorities,

    express liberal views on specific issues, such as abortion rights, gun con-trol, and drug-law reform.

    Perhaps, then, voters have changed on a few touchstone issues that

    make all the difference for todays elections. Here the data are more frag-

    mentaryspecific-issues questions come and go on surveys. But the Pew

    Research Center has conducted surveys on forty-two attitude, value, and

    policy subjects since the late Reagan years. Its 2012 report concludes:

    The way that the public thinks about poverty, opportunity, business,

    unions, religion, civic duty, foreign affairs, and many other subjects is,

    to a large extent, the same today as in 1987. The values that unified

    Americans twenty-five years ago remain areas of consensus today, while

    the values that evenly divide the nation remain split. On most of the

    questions asked in both 1987 and 2012, the number agreeing is within 5

    percentage points of the number who agreed twenty-five years ago. And

    on almost none has the basic balance of opinion tipped from agree to

    disagree or vice versa.

    In sum, an examination of popular attitudes toward particular subjects

    yields the same conclusion as an examination of partisanship and general

    ideology. In the aggregate the American electorate has changed little in the

    past generation.

    Political independents and ideological moderates in the American elec-torate have not declined in numbers, let alone disappeared. Indeed, their

    numbers continue to exceed those of partisans and ideologues on either

    side. How then, do we explain the indisputable fact that politics in Wash-

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    41/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 340

    ington and in many state capitols is more bitter, contentious, and polar-

    ized than a generation ago?

    A large part of the answer is that those most active in politicsthe

    political class, including convention delegates, donors, and campaign activ-istshave indeed become more polarized since the 1970s. And the partisan

    media and many of the myriad groups devoted to a single cause did not even

    exist a generation ago. As a general observation, the higher up the scale of

    political activity one goes, the more common extreme views become and the

    more intensely they are held; there are few raging moderates or knee-jerk

    independents at the higher levels of politics. Although relatively few, those Illustrationb

    y

    TaylorJones

    for

    the

    HooverDigest.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    42/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 41

    in the political class structure politics. Ordinary voters can only react to the

    alternatives they are offered, and often they must choose between two polar-

    ized alternatives even if they prefer a more moderate choice. Or, of course,

    they can choose simply not to vote. The much-discussed decline in electoralturnout between 1960 and 1996 was concentrated among independents

    and moderates. Strong partisans did not drop off, suggesting they found the

    choices more palatable than did those in the middle.

    A second major explanation for todays polarization lies at the root of

    a great deal of mistaken commentary about American politics: while the

    middle of the American electorate remains as large as ever, it no longer has

    a home in either party. As we have seen, the distributions of partisanshipand ideology have not changed shape for a generation, but the relation-

    ship between the distributions has changed since the 1980s.

    Political scientists refer to this development as a process ofparty sorting. To

    explain, consider a hypotheti-

    cal electorate in which Demo-

    crats are a left-of-center party

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    43/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 342

    with a right wing, while Republicans are a right-of-center party with a left

    wing. Assume that over time demographic changes and electoral strategies

    move the parties toward their respective poles. The numbers of Democrats,

    independents, and Republicans have not changed. Nor have the numbers ofliberals, moderates, and conservatives. But the parties have sorted: liberals

    and conservatives are increasingly aligned with the correct party.

    Something like this has also happened in the American electorate. Since

    the mid-twentieth century, demographic changes such as the migration of

    African-Americans to the north, the rise of the Sunbelt, and immigration,

    coupled with electoral strategies described in books with titles like The Emerg-

    ing Republican (Democratic) Majority, have produced political parties that aremore homogeneous than they were a generation ago. And the most active and

    involved members come from the most extreme reaches of each party.

    In consequence, the dynamics of American politics are increasingly driven

    by small and highly unrepresentative slices of the population. Consider the

    Republican presidential primary contest in 2012. On February 7 the media

    declared Rick Santorum a legitimate contender for the nomination on the

    basis of three victories: the Minnesota caucuses, in which one of every onehundred eligible voters participated, the Colorado caucus, in which two of

    every one hundred eligible participated, and the Missouri beauty contest

    primary in which seven of every one hundred eligible participated.

    American voters have changed little in the past generation. But the way

    the parties represent them has changed a great deal.

    Of course, primary electorates have always been small and unrepre-

    sentative, but primaries were not as common a generation ago, and the

    participants were unrepresentative in different waysthe Democratic pri-

    mary electorate in Massachusetts was very different from that in Missis-

    sippi. Today primary electorates are more homogeneous across the coun-

    try. Democrats appeal to public employees, environmentalists, and liberal

    cause groups, while Republicans rely on business and taxpayer groupsalong with conservative cause groups.

    Thus, while the electorate at large has changed little during the course

    of the past generation, there is a closer connection between partisanship

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    44/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 43

    on the one hand and issues and ideology on the other, resulting in the

    kind of partisan warfare common today. Still, it is important to recognize

    that the process of party sorting weakens rapidly as one moves beyond the

    political class to the larger electorate. There is still considerable commonground in the electoratebut it is difficult in todays political configura-

    tion for anyone in either major party to appeal to it. To take a striking

    example, consider abortion.

    While the middle of the electorate remains as large as ever, it no longer

    has a home in either party.

    The activists who attended the Republican presidential nominating

    convention in 2012 adopted an abortion plank in the party platform that

    essentially said no abortions, no exceptions. Their counterparts at the

    Democratic convention adopted a platform that essentially said abortion

    at any time, no restrictions, regardless of ability to pay. Now compare those

    extreme positions with those held not just by partisans in the electorate, but

    by those who characterize their partisanship as strong (strong Democratsare about a fifth of the population, strong Republicans about a seventh).

    For thirty years the American National Election Studies project has

    included an item that offers citizens multiple positions on abortion, not

    just the simplistic pro-choice/pro-life choices offered by some polls. The

    2012 data are not yet available, but there has been little variation over time

    in the response patterns. In 2008, 11 percent of the strong Democrats

    queried said abortion should never be permitted, and 26 percent that itshould be permitted only in case of rape, incest, or a threat to the womans

    life. So, more than a third of strong Democrats were closer to Mitt Rom-

    neys position on abortion than to that of their own party. Perhaps even

    more surprising, 22 percent of strong Republicans said abortion should

    always be available as a matter of personal choice, and an additional 16

    percent in case of a clear need. So, more than a third of strong Republicans

    were closer to the Democratic position than to that of their own party.Turning to those partisans who label themselves not so strong, we find

    that more than 40 percent of Democrats and more than half of Republi-

    cans are at odds with their partys platform. Similar results hold for other

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    45/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 344

    so-called hot button issues, like gun control. Setting aside independents,

    even partisans in the electorate are out of step with many of the positions

    held by their purported leaders.

    ON TO 2012

    Barack Obama won a handsome victory in 2008. Historically speaking,

    Americans do not replace presidential parties in landslidesFDR in 1932

    is the exception, not the rule. Obamas 7.2-percentage-point margin in the

    popular vote was the fifth largest in fourteen elections in American history in

    which one party turned out the otherjust after Ronald Reagans 9.7-point

    margin in 1980. In addition, the Democrats scrambled the red-blue map, flip-ping nine states, three each in the Southwest, Midwest, and South Atlantic. In

    the aftermath of the election many Democrats believed they had a mandate to

    move the country sharply in what they term a progressive direction.

    The American people do not give mandates. They hire parties pro-

    visionally and grant them a probationary period to prove their worth.

    A major electoral victory by the out party generally says no more than

    for heavens sake, do something different! Such was the case in 2008.From their post-9/11 heights President Bushs approval ratings steadily

    declined to dismal Truman and Nixon levels. Americans first registered

    their displeasure with the administration in 2006 and emphatically made

    the point in 2008. Obamamania was icing on the Democratic cake.

    In the aftermath of the election the Democrats overreached: the Obama

    administration governed in a way that caused the defection of marginal

    members of its majority. Loosely speaking, Democrats build their coali-tions from the left, Republicans from the right. Each must add to their

    base enough of the center to win. After winning, however, activists pres-

    sure their leaders to govern from the left or right, possibly reinforcing

    what the leaders would like to do anyway, which risks alienating those at

    the center. After a narrow victory in 2004 George W. Bush proclaimed

    that he had earned political capital and intended to spend it. Many voters,

    however, were unaware that they had voted for a Freedom Agenda orfor Social Security private accounts. In his 2010 memoir Bush expressed

    sober second thoughts: On Social Security, I may have misread the elec-

    toral mandate. Such misreading contributed to the 2006 thumpin.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    46/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 45

    Similarly, according to Gallup data, when Obama was elected about 45

    percent of the country thought they had elected a moderate and similar

    numbers a liberal (nearly 10 percent thought they had elected a conserva-

    tive). Nine months later, 55 percent felt they had elected a liberal and only35 percent a moderate, and voters remorse began to set in. Obamas approv-

    al ratings among independents were underwater by late summer 2009, pre-

    saging the massive swing against the Democrats more than a year later.

    The American people dont give mandates. They hire parties provisionally

    and grant them a probationary period to prove their worth.

    The subject of independents engenders much confusion among politi-

    cal commentators. Some advocates of a more centrist politics treat inde-

    pendents as an undifferentiated mass of centrist voters. They are not.

    Independents are a heterogeneous lot. While some are moderates, others

    are largely uninformed about the issues. Many independents are cross-

    pressured, attracted to one party on some issue or set of issues and to the

    other on different issues. Still others dislike both parties. The label sub-sumes many different types of voters.

    At the same time some political scientists have asserted that the lions

    share of independents are nothing of the sort; they are rather closet par-

    tisans who like the independent label but are actually no different from

    the not so strong partisans. There is remarkably little evidence for this

    contention. The entire subject cries out for more detailed examination in

    an era when as many as 40 percent of Americans take the independentoption when queried in national surveys. Whatever they are, indepen-

    dents have provided much of the volatility present in recent elections,

    swinging 18 points against the Republicans in 2006 (compared to 2002)

    and 17 points against the Democrats in 2010 (compared to 2006).

    Health care reform was a large part of the explanation for the Demo-

    cratic slide between 2008 and 2010. To this day the law has never achieved

    majority support in the polls, and Democrats singular focus on passingit at a time when voters considered the economy and jobs much higher

    priorities contributed to the perception that the administration was driven

    by its own ideological commitments rather than the problems facing the

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    47/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 346

    citizenry. The result was the great shellacking of 2010. While the recession

    played a major role, Democratic losses were much larger than predicted by

    economic forecasting models. Several colleagues and I calculated that the

    Democrats might have barely held their House majority were it not forthe vote on the health care bill. In particular, it was the difference between

    victory and defeat for Democratic representatives whose districts voted for

    McCain or only narrowly for Obama in 2008.

    After the 2010 elections Republican expectations for 2012 skyrocketed.

    The House majority looked safe, Democrats were defending two-thirds

    of the Senate seats to be filled in 2012, and by all indications Obama was

    highly vulnerable. But the comedic Republican nominating process illus-trated the problem with a political process driven by party fringes. The

    Massachusetts moderate Mitt Romney was never comfortable playing the

    role of a severe conservative; poor nominees threw away almost certain

    Senate pickups in Missouri and Indiana (after arguably doing the same in

    Colorado, Delaware, and Nevada in 2010), and the election results basi-

    cally reaffirmed the status quo, a great relief for the Democrats and a bitter

    disappointment for the Republicans.

    MISREADING THE RESULTS

    Various interpretations of what it all meant are piling up. The imme-

    diate post-election narrative held that an old, white Republican Party

    had been overwhelmed by an electorate newly dominated by minorities,

    young people, single women, and well-educated professionals of a decid-

    edly more liberal bent. There is an element of truth to this interpreta-tion, but it lets the Republicans off too easily. The facts paint a more

    complicated picture.

    Obama won about 51.9 percent of the two-party vote in 2012, a bit

    better than George W. Bushs 51.2 percent in 2004, but down more than 3

    percent from his 2008 margin. Republicans assumed that the excitement

    surrounding the Obama candidacy in 2008 had produced an electorate

    unusually young, non-white, and liberal, and that with Obamamania onlya distant memory the 2012 electorate would look more like the 2004

    electorate. But the Obama campaigns efficient turnout operation made

    the 2012 electorate look like the 2008 electorate; indeed, even more so.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    48/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 47

    Young people participated at about the same rate in 2012 as in 2008, and

    minorities increased their participation. Although Romney won a higher

    proportion of the white vote than any Republican since 1988, rather than

    the 75 percent white electorate of 2004, the electorate in 2012 was only72 percent white. But the conclusion that Republicans were only victims

    of a changing electorate weakens when we look at the 2012 electorate in

    terms of numbers of voters rather than their percentages.

    Three decades of data undermine pundits claims that the country is half

    Republican red and half Democratic blue.

    According to the exit polls, African-Americans marginally increased their

    participation in 2012by about 300,000, as did Asians and other small

    groups by about 400,000, and Latinos registered a big increase, about 1.7

    million. These increases clearly contributed to the Obama victory. But pre-

    liminary analyses suggest that Obama would have won comfortably even

    without any increase in the Hispanic vote or the large majorities Democrats

    ran up in this demographic. Despite an increase of about 6 million in theeligible voter population, almost 2.5 million fewer votes were cast in 2012

    compared to 2008. Given that minorities cast nearly 2.5 million more votes,

    the implication is that almost 5 million fewer whites voted in 2012. (Turn-

    out figures are from data compilations by Michael McDonald, the United

    States Elections Project, George Mason University.)

    We do not yet know in detail where and why white turnout declined.

    Some of it is no doubt due to non-political factors, such as the disruptionscaused by Hurricane Sandy on the East Coast, but it seems likely that the

    Republicans underperformed even among their targeted demographic. So

    while a re-examination of the partys position on immigration (or at least

    the rhetoric that accompanies it) is certainly advisable, it should not dis-

    tract from the larger problem suggested by the partys weaker performance

    in the larger white electorate.

    Again, definitive studies remain to be conducted, but a number ofpossibilities merit investigation. My impression is that the Republi-

    can embrace of social conservatism has become counterproductive at

    the national level. It enabled the party to win control of Congress in

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    49/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 348

    the 1990s after forty years in the minority, but the views espoused by

    Republican candidates chosen in unrepresentative primaries dominated

    by social conservatives are toxic to many in the younger generation, as

    well as to moderate middle-class Americans who reside in cities and sub-urbs outside the South. Even if they believe that entitlements must be

    restructured, regulatory hurdles lowered, and the tax system reformed,

    they are reluctant to vote for a party whose candidates make statements

    about rape and evolution that strike them as outrageous. I live among

    thousands of affluent, educated professionals who regularly vote for

    Democrats who will raise their taxes. I doubt that altruism is the expla-

    nation. Rather, their alternative is to vote for candidates of a party theysee as more interested in outlawing abortion, stigmatizing homosexuals,

    and logging the redwoods.

    Whether the Republicans can or will reposition themselves on issues

    like immigration, abortion, and gay rights remains to be seen. But

    whether they do or not, the status quo affirmed by the 2012 elections

    seems likely to persist for four more years. Given a Democratic presi-

    dent, the Republican House majority looks safe in the 2014 midtermelections (barring some incredible new manifestation of political mal-

    practice). And once again, the Democrats will be defending the large

    majority of Senate seats up in 2014, giving Republicans still another

    chance to make Senate gains. Events in the real world may force changes

    that will surprise us, but there is little in the internal dynamics of the

    current political situation to make the next four years much different

    from the past four.

    A SECOND ERA OF INDECIS ION

    I wrote above that the elections of 200410 had produced a period of

    almost unprecedented electoral instability. The reason for the modifier

    almost was the even more unstable period of 188694, a period embed-

    ded in what political historians refer to as the era of indecision, which

    extended from the 1874 election that ended the Civil War Republicanmajority, to the 1896 election, when the McKinley Republicans ended the

    long standoff and began an extended period of Republican control that

    lasted until 1912.

  • 7/28/2019 Hoover Digest, 2013, No. 3, Summer

    50/200

    Hoover Digest 2013 No. 3 49

    The nineteenth-century era of indecision has also been called the Gild-

    ed Age. It was a time when robber barons built great fortunes, legitimate

    and otherwise. Great disparities in wealth opened up between the owners

    and investors in the new industrial economy and those who labored intheir enterprises. Today, economic inequality is back atop the political

    agenda for the first time since the New Deal.

    Independents are a heterogeneous lot.

    Social and economic changes in such times create new social and eco-

    nomic problems. They disrupt old coalitions and suggest new possibilitiesto ambitious political entrepreneurs. When changes are major, rapid, and

    cumulative, as they were before and now are again, their effect