global inequality and poverty: distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource...

51
Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University of Sussex Oxford Institute for Energy Studies

Post on 21-Dec-2015

216 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and

the case of natural resource ownership

Paul Segal

Department of Economics, University of SussexOxford Institute for Energy Studies

Page 2: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 2

Four concepts of global inequalityConcept Unit Metric Uses

Zero Country Total GDP GeopoliticsTrade volumes

One Country Per capita GDP Growth and convergence

Two Individual Per capita GDP of country

“Between-country global inequality”

Three Individual Individual income (per capita household income)

Global welfare/well-being/social justice

Page 3: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 3

Source: Anand and Segal (2008)

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 20000.60

0.62

0.64

0.66

0.68

0.70

0.72Global inequality (concept 3), various estimates

Bhalla (2002) (Income) Bhalla (2002) (Consumption)Bourguignon and Morrisson (2002) Chotikapanich, Valenzuela and Rao (1997)Dikhanov and Ward (2002) Dowrick and Akmal (2005) (GK)Dowrick and Akmal (2005) (Afriat) Milanovic (2002)Milanovic (2005) Sala-i-Martin (2006)

Page 4: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 4

• Most estimates are based on GDP per capita from National Accounts.

• This is a very poor proxy for individual incomes: conceptual and empirical problems.

• Milanovic consistently uses household survey data: directly measures the variable we want.

Page 5: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 5

Source: Milanovic (2011)

Page 6: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 6

Between-country inequality

• For the decomposable measure Theil L (MLD), the between-country component (concept 2) is larger than the within-country component: between 65% and 75%.

• Between-country inequality has declined due to China.

• NB. Once China passes global average, further rapid growth will increase inequality!

Page 7: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 7

Source: Milanovic (2011)

Page 8: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 8

• Within-country inequality has been growing: most people live in countries where inequality has risen.

• This explains why there is no clear trend in global inequality (concept 3).

• Even though between-country is larger, within-country inequality is also important:If between-country inequality were eliminated, global Gini would still be at least population- or GDP-weighted average Gini across countries.

This is close to a Gini of 40.

Within-country inequality

Page 9: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 9

Global poverty

• World Bank (Chen and Ravallion) poverty line: PPP$1.25/day. This is the mean of national lines of the poorest 15 countries.

Page 10: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 10

Global poverty at PPP$1.25/day, %

Source: Chen and Ravallion (2008)

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 20050

10

20

30

40

50

60

Developing countries

Ex China

Page 11: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 11

Inequality within countries and global poverty

Most economists argue that growth is the solution to poverty.Kraay (2006): “sustained poverty reduction is impossible without sustained growth.” Growth is certainly important. But:

1. Growth can be difficult – an “elusive quest” (e.g. Easterly 2001, Collier 2007).

2. Growth is not sufficient for poverty reduction.E.g India 1981-2005: per capita GDP grew by 135 percent; people below $1 a day rose from 421 to 456 million.

We will see that plausible redistribution within countries can massively reduce global poverty.

Page 12: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 12

Poverty and redistribution

• Rich countries use redistribution as a powerful poverty reduction tool.– Cash benefits excluding pensions in the EU15 countries

comprised 6.6 percent of GDP.• At national poverty lines, 16% of the population of the

EU15 were living in poverty in 2003.• Without social payments other than pensions it would have

been 25%; also taking out pensions, it would have been 39%.

Inequality represents a wasted opportunity for poverty reduction. Redistribution addresses that.

Page 13: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 13

Redistribution à la Ravallion (2010)

• Rich country donors may argue that the rich in poor countries should be paying for poverty reduction.

• Ravallion asks which countries can afford to address their own poverty through redistribution, using taxes that are:1. only on those not poor by rich country standards;2. ‘not too high’ in terms of marginal rates.

• Thus he exempts poor country ‘middle classes’: richer than poor country poverty lines but poorer than rich country poverty lines.

Page 14: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 14

• Poor country poverty line zp = PPP$1.25

• zr = US poverty line = PPP$13/day.

• Those with income y > zr subject to the tax.• Tax is redistributed to the poorest.• The tax is linear above zr , so it is progressive:

– Tax is zero for y < zr .

– Tax is τ(y - zr) for y > zr , 0 < τ < 1.

• With perfect redistribution, what marginal tax rate τ is required to fill the poverty gap?

Page 15: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 15

• Brazil: MTR of 1% on those above $13 a day will cover the whole poverty gap.– To eliminate poverty at Brazil’s national poverty

line of $3/day, tax required is 12%.• China: MTR of 37%.

– National poverty line of $1 requires 30% MTR.• India: Too many poor, and not enough people

above $13, so it is not possible to fill the poverty gap.– Even at 100% MTR, only 20% of poverty gap filled.

Page 16: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 16

• For one third of his 90 countries, the MTR required is over 100%: they are too poor to eliminate poverty in this way.

• For most countries with per capita expenditure (PCE) above PPP$2,000, the MTR is 20% or less.

• For countries with PCE above PPP$4,000, MTR averages 0.8% at $1.25, and 2.4% at $2 poverty line.

Page 17: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 17

Another approach to distribution: natural resources and global poverty

• First interesting fact: commodity prices are very high, and affect global poverty. High commodity prices

high food prices high poverty

In 2008 the World Bank estimated that increased food prices could undo 7 years of poverty reduction.

Page 18: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 18

1992-01

1994-01

1996-01

1998-01

2000-01

2002-01

2004-01

2006-01

2008-01

2010-010.00

50.00

100.00

150.00

200.00

250.00

IMF real commodity prices to Feb 2011(deflated by US CPI)

Page 19: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 19

Second interesting fact: natural resources are owned by all citizens in a country

In international law they belong to “peoples” (Wenar 2007):

• Both the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights and the International Covenant on Economic, Social, and Cultural Rights state:

All peoples may, for their own ends, freely dispose of their natural wealth and resources.

• The African Charter on Human and Peoples’ Rights statesAll peoples shall freely dispose of their wealth and natural resources. This right shall be exercised in the exclusive interest of the people. In no case shall a people be deprived of it.

• The (US-approved) Iraqi constitution of 2005 statesOil and gas are the property of the Iraqi people in all the regions and provinces.

Page 20: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 20

The Resource Dividend• Natural resource rents distributed directly, equally

and unconditionally to every adult citizen: a “basic income” funded by resource rents.

• Rents are the payment to a factor of production over that necessary to induce it to do its work. => Resource rents = revenues remaining after competitive

costs of extraction have been paid• Hence oil or mineral companies still get paid!• NB: The RD is distribution, but not redistribution:

no individual owns them to start with, unlike most income.

Page 21: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 21

Antecedents

• The idea has a long pedigree:– Thomas Paine’s Agrarian Justice, 1795. – British North Sea oil. Brittan and Riley (1978, 1980): “The

simplest and also the wisest answer to the question ‘What should we do with the state’s oil revenues?’ is ‘Give them to the people’.”

– Alaska Permanent Fund Dividend since 1983; typically $1,000-$2,000 per year.

– Recent proposals: Nigeria, Iraq, Bolivia.

• I consider the global impact on poverty if all countries adopted it, for all natural resources.

• NB Thomas Pogge’s Global Resource Dividend.

Page 22: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 22

Data1. Resource Rents: value of output less competitive cost

of production. World Bank data.15 resources: oil, natural gas, hard coal, lignite, forestry, bauxite, copper, gold, iron ore, lead, nickel, phosphate, silver, tin and zinc

2. Distributional data: World Bank’s Povcalnet website– 115 countries comprising 5.2 billion people, or 96% of the

population of the developing world.– Incomes (or consumption) in 2005 direct from surveys.– Deciles for all countries with populations below 50 million.

17 larger countries divided into 1,000 income groups eachÞ Largest income group <5 million people, or < 0.1% of total.

Page 23: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 23

Calculating the Resource Dividend

• RD calculated for individual years, and 5-year averages, over 2000 – 06. RD is total rents / population.

• If governments are currently taxing resource rents then they have to raise other taxes to maintain expenditures.1. One extreme: the government does not raise other taxes; or,

equivalently for poverty, all new taxes fall on the non-poor. 2. Other extreme: taxes fully compensate for the total Resource

Dividend, levied on each individual in proportion to income.

• Thus I perform two sets of calculations. 1. Add Resource Dividend to everyone’s income.2. Add Resource Dividend, and subtract tax equal to r% of income

where r% is the rent-share of GDP.

Page 24: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 24

2005 Global Poverty Estimates with the Resource Dividend

With RD With RD, less tax

Year of rents Number (millions) Share Poverty

reductionNumber

(millions) Share Poverty reduction

2000 770 14.9% 42% 930 17.9% 30%2001 747 14.4% 44% 885 17.1% 33%2002 795 15.3% 40% 914 17.6% 31%2003 753 14.5% 43% 893 17.2% 33%2004 561 10.8% 58% 696 13.4% 48%2005 499 9.6% 62% 682 13.2% 49%2006 448 8.6% 66% 545 10.5% 59%

2000-04 709 13.7% 47% 846 16.3% 36%2001-05 639 12.3% 52% 773 14.9% 42%2002-06 567 10.9% 57% 689 13.3% 48%

Without RD: 1,327m poor, or 25.6% of developing world population.

Page 25: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 25

Estimated poverty reduction as a function of commodity prices

Poverty better-than halved:• since 2004 if the poor do not pay increased taxes• since 2006 if they do

Com

mod

ity p

rices

, 20

06=1

00

Pove

rty

redu

ction

Page 26: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 26

Figure 1: Log income distributions for all developing countries, 2002-06 RD

Notes: Kernel density estimation using Epanechnikov kernel.

0.2

.4.6

Po

pula

tion

PPP$1.25/dayLog Income

IncomeIncome with RDIncome with RD less tax

Page 27: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 27

China0

.2.4

.6P

opu

latio

n

PPP$1.25/dayLog Income

IncomeIncome with RDIncome with RD less tax

Page 28: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 28

India0

.2.4

.6.8

1P

opu

latio

n

PPP$1.25/dayLog Income

IncomeIncome with RDIncome with RD less tax

Page 29: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 29

Nigeria

0.5

11

.5P

opu

latio

n

PPP$1.25/dayLog Income

IncomeIncome with RDIncome with RD less tax

Page 30: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 30

Selected Countries, 2002-06 Rents

Poverty at PPP$1.25 a day Gini coefficient

Rents % of GDP

RD (monthly) Current RD, no taxes

RD, with taxes Current

With RDCountry PPP$ US$ Millions Share

Bangladesh 3.9 3.3 1.3 70.4 49.6% 42.1% 45.8% 31.0 29.0

Brazil 4.6 27.1 17.5 14.5 7.8% 0.0% 0.0% 55.4 50.4

China 5.2 rural: 19.6 7.16 211.9 16.2% 1.1% 1.9% 41.7 35.2urban: 14.3

India 4.9rural: 11.1

2.86 455.4 41.6% 18.2% 19.5% 34.9 29.8urban: 7.3

Indonesia 11.4 rural: 32.3 11.6 47.3 21.5% 0.0% 0.0% 36.2 26.2urban: 22.9

Nigeria 51 49.4 29.6 91.1 64.4% 0.0% 48.8% 42.9 19.1Pakistan 5.3 9 3.1 35.2 22.6% 7.5% 7.8% 31.2 27.4

Page 31: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 31

How big is the RD? In 2002-06:

• Median of 104 countries with RD>0 is 4.3% of GDP.• Bangladesh, Brazil, China, India, Pakistan, South

Africa: 57% of total population, 68% of poverty reduction due to the RD; each has RD <6% of GDP. Poverty reduction not due to resource-rich countries.

• Compare with social benefits in the EU15: – Cash benefits are 6.6% of GDP.– 16% of EU15 population is below national poverty lines.

Without these cash benefits, this would be 25%.Þ Hence RD is not particularly large as a redistributive

scheme, and its effect should not be surprising.

Page 32: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 32

Five advantages of universal benefits

1. Easier to administer (even in “Swiss cheese states”).

2. Minimize errors of exclusion.– Bolsa Familia and Oportunidades reach only 41%

and 30% of the poor.

3. No substitution effect on work/leisure.4. Political support from the middle classes

(Cornia and Stewart, Skocpol).5. Reduces risk of corruption and clientelism.

Page 33: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

[email protected] 33

The RD, Output and Growth

• The RD may lower output:– Reduced work effort through income effect

• But effect largest for least productive workers.

– Distortions due to increased taxes.• The RD may raise output:

– “Efficiency wages” argument: better nutrition etc.• The RD may raise growth:

– Eases credit constraints on the poor.

Page 34: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

The Case of Oil in Mexico: Who benefits?

Government

Citizens

Pemex

Expenditure

Oil revenues

Taxes

Page 35: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

Oil revenues have recently comprised 8-10% of GDP and about 35-40% of government revenues.

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 20095.0%

6.0%

7.0%

8.0%

9.0%

10.0%

11.0%

20.0%

25.0%

30.0%

35.0%

40.0%

45.0%

Share of GDP

Share of gov revenues (right axis)

Page 36: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

Despite oil revenues, the Mexican government is very small:

• Government consumption: 9% of GDP

• Government revenue: 21% of GDP.(Also spent on investment, debt payments, etc.)Since up to 10.5% of this is from oil, the impact on Mexican households and businesses is even smaller.

Page 37: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

Government consumption expenditure as % of GDPLatin America, 2008

Cuba

Colombia

Honduras

Latin Americ

a Chile

Nicarag

ua

Paragu

ay

Costa Rica

El Salv

ador

Mexic

o

Guatemala

Haiti

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

Source: ECLAC

Page 38: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

Total tax revenue as % of GDP, OECD, 2008D

enm

ark

Swed

enBe

lgiu

mIta

lyFr

ance

Finl

and

Aust

riaN

orw

ayH

unga

ryN

ethe

rland

sSl

oven

iaG

erm

any

Icel

and

Czec

h Re

publ

icU

nite

d Ki

ngdo

mLu

xem

bour

gPo

rtug

alO

ECD

- To

tal

Pola

ndIs

rael

New

Zea

land

Spai

nG

reec

eCa

nada

Slov

ak R

epub

licSw

itzer

land

Irel

and

Japa

nAu

stra

liaKo

rea

Uni

ted

Stat

esTu

rkey

Chile

Mex

ico

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

Source: OECD

Page 39: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

Who benefits from fiscal policy?

Consider the distribution of income before and after taxes and spending.

Compared with market incomes, fiscal policy is progressive:

Page 40: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

Fiscal policy benefits poorer Mexicans relative to market income:

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 100%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

45%

50% Income shares by decile

Market income

Post-fisc

Page 41: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

But this ignores the fact that all Mexicans have an equal right to their country’s oil revenues.

In 2008, 10.5 percent of GDP belonged in equal share to all Mexicans:M$11,925 (US$1,055 or PPP$1,529) per person

per year.

Given this, fiscal policy is regressive:

Page 42: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 100%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

45%

50%Income shares by decile

Market incomePost-fiscWith oil entitlements

Fiscal policy gives the poorest 90% of citizens less than their share of oil revenues:

Page 43: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

-6.0%

-4.0%

-2.0%

0.0%

2.0%

4.0%

6.0% Post-fisc income relative to market income plus oil entitlements

Income decile

Page 44: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

The net effect of fiscal policy is to transfer oil entitlements from the poorer 90 percent of the population to the richest 10 percent. •Those in the bottom 90 percent lose on average M$1,750 (US$170) per year.

•Those in the richest 10 percent gain an extra M$16,000 (US$1,500) per person per year.

Page 45: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

Mexico’s famous conditional cash transfer oportunidades: Nice, but tiny

Decile Share of total benefit received by decile, %

Average yearly payment per capita, M$

1 33.3 12662 18.5 7033 12.7 4834 9.4 3575 6.4 2436 7.3 2787 4.8 1828 3.3 1259 2.7 103

10 1.7 65

Total /average

100 381

•Total expenditure: 0.35% of GDP

•And: it reaches only 30% of the poorest 20%.

Page 46: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

Can fiscal policy be made fairer?

A long-term proposal: In addition to current fiscal policy, give every citizen her/his share of oil revenues.

5-year average of oil revenues: M$9,800 (US$880) per person per year

• Could be cash, or could be public services.• Requires raising taxation to accommodate.• Compare: Renta dignidad is paid to all Bolivians over the age of 60, and is Bs2,400 (US$340 or PPP$860).

Page 47: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

Under this policy, over the past 5 years government revenue would have averaged 27.1% of GDP.

= 5-year average government revenue of 18.5% of GDPplus5-year average oil revenues of 8.6% of GDP.

This maintains current expenditures, plus giving citizens their oil entitlements.

Would 27.1% be dramatic?

Page 48: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

Gov revenue as % of GDP, OECD plus Argentina, BrazilDe

nmar

kSw

eden

Belg

ium

Italy

Fran

ceFi

nlan

dAu

stria

Nor

way

Hun

gary

Net

herla

nds

Slov

enia

Ger

man

yIc

elan

dBr

azil

Czec

h Re

publ

icU

nite

d Ki

ngdo

mLu

xem

bour

gPo

rtug

alO

ECD

- Tot

alPo

land

Isra

elN

ew Z

eala

ndAr

genti

naSp

ain

Gre

ece

Cana

daSl

ovak

Rep

ublic

Switz

erla

ndIre

land

Japa

nM

exic

o pl

usAu

stra

liaKo

rea

Uni

ted

Stat

esTu

rkey

Chile

Mex

ico

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

Page 49: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

Effect on poverty

In 2008 16.5% were below the national extreme poverty line: •M$611/month in rural areas (US$51)•M$870/month in urban areas (US$73)

5-year average oil entitlement is M$815 per month. Even accounting for additional taxation, this would eliminate extreme poverty.

Page 50: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

Effect on inequality

Gini coefficient would decline from 49 to 44.Market inequality is 54; total decline would be 10.1.

Total redistributive impact of fiscal policy would remain lower than most European countries.

Page 51: Global inequality and poverty: Distribution, redistribution, and the case of natural resource ownership Paul Segal Department of Economics, University

This redistribution is not radical by international standards:

Reduction in Gini due to fiscal policy

Reduction in Gini due to fiscal policy

Mexico 5.1 EU-15 12.5Mexico with oil entitlements

10.1Denmark 18.1Ireland 17.4

Bolivia 4.3 Italy 9.1Colombia 5.4 Portugal 10.2Costa Rica 6.8 Spain 10.8El Salvador 1.6 Sweden 14.5Guatemala 3.7Honduras 2.7Nicaragua 3.1Panama 8.0Peru 3.1