econ.au.dk · asymptotic normality of the qmle of stationary and nonstationary garch with serially...

36
Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations Christian M. Dahl CREATES School of Economics and Management University of Aarhus Emma M. Iglesias Department of Economics Michigan State University April 15, 2007 Abstract This paper proposes a new parametric volatility model that introduces serially dependent innovations in GARCH specifications. We first prove the asymptotic normality of the QML estimator in this setting, allowing for possible explosive and nonstationary behavior of the GARCH process. We provide a general valid asymptotic theory that holds both in the stationary and the nonstationary regions of the parameter space. We show that this model can generate an alternative measure of risk premium relative to the GARCH-M. As there exist no asymptotic results for QML estimators in GARCH-M type models we fill in an important gap in the literature and additionally facilitate simple quasi-likelihood based tests of the presence of risk premiums. Finally, we provide evidence of the usefulness and advantages of our approach relative to competing volatility models through a Monte Carlo experiment and by an application to US treasury bill spot rates. In particular, we illustrate the consequences of dynamic misspecification and demonstrate that the new volatility model can improve significantly upon the fit in-sample as well as out-of-sample relative to traditional GARCH-type specifications. Keywords: Asymptotics; Estimation; Nonstationarity; Risk Premium; Weak-form GARCH; * Comments from Lynda Khalaf, Nour Meddahi, Jeffrey Wooldridge and participants at seminars at University of Aarhus and at the conferences: 2005 Symposium on Econometric Theory and Applications (Taipei, Taiwan); the 2006 North American Summer meeting of the Econometric Society (Minnesota), 2006 IMS Annual Meeting in Statistics (Rio de Janeiro), 2006 Canadian Econometrics Group (Niagara Falls, Canada) and the 2006 European Meeting of the Econometric Society (Vienna) are gratefully acknowledged. The first author acknowledges support from Center for Research in Econometric Analysis of Time Series, funded by the Danish National Research Foundation. Corresponding author. Address: School of Economics and Management, Room 225, Building 1326. Phone: +45 8942 1559. E-mail: [email protected]. 1

Upload: others

Post on 18-Mar-2020

9 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary

GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗

Christian M. Dahl†

CREATES

School of Economics and Management

University of Aarhus

Emma M. Iglesias

Department of Economics

Michigan State University

April 15, 2007

Abstract

This paper proposes a new parametric volatility model that introduces serially dependent innovations in GARCH

specifications. We first prove the asymptotic normality of the QML estimator in this setting, allowing for possible

explosive and nonstationary behavior of the GARCH process. We provide a general valid asymptotic theory that

holds both in the stationary and the nonstationary regions of the parameter space. We show that this model

can generate an alternative measure of risk premium relative to the GARCH-M. As there exist no asymptotic

results for QML estimators in GARCH-M type models we fill in an important gap in the literature and additionally

facilitate simple quasi-likelihood based tests of the presence of risk premiums. Finally, we provide evidence of

the usefulness and advantages of our approach relative to competing volatility models through a Monte Carlo

experiment and by an application to US treasury bill spot rates. In particular, we illustrate the consequences of

dynamic misspecification and demonstrate that the new volatility model can improve significantly upon the fit

in-sample as well as out-of-sample relative to traditional GARCH-type specifications.

Keywords: Asymptotics; Estimation; Nonstationarity; Risk Premium; Weak-form GARCH;

∗Comments from Lynda Khalaf, Nour Meddahi, Jeffrey Wooldridge and participants at seminars at University of Aarhus and at the

conferences: 2005 Symposium on Econometric Theory and Applications (Taipei, Taiwan); the 2006 North American Summer meeting

of the Econometric Society (Minnesota), 2006 IMS Annual Meeting in Statistics (Rio de Janeiro), 2006 Canadian Econometrics Group

(Niagara Falls, Canada) and the 2006 European Meeting of the Econometric Society (Vienna) are gratefully acknowledged. The first

author acknowledges support from Center for Research in Econometric Analysis of Time Series, funded by the Danish National Research

Foundation.†Corresponding author. Address: School of Economics and Management, Room 225, Building 1326. Phone: +45 8942 1559. E-mail:

[email protected].

1

Page 2: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

1 Introduction

Since Engle (1982) proposed the ARCH (autoregressive conditional heteroskedastic) model, and Bollerslev (1986)

generalized it to GARCH, there has been a substantial interest in conditional volatility modelling. If yt denotes the

time series of interest, and its conditional variance is given by σ2t , the GARCH(1,1) model is specified as

yt (θ∗) = σtǫt,

σ2t (θ∗) = w + αy2

t−1 + βσ2t−1 (θ∗) ,

with θ∗ =

(w, α, β, σ2

0 (θ∗)). Following Drost and Nijman (1993), GARCH models can be classified into three cate-

gories: strong GARCH (where the innovation process ǫt is i.i.d. with zero mean and unit variance); the semi-strong

form (where the innovation process is a martingale difference sequence), and finally the weak form, where also the

martingale difference sequence assumption is relaxed.

Asymptotic normality of the Quasi Maximum Likelihood (QML) estimator has been established under a wide

range of alternative assumptions for strong-GARCH models see, e.g., Lumsdaine (1996)). One of the most recent

contribution is by Jensen and Rahbek (2004a, 2004b), who show that the QMLE is asymptotically normal both in the

stationary and the nonstationary region of the parameter space. Lee and Hansen (1994) show asymptotic normality

of the QMLE for the semi-strong form. In relation to weak-form GARCH models, the asymptotic normality of the

QML estimator has not yet been established, see, e.g., Linton and Mammen (2005, page 787).

Weak-form GARCH processes have mainly been treated semiparametrically in the literature, see, e.g., Meddahi and

Renault (2004), Linton and Mammen (2005) and Dahl and Levine (2005). However, common for the semiparametric

approaches is that they do not permit nonstationary and explosive GARCH processes. The first main contribution of

this paper is to analyze a fully parametrically specified GARCH process, where the innovations are neither i.i.d. nor a

martingale difference sequence and by allowing for explosive and nonstationary behavior of the GARCH process. We

are hereby extending the work of Jensen and Rahbek (2004a, 2004b) from strong-GARCH processes to weak-GARCH

with serially dependent innovations. Linton and Mammen (2005) argue that one of the important challenges in

relation to modelling weak-form GARCH processes parametrically is to avoid higher order moment restriction on the

dependent variable. Importantly, we show the moment restriction needed for asymptotic normality of the QMLE are

not stronger for the weak-GARCH process we consider relative to the strong-GARCH specification in Jensen and

Rahbek (2004a, 2004b).

One popular extension of GARCH models is the GARCH-in-Mean (GARCH-M) model proposed by Engle, Lilien

and Robins (1987), where the conditional volatility function (or functionals of the volatility such as the logarithm)

is introduced into the conditional mean equation. This appears to be a very easy way to model the risk premium.

However, GARCH-M models have been shown to be very difficult to handle from a theoretical point of view and very

little is known about the sample properties of the GARCH-M estimation procedures, see e.g. Engle and Kroner (1995).

The second main contribution of our approach is that by allowing for dynamics in the innovation process it is possible

to create a pattern in the mean equation that introduces interaction effects between the standardized conditional

volatility and lags of the dependent variable (see Section 2 for analytical details). Consequently, the model can be

viewed as an alternative specification to the GARCH-M modelling of the risk premium. Contrary to the GARCH-M

specification we demonstrate that our model permits a very straightforward proof of the asymptotic properties of

2

Page 3: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

the QML estimator. Furthermore, our approach and asymptotic results permit having a function of the conditional

volatility in the mean equation as well as having nonstationary behavior in the GARCH process. The properties of the

QML estimates associated with GARCH-M models with this type of nonstationarity in the GARCH process has not

been considered, again possibly due to the theoretical difficulties the GARCH-M specification generates. In addition,

we show that the GARCH model with serially dependent innovations is a generalization of the double autoregressive

model proposed recently by Ling (2004), where the conditional mean function is augmented with a function of the

volatility function hereby allowing for a risk premium effect.

An additional interesting feature of our model is that - contrary to the GARCH-M model - it does not suffer from

identification problems when testing for GARCH effects. This is because the coefficients are identified through the

equation for the innovation process. See, for example, Dufour, Khalaf, Bernard and Genest (2004) for issues related

to the GARCH-M in this context.

The third contribution of our new approach, is that it suggests a particular functional form relationship between the

conditional volatility and the conditional mean. In particular, the model implies that it is the ratio of the conditional

volatility at time t over the conditional volatility at (t − 1) that should enter the mean function. This type of functional

relationship between the mean and the volatility is not possible to capture by the applying the traditional GARCH-M.

As there exist no asymptotic results for QML estimators in GARCH-M type models we fill in an important gap and

additionally facilitate simple quasi-likelihood based tests of the presence risk premiums. In fact, our model can be

combined with the GARCH-M, providing empirical researchers with an even richer menu of choices to model volatility

and the risk premium.

Finally, we offer an example showing that the new volatility model can provide improvements in fit in-sample as

well as out-of-sample in relation to other competing GARCH type specifications.

It should be emphasized that the weak-GARCH representation we consider is not new in the literature. It has been

used previously, for example, by Goncalves and White (2004, page 208) in their simulations illustrating the effects

of misspecification when the true model is a GARCH with an innovation term that follows an AR(1) process and

the researcher erroneously estimate a traditional GARCH. Kristensen and Rahbek (2005) also note the relevance of

this model. However the asymptotic properties of this model have not previously been analyzed. In this paper, we

also provide an empirical application showing that this process has empirical relevance. Based on modeling the US

treasury bill spot rates, we demonstrate its empirical advantages over the traditional GARCH and other competing

GARCH models such as the AR-GARCH.

An important final remark is that all the proofs associated with the main results in this paper, although focusing

on the nonstationary regions of the parameter space, carry over straightforwardly to the stationary region. The

asymptotic theory provided therefore apply to the stationary as well as the nonstationary regions of the parameter

space.

The plan of the paper is as follows. Section 2 presents the general model and the results on consistency and

asymptotic normality of the QML estimator. Section 3 presents some illustrations of our approach: First we provide

a Monte Carlo simulation study on the consequences of dynamic misspecification of the GARCH model and secondly

we present an empirical application illustrating how our new model can be potentially useful for applied researchers.

Finally, Section 4 concludes.

3

Page 4: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

2 Strictly stationarity of the weak-GARCH(1,1) process

We are interested in the process yt, with the following representation

yt = σt (θ∗) ǫt, (1)

σ2t (θ∗) = w + αy2

t−1 + βσ2t−1 (θ∗) , (2)

for t = 1, 2, ..., T . Let γ = σ20 . The vector of parameters interest is then given as θ

∗ = (w, α, β, γ)′ ∈ Θ∗, where the

true parameter vector is defined as θ∗

0 . In establishing strictly stationarity we will work under the following set of

general assumptions which are maintained throughout the paper

Assumption A

A1 Θ∗ ⊂ R4+ is a compact set.

A2 ǫt is an ergodic and strictly stationary process.

For simplicity of notation we write σ2t = σ2

t (θ∗

0) . We can now establish the following result regarding strictly station-

arity of yt, which is an extension of the results of Bougerol and Picard (1992b).

Lemma 1 Let Assumption A hold. A necessary and sufficient condition for strict stationarity of yt generated by

(1)-(2) is given by

E log(α0ǫ

2t + β0

)< 0.

Proof of Lemma 1 Given in Appendix 1.

An additional and important new result (extending the results in Nelson (1990)), under the broad definition of ǫt in

Assumption A,can now be formulated as follows:

Lemma 2 Let Assumption A hold. If E log(α0ǫ

2t + β0

)≥ 0 as t → ∞, then σ2

ta.s.→ ∞.

Proof of Lemma 2 Given in Appendix 1.

Lemmas 1 and 2 generalize the well known conditions for strict stationarity of strong-GARCH processes, to include

weak-GARCH processes.

3 The GARCH(1,1)-AR(1) representation and its properties

To obtain quasi-likelihood based estimators of the unknown parameters in θ∗ we proceed by parameterizing the process

generating ǫt. We will begin under the simplifying assumption that ǫt follows a strictly stationary and ergodic AR(1)

4

Page 5: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

process. Later we will generalize all the results to the AR(p) case. In particular, consider first the GARCH(1,1)-AR(1)

representation given as

yt = σt (θ) ǫt (θ) , (3)

ǫt (θ) = ρǫt−1 (θ) + vt, (4)

σ2t (θ) = w + αy2

t−1 + βσ2t−1 (θ) , (5)

where the parameter vector is redefined as θ = (w, α, β, γ, ρ) ∈ Θ with true values θ0 = (w0, α0, β0, γ0, ρ0) and where

vt is a white noise process defined by Assumption B below. We write ǫt, σ2t = ǫt (θ0) , σ2

t (θ0).To illustrate a potential and important difference, we will first consider the unconditional variance of the process

given by (3) - (5) and compare it to the unconditional variance generated from the strong-GARCH process. For

illustration only, let us restrict attention to the case where the unconditional variance is bounded and σ2t is a strictly

stationary and ergodic process. We immediately have that

E(σ2

t

)= w0 + α0 E

(σ2

t−1ǫ2t−1

)+ β0 E

(σ2

t−1

),

where

E(σ2

t−1ǫ2t−1

)= E

(σ2

t−1 (ρ0ǫt−2 + vt−1)2)

,

= ρ20 E(σ2

t−1ǫ2t−2

)+ E

(σ2

t−1

),

such that,

E(σ2

t

)=

w0 + α0ρ20 E(σ2

t−1ǫ2t−2

)

(1 − α0 − β0).

Consequently, the difference between the unconditional variance of the standard GARCH(1,1) process and the GARCH(1,1)-

AR(1) generated from (3) - (5) is equal to α0ρ20 E(σ2

t−1ǫ2t−2

)/ (1 − α0 − β0) and the GARCH(1,1)-AR(1) model will

be able to generate relative larger (smaller) unconditional variance depending on the sign and magnitude of this term.

Again we would like to emphasize that stationarity of σ2t is not required in the estimation framework presented below,

so the unconditional variance may not exist in the GARCH(1,1)-AR(1) setting. This feature introduces additional

flexibility in the volatility process modelling relative to the traditional GARCH(1,1) model.

A second important issue is how to interpret the conditional variance function σ2t (θ) in the representation given

by (3) - (5). In what follows, let ηt = σt (θ) vt and define the information set at time t−1 as It−1 = yt−1, yt−2, .... To

help the understanding, let us compare to the traditional AR(1)-ARCH(1) model, see e.g., Ling and McAleer (2003,

p. 283), where

yt − φyt−1 = ηt, (6)

σ2t (θ) = w + αη2

t−1. (7)

Here the interpretation is that σ2t (θ) is the conditional variance (conditional on information up to and including t−1)

since σ2t (θ) = E

((yt − φyt−1)

2 |It−1

)= var (ηt). Note, that in (6)- (7) σ2

t (θ) is a function of η2t−1 which is the original

5

Page 6: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

idea of Engle (1982). Alternatively, consider the double autoregressive model of Ling (2004), where

yt − φyt−1 = ηt,

σ2t (θ) = w + αy2

t−1.

Again the interpretation is that σ2t (θ) = E

((yt − φyt−1)

2 |It−1

)= var (ηt). It does not change this interpretation

that σ2t (θ) is a function of y2

t−1 which is different from η2t−1 in (7) whenever φ 6= 0. Regarding the interpretation of

σ2t (θ) in the model given by (3) - (5), note that it can be re-represented as

yt − ρσt (θ)σ−1t−1 (θ) yt−1 = ηt, (8)

σ2t (θ) = w + αy2

t−1 + βσ2t−1 (θ) , (9)

since the model allows the innovations as defined in the traditional GARCH model to be partially predicted through

the existence of an autoregressive innovation process. Note that with (8), we are back in the traditional context of

having an innovation term ηt that is an unanticipated random variable. Also, this emphasizes the differences between a

traditional AR-GARCH model with a constant AR coefficient given by φ in the mean equation versus the GARCH-AR

having a variable AR coefficients in the mean equation given by ρσt (θ)σ−1t−1 (θ). However, because of the properties

of ηt we again have that

E((

yt − ρσt (θ)σ−1t−1 (θ) yt−1

)2 |It−1

)= σ2

t (θ) ,

= var (ηt) .

In conclusion, the interpretation of σ2t (θ) as the conditional variance still holds in the GARCH(1,1)-AR(1) model and

this result easily generalizes to any GARCH(1,1)-AR(p) model. This result is not surprising as the GARCH(1,1) with

serially dependent innovations given by (3) - (5) is a generalization of a Ling’s (2004) double autoregressive model

with a function of the volatility in the mean equation (i.e. allowing for a risk premium effect).

From (8) it also becomes clear how by specifying an AR(1) process for the innovation term, a measure of the

volatility is introduced into the mean equation of the process yt. The model hereby provides an alternative approach

to modelling the risk premium relative to the traditional GARCH-M proposed by Engle, Lilien and Robins (1987).

Interestingly, this gives an easy test for the presence of risk effects in the mean equation: if the hypothesis that

ρ = 0 cannot be rejected, then data supports the traditional GARCH(1,1) process without risk effects in the mean .

Furthermore, as pointed out by Dufour, Khalaf, Bernard and Genest (2004) it is difficult to test for GARCH effects

within the traditional GARCH-M framework due to the presence of identification problems. These problems are not

present in the GARCH-AR specification. To see this let us define ρt = ρσt (θ)σ−1t−1 (θ) . A test for no GARCH effects

would reduce to a test of the null hypothesis ρt = ρ for all t, i.e., a test whether ρt is a constant versus a time varying

parameter. This test is particular simple since under the null hypothesis the innovation term is i.i.d.

3.1 Estimation and the Asymptotics

In addition, we need to modify the set of assumptions we will be work under.

6

Page 7: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

Assumption B

B1 Θ ⊂ R4+ × R is a compact set, θ0 ∈ interior (Θ) and |ρ0| < 1.

B2 E log(α0ǫ

2t + β0

)≥ 0.

B3 vt ∼ i.i.d. (0, 1) with E(v4

t − 1)

= ζ < ∞.

Note that we impose Assumption B2 to explicitly focus on the nonstationarity region for the GARCH process

given by (1).

We now present the result of the asymptotic behavior of the QMLE in this setting. The QML estimators will

maximize the quasi log-likelihood (with θ = (w0, α, β, γ0, ρ) ) given as

lT (θ) = −1

2

T∑

t=1

(log(w0 + αy2

t−1 + βσ2t−1 (θ)

)+

(yt − ρσt (θ)σ−1

t−1 (θ) yt−1

)2

σ2t (θ)

). (10)

We then have,

Theorem 1 Let Assumption B hold with (w, γ) fixed at their true values, (w0, γ0) , and assume that yt is generated

from (3) - (5). Then there exists a fixed open neighborhood U = U (α0, β0, ρ0) of (α0, β0, ρ0) such that with probability

tending to one as T −→ ∞, lT (θ) given by (10) has a unique maximum point(α, β, ρ

)´in U. In addition, the QML

estimator(α, β, ρ

)´is consistent and asymptotically normal, i.e.,

√T[(

α, β, ρ)− (α0, β0, ρ0)

d−→ N(0, Ω−1

),

with µi = E(β0/

(α0ǫ

2t + β0

))i, i = 1, 2 and where

Ω =

1ζα2

0

µ1

ζα0β0(1−µ1) 0µ1

ζα0β0(1−µ1)(1+µ1)µ2

ζβ2

0(1−µ1)(1−µ2)

0

0 0 1

(1−ρ2

0)

.

Proof of Theorem 1 Given in Appendix 1.

Furthermore,

Theorem 2 If E log(α0ǫ

2t + β0

)> 0, then the results in Theorem 1 hold for any arbitrary value of w > 0 and γ > 0.

Proof of Theorem 2 Theorem 2 is proved by a direct application of Theorem 2 of Jensen and Rahbek (2004b).

In order to make the proofs easier to follow, we have structured the derivatives in the Appendix such that comparisons

to the results of Jensen and Rahbek (2004a, 2004b) are straightforward to make.

7

Page 8: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

4 Asymptotics of the QMLE for the GARCH(1,1)-AR(p) process

We now generalize the results in Theorems 1 and 2 to the AR(p) case. Consider now the GARCH(1,1)-AR(p) model

given as

yt = σtǫt, (11)

ρ (L) ǫt = vt, (12)

σ2t = w + αy2

t−1 + βσ2t−1, (13)

where ρ (L) = 1 −∑pi=1 ρiL

i and θ = (w, α, β, γ, ρ1, ..., ρp)′ ∈ Θ with its true value at θ0. Again we write ǫt, σ

2t =

ǫt (θ0) , σ2t (θ0). As in the previous section it can be shown that the unconditional variance of this process relative

to the unconditional variance of the traditional GARCH(1,1) (provided that they both exist) will depend on θ0, in

particular, on the term

α0

(1 − α0 − β0)

(∑

i

ρ2i0 E

(σ2

t−1ǫ2t−i−1

)+ 2

i

ρi−10ρi0 E(σ2

t−1ǫt−iǫt−i−1

))

.

It is again clear that there are some new extra-terms in the unconditional volatility that would not be present given

that the data was generated from the traditional GARCH(1,1) process. Hence, more flexibility is introduced.

For estimation purpose we next impose the following set of assumptions

Assumption C

C1 Θ ⊂ R4+ × R

p is a compact set, θ0 ∈ interior (Θ) and the roots of ρ (z) are all outside the unit circle.

C2 E log(α0ǫ

2t + β0

)≥ 0.

C3 vt ∼ i.i.d. (0, 1) with E(v4

t − 1)

= ζ < ∞

As Assumption C is more restrictive than Assumption A, Lemmas 1 and 2 still hold when data under this assump-

tion is generated from (11)-(13). In order to deriving the limiting properties of the QML estimators, we represent

(11)-(13) as

yt −p∑

i=1

ρiσt (θ)σ−1t−i (θ) yt−i = σt (θ) vt,

σ2t (θ) = w + αy2

t−1 + βσ2t−1 (θ) .

As in the previous section, we note that the AR(p) structure in the innovation process generates a measure of risk

premium in the mean equation. With (w, γ) fixed at their true values, (w0, γ0) ,the Quasi loglikelihood function

associated with (11)-(13) then writes

lT (θ) = −1

2

T∑

t=1

(log(w0 + αy2

t−1 + βσ2t−1 (θ)

)+

(yt −

∑pi=1 ρiσt (θ)σ−1

t−i (θ) yt−i

)2

σ2t (θ)

). (14)

We can now state the most important results of the paper.

8

Page 9: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

Theorem 3 Let Assumption C hold and let data be generated according to the GARCH(1,1)-AR(p) process given

by (11)-(13) Then the results of Theorem 1 hold. The variance-covariance matrix Ω will be block diagonal. The upper

block will be unchanged while the lower block will consist of the information matrix of the AR(p) process as given in

Hamilton (1994, page 125) using the Galbraith and Galbraith (1974) equation.

Proof of Theorem 3 Given in Appendix 2.

As in the GARCH(1,1)-AR(1) case we have the following companion result to Theorem 3.

Theorem 4 If E log(α0ǫ

2t + β0

)> 0, then the results in Theorem 3 hold for any arbitrary value of w > 0 and γ > 0.

Proof of Theorem 4 Theorem 4 is proved by a direct application of Theorem 2 of Jensen and Rahbek (2004b).

Very importantly, it is straightforward to show using similar techniques as in Jensen and Rahbek (2004b) that the

results in Theorem 1 and 3 carry over to the stationary case by the ergodic theorem. This important result can be

summarized as follows:

Theorem 5 Let Assumptions C1 and C3 hold and assume that E log(α0ǫ

2t + β0

)< 0. Furthermore, let data be

generated according to the GARCH(1,1)-AR(p) process given by (11)-(13). Then the results of Theorem 3 hold.

Proof of Theorem 5 Given in Appendix 3.

By Theorems 3, 4 and 5 we have generalized the main results of Lumsdaine (1996) and Jensen and Rahbek

(2004a,2004b) to a much richer class of volatility models. In the next section we will turn to the subject of the

empirical relevance of the new approach.

5 Illustrations

In this section we illustrate the importance and need of carefully considering whether to specify the dynamics of the

GARCH process in the conditional mean function (i.e., by choosing the AR-GARCH specification), a GARCH-M

model or to specify the dynamics in the innovation process by working with the GARCH-AR specification (our new

model). We begin by analyzing the effects on the estimated parameters in the conditional mean function if it is

misspecified, i.e., if the researcher estimates an AR-GARCH model when the true data generating process is GARCH-

AR. We derive the relative inconsistency theoretically and we quantify it under various distributional assumptions by

conducting simulations. Secondly, we provide an empirical illustration showing that the GARCH-AR model provides

a strong and a perhaps better alternative to the AR-GARCH model and the AR-GARCH-M as a representation of

the change in the US 3 and 6 month treasury bill interest (spot) rates.

9

Page 10: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

−4 −3 −2 −1 0 1 2 3 4

0.2

0.4 DensityN(0,1)

−17.5 −15.0 −12.5 −10.0 −7.5 −5.0 −2.5 0.0 2.5 5.0 7.5 10.0 12.5 15.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4 Densityt(5)

−10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8

0.2

0.4 DensityMixN(−1.5,1.5,4,0.25)

Figure 1: Alternative densities for vt.

5.1 Effects of misspecification: A simple illustration

Consider the time series of interest yt being generated according to the following GARCH(1,1)-AR(1) process (every-

thing evaluated at the parameter vector)

yt = σtǫt, (15)

ǫt = φ0ǫt−1 + vt, (16)

where vt is white noise and σ2t = 1 + αy2

t−1 + βσ2t−1. Assume, for simplicity that a) the researchers primary interest

is in estimating φ0 and b) that she can observe the conditional variance function perfectly. However, the researcher

“wrongly” assumes that the model is given by an AR(1)-GARCH(1,1), hence uses the representation in the mean

given as

yt = φyt−1 + σtvt, (17)

for estimation of the parameter φ0. The main interest is to analyze the consequences of using the wrong model and to

establish the asymptotic properties of the estimator of φ based on (17) given that σt is known and data is generated

from (15). When σt is known, a proper estimator of φ0 is the WLS (Weighted Least Squares) estimator φ given as

φ =1T

∑σ−2

t ytyt−1

1T

∑σ−2

t y2t−1

, (18)

= φ0

1T

∑(σ2

t /σ2t−1

)1/2 (σ−2

t y2t−1

)

1T

∑σ−2

t y2t−1

+ op(1),

10

Page 11: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

0.2

0.4

0.6 GARCH: (α ,β) =(0.4,0.6) and vt ~ N(0,1)

φ0

|plim ( φ−φ0)/ φ0|

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

0.25

0.50

0.75

GARCH: (α ,β) =(0.4,0.6) and vt ~ t(5)

φ0

|plim ( φ−φ0)/ φ0|

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0 GARCH: (α ,β) =(0.4,0.6) and vt ~ MixN(−1.5,1.5,4,0.25)

φ0

|plim ( φ−φ0)/ φ0|

Figure 2: Measures of absolute relative inconsistency for alternative values of |φ0| and alternative distributional

assumptions.

For simplicity assume that y2t

a.s.→ ∞. Then from straightforward calculations we have σ−2t y2

t−1 → 1/α, and σ2t /σ2

t−1 =

1/σ2t−1 + αǫ2t−1+ β. By inserting in (18) it follows that

∣∣∣∣∣∣

plim(φ − φ0

)

φ0

∣∣∣∣∣∣=

∣∣∣∣plim

(1

T

∑(αǫ2t−1 + β

)1/2)− 1

∣∣∣∣ . (19)

We will denote∣∣∣plim

(φ − φ0

)/φ0

∣∣∣ as the measure of absolute relative inconsistency. From (19) it can be seen that

estimating φ0 based on (17) when (15) is the actual data generating process generally leads to relative inconsistency

except in the trivial case when φ0 = 0. In general plim 1T

∑(αǫ2t−1 + β

)1/2can be far away from unity in particular

for larger values of |φ0| that will generate a large variance of ǫ2t−1.

To quantify the measure of absolute relative inconsistency under different distributional assumptions on vt and

for alternative values of |φ0| we next conduct a small simulation study. We consider vt being generated from three

alternative densities depicted in Figure 1. As we expect the relative inconsistency to grow with the variance of vt,

we include the standard Gaussian density as well as a student t-density with 5 degrees of freedom and a Gaussian

mixture density.

In Figure 2 we have depicted the measure of absolute relative asymptotic inconsistency for alternative values of |φ0|when (α, β) = (0.4, 0.6). Not surprisingly, the inconsistencies become more severe as the variance of ǫt−1 increases.

Note that var(ǫt−1) increases with φ0 and when the density of vt goes from the normal to densities with fatter tails such

as the student-t and Gaussian mixture. Such fat-tailed distributions are common in financial time series. In general

the inconsistencies seem significant even for very small values of |φ0| ranging from 5% in the Gaussian case to about

11

Page 12: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

45% for the Gaussian mixture. This simple example stresses that careful model evaluation is needed to determine

whether to model the dynamics in the innovation terms or in the conditional mean function, particularly when the

density of the data exhibit fat-tail behavior. This evidence emphasizes again that the choice between the traditional

AR-GARCH model with constant AR coefficients in the mean equation versus the GARCH-AR with variable AR

coefficients potentially is of great importance.

5.2 Empirical illustration

Based on monthly data from January 1984 to March 2005 on the US 3 and 6 month treasury bill spot rates we com-

pare the estimated AR-GARCH model and GARCH-AR models. We also consider the AR-GARCH-M specification.

Following the theoretical framework by Cox, Ingersoll and Ross (1985), we consider the following general empirical

model for the spot interest rates, denoted rt, given by

∆rt = φ0 + φ1rt−1 + φ2 log σt +

p1∑

i=1

φi∆rt−1−i + zt,

zt = σtǫt,

ǫt =

p2∑

i=1

ρiǫt−1−i + vt,

vt ∼ i.i.d.(0, 1),

where

σ2t = α0 + αz2

t−1 + βσ2t−1,

for the AR(p1)-GARCH (see e.g. Ling and McAleer (2003) for a general definition of AR-GARCH models) and

σ2t = α0 + α∆r2

t−1 + βσ2t−1,

for the GARCH-AR(p2) specification. Since the limiting properties of the estimated parameters in the GARCH-AR

model have been derived under the assumption that φ0 = φ1 = φ2 = 0 and φ1 = φ2 = ... = φp1= 0, we will estimate

the model under this assumption and test the validity of the assumption using a series of robust misspecification tests

proposed by Wooldridge (1991). Similarly, the limiting properties of the estimated parameters in the AR-GARCH is

valid only if ρ1 = ρ2 = ... = ρp2= 0 (as in Ling and McAleer (2003)), and again we estimate the model under this

assumption and test its validity using the robust tests suggested by Wooldridge (1991).

The estimation results are reported in Table 1. To minimize the size of the table, let xt−i−1 = ∆rt−1−i in relation

to the AR-GARCH columns and let xt−i−1 = ǫt−1−i in the GARCH-AR columns. Similarly, let y2t−1 =z2

t−1 and y2t−1

=∆r2t−1 in the AR-GARCH and GARCH-AR columns respectively. It should be noted that although the parameters

entering the conditional mean function are practical identically, the estimated coefficients in the conditional variance

equation differ substantially between the AR-GARCH and GARCH-AR specification. Note also, that the parameters in

the conditional variance seem to be much more precisely estimated in the GARCH-AR model. We have also considered

the AR-GARCH-M specification, but the risk premium effect through the model of Engle, Lilien and Robins (1987)

seems not to be statistically significant in this framework. We show however, that there are risk premium effects but

iterating with lags of the first difference of the treasury bill spot rates (what our model is able to generate). Various

12

Page 13: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

Table 1: Estimation results for the GARCH-AR and AR-GARCH specification for the change in the 3 and 6 months

US. t-bill spot rates. The sample period is January 1984 to March 2005.

change in 3m t-bill change in 6m t-bill

GARCH-AR AR-GARCH GARCH-AR AR-GARCH

xt−1 0.398*** 0.388*** 0.418*** 0.456***

(0.076) (0.081) (0.070) (0.067)

xt−2 -0.098 -0.089 -0.117* -0.110

(0.060) (0.076) (0.064) (0.079)

xt−3 0.165** 0.223** 0.138** 0.161***

(0.068) (0.093) (0.063) (0.057)

xt−6 0.182*** 0.188*** 0.158*** 0.163***

(0.056) (0.054) (0.050) (0.052)

xt−13 -0.166*** -0.128** -0.158*** -0.101*

(0.056) (0.054) (0.057) (0.053)

ω0 0.006** 0.009 0.003*** 0.010***

(0.003) (0.006) (0.001) (0.004)

y2t−1 0.153** 0.387** 0.166*** 0.396**

(0.069) (0.193) (0.038) (0.183)

σ2t−1 0.576*** 0.339 0.690*** 0.356*

(0.147) (0.275) (0.057) (0.200)

Log likelihood 307.740 308.192 290.213 289.757

AIC 2.350 2.354 2.213 2.210

s.e. in parenthesis. p-values in brackets.

’*’: significant on 10 percent level, double-sided (normal dist.).

’**’: significant on 5 percent level, double-sided (normal dist.).

’***’: significant on 1 percent level, double-sided (normal dist.).

13

Page 14: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

Table 2: Specification testing and forecast performance results for the GARCH-AR and AR-GARCH models for the

change in the 3 and 6 months US. t-bill spot rates. The sample period is January 1984 to March 2005.

change in 3m t-bill change in 6m t-bill

GARCH-AR AR-GARCH GARCH-AR AR-GARCH

LB[10] 7.892 15.293 8.278 9.084

[0.639] [0.122] [0.602] [0.524]

LB[20] 20.613 29.353 18.443 22.623

[0.420] [0.081] [0.558] [0.308]

LB[40] 42.600 48.637 40.049 44.269

[0.360] [0.164] [0.468] [0.296]

Wooldridge 1 3.740* 10.164*** 3.182* 5.438**

[0.053] [0.001] [0.074] [0.020]

Wooldridge 2.1 1.469 0.007 1.146 0.429

[0.225] [0.934] [0.284] [0.512]

Wooldridge 2.2 .870 1.484 2.365 1.411

[0.171] [0.223] [0.124] [0.234]

Wooldridge 2.3 0.984 0.464 1.193 0.372

[0.321] [0.496] [0.274] [0.541]

Out-of-sample MSFE 0.024 0.026 0.023 0.024

LB[XX] is the Ljung-Box test for neglected serial dependence up to order XX.

Wooldridge 1 is Wooldridge’s (1991) robust test for neglected serial dependence.

Wooldridge 2.1 is the robust test for omitted variable, see, e.g., Wooldridge’s (1991)

For the AR-GARCH models the omitted variables is σtσ−1t−1xt−1 while

it is xt−1 for the GARCH-AR models.

Wooldridge 2.2 is as 2.1, but where the omitted variable is the level of the interest rates.

Wooldridge 2.3 is as 2.1, but where the omitted variable is log(σ2t )

Models estimated for 1984m1-1999m12 and MSFE is computed using the out-of-sample

period 2000m1-2005m3.

14

Page 15: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

−0.50

−0.25

0.00

0.25 D3m GARCH−AR

AR−GARCH

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

−0.50

−0.25

0.00

0.25 D6m GARCH−AR

AR−GARCH

Figure 3: Out-of-sample forecasts

misspecification test are reported in Table 2. Moreover, it is important to note that we have not found asymmetric

volatility effects in our data. Although all the models pass the Ljung-Box tests, the AR-GARCH models could not be

augmented with lags such that there was no evidence of neglected serial correlation according to Wooldridge 1. On

the contrary there is no evidence of neglected serial correlation in the GARCH-AR models. Based on all models we

cannot reject that φ0 = φ1 = φ2 = 0.

Finally, we look at the out-of sample forecast accuracy of the two models. We estimate the parameters for all

models based on the sample from January 1984 to December 2000, and based on the remaining part of the sample we

compute the mean squared forecast errors which in Table 2 is referred to as out-of-sample MSFE. It turns out that

the GARCH-AR improves the forecast accuracy over the AR-GARCH model by about 5%. However, perhaps more

importantly it can be seen from Figure 3 that the main difference between the models forecast seems to be in periods

with “larger” variance or higher probability of more extreme observation. Note that the GARCH-AR model is able to

generate these “extreme” forecast, something that the AR-GARCH seems not to be able to do in the two illustrations.

To sum up, the new GARCH-AR model passes all the diagnostic tests at the 5% level in both applications,

while the AR-GARCH have problems passing some of the Wooldridge diagnostic tests at the 5% level. Moreover,

the new GARCH-AR model produces a better MSFE relative to the AR-GARCH in both applications. Following

Hansen and Lunde (2005), the regular AR-GARCH model beats most alternative GARCH models in terms of better

relative forecasting performance. But this is not the case in the two empirical application presented here, where the

GARCH-AR model - not considered by Hansen and Lunde (2005) - beats the regular AR-GARCH.

6 Conclusion

In this paper we introduce a new parametric volatility model that allows for serially dependent innovations in GARCH

specifications. We first prove the asymptotic normality of the QML estimator in this setting, allowing for possible

15

Page 16: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

explosive and nonstationary behavior of the GARCH. We also show that this model is capable of generating an

alternative measure of risk premium relative to the GARCH-M model of Engle, Lilien and Robins (1987). In particular

the model generates iteration effects between functions of the conditional volatility and lags of the dependent variable

of interest. Finally, we provide evidence of the usefulness of our approach in a Monte Carlo experiment and in practical

applications. We first show the consequences of dynamically misspecifying the GARCH model when the actual data

generating mechanism is an GARCH-AR specification. We provide evidence of the large inconsistencies that this type

of misspecification can generate. Finally we show, using US interest rates, how the new model can improve the fit

in-sample as well as out-of-sample relative to traditional GARCH type models. This evidence hereby strongly supports

the empirical relevance of the GARCH-AR model.

Appendix 1

Proof of Lemma 1 Let Assumption A hold and write the process

σ2t = w0 +

(α0ǫ

2t−1 + β0

)σ2

t−1 = Bt + Atσ2t−1,

where At =(α0ǫ

2t−1 + β0

)and Bt = w0. Then, applying Theorem 1.1 of Bougerol and Picard (1992a, page 1715),

we verify the conditions that E (log (max ‖1, A0‖)) < ∞, E (log (max ‖1, B0‖)) < ∞ (since by Assumption A

w0, α0, β0 > 0), and also σ2t is strictly stationary if the Lyapunov exponent τ

τ = inf

E

(1

T + 1log ‖A0···AT ‖

)< 0.

In the case of one-dimensional recurrence equations

1

T + 1E (log |A0···AT |) =

1

T + 1

T∑

i=0

E log |Ai| = E log |A0| < 0.

Therefore, σ2t is strictly stationary if

E log |A0| = E log(α0ǫ

2t + β0

)< 0.

This provides the conditions under which σ2t is strictly stationary. Since the pair

(yt, σ

2t

)´ =

(σtǫt, σ

2t

)´ is a fixed

function of(σ2

t , ǫt

)´which is ergodic and strictly stationary, then it follows that if

(σ2

t , ǫt

)´is strictly stationary, then

(σtǫt, σ

2t

)´is also strictly stationary.

We note that this is the same sufficient and necessary condition when we have and i.i.d. process in ǫt. Therefore,

we prove that the results carry over from the i.i.d. case to the ergodic and strictly stationary framework. This is not

a trivial result, since almost all theory in the literature is developed only for strong GARCH processes.

16

Page 17: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

Proof of Lemma 2 Let Assumption A hold. By recursions,

σ2t = w0 +

(α0ǫ

2t−1 + β0

)σ2

t−1, (20)

= Bt + Atσ2t−1,

= At···A1σ20 +

t−1∑

i=0

At···At−i+1Bt−i,

= σ21t + σ2

2t,

where σ21t = At···A1σ

20 and σ2

2t =∑t−1

i=0 At···At−i+1Bt−i. Since σ22t is always positive (and β0 and w0 are always positive

by Assumption A), it suffices to show thatlog σ2

1t

t

a.s.−→ E log(α0ǫ

2t + β0

)≥ 0. After taking logarithms and dividing by

t in the expression for σ21t in (20) we obtain

log σ21t

t=

∑t−1i=0 log

(α0ǫ

2t−i + β0

)+ log σ2

0

t,

and by the strong law of large numbers for ergodic and strictly stationary processes, when E log At ≥ 0, and as t → ∞,log σ2

1t

t

a.s.−→ E log(α0ǫ

2t + β0

)≥ 0, since

log σ2

0

t

a.s.−→ 0.

Proof of Theorem 1 In order to allow for nonstationarity in the GARCH along the lines of Jensen and Rahbek

(2004a, 2004b), we first find the expressions for the first, second and third order derivatives (Lemmas 1 and 2 are used

in our results). Later, Lemmas 3, 4 and 5 establish the Cramer type conditions. As in Jensen and Rahbek (2004a,

2004b) we also use the central limit theorem in Brown (1971). In order to make our results clear, we order the terms

of the derivatives to find a similar structure as in Jensen and Rahbek (2004a, 2004b), in all those cases where this is

possible. We also use Lemma 1 of Jensen and Rahbek (2004b) to prove uniqueness and the existence of the consistent

and asymptotically Gaussian estimator.

Result 1: First order derivatives The first order derivatives are given by

∂zlT (θ) = −1

2

T∑

t=1

(

1 −(yt − ρσt (θ)σ−1

t−1 (θ) yt−1

)2

σ2t (θ)

)∂σ2

t (θ)∂z

σ2t (θ)

+

∂(yt−ρσt(θ)σ−1

t−1(θ)yt−1)

2

∂z

σ2t (θ)

; ∀z = α, β,

with

∂αlT (θ) =

T∑

t=1

s1t (θ) ,

∂βlT (θ) =

T∑

t=1

s2t (θ) ,

∂ρlT (θ) =

T∑

t=1

s3t (θ) =

T∑

t=1

(yt − ρσt (θ)σ−1

t−1 (θ) yt−1

)σ−1

t−1 (θ) yt−1

σt (θ),

17

Page 18: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

where

∂σ2

t (θ)∂α

σ2t (θ)

=

∑Tj=1 βj−1y2

t−j

σ2t (θ)

,

∂σ2

t (θ)∂β

σ2t (θ)

=

T∑

j=1

βj−1σ2

t−j (θ)

σ2t (θ)

,

∂(yt − ρσt (θ)σ−1

t−1 (θ) yt−1

)2

∂z=

−(yt − ρσt (θ)σ−1

t−1 (θ) yt−1

)ρyt−1

(1 + αy2

t−2 + βσ2t−2 (θ)

)3/2 (1 + αy2

t−1 + βσ2t−1 (θ)

)1/2

×((

1 + αy2t−2 + βσ2

t−2 (θ)) ∂σ2

t (θ)

∂z−(1 + αy2

t−1 + βσ2t−1 (θ)

) ∂σ2t−1 (θ)

∂z

),

for ∀z = α, β.

Lemma 3 Let Assumption B hold. Define sit = sit (θ0) , ∀i = 1, 2, 3 where sit (θ0) is defined in Result 1. Then

1√T

T∑

t=1

s1td−→ N

(0,

ζ

4α20

),

1√T

T∑

t=1

s2td−→ N

(0,

ζ (1 + µ1)µ2

4β20 (1 − µ1) (1 − µ2)

),

1√T

T∑

t=1

s3td−→ N

(0,

1

(1 − ρ20)

),

with µi = E(β0/

(α0ǫ

2t + β0

))i, i = 1, 2 as T −→ ∞.

Proof of Lemma 3 Define It−1 = yt−1, yt−2, ....As in Jensen and Rahbek (2004b, Lemma 5 and its extension to

the α parameter), using the law of iterated expectations and the properties of vt, we have E (s1t|It−1) = E (s2t|It−1) =

E (s3t|It−1) = 0. Also, the proof of Lemma 3 requires that

E |s1t| < ∞, E |s2t| < ∞, E |s3t| < ∞. (21)

We prove now (21). For the first two scores, we have, evaluated at θ0

1

2

(1 − v2

t

) ∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t

+ρ0

2

vtyt−1((w0 + α0y

2t−1 + β0σ

2t−1

) ∂σ2

t−1

∂z −(w0 + α0y

2t−2 + β0σ

2t−2

) ∂σ2

t

∂z )

σ2t σ3

t−1

=

1

2

(1 − v2

t

) ∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t

+ρ0

2vtǫt−1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z

σ2t−1

−∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t

, ∀z = α, β,

where the first term follows from Lemma 5 in Jensen and Rahbek (2004b), and for the second term, note that

∣∣∣∣∣∣ρ0

2vtǫt−1

∂σ2

t−1

∂α

σ2t−1

−∂σ2

t

∂α

σ2t

∣∣∣∣∣∣≤∣∣∣ρ0

2vtǫt−1

∣∣∣

∂σ2

t−1

∂α

σ2t−1

−∂σ2

t

∂α

σ2t

.

18

Page 19: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

In addition

|vtǫt−1| =

∣∣∣∣∣∣

∞∑

j=0

ρj0vtvt−1−j

∣∣∣∣∣∣,

≤∞∑

j=0

∣∣∣ρj0

∣∣∣ |vtvt−1−j | ,

and from Holder’s inequality

E |vtvt−1−j | ≤√

E(v2t )√

E(v2t−1−j),

= E(v2t ),

= 1.

Finally, E |vtǫt−1| < ∞ (as∑

j=0

∣∣∣ρj0

∣∣∣ < ∞), and hence E |s1t| < ∞ and E |s2t| < ∞. For the third score, we have

s3t = vtǫt−1,

and from the previous results for the first and second score, it follows directly that

E |s3t| = E |vtǫt−1| < ∞.

Besides

1

T

T∑

t=1

E(s21t|It−1

)=

1

T

T∑

t=1

ζ

4

(∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t

)2

+1

T

T∑

t=1

ρ20y

2t−1

((w0 + α0y

2t−2 + β0σ

2t−2

) ∂σ2

t

∂z −(w0 + α0y

2t−1 + β0σ

2t−1

) ∂σ2

t−1

∂z

)2

4(1 + α0y2

t−2

)3 (1 + α0y2

t−1

)2

p−→ ζ

4α20

,

using Lemmas 4-6 in Jensen and Rahbek (2004b) and its extension to the α parameter, since

1

T

T∑

t=1

ζ

4

(∂σ2

t

∂α

σ2t

)2

p−→ ζ

4α20

,

and

ρ20

4T

T∑

t=1

ǫ2t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t

−∂σ2

t−1

∂z

σ2t−1

p−→ 0.

For the second score and the outer product

1

T

T∑

t=1

E(s22t|It−1

) p−→ ζ (1 + µ1)µ2

4β20 (1 − µ1) (1 − µ2)

,

1

T

T∑

t=1

E (s1ts2t|It−1)p−→ ζµ1

4α0β0 (1 − µ1),

19

Page 20: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

since

1

T

T∑

t=1

ζ

4

∂σ2

t

∂β

σ2t

2

p−→ ζ (1 + µ1)µ2

4β20 (1 − µ1) (1 − µ2)

,

following Jensen and Rahbek (2004b), Lemmas 3, 4 and 5. For the last score

1

T

T∑

t=1

E(s23t|It−1

)=

1

T

T∑

t=1

y2t−1(

1 + α0y2t−2

) ,

p−→ 1

(1 − ρ20)

,

under Assumption B. Finally, we can derive a Lindeberg type condition as in Jensen and Rahbek (2004a), where we

have

1

4

(1 − v2

t

) ∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t

+ ρ0

vtyt−1((w0 + α0y

2t−1 + β0σ

2t−1

) ∂σ2

t−1

∂z −(w0 + α0y

2t−2 + β0σ

2t−2

) ∂σ2

t

∂z )

σ2t σ3

t−1

2

=1

4[(1 − v2

t

)2(

∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t

)2

+ ρ20

v2t y2

t−1((w0 + α0y

2t−1 + β0σ

2t−1

) ∂σ2

t−1

∂z −(w0 + α0y

2t−2 + β0σ

2t−2

) ∂σ2

t

∂z )2

σ4t σ6

t−1

+2ρ0vt

(1 − v2

t

) ∂σ2

t

∂z yt−1((w0 + α0y

2t−1 + β0σ

2t−1

) ∂σ2

t−1

∂z −(w0 + α0y

2t−2 + β0σ

2t−2

) ∂σ2

t

∂z )

σ4t σ3

t−1

],

=1

4

(1 − v2

t

)2(

∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t

)2

+1

4ρ20 (vtǫt−1)

2

∂σ2

t−1

∂z

σ2t σ4

t−1

−∂σ2

t

∂z

σ4t σ2

t−1

+1

2ρ0 (vtǫt−1)

(1 − v2

t

)(

∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t

)

∂σ2

t−1

∂z

σ2t−1

−∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t

,

and

s23t = v2

t ǫ2t−1,

with the following bounds for s21t (for s2

2t, it would follow the same argument) and s23t

s21t ≤ µ2

1t ≡1

4α20

(1 − v2

t

)2+ ρ2

0 (vtǫt−1)2

+ |ρ0| |(vtǫt−1)|∣∣(1 − v2

t

)∣∣ , (22)

s23t ≤ µ2

3t ≡ v2t ǫ2t−1(1 + γ0) for 0 ≤ γ0 < ∞ . (23)

Since vt and ǫt−1 are stationary and ergodic, then also any measurable mapping of vt and ǫt−1 will be stationary and

ergodic, see, e.g., White (1984, Th. 3.35). Consequently, µ21t and µ2

3t are stationary and ergodic and it follows that

limT→∞

1

T

T∑

t=1

E(s2

itI(|sit| >

√T∂))

≤ limT→∞

1

T

T∑

t=1

E(µ2

itI(|µit| >

√T∂))

= limT→∞

E(µ2

i1I(|µi1| >

√T∂))

(24)

→ 0.

for i = 1, 2, 3. This establishes the Lindeberg type condition as in Jensen and Rahbek (2004a, 2004b).

20

Page 21: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

Result 2: Second order derivatives We have,

∂2

∂z1∂z2lT (θ) =

1

2

T∑

t=1

(

1 − 2(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

σ2t (θ)

)∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ4t (θ)

+

((yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

σ2t (θ)

− 1

)∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

σ2t (θ)

+1

2

T∑

t=1

∂2(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z1∂z2

σ2t

+

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z2

+∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z1

)

σ4t

,

∂2

∂ρ2lT (θ) = −

T∑

t=1

σ−2t−1y

2t−1,

∂2

∂z∂ρlT (θ) =

T∑

t=1

∂[(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)σtσ−1

t−1yt−1]

∂z

σ2t

−(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)σ−1

t−1yt−1∂σ2

t

∂z

σ3t

,

where

∂2σ2

t

∂α2

σ2t

= 2

∑Tj=1 (j − 1)βj−2y2

t−j

σ2t

,

∂2σ2

t

∂β2

σ2t

= 2

t∑

j=1

(j − 1)βj−2σ2

t−j

σ2t

,

∂[(

yt − ρσtσ−1t−1yt−1

)σtσ

−1t−1yt−1

]

∂z=

ytyt−1

2σtσt−1

∂σ2

t

∂z− σ2

t∂σ2

t−1

∂z

σ2t−1

− ρy2

t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t−1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z

σ4t−1

,

and

∂2(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

∂z1∂z2=

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)(−ρyt−1)

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

+ σ2t−1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

− ∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z1∂z2

σ3t−1σt

+(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)(ρyt−1)

(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)(3

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

σt + σ2t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ−1t

)

2σ5t−1σ

2t

+ρ2y2t−1

[σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

] [σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

]

2σ6t−1σ

2t

,

for ∀z, z1, z2 = α, β. Then

Lemma 4 Under Assumption B, with the expressions of the second order derivatives from Result 2 evaluated at θ0

(a) 1T

(− ∂2

∂α2 lT (θ) |θ=θ0

)p−→ 1

2α2

0

> 0,

(b) 1T

(− ∂2

∂β2 lT (θ) |θ=θ0

)p−→ (1+µ1)µ2

2β2

0(1−µ1)(1−µ2)

> 0,

(c) 1T

(− ∂2

∂α∂β lT (θ) |θ=θ0

)p−→ µ1

2α0β0(1−µ1) ,

(d) 1T

(− ∂2

∂α∂ρ lT (θ) |θ=θ0

)p−→ 0,

21

Page 22: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

(e) 1T

(− ∂2

∂β∂ρ lT (θ) |θ=θ0

)p−→ 0,

(f) 1T

(− ∂2

∂ρ2 lT (θ) |θ=θ0

)p−→ 1

(1−ρ2

0)> 0,

as T −→ ∞.

Proof of Lemma 4 For expressions (a), (b) and (c)

− 1

2T

T∑

t=1

(

1 − 2(yt − ρ0σtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

σ2t

)∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ4t

+

((yt − ρ0σtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

σ2t

− 1

)∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

σ2t

p−→ 1

2α20

, with z1 = z2 = α,

p−→ (1 + µ1)µ2

2β20 (1 − µ1) (1 − µ2)

, with z1 = z2 = β,

p−→ µ1

2α0β0 (1 − µ1), with z1 = α and z2 = β,

because of Lemma 6 in Jensen and Rahbek (2004b), and its extension to α and the cross products of α and β. Also

− 1

2T

T∑

t=1

∂2(yt−ρ0σtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z1∂z2

σ2t

+

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂(yt−ρ0σtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z2

+∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂(yt−ρ0σtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z1

)

σ4t

p−→ 0; ∀z1, z2 = α, β,

by using again Lemmas 3 and 4 in Jensen and Rahbek (2004b) and the same results as in Lemma 3 for our score. An

expression of the most complicated term in the previous expression is

ρ20

4T

T∑

t=1

y2t−1

σ2t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ4t

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

+∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)

σ2t−1σ

2t

−∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

σ4t−1

p−→ 0; ∀z1, z2 = α, β.

For expressions (d) and (e)

− 1

T

T∑

t=1

∂[(yt−ρ0σtσ−1

t−1yt−1)σtσ−1

t−1yt−1]

∂z

σ2t

−(yt − ρ0σtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)σ−1

t−1yt−1∂σ2

t

∂z

σ3t

p−→ 0; ∀z = α, β,

since

1

T

T∑

t=1

ρ0y2t−1

σ2t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t

−∂σ2

t−1

∂z

σ2t−1

− ytyt−1

2σtσt−1

∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t

−∂σ2

t−1

∂z

σ2t−1

p−→ 0; ∀z = α, β,

and by a simple application again of Lemmas 3 and 4 in Jensen and Rahbek (2004b). Finally, expression (f)

1

T

T∑

t=1

σ−2t−1y

2t−1 =

1

T

T∑

t=1

ǫ2t−1

p−→ 1

(1 − ρ20)

,

by Assumption B.

22

Page 23: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

Result 3: Third order derivatives We have,

∂3

∂z21∂z2

lT (θ) = −1

2

T∑

t=1

(1 −

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

σ2t

) ∂3σ2

t

∂z2

1∂z2

σ2t

−T∑

t=1

(1 − 3

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

σ2t

) (∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ6t

+T∑

t=1

12

(∂2(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z2

1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

+∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

∂(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z2

)

σ4t

+T∑

t=1

(∂2(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z1∂z2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

+∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

∂(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z1

)

σ4t

−T∑

t=1

(2

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

σ2t

− 1

) ( ∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

+ 12

∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ4t

− 1

2

T∑

t=1

∂3(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z2

1∂z2

σ2t

−T∑

t=1

(∂(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z2

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2

+ 2∂(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z1

∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ6t

,

∂3

∂ρ3lT (θ) = 0,

∂3

∂z1∂z2∂ρlT (θ) =

T∑

t=1

2(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)σtσ

−1t−1yt−1

∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ6t

+T∑

t=1

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)σtσ

−1t−1yt−1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

σ4t

+1

2

T∑

t=1

∂3(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z1∂z2∂ρ

σ2t

+

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂2(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z2∂ρ +∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂2(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z1∂ρ

)

σ4t

,

and

∂3

∂z∂ρ2lT (θ) =

T∑

t=1

y2t−1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z

σ4t−1

,

∂3σ2

t

∂α3

σ2t

= 3

∑Tj=1 (j − 1) (j − 2)βj−3y2

t−j

σ2t

,

∂3σ2

t

∂β3

σ2t

= 3

t∑

j=1

(j − 1) (j − 2)βj−3σ2

t−j

σ2t

,

23

Page 24: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

for ∀z, z1, z2 = α, β where

∂3(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

∂z21∂z2

= −ρyt−1

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)[

(∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

+∂3σ2

t−1

∂z2

1∂z2

σ2t−1 −

∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z2

1

− σ2t

∂3σ2

t−1

∂z2

1∂z2

)

σ3t−1σt

(σ2

t−1∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z2

1

)(3σt−1σt

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

+ σ−1t σ3

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

2σ6t−1σ

2t

(∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

+∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z1∂z2

)

σ4t−1σt

+

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)(2σ2

t−1σt∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

+ 12σ−1

t σ4t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ8t−1σ

2t

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

)

σ2t−1σ

3t

+3(

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z1∂z2

)

σ6t−1σ

−1t

+

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2 (σ3

t

2

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

+ σtσ2t−1

34

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ4t−1σ

6t

−32

(∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)2 (3σ4

t−1σ−1t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

− σ−3t σ6

t−112

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ12t−1σ

−2t

]

−ρ2y2t−1

2[

(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

)

σ3t−1σt

(2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)

σ4t−1σt

+

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2

σ2t−1σ

3t

−3(

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)2

σ6t−1σ

−1t

−2(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

+ σ2t−1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

− ∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z1∂z2

)

σ6t−1σ

2t

+

(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)(3σ4

t−1σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

+ σ6t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ12t−1σ

4t

(σ2

t−1∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z2

1

)(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

)

σ6t−1σ

2t

],

∂2(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

∂z∂ρ=

[(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)yt−1 − ρσtσ

−1t−1y

2t−1

]

σt∂σ2

t−1

∂z

σ3t−1

−∂σ2

t

∂z

σtσt−1

,

∂3(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

∂z1∂z2∂ρ=

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

+ σ2t−1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

− ∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z1∂z2

σ3t−1σt

×[ρσtσ

−1t−1y

2t−1 −

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)yt−1

]

+

(σ2

t∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

− σ2t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z1

)(3σt−1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

σt + σ3t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ−1t

)

2σ6t−1σ

2t

×[ρσtσ

−1t−1y

2t−1 −

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)yt−1

]

+2ρy2t−1

[σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

] [σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

]

2σ6t−1σ

2t

,

24

Page 25: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

again for ∀z, z1, z2 = α, β.

Definition 1 Following Jensen and Rahbek (2004b), we introduce the following lower and upper bounds on each

parameter in θ0 as

wL < w0 < wU ; αL < α0 < αU ,

βL < β0 < βU ; γL < γ0 < γU ; ρL < ρ0 < ρU ,

and we define the neighborhood N (θ0) around θ0 as

N (θ0) = θ\wL ≤ w ≤ wU , αL ≤ α ≤ αU , βL ≤ β ≤ βU , γL < γ < γU and ρL ≤ ρ ≤ ρU . (25)

Lemma 5 Under Assumption B, there exists a neighborhood N (θ0) given by (25) in Definition 1 for which

(a) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ ∂3

∂α3 lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w1t, (b) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ ∂3

∂β3 lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w2t,

(c) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂ρ3 lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w3t, (d) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂α2∂β lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w4t,

(e) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂α2∂ρ lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w5t, (f) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂β2∂ρ lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w6t,

(g) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂α∂β2 lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w7t, (h) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂α∂ρ2 lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w8t,

(i) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂β∂ρ2 lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w9t , (j) sup

θ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂α∂β∂ρ lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w10t,

where w1t, ..., w9t and w10t are stationary and have finite moments, E (wit) = Mi < ∞, ∀i = 1, ..., 10. Furthermore1T

∑Tt=1 wit

a.s.−→ Mi, ∀i = 1, ..., 10.

Proof of Lemma 5 In this proof we change the notation slightly. We first define σ2t when the conditional variance

is evaluated at θ, and σ2t (θ0) when it is evaluated at the true parameter. By definition

(yt − ρσt (θ0)σ−1

t−1 (θ0) yt−1

)2

σ2t (θ0)

= v2t .

For expressions (a), (b), (d) and (g), then w1t (θ) , w2t (θ) , w4t (θ) and w7t (θ) are given by

−1

2

T∑

t=1

(1 −

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

σ2t

) ∂3σ2

t

∂z2

1∂z2

σ2t

−T∑

t=1

(1 − 3

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

σ2t

) (∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ6t

−T∑

t=1

(2

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

σ2t

− 1

) ( ∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

+ 12

∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ4t

,

with z1 and z2 being the corresponding α and β that are needed. If in all the three previous ratios we replace(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

σ2

t

by

σ2t (θ0)

σ2t

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2(yt − ρσt (θ0) σ−1

t−1 (θ0) yt−1

)2 v2t ,

then, using Lemmas 3 and 9 of Jensen and Rahbek (2004b) as in their Lemma 10, and knowing that

σ2t (θ0)

σ2t

≤ R1 < ∞;σ2

t

σ2t (θ0)

≤ R2 < ∞ ,

25

Page 26: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

therefore

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2(yt − ρ0σt (θ0)σ−1

t−1 (θ0) yt−1

)2 v2t =

(y2

t + ρ2σ2t σ−2

t−1σ2t−1 (θ0) ǫ2t−1 − 2ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1yt

)

σ2t (θ0)

,

≤ ǫ2t + ρ2 σ2t

σ2t (θ0)

σ2t−1 (θ0)

σ2t−1

ǫ2t−1 +σ2

t

σ2t (θ0)

√σ2

t−1 (θ0)

σ2t−1

2 |ρ| |ǫt−1ǫt| ,

≤ ǫ2t + ρ2R1R2ǫ2t−1 + 2 |ρ|R2

√R1 |ǫt−1ǫt| ,

and, for example, for the second of the previous ratios

D1 ≡(

3σ2

t (θ0)

σ2t

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2(yt − ρσt (θ0)σ−1

t−1 (θ0) yt−1

)2 v2t − 1

) (∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ6t

,

≤(

3σ2

t (θ0)

σ2t

(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2(yt − ρσt (θ0)σ−1

t−1 (θ0) yt−1

)2 v2t + 1

) (∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ6t

,

≤ 3A(R1ǫ

2t + max

(ρ2

L, ρ2U

)R2

1R2ǫ2t−1 + 2 max (|ρL| , |ρU |)R2R1 |ǫt−1ǫt| + 1/3

),

≡ w∗

1t,

where A is the lower bound that is obtained in Lemma 9 of Jensen and Rahbek (2004b). Finally E (w∗

it) < ∞,

∀i = 1, 2, 4, 7 as E(ǫ2t ) < ∞, E(ǫ2t−1) < ∞ and E(|ǫt−1ǫt|) < ∞ provided that |ρ0| < 1 and E(v2t ) < ∞. For the

remaining ratios (and using the results of Lemma 4 with the same type of ratios that have been already analyzed), it

is enough to deal with the extra expression

∂3(yt − ρσtσ

−1t−1yt−1

)2

∂z21∂z2

.

The most complicated terms of the previous expression are the terms

−ρ2y2t−1

2σ2t−1

[

(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

)

σt−1σ3t

(β + αǫ2t−1

) (2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)

σ2t−1σt (σ2

t − 1)+

(β + αǫ2t−1

) (∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2

(σ2t − 1)σ3

t

−3(

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)2

σ6t−1σ

−1t

−2(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

+ σ2t−1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

− ∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z1∂z2

)

σ6t−1σ

4t

+

(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)(3σ4

t−1σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

+ σ6t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ12t−1σ

6t

(σ2

t−1∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z2

1

)(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

)

σ6t−1σ

4t

],

for ∀z1, z2 = α, β, where we have re-arranged the terms and used the fact that σ2t−1 =

(σ2

t −1)(β+αǫ2

t−1). Applying Lemma 9 of

Jensen and Rahbek (2004b) directly again, we get that the previous expectation is bounded. The proof for expression

26

Page 27: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

(c) is trivial. For the proof of expressions (e) (f) and (j), we need to consider the extra ratios

∂3(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z1∂z2∂ρ

σ2t

, and

∂2(yt−ρσtσ−1

t−1yt−1)

2

∂z∂ρ

σ2t

.

For the first term, we use the law of iterated expectations and the fact that

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

+ σ2t−1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

− ∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z1∂z2

σ2t−1σ

2t

[ρy2

t−1

σ2t−1

],

and

(σ2

t∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

− σ2t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z1

)(3σt−1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

σt + σ3t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ−1t

)

2σ5t−1σ

3t

[ρy2

t−1

σ2t−1

],

as well as

2ρy2t−1

σ2t−1

[σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

] [σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

]

2σ4t−1σ

4t

,

for ∀z1, z2 = α, β are all bounded. For the second term we need

[ρy2

t−1

σ2t−1

]

∂σ2

t−1

∂z

σ2t−1

−∂σ2

t

∂z

σ2t

,

which is also bounded. For the proof of expressions (h) and (i), we have

wit (θ) = ǫ2t−1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z

σ2t−1

; ∀z = α, β; i = 8, 9.

and due to Assumption 1, E (wit) < ∞, i = 8, 9.

Appendix 2

Proof of Theorem 3 We begin again with the first order derivatives (Lemma 6). Later, we move to the second and

third order derivatives (Lemmas 7 and 8). Brown (1971) provides the type of central limit theorem we need. Lemmas

1 and 2 also hold for the AR(p), and they are used in our proofs.

Result 4: First order derivatives The first order derivatives associated with (14) are given by (∀z = α, β)

∂zlT (θ) = −1

2

T∑

t=1

(

1 − (σt (θ) vt)2

σ2t (θ)

)∂σ2

t (θ)∂z

σ2t (θ)

+

∂(yt−∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z

σ2t (θ)

,

with

∂αlT (θ) =

T∑

t=1

s1t (θ) ,

∂βlT (θ) =

T∑

t=1

s2t (θ) ,

27

Page 28: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

and

∂ρilT (θ) =

T∑

t=1

s(2+i)t (θ) =

T∑

t=1

(σt (θ) vt) σ−1t−i (θ) yt−i

σt (θ); ∀i = 1, ..., p,

where

∂σ2

t (θ)∂α

σ2t (θ)

=

∑Tj=1 βj−1y2

t−j

σ2t (θ)

,

∂σ2

t (θ)∂β

σ2t (θ)

=

T∑

j=1

βj−1σ2

t−j (θ)

σ2t (θ)

,

∂(yt −

∑pi=1 ρiσt (θ)σ−1

t−i (θ) yt−i

)2

∂z= − (σt (θ) vt)

p∑

i=1

(σ2

t−i (θ)∂σ2

t (θ)∂z − σ2

t (θ)∂σ2

t−i(θ)

∂z

)ρiyt−i

σ3t−i (θ)σt (θ)

,

Lemma 6 Let Assumption C hold and write the scores associated with (14), derived in Result 4, as slt = slt (θ0) .

Then

1√T

T∑

t=1

s1td−→ N

(0,

ζ

4α20

),

1√T

T∑

t=1

s2td−→ N

(0,

ζ (1 + µ1)µ2

4β20 (1 − µ1) (1 − µ2)

),

1√T

T∑

t=1

s(2+i)td−→ N

(0,

1

(1 − ρ2i0)

),

for ∀i = 1, ..., p, with µj = E(β0/

(α0ǫ

2t + β0

))j, j = 1, 2 as T −→ ∞.

Proof of Lemma 6 The proof follows the same type of argument as Lemma 3 and the proof in Jensen and Rahbek

(2004b). Note that Lemma 6 is the same as Lemma 3, but with i = 1, ..., p. Define again It−1 = yt−1, yt−2, .... Using

the law of iterated expectations and the properties of vt, then E (s1t|It−1) = E (s2t|It−1) = E(s(2+i)t|It−1

)= 0. Also,

by the same argument as in Lemma 3

E |s1t| < ∞; E |s2t| < ∞; E∣∣s(2+i)t

∣∣ < ∞; ∀i = 1, ..., p.

In addition,

1

T

T∑

t=1

E(s21t|It−1

) p−→ ζ

4α20

,

1

T

T∑

t=1

E(s22t|It−1

) p−→ ζ (1 + µ1)µ2

4β20 (1 − µ1) (1 − µ2)

,

1

T

T∑

t=1

E (s1ts2t|It−1)p−→ ζµ1

4α0β0 (1 − µ1),

1

T

T∑

t=1

E(s2(2+i)t|It−1

)p−→ 1

(1 − ρ2i0)

.

28

Page 29: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

Result 4: Second order derivatives The second order derivatives associated with (14) are given by

∂2

∂z1∂z2lT (θ) =

1

2

T∑

t=1

(

1 − 2 (σtvt)2

σ2t

)∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ4t

+

((σtvt)

2

σ2t

− 1

)∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

σ2t

−∂2(yt−

∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z1∂z2

σ2t

+1

2

T∑

t=1

∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂(yt−∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z2

+∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂(yt−∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z1

σ4t

,

∂2

∂ρi∂ρjlT (θ) = −

T∑

t=1

σ−1t−iyt−iσ

−1t−jyt−j ,

∂2

∂z∂ρilT (θ) =

T∑

t=1

∂[(yt−∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)σtσ−1

t−iyt−i]

∂z

σ2t

−T∑

t=1

(σtvt)σ−1t−iyt−i

∂σ2

t

∂z

σ3t

,

for ∀i, j = 1, ..., p,and ∀z, z1, z2 = α, β, where

∂2σ2

t

∂α2

σ2t

= 2

∑Tj=1 (j − 1)βj−2y2

t−j

σ2t

,

∂2σ2

t

∂β2

σ2t

= 2

t∑

j=1

(j − 1)βj−2σ2

t−j

σ2t

,

∂2 (σtvt)2

∂z1∂z2= − (σtvt)

(ρ1yt−1)

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

+ σ2t−1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

− ∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z1∂z2

σ3t−1σt

−... − (σtvt)

(ρpyt−p)

∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

+ σ2t−p

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

− ∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−p

∂z1∂z2

σ3t−pσt

+ (σtvt)

(ρ1yt−1)

(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)(3

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

σt + σ2t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ−1t

)

2σ5t−1σ

2t

+... + (σtvt)

(ρpyt−p)

(σ2

t−p∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

)(3

∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

σt + σ2t−p

∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ−1t

)

2σ5t−pσ

2t

+ρ21y

2t−1

[σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

] [σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

]

2σ6t−1σ

2t

+... + ρ2py

2t−p

[σ2

t−p∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

] [σ2

t−p∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

]

2σ6t−pσ

2t

,

29

Page 30: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

and

∂[(

yt −∑p

i=1 ρiσt (θ)σ−1t−i (θ) yt−i

)σtσ

−1t−iyt−i

]

∂z= −ytyt−i

2

[σtσ

−3t−i

∂σ2t−i

∂z− σ−1

t σ−1t−i

∂σ2t

∂z

]

− ρ1yt−1yt−i

[σ−1

t−1σ−1t−i

∂σ2t

∂z− σ2

t

2

[σ3

t−1σ−1t−i

∂σ2t−1

∂z+ σ−1

t−1σ−3t−i

∂σ2t−i

∂z

]]

− ... − ρpyt−pyt−i

[σ−1

t−pσ−1t−i

∂σ2t

∂z− σ2

t

2

[σ3

t−pσ−1t−i

∂σ2t−p

∂z+ σ−1

t−pσ−3t−i

∂σ2t−i

∂z

]].

Lemma 7 Under Assumption C, with the expressions of the second order derivatives given by Result 5 and evaluated

at θ0

(a) 1T

(− ∂2

∂α2 lT (θ) |θ=θ0

)p−→ 1

2α2

0

> 0,

(b) 1T

(− ∂2

∂β2 lT (θ) |θ=θ0

)p−→ (1+µ1)µ2

2β2

0(1−µ1)(1−µ2)

> 0,

(c) 1T

(− ∂2

∂α∂β lT (θ) |θ=θ0

)p−→ µ1

2α0β0(1−µ1) ,

(d) 1T

(− ∂2

∂α∂ρilT (θ) |θ=θ0

)p−→ 0, ∀i = 1, ..., p,

(e) 1T

(− ∂2

∂β∂ρilT (θ) |θ=θ0

)p−→ 0, ∀i = 1, ..., p,

(f) 1T

(− ∂2

∂ρ2

i

lT (θ) |θ=θ0

)p−→ 1

(1−ρ2

i0)> 0, ∀i = 1, ..., p,

with µj = E(β0/

(α0ǫ

2t + β0

))j, j = 1, 2 as T −→ ∞.

Proof of Lemma 7 The proof follows the same type of arguments as in Lemma 4. Note that Lemma 7 is the same

as Lemma 4, but for i = 1, ..., p. All the results of the proof of Lemma 4 apply here directly.

30

Page 31: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

Result 6: Third order derivatives The third order derivatives associated with (14) are given by

∂3

∂z21∂z2

lT (θ) = −1

2

T∑

t=1

(1 − (σtvt)

2

σ2t

) ∂3σ2

t

∂z2

1∂z2

σ2t

−T∑

t=1

(2(σtvt)

2

σ2t

− 1

) ( ∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

+ 12

∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ4t

−T∑

t=1

(1 − 3 (σtvt)

2

σ2t

) (∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ6t

− 1

2

T∑

t=1

∂3(yt−∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z2

1∂z2

σ2t

+

T∑

t=1

(12

∂2(yt−∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z2

1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

+∂2(yt−

∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z1∂z2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

)

σ4t

+

T∑

t=1

(12

∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

∂(yt−∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z2

+∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

∂(yt−∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z1

)

σ4t

−T∑

t=1

(∂(yt−

∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z2

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2

+ 2∂(yt−

∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z1

∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ6t

,

∂3

∂z1∂z2∂ρilT (θ) =

T∑

t=1

2 (σtvt)σtyt−i∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

σt−iσ6t

+

T∑

t=1

(σtvt)σtyt−i∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

σt−iσ4t

−T∑

t=1

∂3(yt−∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z1∂z2∂ρi

2σ2t

+1

2

T∑

t=1

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂2(yt−∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z2∂ρi+

∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂2(yt−∑p

i=1ρiσt(θ)σ−1

t−i(θ)yt−i)

2

∂z1∂ρi

)

σ4t

,

∂3

∂z∂ρi∂ρjlT (θ) =

T∑

t=1

yt−iyt−j

(σt−i

∂σt−j

∂z + σt−j∂σt−i

∂z

)

σ2t−iσ

2t−j

,

∂3

∂ρi∂ρj∂ρklT (θ) = 0,

for ∀z1, z2 = α, β and ∀i, j, k = 1, ..., p where

∂3σ2

t

∂α3

σ2t

= 3

∑Tj=1 (j − 1) (j − 2)βj−3y2

t−j

σ2t

,

∂3σ2

t

∂β3

σ2t

= 3

t∑

j=1

(j − 1) (j − 2)βj−3σ2

t−j

σ2t

,

31

Page 32: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

and

∂3(yt −

∑pi=1 ρiσt (θ)σ−1

t−i (θ) yt−i

)2

∂z21∂z2

= −ρ1yt−1 (σtvt) [

(∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

+∂3σ2

t−1

∂z2

1∂z2

σ2t−1 −

∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z2

1

− σ2t

∂3σ2

t−1

∂z2

1∂z2

)

σ3t−1σt

(σ2

t−1∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z2

1

)(3σt−1σt

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

+ σ−1t σ3

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

2σ6t−1σ

2t

(∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

+∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z1∂z2

)

σ4t−1σt

+

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)(2σ2

t−1σt∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

+ 12σ−1

t σ4t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ8t−1σ

2t

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

)

σ2t−1σ

3t

+3(

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z1∂z2

)

σ6t−1σ

−1t

+

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2 (σ3

t

2

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

+ σtσ2t−1

34

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ4t−1σ

6t

−32

(∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)2 (3σ4

t−1σ−1t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

− σ−3t σ6

t−112

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ12t−1σ

−2t

]

−... − ρpyt−p (σtvt) [

(∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

+∂3σ2

t−p

∂z2

1∂z2

σ2t−p − ∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂2σ2

t−p

∂z2

1

− σ2t

∂3σ2

t−p

∂z2

1∂z2

)

σ3t−pσt

(σ2

t−p∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−p

∂z2

1

)(3σt−pσt

∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

+ σ−1t σ3

t−p∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

2σ6t−pσ

2t

(∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

+∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂2σ2

t−p

∂z1∂z2

)

σ4t−pσt

+

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

)(2σ2

t−pσt∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

+ 12σ−1

t σ4t−p

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ8t−pσ

2t

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

)

σ2t−pσ

3t

+3(

∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

∂2σ2

t−p

∂z1∂z2

)

σ6t−pσ

−1t

+

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2 (σ3

t

2

∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

+ σtσ2t−p

34

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ4t−pσ

6t

−32

(∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

)2 (3σ4

t−pσ−1t

∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

− σ−3t σ6

t−p12

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ12t−pσ

−2t

]

−ρ21y

2t−1

2[

(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

)

σ3t−1σt

(2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)

σ4t−1σt

+

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2

σ2t−1σ

3t

−3(

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)2

σ6t−1σ

−1t

−2(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

+ σ2t−1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

− ∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z1∂z2

)

σ6t−1σ

2t

+

(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

)(3σ4

t−1σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

+ σ6t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ12t−1σ

4t

(σ2

t−1∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z2

1

)(σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

)

σ6t−1σ

2t

]

−... −ρ2

py2t−p

2[

(σ2

t−p∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

)

σ3t−pσt

(2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

)

σ4t−pσt

+

(∂σ2

t

∂z1

)2

σ2t−pσ

3t

−3(

∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

)2

σ6t−pσ

−1t

−2(σ2

t−p∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

)(∂σ2

t

∂z1

∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

+ σ2t−p

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

− ∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−p

∂z1∂z2

)

σ6t−1σ

2t

+

(σ2

t−p1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

)(3σ4

t−pσ2t

∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

+ σ6t−p

∂σ2

t

∂z2

)

σ12t−pσ

4t

+

(σ2

t−p∂2σ2

t

∂z2

1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−p

∂z2

1

)(σ2

t−p∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

)

σ6t−pσ

2t

],

32

Page 33: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

for ∀z1, z2 = α, β. Furthermore,

∂2(yt −

∑pi=1 ρiσt (θ)σ−1

t−i (θ) yt−i

)2

∂z∂ρ=

[(σtvt) yt−1 − ρ1σtσ

−1t−1y

2t−1

]σt

∂σ2

t−1

∂z

σ3t−1

−∂σ2

t

∂z

σtσt−1

+... +[(σtvt) yt−p − ρpσtσ

−1t−py

2t−p

]σt

∂σ2

t−p

∂z

σ3t−p

−∂σ2

t

∂z

σtσt−p

,

∂3 (σtvt)2

∂z1∂z2∂ρ=

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

+ σ2t−1

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

− ∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−1

∂z1∂z2

σ3t−1σt

×[ρ1σtσ

−1t−1y

2t−1 − (σtvt) yt−1

]

+... +

∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

∂σ2

t

∂z1

+ σ2t−p

∂2σ2

t

∂z1∂z2

− ∂σ2

t

∂z2

∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

− σ2t

∂2σ2

t−p

∂z1∂z2

σ3t−pσt

×[ρpσtσ

−1t−py

2t−p − (σtvt) yt−p

]

+

(σ2

t∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

− σ2t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z1

)(3σt−1

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

σt + σ3t−1

∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ−1t

)

2σ6t−1σ

2t

×[ρ1σtσ

−1t−1y

2t−1 − (σtvt) yt−1

]

+... +

(σ2

t∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

− σ2t−p

∂σ2

t

∂z1

)(3σt−p

∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

σt + σ3t−p

∂σ2

t

∂z2

σ−1t

)

2σ6t−pσ

2t

×[ρpσtσ

−1t−py

2t−p − (σtvt) yt−p

]

+2ρ1y2t−1

[σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z1

] [σ2

t−1∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−1

∂z2

]

2σ6t−1σ

2t

+... + 2ρpy2t−p

[σ2

t−p∂σ2

t

∂z1

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−p

∂z1

] [σ2

t−p∂σ2

t

∂z2

− σ2t

∂σ2

t−p

∂z2

]

2σ6t−pσ

2t

,

for ∀z, z1, z2 = α, β.

Definition 2 Similar to Definition 1 we introduce lower and upper values for each parameter in θ0 as

wL < w0 < wU ; αL < α0 < αU ; βL < β0 < βU ,

γL < γ0 < γU ; ρL < ρ10 < ρU ; ...; ρL < ρp0 < ρU ,

and we define the neighborhood N (θ0) around θ0 as

N (θ0) = θ\wL ≤ w ≤ wU , αL ≤ α ≤ αU , βL ≤ β ≤ βU , γL < γ < γU , ρL < ρ1 < ρU , ρL ≤ ρp ≤ ρU , (26)

Lemma 8 Under Assumption C, there exists a neighborhood N (θ0) given (26) in Definition 2 for which

33

Page 34: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

(a) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ ∂3

∂α3 lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w1t, (b) sup

θ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ ∂3

∂β3 lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w2t,

(c) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂ρi∂ρj∂ρklT (θ)

∣∣∣ ≤ 1T

∑Tt=1 w3t, (d) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂α2∂β lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w4t,

(e) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂α2∂ρilT (θ)

∣∣∣ ≤ 1T

∑Tt=1 w5t, (f) sup

θ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂β2∂ρilT (θ)

∣∣∣ ≤ 1T

∑Tt=1 w6t,

(g) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂α∂β2 lT (θ)∣∣∣ ≤ 1

T

∑Tt=1 w7t, (h) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂α∂ρi∂ρjlT (θ)

∣∣∣ ≤ 1T

∑Tt=1 w8t,

(i) supθ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂β∂∂ρi∂ρjlT (θ)

∣∣∣ ≤ 1T

∑Tt=1 w9t, (j) sup

θ∈N(θ0)

∣∣∣ 1T

∂3

∂α∂β∂ρilT (θ)

∣∣∣ ≤ 1T

∑Tt=1 w10t,

with i, j, k = 1, ...p, where w1t, ..., w9t and w10t are stationary and have finite moments, Ewlt = Ml < ∞, ∀l =

1, ..., 10. Furthermore 1T

∑Tt=1 wlt

a.s.−→ Ml, ∀l = 1, ..., 10.

Proof of Lemma 8 The proof follows the same argument as Lemma 5. Note that Lemma 8 is the same as Lemma

5, but instead for i = 1, ..., p. All the results of the proof of Lemma 5 apply here directly.

Appendix 3

Proof of Theorem 5 The proof of Theorem 5 uses the same expressions of the first, second and third order

derivatives of Theorem 3. Lemmas 6 and 7 apply directly to the stationary region by using the ergodic theorem for

the observed information as in Jensen and Rahbek (2004a , page 641 and 2004b, Remark 4, page 1212). Lemma 8

does not use the nonstationary condition and therefore it applies directly both in the stationary and the nonstationary

case (see Jensen and Rahbek (2004b, page 1216 and Remark 5 page 1218). Brown (1971) provides the type of central

limit theorem we need. We also use Lemma 1 of Jensen and Rahbek (2004b) to prove uniqueness and the existence of

the consistent and asymptotically Gaussian estimator.

34

Page 35: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

REFERENCES

Bollerslev, T. (1986), Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity, Journal of Econometrics 31, 307-

327.

Bougerol P. and N. Picard (1992a), Strict Stationarity of Generalized Autoregressive Processes, The Annals of

Probability 20, 4, 1714-1730.

Bougerol P. and N. Picard (1992b), Stationarity of GARCH Processes and of some non-negative time series, Journal

of Econometrics 52, 115-127.

Brown, B. M. (1971), Martingale Central Limit Theorems, Annals of Mathematical Statistics 42, 59-66.

Cox, J., J. Ingersoll and S. Ross (1985), A Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates, Econometrica 53, 385-407.

Dahl, C. M., and M. Levine (2005), Nonparametric estimation of volatility models with serially dependent innovations,

Statistics and Probability Letters (forthcoming)

Drost, F. C. and T. E. Nijman (1993), Temporal Aggregation of GARCH Processes, Econometrica 61, 909-927.

Dufour, J. M., L. Khalaf, J.-T.- Bernard and I. Genest (2004), Simulation-Based Finite-Sample Tests for Heteroscedas-

ticity and ARCH Effects, Journal of Econometrics, 122, 2, 317-347.

Engle, R. F. (1982), Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity with Estimates of the Variance of United Kingdom

Inflation. Econometrica 50, 987-1007.

Engle, R. F., D. M. Lilien and R. P. Robins (1987), Estimating Time Varying Risk Premia in the Term Structure:

The ARCH-M Model, Econometrica 55, 2, 391-407.

Engle, R. F. and K. F. Kroner (1995), Multivariate Simultaneous Generalised ARCH, Econometric Theory 11, 122-

150.

Galbraith, R. F. and J. I. Galbraith (1974), On the Inverses of Some Patterned Matrices Arising in the Theory of

Stationary Time Series, Journal of Applied Probability 11, 63-71.

Goncalves, S. and H. White (2004), Maximum Likelihood and the Bootstrap for Nonlinear Dynamic Models, Journal

of Econometrics 119, 199-219.

Hamilton, J. D. (1994), Time Series Analysis. Princeton University Press, Princeton.

Hansen, P. R. and A. Lunde (2005), A Forecast Comparison of Volatility Models: Does Anything Beat a GARCH(1,1)?,

Journal of Applied Econometrics 20, 873-889.

Jensen, S. T. and A. Rahbek (2004a), Asymptotic Normality of the QML Estimator of ARCH in the Nonstationary

Case, Econometrica, 72, 2, 641-646.

35

Page 36: econ.au.dk · Asymptotic normality of the QMLE of stationary and nonstationary GARCH with serially dependent innovations∗ Christian M. Dahl† CREATES School of Economics and Management

Jensen, S. T. and A. Rahbek (2004b), Asymptotic Inference for Nonstationary GARCH, Econometric Theory 20, 6,

1203-1226.

Kristensen, D. and A. Rahbek (2005), Asymptotics of the QMLE for a Class of ARCH(q) Models, Econometric

Theory 21, 946-961.

Lee, S. and B. Hansen (1994), Asymptotic Theory for the GARCH(1,1) Quasi-Maximum Likelihood Estimator,

Econometric Theory 10, 29-52.

Ling, S. and McAleer, M. (2003), Asymptotic theory for a vector ARMA-GARCH model. Econometric Theory 19,

280-310.

Ling, S. (2004), Estimation and Testing Stationarity for Double-Autoregressive Models, Journal of the Royal Statis-

tical Society Series B 66, 1, 63-78.

Linton, O. and E. Mammen (2005), Estimating Semiparametric ARCH(∞) Models by Kernel Smoothing Methods,

Econometrica 73, 3, 771-836.

Lumsdaine, R. L. (1996), Consistency and Asymptotic Normality of the Quasi Maximum Likelihood Estimator in

IGARCH(1,1) and Covariance Stationary GARCH(1,1) Models. Econometrica 64, 3, 575-596.

Meddahi, N. and E. Renault (2004), Temporal Aggregation of Volatility Models, Journal of Econometrics 119,

355-379.

Nelson, D. B. (1990), Stationarity and Persistence in the GARCH(1,1) Model, Econometric Theory 6, 318-334.

White, H. (1984), Asymptotic Theory for Econometricians. New York: Academic Press.

Wooldridge, J. (1991), On the Application of Robust, Regression-Based Diagnostics to Models of Conditional Means

and Conditional Variances, Journal of Econometrics 47, 5-46.

36