subsidiary role and skilled labour effects in small developed countries

16
RESEARCH ARTICLE Abstract and Key Results: 0 This paper considers the proportion of skilled labour employed by subsidiaries in small coun- tries in the context of the strategic role of subsidiaries. Strategic role is connected to auto- nomy and intra-organisational relationships and the mandates given to the subsidiary. In the paper, we draw on the literature on the strategic development of multinational corporations, and insights from inward foreign direct investments in small developed countries. This is presented in a unifying framework in order to predict diverse categorizations of the impact of subsidiary role on the proportion of their employment of skilled labour. 0 The paper derives two propositions that postulate interactions between three roles containing different levels of autonomy and intra-organisational relationships in small developed coun- tries that lead to different proportions of skilled labour in subsidiaries. 0 We predict the highest proportion of skilled labour by subsidiaries located in small developed countries in the case of world mandates when autonomous-based operations are emphasized. When there is an emphasis on intra-organizational relationships, measured by product flows and integrated international value-chain configurations, we predict the proportion of skilled labour to be highest in the cases of specialized contributors. We propose the proportion of skilled labour to be lowest in the case of local implementers. Keywords: Subsidiary Roles · Small Developed Countries · Employment · Skilled Labour · Autonomy · Intra-Organisational Relationships MIR (2009) 49:27–42 DOI 10.1007/s11575-008-0123-8 Subsidiary Role and Skilled Labour Effects in Small Developed Countries Jens Gammelgaard · Frank McDonald · Heinz Tüselmann · Christoph Dörrenbächer · Andreas Stephan Received: 01.02.2008 / Revised: 01.04.2008 / Accepted: 01.05.2008 © Gabler-Verlag 2009 Associate Professor J. Gammelgaard () Department of International Economics and Management, Copenhagen Business School, Copenhagen, Denmark. Professor F. McDonald Bradford Centre in International Business, Bradford University School of Management, Bradford, United Kingdom. Professor H. Tüselmann Centre of International Business and Innovation, Manchester Metropolitan University, Manchester, United Kingdom. Assistant Professor C. Dörrenbächer Department of International Business and Management, University of Groningen, Groningen, Netherlands. Associate Professor A. Stephan Jönköping International Business School, Jönköping University, Jönköping, Sweden.

Upload: independent

Post on 14-May-2023

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

ReseaRch aRticle

Abstract and Key Results:0 this paper considers the proportion of skilled labour employed by subsidiaries in small coun-

tries in the context of the strategic role of subsidiaries. strategic role is connected to auto-nomy and intra-organisational relationships and the mandates given to the subsidiary. in the paper, we draw on the literature on the strategic development of multinational corporations, and insights from inward foreign direct investments in small developed countries. this is presented in a unifying framework in order to predict diverse categorizations of the impact of subsidiary role on the proportion of their employment of skilled labour.

0 the paper derives two propositions that postulate interactions between three roles containing different levels of autonomy and intra-organisational relationships in small developed coun-tries that lead to different proportions of skilled labour in subsidiaries.

0 We predict the highest proportion of skilled labour by subsidiaries located in small developed countries in the case of world mandates when autonomous-based operations are emphasized. When there is an emphasis on intra-organizational relationships, measured by product flows and integrated international value-chain configurations, we predict the proportion of skilled labour to be highest in the cases of specialized contributors. We propose the proportion of skilled labour to be lowest in the case of local implementers.

Keywords: subsidiary Roles · small Developed countries · employment · skilled labour · autonomy · intra-Organisational Relationships

MiR (2009) 49:27–42DOi 10.1007/s11575-008-0123-8

Subsidiary Role and Skilled Labour Effects in Small Developed Countries

Jens Gammelgaard · Frank McDonald · Heinz Tüselmann · Christoph Dörrenbächer · Andreas Stephan

Received: 01.02.2008 / Revised: 01.04.2008 / Accepted: 01.05.2008© Gabler-Verlag 2009

associate Professor J. Gammelgaard ()Department of international economics and Management, copenhagen Business school, copenhagen, Denmark.

Professor F. McDonaldBradford centre in international Business, Bradford University school of Management, Bradford, United Kingdom.

Professor h. tüselmanncentre of international Business and innovation, Manchester Metropolitan University, Manchester, United Kingdom.

assistant Professor c. DörrenbächerDepartment of international Business and Management, University of Groningen, Groningen, Netherlands.

associate Professor a. stephanJönköping international Business school, Jönköping University, Jönköping, sweden.

28 J. Gammelgaard et al.

Introduction

studies of the strategic objectives of the multinational corporation (MNc) have been associated to themes such as role categorizations (White/Poynter 1984, Birkinshaw/Mor-rison 1995) autonomy (luo 2006) organizational relationships (holm/holmström/sharma 2005, Mu/Gnyawali/Hatfield 2007) and competence (Moore 2001, Cantwell/Mudambi 2005 ). These studies offer important insights into the configurations of MNC and role of subsidiaries, but do not directly investigate the composition of skilled labour employed in subsidiaries. Furthermore, subsidiary role has not been extensively examined in the context of small countries. this paper conceptualizes the effects of inward foreign direct investments (FDi) into small developed countries in relation to subsidiary role and the consequent impact on their demand for skilled labour.

The growth of international trade and investment flows and the subsequent changes in the employment of labour has called into question whether the globalisation process leads to beneficial outcomes for labour (Gray 1998, Bakan 2004, Stiglitz 2006). In developed countries there is a fear of a loss of jobs as MNcs engage in FDi that is thought to lead to a transfer of employment from developed to developing countries (Giddens 2004, Dobbs 2004). there has arisen a popular opinion that MNcs are creating major problems for employment in developed economies. Managers of parent companies and also in the subsidiaries of MNcs face considerable pressures to justify and defend their trade and investment policies in the face of the criticism that they are exporting jobs to developing countries. Government and regional development policy makers are also caught up in the controversy that surrounds the globalisation debate as they seek to defend employment levels in their regions in the face of the challenges arising from globalisation. small deve-loped countries may be considered to be especially vulnerable to the employment effects that arise from the present globalisation process because they lack the political power to limit the ability of MNcs to relocate to lower cost locations. small countries also lack large market size. there is likely to be a size advantage that induces MNcs, located in large countries, to retain these locations in order to benefit from the supply channels to significant markets.

there is however a debate on whether the globalisation process is stimulating an incre-ase in the demand for skilled workers in developed countries as lower value-added work is transferred to developing countries thereby creating incentives for subsidiaries in deve-loped countries to move up the value chain (Wolf 2005). in this scenario the globalisation process is stimulating a new international division of labour, which is inducing developed countries to specialise in higher valued added activities that normally require highly skil-led labour. this outcome is crucially dependent on the strategic development of subsidia-ries in ways that permit them to move up the value chain and thereby to demand a higher proportion of skilled labour.

there is an extensive literature on the employment effects of FDi (Barrell/Pain 1997, Driffield 2006), but most of the studies focus on the spillover employment effects of investments rather than the direct employment effects of the strategic development of MNcs and their subsidiaries. the strategic development of MNcs should lead to the cre-ation of skilled jobs in areas that are connected to the competitive advantages that exist and are being developed in the various host locations of MNcs. in developed countries,

29subsidiary Role and skilled labour effects

given the relatively high cost of labour, this will tend to increase the demand for skilled labour in order to obtain high productivity to compensate for high wage and non-wage costs. the ability of subsidiaries to increase employment of skilled labour is likely to be associated with the level of autonomy and intra-organisational relationships because subsidiaries need to be able to develop competencies that permit them to increase their use of skilled labour. therefore, the globalisation process should stimulate demand for the employment of a higher proportion of skilled labour by subsidiaries. there are only few studies on the links between the strategy of subsidiaries and their employment of skilled labour (e.g., McDonald et al. 2005). Further, there is also a lack of developed conceptual models that link the role of subsidiaries to their direct employment of skilled labour. Using a framework proposed by Birkinshaw and Morrison (1995) this paper develops a conceptual model that considers the links between the demand for skilled labour by sub-sidiaries in small developed countries, and the strategic role of such entities.

the paper is structured in the following way. First, the debate on inward FDi in small developed countries is outlined. this is followed by a section outlining the major existing literature on the role of subsidiaries, with a focus on small developed countries. the next sections develop a conceptual model and derive propositions on the relationships between the proportion of skilled labour employed by subsidiaries in small developed countries and the ‘local implementer’, ‘specialized contributor’ and ‘world mandate’ types of subsi-diaries. the paper concludes with consideration of some of the implications of the model for the managers of parent companies, subsidiary managers and regional development policy makers.

Definitions of Small Countries and Skills

this paper investigates FDi and subsidiary developments in small developed countries, such as, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, ireland, and New Zealand. a small country is defined by the size of gross domestic product (GDP), which is a proxy for the quantity of labour, capital assets, and natural resources bases, whereas the level of development is estimated by GDP per capita which is a estimate of social infrastructures such as life expectancy, percentage of urban population, and education levels (allred/steensma 2005). thus small developed countries have relatively small GDP but high GDP per capita. In defining skil-led labour we follow the logic of Nelson and Winter (1982) in regarding skills as a “capa-bility” and exemplify this as “the ability to serve a tennis ball well” (Nelson/Winter 1982, p. 73). skills would, using this line of argumentation, relate to the ability or cleverness of an employee executing a specific task, or at an aggregated level the skills of the organiza-tion, often represented by best practices or routines.

FDI Inflows into Small Developed Countries

Most theories of FDi suggest that the size of countries is an important determinant of FDi inflows because of host location advantages and from the large size of domestic markets that are available in large countries. These benefits lead to abilities to generate economies

30 J. Gammelgaard et al.

of size and scope in production, and sales and distribution activities (Buckley/casson 1976). however, FDi can also be driven by resource seeking motives to gain access to pools of assets that can help promote innovation and learning. in this context, a study of Nordic manufacturing companies found that there was a significant transfer of knowledge intensive operations to eU countries from those Nordic countries that were not members of the eU (Oxelheim/Gartner 1994). Denmark, the only eU member at that time, did not experience an increase in FDi of this type from the other Nordic countries. this was taken to indicate that the benefits of the size of some EU countries had enabled them to attract this FDi, rather than Denmark, because they had more desirable resources in terms of both the width and depth of their resource base.

the development of regional blocs such as NaFta and the eU should expand both market and resource seeking motives for FDI, because it provides, for those firms inside the bloc, a larger market and access to a larger pool of resources. however, evidence is mixed on whether FDI inflows can be enhanced by increasing the economic size of countries by developing regional economic integration policies in blocs such as the eU and NaFta (Buckley et al. 2001). this study found that the creation and development of NaFta had a positive, but small, effect, and no clear evidence of this effect was found for the eU. Market size has also been found to be an important driver of research and development (R&D) focused FDI inflows, but the presence of desirable resources was also found to have an important positive effect on such flows (Kuemmerle 1999). The evi-dence suggests that large countries are likely to have host location advantages that induce FDI flows, but the presence of desirable resources in host locations can also provide cost and quality advantages that are attractive for FDi. this evidence implies that although small countries will often lack strong incentives to attract market seeking FDi, they could be powerful magnets for resource seeking FDi if they have pools of desirable resources or good potential to develop existing, or to create new, reservoirs of attractive assets.

there is evidence that the presence of desirable resources in small developed countries can be very attractive for FDi that is resource seeking. the case of ireland demonstrates how a small country can attract FDi because of its stock of desirable resources and its abi-lity to develop this stock (Barry/Kearney 2006). this study found that FDi had also con-tributed to diversifying the industrial structure of ireland, especially in high technology sectors, and had help to make industry growth paths more stable. thus, in ireland FDi has helped to create a virtuous cycle of further improving the pool of desirable resources, thereby attracting more FDi. a resource enhancing aspect of FDi into small countries was also found in a study of FDi in hungary. the study found that the marketing competen-cies of domestic firms were significantly enhanced by the FDI in their firms (Hooley et al. 1996). the creation and effective evolution of government policies to develop skilled labour and to enhance the quantity and quality of physical and social infrastructures, toge-ther with the ability of subsidiary managers to effectively access these resources has also been found to be important for developing FDi in small countries (Barclay/Gray 2001, hood/taggart 1997).

Market seeking FDi can also be attracted to small countries if they are members of effective regional economic integration blocs. a study of irish subsidiaries by egelhoff, Gorman, and Mccormick (2000) found that FDi had considerably boosted irish exports to EU countries. This implication was reinforced by the significant number of Irish sub-

31subsidiary Role and skilled labour effects

sidiaries that appeared to operate under regional rather than multi-domestic strategies. this study also found that large subsidiaries were more likely to export widely, as where the subsidiaries with UK, Dutch, and Us parent companies and that the ability of foreign owned subsidiaries to exploit desirable resources in their home base was linked to their export performance. thus small countries that are members of regional economic integra-tion blocs and that have attractive location characteristics may attract FDi that requires large markets.

the literature on FDi into small developed countries indicates that the attractiveness of small countries is connected to the ability of foreign owned subsidiaries to be able to find and develop pools of desirable resources in host locations and to compensate for small size by developing strong export markets for goods and services. clearly, the drivers of the strategic development of foreign owned subsidiaries to enable them to deliver these benefits to their parent companies is an important factor for the ability of small develo-ped countries to attract, retain and develop their FDI inflows. Although there is limited evidence on some of the characteristics of subsidiaries in small developed countries that seem to be conducive to such developments, there is no clear conceptual framework of the drivers of the type of strategic roles of subsidiaries that is conducive to enhancing the attractiveness and effectiveness of FDi into small countries. this paper provides such a conceptual framework by investigating subsidiary role in small developed countries.

Subsidiary Roles in Small Developed Countries

subsidiary roles have been heavily researched and surveyed since White and Poynters (1984) investigation into subsidiaries located in canada. however, there are only a few studies on this area from small developed countries. scotland has been the point of depar-ture for some of these surveys. Birkinshaw, hood, and Young (2005) surveyed 24 manuf-acturing subsidiaries in relation to internal (within MNc) and external (host country) competitive pressures. half of the sample experienced only internal competition, and such subsidiaries were typically given low autonomy, and faced restrictions in value-chain operation. Further, these subsidiaries were subject to challenges on labour costs from those subsidiaries located in low-wage host locations. subsidiaries facing either external and internal, or only external, competition were in contrast given high autonomy, and operated within a broad range of the value-chain. earlier, Young, hood, and Dun-lop (1988) sampled 129 scottish subsidiaries and found that the largest group of those were rationalized manufacturers, possessing very low autonomy, employing fewer than 200 people and typically controlled by an american MNc. in addition, siler, Wang, and liu (2003) also surveyed scottish subsidiaries, though not looking at role, but on labour productivity, which was impacted by the R&D activity of their Us parent company, and subsidiary development of human capital.

ireland has also been surveyed; among others by egelhoff, Gorman, and Mccor-mick (1998) who investigated subsidiary development of technology-based advantages and found it typically was an outcome of backward-integrating the subsidiary into pro-cess technology developments. Delany (1998) investigated subsidiary development but departed from the White and Poynter (1984) typology and found most cases were

32 J. Gammelgaard et al.

‘rationalized operators’ (i.e., rationalized manufacturers with addition of activities such as software- and product developments). Furthermore, coughlan and Brady (1996) inves-tigated a broadened mandate of four subsidiaries as a result of developments in product skills, and the establishments of linkages to parent company’ managers. comparing Por-tuguese and irish subsidiaries, tavares (2002) discovered the rationalized manufacturer to be the most common type. in the irish case she, further, discovered an increase towards more autonomous based subsidiaries, especially in relation to decisions concerning technology.

surveys focused on the scandinavian context by Forsgren and Pedersen (1998) inves-tigated characteristics of Danish located product mandate subsidiaries but found mixed results in the ratio of internal and external embeddedness – though 17 percent were able to establish intensive and dual relationships. swedish located subsidiaries were investi-gated by Birkinshaw (1998) who revealed that the level of communication with parent company was highest in the case of acquired sales subsidiaries, whereas the level of subsidiary autonomy was highest in the case of acquired manufacturing and R&D units. Finally, building on a Danish/Finnish/swedish sample, holm, holmström, and sharma (2005) concluded that the competitive environment of host country impacts subsidiary competence development in business relationships that again makes the subsidiary influ-ential in the MNc in regard to its competence development, and performance.

studies on small countries in continental europe, for example, hogenbirk and Kra-nenburg (2006) concluded that half of foreign owned subsidiaries in the Dutch electro-nics and electrical application industry used the Netherlands as an export base. soenen and Van Den Bulcke (1988) compared performance between Belgian firms and foreign owned subsidiaries in Belgium, and found the performance of american subsidiaries to be higher, due to their higher degree of multinationality and, their focus on ec-mar-kets. Greece has been investigated by Manolopoulos, Papanastassiou, and Pearce (2007), who find a high proportion of truncated miniature replica that produce products, for the Greek market, that are already established in the MNc group’s product range, and, the-refore, typically orientated R&D toward local adaptations. Outside europe, scott-Kennel (2007) analyzed New Zealand located subsidiaries and found a balanced representation of manufacturing, service-, and sales oriented affiliates – all of them having limited inter-organizational relationships.

It is difficult to draw firm conclusions on the small country effect on subsidiary role because of the mixed results that is evident in the literature. Many surveys were based on a high proportion of manufacturing or product oriented companies, though sales outlets are represented as well. Moreover, several studies report a high degree of relationships to the parent company. the consequences of these facts, though, has not been discussed and surveyed in relation to subsidiary employment, therefore, we see the need for developing propositions for subsequent research.

Conceptual Model

the two key factors that characterizes subsidiary role as suggested by Birkinshaw and Morrison (1995) are autonomy, and intra-organisational networks. the relationships

33subsidiary Role and skilled labour effects

between each of these factors and the employment of skilled labour by subsidiaries are investigated in the context of a small developed country.

subsidiary Role

the international business literature suggests that the strategic objectives of MNcs are likely to have significant implications for subsidiary role and by extension to employment and other economic factors of host locations (Young/hood/Dunlop 1988, Birkinshaw/hood 1998a, Young/tavares 2004). this paper focuses on the framework that is suggested by Birkinshaw and Morrison (1995), which identifies three types of subsidiary roles. Local Implementers are subsidiaries with limited geographic scope, typically a single country, and these subsidiaries are strongly constrained in terms of product development and/or expanding the scope of value-added activities. Specialized Contributors are sub-sidiaries with considerable expertise in certain specific functions or activities, but where their activities are tightly coordinated with the activities of other subsidiaries within the MNc. this type of subsidiary is characterized by a narrow set of value-added activities and high levels of interdependencies with affiliated subsidiaries. Finally, World Man-date subsidiaries have worldwide or regional responsibility for a product line or entire business, and they typically have unconstrained product development scope and broad value-added scope (cited from Birkinshaw/Morrison 1995, pp. 733 et seq.). autonomy is predicted to be low in cases of local implementers, medium in case of specialized contri-butors and high in case of world mandates. strong intra-organizational networks promote product dependency on parent companies, high level inter-subsidiary purchases and an integrated configuration of manufacturing, and downstream activities (distribution, sales, service, and advertising). local implementers have high degree of relationships on the product dependency and inter-subsidiary purchasing and have low value-chain configura-tion. specialized contributors have high network relationships in all areas. Finally, world mandates display low product dependency and inter-subsidiary purchases and medium value-chain network relationships.

autonomy

Autonomy has been identified as one of the most important areas of research in cases where the subsidiary is the unit of analysis (Paterson/Brock 2002) and researchers have extensively studied the process of autonomy granted to subsidiaries in host locations (Jarillo/Martinez 1990, Birkinshaw/hood 1998b). Further, the relationships between auto-nomy and knowledge creation processes have often been emphasized (Brockhoff/sch-maul 1996, taggart 1997, taggart/hood 1999, ensign/Birkinshaw/Frost 2000). clearly, autonomy plays an important role in the strategic development of subsidiaries.

The definition of autonomy used in this paper is the one provided by Brooke (1984, p. 9) where autonomy refers to an organization “in which units and sub-units possess the ability to take decisions for themselves on issues which are reserved to a higher level in comparable organizations”. This definition indicates that the subsidiary possesses some strategic decision making authority (O’Donnell 2000), though in most cases autonomy will mainly relate to its daily operations, (edwards/ahmad/Moss 2002). the extent of

34 J. Gammelgaard et al.

autonomy granted to subsidiaries is also connected to the value-chain of the subsidiary where Vachani (1999) found that subsidiary autonomy was greater for marketing and personnel decisions than for R&D and finance. Furthermore, autonomy relates to the negotiation processes between parent company and its subsidiary, showing that decisions are not necessarily exclusively made by either the parent company or the subsidiary, but rather being an outcome of a bargaining process leading to either joint decisions, or deci-sion made by one of the partner after consulting the other (taggart 1999, Dörrenbächer/Gammelgaard 2006). clearly, there are a multitude of factors that underpin the decision by MNcs to grant autonomy or to retain centralised control (Young/tavares 2004).

autonomy is often associated to the subsidiary’s ability to establish inter-organisational relationships. these local networks enhance the ability to attain collective learning and innovation benefits (Lundvall 1999) and to acquire spillover benefits associated with pro-ximity (Porter/Sölvell 1998), and advantages of tapping into clusters (Driffield/Munday 2000). cantwell and Mudambi (2005) argue that enhanced autonomy can lead to com-petence creating mandates to exploit locally available assets that increase R&D intensity and thereby induce an increased demand for skilled labour. increased effective autonomy helps subsidiary management to more successfully establish and deal with beneficial inter-organisational relationships because of a decreased need to obtain approval from the parent company (Birkinshaw/hood/Young 2005). autonomy is then predicted to extend the quality and scope of subsidiary operations, due to improved entrepreneurial capabilities and utilisation of host country localization advantages. autonomy that leads to the development of inter-organisational relationships can lead to a changed compo-sition of the labour force by increasing the value of operations by reducing transaction costs, improve learning effects and gaining access to desirable local assets. Further, entre-preneurial activities are likely to occur, where the subsidiary for example start up inde-pendent R&D projects or product development and new product development projects. these types of entrepreneurial behaviour have been found in R&D ventures (Papanast-assiou/Pearce 2005) and in areas such as product and market development (Birkinshaw 1998, Birkinshaw/hood/Young 2005). these types of entrepreneurial activities require an increased proportion of skilled labour in subsidiaries, as entrepreneurship and derived innovations typically make existing market and technical capabilities of the subsidiary increasingly obsolete (abernathy/clark 1985). this effect often requires, for example, workers from other scientific, engineering, technical and knowledge based disciplines, to fill in the resource gap that the innovations produced (Teng 2007).

Relating this discussion to predict developed small country effects, subsidiary auto-nomy buttresses both resource-seeking FDi, as autonomy closely relates to the ability of tapping into these clusters. Further, from a market-seeking point of view, autonomy maybe associated with incentives to subsidiary management to boost sales in regions or blocs. as World Mandates are given the highest level of autonomy, we predict such sub-sidiaries to have the highest proportion of skilled labour to either carry out their internati-onal activities, by for example, autonomous-based innovation, or to manage international sales relationships. specialized contributors on the other hand have lower autonomy and are therefore less likely to demand a higher proportion of skilled labour, and local imple-menters will have the lowest proportion of skilled labour. This reasoning leads to our first proposition.

35subsidiary Role and skilled labour effects

Proposition 1. in a small developed country, a subsidiary acting as a world mandate will have a higher proportion of skilled labour in order to manage autonomous-based innovation or international sales-oriented activities, than a subsidiary acting as a specia-lized contributor or a local implementer, and a specialized contributor will have a higher proportion of skilled labour than a local implementer.

intra-organisational Relationships

intra-organisational relationships are the links that the subsidiary has established with the parent company and other subsidiaries within the MNc (Birkinshaw/hood/Young 2005). intra-organisational relationships provide the means to access resources within the MNc that can increase organisational learning (lundvall 1999), access to valuable knowledge (schmid/schurig 2003, Forsgren/holm/Johanson 2005), and lower transactions costs (Birkinshaw/hood 1998a, Dunning 2000, hennart 2001). accessing technological know-ledge that enhances capabilities to innovate is often regarded as being the major benefits that arises from intra-organisational relationships (Papanastassiou/Pearce 1997, taggart 1998a, Pearce 1999, ivarsson 2002).

To obtain these benefits from intra-organisational relationships, the subsidiary needs to recruit more senior management, professional, technical, and other expertise to effec-tively managing and exploit the internal relationships within the MNc. this implies an increased proportion of skilled labour. some of these heavily integrated subsidiaries will provide goods and/or services for all or large parts of the MNC and/or service specific parts of the global markets of the MNc (holm/Pedersen 2000). such subsidiaries are likely to operate within more narrowly defined areas of specializations (Birkinshaw/Mor-rison 1995) and this specialization within high value activities, such as R&D, requires more skilled labour. in some cases, management of intra-organisational relationships will only require a minor increase in the proportion of skilled labour, for example in order to coordinate activities with parent companies. in other cases, where the level of spe-cialisation resulting from intra-organisational relationships is stronger, for example in knowledge creation and innovation processes, this is likely to lead to a higher proportion of skilled labour (e.g., technicians and associated professionals). Furthermore, skilled labour to produce additional reports, enquires and feedback to the parent company and other subsidiaries are often required for the efficient operation of MNC supply chains. To obtain these benefits from intra-organisational relationships, the subsidiary needs to expand senior management, professional, technical, and other knowledge intensive expertise, and this implies an increased proportion of skilled labour.

specialization from a manufacturing and R&D point of view is likely to correlate with small developed countries, because an economy of this size typically offers niches and have specialities in narrowly defined area. From a resource-seeking point of view, MNC can establish specialized contributors by greenfield or by acquisition of a local firm to access desirable assets and they will therefore require skilled labour to manage such operations. Furthermore, a consequence of high international configuration of value-chain activities is the need to manage the relationships with external and internal partners respectively, and to establish of cross-functional interfaces among inter and intra-orga-nisational relationships (trent/Monozka 2002). thus, a high proportion of skilled labour

36 J. Gammelgaard et al.

is needed. however, more locally sales oriented subsidiaries, like the local implementer, maybe disadvantage from being locally embedded in a small country. it might require skills to operate with particular business-to-business relationships, but employment is not directed to achieve scale and scope in international sales operations. Furthermore, interconnected flows of products with other organization units are typical one-way from the parent company, and hence the proportion of skilled labour is, therefore, suggested to be lower. Finally, world mandates are predicted to have a medium need for skilled labour, as it has to operate internationally in terms of sales, but international value-chain confi-guration is predicted to be less than for the specialized contributor. therefore, less skilled labour, compared to the case for specialized contributors, will be required to manage intra-MNc relationships. this leads to our second proposition.

Proposition 2. in a small developed country, a subsidiary acting as a specialized contributor will employ a higher proportion of skilled labour in order to manage intra-organizational relationships than a subsidiary acting as a world mandates or a local imple-menter, and a world mandate will have a higher proportion of skilled labour than a local implementer.

Conclusions

this paper postulates that the proportion of skilled labour employed by subsidiaries is influenced by the size of its host country location, and the strategic role played by this entity in the MNc. Utilizing Birkinshaw and Morrison’s (1995) framework on subsidi-ary roles we predict the proportion of skilled labour employed by a subsidiary located in a small developed country will be highest in case of world mandates that stimulates autonomous-based operations by the subsidiary. When the emphasis is on intra-organi-zational relationships based on product flows and integrated international value-chain configuration, we predict the proportion of employment of skilled labour will be highest in the cases of specialized contributors. in all cases, we predict that the proportion of employment of skilled labour will be lowest in local implementers.

the conceptual framework developed in this paper provides a structure to construct research agendas that will be useful to verify the postulated relationships that are deri-ved from the framework, and also provide evidence on the strength of these relation-ships. empirical evidence derived from the conceptual framework will provide useful information to illuminate the debate about the impact of the globalisation process on the host locations of foreign owned subsidiaries. this would help to provide regional policy makers with greater understanding on the impact of the globalisation process on national and local economies and labour markets, and to help the adjustment to the emerging international division of labour between developing and emerging economies. Identifi-cation of the conditions that are likely to attract, retain and develop FDi for specialized contributors and world mandate subsidiaries would help government and regional policy-makers to develop strategies that would appeal to and encourage the development of the type of subsidiaries that are most likely to be successful in the present era of globalisation. attracting and developing these types of subsidiaries will crucially depend on the ability of host locations in small countries to provide desirable homes for resource seeking and

37subsidiary Role and skilled labour effects

possibly market seeking FDi. in these circumstances, providing pools of attractive assets, especially appropriately skilled labour will be important. the key labour factors are likely to be skills connected to the effective creation and exploitation of locally available assets that is in accord with the overall strategic objectives of the MNc. this implies that not only scientific and technical skills will be required, but also managerial and negotiating competencies that will enable the effective management and development of complex interactions between subsidiary autonomy and intra-organisational relationships. low cost access to large markets for buying and selling goods and services by, for example, membership of regional economic integration blocs, may also be necessary to overcome barriers connected to the small size of host countries.

the model and extensions of the model together with appropriate empirical evidence would be also be helpful for parent company managers to assess the likely effect of deve-lopments in autonomy and intra-organisational relationships of their subsidiaries. even without empirical evidence from large-scale studies, the predictions can frame research on the effects on the direct employment by their subsidiaries of the strategic decisions of the parent company. this type of exercise could be helpful to develop public relations policies to counter the views, harmful to the achieving of the strategic objectives of the MNc that are often expressed by anti-globalisation activists. thus a positive spin could be placed on the role that MNcs play in helping small developed economies to adjust to the new patterns of employment that are being generated by the globalisation process. this can be painted in a positive light as MNcs with world mandate and specialised contributors subsidiaries will push them develop higher valued operations that face less competition from lower labour cost countries, and also from those emerging economies that lack the specialized assets that are available in small developed countries.

Subsidiary managers will also find these predictions useful, as it would provide guidance on some of the implications for direct employment of developing autonomy and intra-organisational relationships. this could be used to assess the possible impact of entrepreneurial activities to develop these factors and/or to help to put a case to parent companies for enhancement of autonomy and the development of organisational relation-ships. this type of analysis could help subsidiary managers to develop strategies that will allow their subsidiaries to survive, or even flourish, in the emerging international division of labour that is arising from the present globalisation process. subsidiaries in steady state and decline phases of strategic development could also use this framework for identifying where and what type of entrepreneurial action was needed to revive the status of such sub-sidiaries and move them towards higher value activities. this kind of analysis could also be used by subsidiary managers to enlist the support of government and regional policy-makers to help struggling subsidiaries to adjust to the demands of globalisation.

the model, and empirical evidence derived from it, would therefore provide useful material for small country development decision makers because it indicates likely effects for the direct employment of skilled labour in host locations of the strategic development of foreign owned subsidiaries. to be useful for these proposes evidence on whether host locations had key subsidiaries in terms of autonomy and international value-chain confi-guration is important to policy makers in order to support such subsidiaries in their further development, as both factors positively related to recruitment of skilled labour.

38 J. Gammelgaard et al.

References

abernathy, W./clark, K. B., Mapping the Winds of creative Destruction, Research Policy, 14, 3, 1985, pp. 3–22.

Allred, B. B./Steensma, H. K., The Influence of Industry and Home Country Characteristics on Firms’ Pursuit of innovation, Management International Review, 45, 4, 2005, pp. 383–412.

Bakan, J., The Corporation: The Pathological Pursuit of Profit and Power, New York: Free Press 2004.

Barclay, l./Gray, s. Upgrading the Diamond of Developing countries through FDi: the case of four MNes in information services industry in Barbados, Management International Review, 41, 4, 2001, pp. 333–356.

Barrell, R./Pain, N., Foreign Direct investment, technological change and economic Growth within europe, Economic Journal, 107, 4, 1997, pp. 1770–1786.

Barry, F./Kearney, c., MNes and industrial structure in host countries: a Portfolio analysis of irish Manufacturing, Journal of International Business Studies, 37, 3, 2006, pp. 392–406.

Birkinshaw, J., Foreing-Owned subsidiaries and Regional Development: the case of sweden, in Birkinshaw, J./hood, N. (eds.), Multinational Corporate Evolution and Subsidiary Develop-ment, Houndsmill: Macmillan Press 1998, pp. 268–297.

Birkinshaw, J./hood, N., Multinational Corporate Evolution and Subsidiary Development, hounds-mill Basingstoke: Macmillan 1998a.

Birkinshaw, J./hood, N., Multinational subsidiary Development: capability evolution and charter change in Foreign-owned subsidiary companies, Academy of Management Review, 23, 4, 1998b, pp. 773–795.

Birkinshaw, J./hood, N.,/Young, s., subsidiary entrepreneurship, internal and external compe-titive Forces, and subsidiary Performance, International Business Review, 14, 1, 2005, pp. 227–248.

Birkinshaw, J./Morrison, A. J., Configurations of Strategy and Structure in Subsidiaries of Multina-tional corporations, Journal of International Business Studies, 26, 4, 1995, pp. 729–753.

Brockhoff, K./schmaul, B., Organization, autonomy, and success of internationally Dispersed R&D Facilities’ ieee transactions of engineering Management, 43, 1, 1996, pp. 33–40.

Brooke, M. Z., Centralization and Autonomy: A Study in Organization Behaviour, london: holt, Rinehart and Winston 1984.

Buckley, P. et al., increasing the size of the ‘country’: Regional integration and Foreign investment in a Globalised World, Management International Review, 41, 3, 2001, pp. 251–274.

Buckley, P. J./Clegg, J./Tan, H., Knowledge Transfer to China: Policy Lesson from Foreign Affili-ates, Transnational Corporations, 13, 1, 2004, pp. 31–72.

Buckley, P. J./casson, M., the Future of the Multinational enterprise, london: Macmillan 1976.cantwell, J./Mudambi, R., MNe competence-creating subsidiary Mandates, Strategic Manage-

ment Journal, 26, 12, 2005, pp. 1109–1128.cohen, W. M./levinthal, D. a., absorptive capacity: a New Perspective on learning and innova-

tion, Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 1, 1990, pp. 128–152.coughlan, P./Brady, e., evolution towards integrated Product Development in subsidiaries of

Multinational enterprises, International Journal of Technology Management, 12, 7/8, 1996, pp. 733–747.

Delany, e., strategic Development of Multinational subsidiaries in ireland, in Birkinshaw, J./hood, N. (eds.), Multinational Corporate Evolution and Subsidiary Development, New York: st. Martin´s Press 1998, pp. 239-267.

Dobbs, l., Exporting America, New York: time Warner Books 2004.

39subsidiary Role and skilled labour effects

Dörrenbächer, c./Gammelgaard, J., subsidiary Role Development: the effect of Micro-politi-cal headquarters-subsidiary Negotiations on the Product, Market, and Value-added scope of Foreign Owned subsidiaries, Journal of International Management, 12, 3, 2006, pp. 266–283.

Driffield, N., The Search for Spillovers from Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) with Spatial Depen-dency, Regional Studies, 40, 1, 2006, pp. 107–119.

Driffield, N./Munday, M., Industrial Performance, Agglomeration and Foreign Manufacturing investment in the UK, Journal of International Business Studies, 31, 1, 2000, pp. 21–37.

Dunning, J., Regions, Globalisation, and the Knowledge economy: the issues stated, in Dunning, J. (ed.), Regions, Globalisation, and the Knowledge Economy, Oxford: Oxford University Press 2000.

edwards, R./ahmad, a./Moss, s., subsidiary autonomy: the case of Multinational subsidiaries in Malaysia, Journal of International Business Studies, 33, 1, 2002, pp. 183–191.

egelhoff, W. G./Gorman, l./Mccormick, s., Using technology as a Path to subsidiary Develop-ment, in Birkinshaw, J./hood, N. (eds.), Multinational Corporate Evolution and Subsidiary Development, houndsmill: Macmillan Press 1998, pp. 312–328.

Egelhoff, W. G./Gorman, L./McCormick, S. How FDI Characteristics Influence Subsidiary Trade Patterns: the case of ireland, Management International Review, 40, 3, 2000, pp. 203–236.

ensign, P./Birkinshaw, J./Frost, t., R&D centres of excellence in canada, in holm, U./Pedersen, t. (eds.), The Emergence and Impact of MNC Centres of Excellence: A Subsidiary Perspective, Basingstoke: Macmillan Press 2000.

Forsgren, M./holm, U./Johanson, J., Managing the Embedded Multinational: A Business Network View, chelterham: edward elgar 2005.

Forsgren, M./Pedersen, t., centres of excellence in Multinational companies: the case of Den-mark, in Birkinshaw, J./hood, N. (eds.), Multinational Corporate Evolution and Subsidiary Development, houndsmill: Macmillan Press 1998, pp. 141–161.

Giddens, a, Runaway World, london: Routledge 2004.Gray, J., False Dawn: The Delusions of Global Capitalism, london: Granta Publications 1998.hennart, J.-F., Theories of Multinational Enterprises, ann arbour: University of Michigan Press

2001.hogenbirk, a. e./Kranenburg, h. l. v., Roles of Foreign Owned subsidiaries in a small country,

International Business Review, 15, 1, 2006, pp. 53–67.holm, U./holmström, c./sharma, D., competence Development through Business Relationships

or competitive environment? subsidiary impact on MNc competitive advantage, Manage-ment International Review, 45, 2, 2005, pp. 197–218.

holm, U./Pedersen, t., The Emergence and Impact of MNC Centres of Excellence: A Subsidiary Perspective, houndsmill: Macmillan 2000.

hood, N./taggart, J., German Foreign Direct investment in the UK and ireland: survey evidence, Regional Studies, 31, 2, 1997, pp. 139–150.

hooley, G. et al., Foreign Direct investment in hungary: Resource acquisition and Domestic com-petitive advantage, Journal of International Business Studies, 27, 4, 1996, pp. 683–695.

ivarsson i., transnational corporations and the Geographical transfer of localised technology: a Multi-industry Study of Foreign Affiliates in Sweden, Journal of Economic Geography, 2, 2, 2002, pp. 221–243.

Jarillo, c./Martinez, J. Different Roles for subsidiaries: the case of Multinational corporations in spain, Strategic Management Journal, 11, 7, 1990, pp. 501–512.

Kuernmerle, W., the Drivers of Foreign Direct investment into Research and Development: an empirical investigation, Journal of International Business Studies, 30, 1, 1999, pp. 1–24.

lundvall, B.,technology Policy in the learning economy, in archibugi, D./howells, J./Michie, J. (eds.), Innovation Systems and Policy in a Global Economy, cambridge: cambridge Univer-sity Press 1999.

40 J. Gammelgaard et al.

luo, Y., autonomy of Foreign R&D Units in an emerging Market: an information Processing Perspective, Management International Review, 46, 3, 2006, pp. 349–378.

Manolopoulos, D./Papanastassiou, M./Pearce, R., Knowledge-related competitiveness and the Roles of Multinationals’ R&D in a Peripheral european economy: survey analysis of Greece, Management International Review, 47, 5, 2007, pp. 661–681.

McDonald, F. et al., the strategic Development of Foreign Owned subsidiaries and employment in host locations in the UK, Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 23, 6, 2005, pp. 867–882.

Moore, K., A., Strategy for Subsidiaries: Centres of Excellence to Build Subsidiary Specific Advan-tages, Management International Review, 41, 3, 2001, pp. 275–292.

Mu, S. C./Gnyawali, D. R./Hatfield, D. E., Foreign Subsidiaries’ Learning from Local Environ-ments: an empirical test, Management International Review, 47, 1, 2007, pp. 79–102.

Mudambi, R./Navarra, P., Divisional Power, Intra-firm Bargaining and Rent-seeking Behavior in Multidivisional corporations, Economics Bulletin, 4, 3, 2004, pp. 1–10.

Nelson, R. R./Winter, s., An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, cambridge: the Belknap Press of harvard University Press 1982.

O’Donnell, s., Managing Foreign subsidiaries: agents of headquarters, or an interdependent Net-work?, Strategic Management Journal, 21, 5, 2000, pp. 525–548.

Oxelheim, l./Gartner, R. small country Manufacturing industries in transition: the case of the Nordic Region, Management International Review, 34, 1994, pp. 331–356.

Papanastassiou, M./Pearce, R., technological sourcing and the strategic Roles of Manufacturing subsidiaries in the UK: local competencies and Global competitiveness, Management Inter-national Review, 37, 1, 1997, pp. 5–26.

Papanastassiou, M./Pearce, R., Funding sources and the strategic Roles of Decentralised R&D in Multinationals, R&D Management, 35, 1, 2005, pp. 89–100.

Paterson, s./Brock, D., the Development of subsidiary Management Research: Review and theo-retical analysis, International Business Review, 11, 1, 2002, pp. 139–163.

Pearce, R., the evolution of technology in Multinational enterprises: the Role of creative subsi-diaries, International Business Review, 8, 2, 1999, pp. 125–148.

Porter, M. e.,/sölvell, O., the Role of Geography in the Process of innovation and the sustainable competitive advantage of Firms, in chandler, a./hagstrom, P./sölvell, O. (eds.), The Dyna-mic Firm: The Role of Technology, Strategy, and Regions, Oxford: Oxford University Press 1998.

schmid, s./schurig, a., the Development of critical capabilities in Foreign subsidiaries: Disen-tangling the Role of the subsidiary’s Business Network, International Business Review, 12, 4, 2003, pp. 755–782.

scott-Kennel, J., Foreign Direct investment and local linkages: an empirical investigation, Management International Review, 47, 1, 2007, pp. 51–77.

siler, P./Wang, c./liu, X., technology transfer Within Multinatinal Firms and its impact on the Productivity of scottish subsidiaries, Regional Studies, 37, 1, 2003, pp. 15–25.

stiglitz J., Making Globalisation Work, New York: W. W. Norton company 2006.soenen, l. a./Van Den Bulcke, D., Belgium’s largest industrial companies: a comparison of size

and Financial Performance Between Foreign and Belgian Owned companies, Management International Review, 28, 1, pp. 51–63.

taggart, J., R&D complexity in UK subsidiaries of Manufacturing Multinational corporations’, Technovation, 17, 2, 1997, pp. 73–82.

Taggart, J., Determinants of Increasing R&D Complexity in Affiliates of Manufacturing Multinati-onal corporations in the UK, R&D Management, 28, 2, 1998, pp. 101–110.

taggart, J., Us MNc subsidiaries in the UK: characteristics and strategic Role’, in Burton, F./chapman, M./cross, a. (eds.), International Business Organization, Basingstoke: MacMillan Press ltd 1999.

41subsidiary Role and skilled labour effects

taggart, J./hood, N., Determinants of autonomy in Multinational corporation subsidiaries, Euro-pean Management Journal, 17, 2, 1999, pp. 226–236.

tavares, a. t., Multinational subsidiary evolution and Public Policy: two tales from the european Periphery, Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 2, 3, 2002, pp. 195–213.

teng, B.-s., corporate entrepreneurship activities through strategic alliances: a Resource-Based approach toward competitive advantage, Journal of Management Studies, 44, 1, 2007, pp. 119–142.

trent, R. J./Monozka, R. M., Pursuing competitive advantage through integrated Global sourcing, Academy of Management Executive, 8, 2, 2002, pp. 66–80.

Vachani, S., Global Diversification’s Effect on Multinational Subsidiaries’ Autonomy, Internatio-nal Business Review, 8, 5, 1999, pp. 535–560.

White, R./Poynter, t. a., strategies for Foreign-Owned subsidiaries in canada, Business Quar-terly, 49, 2, 1984, pp. 59–69.

Wolf, M., Why Globalisation Works, New haven: Yale University Press 2005.Young, s./hood, N./Dunlop, s., Multinational subsidiary Roles and economic impact on scotland,

Regional Studies, 22, 6, 1988, pp. 487–497.Young, s./tavares, a., centralization and autonomy: Back to the Future, International Business

Review, 13, 2, 2004, pp. 215–237.

42 J. Gammelgaard et al.

070028_Scholz_155x235.indd 1 24.01.2008 14:23:02