the vanishing procyclicality of labor productivity

49

Upload: warwick

Post on 28-Nov-2023

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

The Vanishing Procyclicality of Labor Productivity�

Jordi Galí

CREI, Universitat Pompeu Fabra and Barcelona GSE

[email protected]

Thijs van Rens

CREI, Universitat Pompeu Fabra and Barcelona GSE

[email protected]

This version: July 2010

First version: August 2008

Abstract

We document three changes in postwar US macroeconomic dynamics: (i) the

procyclicality of labor productivity has vanished, (ii) the relative volatility of em-

ployment has risen, and (iii) the relative (and absolute) volatility of the real wage

has risen. We propose an explanation for all three changes that is based on a com-

mon source: a decline in labor market frictions. We develop a simple model with

labor market frictions, variable e¤ort, and endogenous wage rigidities to illustrate

the mechanisms underlying our explanation. We show that the reduction in frictions

may also have contributed to the observed decline in output volatility.

Keywords: labor hoarding, labor market frictions, wage rigidities, e¤ort choice

JEL classi�cation: E24 E32

�We have bene�ted from comments and suggestions by Almut Balleer, Paula Bustos, Vasco Carvalho,Wouter Denhaan, Jan Eeckhout, Ester Faia, Claudio Michelacci, Kris Nimark, Evi Pappa, Giorgio Prim-iceri, Aysegül Sahin, Carlos Thomas, Jaume Ventura, Joachim Voth, Eran Yashiv and participants inthe CREI Macro Faculty Lunch, NBER Summer Institute, EES research network workshop in Kiel,CEPR-RIETI Workshop on �Labor Markets and the Macroeconomy� in Tokyo, University of Amster-dam, Malaga Workshop on �Labor Market Frictions�, European Central Bank, Norges Bank, CPB,ECB-CEPR Workshop on �European Labor Market Adjustment�, Sabanci University, ESSIM 2010 andSED 2010. Davide Debortoli provided outstanding research assistance. We gratefully acknowledge �-nancial support from the European Research Council, the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation(grants SEJ2006-02235, ECO2008-01665, CSD2006-00016 and Juan de la Cierva); the Generalitat deCatalunya (DIUE grant 2009SGR1157); and the Barcelona GSE Research Network.

1

1 Introduction

The nature of business cycle �uctuations changes over time. There is a host of evi-

dence for changes in the dynamics of postwar US macroeconomic time series (Blanchard

and Watson (1986), McConell and Pérez-Quirós (2000), Stock and Watson (2002), Hall

(2007), Galí; and Gambetti (2009)). The present paper documents and discusses three

aspects of these changes:

� The correlation of labor productivity with output or labor input has declined, by

some measures dramatically so.1

� The volatility of labor input measures has increased (relative to that of output).2

� The volatility of real wage measures has increased, both in relative and absolute

terms.3

All three of the above observations point towards a change in labor market dynamics.

While each may be of independent interest and have potentially useful implications for

our understanding of macro �uctuations, our goal in the present paper is to explore their

possible connection. In particular, we seek to investigate the hypothesis that all three

changes may be driven by an increase in labor market �exibility, allowing �rms to adjust

their labor force more easily in response to various kinds of shocks. In order to illustrate

the mechanism behind this explanation, we develop a stylized model of �uctuations with

labor market frictions, and investigate how its predictions vary with the parameter that

indexes the importance of such frictions.

The main intuition behind that mechanism is easy to describe. The idea goes back to

a literature, starting with Oi (1962) and Solow (1964), which attributes the procyclicality

of productivity to variations in e¤ort, resulting in seemingly increasing returns to labor.4

Suppose that �rms have two margins for adjusting their e¤ective labor input: (observed)

employment and (unobserved) e¤ort, which we respectively denote (in logs) by nt and

1As far as we know, Stiroh (2009) was the �rst to provide evidence of a decline in the laborproductivity-hours correlation. Gordon (2010), Barnichon (2008), Galí; and Gambetti (2009), andNucci and Riggi (2009), using di¤erent approaches, independently investigated the potential sources ofthat decline.

2To the best of our knowledge, Galí; and Gambetti (2009) were the �rst to uncover that �nding, butdid not provide the kind of detailed statistical analysis found below. Independently, Hall (2007) o¤eredsome evidence on the size of the decline in employment in the most recent recessions that is consistentwith our �nding.

3As far as we know, this �nding was not known previously, although it is reported in independentwork by Gourio (2007) and Champagne and Kurmann (2010).

4Contributions include studies by Fair (1969), Fay and Medo¤ (1985), Hall (1988), Rotemberg andSummers (1990), Bernanke and Parkinson (1991), Shapiro (1993), Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo(1993), Bils and Cho (1994), Uhlig and Xu (1996), Basu (1996), Basu and Fernald (1997), Basu andKimball (1997), Shea (1999), Gordon (2004), Wen (2004), Arias, Hansen, and Ohanian (2007), andGordon (2010)

2

et.5 Labor input (employment and e¤ort) are transformed into output according to a

standard production function,

yt = (1� �)(nt + et) + at

where at is log total factor productivity and � is a parameter measuring diminishing

returns to labor.

Measured labor productivity, or output per person, is given by

yt � nt = ��nt + (1� �) et + at

Labor market frictions make it costly to adjust employment nt. E¤ort et provides an

alternative margin of adjustment of labor input and is not subject to those frictions (or

to a lesser degree). Thus, the larger the frictions, the less employment �uctuates and

the more volatile �uctuations in e¤ort. As a result, a reduction in frictions decreases

the volatility of e¤ort and therefore increases the relative volatility of employment with

respect to output. The increased volatility of nt also makes labor productivity less

procyclical, and, in the presence of shocks other than shifts in technology, may even

make productivity countercyclical, consistent with the evidence reported below.

In addition, as emphasized by Hall (2005), the presence of labor market frictions

generates a non-degenerate bargaining set for the wage, i.e. a wedge between �rms�

and workers� reservation wages. Any wage within that bargaining set is consistent with

labor market equilibrium. That feature makes room for wage rigidities. We model

wages as rigid within the bargaining set, adjusting only when approaching its bounds.

In our model, a reduction in labor market frictions narrows the bargaining set and

therefore endogenously makes wages more sensitive to shocks, increasing the volatility of

�uctuations in wages. If the rigidity is extended to the wages of newly hired workers, then

the increased �exibility of wages may dampen the volatility of output and employment in

response to shocks.6 That feature may help explain the observed decline in the volatility

of those two variables in the recent US experience.7 Other authors have also argued

that the Great Moderation may have been driven at least in part by increased wage

�exibility (Gourio (2007), Champagne and Kurmann (2010), Nucci and Riggi (2009)).

However, this paper is the �rst to show that such an increase in wage �exibility can

arise endogenously from a decrease in labor market frictions.8

5To simplify the argument, we assume hours per worker are constant, consistent with the observationthat in the U.S. data most adjustments in total hours worked take place along the extensive margin.

6This is clearly true for technology shocks. As argued in Blanchard and Galí (2008), increased wage�exibility may also dampen the sensitivity of GDP and in�ation to oil price shocks.

7A more �exible labor market does of course not make the economy immune to very large shocks likethe recent �nancial crisis. Under our hypothesis, if the labor market were as rigid as it was in the early80s, the current recession might have been even substantially more severe.

8Uren (2008) develops a model, in which a reduction in search frictions decreases output volatility.However, the mechanism in that paper (increased assortative matching) is completely di¤erent.

3

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 documents the changes

in the patterns of �uctuations in labor productivity, employment and wages. Section

3 develops the basic model. Section 4 describes the outcome of simulations of a cali-

brated version of the model, and discusses its consistency with the evidence. Section 5

concludes.

2 Changes in Labor Market Dynamics

We document three stylized facts regarding postwar changes in US economic �uctuations

that motivate our investigation. All three facts are about changes in the dynamics of

the labor market and pertain to the cyclical behavior of labor productivity, labor input

and wages. We use quarterly time series over the period 1948:1-2007:4 drawn from

di¤erent sources (see below for a detailed description). To illustrate the changes in the

di¤erent statistics considered, we split the sample period into two subperiods, pre-84

(1948:1-1983:4) and post-84 (1984:1-2007:4). The choice of the break date is motivated

by existing evidence on the timing of the Great Moderation, the sharp drop in output

volatility around 1984 (McConell and Pérez-Quirós (2000)).

Our evidence makes use of alternative measures of output and labor input. In all

cases labor productivity is constructed as the ratio between the corresponding output

and labor input measures. Most of the evidence uses output and hours in the private

sector from the BLS Labor Productivity and Cost (LPC) program. We also use GDP as

an economy-wide measure of output, with the corresponding labor input measures being

total hours or employment. The time series for economy-wide hours is an unpublished

series constructed by the BLS and used in Francis and Ramey (2008). The employment

series is the usual one from the Current Employment Statistics (CES) establishment

survey. In all cases we normalize the output and labor input measures by the size of the

civilian noninstitutional population (16 years and older).

We apply two alternative transformations on the logarithms of all variables in order

to render the original time series stationary. Our preferred transformation uses the

bandpass (BP) �lter to remove �uctuations with periodicities below 6 and above 32

quarters, as in Stock and Watson (1999). We also apply the fourth-di¤erence (4D)

operator, which is the transformation favored by Stock and Watson (2002) in their

analysis of changes in output volatility.9

2.1 The Vanishing Procyclicality of Labor Productivity

Figure 1 shows the �uctuations at business cycle frequencies in labor productivity in

the US over the postwar period. It is clear from the graph that in the earlier part

9We also showed the results are robust to detrending with the Hodrick-Prescott (HP) �lter andto using shorter sample periods, centered around the break date 1984. These estimates, which aresuppressed for brevity, are available upon request.

4

of the sample, productivity was signi�cantly below trend in each recession. However,

in the post-84 data, this is no longer the case. When we calculate the correlation of

productivity with output or employment, as in Figure 2, it is clear that there is a sharp

drop in the cyclicality of productivity around 1984. The correlation of productivity

with output, which used to be strongly positive, fell to a level close to zero, while the

correlation of productivity with employment, which was zero or slightly positive in the

earlier period of the sample, became negative.

These �ndings are formalized in Table 1, which reports the contemporaneous corre-

lation between labor productivity and output and employment, for alternative transfor-

mations and time periods. In each case, we report the estimated correlation for the pre

and post-84 subsamples, as well as the di¤erence between those estimates. The standard

errors, reported in brackets, are computed using the delta method.10 We now turn to a

short discussion of the results in this Table.

2.1.1 Correlation with Output

Independently of the detrending procedure, the correlation of output per hour with out-

put in the pre-84 period is high and signi�cantly positive, with a point estimate around

0:60. In other words, from the vantage point of the early 80s �the period when the sem-

inal contributions to RBC theory were written� the procyclicality of labor productivity

was a well established empirical fact, which lent support to business cycle theories that

assigned a central role to technology shocks as a source of �uctuations.

In the post-84 period, however, that pattern changed considerably. The estimates

of the productivity-output correlation dropped to a value close to (and not signi�cantly

di¤erent from) zero. The di¤erence with the corresponding pre-84 estimates is highly

signi�cant. Thus, on the basis of those estimates labor productivity has become an

acyclical variable (with respect to output) over the past two decades.

When we use an employment-based measure of labor productivity, output per worker,

the estimated correlations also drop substantially but remain signi�cantly greater than

zero in the post-84 period. This should not be surprising given that hours per worker are

highly procyclical in both subperiods and that their volatility relative to employment-

based labor productivity has increased considerably.11

10We use least squares (GMM) to estimate the second moments (variances and and covariances) ofeach pair of variables, as well as the (asymptotic) variance-covariance matrix of this estimator. Then,we calculate the standard errors for the standard deviations, the relative standard deviations and thecorrelation coe¢cient using the delta method.11Letting n and h denote employment and total hours respectively, a straightforward algebraic ma-

nipulation yields the identity:

�(y � n; y) =�y�h�y�n

�(y � h; y) +�h�n�y�n

�(h� n; y)

Thus, even in the case of acyclical hours-based labor productivity, i.e. �(y � h; y) ' 0, we would expect�(y � n; y) to remain positive if hours per worker are procyclical, i.e. �(h� n; y) > 0.

5

2.1.2 Correlation with Labor Input

The right-hand side panels in Table 1 display several estimates of the correlation between

labor productivity and labor input. The estimates for the pre-84 period are low, and in

the case of output per hour, insigni�cantly di¤erent from zero. Thus, labor productivity

was largely acyclical with respect to labor input in that subperiod. This near-zero

correlation is consistent with the evidence reported in the early RBC literature, using

data up to the mid 80s.12

As was the case when using output as the cyclical indicator, the estimated correla-

tions between labor productivity and employment decline dramatically in the post-84

period. In fact these correlations become signi�cantly negative for output per hour, with

a point estimate ranging from �0:40 to �0:54, depending on the �lter. The change with

respect to the pre-84 period is highly signi�cant. In other words, labor productivity in

the past two decades has become strongly countercyclical with respect to labor input.

2.2 The Rising Relative Volatility of Labor Input

The left-hand panel of Table 2 displays the standard deviation of several measures

of labor input in the pre and post-84 periods, as well as the ratio between the two.

The variables considered include employment in the private sector, hours in the private

sector (employment times hours per worker) and economy-wide hours. The decline in

the volatility of hours since the mid 80s, like that of other major macro variables, is seen

to be large and highly signi�cant, with the standard deviation falling between 35% and

49% and always signi�cantly so.

A more interesting piece of evidence is the change in the relative volatility of labor

input, measured as the ratio of the standard deviation of labor input to the standard

deviation of output. These estimates are presented in the right-hand panel of Table

2. Without exception, all labor input measures have experienced an increase in their

relative volatility in the post versus pre-84 period. In other words, the decline in the

variability of labor input has been less pronounced than that of output. The increase in

the relative volatility of hours worked ranges from 30% to 48% in the private sector and

from 7% to 30% in the total economy. The corresponding increase for employment is

slightly smaller, ranging from 23% to 43% in the private sector, but is still statistically

signi�cant.

The previous evidence points to a rise in the elasticity of labor input with respect to

output. Put di¤erently, �rms appear to have relied increasingly on labor input adjust-

ments in order to meet their changes in output.

12Christiano and Eichenbaum (1992) used data up to 1983:4 (which coincides with the cut-o¤ date forour �rst subperiod), but starting in 1955:4. Their estimates of the correlation between labor productivityand hours were �0:20 when using household data and 0:16 using establishment data.

6

2.3 The Rising Volatility of Wages

Next we turn our attention to the volatility of (real) wages, both in absolute and relative

terms. We consider four di¤erent wage measures. The �rst three are constructed as real

compensation per hour. The �rst di¤erence is in the measure of compensation, which is

measured either from the national income and product accounts (NIPA) or as earnings

from the CES establishment survey. The second di¤erence is in the measure of hours,

which refers to the private sector or to the total economy.13 The fourth measure is

usual hourly earnings (or usual weekly earnings divided by usual weekly hours) from

the Current Population Statistics (CPS). For all measures, compensation or earnings

are de�ated using the compensation de�ator from the LPC, but the results are robust

to de�ating with the consumer price index (CPI-U) as we show below.

2.3.1 Average Wages

The left-hand panel of Table 3 displays the standard deviation for each wage measure for

di¤erent detrending procedures. Our statistics uncover a surprising �nding: despite the

general decline in macro volatility associated with the Great Moderation, the volatility

of several wage measures has increased in absolute terms. The estimated increase the

standard deviation is fairly large, between 10 and 42% and mostly signi�cant for the

bandpass �ltered NIPA-based wage measures. Using fourth di¤erences, the increase is

much smaller and no longer signi�cant and by some periods there seems to have been a

(small) decrease in wage volatility.

Using earnings per hour from the CES, however, there seems to be a large and highly

signi�cant reduction in wage volatility.14 One di¤erence between the two measures is

that the NIPA compensation measure includes non-wage payments and, in particular,

employee stock options. Mehran and Tracy (2001) have argued that since these options

are recorded when they realize rather than when they are handed out to employees, the

NIPA measure gives a misleading picture of the evolution and volatility of compensation

in the 90s. However, using the CPS measure of usual hourly earnings, presented in

Table 4, which includes non-wage compensation but not stock options, we again observe

a fairly large increase in the volatility of wages.15 Given the short time series available

13Our baseline measure uses compensation from the NIPA and hours in the private sector and corre-sponds to compensation per hour from the BLS labor productivity and cost program (LPC).14This �nding is not driven by the fact that the CES earnings measure is only available after 1965. If

we restrict the sample for the NIPA based wage measures to the 1965-2004, the volatility statistics forthese measures look very similar those in the table.15We use data from the CPS outgoing rotation groups. Since these data are available only from

1979 onwards, we compare the volatility over the 1980-1984 period (allowing for fourth di¤erences) withthat of the 1985-2005 period. For comparison, the �rst panel of Table 4 presents the volatility of ourbaseline measure for compensation per hour for this period. The second panel presents comparablestatistics from the CPS series. Because the CPS wage series is based on a fairly small cross-section ofworkers, there is substantial measurement error in these series. Therefore, the standard deviations ofthe fourth di¤erenced data are biased upward, see Haefke, Sonntag, and van Rens (2008) for details.

7

for these data, it is remarkable that the increase in volatility is (borderline) signi�cant

for the bandpass �ltered series. Using fourth di¤erences, wage volatility seems roughly

constant.

Our �nding that wage volatility increased or at least did not decrease around the

time of the Great Moderation, although with a caveat, is consistent with the results in

Champagne and Kurmann (2010), who also use the CPS to show that the increase in

wage volatility is not driven by compositional changes in the labor force. To the best of

our knowledge, this result was not previously known.16

An immediate implication of the previous �nding, and the one that we want to

emphasize here, is the possibly very large increase in the relative volatility of wages

with respect to to output or labor input, as shown in the right-hand panels of Tables

3 and 4. The relative volatility of wages with respect to output more than doubled for

the NIPA-based measures and for the CPS wage. We interpret this evidence as being

consistent with a decline in the signi�cance of real wage rigidities around 1984.17

2.3.2 Wages of Newly Hired Workers

On a frictional labor market, the average wage is not allocative, since the frictions drive

a wedge between the reservation wages of �rms and workers. Therefore, in order to

assess the implications of increased wage �exibility for other labor market variables, we

also consider the volatility of the wage of newly hired workers as suggested by Haefke,

Sonntag, and van Rens (2008) and Pissarides (2009).

Table 4 presents volatility statistics for the wage of new hires, constructed from the

CPS as in Haefke, Sonntag, and van Rens (2008).18 The �rst thing to notice is that the

wage of newly hired workers is much more volatile than the average wage in the entire

labor force. This is consistent with the results in Haefke, Sonntag, and van Rens (2008),

who argue that, in the post-84 period, wages of newly hired workers are perfectly �exible,

in the sense that they respond one-to-one to changes in labor productivity. Here, we

focus on the change in the volatility of wages over time.

The absolute volatility of the wage of newly hired workers, unlike the average wage,

decreased substantially and signi�cantly between the pre and post-84 periods. As a

result, the increase in the relative volatility with respect to output is much smaller for

There is no reason however, why the ratio of the standard deviations before and after 1984 would bebiased. In addition, the bandpass �ltered data, which do not include the high frequencies induced bythe measurement error, are not subject to this bias.16Stock and Watson (2002) uncover breaks in the volatility of a long list of macro variables, but they

do not provide evidence for any wage measure.17Blanchard and Galí (2008) argue that a reduction in the rigidity of real wages is needed in order to

account for the simultaneous decline in in�ation and output volatility, in the face of oil price shocks ofa similar magnitude.18But unlike in that paper, we do not correct �uctuations in the CPS wage series for changes in

the composition of the labor force by demographic characteristics, education level and experience forcomparability with the other wage measures. Doing so however, makes very little di¤erence for theconclusions presented here.

8

new hires, ranging between 3% and 69%, depending on whether we use the mean or

median wage and on the �lter used. Although the increase in the relative volatility of

the wage of newly hired workers is much less pronounced, there is some evidence that

wages �uctuated more between recessions and booms also for this group of workers.

This �nding is consistent with the evidence presented in Haefke, Sonntag, and van Rens

(2008, section 3.4) and points towards a decrease in wage rigidity that may be important

for employment �uctuations.

2.4 Conclusions

Summarizing, we showed that labor productivity became less procyclical or acyclical

with respect to output, and countercyclical with respect to employment. In addition,

the relative volatility of both employment and wages increased. For completeness, we

also report that the relative volatility of labor productivity increased, and the correla-

tion between employment and output decreased slightly, see Table 5.19 These changes

coincided with the reduction in volatility in output and most other macroeconomic

aggregates, the so called Great Moderation. This evidence is suggestive of structural

change in the labor market.

In macroeconomic models with a perfectly competitive labor market and a standard

production function, wages are proportional to labor productivity.20 Our evidence makes

clear that the extent to which this is true in the data depends very much on the period

one looks at. From Tables 3 and 5, we see that the relative standard deviation of wages

with respect to labor productivity was about 0:3� 0:7 in the the pre-84 period. In the

post-84 period, this relative standard deviation more than doubled to about 1:2 � 1:3.

This is consistent with the evidence in Haefke, Sonntag, and van Rens (2008, section

3.4), who show that the elasticity of wages with respect to productivity in 1984 increases

from 0:2 to 0:4 for all workers, and from 0:3 to 0:8 for newly hired workers. This evidence

suggests that labor market frictions are crucial to understand the observed changes in

labor market dynamics.

In the remainder of this paper, we will show that the vanishing procyclicality of labor

productivity and the increasing relative volatility of employment, can be explained by

a reduction in labor market frictions, if production requires an unobservable input, e.g.

e¤ort. If wages are set competitively, then a reduction in labor market frictions, which

makes employment faster to adjust, should make wages relatively less volatile. Although

the relative standard deviation of wages decreased in some datasets, we argued above

that the majority of the evidence seems to point towards a large increase in the relative

19These observations are completely determined by the statistics already reported and do not containindependent information We emphasize the statistics that we considered easiest to interpret.20With competitive labor markets, the wage equals the marginal product of labor, and with a Cobb-

Douglas production function, the marginal and average product of labor are proportional to eachother.This well-known argument, which does not rely on business cycles being driven by productivity shocks,was used recently by Rogerson and Shimer (2010, section 1.3.2).

9

volatility of wages. Therefore, we show below how the model can be extended with

endogenous wage rigidities in order to generate this result.

3 A Model of Fluctuations with Labor Market Frictions

and Endogenous E¤ort

Having documented in some detail the changing patterns of labor productivity, labor in-

put, and wages, we turn to possible explanations. More speci�cally, and as anticipated

in the introduction, we explore the hypothesis that all three observed changes docu-

mented above may have, at least partly, been caused by the same institutional change:

increasing �exibility of the labor market.

To formalize this explanation, we develop a model of �uctuations with labor market

frictions, modelled as adjustment costs in employment (hiring costs). The crucial element

in this model is an endogenous e¤ort choice, which provides an intensive margin for

labor adjustment that is not subject to the adjustment costs. Since the purpose of the

model is to illustrate the main mechanisms at work, we keep the model as simple as

possible in dimensions that are likely to be orthogonal to the factors emphasized by

our analysis. Thus, we abstract from endogenous capital accumulation, trade in goods

and assets with the rest of the world, and imperfections in the goods and �nancial

markets. We also ignore any kind of monetary frictions, even though we recognize that

these, in conjunction with changes in the conduct of monetary policy in the Volcker-

Greenspan years, may have played an important role in accounting for the decline in

macro volatility.21

3.1 Households

Households are in�nitely-lived and consist of a continuum of identical members repre-

sented by the unit interval. The household is the relevant decision unit for choices about

consumption and labor supply. Each household member�s utility function is additively

separable in consumption and leisure, and the household assigns equal consumption Ct

to all members in order to share consumption risk within the household. Thus, the

household�s objective function is given by,

E0

1X

t=0

�t

"

ZtC1��t

1� �� Lt

#

(1)

where � 2 (0; 1) is the discount factor, � 2 [0; 1] is the inverse of the intertemporal

elasticity of substitution, > 0 can be interpreted as a �xed cost of working and Zt

is a preference shock. The second term in the period utility function is disutility from

21See, e.g. Clarida, Galí, and Gertler (2000) for a discussion of the possible role of monetary policyin the Great Moderation.

10

e¤ective labor supply Lt, which depends on the fraction Nt of household members that

are employed, as well as on the amount of e¤ort Eit exerted by each employed household

member i. Formally,

Lt =

Z Nt

0

1 + �E1+�it

1 + �di =

1 + �E1+�t

1 + �Nt (2)

where the second equality imposes the equilibrium condition that all working household

members exert the same level of e¤ort, Eit = Et for all i. The parameter � � 0 measures

the importance of e¤ort for the disutility of working, and the elasticity parameter � � 0

determines the degree of increasing marginal disutility from exerting e¤ort. For simplic-

ity we assume a constant workweek, thus restricting the intensive margin of labor input

adjustment to changes in e¤ort.

The household maximizes its objective function above subject to the sequence of

budget constraints,

Ct =

Z Nt

0Witdi+�t (3)

where �t represents �rms� pro�ts, which are paid out to households in the form of

lump-sum dividents, and Wit are wages accruing to employed household member i. The

household takes into account the e¤ect of its decisions on the level of e¤ort exerted by

its members.

3.2 Firms

Firms produce a homogenous consumption good using a production technology that

uses labor and e¤ort as inputs,

Yt = At

�Z Nt

0E itdi

�1��

= At

E t Nt

�1��(4)

where Yt is output, Eit is e¤ort exerted by worker i, � 2 (0; 1) is a parameter that

measures diminishing returns to total labor input in production, 2 [0; 1] measures

additional diminishing returns to e¤ort, and At is a technology shock common to all

�rms. Since all �rms are identical, we normalize the number of �rms to the unit interval,

so that Yt and Nt denote output and employment of each �rm as well as aggregate output

and employment in the economy. The second equality imposes the equilibrium condition

that all workers in a �rm exert the same level of e¤ort, Eit = Et for all i.

Firms choose how many workers to hire Ht in order to maximize the expected dis-

counted value of pro�ts,

E0

1X

t=0

Q0;t [Yt �WtNt � g (Ht)] (5)

11

subject to a law of motion for employment implied by the labor market frictions,

Nt = (1� �)Nt�1 +Ht (6)

where the function g (:), with g0 > 0 and g00 > 0, represents the costs (in terms of output)

of hiring new workers and Q0;t is the stochastic discount factor for future pro�ts. The

stochastic discount factor is de�ned recursively as Q0;t � Q0;1Q1;2:::Qt�1;t, where

Qt;t+1 � �Zt+1Zt

CtCt+1

��

(7)

measures the marginal rate of substitution between two subsequent periods. Like the

household, the �rm takes into account the e¤ect of its decisions on the level of e¤ort

exerted by its workers.

3.3 E¤ort Choice and Job Creation

The household and the �rm jointly decide the wage and the level of e¤ort that the worker

will put into the job. In equilibrium, the e¤ort level of all workers is set e¢ciently,

maximizing the total surplus generated by each match.22 This e¢cient e¤ort level, in

each period and for each worker, equates the cost of exerting more e¤ort, higher disutility

to the household, to the bene�t, higher production and therefore pro�ts for the �rm.

Consider a worker i, who is a member of household h and is employed in �rm j. The

marginal disutility to the household from that worker exerting more e¤ort, expressed in

terms of consumption, is obtained from equation (2) for total e¤ective labor supply and

equals:

C�htZt

@Lht@Eit

=(1 + �) �

1 + �

C�htE�it

Ztdi (8)

The marginal product of that additional e¤ort to the �rm is found from production

function (4):

@Yjt@Eit

= (1� �) At

�Z Njt

0E vtdv

���

E�(1� )it di (9)

In equilibrium, the marginal disutility from e¤ort must equal its marginal product for

all workers i. Also, because all �rms and all households are identical, it must be that

Cht = Ct and Njt = Nt in equilibrium. Therefore, it follows that all workers exert the

same level of e¤ort in equilibrium, Eit = Et for all i. Imposing this property, we obtain

the following equilibrium condition for e¤ort,

Et =

(1� �) (1 + �)

(1 + �) �

Zt C�t

AtN��t

� 11+��(1��)

(10)

22Suppose not. Then, household and �rm could agree on a di¤erent e¤ort level that increases totalmatch surplus, and a modi�ed surplus sharing rule (wage) that would make both parties better o¤.

12

or, using production function (4) to simplify:

E1+�t =

1 + �

1 + �

Zt C�t

(1� �)YtNt

(11)

When considering whether to hire a worker, �rms take into account the impact of

the resulting increase in employment on the e¤ort level exerted by their workers. Thus,

the marginal product of a new hire is given by,23

dYjtdNjt

=@Yjt@Njt

+@Yjt@Ejt

@Ejt@Njt

= (1�F )(1� �)Yt

Nt(12)

where F =�

1+��(1��) measures the additional (negative) e¤ect from a new hire on

output that comes from the endogenous response of the e¤ort level in the �rm.

Maximizing the expected net present value of pro�ts (5), where output is given by

production function (4) and the stochastic discount factor by (7), subject to the law

of motion for employment implied by the matching technology (6) and the equilibrium

condition for e¤ort (11), gives rise to the following �rst order condition,

g0 (Ht) = SFt (13)

where SFt is the marginal value to the �rm of having an additional worker in period t,

which is given by,

SFt = (1�F )(1� �)Yt

Nt�Wt + (1� �)Et

Qt;t+1SFt+1

(14)

= Et

1X

s=0

(1� �)sQt;t+s

(1�F )(1� �)Yt+s

Nt+s�Wt+s

(15)

where the second equality follows from iterating forward (and de�ning Qt;t = 1). This

is a job creation equation, which states that the marginal costs of hiring a new worker

g0 (Ht), must equal the expected net present value of marginal pro�ts (additional output

minus the wage) of the �lled job, SFt .

3.4 The Bargaining Set

Because of labor market frictions, employment relationships generate a strictly positive

surplus. The reason is that if �rm and worker cannot agree to continue their relationship,

23With a slight abuse of notation, Ejt denotes the e¤ort level exerted by all workers (from di¤erenthouseholds) in a particular �rm j. Firm j considers employing Njt workers, given that all other �rmsemploy the equilibrium number of workers Nt. Because there are in�nitely many �rms, �rm j�s decisionto employ Njt 66= Nt workers does not a¤ect the fraction of household h�s members that are employed, sothat by the assumption of perfect risk-sharing within the household, the consumption of workers in �rmj, Cht = Ct, is not a¤ected. Therefore, the relation between e¤ort and employment that the �rm facesif all other �rms (and all households) play equilibrium strategies, is given by equation (10), keeping Ct�xed. See appendix A for details on the derivation of equation (12).

13

then the �rm has to pay the hiring costs again in order to �nd another worker to match

with. Firms and households bargain over the wage as a way to share the match surplus.

These negotations are limited only by the outside option of each party. The lower bound

of the bargaining set is given by the reservation wage of the household, the wage o¤er at

which the household is indi¤erent between accepting the o¤er and looking for another

job. Similarly, the upper bound of the bargaining set is the reservation wage of the �rm,

the wage o¤er that makes the �rm indi¤erent between accepting the o¤er and hiring

a di¤erent worker. Within these bounds, any wage is consistent with equilibrium, see

Hall (2005). Clearly, the bounds of the bargaining set are endogenous variables, which

we now derive before introducing an equilibrium selection rule for the wage within the

bargaining set.

The part of the match surplus that accrues to the �rm SFt , as a function of the wage,

is given by equation (14). In order to derive a similar expression for the household�s part

of the surplus SHt , we must �rst calculate the marginal disutility to the household of

having one additional employed member, taking into account the endogenous response

of e¤ort. This marginal disutility of employment, expressed in terms of consumption, is

given by,24

C�tZt

dLhtdNht

=1

1 + �

C�tZt

1 + �(1 + �)H

E1+�t

=1

1 + �

C�tZt

+H(1� �)Yt

Nt(16)

where the second equality follows from substituting equation (11), and where H = 1+�

(1��)(1+�)� 1+�� captures the e¤ect on utility of one more employed member in the

household through the endogenous response of e¤ort. Using this expression, we can

take a derivative of the household�s objective function (1) with respect to Nt and divide

by the marginal utility of consumption, to obtain the following expression for SHt .

SHt =Wt �1

1 + �

C�tZt

�H(1� �)Yt

Nt+ (1� �)Et

Qt;t+1SHt+1

(17)

The value to the household of having one more employed worker, equals the wage minus

the disutility expressed in terms of consumption, plus the expected value of still having

that worker next period, which is discounted by the probability that the worker is still

employed next period.

The upper bound of the bargaining set WUBt is the highest wage such that SFt � 0,

whereas the lower bound WLBt is the lowest wage such that SHt � 0. Using equations

(14) and (17), we get SFt = WUBt �Wt and S

Ht = Wt �WLB

t . Substituting back into

equations (13), (14) and (17), we can explicitly write the equilibrium of the model in

terms of the wage and the bounds of the bargaining set.

g0 (Ht) =WUBt �Wt (18)

24The derivation of this expression is similar to that of equation (12), see appendix A for details.

14

WUBt = (1�F )

(1� �)YtNt

+ (1� �)Et�

Qt;t+1�

WUBt+1 �Wt+1

��

(19)

WLBt =

1

1 + �

C�tZt

+H(1� �)Yt

Nt+ (1� �)Et

Qt;t+1�

WLBt+1 �Wt+1

��

(20)

Everything else equal, the more rigid is the wage in response to technology or preference

shocks that shift the bounds of the bargaining set, the more volatile is hiring Ht and

therefore employment Nt in response to those shocks, see equation (18). We now turn

to various possibilities for how wages are determined within the bargaining set.

3.5 Wage Determination

One possible criterion for wage determination that we can interpret as �exible wages

in a model with a frictional labor market, is period-by-period Nash bargaining. Nash

bargaining assumes that the wage is set such that the total surplus from the match is

split in equal proportions between household and �rm. It is straightforward to see that

in our framework, this assumption implies that the wage is the average of the lower and

upper bounds of the bargaining set, SHt = 12

SHt + SFt

= 12

WUBt �WLB

t

. Then,

W �

t =12

WUBt +WLB

t

(21)

where W �

t denotes the Nash bargained wage.

Shimer (2005) and Hall (2005), among others, have argued that period-by-period

Nash bargaining generates too volatile a wage in equilibrium, relative to what is observed

in the data. As discussed below, in our model period-by-period Nash bargaining leads to

�uctuations in the (log) wage of the same amplitude as labor productivity, and perfectly

correlated with the latter. This is at odds with the data, where wages are about half

as volatile as labor productivity in the pre-84 period, with the correlation between the

two variables much smaller than one. Both the relative volatility of wages and their

correlation with labor productivity increases signi�cantly in the post-84 period. This

motivates the introduction of a wage setting mechanism that departs from period-by-

period Nash bargaining.25 We use the following wage determination process,

Wt = Rt�1Wt�1 + (1�Rt�1)W�

t (22)

where Rt measures the degree of wage rigidity, which is endogenous.

Only wages within the bargaining set are renegotiation-proof and therefore consistent

with equilibrium, see Barro (1977). The maximum degree of wage stickiness that respects

this condition, is for the wage to remain �xed inside the bargaining set, but to be adjusted

25This is consistent with the recent trend in the literature, see e.g. Hall (2005), Blanchard and Galí(2007), Hall and Milgrom (2008), Christo¤el and Kuester (2008), Gertler and Trigari (2009), and Shimer(2009).

15

when it hits either bound. This is the wage determination mechanism in Thomas and

Worrall (1988) and Hall (2003). We use a convex version of this wage rule, in order

to be able to solve the model using perturbation methods, and assume the following

reduced-form equation for wage rigidity,

Rt = �R

0

@1�

Wt �W�

t12

WUBt �WLB

t

!2�1

A (23)

where � 2 N+0 . This wage rule captures the idea that the wage is more likely to adjust

when it is closer to the bounds of the bargaining set. The parameter � captures the

degree of non-linearity in this relation. For � = 0, Rt = 0 and Wt = W �

t , i.e. wages

are �exible. For � 2 N+, the degree of wage rigidity is endogenous, with wages being

perfectly �exible at the upper or lower bound of the bargaining set and most rigid at

the Nash-bargained wage W �

t . As � becomes larger, wages are rigid in a larger part of

the bargaining set. The limiting case for � ! 1 and �R = 1 captures the case where

the wage is �xed within the bargaining set but adjusts when it has to in order to avoid

ine¢cient match destruction as in Hall (2003). We consider a �exible wage regime with

� = 0 and regime with endogenous wage rigidity, � 2 N+ and �R = 1.

The crucial insight for our purposes is that with this type of wage rule, the degree

of wage rigidity depends endogenously on the size of the frictions. If frictions decrease,

the width of the bargaining set decreases as well, so that there is less room for wage

rigidity. Notice also that this type of wage rigidity can never lead to ine¢cient match

destruction.

3.6 Equilibrium

We conclude the description of the model by listing the conditions that characterize the

equilibrium. Vacancy posting decisions by �rms are summarized by the job creation

equation (18).

g0 (Ht) =WUBt �Wt (24)

The equilibrium level of e¤ort is determined by e¢ciency condition (11),

E1+�t =

1 + �

1 + �

Zt C�t

(1� �)YtNt

(25)

and wage negotations are described by equations (22) and (23) for the equilibrium

selection rule, and stochastic di¤erence equations for the upper and lower bounds of the

bargaining set (19) and (20).

Wt = RtWt�1 + (1�Rt)12

WUBt +WLB

t

(26)

16

Rt = �R

0

@1�

Wt �12

WUBt +WLB

t

12

WUBt �WLB

t

!2�1

A (27)

WUBt = (1�F )

(1� �)YtNt

+ (1� �)Et�

Qt;t+1�

WUBt+1 �Wt+1

��

(28)

WLBt =

1

1 + �

C�tZt

+H(1� �)Yt

Nt+ (1� �)Et

Qt;t+1�

WLBt+1 �Wt+1

��

(29)

Employment evolves according to its law of motion (6).

Nt = (1� �)Nt�1 +Ht (30)

Finally, goods market clearing requires that consumption equals output minus hiring

costs.

Ct = Yt � g (Ht) (31)

Output is de�ned as in production function (4), and the stochastic discount factor

as the marginal rate of intertemporal substitution (7).

Yt = At

E t Nt

�1��(32)

Qt;t+1 = �Zt+1Zt

CtCt+1

��

(33)

and the parameters F =�

1+��(1��) and H = 1+�

(1��)(1+�)� 1+�� are functions of the

structural parameters. In total, we have 8 equations in the endogenous variables Ht,

Et, Wt, Rt, WUBt , WLB

t , Nt and Ct, or 10 equations including the de�nitions for Yt and

Qt;t+1.

Without an endogenous e¤ort choice ( = 0 so that e¤ort is not useful in production,

F = H = 0, and Et = 0 for all t in equilibrium), and with �exible wages ( �R = 0 so

that Rt = 0 for all t), the model reduces to a standard RBC model with labor market

frictions. However, unlike in the standard model, �uctuations in our model are driven

by technology shocks as well as non-technology shocks or preference shocks. The two

driving forces of �uctuations, log total factor productivity at � logAt and log preferences

over consumption zt � logZt follow stationary AR(1) processes,

at = �aat�1 + "at (34)

zt = �zzt�1 + "zt (35)

where "at and "zt are independent white noise processes with variances given by �

2a and

�2z respectively.

We now proceed to use this model to analyze the possible role of labor market

17

frictions in generating the observed changes in the cyclical patterns of output, labor

input, productivity, and wages. For this analysis, all three above-mentioned elements

are important, i.e. multiple shocks, endogenous e¤ort and endogenous wage rigidity.

4 The Increasing Flexibility of the Labor Market

This section provides an analysis of our model economy�s equilibrium under alternative

assumptions regarding the size of labor market frictions and wage determination. We

start by looking at a version of the model with a frictionless labor market. This model

provides a useful benchmark that we can solve for in closed form. Then, we introduce

frictions and rely on numerical methods to simulate the model for di¤erent calibrations

of the parameters.

4.1 The Frictionless Case

Consider the limiting case of an economy without labor market frictions, i.e. g (H) = 0

for all H. The �rst thing to note is that in this case the width of the bargaining set

collapses to zero, and the job creation equation (24) and the wage block of the model,

equations (26), (27), (28) and (29), imply

Wt =WUBt =WLB

t = (1�F )(1� �)Yt

Nt=

1

1 + �

C�tZt

+H(1� �)Yt

Nt(36)

for all t. Employment becomes a choice variable, so that its law of motion (30) is dropped

from the system and employment is instead determined by the static condition (36).

Nt = (1� �) (1�F �H)(1 + �)ZtYt

C�t(37)

Substituting into the equilibrium condition for e¤ort (25), we obtain

E1+�t =

1 + �

1

1

1�F �H(38)

implying an e¤ort level that is invariant to �uctuations in the model�s driving forces.

Since e¤ort has stronger diminishing returns in production and stronger increasing mar-

ginal disutility than employment, this intensive margin of adjustment is never used if

the extensive margin is not subject to frictions.

Without hiring costs, the aggregate resource constraint (31) reduces to Ct = Yt.

Combining the resource constraint and equations (37) and (38) with the production

function (32), we can derive closed-form expressions for equilibrium employment, output,

wages and labor productivity. Using lower-case letters to denote the natural logarithms

of the original variables, ignoring constant terms and normalizing the variance of the

18

shocks,26 we get:

nt = (1� �) at + zt (39)

yt = at + (1� �) zt (40)

wt = yt � nt = �at � �zt (41)

A useful benchmark is the model with logarithmic utility over consumption (� = 1). In

this case, employment �uctuates in proportion to the preference shifter zt but does not

respond to technology shocks.27

From the previous equations, it is straightforward to calculate the model�s implica-

tions for the second moments of interest. In particular we have

cov (yt � nt; yt) = � var (at)� � (1� �) var (zt) (42)

cov (yt � nt; nt) = � (1� �) var (at)� � var (zt) (43)

In the absence of labor market frictions, labor productivity is unambiguously counter-

cyclical in response to preference shocks. The intuition for this result is that output

responds to preference shocks only through employment, and this response is less than

proportional because of diminishing returns in labor input (� > 0). Since productivity

is unambiguously procyclical in response to technology shocks, the unconditional corre-

lations depend on the relative variances of the shocks and the model parameters. For a

wide range of parameter values, e.g. with logarithmic utility over consumption (� = 1),

productivity is procyclical with respect to output but countercyclical with respect to

employment.

The relative volatility of employment and wages with respect to output are given by

the following expressions:

var (nt)

var (yt)=(1� �)2 var (at) + var (zt)

var (at) + (1� �)2 var (zt)

(44)

var (wt)

var (yt)=

�2 var (at) + �2 var (zt)

var (at) + (1� �)2 var (zt)

(45)

The size of the relative volatility measures above depends again on the relative impor-

tance of the shocks, as well as on the size of �, the parameter determining the degree

of diminishing returns to labor.

26 If the original shocks are ~at and ~zt, then we de�ne at = ~at and zt = ~zt, where =1= [1� (1� �) (1� �)].27This result is an implication of the logarithmic or �balanced growth� preferences over consumption

in combination with the absence of capital or any other intertemporal smoothing technology, and issimilar to the �neutrality result� in Shimer (2009).

19

4.2 In�nite Labor Market Frictions

We can contrast the predictions of the frictionless model above, with the opposite ex-

treme case of in�nitely large labor market frictions, i.e. g (H) = 1 if H > 0. In this

case, no new workers will be hired, so that by the aggregate resource constraint (31)

Ct = Yt, as in the frictionless case. For simplicity, also assume that the separation rate

equals zero, � = 0, so that employment is �xed. In this case, combining the produc-

tion function (32) with the equilibrium condition for e¤ort (25), and taking logarithms,

ignoring constant terms and normalizing the variance of the shocks,28 we get:

et = (1� �) at + zt (46)

yt = yt � nt = (1 + �) at + (1� �) zt (47)

Since employment is �xed, e¤ort is now procyclical in response to both types of shocks, as

all of the adjustment of labor input occurs on the intensive margin. With in�nitely large

labor market frictions, labor productivity is perfectly (positively) correlated with output.

The correlation between productivity and employment, as well as the relative volatility

of employment with respect to output equal zero. Finally, since the bargaining set is

now in�nitely wide, wages may be arbitrarily rigid, depending on the model parameters,

so that the relative volatility of wages is also arbitrarily close to zero.

4.3 Preview of the Results

Comparing these predictions with those of the frictionless model in the previous sub-

section, it is clear that by moving from a completely rigid to a completely �exible labor

market:

1. Labor productivity becomes less procyclical with respect to output.

2. Labor productivity goes from acyclical to countercyclical with respect to employ-

ment, depending on parameter values (a su¢cient condition is logarithmic utility

over consumption).

3. The relative volatility of employment increases.

4. The relative volatility of wages increases.

All four of these predictions are consistent with the data, as we documented in section

2. We are not arguing, of course, that the US labor market went from completely

rigid to completely �exible. Rather, the argument so far is meant to illustrate that if

the reduction in labor market frictions was large enough, it can qualitatively explain

28 In this case, the normalization factor is 1= [1 + �� (1� �) (1� �) ].

20

the patterns we observe in the data. To answer the question whether we can also

quantitatively match those patterns for reasonable parameter values, we now turn to a

numerical analysis of the full model.

4.4 Calibration

We simulate data at quarterly frequency and calibrate accordingly. The calibration is

summarized in Table 6. Many of the model�s parameters can be easily calibrated to

values that are standard in the literature. In this vein, we set the discount factor �

equal to 0:99, assume logarithmic utility over consumption (� = 1), and assume � = 1=3

for the curvature of the production function to match the capital share in GDP.

In the model there is no di¤erence between unemployment and non-participation.

Therefore, we set the marginal utility from leisure to match the employment-population

ratio. Since the amount of labor market frictions a¤ects this ratio as well, we calibrate

to an employment-population ratio of 0:7 in the frictionless model. For the (gross) sep-

aration rate �, we assume 30:6% per quarter, calculated from the monthly worker �ows

in Shimer (2007).29

The calibration of the labor market frictions is crucial for the simulation exercise.

We assume a quadratic cost function, g (H) = 12�H

2, see Yashiv (2010), and consider

a range of values for � such that hiring costs vary from 0 to 3% of output. This range

is based on Silva and Toledo (2009), who estimate the costs of hiring a new worker

to be between 3 and 4:5% of the wage of a newly hired worker, see also Hagedorn

and Manovskii (2008, p.1699). In steady state, the number of newly hired workers

equals �H = � �N per quarter, see (30). Wages, in the frictionless model without e¤ort,

approximately equal the marginal product of labor, �W = (1� �) �Y = �N , see (36). Thus,

hiring costs of 4:5% of the wage translate to total hiring costs of about 1% of output.

For the model�s driving forces, we assume high persistence in both shocks, setting

�a = 0:97 to match the �rst-order autocorrelation in Solow residuals, and �z = 0:97

to make sure that none of the results are driven by di¤erences in persistence. Given

those values, we calibrate �2a and �2z so that the frictionless version of the calibrated

model matches the relative volatility of employment and predicts a standard deviation

of log output of 1%. The �rst target is justi�ed by the observation that in this very

simple model, preference shocks are a stand-in for all sources of misspeci�cation that

result in the unemployment volatility puzzle. The second target is arbitrarily chosen

to emphasize that we consider this model mostly illustrative and not able to generate

29Shimer (2007) �nds a monthly separation rate of sm = 0:034 and a monthly job �nding rate offm = 0:45. Then, the quarterly separation rate, the probability that a worker who is employed at thebeginning of the quarter is no longer employed at the end of the quarter, is given by s = sm (1� fm)

2+(1� sm) sm (1� fm) + (1� sm)

2 sm + s2mfm = 0:0606 and the quarterly job �nding rate equals f =fm (1� sm)

2 + (1� fm) fm (1� sm) + (1� fm)2 fm + f2msm = 0:802. Since workers that are separated

in a given quarter may �nd another job within that quarter, the gross separation rate is given by� = s= (1� f) = 0:306.

21

realistic predictions for the overall level of volatility in the economy.

For the parameters related to e¤ort, we have very little guidance from previous

literature. We normalize � and � such that e¤ort is expressed in utility units and

equals 1 in the frictionless steady state. We treat the curvature of the production

function in e¤ort as a free parameter. Since we are mostly interested to illustrate

the qualitative changes in the business cycle moments that the model can generate, we

pick this parameter such that the model approximately replicates the second moments

in the data. The testable prediction here is not whether the model can quantitatively

match some or most of the second moments, but whether it can qualitatively generate

all observed changes, changing only the labor market frictions.

4.5 Simulation Results

We now simulate the calibrated model in order to calculate the second moments of

interest. We start with the model with �exible wages and show that a reduction in

labor market frictions matches the data on the cyclicality of labor productivity and the

relative volatility of labor input. Then we consider endogenous wage rigidity and show

that the model can also match an increase in the relative volatility of wages, and -if

endogenous wage rigidities are strong enough- can also generate a reduction in output

volatility.

The model with �exible wages is close to log-linear and a �rst-order approximation

captures well the dynamics generated by the model. However, the model with endoge-

nous wage rigidity is non-linear, because the wage depends on the past wage Wt�1 and

the bounds of the bargaining setWUBt andWLB

t , multiplied by the degree of rigidity Rt,

which itself depends again on Wt and WUBt and WLB

t , see (26) and (27). If we were to

log-linearize this wage rule, it would reduce to a partial adjustment rule with a constant

degree of wage rigidity. Therefore, we use a second-order approximation of the policy

functions. As an accuracy check, Figure 3 shows that a second-order approximation

captures well the non-linear wage rule for � = 1, but for � = 2 or larger, a higher-order

approximation is needed. We simulate the second-order approximation of the model

201; 000 periods, discarding the �rst 1; 000 observations to eliminate the e¤ect of the

initial conditions. The results of this exercise are reported in Table 7.

4.5.1 Flexible Wages

Labor productivity is strongly procyclical in terms of its correlation with output in

the model with a frictional labor market, and its procyclicality falls substantially as

we reduce labor market frictions. The correlation of productivity with employment also

falls, from around zero in the frictional labor market to countercyclical in the frictionless

model. Both observations are consistent with the evidence. The reason for the decline in

22

the procyclicality of productivity, is the increase in the relative volatility of employment,

a result that is consistent with the data as well.

Two elements in the model are crucial for these results. First, the e¤ort choice

provides an intensive margin of adjustment for labor input. As frictions fall, it becomes

optimal to adjust labor more through employment and less through e¤ort. Thus, the

volatility of employment increases more than that of output. Second, �uctuations in the

model are driven by two types of shocks: technology shocks and preference shocks or

labor supply shocks. In a one-shock model, the correlations between all variables would

be close to either 1 or �1.30 In addition, if �uctuations were driven only by technology

shocks then productivity could never be countercyclical, since employment would only

�uctuate because of changes in labor demand, and the direct e¤ect of technology on

productivity would always prevail over the indirect e¤ect of employment. It is important

to stress, however, that our results are not driven by changes in the relative importance

of both shocks, which we keep constant, but by the reduction in frictions, which changes

the response of the economy conditional on each shock.

The model also predicts a small decrease in the relative volatility of wages and a

small increase in the volatility of output. As argued in section 2.3, the �rst prediction is

arguably not consistent with the data. The second one clearly is in contradiction with

the well-documented reduction in output volatility, the so called Great Moderation.

The decrease in the relative volatility of wages is driven by the fact that the wage

is approximately proportional to the marginal product of labor.31 Since the marginal

product of labor is proportional to output, but inversely proportional to employment,

an increase in the relative volatility of employment must necessarily also decrease the

relative volatility of wages. The increase in the volatility of output simply stems from the

fact that reducing adjustment costs ampli�es �uctuations in employment and therefore

in output as well. In the next subsection we show that endogneous wage rigidities

can easily reverse the predictions of the model for wages and possibly also bring the

prediction for output volatility closer to the evidence.

4.5.2 Endogenous Wage Rigidity

The third panel in Table 7 presents the simulated second moments for the model with

endogenous wage rigidity (� = 1 and �R = 0:95). Comparing these moments to those for

the �exible wage model, we see that the previously described predictions of the model

for the cyclicality of labor productivity and the relative volatility of employment remain

30This is exactly true in a static, linear model. Our model is close to (log)linear and the versionwithout capital and with �exible wages has only one state variable (employment), which has very fasttransition dynamics.31On a frictional labor market, the wage is not equal to marginal product of labor, but as long as

is not too large, they are still proportional since workers and �rms share the match surplus in equalproportions.

23

virtually unchanged. The reason is that the fact that wages adjust when they get close

to the bounds of the bargaining set mitigates the allocative e¤ect of wage rigidity.

The prediction of the model for the relative volatility of wages, however, is reversed.

The reduction in labor market frictions now increases the volatility of wages, although

not by as much as in the data. To understand the mechanism behind this result, it

is useful to consider the extreme case of endogenous wage rigidity (� ! 1), in which

wages are completely �xed within the bargaining set, but adjust when they hit the

bounds of the bargaining set. If frictions are high enough, so that the bargaining set

is very wide, wages never adjust and their volatility is zero. On the other extreme, on

a frictionless labor market, the bargaining set reduces to a point and wages behave as

if they were �exible. Of course this e¤ect is counteracted by the fact that the bounds

of the bargaining set themselves are less volatile when frictions are lower. However, for

our calibration of the parameters, the �rst e¤ect dominates, as illustrated in Figure 4.

The small increase in output volatility in response to the reduction in labor market

frictions is reversed to a small decrease for the model with endogenous wage rigidity.

The reason is that increased wage �exibility dampens �uctuations in output in response

to technology shocks.32 This result is consistent with a possible role of a decline in labor

market frictions as a source of the Great Moderation. However, the e¤ect is again much

smaller than in the data. Thus, whereas we �nd this last result intuitively compelling, it

is speculative in the sense that it is not clear whether it may be important quantitatively.

5 Conclusions

In this paper, we documented three changes in labor market dynamics over the postwar

period in the US: the strong procyclicality of labor productivity has vanished, the volatil-

ity of employment has increased with respect to output, and the volatility of wages has

increased relative to output and possibly even in absolute terms. We presented a model

to argue that a more �exible labor market, modelled as a reduction in hiring costs, can

explain all three facts. In addition, we showed that -in principle- the reduction in labor

market frictions may also have contributed to the reduction in output volatility, which

happened around the same time.

The intuition for why a reduction in labor market frictions increases the relative

volatility of employment and reduces the procyclicality of labor productivity is straight-

forward and compelling. If there is another input into production that can be used at

least partly as a substitute for labor, and which is not subject to the frictions, then a

reduction in frictions will make that input less volatile, so that employment becomes

more volatile with respect to output. In this paper, we refer to this other factor input

as e¤ort. But a very similar argument can be made for capacity utilization of capital.

32 In reponse to preference shocks, which a¤ect labor supply rather than labor demand, the reverse istrue. However, the e¤ect of technology shocks dominates that of preference shocks in our calibration.

24

Given that capital does not �uctuate much at business cycle frequencies, the fact that

the comovement of labor and output -and therefore labor productivity- has changed

almost unavoidably leads to the conclusion that there must be another input into the

production process.

Our argument that the reduction in labor market frictions is also responsible for the

increase in the relative volatility of wages is more contentious. Our simulations of the

model with endogenous wage ridigity show that this e¤ect is qualitatively present, and

can be made to dominate the direct e¤ect on wages for reasonable parameter values.

However, the increase in wage volatility in our simulations is much smaller than in the

data.33 Potentially, we can amplify this e¤ect by using a more non-linear wage rule,

but then we also need to use a higher-order approximation of the model. While there

is a compelling argument that wage rigidity is, at least to some degree, endogenous, it

remains an open question quantitatively how important this mechanism is.

What have we learned about the possible causes of the Great Moderation? We

showed that a reduction in labor market frictions, through an endogenous decrease in

wage rigidity, can lead to a decrease in output volatility. However, this e¤ect is small in

our simulations, partly because the decrease in wage rigidity is relatively small (at least

much smaller than in the data), but also because there is a direct e¤ect of the reduction

in labor market frictions that counteracts the e¤ect of decreased wage rigidity: reduced

frictions make labor more volatile, reducting the volatility of its marginal product. A

further caveat against the conclusion that the Great Moderation is driven by a reduction

in labor market frictions is that this story only works if technology shocks are relatively

important as a source of business cycle �uctuation. The reason is that preference shocks

act as labor supply shocks, so that wage rigidity dampens rather than ampli�es �uctu-

ations in employment in response to those shocks. Finally, reduced wage rigidity can

only lead to reduced output volatility if the wage is allocative, i.e. if the reduction in

wage rigidity applies to the wage of newly hired workers. We documented an increase

in the relative volatility of wages of new hires, see section 2.3.2, but that increase is

substantially smaller than for the average wage in the economy, casting further doubt

on the importance of this mechanism for the Great Moderation.

If it is true that the US labor market become more �exible in the mid 80s, then what

institutional change was responsible for it? It is tempting to attribute the lower labor

market frictions to improvements in recruitment technologies, particularly web-based

job search. However, that development, while potentially important, happened much

later.34 Major changes on the US labor market in the mid 80s include the introduction of

wrongful discharge laws in many states (Autor, Kerr, and Kugler (2007)), the increase

33At least than the data from the Labor Productivity and Cost program and the Current PopulationSurvey. The data from the Current Employment Statistics show a decrease in the relative volatility ofwages, see section 2.3, which our model has no trouble generating.34The largest and one of the �rst internet recruitment providers, monster.com, started in 1994.

25

in temporary help services and the decline of unionization. The introduction of the

wrongful discharge legislation constitutes an increase in employment protection, which

would increase rather than decrease frictions in our simple model. The increased share

of temporary help workers (workers employed by a temporary help agency rather than

directly by the employer where they work) is often seen as a response to increased

employment protection and happened very gradually, see Estevão and Lach (1999),

whereas the changes we document seem to have happened relatively suddenly around

1984.

In terms of timing, the decline in union power lines up very well with our story.

Farber and Western (2002) document a sharp decline in the number of certi�cation

elections in the early 80s and interpret this as evidence for an �unfavourable political

climate which raises the costs of unionization�, induced by the Reagan�s policies and

in particular his handling of the air-tra¢c controllers� strike in 1981. Moreover, recent

evidence suggests that union power is an important institution to explain di¤erences in

labor market volatility across countries and time periods, see Kent, Smith, and Holloway

(2005), Bertola and LoPrete (2009) and Gnocchi and Pappa (2009). A logical next step

for future research would be to write down a model with unions and endogenize the

reduction in labor market frictions.

26

A Marginal Product and Disutility of E¤ort

This appendix derives the marginal product of employment to the �rm, equation (12),

and the marginal disutility from employment, expressed in consumption terms, to the

household, equation (16), if e¤ort adjusts endogenously. From equations (4) and (2), it

is straightforward di¤erentation to decompose the total e¤ect of employment on output

and total e¤ective labor supply into a direct e¤ect and an e¤ect through the endogenous

response of e¤ort.

dYjtdNjt

=@Yjt@Njt

+@Yjt@Ejt

@Ejt@Njt

=(1� �)Yjt

Njt

1 + Njt

Ejt

@Ejt@Njt

(48)

dLhtdNht

=@Lht@Nht

+@Lht@Eht

@Eht@Nht

=1

1 + �

1 + �E1+�ht

1 + (1 + �)Nht

Eht

@Eht@Nht

��

(49)

Here, Ejt denotes the e¤ort of all workers i that are employed in �rm j and Eht the e¤ort

of all workers that are members of household h.

To �nd the response of e¤ort to changes in employment that �rm and household

face, we use the condition that the marginal disutility from e¤ort of a given worker

i (expressed in consumption terms) from equation (8), in equilibrium must equal the

marginal productivity of that worker to the �rm from equation (9).

E1+�� it =

(1 + �)

(1 + �) �

Zt C�ht

(1� �)At

�Z Njt

0E vtdv

���

(50)

First, suppose �rm j considers employing Njt workers, given that all other �rms

employ the equilibrium number of workers Nt. Because there are in�nitely many �rms,

�rm j�s decision to employ Njt 66= Nt workers does not a¤ect the fraction of household h�s

members that are employed, so that by the assumption of perfect risk-sharing within the

household, the consumption of workers in �rm j is not a¤ected, Cht = Ct. Substituting

this, as well as the condition that all workers in �rm j exert the same amount of e¤ort,

Eit = Ejt for all i 2 [0; Njt], the e¤ort condition becomes,

E1+�� jt =

(1 + �)

(1 + �) �

Zt C�t

(1� �)At

E jtNjt

��

(51)

so that the elasticity of e¤ort in a given �rm j with respect to employment in that �rm,

is given byNjt

Ejt

@Ejt@Njt

= ��

1 + �� (1� �) (52)

Substituting this elasticity into equation (48) above, gives expression (12) in the text.

Next, suppose household h considers having Nht employed workers, given that all

other households have Nt employed workers. Because there are in�nitely many house-

holds, household�s h�s decision to have a fraction of Nht 66= Nt of its members employed,

27

does not a¤ect the level of employment in any �rm Njt = Nt. Furthermore, although

the e¤ort level of worker i may change because of household h�s decision, e¤ort of all

other workers in �rm j, who are members of di¤erent households, is una¤ected, Eit = Eht

and Ei0t = Et for i0 6= i. Thus, the e¤ort condition becomes,

E1+�� ht =

(1 + �)

(1 + �) �

Zt C�ht

(1� �)At

E t Nt

��

(53)

and the elasticity of e¤ort exerted by members of household h with respect to employ-

ment in that household, using equation (3), is given by,

Nht

Eht

@Eht@Nht

=ChtEht

@Eht@Cht

�Nht

Cht

@Cht@Nht

= ��

1 + ��

WhtNht

Cht= �

1 + �� (54)

Substituting this elasticity into equation (49) above, gives expression (16) in the text.

28

References

Arias, A., G. Hansen, and L. E. Ohanian (2007). Why have business cycle �uctuations

become less volatile? Economic Theory 32 (1), 43�58.

Autor, D. H., W. R. Kerr, and A. D. Kugler (2007). Does employment protection

reduce productivity? evidence from US states. Economic Journal 117 (June).

Barnichon, R. (2008). Productivity, aggregate demand and unemployment �uctua-

tions. Board of governors of the federal reserve system: Finance and economics

discussion series 2008-47.

Barro, R. J. (1977). Long-term contracting, sticky prices, and monetary policy. Jour-

nal of Monetary Economics 3 (3).

Basu, S. (1996). Procyclical productivity: increasing returns or cyclical utilization?

Quarterly Journal of Economics 111 (3).

Basu, S. and J. Fernald (1997). Returns to scale in U.S. production: Estimates and

implications. Journal of Political Economy 105, 249�283.

Basu, S. and M. S. Kimball (1997). Cyclical productivity with unobserved input vari-

ation. NBER working paper 5915.

Bernanke, B. and M. Parkinson (1991). Procyclical labor productivity and competing

theories of the business cycle: Some evidence from interwar u.s. manufacturing

industries. Journal of Political Economy 99 (3), 439�459.

Bertola, G. and A. LoPrete (2009). Reforms, �nance, and current accounts. Upub-

lished manuscript.

Bils, M. and J.-O. Cho (1994). Cyclical factor utilization. Journal of Monetary Eco-

nomics 33 (2), 319�354.

Blanchard, O. and J. Galí (2007). Real wage rigidities and the new keynesian model.

Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39 (s1), 35�65.

Blanchard, O. and J. Galí (2008). The macroeconomic e¤ects of oil price shocks: Why

are the 2000s so di¤erent from the 1970s? CREI working paper.

Blanchard, O. and M. Watson (1986). Are business cycles all alike? In R. Gordon

(Ed.), Continuity and Change in the American Business Cycle. NBER and the

University of Chicago Press.

Burnside, C., M. Eichenbaum, and S. Rebelo (1993). Labor hoarding and the business

cycle. Journal of Political Economy 101 (2), 245�273.

Champagne, J. and A. Kurmann (2010). The great increase in relative wage volatility

in the United States. Unpublished manuscript.

29

Christiano, L. and M. Eichenbaum (1992). Current Real Business Cycle theories and

aggregate labor market �uctuations. American Economic Review 82 (3).

Christo¤el, K. and K. Kuester (2008). Resuscitating the wage channel in models with

unemployment �uctuations. Journal of Monetary Economics 55 (5), 865�887.

Clarida, R., J. Galí, and M. Gertler (2000). The science of monetary policy: A new

Keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Literature XXXVII (December 1999).

Estevão, M. and S. Lach (1999). The evolution of the demand for temporary help

supply employment in the United States. NBER working paper 7427.

Fair, R. (1969). The Short-run Demand for Workers and Hours. Amsterdam: North-

Holland.

Farber, H. S. and B. Western (2002). Ronald Reagan and the politics of declining

union organization. British Journal of Industrial Relations 40 (3).

Fay, J. A. and J. L. Medo¤ (1985). Labor and output over the business cycle: Some

direct evidence. American Economic Review 75 (4), 638�655.

Francis, N. and V. Ramey (2008). Measures of hours per capita and their implications

for the technology-hours debate. Unpublished manuscript.

Galí;, J. and L. Gambetti (2009). On the sources of the great moderation. American

Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1 (1), 26�57.

Gertler, M. and A. Trigari (2009). Unemployment �uctuations with staggered nash

wage bargaining. Journal of Political Economy 117 (1), 38�86.

Gnocchi, S. and E. Pappa (2009). Do labor market rigidities matter for business

cycles? yes they do. Unpublished manuscript.

Gordon, R. J. (2004). Are procyclical productivity �uctuations a �gment of measure-

ment error. In R. Gordon (Ed.), Productivity Growth, In�ation, and Unemploy-

ment, pp. 239�272. Cambridge University Press.

Gordon, R. J. (2010). Okun�s law, productivity innovations, and conundrums in busi-

ness cycle dating. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings 100 (2).

Gourio, F. (2007). Labor market �exibility and the Great Moderation. Unpublished

manuscript.

Haefke, C., M. Sonntag, and T. van Rens (2008). Wage rigidity and job creation.

CREI working paper.

Hagedorn, M. and I. Manovskii (2008). The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unem-

ployment and vacancies revisited. American Economic Review 98 (4), 1692�1706.

Hall, R. E. (1988). The relation between price and marginal cost in U.S. industry.

Journal of Political Economy 96 (5), 921�947.

30

Hall, R. E. (2003). Wage determination and employment �uctuations. Working Paper

9967, NBER.

Hall, R. E. (2005). Employment �uctuations with equilibrium wage stickiness. Amer-

ican Economic Review 95 (1), 50�65.

Hall, R. E. (2007). How much do we understand about the modern recession? Brook-

ings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 13�28.

Hall, R. E. and P. R. Milgrom (2008). The limited in�uence of unemployment on the

wage bargain. American Economic Review 98 (4), 1653�74.

Kent, C., K. Smith, and J. Holloway (2005). Declining output volatility: What role

for structural change? In C. Kent and D. Norman (Eds.), The Changing Nature

of the Business Cycle. Reserve Bank of Australia.

McConell, M. M. and G. Pérez-Quirós (2000). Output �uctuations in the United

States: What has changed since the early 1980�s? American Economic Re-

view 90 (5), 1464�1476.

Mehran, H. and J. Tracy (2001). The e¤ect of employee stock options on the evolution

of compensation in the 1990s. Economic Policy Review, Federal Reserve Bank of

New York Dec, 17�34.

Nucci, F. and M. Riggi (2009). The Great Moderation and changes in the structure

of labor compensation. Unpublished manuscript.

Oi, W. Y. (1962). Labor as a quasi-�xed factor. Journal of Political Economy 70,

538�555.

Pissarides, C. A. (2009). The unemployment volatility puzzle: Is wage stickiness the

answer? Walras-Bowley lecture, North American summer meetings of the Econo-

metric Society, Duke University. Econometrica 77 (5), 1339�1369.

Rogerson, R. and R. Shimer (2010). Search in macroeconomic models of the labor

market. In O. Ashenfelter and D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics,

volume 4, pp. forthcoming.

Rotemberg, J. and L. Summers (1990). In�exible prices and procyclical productivity.

Quarterly Journal of Economics 105 (November), 851�874.

Shapiro, M. (1993). Cyclical productivity and the workweek of capital. American

Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings 83, 229�233.

Shea, J. (1999). What do technology shocks do? NBER macroeconomics annual 13,

275�310.

Shimer, R. (2005). The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies.

American Economic Review 95 (1), 25�49.

31

Shimer, R. (2007). Reassessing the ins and outs of unemployment. NBER Working

Papers 13421, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

Shimer, R. (2009). Labor Markets and Business Cycles. Princeton University Press,

CREI Lectures in Macroeconomics.

Silva, J. I. and M. Toledo (2009). Labor turnover costs and the cyclical behavior of

vacancies and unemployment. Macroeconomic Dynamics 13 (S1), 76�96.

Solow, R. M. (1964). On the short-run relation between employment and output.

Presidential address to the econometric society.

Stiroh, K. J. (2009). Volatility accounting: A production perspective on increased

economic stability. Journal of the European Economic Association 7 (4), 671�696.

Stock, J. and M. Watson (2002). Has the Business Cycle Changed and Why? MIT

Press.

Stock, J. H. and M. W. Watson (1999). Business cycle �uctuations in U.S. macroeco-

nomic time series. In J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford (Eds.), Handbook of Macro-

economics, volume 1A, pp. 3�64. Elsevier.

Thomas, J. and T. Worrall (1988). Self-enforcing wage contracts. Review of Economic

Studies 55 (4), 541�54.

Uhlig, H. and Y. Xu (1996). E¤ort and the cycle. Tilburg University, Center for

Economic Research discussion paper 1996-49.

Uren, L. (2008). Inequality, volatility and labour market e¢ciency. B.E. Journals,

Topics in Macroeconomics 8 (1).

Wen, Y. (2004). What does it take to explain procyclical productivity. B.E. Journals,

Contributions to Macroeconomics 4 (1).

Yashiv, E. (2010). On the joint behavior of hiring and investment. Unpublished man-

uscript.

32

Table 1. The Vanishing Procyclicality of Labor Productivity

Corr with output Corr with labor input

Pre-84 Post-84 Change Pre-84 Post-84 Change

Output per hour

BP 0:60 0:25 �0:35 0:19 �0:40 �0:59

[0:06] [0:07] [0:09] [0:09] [0:07] [0:11]

4D 0:62 0:18 �0:44 0:09 �0:54 �0:62

[0:05] [0:09] [0:10] [0:07] [0:08] [0:11]

Output per worker

BP 0:78 0:60 �0:18 0:31 �0:15 �0:47

[0:04] [0:05] [0:06] [0:08] [0:10] [0:13]

4D 0:76 0:46 �0:30 0:13 �0:33 �0:46

[0:03] [0:09] [0:09] [0:08] [0:11] [0:14]

Standard errors in brackets are calculated from the variance-covariance matrix of the

second moments using the delta method. Data for the private sector are from the BLS

labor productivity and cost program (LPC) and refer to the private sector. Labor input

is total hours worked in the �rst panel and employment in the second panel, consistent

with the de�nition of labor productivity. The sample period is 1949-2007.

33

Table 2. The Rising Volatility of Labor Input

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

Employment (private sector)

BP 1:57 0:91 0:58 0:66 0:81 1:23

[0:08] [0:05] [0:04] [0:03] [0:05] [0:09]

4D 2:44 1:54 0:63 0:66 0:94 1:43

[0:13] [0:12] [0:06] [0:03] [0:08] [0:15]

Hours (private sector)

BP 1:93 1:18 0:61 0:81 1:06 1:30

[0:09] [0:06] [0:04] [0:03] [0:05] [0:08]

4D 2:94 1:92 0:65 0:79 1:17 1:48

[0:15] [0:13] [0:06] [0:04] [0:09] [0:13]

Hours (total economy)

BP 1:68 0:85 0:51 0:71 0:76 1:07

[0:08] [0:04] [0:04] [0:03] [0:04] [0:07]

4D 2:56 1:47 0:57 0:69 0:89 1:30

[0:14] [0:10] [0:05] [0:03] [0:07] [0:11]

Standard errors in brackets are calculated from the variance-covariance matrix of the

second moments using the delta method. Data for the private sector are from the BLS

labor productivity and cost program (LPC) and refer to the private sector. Hours (total

economy) is an unpublished series for economy-wide hours constructed by the BLS and

used in Francis and Ramey (2008). The sample period is 1949-2007.

34

Table 3. The Rising Volatility of Wages

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

Compensation per hour (NIPA, private sector)

BP 0:71 0:99 1:38 0:30 0:88 2:93

[0:05] [0:06] [0:12] [0:02] [0:07] [0:31]

4D 1:72 1:61 0:93 0:46 0:98 2:11

[0:12] [0:11] [0:09] [0:04] [0:12] [0:32]

Compensation per hour (NIPA, total economy)

BP 0:78 0:86 1:10 0:33 0:76 2:32

[0:05] [0:05] [0:10] [0:02] [0:07] [0:24]

4D 1:85 1:57 0:85 0:50 0:95 1:92

[0:10] [0:10] [0:07] [0:03] [0:12] [0:26]

Earnings per hour (CES, private sector)

BP 1:38 0:40 0:29 0:54 0:34 0:63

[0:12] [0:02] [0:03] [0:04] [0:03] [0:07]

4D 1:85 0:97 0:52 0:52 0:56 1:08

[0:14] [0:08] [0:06] [0:05] [0:06] [0:16]

Compensation per hour (NIPA, private sector, CPI de�ator)

BP 0:83 0:99 1:20 0:35 0:89 2:54

[0:05] [0:06] [0:10] [0:02] [0:08] [0:27]

4D 1:93 1:70 0:88 0:52 1:04 1:99

[0:13] [0:12] [0:08] [0:04] [0:13] [0:30]

Standard errors in brackets are calculated from the variance-covariance matrix of the

second moments using the delta method. Wages are calculated as real compensation

per hour. Compensation and hours data for the private sector are from the BLS labor

productivity and cost program. Compensation data for NIPA compensation are com-

bined with an unpublished economy-wide series for hours constructed by the BLS and

used in Francis and Ramey (2008). Compensation from the establishment survey or

Current Employment Statistics (CES) exclude non-wage payments. The sample period

is 1949-2007 for the NIPA and 1965-2004 for the CES-based series.

35

Table 4. The Rising Volatility of Wages: Newly Hired Workers

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

Compensation per hour (NIPA, private sector)

BP 0:46 1:01 2:20 0:18 0:88 4:78

[0:06] [0:06] [0:29] [0:04] [0:08] [1:01]

4D 1:71 1:63 0:95 0:37 0:97 2:62

[0:13] [0:11] [0:10] [0:05] [0:13] [0:50]

Mean usual hourly earnings (CPS)

BP 0:49 0:54 1:10 0:20 0:47 2:39

[0:05] [0:03] [0:13] [0:04] [0:04] [0:48]

4D 1:48 1:27 0:86 0:32 0:76 2:36

[0:14] [0:11] [0:11] [0:05] [0:09] [0:46]

Mean usual hourly earnings newly hired workers (CPS)

BP 1:42 0:67 0:47 0:57 0:58 1:03

[0:16] [0:05] [0:07] [0:08] [0:05] [0:17]

4D 4:49 2:77 0:62 0:97 1:65 1:69

[0:60] [0:26] [0:10] [0:17] [0:24] [0:38]

Standard errors in brackets are calculated from the variance-covariance matrix of the

second moments using the delta method. CPS wage data are earnings per hour from the

outgoing rotation groups, which limits the period for which quarterly data are available

to after 1979. Wage series are constructed as in Haefke, Sonntag, and van Rens (2008)

but are not corrected for composition bias for comparability with other data sources.

However, keeping the composition of the labor force contant in terms of education,

experience and demographic characteristics makes very little di¤ererence for the results

presented here. The sample period is 1980-2005.

36

Table 5. Additional Business Cycle Statistics

A. Volatility output and productivity

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

Output

BP 2:37 1:12 0:47

[0:13] [0:06] [0:04]

4D 3:72 1:64 0:44

[0:18] [0:16] [0:05]

Output per worker

BP 1:36 0:81 0:60 0:57 0:72 1:26

[0:08] [0:05] [0:05] [0:03] [0:06] [0:12]

4D 2:50 1:26 0:51 0:67 0:77 1:15

[0:14] [0:08] [0:04] [0:03] [0:07] [0:13]

B. Correlations

Corr with output Corr with employment

Pre-84 Post-84 Change Pre-84 Post-84 Change

Employment (private sector)

BP 0:84 0:70 �0:14

[0:02] [0:05] [0:06]

4D 0:75 0:69 �0:06

[0:03] [0:05] [0:06]

Compensation per hour (NIPA, private sector)

BP 0:40 0:28 �0:12 0:20 �0:11 �0:31

[0:08] [0:09] [0:12] [0:09] [0:09] [0:13]

4D 0:30 0:11 �0:20 �0:02 �0:29 �0:27

[0:07] [0:07] [0:10] [0:07] [0:08] [0:11]

Standard errors in brackets are calculated from the variance-covariance matrix of the

second moments using the delta method. See tables 1, 2 and 3 for data sources. The

sample period is 1949-2007.

37

Table 6. Model Calibration

Parameter Target

Utility: � = 0:99 quarterly data

� = 1 log utility over consumption

= 1:24 frictionless employment population ratio �N = 0:7

Production: f (N) = N1��, � = 1=3 capital share

E¤ort: � = 0:299 normalization: frictionless E = 1

� = 0 normalization so that E is in utils

= 0:3 total curvature �+ is a free parameter

Frictions: � = 0:306 gross quarterly separations, Shimer (2007)

g (H) = 12�H

2 quadratic adjustment costs, Yashiv (2010)

� = 0� 1:35 frictions 0� 3% of output, Silva and Toledo (2009)

Shocks: �A = 0:97; �A = 0:186 normalization: sd(y) = 1%

�z = 0:97, �z = 0:173 sd(n) =sd(y) = 0:66

38

Table 7. Simulation results

empl/pop correlation productivity relative std.dev. std.dev.

ratio �N with output with empl empl nt wage wt output yt

Data

Pre-84 0:78 0:31 0:66 0:30

Post-84 0:60 �0:15 0:81 0:88

Model with �exible wages

frictions 3% 0:59 0:76 �0:05 0:66 0:89 1:00

frictions 2% 0:63 0:70 �0:15 0:72 0:88 0:99

frictions 1% 0:66 0:65 �0:25 0:78 0:89 1:00

frictionless 0:70 0:60 �0:31 0:84 0:86 1:02

Model with endogenous wage rigidity ( � = 1, �R = 0:95)

frictions 3% 0:59 0:74 0:13 0:66 0:71 1:00

frictions 2% 0:63 0:71 0:06 0:71 0:70 1:00

frictions 1% 0:66 0:64 �0:05 0:77 0:71 1:00

frictionless 0:70 0:66 �0:28 0:79 0:88 0:91

Moments for the model are based on simulated time series of 200; 000 quarters. We

simulate the model for 201; 000 quarters but ignore the �rst 1; 000 quarters to eliminate

the e¤ect of the initial conditions. Numbers in bold are calibration targets.

39

Figure 1. The Vanishing Procyclicality of Labor Productivity

-4-2

02

4

1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Labor productivity (bandpass filter)

Output per hour in the US private sector. Shaded areas are NBER recessions.

Figure 2. The Vanishing Procyclicality of Labor Productivity: Rolling Correlations

-.5

0.5

1

1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Correl prod with output (blue) and hours (red), cntrd 6-yr rolling window, bp

Correlations are calculated in a centered 6-year rolling window of quarterly bandpass-

�ltered data.

40

Figure 3. Endogenous Wage Rigidity: Wage Rule

� = 1 (quadratic)

-0.8 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.80.8

0.85

0.9

0.95

1

1.05

� = 2 (quartic)

-0.8 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.80.8

0.85

0.9

0.95

1

1.05

Wage rigidity Rt as a function of the relative distance of the wage from the center of

the bargaining set (Wt �W�

t ) =12

WUBt �WLB

t

, see equation (23). The red diamonds

represent the theoretical non-linear relation. The blue circles are simulated data from a

second-order approximation of the model. In these graphs, frictions are set to 0:3% of

output.

41

Figure 4. Endogenous Wage Rigity: Simulated Wage Data

Large frictions (1% of output)

0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500

-0.55

-0.5

-0.45

-0.4

-0.35

-0.3

Small frictions (0:2% of output)

0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500

-0.55

-0.5

-0.45

-0.4

-0.35

-0.3

Simulated wage paths for the model with large frictions and small frictions. In this

calibration, the wage is more volatile if frictions are smaller.

42

B Additional tables and �gures (not for publication)

Extended Table 1. The Vanishing Procyclicality of Labor Productivity

Output per hour

Pre-84 Post-84 Change Pre-84 Post-84 Change Pre-84 Post-84 Change

1949 - 2007 BP 0.60 0.25 -0.35 0.09 -0.47 -0.56 0.19 -0.40 -0.59

[0.06] [0.07] [0.09] [0.09] [0.07] [0.12] [0.09] [0.07] [0.11]

HP 0.61 0.04 -0.57 0.07 -0.60 -0.67 0.17 -0.56 -0.73

[0.05] [0.09] [0.10] [0.08] [0.06] [0.10] [0.08] [0.07] [0.10]

4D 0.62 0.18 -0.44 -0.03 -0.53 -0.51 0.09 -0.54 -0.62

[0.05] [0.09] [0.10] [0.08] [0.08] [0.11] [0.07] [0.08] [0.11]

1965 - 2004 BP 0.65 0.29 -0.36 0.16 -0.44 -0.60 0.28 -0.36 -0.63

[0.07] [0.07] [0.10] [0.13] [0.08] [0.15] [0.12] [0.08] [0.15]

HP 0.64 0.04 -0.60 0.11 -0.59 -0.70 0.23 -0.54 -0.77

[0.06] [0.09] [0.11] [0.10] [0.07] [0.12] [0.10] [0.07] [0.12]

4D 0.62 0.12 -0.50 -0.01 -0.56 -0.55 0.11 -0.54 -0.65

[0.07] [0.09] [0.12] [0.10] [0.08] [0.13] [0.10] [0.09] [0.13]

1975 - 1994 BP 0.78 0.34 -0.45 0.52 -0.39 -0.92 0.61 -0.36 -0.98

[0.05] [0.09] [0.11] [0.09] [0.11] [0.15] [0.08] [0.11] [0.13]

HP 0.66 -0.01 -0.68 0.26 -0.65 -0.91 0.39 -0.60 -0.99

[0.08] [0.14] [0.17] [0.13] [0.08] [0.15] [0.12] [0.09] [0.15]

4D 0.54 0.20 -0.33 -0.03 -0.51 -0.48 0.08 -0.52 -0.60

[0.11] [0.11] [0.16] [0.14] [0.14] [0.20] [0.14] [0.14] [0.20]

Correlation with Output Correlation with Empl. Correlation with Hours

Output per worker

Pre-84 Post-84 Change Pre-84 Post-84 Change Pre-84 Post-84 Change

1949 - 2007 BP 0.78 0.60 -0.18 0.31 -0.15 -0.47 0.44 0.01 -0.43

[0.04] [0.05] [0.06] [0.08] [0.10] [0.13] [0.07] [0.10] [0.12]

HP 0.77 0.40 -0.37 0.25 -0.32 -0.57 0.40 -0.18 -0.58

[0.03] [0.08] [0.09] [0.07] [0.09] [0.11] [0.07] [0.10] [0.12]

4D 0.76 0.46 -0.30 0.13 -0.33 -0.46 0.30 -0.21 -0.51

[0.03] [0.09] [0.09] [0.08] [0.11] [0.14] [0.07] [0.12] [0.14]

1965 - 2004 BP 0.78 0.63 -0.15 0.33 -0.13 -0.46 0.47 0.06 -0.41

[0.05] [0.05] [0.07] [0.11] [0.10] [0.15] [0.10] [0.10] [0.14]

HP 0.76 0.41 -0.35 0.25 -0.31 -0.55 0.41 -0.15 -0.56

[0.04] [0.08] [0.09] [0.09] [0.09] [0.13] [0.08] [0.11] [0.14]

4D 0.75 0.43 -0.31 0.12 -0.33 -0.45 0.30 -0.20 -0.50

[0.04] [0.09] [0.10] [0.10] [0.12] [0.15] [0.09] [0.12] [0.15]

1975 - 1994 BP 0.86 0.70 -0.16 0.62 -0.03 -0.65 0.73 0.10 -0.63

[0.03] [0.05] [0.06] [0.07] [0.16] [0.18] [0.06] [0.15] [0.16]

HP 0.74 0.36 -0.38 0.35 -0.38 -0.73 0.50 -0.22 -0.72

[0.06] [0.13] [0.15] [0.11] [0.12] [0.16] [0.10] [0.15] [0.17]

4D 0.69 0.49 -0.19 0.13 -0.30 -0.43 0.28 -0.18 -0.46

[0.08] [0.12] [0.14] [0.13] [0.19] [0.23] [0.12] [0.19] [0.23]

Correlation with HoursCorrelation with Output Correlation with Empl.

Standard errors in brackets are calculated from the variance-covariance matrix of the

second moments using the delta method. Data for the private sector are from the BLS

labor productivity and cost program (LPC) and refer to the private sector.

43

Extended Table 2. The Rising Volatility of Labor Input

Employment (private sector)

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

1949 - 2007 BP 1.57 0.91 0.58 0.66 0.81 1.23

[0.08] [0.05] [0.04] [0.03] [0.05] [0.09]

HP 1.62 1.16 0.72 0.66 0.97 1.47

[0.08] [0.07] [0.06] [0.03] [0.06] [0.12]

4D 2.44 1.54 0.63 0.66 0.94 1.43

[0.13] [0.12] [0.06] [0.03] [0.08] [0.15]

1975 - 1994 BP 1.71 0.83 0.49 0.65 0.71 1.11

[0.13] [0.07] [0.06] [0.04] [0.06] [0.11]

HP 2.10 1.27 0.60 0.71 1.01 1.41

[0.15] [0.11] [0.07] [0.05] [0.10] [0.17]

4D 2.94 1.60 0.54 0.73 0.91 1.24

[0.20] [0.13] [0.06] [0.06] [0.12] [0.20]

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Hours (private sector)

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

1949 - 2007 BP 1.93 1.18 0.61 0.81 1.06 1.30

[0.09] [0.06] [0.04] [0.03] [0.05] [0.08]

HP 1.96 1.44 0.73 0.80 1.20 1.50

[0.10] [0.08] [0.05] [0.03] [0.07] [0.10]

4D 2.94 1.92 0.65 0.79 1.17 1.48

[0.15] [0.13] [0.06] [0.04] [0.09] [0.13]

1975 - 1994 BP 2.08 1.18 0.57 0.79 1.01 1.28

[0.15] [0.09] [0.06] [0.03] [0.07] [0.10]

HP 2.40 1.58 0.66 0.81 1.25 1.54

[0.19] [0.13] [0.08] [0.04] [0.11] [0.15]

4D 3.39 2.01 0.59 0.85 1.15 1.36

[0.27] [0.15] [0.07] [0.06] [0.14] [0.20]

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Hours (total economy)

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

1949 - 2007 BP 1.68 0.85 0.51 0.71 0.76 1.07

[0.08] [0.04] [0.04] [0.03] [0.04] [0.07]

HP 1.71 1.06 0.62 0.70 0.89 1.27

[0.09] [0.07] [0.05] [0.03] [0.05] [0.09]

4D 2.56 1.47 0.57 0.69 0.89 1.30

[0.14] [0.10] [0.05] [0.03] [0.07] [0.11]

1975 - 1994 BP 1.63 0.94 0.58 0.62 0.81 1.31

[0.11] [0.06] [0.06] [0.03] [0.06] [0.11]

HP 1.98 1.22 0.61 0.67 0.97 1.44

[0.15] [0.10] [0.07] [0.03] [0.09] [0.15]

4D 2.67 1.54 0.58 0.67 0.88 1.32

[0.20] [0.11] [0.06] [0.05] [0.11] [0.19]

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Standard errors in brackets are calculated from the variance-covariance matrix of the

second moments using the delta method. Data for the private sector are from the BLS

labor productivity and cost program (LPC) and refer to the private sector. Hours (total

economy) is an unpublished series for economy-wide hours constructed by the BLS and

used in Francis and Ramey (2008).

44

Extended Table 3. The Rising Volatility of Wages

Compensation per hour (NIPA, private sector)

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

1949 - 2007 BP 0.71 0.99 1.38 0.30 0.88 2.93

[0.05] [0.06] [0.12] [0.02] [0.07] [0.31]

HP 0.85 1.03 1.21 0.35 0.86 2.48

[0.06] [0.06] [0.11] [0.03] [0.08] [0.29]

4D 1.72 1.61 0.93 0.46 0.98 2.11

[0.12] [0.11] [0.09] [0.04] [0.12] [0.32]

1965 - 2004 BP 0.73 1.03 1.42 0.29 0.89 3.09

[0.07] [0.06] [0.16] [0.02] [0.08] [0.35]

HP 0.80 1.07 1.35 0.31 0.86 2.80

[0.06] [0.07] [0.14] [0.03] [0.08] [0.37]

4D 1.43 1.64 1.15 0.40 0.96 2.39

[0.10] [0.12] [0.11] [0.03] [0.13] [0.38]

1975 - 1994 BP 0.65 1.22 1.86 0.25 1.04 4.22

[0.07] [0.08] [0.24] [0.02] [0.13] [0.67]

HP 0.76 1.12 1.46 0.26 0.89 3.43

[0.08] [0.09] [0.18] [0.03] [0.10] [0.60]

4D 1.42 1.75 1.24 0.35 1.00 2.82

[0.11] [0.17] [0.15] [0.04] [0.21] [0.68]

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Compensation per hour (NIPA, total economy)

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

1949 - 2007 BP 0.78 0.86 1.10 0.33 0.76 2.32

[0.05] [0.05] [0.10] [0.02] [0.07] [0.24]

HP 0.84 0.95 1.14 0.34 0.80 2.33

[0.05] [0.08] [0.11] [0.02] [0.09] [0.30]

4D 1.85 1.57 0.85 0.50 0.95 1.92

[0.10] [0.10] [0.07] [0.03] [0.12] [0.26]

1965 - 2004 BP 0.84 0.91 1.09 0.33 0.78 2.36

[0.08] [0.05] [0.12] [0.02] [0.07] [0.27]

HP 0.86 0.99 1.14 0.33 0.79 2.37

[0.08] [0.08] [0.14] [0.03] [0.09] [0.35]

4D 1.67 1.59 0.95 0.47 0.92 1.98

[0.11] [0.11] [0.09] [0.04] [0.12] [0.30]

1975 - 1994 BP 0.78 1.08 1.39 0.29 0.93 3.15

[0.10] [0.07] [0.20] [0.03] [0.11] [0.52]

HP 0.81 1.09 1.34 0.28 0.86 3.14

[0.08] [0.13] [0.20] [0.03] [0.14] [0.62]

4D 1.68 1.86 1.11 0.42 1.06 2.53

[0.14] [0.17] [0.14] [0.05] [0.21] [0.58]

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

continued on next page ...

45

Earnings per hour (CES, private sector)

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

1965 - 2004 BP 1.38 0.40 0.29 0.54 0.34 0.63

[0.12] [0.02] [0.03] [0.04] [0.03] [0.07]

HP 1.27 0.46 0.36 0.49 0.37 0.75

[0.11] [0.03] [0.04] [0.05] [0.04] [0.10]

4D 1.85 0.97 0.52 0.52 0.56 1.08

[0.14] [0.08] [0.06] [0.05] [0.06] [0.16]

1975 - 1994 BP 1.32 0.36 0.27 0.50 0.30 0.61

[0.15] [0.04] [0.04] [0.05] [0.04] [0.11]

HP 1.21 0.35 0.29 0.41 0.27 0.67

[0.14] [0.05] [0.05] [0.05] [0.04] [0.13]

4D 1.63 0.82 0.50 0.41 0.47 1.14

[0.19] [0.10] [0.08] [0.05] [0.07] [0.23]

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Compensation per hour (NIPA, private sector, output de�ator)

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

1949 - 2007 BP 0.67 0.95 1.42 0.28 0.85 3.02

[0.04] [0.07] [0.13] [0.02] [0.08] [0.34]

HP 0.82 1.06 1.30 0.33 0.89 2.65

[0.06] [0.07] [0.12] [0.03] [0.08] [0.32]

4D 1.48 1.65 1.11 0.40 1.00 2.51

[0.11] [0.11] [0.11] [0.04] [0.13] [0.39]

1975 - 1994 BP 0.62 1.22 1.97 0.23 1.04 4.47

[0.08] [0.10] [0.29] [0.03] [0.14] [0.80]

HP 0.70 1.10 1.57 0.24 0.88 3.68

[0.09] [0.10] [0.23] [0.04] [0.11] [0.70]

4D 1.26 1.69 1.34 0.32 0.96 3.05

[0.09] [0.18] [0.17] [0.04] [0.21] [0.74]

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Compensation per hour (NIPA, private sector, CPI de�ator)

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

1949 - 2007 BP 0.83 0.99 1.20 0.35 0.89 2.54

[0.05] [0.06] [0.10] [0.02] [0.08] [0.27]

HP 0.96 1.04 1.08 0.39 0.87 2.21

[0.06] [0.06] [0.09] [0.03] [0.08] [0.26]

4D 1.93 1.70 0.88 0.52 1.04 1.99

[0.13] [0.12] [0.08] [0.04] [0.13] [0.30]

1975 - 1994 BP 1.00 1.19 1.19 0.38 1.02 2.68

[0.09] [0.09] [0.13] [0.04] [0.13] [0.44]

HP 1.16 1.14 0.98 0.39 0.90 2.30

[0.09] [0.09] [0.11] [0.05] [0.11] [0.40]

4D 2.01 1.94 0.96 0.50 1.10 2.20

[0.24] [0.19] [0.15] [0.07] [0.23] [0.56]

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Standard errors in brackets are calculated from the variance-covariance matrix of the

second moments using the delta method. Wages are calculated as real compensation per

hour. Compensation and hours data for the private sector are from the BLS labor pro-

ductivity and cost program. Compensation data for NIPA compensation are combined

with an unpublished economy-wide series for hours constructed by the BLS and used

in Francis and Ramey (2008). Compensation from the establishment survey or Current

Employment Statistics (CES) exclude non-wage payments.

46

Extended Table 4. The Rising Volatility of Wages: Newly Hired Workers

Compensation per hour (NIPA, private sector)

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

1980 - 2005 BP 0.46 1.01 2.20 0.18 0.88 4.78

[0.06] [0.06] [0.29] [0.04] [0.08] [1.01]

HP 0.59 1.05 1.78 0.20 0.86 4.22

[0.08] [0.07] [0.27] [0.05] [0.08] [1.09]

4D 1.71 1.63 0.95 0.37 0.97 2.62

[0.13] [0.11] [0.10] [0.05] [0.13] [0.50]

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Usual hourly earnings (CPS)

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

Median BP 0.54 0.93 1.73 0.22 0.81 3.77

[0.08] [0.08] [0.28] [0.03] [0.08] [0.60]

HP 0.78 1.14 1.46 0.27 0.93 3.46

[0.14] [0.10] [0.28] [0.06] [0.10] [0.84]

4D 1.59 1.75 1.10 0.35 1.04 3.02

[0.28] [0.12] [0.21] [0.07] [0.08] [0.65]

Mean BP 0.49 0.54 1.10 0.20 0.47 2.39

[0.05] [0.03] [0.13] [0.04] [0.04] [0.48]

HP 0.66 0.83 1.27 0.23 0.68 3.02

[0.11] [0.06] [0.24] [0.05] [0.07] [0.78]

4D 1.48 1.27 0.86 0.32 0.76 2.36

[0.14] [0.11] [0.11] [0.05] [0.09] [0.46]

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Usual hourly earnings newly hired workers (CPS)

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

Median BP 1.96 1.09 0.56 0.79 0.95 1.21

[0.25] [0.08] [0.08] [0.09] [0.10] [0.19]

HP 5.08 2.94 0.58 1.75 2.40 1.37

[0.73] [0.24] [0.10] [0.35] [0.25] [0.31]

4D 5.67 3.40 0.60 1.23 2.02 1.65

[0.63] [0.27] [0.08] [0.18] [0.25] [0.31]

Mean BP 1.42 0.67 0.47 0.57 0.58 1.03

[0.16] [0.05] [0.07] [0.08] [0.05] [0.17]

HP 3.54 2.31 0.65 1.22 1.88 1.54

[0.47] [0.18] [0.10] [0.25] [0.18] [0.35]

4D 4.49 2.77 0.62 0.97 1.65 1.69

[0.60] [0.26] [0.10] [0.17] [0.24] [0.38]

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Standard errors in brackets are calculated from the variance-covariance matrix of the

second moments using the delta method. CPS wage data are earnings per hour from the

outgoing rotation groups, which limits the period for which quarterly data are available

to after 1980. Wage series are constructed as in Haefke, Sonntag, and van Rens (2008)

but are not corrected for composition bias for comparability with other data sources.

However, keeping the composition of the labor force contant in terms of education,

experience and demographic characteristics makes very little di¤ererence for the results

presented here.

47

Extended Table 5. Additional Business Cycle Statistics

Volatility output and productivity (1949-2007)

Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio Pre-84 Post-84 Ratio

Output BP 2.37 1.12 0.47

[0.13] [0.06] [0.04]

HP 2.45 1.20 0.49

[0.13] [0.07] [0.04]

4D 3.72 1.64 0.44

[0.18] [0.16] [0.05]

/worker BP 1.36 0.81 0.60 0.57 0.72 1.26

[0.08] [0.05] [0.05] [0.03] [0.06] [0.12]

HP 1.48 0.85 0.58 0.60 0.71 1.18

[0.08] [0.06] [0.05] [0.03] [0.06] [0.12]

4D 2.50 1.26 0.51 0.67 0.77 1.15

[0.14] [0.08] [0.04] [0.03] [0.07] [0.13]

/hour BP 1.06 0.75 0.71 0.45 0.67 1.51

[0.06] [0.06] [0.07] [0.03] [0.07] [0.18]

HP 1.17 0.85 0.72 0.48 0.71 1.48

[0.07] [0.06] [0.07] [0.03] [0.07] [0.18]

4D 2.04 1.32 0.64 0.55 0.80 1.46

[0.13] [0.08] [0.06] [0.03] [0.09] [0.19]

Std. Dev. Relative Std. Dev.

Correlations (1949-2007)

Pre-84 Post-84 Change Pre-84 Post-84 Change Pre-84 Post-84 Change

Employment BP 0.84 0.70 -0.14

[0.02] [0.05] [0.06]

HP 0.81 0.74 -0.07

[0.03] [0.04] [0.05]

4D 0.75 0.69 -0.06

[0.03] [0.05] [0.06]

Hours BP 0.90 0.79 -0.11

[0.02] [0.04] [0.04]

HP 0.88 0.81 -0.07

[0.02] [0.03] [0.04]

4D 0.84 0.74 -0.10

[0.02] [0.05] [0.05]

Wage BP 0.40 0.28 -0.12 0.20 -0.11 -0.31 0.22 -0.09 -0.31

[0.08] [0.09] [0.12] [0.09] [0.09] [0.13] [0.09] [0.10] [0.14]

HP 0.37 -0.01 -0.38 0.23 -0.31 -0.54 0.21 -0.31 -0.52

[0.08] [0.10] [0.12] [0.09] [0.10] [0.14] [0.09] [0.10] [0.14]

4D 0.30 0.11 -0.20 -0.02 -0.29 -0.27 0.01 -0.36 -0.36

[0.07] [0.07] [0.10] [0.07] [0.08] [0.11] [0.07] [0.08] [0.11]

Correlation with Output Correlation with Empl. Correlation with Hours

Standard errors in brackets are calculated from the variance-covariance matrix of the

second moments using the delta method. See tables 1, 2 and 3 for data sources.

48

Figure 5. The Rise of Temporary Help Services

Source: Estevão and Lach (1999)

Figure 6. The Decline of Unions

Source: Farber and Western (2002)

49