econ 522 economics of law dan quint spring 2010 lecture 21

46
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

Upload: christopher-geoffrey-caldwell

Post on 17-Jan-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

2  Formulated the goal of the legal process  Minimize social costs, which consist of:  Administrative costs, and  Error costs  Broke the legal process into a series of steps, and discussed a couple of them  Today:  More on the legal process  Crime and criminal law Last Wednesday, we…

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

Econ 522Economics of Law

Dan QuintSpring 2010Lecture 21

Page 2: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

2

The legalprocess

Page 3: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

3

Formulated the goal of the legal process Minimize social costs, which consist of: Administrative costs, and Error costs

Broke the legal process into a series of steps, and discussed a couple of them

Today: More on the legal process Crime and criminal law

Last Wednesday, we…

Page 4: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

4

Stages of the legal process…decision to pursue a legal claimbargaining over out-of-court settlementspre-trial exchange of informationtrial itselfappeals process

Page 5: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

5

Stages of the legal process…decision to pursue a legal claimbargaining over out-of-court settlementspre-trial exchange of informationtrial itselfappeals process

Page 6: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

6

In Europe… Judges in civil trials take active role in asking questions and

developing case “Inquisitorial system,” since judge asks questions

In U.S… Lawyers’ job to develop case Judge is more of a passive referee “Adversarial system,” since competing lawyers are adversaries

Trial

Page 7: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

7

Lawyers have a strong incentive to win at trial May be working on contingency Value reputation for winning

Judges have no stake in outcome of the trial Judges will (we hope) generally do what is right… …but have less motivation to work hard

“Judges have incentives to do what is right and easy; lawyers have incentives to do what is profitable and hard.”

Incentives

Page 8: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

8

In U.K., loser in a lawsuit often pays legal expenses of winner Discourages “nuisance suits” But also discourages suits where there was actual harm that may

be hard to prove

In U.S., each side generally pays own legal costs But some states have rules that change this under certain

circumstances

Who pays the costs of a trial?

Page 9: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

9

Rule 68 of Federal Rules of Civil Procedure“At any time more than 10 days before the trial begins, a party defending against a claim may serve upon the adverse party an offer [for a settlement]…If the judgment finally obtained by the offeree is not more favorable than the offer, the offeree must pay the costs incurred after the making of the offer.”

“Fee shifting rule” Example

I hit you with my car, you sue Before trial, I offer to settle for $6,000, you refuse If you win at trial, but judgment is less than $6,000… …then under Rule 68, you would have to pay me for all my legal expenses

after I made the offer

Who pays the costs of a trial?

Page 10: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

10

Rule 68 does two things to encourage settlements: Gives me added incentive to make a serious settlement offer Gives you added incentive to accept my offer

But not actually as generous as it sounds Attorney’s fees not always included in fees that are covered

Asymmetric Plaintiff is penalized for rejecting defendant’s offer Defendant is not penalized for rejecting offer from plaintiff

Who pays the costs of a trial?

Page 11: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

11

Kathryn Spier, “Pretrial Bargaining and the Design of Fee-Shifting Rules” Game-theory analysis of Rule 68 and similar rules Shows that when parties have private information, fee-shifting rules

like this increase probability of settlement Then considers designing “perfect” rule to maximize number of cases

that would settle out of court Ideal rule is similar to two-sided version of Rule 68

Take each side’s most generous settlement offer Compute a cutoff If eventual judgment is below this cutoff, plaintiff pays both sides’ legal

fees; if above cutoff, defendant pays both sides’ fees

Who pays the costs of a trial?

Page 12: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

12

Trial has to answer two questions: Is defendant liable? If so, how much are damages?

Unitary trial considers liability and damages at same time Economies of scope

Segmented trial considers liability first, then damages later (if necessary) Damages phase may not be necessary

In U.S., judges have discretion over which type of trial

Unitary versus Segmented Trials

Page 13: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

13

Burden of proof: who is responsible for showing what at trial In criminal case, prosecutor’s burden to show defendant is guilty,

not defendant’s burden to show he’s innocent Similarly, in civil case, plaintiff’s burden to make case Under negligence rule, plaintiff has to prove defendant was

negligent (rather than defendant having to show he was not) Under contributory negligence, once defendant is shown to be

negligent, it’s defendant’s burden to show plaintiff was also negligent

Burden of proof

Page 14: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

14

Standard of proof: degree of certainty to which something must be shown in court In criminal cases, “beyond a reasonable doubt” – very high standard In civil cases, plaintiff usually has to prove case by “a preponderance

of the evidence” Much lower standard –interpreted as anything over 50% certainty

For punitive damages to be awarded, high standard of proof is often required: “clear and convincing evidence”

Efficient level depends on relative costs of two types of errors Finding someone liable when they should not be Finding someone not liable when they should be

Standard of proof

Page 15: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

15

Rules for what evidence court can pay attention to

Textbook gives examples where rules seem inconsistent, if goal is simply to maximize probability of “right outcome”

When we focus on efficiency, we care only about outcomes, not about process

But in real-world legal system, process is important in its own right

Rules of evidence

Page 16: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

16

Stages of the legal process…decision to pursue a legal claimbargaining over out-of-court settlementspre-trial exchange of informationtrial itselfappeals process

Page 17: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

17

In U.S., three levels of federal courts District courts, circuit courts of appeals, Supreme Court (Many state court systems also have three levels, but this varies by

state) Parties in district court cases have right of appeal

Circuit court is required to consider their appeal Parties in circuit court cases do not

Supreme Court has discretionary review – chooses which cases to hear

In common law countries, appeals courts tend to only consider certain issues Appeals generally limited to matters of law Matters of fact generally not considered

Appeals

Page 18: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

18

Recall goal of legal system Minimize administrative costs + error costs

Clearly, appeals process increases administrative costs So only efficient if it reduces error costs

Reasons why appeals process may reduce error costs Appeals courts are more likely to reverse “wrong” decisions than “right”

decisions… …which leads to losing parties appealing more often when decision

was “wrong”

Appeals

Page 19: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

19

CriminalLaw

Page 20: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

20

Just like with civil law…

To achieve efficiency, we want to minimize total social cost

Which consists of… Social cost of crimes that are committed Cost of detecting and punishing offenders

What is the goal of criminal law?

Page 21: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

21

Criminal intended to do wrong

Case brought by government, not individual plaintiff

Harm done tends to be public as well as private

Standard of proof is higher

If found guilty, defendant will be punished

Criminal law differs from civil law in several ways

Page 22: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

22

Unlike a tort, a crime generally requires intent Mens rea – a “guilty mind”

But… In some situations, literal intent is not required

You’ve been hired as a lifeguard or a nurse You show up to work drunk, and as a result someone dies You can be charged with criminally negligent homicide even though

you didn’t want the person to die Sometimes intent without harm is enough

Attempted murder

Intent

Page 23: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

23

Recall wrongful death tort cases Victim is dead, can’t receive compensation Family/friends can sue for lost wages, lost companionship, etc.

Criminal cases don’t require living victim

This allows prosecution of “victimless crimes” Theory is that all crimes harm the public – are “public bads” That is, breakdown of law and order in society harms everyone So public (represented by state) brings criminal actions

Criminal cases are brought by the state

Page 24: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

24

Most civil cases: preponderance of the evidence

For punitive damages, clear and convincing evidence

In criminal cases, prosecution must prove guilt beyond a reasonable doubt

Criminal cases have higher standard of proof

Page 25: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

25

Nuisance law, contract law, tort law: damages serve two purposes Compensate the victim Cause injurer to internalize cost of harm done

When injurer internalizes harm, we get pollution, or breach, or accidents, only when they are efficient

Criminal law: intention is to deter crimes – that is, prevent them entirely, not just the “inefficient ones” So punishment need not be limited to magnitude of harm done Criminal punishments – imprisonment, execution – destroy resources

Make criminal worse off, may not make anyone better off

Distinction between civil remedies and punishment

Page 26: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

26

Most crimes are clearly inefficient To steal my laptop, you might break my car window And, my laptop is worth more to me than to other people Stolen cars are worth much less than legally-owned ones And if you value my car more than me, there’s a legal alternative to

you stealing it

Are crimes ever efficient?

Page 27: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

27

Most crimes are clearly inefficient To steal my laptop, you might break my car window And, my laptop is worth more to me than to other people Stolen cars are worth much less than legally-owned ones And if you value my car more than me, there’s a legal alternative to you

stealing it

But Friedman offers examples of efficient crimes Starving hiker lost in the woods finds cabin with nobody home, breaks in and

steals food Efficient murder

Rich guy decides he’d derive immense pleasure from hunting a human Offers 10 people $1,000,000 each to draw straws, he gets to hunt and kill the loser If they all agree, is this transaction efficient?

Are crimes ever efficient?

Page 28: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

28

In 2001, Armin Miewes posted an ad online,“looking for a well-built 18-to-30-year-old tobe slaughtered and then consumed.”

And someone answered.

They met, discussed it, and agreed Mieweswould kill and eat the guy.

So he did. And videotaped it.

At the time, cannibalism was not illegal in Germany

Is it a crime to kill someone who has consented to be murdered? In 2004, Miewes was convicted of manslaughter In 2006, he was retried, convicted of murder, sentenced to life in prison

But also… if Miewes and his victim agreed he should be killed and eaten, and no one else was harmed, was this crime efficient?

Are crimes ever efficient?

Page 29: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

29

Tort law creates an incentive to avoid harms If it worked perfectly, might be no need for criminal law

Reasons tort law may not work for certain offenses Relies on perfect compensation, which may be impossible

Loss of life, crippling injury Even if possible in theory, might be impossible in practice If probability of being caught/convicted is less than one,

deterrence requires punishment more severe than benefit received And if we made civil penalties severe enough, criminals might be

judgment-proof

Why not use tort law to cover crimes too?

Page 30: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

30

A theory of criminal law must answer… Which acts should be punished as crimes? How should they be punished?

Cooter and Ulen: Acts should be punished when aim is deterrence Acts should be priced when aim is internalization Aim should be deterrence when…

perfect compensation is impossible people want law to protect rights instead of interests or enforcement errors undermine liability

Rest of today is from ch. 15 of Friedman book (Law’s Order)

Theory of criminal law

Page 31: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

31

General model ofcrime and punishment

Page 32: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

32

Key assumption: rational criminals Potential criminals weigh private cost – chance of getting caught,

times severity of punishment – against benefit

If enforcement were free, we could eliminate crime Hire enough police to detect nearly all crimes Punish them very severely Nobody rational would commit a crime

But enforcement isn’t free, making things interesting

Economic model of crime and punishment

Page 33: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

33

To deter crime, we need to do two things: Catch offenders… …and punish them

Catching a higher fraction of offenders is more costly Requires more police, more detectives, etc.

More severe punishment also tends to be more expensive Most common punishments are fines and imprisonment Fines cost nothing – state even makes money But fines don’t always work, because not everyone can pay them Besides fines, most punishments are inefficient – make offender worse

off, and are costly to state

Economic model of crime and punishment

Page 34: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

34

Suppose some crime is punished by 20% chance of being caught and convicted, and a punishment equal to $20,000

We could save money by… Fire half the police and judges, so probability of being caught and

convicted dropped to 10% Raise the punishment to $40,000 Punishing someone $40,000 may cost more than punishing them

$20,000, but not more than twice as much… …and half as many people to punish So cost of punishing people would be same or lower But we’d save money on detection/apprehension

Repeating the argument, the “optimal” system is an infinitely low probability of an infinitely severe punishment!

Gary Becker, “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach”

Page 35: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

35

With rational criminals, raising the expected punishment should lead to fewer crimes being committed

On a per-crime basis, raising either the probability of being caught or the severity of the punishment is costly

But as we increase expected punishment… we get fewer crimes committed, and maybe fewer offenders we need to detect and punish

So the cost of punishing those criminals we do catch could go up or down

Which means the marginal cost of deterring another crime could be positive or negative!

Marginal cost of deterrence

Page 36: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

36

Sample exam question (Fall 2008 final exam):

Suppose a particular crime is always inefficient: it harms the rest of society $10,000 more than it benefits the criminal.Every time an offender is caught, he or she is tried, convicted, and imprisoned; the total (social) cost of trials and punishment is $100,000 per criminal caught.Recall that the aim of criminal law is to minimize the sum of three things:(1) the social cost of the crimes that are committed,(2) the cost of detection, and(3) the cost of trying and punishing the offenders who get caught.A city is considering hiring additional policemen dedicated to detecting this particular crime. This change would increase the fraction of offenders who get caught from 15% to 20%.

“The marginal cost of deterring another crime could be positive or negative”

Page 37: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

37

Social cost of each crime: $10,000 Cost of trial and punishment: $100,000 Increase fraction of crimes detected from 15% to 20% (a) Suppose this increase in detection would result in a decrease in the number of crimes

committed from 1,000 a year to 700 a year.i. Calculate the effect that hiring the new policemen would have on the social cost of crimes committed.before: 1,000 X $10,000 = $10,000,000after: 700 X $10,000 = $7,000,000effect: $3,000,000 reduction in social cost of crimeii. Calculate the effect it would have on the cost of trying and punishing offenders.before: 1,000 X 15% X $100,000 = $15,000,000after: 700 X 20% $100,000 = $14,000,000effect: $1,000,000 reduction in cost of trials and punishmentiii. From an efficiency point of view, what is the most that the city should be willing to pay for the new policemen?$4,000,000, since this is how much social costs are reduced byhaving higher detection

“The marginal cost of deterring another crime could be positive or negative”

Page 38: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

38

Social cost of each crime: $10,000 Cost of trial and punishment: $100,000 Increase fraction of crimes detected from 15% to 20% (b) Now suppose instead that the increase in detection would decrease the number of crimes

committed from 1,000 a year to 900 a year.i. Calculate the effect that hiring the new policemen would have on the social cost of crimes committed.before: 1,000 X $10,000 = $10,000,000after: 900 X $10,000 = $9,000,000effect: $1,000,000 reduction in social cost of crimeii. Calculate the effect it would have on the cost of trying and punishing offenders.before: 1,000 X 15% X $100,000 = $15,000,000after: 900 X 20% $100,000 = $18,000,000effect: $3,000,000 increase in cost of trials and punishmentiii. From an efficiency point of view, is there any positive amount that the city should be willing to pay for the new policemen?No – higher detection increases social costs, so even if the new policemen were free, from an efficiency point of view, we wouldn’t want them!

“The marginal cost of deterring another crime could be positive or negative”

Page 39: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

39

Social cost of each crime: $10,000 Cost of trial and punishment: $100,000 Increase fraction of crimes detected from 15% to 20% (c) Defend the following statement applied to this type of crime:

“Even when detection is cheap, more detection is only efficient if the supply of crimes is elastic.”When the supply of crimes is inelastic, detecting more of them increases social costs – the number of crimes does not drop much, but more is spent punishing those who are caught.When the supply of crimes is elastic, detecting more of them reduces social costs – fewer crimes get committed, and fewer criminals need to be punished.

“The marginal cost of deterring another crime could be positive or negative”

Page 40: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

40

So depending on how much the crime rate responds to deterrence, increasing the likelihood of being caught could… Reduce social costs – by reducing the number of crimes committed

and the number of criminals we have to punish Increase social costs – by increasing the number of criminals we

catch and have to punish (in addition to requiring more spending on detection)

What does this say about the optimal level of deterrence? Or, if you prefer, the optimal level of crime? Or the optimal level of punishment?

Optimal deterrence

Page 41: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

41

Suppose there’s some crime for which expected punishment (probability X severity) equals $900

Suppose raising expected punishment from $900 to $901 would deter exactly one crime. Should we do it?

Depends whether social cost of that one crime is more or less than the social cost of deterring it

Suppose that… Raising expected punishment from $900 to $901 would cost $50 “Marginal crime” does $1,000 worth of damage To calculate social cost, also need to consider benefit to criminal Marginal crime gets committed when expected punishment is $900, but not

when expected punishment is $901; so benefit to criminal is $900 So social cost of that crime is $1,000 - $900 = $100 If social cost of raising expected punishment enough to deter that crime is $50,

we should do it!

Optimal punishment – example

Page 42: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

42

Optimal punishment – general theory

Cost of deterring one more crime

Social cost of marginal crime=

Cost of deterring one more crime

Damage to Victim= Benefit to

Criminal–

Cost of deterring one more crime

Damage to Victim= Expected

Punishment–

Expected Punishment

Damage to Victim= Marginal Cost

of Deterrence–

at efficient level of deterrence:

since “marginal criminal” is indifferent…

rearranging,

Page 43: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

43

When deterrence is free, expected punishment = damage to victim Offender internalizes costs of his actions Just like with tort law, leads to only efficient crimes

When deterrence is costly, expected punishment < damage to victim When preventing marginal crime is costly, we allow all efficient crimes… …and some slightly inefficient ones, because it’s cheaper to allow them then to

prevent them

When marginal cost of deterrence is negative, we should setexpected punishment > damage to victim When preventing the marginal crime saves money (because there are fewer criminals

to punish)… We prevent some efficient crimes too, because it’s cheaper to deter them than to

allow them and have to punish them!

At efficient level of deterrence, Expected

PunishmentDamage to

Victim= Marginal Cost of Deterrence–

Page 44: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

44

Why count criminal’s payoff when calculating social costs? We said fines cost nothing – make offender worse off, state better off Why not just say, screw the offender, fines raise money? And social cost of crime = damage to victim – benefit to offender Why not: by committing certain acts, you give up right to be counted?

Friedman argues it this way: We want an economic theory for why things like murder and

embezzlement should be treated differently than nuisances and torts If we start out by assuming they’re morally different, we’re assuming the

answer to our question If we avoid making assumptions like that, and still come up with reasons

they should be treated differently, then we’ve learned something

Aside: why do we count the criminal’s benefit?

Page 45: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

45

Friedman: “It would be designed to squeeze the largest possible fines out of

convicted criminals, using the threat of more unpleasant alternatives for those who failed to pay.

If the fines that victims can pay, even under such threats, are inadequate, they are supplemented by penal slavery for criminals who can produce more than it costs to guard and feed them, execution (with the organs forfeiting to the state) for those who cannot.

Any prisons that do exist and do not pay for themselves are as unpleasant as possible, so as to produce as much punishment as possible per dollar of imprisonment cost.

It is a consistent picture, and considerable parts of it can be found in the not very distant past, but not a pretty one.”

So what would the efficient criminal law system look like?

Page 46: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 21

46

Punishments are designed to make someone worse off

So if they’re efficient, must be making someone better off State gets to collect fines

But this creates large incentive for abuse Some feel too much police effort goes into drug cases, in which

forfeiture of dealers’ money and property is common Once traffic cameras are installed, towns realize catching speeders is

profitable – article on syllabus lists six cities caught shortening length of yellow lights beyond what’s allowed by law

The problem with efficient punishments