econ 522 economics of law dan quint fall 2013 lecture 5

55
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

Upload: johnathan-lester

Post on 17-Jan-2018

219 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

2  Coase Theorem: In the absence of transaction costs, if property rights are well-defined and tradeable, voluntary negotiations will lead to efficiency.  The initial allocation of property rights therefore does not matter for achieving efficiency…  …provided there are no transaction costs  On the other hand, the initial allocation does affect distribution…  And if there are transaction costs, it can also affect efficiency Monday, we saw the Coase Theorem

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

Econ 522Economics of Law

Dan QuintFall 2013Lecture 5

Page 2: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

2

HW1 due online at 11:59 p.m. Thursday

Reminder

Page 3: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

3

Coase Theorem: In the absence of transaction costs,if property rights are well-defined and tradeable,voluntary negotiations will lead to efficiency.

The initial allocation of property rights therefore does not matter for achieving efficiency…

…provided there are no transaction costs

On the other hand, the initial allocation does affect distribution…

And if there are transaction costs, it can also affect efficiency

Monday, we saw the Coase Theorem

Page 4: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

4

Foxes

Page 5: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

55

Pierson v. Post (NY Supreme Court, 1805) Lodowick Post organized a fox hunt, was chasing

a fox Jesse Pierson appeared “out of nowhere,” killed

the fox and took it Post sued to get the fox back Lower court sided with Post; Pierson appealed

to NY Supreme Court

Question: when do you own an animal?

One early, “classic” property law case

Page 6: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

66

Court ruled for Pierson (the one who killed the fox) “If the first seeing, starting, or pursuing such animals… should

afford the basis of actions against others for intercepting and killing them, it would prove a fertile source of quarrels and litigation”

(Also: just because an action is “uncourteous or unkind” does not make it illegal)

Dissenting opinion: a fox is a “wild and noxious beast,” and killing foxes is “meritorious and of public benefit” Post should own the fox, in order to encourage fox hunting

One early, “classic” property law case

Page 7: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

77

Pierson gets the fox

simpler rule (finders keepers)

easier to implement

fewer disputes

Same tradeoff we saw earlier:

Post gets the fox

more efficient incentives

(stronger incentive to pursue animals that may be hard to catch)

Just like Fast Fish/Loose Fish vs Iron Holds The Whale Fast Fish/Loose Fish is the simpler rule, leads to fewer disputes Iron Holds the Whale is more complicated, but is necessary with

whales where hunting them the old-fashioned way is too dangerous

Page 8: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

8

Coase seems to say: for efficiency, it doesn’t matter who starts off with the right to the fox If Post values it more, he can buy it from Pierson, or vice versa Seems to imply: one rule is just as good as the other, as long as we all

know what the rule is

So why does Pierson v Post matter? Transaction costs! Majority: if Post gets the fox back, “it would prove a fertile course of

quarrels and litigation” – the ensuing lawsuits would be costly Dissent: killing foxes is a good thing (externality), so lots of people

benefit – so hard to get efficient amount of fox hunting through bargaining

Doesn’t Coase make Pierson v Post irrelevant?

Page 9: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

9

Coase: “in the absence of transaction costs, if property rights are well-defined and tradable, voluntary negotiations will lead to efficiency.”

This suggests that if there are transaction costs, voluntary negotiations may not lead to efficiency

Car example (yet again) If transactions are costly, we may not trade And if we do trade, we incur that cost

Transaction costs

Page 10: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

10

“If market transactions were costless, all that matters (questions of equity apart) is that the rights of the various parties should be well-defined and the results of legal actions easy to forecast.

But… the situation is quite different when market transactions are so costly as to make it difficult to change the arrangement of rights established by the law.

In such cases, the courts directly influence economic activity.

…Even when it is possible to change the legal delimitation of rights through market transactions, it is obviously desirable to reduce the need for such transactions and thus reduce the employment of resources in carrying them out.

Quoting Coase…

Page 11: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

11

“In the absence of transaction costs, if property rights are well-defined and tradable, voluntary negotiations will lead to efficiency.”

We can read this as… “As long as transaction costs aren’t a big deal, we’ll get efficiency” Or as, “we’ll only get efficiency automatically if there are no transaction

costs”

Coase also gives two examples of institutions that may emerge in response to high transaction costs: Firms Government regulation

We can see the Coase Theorem as either a positive or negative result

Page 12: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

12

Overfishing in communal lake? It’s because property rights over those fish aren’t well-defined

Firm polluting too much? It’s because property rights over clean air aren’t well-defined

So one solution… Make property rights complete enough to cover “everything,” and

tradable, and use the law to minimize transaction costs… …Then Coase kicks in and we get efficiency! (Booya!) So why not do this? COSTS!

Many externalities can be thought of as missing property rights

Page 13: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

13

General equilibrium given prices, consumers maximize utility given prices, firms maximize profits prices are such that all markets clear

First Welfare Theorem: general equilibrium is efficient

But not when there are externalities, or “missing markets”

Allowing the consumer to negotiate with the firm is like introducing a “missing market” in air rights

Relating Coase to general equilibrium/first welfare theorem

Page 14: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

14

General equilibrium given prices, consumers maximize utility given prices, firms maximize profits prices are such that all markets clear

First Welfare Theorem: general equilibrium is efficient

But not when there are externalities, or “missing markets”

Allowing the consumer to negotiate with the firm is like introducing a “missing market” in air rights

Relating Coase to general equilibrium/first welfare theorem

Page 15: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

15

Bargaining

Page 16: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

16

Let’s go back to ourrancher and farmer

Do nothing: $500 in crop

damage

Page 17: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

17

Let’s go back to ourrancher and farmer

Rancher builds fence: $400

Farmer builds fence: $300

Page 18: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

18

Three possibilities Nobody builds a fence – $500 in damage Rancher builds fence – $400 cost Farmer builds fence – $300 cost

Suppose we’re in a farmer’s rights world Rancher is liable for any damage done by his herd

What does Coase predict will happen? They’ll bargain to efficient outcome Meaning, the farmer will build a fence (and the rancher will pay him) How much will he pay?

Let’s go back to ourrancher and farmer

No fence: $500 in harmRancher builds fence: $400Farmer builds fence: $300

Page 19: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

19

Threat point – each party’s expected outcome if bargaining fails

“If we can’t agree to a deal and we go our separate ways, how well off am I?”

Also called outside option, or reservation utility

Deal has to make everyone better off than that!

Before bargaining:threat points

No fence: $500 in harmRancher builds fence: $400Farmer builds fence: $300

Page 20: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

20

Threat points No fence: $500 in harmRancher builds fence: $400Farmer builds fence: $300

What happens to me if I don’t reach a deal with the rancher?Well, he’s liable for any crop damage……so there’s no reason for me to build a fence……and if there’s any damage, he’ll have to reimburse me……so if bargaining breaks down and I do nothing, my payoff is 0.That’s the best I can do on my own……so that’s my threat point.

Page 21: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

21

Threat points No fence: $500 in harmRancher builds fence: $400Farmer builds fence: $300

What happens if I don’t reach a deal with the farmer?He has no reason to build a fence……and I’m liable for crop damage……so my choices are to pay for $500 in damage……or to build a $400 fenceSo clearly, I’ll build a fenceSo my payoff if we don’t make a deal is –$400So that’s my threat point

Page 22: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

22

So under a closed-range law…

The farmer’s threat point is 0, the rancher’s is –$400 Those are the payoffs that will happen if no agreement is reached

If a deal happens: total payoffs go up from –$400 to –$300 Farmer will build a fence (efficient outcome), rancher will pay him some

money

Cooperation causes total payoffs to go up by $100

So $100 is gains from cooperation (or gains from trade)

Gains from cooperation No fence: $500 in harmRancher builds fence: $400Farmer builds fence: $300

Page 23: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

23

Coase predicts negotiation will lead to efficiency So the gains from cooperation will be realized (The farmer will build a fence)

Both sides have to do at least as well as their threat point Otherwise, wouldn’t agree to deal

So rancher will pay farmer somewhere between $300 and $400 to build the fence But what if we want a more precise prediction?

So what will happen? No fence: $500 in harmRancher builds fence: $400Farmer builds fence: $300

Page 24: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

24

What if gains from cooperation were split evenly?

Threat points 0 and –400, gains of 100

Farmer’s payoff: 0 + ½ (100) = 50

Rancher’s payoff: –400 + ½ (100) = –350

How is this achieved? Rancher pays farmer $350 to build fence

So what will happen? No fence: $500 in harmRancher builds fence: $400Farmer builds fence: $300

Page 25: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

25

If gains are split evenly…

-300Combined Payoffs

Farmer’s Payoff

Rancher’s Payoff (IF…)

100Gains From Cooperation

0Farmer’s Threat Point

-400Rancher’s Threat Point

Farmer’s Rights

No fence: $500 in harmRancher builds fence: $400Farmer builds fence: $300

–400 + ½ (100)

0 + ½ (100)

= –350

= 50

Page 26: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

26

If gains are split evenly…

-300-300Combined Payoffs

50-300Farmer’s Payoff

-3500Rancher’s Payoff (IF…)

1000Gains From Cooperation

0-300Farmer’s Threat Point

-4000Rancher’s Threat Point

Farmer’s RightsRancher’s Rights

=

No fence: $500 in harmRancher builds fence: $400Farmer builds fence: $300

Page 27: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

27

Let’s suppose… Having the party is worth $150 to you… …and a good night’s sleep is worth $100 to me So it’s efficient to have the party

If parties are allowed… No need for negotiation

If parties are not allowed… My threat point: 0 Your threat point: 0 Gains from cooperation: $50 If split evenly: payoffs are $25 and $25 Which requires you paying me $125 to have the party

One more example – you having a party next door to my house

Page 28: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

28

When are stronger property rights “worth it”?

Page 29: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

2929

We motivated property law by looking at a game between two neighboring farmers

10 – c, 10 – c -5 – c, 12 – P

12 – P, -5 – c -P, -P

Farm Steal

Farm

Steal

Player 2

Pla

yer 1

10, 10 -5, 12

12, -5 0, 0

Farm Steal

Farm

Steal

Player 2

Pla

yer 1

MODIFIED GAMEORIGINAL GAME

Changing the game had two effects: Allowed us to cooperate by not stealing from each other Introduced a cost c of administering a property rights system

Page 30: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

30

Incentive to overuse communal resources “Tragedy of the commons” – private property rights can fix this

Collective farming – incentive to shirk/freeride Again, private property rights fix this – for example… “It’s one of the ironies of American history that when the Pilgrims first arrived at

Plymouth rock they promptly set about creating a communist society. Of course, they were soon starving to death.

Fortunately… Governor William Bradford ended corn collectivism, decreeing that each family should keep the corn that it produced. Bradford described the results…

“[Ending corn collectivism] had very good success, for it made all hands very industrious… The women now went willingly into the field, and took their little ones with them to set corn; which before would allege weakness and inability…””- Marginal Revolution (blog post), “Thanksgiving Lessons”

Private property leads to better use of resources, by eliminating externalities

Page 31: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

31

“A primary function of property rights is that of guiding incentives to achieve a greater internalization of externalities”

“[ In order for an externality to persist, ] The cost of a transaction in the rights between the parties… must exceed the gains from internalization.”

“Property rights develop to internalize externalities when the gains from internalization become larger than the cost of internalization.”

Harold Demsetz (1967), “Toward a Theory of Property Rights”

Page 32: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

32

“Property rights develop to internalize externalities when the gains from internalization become larger than the cost of internalization.”

Private ownership of land among Native Americans Cost of administering private ownership: moderate Before fur trade…

externality was small, so gains from internalization were small gains < costs no private ownership of land

Harold Demsetz (1967), “Toward a Theory of Property Rights”

Page 33: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

33

“Property rights develop to internalize externalities when the gains from internalization become larger than the cost of internalization.”

Private ownership of land among Native Americans Cost of administering private ownership: moderate Before fur trade…

externality was small, so gains from internalization were small gains < costs no private ownership of land

As fur trading developed… externality grew, so gains from internalization grew gains > costs private property rights developed

Harold Demsetz (1967), “Toward a Theory of Property Rights”

Page 34: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

34

The date is 10,000 or 11,000 B.C. You are a member of a primitive tribe that farms its land in common. Farming land in common is a pain; you spend almost as much time watching each other and arguing about who is or is not doing his share as you do scratching the ground with pointed sticks and pulling weeds.

…It has occurred to several of you that the problem would disappear if you converted the common land to private property. Each person would farm his own land; if your neighbor chose not to work very hard, it would be he and his children, not you and yours, that would go hungry.

Friedman tells a similar story: “we owe civilization to the dogs”

Page 35: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

35

There is a problem with this solution… Private property does not enforce itself. Someone has to make sure that the lazy neighbor doesn’t solve his food shortage at your expense.

[Now] you will have to spend your nights making sure they are not working hard harvesting your fields. All things considered, you conclude that communal farming is the least bad solution.

Friedman tells a similar story: “we owe civilization to the dogs”

Page 36: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

36

Agricultural land continues to be treated as a commons for another thousand years, until somebody makes a radical technological innovation: the domestication of the dog.

Dogs, being territorial animals, can be taught to identify their owner’s property as their territory and respond appropriately to trespassers. Now you can convert to private property in agricultural land and sleep soundly. Think of it as the bionic burglar alarm.

-Friedman, Law’s Order, p. 118

Friedman tells a similar story: “we owe civilization to the dogs”

Page 37: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

37

Coase: if property rights are complete and tradable, we’ll always get efficiency can “fix” externalities by expanding property rights to cover

Demsetz: yes, but this comes at a cost property rights will expand when the benefits outweigh the costs either because the benefits rise… …or because the costs fall

So…

Page 38: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

38

“If market transactions were costless, all that matters (questions of equity apart) is that the rights of the various parties should be well-defined and the results of legal actions easy to forecast.

But… the situation is quite different when market transactions are so costly as to make it difficult to change the arrangement of rights established by the law.

In such cases, the courts directly influence economic activity.

…Even when it is possible to change the legal delimitation of rights through market transactions, it is obviously desirable to reduce the need for such transactions and thus reduce the employment of resources in carrying them out.”

Of course, Coase wasn’t actually ignoring costs…

Page 39: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

39

What are transaction costs, and how do we deal with them?

So…

Page 40: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

40

TransactionCosts

Page 41: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

41

Anything that makes it difficult or expensive for two parties to achieve a mutually beneficial trade

Three categories Search costs – difficulty in finding a trading partner Bargaining costs – difficulty in reaching an agreement Enforcement costs – difficulty in enforcing the agreement

afterwards

What are transaction costs?

Page 42: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

42

Asymmetric information Akerloff (1970), “The Market for Lemons” – adverse selection

Bargaining costs come in many forms

Page 43: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

43

Asymmetric information Akerloff (1970), “The Market for Lemons” – adverse selection

Private information (don’t know each others’ threat points) Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983), “Efficient Mechanisms for

Bilateral Trading” – always some chance of inefficiency

Bargaining costs come in many forms

Page 44: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

44

Asymmetric information Akerloff (1970), “The Market for Lemons” – adverse selection

Private information (don’t know each others’ threat points) Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983), “Efficient Mechanisms for

Bilateral Trading” – always some chance of inefficiency

Uncertainty If property rights are ambiguous, threat points are uncertain, and

bargaining is difficult

Bargaining costs come in many forms

Page 45: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

45

Large numbers of parties Developer values large area of land at $1,000,000 10 homeowners, each value their plot at $80,000

Bargaining costs come in many forms

Page 46: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

46

Large numbers of parties Developer values large area of land at $1,000,000 10 homeowners, each value their plot at $80,000 Holdout, freeriding

Hostility

Bargaining costs come in many forms

Page 47: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

47

Example of high transaction costs when there are many sellers

Page 48: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

48

Search costs

Bargaining costs Asymmetric information/adverse selection Private information/not knowing each others’ threat points Uncertainty about property rights/threat points Large numbers of buyers/sellers – holdout, freeriding Hostility

Enforcement costs

Sources of transaction costs

Page 49: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

49

So, whatdo we do?

(won’t get to this)

Page 50: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

50

No transaction costs initial allocation of rights doesn’t matter for efficiency wherever they start, people will trade until efficiency is achieved

Significant transaction costs initial allocation does matter, since trade may not occur (and is costly if it does)

This leads to two normative approaches we could take

What we know so far…

Page 51: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

51

Design the law to minimize transaction costs “Structure the law so as to remove the impediments to private

agreements” Normative Coase “Lubricate” bargaining

Two normative approaches to property law

Page 52: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

52

Design the law to minimize transaction costs “Structure the law so as to remove the impediments to private

agreements” Normative Coase “Lubricate” bargaining

Try to allocate rights efficiently to start with, so bargaining doesn’t matter that much “Structure the law so as to minimize the harm caused by failures in

private agreements” Normative Hobbes

Two normative approaches to property law

Page 53: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

53

Compare cost of each approach Normative Coase: cost of transacting, and remaining inefficiencies Normative Hobbes: cost of figuring out how to allocate rights

efficiently (information costs)

When transaction costs are low and information costs are high, structure the law so as to minimize transaction costs

When transaction costs are high and information costs are low, structure the law to allocate property rights to whoever values them the most

Which approach should we use?

Page 54: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

54

When transaction costs are low, design the law to facilitate voluntary trade

When transaction costs are high, design the law to allocate rights efficiently whenever possible

So now we have one general principle we can use for designing property law

Page 55: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 5

55

HW due tomorrow night at midnight

For next Monday: read Calabresi and Melamed

That’s it for today