Transcript
Page 1: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

Alan M. Taylor and Mark P. Taylor

Our willingness to pay a certain price for foreign money must ultimately and essentiallybe due to the fact that this money possesses a purchasing power as against commoditiesand services in that country. On the other hand, when we offer so and so much of ourown money, we are actually offering a purchasing power as against commodities andservices in our own country. Our valuation of a foreign currency in terms of our own,therefore, mainly depends on the relative purchasing power of the two currencies in theirrespective countries.

Gustav Cassel, economist (1922, pp. 138–39)The fundamental things applyAs time goes by.

Herman Hupfeld, songwriter (1931; from the film Casablanca, 1942)

P urchasing power parity (PPP) is a disarmingly simple theory that holds thatthe nominal exchange rate between two currencies should be equal to theratio of aggregate price levels between the two countries, so that a unit of

currency of one country will have the same purchasing power in a foreign country.The PPP theory has a long history in economics, dating back several centuries, butthe specific terminology of purchasing power parity was introduced in the yearsafter World War I during the international policy debate concerning the appro-priate level for nominal exchange rates among the major industrialized countriesafter the large-scale inflations during and after the war (Cassel, 1918). Since then,the idea of PPP has become embedded in how many international economists thinkabout the world. For example, Dornbusch and Krugman (1976) noted: “Under theskin of any international economist lies a deep-seated belief in some variant of thePPP theory of the exchange rate.” Rogoff (1996) expressed much the same

y Alan M. Taylor is Professor of Economics and Chancellor’s Fellow, University of Californiaat Davis, Davis, California, and Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research,Cambridge, Massachusetts. Mark P. Taylor is Professor of Macroeconomics, University ofWarwick, United Kingdom. Both authors are Research Fellows, Centre for Economic PolicyResearch, London, United Kingdom. Their e-mail addresses are �[email protected]� and�[email protected]�, respectively.

Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 18, Number 4—Fall 2004—Pages 135–158

Page 2: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

sentiment: “While few empirically literate economists take PPP seriously as ashort-term proposition, most instinctively believe in some variant of purchasingpower parity as an anchor for long-run real exchange rates.”

The question of how exchange rates adjust is central to exchange rate policy,since countries with fixed exchange rates need to know what the equilibriumexchange rate is likely to be and countries with variable exchange rates would liketo know what level and variation in real and nominal exchange rates they shouldexpect. In broader terms, the question of whether exchange rates adjust toward alevel established by purchasing power parity helps to determine the extent to whichthe international macroeconomic system is self-equilibrating.

Should PPP Hold? Does PPP Hold?

The general idea behind purchasing power parity is that a unit of currencyshould be able to buy the same basket of goods in one country as the equivalentamount of foreign currency, at the going exchange rate, can buy in a foreigncountry, so that there is parity in the purchasing power of the unit of currencyacross the two economies. One very simple way of gauging whether there may bediscrepancies from PPP is to compare the prices of similar or identical goods fromthe basket in the two countries. For example, the Economist newspaper publishes theprices of McDonald’s Big Mac hamburgers around the world and compares themin a common currency, the U.S. dollar, at the market exchange rate as a simplemeasure of whether a currency is overvalued or undervalued relative to the dollarat the current exchange rate (on the supposition that the currency would be valuedjust right if the dollar price of the burger were the same as in the United States).In January 2004, the cheapest burger was in China, at $1.23, compared with anaverage American price of $2.80. According to the Big Mac index, therefore, thisimplied that China’s yuan was 56 percent undervalued. The average price of a BigMac in the euro area countries was $3.48, suggesting that the euro was 24 percentovervalued against the dollar. In contrast, the Japanese yen was 12 percent under-valued on the Big Mac PPP standard. The Big Mac index has proved so popular thatthe Economist has also started to publish prices around the world of another globallyinvariable standard of value: a tall latte cup of coffee from Starbucks.

While the Big Mac and tall latte indices are an immediately engaging and funway to think about exchange rates, it is easy to come up with good reasons why theprices of coffee and burgers might differ internationally, most of which are relatedto the fact that many of the inputs into a tall latte or a Big Mac cannot be tradedinternationally or not easily at least: each good contains a high service component—thewages of the person serving the food and drink—and a high property rentalcomponent—the cost of providing you with somewhere to sit and sip your coffee ormunch your two beef patties on a sesame seed bun with secret-recipe sauce. Neitherthe service-sector labor nor the property (nor the trademark sauce) is easilyarbitraged internationally, and advocates of PPP have generally based their viewlargely on arguments relating to international goods arbitrage. Thus, while these

136 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Page 3: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

indices may give a lighthearted and suggestive idea of the relative value of curren-cies, they should be treated with caution.

The idea that purchasing power parity may hold because of internationalgoods arbitrage is related to the so-called Law of One Price, which holds that theprice of an internationally traded good should be the same anywhere in the worldonce that price is expressed in a common currency, since people could make ariskless profit by shipping the goods from locations where the price is low tolocations where the price is high (for example, by arbitraging). If the same goodsenter each country’s market basket used to construct the aggregate price level—and with the same weight—then the Law of One Price implies that a PPP exchangerate should hold between the countries concerned.

Possible objections to this line of reasoning are immediate. For example, thepresence of transactions costs—perhaps arising from transport costs, taxes, tariffsand duties and nontariff barriers—would induce a violation of the Law of OnePrice. Engel and Rogers (1996), for example, looked at the price differentialsbetween similar goods in cities across the United States and Canada and reportedevidence broadly in support of this hypothesis: they found that the volatility of theprice differential tended to be larger the greater the distance between the citiesconcerned, and it increased substantially when prices in cities in different countrieswere compared (the so-called “border effect”).

Moreover, not all goods are traded between all countries, and the weightattached to similar goods in aggregate price indices will differ across countries. Inaddition, different countries tend to produce goods that are differentiated ratherthan perfectly substitutable. Some of these problems could be addressed, at least inprinciple, with better data. Also, since PPP is based on traded goods, it might bemore usefully tested with producer price indices that tend to contain the prices ofmore manufactured tradables, rather than consumer price indices, which tend toreflect the prices of relatively more nontradables, such as many services. A recenttheoretical and empirical literature, discussed below, has attempted to allow forshort-run deviations from PPP arising from sources such as these, while retainingPPP in some form as a long-run average or equilibrium.

These objections notwithstanding, however, it is often asserted that the PPPtheory of exchange rates will hold at least approximately because of the possibilityof international goods arbitrage. There are two senses in which the PPP hypothesismight hold. Absolute purchasing power parity holds when the purchasing power ofa unit of currency is exactly equal in the domestic economy and in a foreigneconomy, once it is converted into foreign currency at the market exchange rate.However, it is often difficult to determine whether literally the same basket of goodsis available in two different countries. Thus, it is common to test relative PPP, whichholds that the percentage change in the exchange rate over a given period justoffsets the difference in inflation rates in the countries concerned over the sameperiod. If absolute PPP holds, then relative PPP must also hold; however, if relativePPP holds, then absolute PPP does not necessarily hold, since it is possible thatcommon changes in nominal exchange rates are happening at different levels of

Alan M. Taylor and Mark P. Taylor 137

Page 4: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

purchasing power for the two currencies (perhaps because of transactions costs, forexample).

To get a feel for whether PPP in either its relative or its absolute versions is amoderately good approximation to the real world, start with Figure 1. The toppanel plots data on the U.S. and UK consumer price indices (CPIs) over the period1820–2001. Both are expressed in U.S. dollar terms, which means that the UK CPIwas multiplied by the number of U.S. dollars exchanging for one UK pound at thatpoint in time. The bottom panel shows the comparison using producer priceindices, using data for a slightly longer period 1791–2001.1 We have (arbitrarily)normalized each of the series to be equal to zero in 1900.

At least three points are worth raising from a consideration of these graphs.First, absolute PPP did not hold perfectly and continuously: the correlation betweenthe two lines is less than perfect in both cases. In other words, there are substantialshort-run deviations from PPP. Second, the national price levels of the two coun-tries, expressed in a common currency, did tend to move together over these longperiods. Third, the correlation between the two national price levels is muchgreater with producer prices than with consumer prices.

Figure 2 shows several graphs using data for a large number of countries overthe period 1970–1998.2 Consider first the two graphs in the top row of Figure 2. Foreach country we calculated the one-year inflation rate in each of the 29 years andsubtracted the one-year U.S. inflation rate in the same years to obtain a measure ofrelative inflation (using consumer price indices for the figures on the left andproducer price indices for the figures on the right). We then calculated thepercentage change in the dollar exchange rate for each year and, finally, we plottedrelative annual inflation against exchange rate depreciation for each of the 29 yearsfor each of the countries. If relative PPP held perfectly, then each of the scatterpoints would lie on a 45o ray through the origin. In the second row, we have carriedout a similar exercise, except we have taken averages: we have plotted 29-yearannualized average relative inflation against the average annual depreciation of thecurrency against the U.S. dollar over the whole period, so that there is just onescatter point for each country.

Figure 2 confirms some of the lessons of Figure 1. For small differences inannual inflation between the United States and the country concerned, the corre-lation between relative inflation and depreciation in each of the years seems low.Thus, relative PPP certainly does not appear to hold perfectly and continuously inthe short run, although it appears to hold more closely for countries experiencingrelatively high inflation.

When we take 29-year averages, however, the scatter plots tend to collapse ontothe 45o ray. (This effect is only slightly less marked if we take averages over shorter

1 See Lothian and Taylor (1996, 2004) for a guide to the sources for these data series.2 Data are from the IMF’s International Financial Statistics database over the period 1970–1998 (data werenot available after 1998 for some countries). The sample included data on consumer price indices for20 industrialized countries and 26 developing countries, while that based on producer price indicesincludes 14 industrialized countries and twelve developing countries. The data set is identical to thatused in Coakley, Flood, Fuertes and Taylor (2004), which contains more precise details.

138 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Page 5: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

periods of ten years or so.) Thus, relative PPP seems to hold in a long-run sense. Withthe longer-run averages, the degree of correlation between relative inflation andexchange rate depreciation again seems higher when using PPIs than when using CPIs.

So the conclusions emerging from our informal eyeballing of Figures 1 and 2seem to be the following. Neither absolute nor relative PPP appear to hold closelyin the short run, although both appear to hold reasonably well as a long-runaverage and when there are large movements in relative prices, and both appear tohold better between producer price indices than between consumer price indices.

Figure 1Dollar-Sterling PPP Over Two Centuries

�0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

1811

PPI U.S.PPI UK

1831 1851 1871 1891

(b) U.S. and UK PPIs in dollar terms

1911 1931 1951 1971 19911791

�0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

1840

CPI U.S.CPI UK

1860 1880 1900

(a) U.S. and UK CPIs in dollar terms

1920 1940 1960 1980 20001820

Notes: This figure shows U.S. and UK consumer and producer price indices expressed in U.S. dollarterms over roughly the last two centuries using a log scale with a base of 1900 � 0.

The Purchasing Power Parity Debate 139

Page 6: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

In other words, as far as exchange rates are concerned, the fundamental things—relative price levels—apply increasingly as time goes by. These conclusions are infact broadly in line with the current consensus view on PPP. So where does all thecontroversy arise?

The PPP Debate: A Tour of the Past Three Decades

The Rise and Fall of Continuous PPPUnder the Bretton Woods agreement that was signed after World War II, the

U.S. dollar was tied to the price of gold, and then all other currencies were tied, or

Figure 2PPP at Various Time Horizons

�200

0

200

400

600

800

1000

Annual Consumer Price Inflation Relative to the U.S.versus Dollar Exchange Rate Depreciation,

1970–1998

�200 0 200 400 600 800 1000�200

0

200

400

600

800

1000

Annual Producer Price Inflation Relative to the U.S.versus Dollar Exchange Rate Depreciation,

1970–1998

�200 0 200 400 600 800 1000

�2

0

2

4

6

8

10

�2 0 2 4 6 8 10

Consumer Price Inflation Relative to the U.S. versusDollar Exchange Rate Depreciation,

29-Year Average, 1970–1998

�2

0

2

4

6

8

10

�2 0 2 4 6 8 10

Producer Price Inflation Relative to the U.S. versusDollar Exchange Rate Depreciation,

29-Year Average, 1970–1998

Notes: This figure shows countries’ cumulative inflation rate differentials against the United States inpercent (vertical axis) plotted against their cumulative depreciation rates against the U.S. dollar inpercent (horizontal axis). The charts on the left show CPI inflation, those on the right PPI inflation.The charts in the top row show annual rates, those in the bottom row 29-year average rates from1970 to 1998.

140 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Page 7: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

“pegged,” to the U.S. dollar. However, in 1971, President Nixon ended the con-vertibility of the U.S. dollar to gold and devalued the dollar relative to gold. Afterthe failure of attempts to restore a version of the Bretton Woods agreement, themajor currencies of the world began floating against each other in March 1973.

At this time, the dominant approach to determination of exchange rates wascalled the “monetary approach.” This approach assumed that the purchasing powerparity exchange rate held continuously (Frenkel, 1976; Taylor, 1995; Frankel andRose, 1995). Advocates of this approach argued that since the exchange rate is therelative price of two monies, that relative price should be determined by the relativebalance of supply and demand in the respective money markets in an asset marketequilibrium. Exactly how percentage changes in relative money supplies translated,other things equal, into exactly matching exchange rate movements was notimmediately obvious, however, unless one resorted to the earlier argument basedon goods arbitrage: that is, changes in the relative money supply affect relativeprices, including relative traded goods prices, which then leads to internationalgoods arbitrage.

A wave of empirical studies in the late 1970s tested whether continuouspurchasing power parity did indeed hold, as well as other implications of themonetary approach to the exchange rate, and the initial results were encouraging(Frenkel and Johnson, 1978). With the benefit of hindsight, it seems that theseearly encouraging results arose in part because of the relative stability of the dollarduring the first two or three years or so of the float (after an initial period ofturbulence) and in part because of the lack of a long enough run of data with whichto test the theory properly. Toward the end of the 1970s, however, the U.S. dollardid become much more volatile and more data became available to the econome-tricians, who subsequently showed that both continuous PPP and the simplemonetary approach to the exchange rate were easily rejected. One did not have tobe an econometrician, however, to witness the “collapse of purchasing powerparity” (Frenkel, 1981): one could simply examine the behavior of the real ex-change rate.

The real exchange rate is the nominal exchange rate (domestic price offoreign currency) multiplied by the ratio of national price levels (domestic pricelevel divided by foreign price level); since the real exchange rate measures thepurchasing power of a unit of foreign currency in the foreign economy relative tothe purchasing power of an equivalent unit of domestic currency in the domesticeconomy, PPP would, in theory, imply a real, relative-price-level-adjusted exchangerate of one (although the nominal rate—the rate that gets reported in the Wall StreetJournal or the Financial Times—could, of course, differ from one even if PPP held).In practice, if we are working with aggregate real exchange rates and henceaggregate price indices with arbitrary base periods, it may be difficult to pin downexactly when PPP held true, in order to normalize the measured real exchange rateto unity. What is clear, however, is that there will be some level of the measured realexchange rate that is consistent with PPP and—most importantly—that variation inthe real exchange rate must indicate deviations from PPP (since otherwise it wouldbe constant at the level consistent with PPP). The real trade-weighted value of the

Alan M. Taylor and Mark P. Taylor 141

Page 8: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

U.S. dollar didn’t change too much from 1973 to 1976, thus lending a degree ofplausibility to the continuous PPP argument. But the real value of the dollardropped sharply starting in 1977, and from then on it became increasingly clearthat continuous PPP could not hold as nominal exchange rates were patently farmore volatile than relative national price levels.

Formal Tests of (the Failure of) Long-Run PPP: Random Walks and Unit RootsOne reaction to the failure of purchasing power parity in the short run was a

theory of exchange rate overshooting, in which PPP is retained as a long-runequilibrium while allowing for significant short-run deviations due to sticky prices(Dornbusch, 1976). However, the search for empirical evidence of long-run PPP alsomet with disappointment.

Formal tests for evidence of PPP as a long-run phenomenon have often beenbased on an empirical examination of the real exchange rate. If the real exchangerate is to settle down at any level whatsoever, including a level consistent with PPP,it must display reversion toward its own mean. Hence, mean reversion is only anecessary condition for long-run PPP: to ensure long-run absolute PPP, we shouldhave to know that the mean toward which it is reverting is in fact the PPP realexchange rate. Still, since much of this research has failed to reject the hypothesisthat even this necessary condition does not hold, this has not in general been anissue.

Early empirical studies, such as those by Roll (1979) or Adler and Lehmann(1983), tested the null hypothesis that the real exchange rate does not mean revertbut instead follows a random walk, the archetypal non–mean reverting time seriesprocess where changes in each period are purely random and independent. Someauthors even argued that the random walk property was an implication of theefficiency of international markets, in the sense of prices and exchange ratesreflecting all available information and all arbitrage opportunities being quicklyexploited. Under this “efficient markets PPP” view, Roll (1979), for example,argued that the change in the real exchange rate, since it is effectively a measure ofthe one-period real return from arbitraging goods between countries, should havean expected value of zero if markets are efficient. However, this early strand of theempirical literature suffered from logical and econometric weaknesses. The theo-retical underpinnings of “efficient markets PPP” failed to adjust the expectedreturn for the real cost of financing goods arbitrage (Taylor and Sarno, 2004).Once this arbitrage adjustment is made, efficiency requires that the expected realexchange rate change be equal to the expected real interest rate differential, andlong-run PPP will be implied if the latter differential is stationary.3 On the empirical

3 See Obstfeld and Taylor (2004) for evidence on the stationarity of real interest rate differentials. Underreasonable assumptions, the real interest rate differential will be negatively correlated with the level ofthe real exchange rate if a loss in international competitiveness (a real appreciation) has a netdeflationary impact on the economy, reducing inflation and, other things equal, raising the real interestrate. This in turn implies mean reversion of the real exchange rate, since it implies that changes in thereal exchange rate are negatively correlated with the level of the real exchange rate.

142 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Page 9: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

side, the evidence in favor of a random walk was at best mixed, and resultsdepended on the criteria employed (Cumby and Obstfeld, 1984). Sharper econo-metric tools were still being fashioned, but—as we discuss below—they also sufferedfrom low power just like these early tests, so for many years researchers wereunlikely to reject the null hypothesis of a random walk even if it were false.

In the late 1980s, a more sophisticated econometric literature on long-run PPPdeveloped, at the core of which was the concept of a “unit root process.” If a timeseries is a realization of a unit root process, then while changes in the variable maybe to some extent predictable, the variable may still never settle down at any oneparticular level, even in the very long run. For example, suppose we estimated thefollowing regression equation for the real exchange rate qt over time, where �t is arandom error and � and � are unknown parameters:

qt � � � �qt�1 � �t .

If � � 1, we say that the process generating the real exchange rate contains a unitroot. In that case, changes in the real exchange rate would be predictable—theywould be equal on average to the estimated value of �. The level of the realexchange rate would, however, not be predictable, even in the long run: since thechange each period would be equal to a constant plus an unpredictable randomelement, the long-run level will be equal to the sum of the constant changes eachperiod plus the sum of a large number of random elements. As these randomshocks get cumulated, there is no way of telling in advance what they will add up to.(In fact, the real exchange rate would be following a random walk with drift, whichis an example of a so-called unit root process.) Thus, testing the null hypothesis that� � 1 is a test for whether the path of the real exchange rate over time does notreturn to any average level and thus that long-run PPP did not hold.

The flurry of empirical studies employing these types of tests on real exchangerate data among major industrialized countries that emerged toward the end of the1980s were unanimous in their failure to reject the unit root hypothesis for majorreal exchange rates (for example, Taylor, 1988; Mark, 1990), although—as we shallsee—this result was probably due to the low power of the tests.

In any case, at the time, this finding created great uncertainty about how tomodel exchange rates. At a theoretical level, there was still a consensus belief inlong-run PPP coupled with overshooting exchange rate models; now the data wereraising the possibility that even long-run PPP was a chimera. Some economistsposited theoretical models to explain why the real exchange rate could in fact benon–mean reverting (as in Stockman, 1987). Others questioned the empiricalmethodology.

The Power ProblemFrankel (1986, 1990) noted that while a researcher may not be able to reject

the null hypothesis of a random walk real exchange rate at a given significancelevel, it does not mean that the researcher must then accept that hypothesis.Furthermore, Frankel pointed out that the statistical tests typically employed to

The Purchasing Power Parity Debate 143

Page 10: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

examine the long-run stability of the real exchange, at that time based on datacovering just 15 years or so since 1973, may have low power to reject the nullhypothesis of a unit root even if it is indeed false. This criticism would apply bothto the early random walk studies and to the subsequent literature testing moreformally for unit roots. It was further taken up and examined by other authors(Froot and Rogoff, 1995; Lothian and Taylor, 1996, 1997). The argument is thateven if the real exchange rate tends to revert toward its mean over long periods oftime, examination of one real exchange rate over a relatively short period may notyield enough information to detect this mean reversion. Using simulations in whichthe real exchange rate is assumed to mean revert by about 11 percent per year, theprobability of rejecting at the 5 percent level the null hypothesis of a random walkreal exchange rate, when in fact the real rate is actually mean reverting, is extremelylow—somewhere between about 5 and 8 percent—when using 15 years of data(Lothian and Taylor, 1997; Sarno and Taylor, 2002a). With the benefit of theadditional 10 to 15 years or so of data that are now available, the power of the testincreases by only a couple of percentage points, and even with a century of data,there would be less than an even chance of correctly rejecting the unit roothypothesis.

Moreover, increasing the sample size by increasing the frequency ofobservation—moving from, say, quarterly to monthly data—won’t increase thepower because increasing the amount of detail concerning short-run movementscan only give you more information about short-run as opposed to long-runbehavior (Shiller and Perron, 1985).

More Statistical Power: More Years, More CountriesIf you want to get more information about the long-run behavior of a partic-

ular real exchange rate, one approach is to use more years of data. However, longperiods of data usually span different exchange rate regimes, prompting questionsabout how to interpret the findings. Also, over long periods of time, real factorsmay generate structural breaks or shifts in the equilibrium real exchange rate.Once these issues are recognized, there are ways to look for possible effects ofdifferent regimes and structural shifts.

In one early study in this spirit, using annual data from 1869 to 1984 for thedollar-sterling real exchange rate, Frankel (1986) estimates a first-order autoregres-sive process for the real exchange rate q of the form

�qt � q� � ��qt�1 � q� � �t ,

where q is the assumed constant equilibrium level of q, �t is a random disturbance,and � is the autocorrelation coefficient—an unknown parameter governing thespeed of mean reversion. Notice that a proportion of � times the random shock attime t � 1, �t�1 , will still be part of the real exchange rate deviation at time t.Hence, we can say that shocks die out—or the real exchange rate reverts toward itsmean of q—at the rate of (1 � �) per period. (If the real exchange rate followeda random walk, then � � 1 and shocks would never die out.) Frankel’s point

144 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Page 11: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

estimate of � is 0.86, and he is able to reject the hypothesis of a random walk at the5 percent level.

Similar results to Frankel’s were obtained by Edison (1987), based on ananalysis of data over the period 1890–1978, and by Glen (1992), using a datasample spanning the period 1900–1987. Lothian and Taylor (1996) use two cen-turies of data on dollar-sterling and franc-sterling real exchange rates, reject therandom walk hypothesis and find point estimates of � of 0.89 for dollar-sterling andof 0.76 for franc-sterling. Moreover, they are unable to detect any significantevidence of a structural break between the pre– and post–Bretton Woods period.Taylor (2002) extends the long-run analysis to a set of 20 countries over the1870–1996 period and also finds support for PPP and coefficients that are stable inthe long run. Studies such as these provide the formal counterpart to the informalevidence of long-run relative PPP like eyeballing Figure 1.

Another approach to providing a convincing test of real exchange rate stabil-ity, while limiting the timeframe to the post–Bretton Woods period, is to use morecountries. By increasing the amount of information employed in the tests acrossexchange rates, the power of the test should be increased. In an early study of thistype, Abuaf and Jorion (1990) examine a system of 10 first-order autoregressiveregressions for real dollar exchange rates over the period 1973–1987, where theautocorrelation coefficient is constrained to be the same in every case. Their resultsindicate a marginal rejection of the null hypothesis of joint non–mean reversion atconventional significance levels, which they interpret this as evidence in favor oflong-run PPP. An academic cottage industry sprang up in the 1990s to apply unitroot tests to real exchange rate data on panels of countries for the post–BrettonWoods period. A number of these studies claimed to provide evidence supportinglong-run PPP. Taylor and Sarno (1998), however, issued an important warning ininterpreting these findings. The tests typically applied in these panel-data studiestest the null hypothesis that none of the real exchange rates under consideration aremean reverting. If this null hypothesis is rejected, then the most that can beinferred is that at least one of the rates is mean reverting. However, researcherstended to draw a much stronger inference that all of the real exchange rates weremean reverting—and this broader inference is not valid. Some researchers havesought to remedy this shortcoming by designing alternative tests; for example,Taylor and Sarno (1998) suggest testing the hypothesis that at least one of realexchange rates is non–mean reverting, rejection of which would indeed imply thatthey are all mean reverting. However, such alternative tests are generally lesspowerful, so that their application has not led to clear-cut conclusions (Taylor andSarno, 1998; Sarno and Taylor, 1998).

PPP PuzzlesThe research on the evolution of exchange rates from the 1970s to the turn of

the century has generally been interpreted as supporting the hypothesis thatexchange rates adjust to the PPP level in the long run. But the evidence is weak. Forexample, rejecting at standard levels of statistical significance the null hypothesisthat a unit root exists certainly doesn’t prove that a long-run PPP exchange rate

Alan M. Taylor and Mark P. Taylor 145

Page 12: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

exists, either. The long-span studies raise the issue of possible regime shifts andwhether the recent evidence may be swamped by history. The panel-data studiesraise the issue of whether the hypothesis of non–mean reversion is being rejectedbecause of just a few mean-reverting real exchange rates within the panel. Ifexchange rates do tend to converge to PPP, economists have—at least so far—hada hard time presenting strong evidence to support the claim. Following Taylor, Peeland Sarno (2001), we see the puzzling lack of strong evidence for long-runPPP—especially for the post–Bretton Woods period—as the first PPP puzzle.

A second related puzzle also exists. In the mid-1980s, Huizinga (1987) andothers began to notice that even the studies that were interpreted as supporting thethesis that PPP holds in the long run also suggested that the speed at which realexchange rates adjust to the PPP exchange rate was extremely slow. A few yearslater, Rogoff (1996, p. 647) presented the puzzle this way: “The purchasing powerparity puzzle then is this: How can one reconcile the enormous short-term volatility ofreal exchange rates with the extremely slow rate at which shocks appear to damp out?”

As we noted above, this speed is related to the estimated coefficient in theautoregressive process described earlier: a proportion of � of any shock will stillremain after one period, �2 of it remains after two periods, and in general, �n of theshock will remain after n periods. One way to get a feel for how fast the realexchange rate mean reverts is by asking how long it would take for the effect of ashock to die out by 50 percent—in other words, we can compute the half-life ofshocks to the real exchange rate.

Based on a reading of the panel unit root and long-span investigations oflong-run PPP, Rogoff (1996) notes a high degree of consensus concerning theestimated half-lives of adjustment: they mostly tend to fall into the range of threeto five years. Moreover, most such estimates were based on ordinary least squaresmethods, which may be biased because ordinary least squares will tend to push theestimated autocorrelation coefficient away from one to avoid nonstationarity; usingdifferent estimation methods to correct for bias, but still in a linear setting, someauthors have argued that half-lives are even longer (for example, Murray andPapell, 2004; Chen and Engel, 2004). Now, although real shocks to tastes andtechnology might plausibly account for some of the observed high volatility in realexchange rates (Stockman, 1988), Rogoff argues that most of the slow speed ofadjustment must be due to the persistence in nominal variables such as nominalwages and prices. But nominal variables would be expected to adjust much fasterthan a half-life of three to five years for exchange rates would suggest.

The apparently very slow speed of adjustment of real exchange rates—from 0to about 10 percent or so per annum—has been the source of considerabletheoretical and empirical research in recent years.

Nonlinearity?

One approach to resolving the PPP puzzles lies in allowing for nonlineardynamics in real exchange rate adjustment. In a linear framework, the adjustment

146 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Page 13: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

speed of PPP deviations from parity is assumed to be uniform at all times and, inparticular, for all sizes of deviation, and implicitly the econometric problem isreduced to the estimation of a single parameter—the half-life. While this frame-work is very convenient, there are good reasons for suspecting that the speed ofconvergence toward the PPP exchange rate should be greater as the deviation fromPPP rises in absolute value. Indeed, some 90 years ago, Heckscher (1916) suggestedthat adjustment may be nonlinear because of transactions costs in internationalarbitrage. For example, if two goods differ in price (expressed in a commoncurrency) in different countries because PPP does not hold, it won’t be wortharbitraging and therefore correcting the price difference unless the anticipatedprofit exceeds the cost of shipping goods between the two locations. This insightbegan to be expressed more formally in the theoretical literature starting in the late1980s (for example, Benninga and Protopapadakis, 1988; Williams and Wright,1991; Dumas, 1992). The qualitative effect of such frictions is similar in all of theproposed models: the lack of arbitrage arising from transactions costs such asshipping costs creates a “band of inaction” within which price dynamics in the twolocations are essentially disconnected. Such transactions costs might take the formof the stylized “iceberg” shipping costs (“iceberg” because some of the goodseffectively disappear when they are shipped and the transaction cost may also beproportional to the distance shipped), fixed costs of trading operations or ofshipments or time lags for the delivery of goods from one location to another.

In empirical work on mean reversion in the real exchange rate, nonlinearitycan be examined through the estimation of models that allow the autoregressiveparameter to vary. For example, transactions costs of arbitrage may lead to changesin the real exchange rate being purely random until a threshold equal to thetransactions cost is breached, when arbitrage takes place and the real exchange ratereverts back toward the band through the influence of goods arbitrage (althoughthe return is not instantaneous because of shipping time, increasing marginal costsor other frictions). This kind of model is known as “threshold autoregressive.”

The model applies straightforwardly to individual commodities. Focusing ongold as foreign exchange, Canjels, Prakash-Canjels and Taylor (forthcoming) stud-ied the classical gold standard using such a framework applied to daily data from1879 to 1913; they found dollar-sterling exchange-rate adjustment consistent witha threshold autoregressive model. Examining subindices of the consumer priceindex, Obstfeld and Taylor (1997) modeled price adjustment in various interna-tional cities in the post-1973 period and also found significant nonlinearities. Theimplied transaction cost bands and adjustment speeds were also found to be of areasonable size (consistent with direct shipping cost measures) and to vary system-atically with impediments such as distance, tariffs, quotas and exchange-rate vola-tility. Sarno, Taylor and Chowdhury (2004) employ this approach with disaggre-gated data across a broad range of goods in the G-7 countries (Canada, France,Germany, Italy, Japan, the United Kingdom and the United States). Zussman(2003) uses a threshold autoregressive model with the postwar Penn World Tabledata to show nonlinear adjustment speeds for a very wide sample of countries.

Using a threshold autoregressive model for real exchange rates as a whole,

The Purchasing Power Parity Debate 147

Page 14: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

however, could pose some conceptual difficulties. Transactions costs are likely todiffer across goods, and so the speed at which price differentials are arbitraged maydiffer across goods (Cheung, Chinn and Fujii, 2001). Now, the aggregate realexchange rate is usually constructed as the nominal exchange rate multiplied bythe ratio of national aggregate price level indices and so, instead of a singlethreshold barrier, a range of thresholds will be relevant, corresponding to thevarious transactions costs of the various goods whose prices are included in theindices. Some of these thresholds might be quite small (for example, because thegoods are easy to ship) while others will be larger. As the real exchange rate movesfurther and further away from the level consistent with PPP, more and more of thetransactions thresholds would be breached and so the effect of arbitrage would beincreasingly felt. How might we address this type of aggregation problem? One wayis to employ a well-developed class of econometric models that embody a kind ofsmooth but nonlinear adjustment such that the speed of adjustment increases asthe real exchange rate moves further away from the level consistent with PPP.4

Using a smooth version of a threshold autoregressive model, and data on real dollarexchange rates among the G-5 countries (France, Germany, Japan, the UnitedKingdom and the United States), Taylor, Peel and Sarno (2001) reject the hypoth-esis of a unit root in favor of the alternative hypothesis of nonlinearly mean-reverting real exchange rates—and using data just for the post–Bretton Woodsperiod, thus solving the first PPP puzzle. They also find that for modest realexchange shocks in the 1 to 5 percent range, the half-life of decay is under threeyears, while for larger shocks the half-life of adjustment is estimated muchsmaller—thus going some way toward solving the second PPP puzzle.

While transactions costs models have most often been advanced as possiblesources of nonlinear adjustment, other less formal arguments for the presence ofnonlinearities have also been advanced. Kilian and Taylor (2003), for example,suggest that nonlinearity may arise from the heterogeneity of opinion in theforeign exchange market concerning the equilibrium level of the nominal ex-change rate: as the nominal rate takes on more extreme values, a greater degree ofconsensus develops concerning the appropriate direction of exchange rate moves,and traders act accordingly. Taylor (2004) argues that exchange rate nonlinearitymay also arise from the intervention operations of central banks: intervention ismore likely to occur and to be effective when the nominal—and hence thereal—exchange rate has been driven a long distance away from its PPP or funda-mental equilibrium.

In sum, the nonlinear approach to real exchange rate modeling offers someresolution of the PPP puzzles. Moreover, simulations show that if the true data are

4 The smoothly adjusting extension of the threshold autoregressive or TAR model is the aptly namedsmooth-transition autoregressive, or STAR, model (Granger and Terasvirta, 1993) and the exponentialSTAR or ESTAR has proved very successful in the application to real exchange rates (Michael, Nobayand Peel, 1997; Taylor and Peel, 2000). The ESTAR model can be thought of as a TAR with an infinitenumber of regimes and a continuously varying and bounded adjustment speed; Sarno and Taylor (2002)offer a textbook treatment. Alternative treatments of the goods-aggregation problem are currently beingexplored, but not without controversy (Imbs, Mumtaz, Ravn and Rey, 2002; Chen and Engel, 2004).

148 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Page 15: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

generated by a nonlinear process, but then a linear unit root or other linearautoregressive model is estimated, problems can easily arise. Standard unit roottests, already weak in power, are further enfeebled in this setting and half-lives canbe dramatically exaggerated (Granger and Terasvirta, 1993; Taylor, 2001; Taylor,Peel and Sarno, 2001).

The transactions-cost approach to real exchange rates is also generating influ-ential intellectual spillovers into current research flourishing at the nexus of thetwo fields of international trade and international macroeconomics. The study ofinternational trade has currently been enlivened by a new focus on the role ofphysical and other barriers, such as distance, remoteness, borders or variouspolicies (Anderson and van Wincoop, 2004). International macroeconomists arealso now making explicit the role of these trading frictions in new models wheresuch refinements may yet help us solve some of the major puzzles in the field(Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2001; Betts and Kehoe, 2001; Bergin and Glick, 2003;Ghironi and Melitz, 2003).

Remaining Puzzles: Short-Run Disturbances, Long-Run Equilibrium

Empirical work that focuses on the path of real exchange rates must grapplewith three key factors: the reversion speed; the volatility of the disturbance term;and the long-run, or equilibrium, level of the real exchange rate. Most of ourdiscussion to this point, in keeping with the focus of the literature, has pertainedto the reversion speed, which is a medium-run phenomenon. But in the future, weexpect to see more attention given to the disturbances, which are a short-runphenomenon measured over months and also to the very long run question of whatis the equilibrium real exchange rate. Thus, questions about the real exchange rateare likely to shift—from not so much “how fast is it reverting?” to “how did it deviatein the first place?” and “what is it reverting to?”5

Exchange Rate DisturbancesEven if current work can establish that exchange rates do revert to the PPP rate

over the medium term at a more reasonable speed, the volatilities present in thedata in the short run, at least under floating rate regimes, still cause considerablemystification. Over short periods, nominal exchange rates move substantially andprices do not, so real and nominal exchange rate volatilities in the short term arecorrelated almost one for one, and the Law of One Price for traded goods is oftenviolated (Flood and Rose, 1995). This pattern holds across different monetaryregime types over a wide swathe of historical experience (Taylor, 2002). Despite

5 Of course, with reference to the PPP puzzle, the literature on real exchange rates has generally beenfocused on monthly or lower frequencies, since this is where price index data are available. There areplenty of nominal exchange rate puzzles at even higher frequency—weekly, daily, even intraday—butthese are more properly in the domain of finance than international macroeconomics and are outsidethe scope of this survey.

Alan M. Taylor and Mark P. Taylor 149

Page 16: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

efforts to explain such phenomena as a result of taste or technology shocks inflexible price models, it is implausible that the patterns could be traced wholly toreal factors. History shows that volatilities also differ systematically across monetaryregimes.6 Instead, it is likely that some combination of monetary policy and pricestickiness plays a role in the short-run volatility of exchange rates, mechanisms thatcould be amplified by other types of frictions.

Various new strands in the literature seek to address these issues. One commontheme recognizes the important role of frictions in trade, not just for generatingno-arbitrage bands for traded goods, but for delineating traded from nontradedvarieties. Economies may be more closed than we once thought, since large sectorslike retailing, wholesaling and distribution are nontraded—even if the price ofimports as measured in official data typically includes some element of thesedomestic costs (Obstfeld, 2001; Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2001; Burstein, Neves andRebelo, 2003).

In an economy with price stickiness and a nontraded sector, small monetaryshocks can generate high levels of exchange rate volatility. For example, Burstein,Eichenbaum and Rebelo (2003) model a price sticky nontraded sector with a shareof the economy well above 0.5, which yields a large devaluation response of anemerging market country even for a small monetary shock. When the nontradedshare of the economy rises, the economy is less “open” and the Law of One Priceassumption applies to a smaller fraction of goods (here, imported varieties),implying a larger role for exchange rate overshooting and other sources of ex-change rate volatility (Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2000; Hau, 2000, 2002). Considerablefuture research remains to be done in this area to establish a general frameworkthat will apply to a wide range of cases.

Long-Run Movements of the Real Exchange RateThe PPP exchange rate theory is built on the concept that the exchange rate

is based on actual buying power over a basket of goods, and so changes in thenominal exchange rate should reflect changes in the price of goods—with the realexchange rate staying fixed. But a nation’s equilibrium real exchange rate may notremain fixed forever.

One of the textbook explanations for changes in the level of the real exchangerate focuses on the net international asset position. Consider a small, open econ-omy in long-run equilibrium. Now impose a shock in the form of an increase inexternal debt. The country must run a trade surplus in the future to service theinterest payments due. To encourage foreign consumers to import more, and toencourage its own consumers to import less, the country’s competitiveness mustimprove in equilibrium. With the nominal exchange rate defined as the domesticprice of foreign currency, this means that the equilibrium level of the real exchange

6 For example, it is hard to imagine that, say, the real shocks to the Argentine economy were small inthe 1960s, suddenly became several times larger during the 1980s hyperinflations, then shrank again inthe 1990s currency board epoch, only to mysteriously reappear in late 2001. But we do know that to afirst approximation Argentina’s turbulent monetary history matches the observed volatilities very closely.

150 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Page 17: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

rate must rise, making the country’s exports cheaper to foreigners and its foreignimports more expensive to domestic residents. This example supposes differenti-ated goods at home and abroad, but the logic holds in a wide range of models (likethe portfolio balance model of Taylor, 1995; Sarno and Taylor, 2002b).

Lane and Milesi-Ferreti (2002) present some empirical confirmation of thisargument. They find that countries with larger positive net asset positions havemore negative trade balances and stronger real exchange rates, controlling forother factors and allowing for real return differentials across countries. This resulthas implications for the study of real exchange rate dynamics. If the equilibriumPPP exchange rate changes as a result of changes in net wealth, and if these shiftsare not controlled for in an autoregression, then the exchange rate will appear todeviate from what is falsely assumed to be a fixed PPP rate for too much or for toolong.

The other textbook story for trending real exchange rates is built aroundnontraded goods. Standard arbitrage arguments may lead PPP to hold for tradedgoods, but these arguments fail for nontraded goods, so that we must eitherabandon PPP theory, or else modify it. The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson model ofequilibrium real exchange rates is attracting renewed interest as a desirable mod-ification after languishing for some years in relative obscurity (Harrod, 1933;Balassa, 1964; Samuelson, 1964).

In this model, rich countries supposedly grow rich by advancing productivity intraded “modern” sectors (say, manufacturing). Meantime, all nontraded “tradi-tional” sectors, in rich and poor countries alike, remain in technological stasis (say,haircuts). Suppose the Law of One Price holds among traded goods and we live ina world where labor is mobile intersectorally, but not internationally. As produc-tivity in the modern sector rises, wage levels rise, so prices of nontraded goods willhave to rise (as there has been no rise in productivity in that sector). If we measurethe overall price index as a weighted average of traded and nontraded goods prices,relatively rich countries will tend to have “overvalued” currencies. The example offast-growing Japan springs to mind, where the trend real exchange rate has steadilyappreciated by about 1.5 percent per year since 1880; the opposite trend hassometimes been observed in slow growth eras, for example, in Argentina (Taylor,2002; Froot and Rogoff, 1995; Rogoff, 1996).

Early studies of the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson effect such as Officer (1982)found little support in the data from the 1950s to the early 1970s. But newerresearch dealing with later periods has often found support for this hypothesis, andit is now textbook material (for example, Micossi and Milesi-Ferreti, 1994; DeGregorio, Giovannini and Wolf, 1994; Chinn, 2000).

Why have more recent studies provided stronger evidence of the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson effect? At some level, the reasons reflect developments in thePPP literature more broadly: more data, of longer span, for a wider sample ofcountries, coupled with more powerful univariate and panel econometric tech-niques, has allowed researchers to take a once-fuzzy relationship in the data andmake it tighter.

In addition, recent work suggests that the magnitude of the Harrod-Balassa-

The Purchasing Power Parity Debate 151

Page 18: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

Samuelson effect has been variable over time—certainly in the postwar period andperhaps going back several centuries (Bergin, Glick and Taylor, 2004). Considerthe relationships in Figure 3. The horizontal axis shows the per capita income levelof countries as a ratio of the U.S. per capita income level, expressed in log terms.The vertical axis shows the common currency Penn World Table Consumer PriceIndex price level of other countries as a ratio of the U.S. CPI price level—that is, thereal exchange rate level—again expressed as a log. (Note that most countries haveincomes and price levels lower than the United States, so the ratios are less thanone, and the logs are negative.) The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson hypothesis suggeststhat as per capita income rises, driven by productivity growth in tradables, thenprice levels should also rise: there should be a positive correlation in the scatterplot.The graphs show that the cross-country relationship between income per capita andthe price level has been intensifying since 1950; once close to zero, and statisticallyinsignificant, the elasticity is now over one half. The null hypothesis of a zero slopecan be rejected beginning in the early 1960s when Balassa and Samuelson wrotetheir seminal papers (albeit with no knowledge of these hypothesis tests).

It is not clear why the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson effect has altered over time.One possible explanation is that the nontraded share has increased over time, butthis effect does not seem to have enough magnitude to match the changes that haveoccurred, nor to match the timing of the changes (remember that global trade in1950, after world wars and depression, was a lower share of output than in 1913 orin 2000). Perhaps the productivity advances of traded and nontraded goods havediffered at various times? This may better help us explain the data, but over longtime frames begs the question of which goods are traded and why. Bergin, Glickand Taylor (2004) advance the hypothesis that trade costs determine tradabilitypatterns, which allows a variety of possible productivity shocks to give rise eventuallyto an endogenous Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson effect.

Figure 3Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effects Emerge: Log Price Level versus Log Per CapitaIncome

�3

�2

�1

0

1

�4 �3 �2 �1 0 1�5

ln(p

/pU

S)

ln(y/yUS)

(a) 1995 data (N � 142)

�2

�1

0

1

�3 �2 �1 0�4

ln(p

/pU

S)

ln(y/yUS)

(b) 1950 data (N � 53)

�1

0

1

�2 �1 0 1�3

ln(p

/pU

S)

ln(y/yUS)

(c) 1913 data (N � 24)

Notes: This figure shows countries’ log price level (vertical axis) against log real income per capita for1995, 1950 and 1913, with the United States used as the base country.

152 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Page 19: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

But the key point here is that if the equilibrium exchange rate is movinggradually over time, and our statistical analysis presupposes that the PPP exchangerate is fixed over time, then estimates of the speed of reversion to the PPP will bebiased. An allowance for such long-run trends can make a material difference inresolving the puzzles about whether and how fast the exchange rate moves to itsPPP level. For example, Taylor (2002) finds relatively low half-lives in a 20-countrypanel when an allowance is made for long-run trends in the equilibrium exchangerate. Allowing for nonlinear time trends, Lothian and Taylor (2000) suggest thatthe half-life of deviations from PPP for the U.S.-UK exchange rate may be as low as21

2years. Lothian and Taylor (2004) show that the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson effect

may account for about a third of the variation in this real exchange rate.The equilibrium real exchange rate could shift for a number of reasons over

the very long run: wealth effects, productivity effects and other forces could all beimportant. Models that allow for a time-varying equilibrium real exchange rate, andpermit an exploration of its causes and consequences, are likely to be a busy areafor future research. Coordinated progress on these fronts will not only refine ourresolution of the PPP puzzles, they will also help us address related puzzles in themacroeconomic literature. For example, Engel (1999, 2000) decomposed thevariance of the real exchange rate into external traded goods prices and internaltraded-versus-nontraded goods prices. The component related to external tradedgoods can be viewed as related to the Law of One Price in the basic version of thePPP theory where the real exchange rate is assumed to be fixed, while the compo-nent related to traded and nontraded goods can be related to the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson effect or any approach where the real exchange rate has a trend. Inlooking at post–Bretton Woods samples of data, Engel found that both of thesecomponents have persistence, but the Law of One Price component seems toexperience larger shocks. The two insights may also be unified, as in recent modelsof endogenous tradability (Betts and Kehoe 2001; Bergin and Glick, 2003). Theresearcher can use nonlinear models with trade costs to understand the volatilityrelated to traded goods—as Parsley and Wei (2003) do with the Engel puzzle—andthen use some version of the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson effect to model andestimate the slower and often obscured drift in the prices of nontraded goods.

Conclusion

Since the early 1970s, the purchasing power parity theory of exchange rates hasbeen the subject of an ongoing and lively debate. For much of that period,theoretical work suggested that exchange rates should be linked to relative changesin price levels with deviations that might be only minimal or momentary, whileempirical work could find only the flimsiest evidence in support of purchasingpower parity, and even these weak findings implied an extremely slow rate ofreversion to PPP of, at best, three to five years.

After a struggle to find common ground, the gap between theory and empiricsis being closed from both directions. After early disappointments with dynamic

Alan M. Taylor and Mark P. Taylor 153

Page 20: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

general equilibrium models, recent applications with nominal price rigidities showhow monetary shocks may have large and long-lasting effects on the real exchangerate (Bergin and Feenstra, 2001). When such insights are combined with theoret-ical work on transactions costs and nonlinearity, we can now better understand thevolatility and persistence of the real exchange rate. Going further, the presence ofnontraded goods (a manifestation of extreme transaction costs) enriches ourmodels further. A renewed attention to the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson effect andwealth effects leads to a modified view of PPP where the equilibrium real exchangerate itself may move over time.

The idea that transaction costs matter for PPP is an old one. For Hume(1742–1752 [1987]), goods arbitrage caused countervailing flows of specie, with theanalogy that “all water, wherever it communicates, remains always at a level,” exceptthat if markets are separated “by any material of physical impediment. . .there may,in such a case, be a very great inequality of money.” Heckscher (1916) developedthe idea further, introducing the concept of “commodity points.” Keynes (1923,pp. 89–90, 91–92) highlighted transaction costs as a key substantive issue for thePPP theory:

At first sight this theory appears to be one of great practical utility. . . . Inpractical applications of the doctrine there are, however, two further difficul-ties, which we have allowed so far to escape our attention,—both of themarising out of the words allowance being made for transport charges and imports andexport taxes. The first difficulty is how to make allowance for such charges andtaxes. The second difficulty is how to treat purchasing power of goods andservice which do not enter into international trade at all. . . . For, if we restrictourselves to articles entering into international trade and make exact allow-ance for transport and tariff costs, we should find that the theory is always inaccordance with the facts. . . . In fact, the theory, stated thus, is a truism, andas nearly as possible jejune.

As these venerable ideas start to be incorporated into formal theory andempirics—in particular, via nonlinear adjustment—results are suggesting morestrongly that exchange rates do revert to a certain level determined by the pricelevel in the long run and that the half-life of this reversion is short enough, atperhaps one to three years for moderately sized shocks of more than 1 or 2 percent,to seem theoretically plausible.

Several new directions could now be taken. A very general theoretical modelcould be developed to incorporate all of the above refinements simultaneously andits predictions studied. Empiricists could attempt to include both nonlinearitiesand Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson effects to get even tighter estimates of convergencespeeds. Introducing trade costs and real shocks into a Clarida and Galı (1994)decomposition might advance the potential for reconciliation even further.

In sum, however, our interpretation of the consensus view of the PPP debate—that short-run PPP does not hold, that long-run PPP may hold in the sense thatthere is significant mean reversion of the real exchange rate, although there may

154 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Page 21: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

be factors impinging on the equilibrium real exchange rate through time—ishighly reminiscent of the consensus view that held sway in the period before the1970s. In that sense, this paper may be taken as evidence of mean reversion ineconomic thought.

y For their helpful comments we thank, without implicating, Menzie Chinn, Richard Clarida,Bradford DeLong, Charles Engel, Jeffrey Frankel, James Hines, James Lothian, BennettMcCallum, Michael Melvin, Peter Neary, Maurice Obstfeld, Lawrence Officer, David Papell,David Peel, Phillip Lane, Kenneth Rogoff, Andrew Rose, Lucio Sarno, Timothy Taylor, Ericvan Wincoop and Michael Waldman.

References

Abuaf, Niso and Philippe Jorion. 1990. “Pur-chasing Power Parity in the Long Run.” Journal ofFinance. 45:1, pp. 157–74.

Adler, Michael and Bruce Lehmann. 1983.“Deviations from Purchasing Power Parity in theLong Run.” Journal of Finance. 38:5, pp. 1471–487.

Anderson, James E. and Eric van Wincoop.2004. “Trade Costs.” Journal of Economic Litera-ture. 42:3, pp. 691–751.

Balassa, Bela. 1964. “The Purchasing-PowerParity Doctrine: A Reappraisal.” Journal of Politi-cal Economy. 72:6, pp. 584–96.

Benninga, Simon and Aris A. Protopapadakis.1988. “The Equilibrium Pricing of ExchangeRates and Assets When Trade Takes Time.” Jour-nal of International Economics. 7:2, pp. 129–49.

Bergin, Paul R. and Robert C. Feenstra. 2001.“Pricing-to-Market, Staggered Contracts, andReal Exchange Rate Persistence.” Journal of Inter-national Economics. 54:2, pp. 333–59.

Bergin, Paul R. and Reuven Glick. 2003. “En-dogenous Nontradability and MacroeconomicImplications.” Working Paper Series No. 9739,National Bureau of Economic Research, June.

Bergin, Paul R., Reuven Glick and Alan M.Taylor. 2004. “Productivity, Tradability, and theLong-Run Price Puzzle.” Working Paper SeriesNo. 10569, National Bureau of Economic Re-search, June.

Betts, Caroline M. and Timothy J. Kehoe.2001. “Tradability of Goods and Real ExchangeRate Fluctuations.” University of SouthernCalifornia.

Burstein, Ariel, Martin Eichenbaum and Ser-

gio Rebelo. 2003. “Large Devaluations and theReal Exchange Rate.” Photocopy, NorthwesternUniversity, September.

Burstein, Ariel, Joao Neves, and Sergio Re-belo. 2003. “Distribution Costs and Real Ex-change Rate Dynamics.” Journal of Monetary Eco-nomics. 50:6, pp. 1189–214.

Canjels, Eugene, Gauri Prakash-Canjels andAlan M. Taylor. 2004. “Measuring Market Inte-gration: Foreign Exchange Arbitrage and theGold Standard, 1879–1913.” Review of Economicsand Statistics. 86:4.

Cassel, Gustav. 1918. “Abnormal Deviations inInternational Exchanges.” Economic Journal. De-cember, 28, pp. 413–15.

Cassel, Gustav. 1922. Money and Foreign Ex-change After 1914. New York: Macmillan.

Chen, Shiu-Sheng and Charles Engel. 2004.“Does ‘Aggregation Bias’ Explain the PPP Puz-zle?” Working Paper Series No. 10304, NationalBureau of Economic Research, February.

Cheung, Yin-Wong, Menzie Chinn and Eiji Fu-jii. 2001. “Market Structure and the Persistenceof Sectoral Real Exchange Rates.” InternationalJournal of Finance and Economics. 6:2, pp. 95–114.

Chinn, Menzie D. 2000. “The Usual Suspects?Productivity and Demand Shocks and Asia-Pacific Real Exchange Rates.” Review of Interna-tional Economics. 8:1, pp. 20–43.

Clarida, Richard and Jordi Galı. 1994.“Sources of Real Exchange rate Fluctuations:How Important are Nominal Shocks?” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. 41,pp. 1–55.

Coakley, Jerry, Robert Flood, Ana-Maria

The Purchasing Power Parity Debate 155

Page 22: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

Fuertes and Mark P. Taylor. 2004. “Long-RunPurchasing Power Parity and the Theory of Gen-eral Relativity: the First Tests.” Photocopy, Uni-versity of Warwick. Journal of International Moneyand Finance. Forthcoming.

Corbae, P. Dean and Sam Ouliaris. 1988.“Cointegration and Tests of Purchasing PowerParity.” Review of Economics and Statistics. 70:3,pp. 508–11.

Cumby, Robert E. and Maurice Obstfeld.1984. “International Interest Rate and PriceLevel Linkages under Flexible Exchange Rates:A Review of Recent Evidence,” in Exchange RateTheory and Practice. John F. O. Bilson and Rich-ard C. Marston, eds. Chicago: University of Chi-cago Press, pp. 121–51.

Davutyan, Nurhan and John Pippenger. 1990.“Testing Purchasing Power Parity: Some Evi-dence of the Effects of Transaction Costs.” Econo-metric Reviews. 9:2, pp. 211–40.

De Grauwe, Paul, Marc Janssens and HildeLeliaert. 1985. Real Exchange-Rate Variability from1920 to 1926 and 1973 to 1982. Princeton: Prince-ton Studies in International Finance.

De Gregorio, Jose and Holger C. Wolf. 1994.“Terms of Trade, Productivity, and the Real Ex-change Rate.” Working Paper Series No. 4807,National Bureau of Economic Research, July.

De Gregorio, Jose, Alberto Giovannini andHolger C. Wolf. 1994. “International Evidenceon Tradable and Nontradables Inflation.” Euro-pean Economic Review. 38:6, pp. 1225–244.

Dornbusch, Rudiger. 1976. “Expectations andExchange Rate Dynamics.” Journal of PoliticalEconomy. 84:6, pp. 1161–176.

Dornbusch, Rudiger and Paul Krugman. 1976.“Flexible Exchange Rates in the Short Run.”Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 1:3, pp. 537–75.

Dumas, Bernard. 1992. “Dynamic Equilibriumand the Real Exchange Rate in a Spatially Sep-arated World.” Review of Financial Studies. 5:2,pp. 153–80.

Edison, Hali J. 1987. “Purchasing Power Parityin the Long Run: A Test of the Dollar/PoundExchange Rate, 1890–1978.” Journal of Money,Credit and Banking. 19:3, pp. 376–87.

Engel, Charles. 1999. “Accounting for U.S.Real Exchange Rate Changes.” Journal of PoliticalEconomy. 107:3, pp. 507–38.

Engel, Charles. 2000. “Long-Run PPP May NotHold After All.” Journal of International Economics.51:2, pp. 243–73.

Engle, Robert and Clive W. J. Granger. 1987.“Co-integration and Error Correction: Repre-sentation, Estimation and Testing.” Econometrica.55:2, pp. 251–76.

Flood, Robert P. and Andrew K. Rose. 1995.

“Fixing Exchange Rates: A Virtual Quest for Fun-damentals.” Journal of Monetary Economics. 36:1,pp. 3–37.

Frankel, Jeffrey A. 1986. “International Capi-tal Mobility and Crowding-out in the U.S. Econ-omy: Imperfect Integration of Financial Marketsor of Goods Markets?” in How Open is the U.S.Economy? R. W. Hafer, ed. Lexington, Mass.: Lex-ington Books, pp. 33–67.

Frankel, Jeffrey A. 1990. “Zen and the Art ofModern Macroeconomics: A Commentary,” inMonetary Policy for a Volatile Global Economy. W. S.Haraf and T. D. Willett, eds. Washington, D.C.:AEI Press, pp. 117–23.

Frankel, Jeffrey A. and Andrew K. Rose. 1995.“Empirical Research on Nominal ExchangeRates,” in Handbook of International Economics, Vol-ume 3. G. Grossman and K. Rogoff, eds. Amster-dam, New York and Oxford: Elsevier, North-Holland, chapter 33.

Frankel, Jeffrey A. and Andrew K. Rose. 1996.“A Panel Project on Purchasing Power Parity:Mean Reversion Within and Between Coun-tries.” Journal of International Economics. 40:1-2,pp. 209–24.

Frenkel, Jacob A. 1976. “A Monetary Ap-proach to the Exchange Rate: Doctrinal Aspectsand Empirical Evidence.” Scandinavian Journal ofEconomics. 78:2, pp. 200–24.

Frenkel, Jacob A. 1981. “The Collapse of Pur-chasing Power Parity During the 1970s.” Euro-pean Economic Review. 16:1, pp. 145–65.

Frenkel, Jacob A. and Harry G. Johnson. 1976.The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments.London: Allen & Unwin.

Froot, Kenneth A. and Kenneth Rogoff. 1995.“Perspectives on PPP and Long-Run Real Ex-change Rates,” in Handbook of International Eco-nomics. G. Grossman and K. Rogoff, eds. Amster-dam: North Holland, pp. 1647–688.

Glen, Jack D. 1992. “Real Exchange Rates inthe Short, Medium, and Long Run.” Journal ofInternational Economics. 33:1-2, pp. 147–66.

Granger, Clive W. J. and Timo Terasvirta.1993. Modelling Nonlinear Economic Relationships.Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Harrod, Roy. 1933. International Economics.London: Nisbet and Cambridge University Press.

Hau, Harald. 2000. “Exchange Rate Determi-nation under Factor Price Rigidities.” Journal ofInternational Economics. 50:2, pp. 421–47.

Hau, Harald. 2002. “Real Exchange Rate Vol-atility and Economic Openness: Theory and Ev-idence.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking.34:3, pp. 611–30.

Heckscher, Eli F. 1916. “Vaxelkurens grundvalvid pappersmynfot.” Economisk Tidskrift. 18,pp. 309–12.

156 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Page 23: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

Hsieh, David. 1982. “The Determination ofthe Real Exchange Rate: The Productivity Ap-proach.” Journal of International Economics. May,12, pp. 355–62.

Huizinga, John. 1987. “An Empirical Investi-gation of the Long-Run Behavior of Real Ex-change Rates.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Serieson Public Policy. 27, pp. 149–215.

Hume, David. 1742–1752 [1987]. Essays,Moral, Political, and Literary. Indianapolis, Ind.:The Liberty Fund.

Imbs, Jean, Haroon Mumtaz, Morten Ravnand Helene Rey. 2002. “PPP Strikes Back: Aggre-gation and the Real Exchange Rate.” WorkingPaper Series No. 9372, National Bureau of Eco-nomic Research, December, Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, forthcoming.

Ito, Takatoshi, Peter Isard and Steven Syman-sky. 1999. “Economic Growth and Real Ex-change Rate: An Overview of the Balassa-Samuelson Hypothesis in Asia,” in Changes inExchange Rates in Rapidly Developing Countries:Theory, Practice, and Policy Issues. T. Ito and A. O.Krueger, eds. Chicago: University of ChicagoPress, pp. 109–28.

Keynes, John Maynard. 1923. A Tract on Mon-etary Reform. London: Macmillan.

Kilian, Lutz and Mark P. Taylor. 2003. “Why isit So Difficult to Beat the Random Walk Forecastof Exchange Rates?” Journal of International Eco-nomics. 60:1, pp. 85–107.

Lane, Philip and Gian Maria Mileri-Ferretti.2002. “External Wealth, the Trade Balance andthe Real Exchange Rate.” European Economic Re-view. 46:6, pp. 1049–071.

Lothian, James R. 1990. “A Century Plus ofJapanese Exchange Rate Behavior.” Japan and theWorld Economy. February/March, 2, pp. 47–50.

Lothian, James R. and Mark P. Taylor. 1996.“Real Exchange Rate Behavior: The RecentFloat From the Perspective of the Past TwoCenturies.” Journal of Political Economy. 104:3,pp. 488–509.

Lothian, James R. and Mark P. Taylor. 1997.“Real Exchange Rate Behavior: The Problem ofPower and Sample Size.” Journal of InternationalMoney and Finance. 16:6, pp. 945–54.

Lothian, James R. and Mark P. Taylor. 2004.“Real Exchange Rates, Nonlinearity and RelativeProductivity: The Long and the Short of It.”Photocopy, University of Warwick.

Mark, Nelson. 1990. “Real and Nominal Ex-change Rates in the Long Run: An EmpiricalInvestigation.” Journal of International Economics.28:1-2, pp. 115–36.

Michael, Panos, A. Robert Nobay and DavidA. Peel. 1997. “Transaction Costs and NonlinearAdjustment in Real Exchange Rates: An Empir-

ical Investigation.” Journal of Political Economy.105:4, pp. 862–79.

Micossi, Stefano and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti. 1994. “Real Exchange Rates and thePrices of Nontradable Goods.” Working PapersNo. 94/19, International Monetary Fund.

Murray, Christian J. and David H. Papell.2004. “The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle isWorse Than You Think.” Photocopy, Universityof Houston, January.

Obstfeld, Maurice. 2001. “InternationalMacroeconomics: Beyond the Mundell-Flem-ing Model” IMF Staff Papers. Special Issue, 47,pp. 1–39.

Obstfeld, Maurice and Kenneth Rogoff. 2000.“The Six Major Puzzles in International Macro-economics: Is There a Common Cause?” NBERMacroeconomics Annual 2000. 115:1, pp. 339–90.

Obstfeld, Maurice and Alan M. Taylor. 1997.“Nonlinear Aspects of Goods-Market Arbitrageand Adjustment: Heckscher’s Commodity PointsRevisited.” Journal of the Japanese and InternationalEconomies. 11:4, pp. 441–79.

Obstfeld, Maurice and Alan M. Taylor. 2004.Global Capital Markets: Integration, Crisis, andGrowth. Japan-U.S. Center Sanwa Monographson International Financial Markets Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.

O’Connell, Paul G. J. and Shang-Jin Wei.2002. “‘The Bigger They are, the Harder TheyFall’: Retail Price Differences Across U.S. Cit-ies.” Journal of International Economics. 56:1,pp. 21–53.

Officer, Lawrence H. 1982. Purchasing PowerParity and Exchange Rates: Theory, Evidence andRelevance. Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press.

Papell, David H. 1997. “Searching for Station-arity: Purchasing Power Parity Under the Cur-rent Float.” Journal of International Economics. 43:3-4, pp. 313–32.

Parsley, David C. and Shang-Jin Wei. 2003.“A Prism into the PPP Puzzles: The Micro-Foundations of Big Mac Real Exchange Rates.”Working Paper Series No. 10074, NationalBureau of Economic Research, November.

Redding, Stephen and Anthony J. Venables.2001. “Economic Geography and InternationalInequality.” Discussion Paper No. 0495, Centrefor Economic Performance, London School ofEconomics, May.

Rogoff, Kenneth. 1996. “The PurchasingPower Parity Puzzle.” Journal of Economic Litera-ture. 34:2, pp. 647–68.

Roll, Richard. 1979. “Violations of PurchasingPower Parity and their Implications for EfficientInternational Commodity Markets,” in Interna-tional Finance and Trade, Volume 1. M. Sarnat and

Alan M. Taylor and Mark P. Taylor 157

Page 24: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

G.P. Szego, eds. Cambridge. Mass.: Ballinger,pp. 133–76.

Samuelson, Paul A. 1964. “Theoretical Noteson Trade Problems.” Review of Economics and Sta-tistics. 46:2, pp. 145–54.

Sarno, Lucio and Mark P. Taylor. 2002a. “Pur-chasing Power Parity and the Real ExchangeRate.” International Monetary Fund Staff Papers.49:1, pp. 65–105.

Sarno, Lucio and Mark P. Taylor. 2002b. TheEconomics of Exchange Rates. Cambridge: Cam-bridge University Press.

Sarno, Lucio, Ibrahim Chowdhury and MarkP. Taylor. 2004. “Non-Linear Dynamics in Devi-ations from the Law of One Price: A Broad-Based Empirical Study.” Journal of InternationalMoney and Finance. 23:1, pp. 1–25.

Sercu, Piet, Raman Uppal and Cynthia VanHulle. 1995. “The Exchange Rate in the Pres-ence of Transaction Costs: Implications for Testsof Purchasing Power Parity.” Journal of Finance.50, pp. 1309–319.

Shiller, Robert J. and Pierre Perron. 1985.“Testing the Random Walk Hypothesis: PowerVersus Frequency of Observation.” Economics Let-ters. 18:4, pp. 381–86.

Stockman, Alan C. 1987. “The EquilibriumApproach to Exchange Rates.” Federal ReserveBank of Richmond Economic Review. 73:2, pp. 12–30.

Stockman, Alan C. 1988. “Real Exchange RateVariability under Pegged and Floating NominalExchange Rate Systems: An Equilibrium The-ory.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on PublicPolicy. 29, pp. 259–94.

Taylor, Alan M. 2001. “Potential Pitfalls forthe Purchasing-Power Parity Puzzle? Samplingand Specification Biases in Mean-ReversionTests of the Law of One Price.” Econometrica.69:2, pp. 473–98.

Taylor, Alan M. 2002. “A Century of Purchas-ing Power Parity.” Review of Economics and Statis-tics. 84:1, pp. 139–50.

Taylor, Mark P. 1988. “An Empirical Exami-nation of Long-Run Purchasing Power Parity Us-ing Cointegration Techniques.” Applied Econom-ics. 20:10, pp. 1369–381.

Taylor, Mark P. 1995. “The Economics of Ex-change Rates.” Journal of Economic Literature. 33:1,pp. 13–47.

Taylor, Mark P. 2004. “Is Official ExchangeRate Intervention Effective?” Economica. 71:1,pp. 1–12.

Taylor, Mark P. and Patrick C. McMahon.1988. “Long-Run Purchasing Power Parity in the1920s.” European Economic Review. 32:1, pp. 179–97.

Taylor, Mark P. and Lucio Sarno. 1998. “TheBehavior of Real Exchange Rates During thePost–Bretton Woods Period.” Journal of Interna-tional Economics. 46:2, pp. 281–312.

Taylor, Mark P. and Lucio Sarno. 2004. “In-ternational Real Interest Rate Differentials, Pur-chasing Power Parity and the Behaviour of RealExchange Rates: The Resolution of a Conun-drum.” International Journal of Finance and Eco-nomics. 9:1, pp. 15–23.

Taylor, Mark P., David A. Peel and LucioSarno. 2001. “Nonlinear Mean-Reversion in RealExchange Rates: Towards a Solution to the Pur-chasing Power Parity Puzzles.” International Eco-nomic Review. 42:4, pp. 1015–042.

Williams, Jeffrey C. and Brian D. Wright.1991. Storage and Commodity Markets. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.

Zussman, Asaf. 2003. “The Limits of Arbi-trage: Trading Frictions and Deviations fromPurchasing Power Parity.” SIEPR Policy PaperNo. 02-012.

158 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Page 25: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

This article has been cited by:

1. Guochen Pan, Tsangyao Chang, Chia-Hao Lee, Wen-Chi Liu. 2012. Revisiting purchasing powerparity for 18 African countries: sequential panel selection method. Applied Economics Letters19:9, 877-881. [CrossRef]

2. Guochen Pan, Tsangyao Chang, D.P. Tang, Chia-Hao Lee. 2012. Nonlinear adjustment topurchasing power parity in Latin American countries: the ADL test for threshold cointegration.Applied Economics Letters 19:9, 857-862. [CrossRef]

3. Tsangyao Chang. 2012. Nonlinear adjustment to purchasing power parity in China. AppliedEconomics Letters 19:9, 843-848. [CrossRef]

4. Tsangyao Chang, Chi-Wei Su, Yu-Shao Liu. 2012. Purchasing power parity with nonlinearthreshold unit root test. Applied Economics Letters 19:9, 839-842. [CrossRef]

5. Tsangyao Chang, Yu-Shao Liu, Chi-Wei Su. 2012. Purchasing power parity with nonlinear andasymmetric smooth adjustment for the Middle Eastern countries. Applied Economics Letters 19:5,487-491. [CrossRef]

6. Tsangyao Chang, Chia-Hao Lee, Pei-I Chou. 2012. Nonlinear adjustment to purchasing powerparity in G-7 countries. Applied Economics Letters 19:2, 123-128. [CrossRef]

7. Gawon Yoon. 2011. An empirical demonstration of classical comparative cost theory: a correctionto Balassa (1963). Applied Financial Economics 21:23, 1765-1767. [CrossRef]

8. Doo-Yull Choi, Bong-Han Kim, See-Won Kim. 2011. Nonlinear mean-reversion in SoutheastAsian real exchange rates. Applied Financial Economics 21:19, 1409-1421. [CrossRef]

9. Salah A. Nusair. 2011. Nonlinear adjustment of Asian real exchange rates. Economic Change andRestructuring . [CrossRef]

10. Jan Marc Berk, Job Swank. 2011. Price level convergence and regional Phillips curves in the USand EMU. Journal of International Money and Finance 30:5, 749-763. [CrossRef]

11. Gabriel Porcile, Alexandre Gomes da Silva, Ricardo Viana. 2011. External debt sustainability andpolicy rules in a small globalized economy. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 22:3,269-276. [CrossRef]

12. Chikashi Tsuji. 2011. Positive return premia in Japan. Quantitative Finance 1-23. [CrossRef]

13. Yang-Cheng Ralph Lu, Tsangyao Chang, Chia-Hao Lee. 2011. Nonlinear adjustment topurchasing power parity in transition countries: the ADL test for threshold cointegration. AppliedEconomics Letters 1-5. [CrossRef]

14. Hsu-Ling Chang, De-Chih Liu, Chi-Wei Su. 2011. Purchasing power parity with flexible Fourierstationary test for Central and Eastern European countries. Applied Economics 1-8. [CrossRef]

15. Siyue Liu, Tsangyao Chang, Chia-Hao Lee, Pei-I Chou. 2011. Nonlinear adjustment to purchasingpower parity: the ADL test for threshold cointegration. Applied Economics Letters 1-5. [CrossRef]

16. Ahmad Zubaidi Baharumshah, Siew-Voon Soon. 2011. Mean reversion in bilateral real exchangerates: evidence from the Malaysian ringgit. Applied Economics 1-13. [CrossRef]

17. Steven Gjerstad. 2011. Price dynamics in an exchange economy. Economic Theory . [CrossRef]

18. Su-Yuan Lin, Horng-Jinh Chang, Tsangyao Chang. 2011. Revisiting purchasing power parity fornine transition countries: a Fourier stationary test. Post-Communist Economies 23:2, 191-201.[CrossRef]

19. Yamin Ahmad, Stuart Glosser. 2011. Searching for nonlinearities in real exchange rates. AppliedEconomics 43:15, 1829-1845. [CrossRef]

Page 26: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

20. Joseph Kargbo. 2011. Capital flows, real exchange rate misalignment and PPP tests in emergingmarket countries. Applied Economics 43:15, 1883-1897. [CrossRef]

21. Yang-Cheng Lu, Tsangyao Chang. 2011. Long-run purchasing power parity with asymmetricadjustment: further evidence from China. Applied Economics Letters 18:9, 881-886. [CrossRef]

22. Yiguo Sun, Cheng Hsiao, Qi Li. 2011. Measuring correlations of integrated but not cointegratedvariables: A semiparametric approach. Journal of Econometrics . [CrossRef]

23. Augustine C. Arize. 2011. Purchasing power parity in LDCs: An empirical investigation. GlobalFinance Journal . [CrossRef]

24. Philip L. Brock. 2011. The Penn–Balassa–Samuelson effect through the lens of the dependenteconomy model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control . [CrossRef]

25. Chi-Wei Su, Tsangyao Chang, Hsu-Ling Chang. 2011. Purchasing Power Parity for Fifteen LatinAmerican Countries: Stationary Test with a Fourier Function. International Review of Economics& Finance . [CrossRef]

26. Tsangyao Chang, Han-Wen Tzeng. 2011. Long-run purchasing power parity with asymmetricadjustment: Further evidence from nine transition countries. Economic Modelling . [CrossRef]

27. Chunming Yuan. 2011. The exchange rate and macroeconomic determinants: Time-varyingtransitional dynamics. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance . [CrossRef]

28. Samira Haddou. 2011. Is Tunisian Real Effective Exchange Rate Mean Reverting? Evidence fromNonlinear Models. Transition Studies Review . [CrossRef]

29. Frederick Wallace. 2011. Purchasing power parity in Mexico: a historical note. Applied EconomicsLetters 18:4, 349-352. [CrossRef]

30. Su Zhou, Ali M. Kutan. 2011. Is the evidence for PPP reliable? A sustainability examination ofthe stationarity of real exchange rates. Journal of Banking & Finance . [CrossRef]

31. Yang-Cheng Ralph Lu, Tsangyao Chang, Chi-Chen Chiu, Han-Wen Tzeng. 2011. Revisitingpurchasing power parity for 16 Latin American countries: panel SURADF tests. AppliedEconomics Letters 18:3, 251-255. [CrossRef]

32. Yi-Hua Wu, Eric Lin. 2011. Does purchasing power parity hold following the launch of the euro?Evidence from the panel unit root test. Applied Economics Letters 18:2, 167-172. [CrossRef]

33. Jan Marc Berk, Job Swank. 2011. Price level convergence and regional Phillips curves in the USand EMU. Journal of International Money and Finance 30:5, 749. [CrossRef]

34. Alfred Haug, Syed Basher. 2011. Linear or nonlinear cointegration in the purchasing power parityrelationship?. Applied Economics 43:2, 185-196. [CrossRef]

35. Tsangyao Chang, Yang-Cheng Lu, D. P. Tang, Wen-Chi Liu. 2011. Long-run purchasing powerparity with asymmetric adjustment: further evidence from African countries. Applied Economics43:2, 231-242. [CrossRef]

36. Chi-Wei Su, Hsu-Ling Chang, Meng-Nan Zhu, Yi-Chu Lai. 2011. Purchasing power parityin major OPEC countries: nonlinear threshold unit root test. Applied Economics Letters 1-4.[CrossRef]

37. Tsangyao Chang, Yang-Cheng Lu, Wen-Chi Liu, Shu-Chen Kang. 2011. Revisiting purchasingpower parity for major oil-exporting countries using panel SURADF tests. Applied EconomicsLetters 18:1, 63-67. [CrossRef]

38. Kamrul Hassan, Ruhul Salim. 2011. The linkage between relative population growth andpurchasing power parity: Cross country evidence. International Journal of Development Issues10:2, 154-169. [CrossRef]

Page 27: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

39. Yukio Fukumoto. 2011. International price dispersions of the Big Mac and economic integration.Applied Economics Letters 1-6. [CrossRef]

40. Yang-Cheng Ralph Lu, Tsangyao Chang, Kuei-Chiu Lee, Han-Wen Tzeng. 2011. An empirical testof the purchasing power parity for transition economies: Panel SURADF tests. Applied EconomicsLetters 1-6. [CrossRef]

41. Tsung-Hsien Chen, Tsangyao Chang, Yi-Chun Zhang, Chia-Hao Lee. 2011. Purchasing powerparity in Mainland China and Taiwan: an empirical note based on threshold unit root test. AppliedEconomics Letters 1-6. [CrossRef]

42. Tsangyao Chang, Kuei-Chiu Lee, Yang-Cheng Ralph Lu, Guochen Pan. 2011. Revisitingpurchasing power parity for G-7 countries using nonparametric rank test for cointegration. AppliedEconomics Letters 1-6. [CrossRef]

43. Tsangyao Chang, Hsu-Ling Chang, Ken Hung, Chi-Wei Su. 2011. Nonlinear adjustment topurchasing power parity for Germany's real exchange rate relative to its major trading partners.Applied Economics Letters 1-6. [CrossRef]

44. Darja Borsic, Ahmad Zubaidi Baharumshah, Jani Bek#. 2011. Are we getting closer to purchasingpower parity in Central and Eastern European economies?. Applied Economics Letters 1-5.[CrossRef]

45. Chi-Wei Su, Tsangyao Chang, Yu-Shao Liu. 2011. Revisiting purchasing power parity for Africancountries: with nonlinear panel unit-root tests. Applied Economics 1-11. [CrossRef]

46. Chi-Wei Su, Hsu-Ling Chang, Meng-Nan Zhu. 2011. Flexible Fourier stationary test in purchasingpower parity for African countries. Applied Economics 1-8. [CrossRef]

47. Jean M. Imbs, Haroon Mumtaz, Morten O. Ravn, Hélène Rey. 2010. One TV, One Price?*.Scandinavian Journal of Economics 112:4, 753-781. [CrossRef]

48. Miguel Lacerda, Johannes W. Fedderke, Linda M. Haines. 2010. TESTING FOR PURCHASINGPOWER PARITY AND UNCOVERED INTEREST PARITY IN THE PRESENCE OFMONETARY AND EXCHANGE RATE REGIME SHIFTS. South African Journal of Economics78:4, 363-382. [CrossRef]

49. Helmut Herwartz, Florian Siedenburg. 2010. A New Approach to Unit Root Testing.Computational Economics 36:4, 365-384. [CrossRef]

50. Marjan Senjur. 2010. Differential inflation, Phillips curves, and price competitiveness in a neweuro-member country. Economic Change and Restructuring 43:4, 253-273. [CrossRef]

51. Jen-Chi Cheng, Larry Taylor, Wenlong Weng. 2010. The links between international parityconditions and Granger causality: a study of exchange rates and prices. Applied Economics 42:27,3491-3501. [CrossRef]

52. H. Levent Korap, Ozgur Aslan. 2010. Re-examination of the long-run purchasing power parity:further evidence from Turkey. Applied Economics 42:27, 3559-3564. [CrossRef]

53. Tsangyao Chang, Wen-Chi Liu, Chin-Ping Yu, Shuchen Kang. 2010. Purchasing power parityfor 10 Latin American integration association countries: panel SURKSS tests. Applied EconomicsLetters 17:16, 1575-1580. [CrossRef]

54. Tsangyao Chang, De-Piao Tang, Wen-Chi Liu, Chia-Hao Lee. 2010. Purchasing power parity for15 COMESA and SADC countries: evidence based on panel SURADF tests. Applied EconomicsLetters 17:17, 1721-1727. [CrossRef]

55. Catherine Ho, M. Ariff. 2010. Sticky prices and time to equilibrium: evidence from Asia-Pacifictrade-related economies. Applied Economics 1-11. [CrossRef]

56. Tsangyao Chang, YiChun Zhang, Wen-Chi Liu. 2010. Purchasing power parity for ASEAN-8countries: panel SURKSS tests. Applied Economics Letters 17:15, 1517-1523. [CrossRef]

Page 28: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

57. Mehmet Huseyin Bilgin, Chi Keung Marco Lau, Ender Demir, Nijol# Astrauskien#. 2010. RentalPrice Convergence in a Developing Economy: New Evidence from Nonlinear Panel Unit RootTest. International Journal of Strategic Property Management 14:3, 245-257. [CrossRef]

58. Søren Johansen, Katarina Juselius, Roman Frydman, Michael Goldberg. 2010. Testing hypothesesin an I(2)I(2) model with piecewise linear trends. An analysis of the persistent long swings in theDmk/$ rate. Journal of Econometrics 158:1, 117-129. [CrossRef]

59. Maxym Chaban. 2010. Cointegration analysis with structural breaks and deterministic trends: anapplication to the Canadian dollar. Applied Economics 42:23, 3023-3037. [CrossRef]

60. Tsangyao Chang, Chia-Hao Lee. 2010. Revisiting purchasing power parity for East Asiancountries: panel SURADF tests. Applied Economics Letters 17:13, 1329-1334. [CrossRef]

61. Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee, Scott Hegerty. 2010. Bounds testing cointegration methods and PPP:evidence from 123 Countries. Applied Economics Letters 17:14, 1335-1340. [CrossRef]

62. Alper Aslan, Ferit Kula, Huseyin Kalyoncu. 2010. Additional evidence of long-run purchasingpower parity with black and official exchange rates. Applied Economics Letters 17:14, 1379-1382.[CrossRef]

63. Tsangyao Chang, Wen-Chi Liu, Chin-Ping Yu. 2010. Revisiting purchasing power parity forG7 countries: further evidence based on panel SURKSS tests. Applied Economics Letters 17:14,1383-1387. [CrossRef]

64. Gawon Yoon. 2010. On the performance of a nonparametric measure of convergence towardspurchasing power parity in the presence of linearity. Applied Economics Letters 17:14, 1389-1396.[CrossRef]

65. TORBEN IVERSEN, DAVID SOSKICE. 2010. Real Exchange Rates and Competitiveness: ThePolitical Economy of Skill Formation, Wage Compression, and Electoral Systems. AmericanPolitical Science Review 104:03, 601-623. [CrossRef]

66. Seher Nur Sulku. 2010. Econometric testing of purchasing power parity in less developedcountries: fixed and flexible exchange rate regime experiences. Applied Economics 42:20,2617-2630. [CrossRef]

67. Tsangyao Chang, Wen-Chi Liu, Han-Wen Tzeng, Chin-Ping Yu. 2010. Purchasing power parityfor G-7 countries: panel SURADF tests. Applied Economics Letters 17:12, 1223-1228. [CrossRef]

68. Robert A. Jarrow, Philip Protter. 2010. Foreign currency bubbles. Review of Derivatives Research. [CrossRef]

69. Julian Ramajo, Montserrat Ferre. 2010. Purchasing power parity revisited: evidence from oldand new tests for an organisation for economic co-operation and development panel. AppliedEconomics 42:17, 2243-2260. [CrossRef]

70. Venus Khim-Sen Liew, Ricky Chee-Jiun Chia, Tai-Hu Ling. 2010. Long-run validity ofpurchasing power parity and rank tests for cointegration for Central Asian countries. AppliedEconomics Letters 17:11, 1073-1077. [CrossRef]

71. Hsu-Ling Chang, Chi-Wei Su. 2010. Revisiting purchasing power parity for major OPECcountries: evidence based on nonlinear panel unit-root tests. Applied Economics Letters 17:11,1119-1123. [CrossRef]

72. Gawon Yoon. 2010. Nonlinearity in real exchange rates: an approach with disaggregated data anda new linearity test. Applied Economics Letters 17:11, 1125-1132. [CrossRef]

73. Gawon Yoon. 2010. Nonlinear mean reversion in real exchange rates: threshold autoregressivemodels and stochastic unit root processes. Applied Economics Letters 17:8, 797-804. [CrossRef]

74. Gawon Yoon. 2010. Does nonlinearity help resolve the Fisher effect puzzle?. Applied EconomicsLetters 17:8, 823-828. [CrossRef]

Page 29: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

75. Stefan Norrbin, Aaron Smallwood. 2010. Generalized long memory and mean reversion of thereal exchange rate. Applied Economics 42:11, 1377-1386. [CrossRef]

76. Yu Hsing. 2010. Analysis of movements in the AUD/USD exchange rate: comparison of fourmajor models. Applied Economics Letters 17:6, 575-580. [CrossRef]

77. Saadet Kasman, Adnan Kasman, Duygu Ayhan. 2010. Testing the Purchasing Power ParityHypothesis for the New Member and Candidate Countries of the European Union: Evidence fromLagrange Multiplier Unit Root Tests with Structural Breaks. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade46:2, 53-65. [CrossRef]

78. ahmad zubaidi baharumshah, evan lau, mudziviri t. nziramasanga. 2010. PURCHASING POWERPARITY IN AFRICAN COUNTRIES: EVIDENCE FROM PANEL SURADF TEST. SouthAfrican Journal of Economics 78:1, 40-56. [CrossRef]

79. Guglielmo Maria Caporale, Christoph Hanck. 2010. Are PPP tests erratically behaved? Some panelevidence. International Review of Applied Economics 24:2, 203-221. [CrossRef]

80. Yu Hsing. 2010. Test of the Marshall-Lerner Condition for Eight Selected Asian Countries andPolicy Implications. Global Economic Review 39:1, 91-98. [CrossRef]

81. Gawon Yoon. 2010. Nonlinear mean-reversion to purchasing power parity: exponential smoothtransition autoregressive models and stochastic unit root processes. Applied Economics 42:4,489-496. [CrossRef]

82. Poomthan Rangkakulnuwat, Sung Ahn, Holly Wang, Susan He. 2010. Extended generalizedpurchasing power parity and optimum currency area in East Asian countries. Applied Economics42:4, 497-513. [CrossRef]

83. Derek Bond, Michael Harrison, Edward O'Brien. 2010. Exploring nonlinearity with random fieldregression. Applied Economics Letters 17:2, 121-124. [CrossRef]

84. Kenneth W. Clements, Yihui Lan, Shi Pei Seah. 2010. The Big Mac Index two decades on: anevaluation of burgernomics. International Journal of Finance & Economics n/a-n/a. [CrossRef]

85. António Afonso, Christophe Rault. 2010. What do we really know about fiscal sustainability inthe EU? A panel data diagnostic. Review of World Economics 145:4, 731-755. [CrossRef]

86. Tuomas A. Peltonen, Adina Popescu, Michael Sager. 2010. Can non-linear real shocks explain thepersistence of PPP exchange rate disequilibria?. International Journal of Finance & Economicsn/a-n/a. [CrossRef]

87. Hsu-Ling Chang, Chi-Wei Su, Meng-Nan Zhu, Pei Liu. 2010. Re-examining long-run purchasingpower parity for Central and Eastern European countries: nonlinear panel unit root tests. AppliedEconomics Letters 1-5. [CrossRef]

88. S. H. Hung, M. J. Weng. 2010. Panel unit root tests of purchasing power parity for Central Asiancountries. Applied Economics Letters 1-6. [CrossRef]

89. Marc W. Simpson, Axel Grossmann. 2010. Can a relative purchasing power parity-based modeloutperform a random walk in forecasting short-term exchange rates?. International Journal ofFinance & Economics n/a-n/a. [CrossRef]

90. M. Hashem Pesaran, Ron Smith, Takashi Yamagata, Lyudmyla Hvozdyk. 2009. Pairwise Tests ofPurchasing Power Parity. Econometric Reviews 28:6, 495-521. [CrossRef]

91. Yu Hsing, Bruno S. Sergi. 2009. The Dollar/Euro Exchange Rate and a Comparison of MajorModels. Journal of Business Economics and Management 10:3, 199-205. [CrossRef]

92. L. Erdey, P. Földvári. 2009. Do Purchasing Power and Interest Rate Parities hold for the EUR/HUF exchange rate?. Acta Oeconomica 59:3, 289-306. [CrossRef]

Page 30: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

93. Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee, Scott W. Hegerty. 2009. PURCHASING POWER PARITY IN LESS-DEVELOPED AND TRANSITION ECONOMIES: A REVIEW PAPER. Journal of EconomicSurveys 23:4, 617-658. [CrossRef]

94. Murat Do#anlar, Harun Bal, Mehmet Ozmen. 2009. Testing long-run validity of purchasing powerparity for selected emerging market economies. Applied Economics Letters 16:14, 1443-1448.[CrossRef]

95. Fredj Jawadi. 2009. Essay in dividend modelling and forecasting: does nonlinearity help?. AppliedFinancial Economics 19:16, 1329-1343. [CrossRef]

96. Christoph Hanck. 2009. Cross-sectional correlation robust tests for panel cointegration. Journalof Applied Statistics 36:7, 817-833. [CrossRef]

97. Derek Bond, Michael Harrison, Edward O'Brien. 2009. Nonlinearity and structural breaks in IrishPPP relationships: an application of random field regression. Applied Economics 1-13. [CrossRef]

98. Isabelle Méjean, Cyrille Schwellnus. 2009. Price convergence in the European Union: Within firmsor composition of firms?#. Journal of International Economics 78:1, 1-10. [CrossRef]

99. Ahmad Zubaidi Baharumshah, Siti Hamizah Mohd, Sung Ahn. 2009. On the predictive powerof monetary exchange rate model: the case of the Malaysian ringgit/US dollar rate. AppliedEconomics 41:14, 1761-1770. [CrossRef]

100. Yu Hsing. 2009. Modeling the Behavior of the KRW/USD Exchange Rate and Policy Implications.Global Economic Review 38:2, 205-214. [CrossRef]

101. Cheng-Feng Lee, Ching-Chuan Tsong. 2009. Covariate selection for testing purchasing powerparity. Applied Economics 1-11. [CrossRef]

102. Andrew K. Rose, Saktiandi Supaat, Jacob Braude. 2009. Fertility and the real exchange rate.Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 42:2, 496-518. [CrossRef]

103. KENNETH W. CLEMENTS, H. Y. IZAN, YIHUI LAN. 2009. A Stochastic Measure ofInternational Competitiveness. International Review of Finance 9:1-2, 51-81. [CrossRef]

104. Nikitas Pittis, Christina Christou, Sarantis Kalyvitis, Christis Hassapis. 2009. Long-Run PPP underthe Presence of Near-to-Unit Roots: The Case of the British Pound-US Dollar Rate. Review ofInternational Economics 17:1, 144-155. [CrossRef]

105. Guneratne Wickremasinghe. 2009. Are real exchange rates of Papua New Guinea mean-reverting?Evidence from panel unit root tests. Applied Economics Letters 16:2, 157-161. [CrossRef]

106. Guglielmo Maria Caporale, Andros Gregoriou. 2009. Non-normality, heteroscedasticity andrecursive unit root tests of PPP: solving the PPP puzzle?. Applied Economics Letters 16:3, 223-226.[CrossRef]

107. Mark Taylor. 2009. Editorial: Long-run purchasing power parity and real exchange rates:introduction and overview. Applied Economics Letters 16:1, 1-4. [CrossRef]

108. Paresh Kumar Narayan, Seema Narayan, Arti Prasad. 2009. Evidence on PPP from a cointegrationtest with multiple structural breaks. Applied Economics Letters 16:1, 5-8. [CrossRef]

109. Gawon Yoon. 2009. Are real exchange rates more likely to be stationary during the fixed nominalexchange rate regimes?. Applied Economics Letters 16:1, 17-22. [CrossRef]

110. J. V. Perez-Rodriguez, F. Ledesma-Rodriguez, S. Torra-Porras. 2009. Purchasing power parityand nonlinear adjustment. Applied Economics Letters 16:1, 35-38. [CrossRef]

111. Venus Khim-Sen Liew, Hock-Ann Lee, Kian-Ping Lim. 2009. Purchasing power parity in Asianeconomies: further evidence from rank tests for cointegration. Applied Economics Letters 16:1,51-54. [CrossRef]

Page 31: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

112. Gawon Yoon. 2009. Purchasing power parity and long memory. Applied Economics Letters 16:1,55-61. [CrossRef]

113. Huseyin Kalyoncu. 2009. New evidence of the validity of purchasing power parity from Turkey.Applied Economics Letters 16:1, 63-67. [CrossRef]

114. Nasip Bolatoglu, Funda Telatar, Erdinc Telatar. 2009. Stochastic behaviour of the real exchangerate for Jordan: a re-examination. Applied Economics Letters 16:1, 81-85. [CrossRef]

115. Yu Hsing. 2009. Functional forms and PPP: new evidence for eight Asian countries. AppliedEconomics Letters 16:1, 95-98. [CrossRef]

116. Ruhul Salim, Kamrul Hassan. 2009. Does the relative population growth affect purchasing powerparity?. Applied Economics Letters 16:1, 103-107. [CrossRef]

117. Yu Hsing. 2008. Application of Monetary Models of Exchange Rate Determination for Poland.South East European Journal of Economics and Business 3:2, 19-24. [CrossRef]

118. C. O. Vargas-Tellez. 2008. Purchasing power parity across Mexican cities: a panel data analysis.Applied Economics 40:22, 2891-2899. [CrossRef]

119. Yu Hsing. 2008. On the functional form of PPP: the case of nine new EU countries. AppliedFinancial Economics Letters 4:6, 389-393. [CrossRef]

120. James R. Lothian, Mark P. Taylor. 2008. Real Exchange Rates Over the Past Two Centuries: HowImportant is the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect?*. The Economic Journal 118:532, 1742-1763.[CrossRef]

121. Rakesh Bissoondeeal. 2008. Post-Bretton Woods evidence on PPP under different exchange rateregimes. Applied Financial Economics 18:18, 1481-1488. [CrossRef]

122. Imed Drine, Christophe Rault. 2008. PURCHASING POWER PARITY FOR DEVELOPINGAND DEVELOPED COUNTRIES. WHAT CAN WE LEARN FROM NON-STATIONARYPANEL DATA MODELS?. Journal of Economic Surveys 22:4, 752-773. [CrossRef]

123. MICHAEL SAGER, MARK P. TAYLOR. 2008. Commercially Available Order Flow Data andExchange Rate Movements: Caveat Emptor. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40:4, 583-625.[CrossRef]

124. Nikolaos Mylonidis, Dimitrios Sideris. 2008. Home bias and purchasing power parity: evidencefrom the G-7 countries. International Journal of Finance & Economics 13:2, 199-204. [CrossRef]

125. David O. Cushman. 2008. Real exchange rates may have nonlinear trends. International Journalof Finance & Economics 13:2, 158-173. [CrossRef]

126. Paresh Kumar Narayan, Biman Chand Prasad. 2008. Are shocks to real effective exchangerates permanent or transitory? Evidence from Pacific Island countries. Applied Economics 40:8,1053-1060. [CrossRef]

127. Roberto Frenkel, Martín Rapetti. 2008. Five years of competitive and stable real exchange rate inArgentina, 2002-2007. International Review of Applied Economics 22:2, 215-226. [CrossRef]

128. Zeynel Abidin Ozdemir. 2008. The purchasing power parity hypothesis in Turkey: evidence fromnonlinear STAR error correction models. Applied Economics Letters 15:4, 307-311. [CrossRef]

129. Vishal Jaunky. 2008. The real exchange rate and productivity differentials: a panel cointegrationapproach. Applied Economics Letters 15:4, 313-318. [CrossRef]

130. Lein-Lein Chen, Seungmook Choi, John Devereux. 2008. Have Absolute Price Levels Convergedfor Developed Economies? The Evidence since 1870. Review of Economics and Statistics 90:1,29-36. [CrossRef]

131. Katja Funke, Isabell Koske. 2008. Does the Law of One Price Hold within the EU? A PanelAnalysis. International Advances in Economic Research 14:1, 11-24. [CrossRef]

Page 32: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

132. Lukas Menkhoff, Rafael Rebitzky, Michael Schroder. 2008. Do dollar forecasters believe too muchin PPP?. Applied Economics 40:3, 261-270. [CrossRef]

133. Jyh-Lin Wu, Chien-Chiang Lee. 2008. A revisit to the nonlinear stationarity of real exchange rates.Applied Economics Letters 15:2, 155-159. [CrossRef]

134. Olivier Darné, Jean-François Hoarau. 2008. The purchasing power parity in Australia: evidencefrom unit root test with structural break. Applied Economics Letters 15:3, 203-206. [CrossRef]

135. Tsangyao Chang, Wen-Chi Liu. 2008. Long-run purchasing power parity with asymmetricadjustment: evidence from nine major oil-exporting countries. International Journal of Finance& Economics n/a-n/a. [CrossRef]

136. Duo Qin. 2008. Uncover Latent PPP by Dynamic Factor Error Correction Model (DF-ECM)Approach: Evidence from Five OECD Countries. Economics: The Open-Access, Open-AssessmentE-Journal . [CrossRef]

137. Ahmad Zubaidi Baharumshah, Chan Tze-Haw, Stilianos Fountas. 2008. Re-examining purchasingpower parity for East-Asian currencies: 1976-2002. Applied Financial Economics 18:1, 75-85.[CrossRef]

138. Jani Bek#, Darja Borsic. 2007. Purchasing Power Parity in Transition Economies: Does It Holdin the Czech Republic, Hungary and Slovenia?. Post-Communist Economies 19:4, 417-432.[CrossRef]

139. Gabriel Rodriguez, Indira Romero. 2007. The role of permanent and transitory components inthe fluctuations of Latin-American real exchange rates. Applied Economics 39:21, 2713-2722.[CrossRef]

140. Bernd Schnatz. 2007. Is reversion to PPP in euro exchange rates non-linear?. InternationalEconomics and Economic Policy 4:3, 281-297. [CrossRef]

141. Lukas Menkhoff, Mark P. Taylor. 2007. The Obstinate Passion of Foreign Exchange Professionals:Technical Analysis. Journal of Economic Literature 45:4, 936-972. [Abstract] [View PDF article][PDF with links]

142. Olivier Darné, Jean-François Hoarau. 2007. FURTHER EVIDENCE ON MEAN REVERSIONIN THE AUSTRALIAN EXCHANGE RATE. Bulletin of Economic Research 59:4, 383-395.[CrossRef]

143. Mario Cerrato, Nicholas Sarantis. 2007. Does purchasing power parity hold in emerging markets?Evidence from a panel of black market exchange rates. International Journal of Finance &Economics 12:4, 427-444. [CrossRef]

144. Paresh Kumar Narayan, Seema Narayan. 2007. Are real exchange rates nonlinear with a unit root?Evidence on PPP for Italy: a note. Applied Economics 39:19, 2483-2488. [CrossRef]

145. Mohsen Bahmani Oskooee, Magda Kandil. 2007. Real and nominal effective exchange rates inMENA countries: 1970-2004. Applied Economics 39:19, 2489-2501. [CrossRef]

146. Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee, Hanafia Harvey. 2007. Real and Nominal Effective Exchange Ratesfor LDCs: 1971-2004. The International Trade Journal 21:4, 385-416. [CrossRef]

147. Yu Hsing. 2007. Exchange rate fluctuations in Croatia: test of uncovered interest rate parity andthe open economy model. Applied Economics Letters 14:11, 785-788. [CrossRef]

148. Lean Hooi Hooi, Russell Smyth. 2007. Are Asian real exchange rates mean reverting? Evidencefrom univariate and panel LM unit root tests with one and two structural breaks. Applied Economics39:16, 2109-2120. [CrossRef]

149. Jaehun Chung, Yongmiao Hong. 2007. Model-free evaluation of directional predictability inforeign exchange markets. Journal of Applied Econometrics 22:5, 855-889. [CrossRef]

Page 33: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

150. Ming-Yuan Leon Li. 2007. Purchasing power parity under high and low volatility regimes. AppliedEconomics Letters 14:8, 581-589. [CrossRef]

151. Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee, Abera Gelan. 2007. Real and nominal effective exchange rates forAfrican countries. Applied Economics 39:8, 961-979. [CrossRef]

152. Pär Sjölander. 2007. Unreal exchange rates: a simulation-based approach to adjust misleading PPPestimates. Journal of Economic Studies 34:3, 256-288. [CrossRef]

153. Chikashi Tsuji. 2007. Explaining the dynamics of the NIKKEI 225 stock and stock index futuresmarkets by using the SETAR model. Applied Financial Economics Letters 3:2, 77-83. [CrossRef]

154. Charalambos Pattichis, Marios Maratheftis, Stavros Zenios. 2007. Is the Cyprus Pound RealEffective Exchange Rate Misaligned? A BEER Approach. International Economic Journal 21:1,133-154. [CrossRef]

155. Tsangyao Chang, Hsu-Ling Chang, Hsiao-Ping Chu, Chi-Wei Su. 2006. Is per capita real GDPstationary in African countries? Evidence from panel SURADF test. Applied Economics Letters13:15, 1003-1008. [CrossRef]

156. Yu Hsing. 2006. Responses of output in Poland to shocks to the exchange rate, the stock price,and other macroeconomic variables: a VAR model. Applied Economics Letters 13:15, 1017-1022.[CrossRef]

157. Tsangyao Chang, Hsu-Ling Chang, Hsiao-Ping Chu, Chi-Wei Su. 2006. Does PPP hold in Africancountries? Further evidence based on a highly dynamic non-linear (logistic) unit root test. AppliedEconomics 38:20, 2453-2459. [CrossRef]

158. C. Simon Fan, Xiangdong Wei. 2006. The Law of One Price: Evidence from the TransitionalEconomy of China. Review of Economics and Statistics 88:4, 682-697. [CrossRef]

159. Sang-Kuck Chung. 2006. The out-of-sample forecasts of nonlinear long-memory models of thereal exchange rate. International Journal of Finance & Economics 11:4, 355-370. [CrossRef]

160. Yu Hsing. 2006. Analysis of Short-term Exchange Rate Movements in Korea: Application of anExtended Mundell–Fleming Model. Global Economic Review 35:2, 145-151. [CrossRef]

161. Daiki Maki. 2006. Variance ratio tests for a unit root in the presence of a mean shift: small sampleproperties and an application to purchasing power parity. Applied Financial Economics 16:8,607-615. [CrossRef]

162. Marie Arneberg, Einar Bowitz. 2006. Who Is the Big Spender? Price Index Effects in Comparisonsof Educational Expenditures Between Countries and Over Time. Peabody Journal of Education81:2, 33-46. [CrossRef]

163. Paresh Kumar Narayan. 2006. Are bilateral real exchange rates stationary? Evidence fromLagrange multiplier unit root tests for India. Applied Economics 38:1, 63-70. [CrossRef]

164. Jerry Coakley, Stuart Snaith. 2006. Testing for symmetry and proportionality in a European panel.Applied Financial Economics 16:1-2, 63-71. [CrossRef]

165. Philip Hans Franses, Dick van Dijk. 2006. A simple test for PPP among traded goods. AppliedFinancial Economics 16:1-2, 19-27. [CrossRef]

166. Mohammad S. Hasan. 2006. A century of Purchasing Power Parity: evidence from Canada andAustralia. Applied Financial Economics 16:1-2, 145-156. [CrossRef]

167. Michael J. Sager, Mark P. Taylor. 2006. Under the microscope: the structure of the foreignexchange market. International Journal of Finance & Economics 11:1, 81-95. [CrossRef]

168. Dimitrios Sideris. 2006. Purchasing Power Parity in economies in transition: evidence from Centraland East European countries. Applied Financial Economics 16:1-2, 135-143. [CrossRef]

Page 34: The Purchasing Power Parity Debate

169. Mark P. Taylor. 2006. Real exchange rates and Purchasing Power Parity: mean-reversion ineconomic thought. Applied Financial Economics 16:1-2, 1-17. [CrossRef]

170. Jean-Francois Villeneuve, Jagdish Handa. 2006. Purchasing Power Parity as a long-term memoryprocess: evidence from Canada. Applied Financial Economics 16:1-2, 109-117. [CrossRef]

171. Pan A. Yotopoulos, Yasuyuki Sawada. 2006. Exchange rate misalignment: a new test of long-runPPP based on cross-country data. Applied Financial Economics 16:1-2, 127-134. [CrossRef]

172. Michael Sager. 2006. Explaining the persistence of deviations from PPP: a non-linear Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson effect?. Applied Financial Economics 16:1-2, 41-61. [CrossRef]

173. Guneratne B. Wickremasinghe. 2005. Purchasing Power Parity of Papua New Guinea: evidencefrom the floating exchange rate regime. Applied Financial Economics Letters 1:6, 335-338.[CrossRef]

174. Lucio Sarno. 2005. Viewpoint: Towards a solution to the puzzles in exchange rateeconomics: where do we stand?. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'<html_entglyph="@eacute;" ascii="e"/>conomique 38:3, 673-708. [CrossRef]

175. Jerry Coakley, Stuart Snaith. 2005. Testing for symmetry and proportionality in a European panel.Applied Financial Economics 15:11, 745-752. [CrossRef]

176. Paresh Kumar Narayan. 2005. New evidence on purchasing power parity from 17 OECD countries.Applied Economics 37:9, 1063-1071. [CrossRef]

177. Imed Drine, Christophe Rault. 2005. Can the Balassa-Samuelson theory explain long-run realexchange rate movements in OECD countries?. Applied Financial Economics 15:8, 519-530.[CrossRef]

178. Guglielmo Maria Caporale, Mario Cerrato, Nicola Spagnolo. 2005. Measuring half-lives: using anon-parametric bootstrap approach. Applied Financial Economics Letters 1:1, 1-4. [CrossRef]


Top Related