cores, peripheries, and contemporary political economy

Upload: jimena-sanchez

Post on 14-Apr-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/30/2019 Cores, Peripheries, And Contemporary Political Economy

    1/9

    Cores, Peripheries, and Contemporary

    Political Economy

    Erik Wibbels

    Published online: 22 July 2009

    # Springer Science + Business Media, LLC 2009

    Abstract This note underscores the need for more precise causal theories linking the

    international division of labor, national economies, and public policies. To that end,

    the author recommends two literatures upon which a revised dependency theory

    might build, namely, those on economic geography and the political economy of

    redistribution.

    Keywords Economy . Capital . Dependency . Economic geography . Redistribution

    There could not be a better time to revisit Cardoso and Falleto's seminal

    contribution. As mortgage defaults in Los Vegas and Miami reverberate through

    complex financial ties to the centers of global finance, a global depression looms.

    And, as usual, this downturn will affect the developing world more severely. Thanks

    to declining demand in core economies and retrenched investments by capital in

    those same economies, developing economies will shrink more and suffer greater

    volatility than their rich counterparts. If you think stock markets in New York and

    Frankfurt have fallen sharply, you might consider looking at Russia, India, andChina where values have fallen twice as severely. So we see, yet again, that the

    economies of developing nations are, in fact, dependent on their rich counterparts.

    Whether or not that translates into dependency, as originally articulated in

    Dependency and Development or as envisioned in these more recent contributions

    is a whole different matter.

    There is much to like in this collection of papers. I agree with several common

    themes that appear across the contributionsthat the manner of international

    economic integration varies across countries, that reliance on external markets can be

    consistent with advanced forms of production and development, that the operation ofinternational markets constrains choices, and that different forms of integration,

    therefore, produce different kinds of constraints. I also agree with the widely argued

    St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441449

    DOI 10.1007/s12116-009-9044-1

    E. Wibbels (*)

    Department of Political Science, Duke University, 306 Perkins Library, Durham, NC 27708, USA

    e-mail: [email protected]

  • 7/30/2019 Cores, Peripheries, And Contemporary Political Economy

    2/9

    notion that there is some, albeit varying, scope for political choices. What I remain

    puzzled by is how any of this relates to dependency, a concept that relies on a notion

    of asymmetric political and economic power in the international system.

    To my mind, the fundamental problem in the original dependency literature was a

    failure to clearly define dependency. Yes, Dependency and Development provided agreat advance by linking international structure with national actors and institutions,

    and its historically informed account of country experiences provides a compelling

    view of dependency. At the same time, key concepts such as enclaves and

    unequal exchange lacked the kind of rigor that would allow for the clear

    articulation of causal arguments. In the absence of clear causal arguments,

    convincing empirical tests of the theory's implications were elusive. To my mind,

    it was this looseness of argument rather than any overwhelming evidence against the

    spirit of the argument that contributed to the theory's declining status in the 1980s

    and 1990s.On this point, I find the contributors to this volume to have replicated the key

    weakness of the original work. On the whole, the authors have diverse and vague

    notions of what defines dependency. For Evans, it is reliance on a set of international

    rules and institutions that are biased against developing nations. Kohli suggests that

    dependency is created by political elites who pursue insufficiently nationalist and

    state-led development. In his piece, Cardoso emphasizes the growing importance of

    international financial capital and the ongoing reliance of developing countries on

    technological innovations in the core. Conning and Robinson, though keenly aware

    of the limitations of the original formulation of dependency, choose to emphasize theimportance of production in enclaves. Bruszt and Greskovits emphasize diverse

    international influences, and the concept of dependency expands to include

    countries that export human capital-intensive manufactured goods that historically

    have been the purview of core economies.

    In most of these cases, dependency is defined in terms too vague to know exactly

    how it operatesthe reader just cannot quite figure out what it is. It is also the case

    that when reading across the pieces, it is hard to know what dependency is not, since

    the key characteristics of dependency are so different from one contribution to the

    next. The frequent reliance in these pages on typologies and types of development

    does not help very much. The basic problem is that the political and economic

    mechanisms through which dependency might work remain poorly articulated three

    decades after the touchstone work was published.

    I do not think a theory of dependency can be compelling unless it has reasonably

    rigorous micro-foundations. By that I mean that both the systemic properties of the

    international economy and the local manifestations of political power that

    complement participation in the global economy should be linked to the self-

    interest of the individuals who make up those economies. A micro-foundational

    approach to dependency would work toward identifying the key actorsMNC

    managers, international financiers, politicians, labor market participants, etc.their

    preferences, and the constraints under which they operate such that dependency

    results. Well-developed micro-foundations would provide the basis for a systematic

    exploration of the conditions under which markets and politics interact to produce

    dysfunctional development outcomes. Such an approach would require the

    methodical study of how international markets operate in everything from natural

    442 St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441449

  • 7/30/2019 Cores, Peripheries, And Contemporary Political Economy

    3/9

    resources to primary products to manufactured goods to financial instruments. Only

    a reborn dependency that is rooted in an understanding of individual incentives and

    reflective of a deep understanding of how specific markets operate will be able to

    answer key questions: What kinds of markets are associated with dependency?

    Agricultural markets? Natural resource markets? Financial markets? When and whyis foreign ownership a problem? Under what conditions do politicians have

    incentives to align with foreign capital, domestic capital, labor, or some combination

    thereof? What are the individual-level preferences of investors, labor market

    participants, and the like that underpin the development of enclaves? In short, what

    kinds of comparative advantage are most likely to produce dependency?

    Economic Geography as Precursor to a Reinvigorated Dependency Theory

    What makes the lack of micro-foundations particularly glaring in the contributions to

    this volume is that there has been important work in economics and political science

    over the last several decades that is of direct relevance to the intellectual agenda of

    dependency theory. As Herman Schwartz (2007) noted in the pages of this journal

    3 years ago, one of the most important would seem to be the new economic

    geography inspired by Krugman's (1991) work on trade and geography. Motivated

    by the simple observation that production is highly concentrated in space, Krugman

    develops a simple model of economic cores and peripheries in which small initial

    differences in endowments between two locations result in radically differentdevelopmental outcomes. The key insight of the literature is that local economies

    can be subject to increasing returns to scale. When increasing returns are present,

    each additional investment attracts more investments, local job growth promotes

    migration, and large markets beget larger markets. In such cases, the self-interest of

    market participants can produce economic asymmetries that closely mirror those

    between dependency theory's core, periphery, and semi-periphery.

    In explaining when such dynamics are likely to be present, Krugman

    emphasizes three factors: the size of the local market, transportation costs, and

    externalities. As local market size increases, incentives mount for other producers

    to locate nearby. When combined with positive externalities between firms

    externalities that emerge from labor market pooling, knowledge spillovers, or

    input sharingagglomeration effects redound to the benefit of the local economy

    as productivity gains cumulate and growth explodes. Transportation costs work

    in a parallel manner. As economies of scale mount, the incentives to produce in

    any given location increase as its transportation networks improveonly thus

    will initial investments be recouped by serving a broader market through trade.

    This is true up to the point at which trade is nearly costless, in which case the

    benefits of spillovers among firms are not mediated by proximity and the forces

    for agglomeration begin to decline.

    It is easy to see the relevance of Krugman's insights for the international

    distribution of production, and subsequent work has emphasized the importance of

    increasing returns for country specialization, the international division of labor, and

    development. Related work provides a rigorous modeling of the conditions under

    which domestically oriented big bangs produce development (Murphy et al. 1989)

    St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441449 443

  • 7/30/2019 Cores, Peripheries, And Contemporary Political Economy

    4/9

    and when production is likely to split off from cores, relocate to peripheries and

    result in economic convergence between cores and peripheries (Venables 2007). The

    key difference between these works of economic geography and dependency theory,

    at least as articulated in the pieces for this volume, is that they have much more

    precise accounts of the underlying dynamics that produce uneven development.The economic geographers' account of cores and peripheries leaves little room for

    politics. In Krugman's model, cores emerge for random reasons; initial advantages

    are often minimal, but once increasing returns set in, cores and peripheries emerge

    and only rarely do such dynamics break down. But even a cursory understanding of

    the historical emergence of global capitalism suggests that today's international

    distribution of wealth is the result of a deeply political process. It does not require a

    great deal of imagination to marry Krugman's discussion of economic geography

    with, for instance, Pomerantz's (2000) account of the nineteenth century divergence

    of European wealth from the rest of the world. Carefully reconstructing price dataover the course of centuries, Pomerantz suggests that Western Europe became rich

    thanks to the increasing returns that set in once the British discovered coal and

    subsequently used their initial advantages to extract wealth from the rest of the world

    through colonialism. In this account, the increasing returns that promoted early

    British industrialization also provided the resources and incentives to politically

    construct the first truly global capitalist economy.

    Here, modern-day dependency theorists could bring much to the table by

    analyzing the political causes and consequences of increasing returns. While

    economists have done a nice job of identifying the key ingredients of increasingreturns, other social sciences have done a poor job of identifying the political

    correlates, causes, or consequences of increasing returns.1 One promising avenue lies

    with ongoing attempts to understand path dependency, a concept closely related to

    that of increasing returns, but analyses of path dependency oftentimes lack general

    mechanisms whereby political dynamics in the past inform the present and future

    and, therefore, do not lend themselves easily to causal inference. By building more

    rigorous analytical models of politics onto economic geography's intellectual

    infrastructure, a reborn dependency theory might provide an empirically compelling

    and analytically rigorous characterization of today's cores and peripheries. Such an

    approach to the study of development, to my mind, would represent a stark departure

    from the current conventional wisdom's emphasis on domestic institutions and

    provide a reinvigorated dependency theory with some much-needed analytical rigor.

    Economic Geography and Enclaves

    One area where research on economic geography might speak very precisely to the

    concerns of a reinvigorated dependency theory would be with regards to economic

    enclaves. In this collection of essays, Cardoso revisits the concept and Conning and

    Robinson focus on dependency qua foreign ownership. It is worth emphasizing that

    1 The literature on the developmental state in East Asia probably comes closest to fitting the bill, but

    with few exceptions (see Evans 1995 and Kohli 2004, for instance); it has been disinterested in

    generalizing beyond outcomes in a single region.

    444 St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441449

  • 7/30/2019 Cores, Peripheries, And Contemporary Political Economy

    5/9

    a slightly different approach to enclaves, that inspired by Hirschman's (1958)

    emphasis on natural resource production, has seen a boom over the last decade.

    Broadly consistent with the instincts of dependency theory, research on the resource

    curse suggests that oil wealth produces poor developmental and political out-

    comes.2

    It is worth reflecting for a moment on how profound and heterodox theimplications of these finding are: under predictable circumstances, countries will

    worsen developmental outcomes by relying on their comparative advantage and

    engaging in trade.

    The problem, however, is that the resource curse literature has suffered from

    much the same problems as dependency theorya lack of theoretical precision has

    promoted the proliferation of hypotheses to explain the empirical findings. The main

    problem is that the arguments provide limited insight into why natural resources

    provided the foundation for broad-based economic growth in the USA, Canada,

    Australia, and Norway (Wright 2001), but seem to produce enclave economies inNigeria, Venezuela, and Bolivia. In the former cases, democracy, development, and

    natural resources have gone together. In the latter cases, enclave production has

    promoted rent-seeking, clientelism, and waves of populism and authoritarianism. So

    why are natural resources produced in enclaves, with all of their political and

    economic dysfunctions in some cases while in others they seem consistent with

    development and stable democracy?

    Given that production of natural resources in enclaves is just a special case of

    economic geography, it seems likely that the general theoretical insights from that

    literature might help answer some of these questions. The simplest hypothesis thatwould emerge from the economic geography literature is that the local income boom

    associated with natural resource production will produce positive externalities as the

    size of the local market increases. Where populations are smaller, less dense, and poorer,

    local demand will be lower. The returns to natural resources will ensure extractive

    investments, but the paucity of local demand will militate against positive spillovers to

    other economic activities. Particularly when transportation costs are high, investments

    will likely be concentrated only in the high return resource sectorthe value to weight

    ratio of other products will simply be too low to warrant producing them for outside

    markets, and mineral production will not be associated with increasing returns.

    It would not be hard to generalize these insights into an account of the

    international political economy of natural resources that was consistent with diverse

    national experiences with mineral wealth over the last several hundred years. Of

    course, such an account would abstract away from important issues of international

    powerthe influence of international oil companies and their home governments in

    developing international oil markets, for instancebut it is on these more political

    aspects of economic geography that a reinvigorated dependency theory would have

    much to add. Indeed, a renewed dependency theory might try to generalize these

    insights from the economic geography of natural resource production to enclave

    production more generally and develop systematic arguments as to how different

    types of economic enclaves encourage politicians to pursue governance strategies

    that vary in their use of political exclusion and coercion.

    2 For a critical look at the resource curse literature, see the essays in Lederman and Maloney ( 2007).

    St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441449 445

  • 7/30/2019 Cores, Peripheries, And Contemporary Political Economy

    6/9

    Redistribution, Insurance, and Social Democracy in the Periphery

    If the economic geography literature would provide a reinvigorated dependency

    theory with more systematic tools for analyzing the international distribution of

    production and income, two decades worth of research on redistribution wouldprovide it with more rigorous models of how and when politicians deploy the fiscal

    powers of the state to mediate the domestic distributive effects of participating in

    international markets. On this point, Cardoso's discussion of globalized social

    democracy is quite optimistic, and the point is picked up in the Evans and Munck

    contributions. The hope is that, as in Western Europe, participation in international

    markets can be consistent with redistributive fiscal policy and domestic equity. That

    hope conflicts with Dependency and Developments more pessimistic diagnosis,

    which implied that dependent development implied coercive labor practices and

    pronounced social inequities.The optimistic tone does accord with the dominant account of the relationship

    between trade, production, and social policy. That account suggests that social policy

    emerges as a mean to compensate various labor market participants for the risks they

    face and reflects the electoral power of the left. A key assumption of this story is that

    the dynamics that underpin the emergence of social policy are common across the

    developing and developed world. This assumption is most explicit in the work of

    Lindert (2004), Rodrik (1998), and Adser and Boix (2002), though a large body of

    related literature implies as much.

    Yet, such work fails to consider the fundamental importance of countries' diversepositions in the global economy and how the changing dynamics of global

    capitalism have altered the incentives for social provision through time. Evans

    makes a similar point in his contribution to this volume when he suggests that the

    contemporary international rules of the game militate against globalized social

    democracy. My point is different, namely, that the nature of production and the

    underlying features of the global economy that facilitated the rise of the welfare state

    in the 1950s and 1960s in Europe are wholly gone. Indeed, the literature on

    redistribution and insurance suggests that individuals' preferences for redistribution

    and social insurance are a function of their position in the income distribution and

    their exposure to risk (Moene and Wallerstein 2001), and related research (built

    largely on the experience of the OECD) emphasizes the importance of electoral

    systems and collective wage bargaining for fiscal policy and distributive outcomes.

    While these insights are not directly related to economic openness, it is the case that

    the operation of the global economy has important implications for national income

    and risk distributions.

    Post-war Europe benefited from an ideal set of conditions for the emergence of its

    version of globalized social democracy. First, the European countries that developed

    the large welfare states had comparative advantages in labor-intensive manufactur-

    ing. External demand for OECD goods in the 1950s was concentrated in metal

    working and other sectors dominated by Fordist modes of production. This

    comparative advantage produced large urban working classes that, along with some

    smallholding rural sectors, provided the political foundations for the growth of the

    welfare state. Thanks to their votes, parties of the left were consistently able to form

    governments and implement redistributive policies. Second, manufacturing in the

    446 St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441449

  • 7/30/2019 Cores, Peripheries, And Contemporary Political Economy

    7/9

    OECD of the 1950s was a sector heavily dependent on trade and with high profit

    margins. Given the centrality of trade, the key unions in most European countries

    were in favor of trade. That these were high margin sectors meant that capital could

    at least plausibly afford the tax burdens that funded the welfare state. Third and

    finally, the most industrialized societies were small, trade-dependent ones where thewelfare state served to insure against the risks associated with heady levels of

    external exposure. In these societies, coordinated wage bargaining, which was so

    central to the insurance-laden systems of the OECD, emerged, in part, as an attempt

    by cross-class coalitions to mediate the risks of international competition. As Mares

    (2003) notes, organized employers played a central role in pushing for collective

    bargaining and risk-sharing policies that provided the political backbone for the

    insurance component of OECD welfare states. In short, Europe's position in the

    global economy produced large, free-trading union movements that supported left

    parties and redistributive spending while capital and labor coordinated risk-sharingpolicies of social insurance to promote competitiveness and stability in open

    economies.

    The changed nature of the global economy in 2009 makes those ideal conditions

    very difficult to replicate. The single most important difference between the 1950s

    and the 2000s is the nature of manufacturing. While it is true that much

    manufacturing has relocated to the developing world, technological innovations

    allow for much higher levels of productivity with many fewer employees (Krugman

    2000). Thus, while globalization has greatly increased global demand for

    manufacturing, that demand can be satisfied with far fewer workers per unitproduced than in the heyday of European welfare state growth. One important

    political implication is that manufacturing working classes, even in the most

    industrialized developing nations, are far smaller than those in 1950s Norway, for

    instance. Indeed, the most industrialized developing countries have manufacturing

    workforces 25% smaller than Sweden or Germany in 1960.3 So while Chinese and

    Malaysian working classes might be as free-trading as their counterparts 50 years

    ago in much of Europe, they form a much smaller share of the working population

    and have scarce the voice of their predecessors.

    Second, while manufacturing today is a highly competitive, internationally

    oriented sector much as it was in 1950s Europe, it is now typically a low-skill, low-

    value added sector with small profit margins. As a result, employers are much more

    sensitive to the economic costs of social policy than they were in the 1950s in

    Norway, and one is hard-pressed to find evidence of employers in the developing

    world leading the charge on the benefits of wage coordination and social insurance.

    It is also the case that the manufacturing production that has splintered off from the

    OECD and relocated to the developing world has responded to agglomeration

    economies. That means that it is the largest economies in the developing world that

    are attracting the lion's share of industrial productionBrazil, Mexico, China, etc.

    whereas it was the smallest countries that became the most industrialized in the

    OECD. In these large economies, the interests of workers and employers are more

    heterogeneous and the high levels of political coordination that promoted the welfare

    3 Data for developing countries is from the World Development Indicators 2008. The data for the West

    European countries comes from Iversen and Cusack (2000) and is for the year1960.

    St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441449 447

  • 7/30/2019 Cores, Peripheries, And Contemporary Political Economy

    8/9

    state in Sweden are harder to pull off. When combined with the fact that capital

    owners typically are much more mobile than 50 years ago, it is hard to imagine

    employerlabor coordination playing the central role in the development of risk-

    sharing policies that provide the backbone for the European welfare states.

    This all suggests that we need to pay attention to dependency theory's coreinsight, namely, that there is an international division of labor and that division of

    labor matters. To that I would add that the international division of labor is dynamic

    and, therefore, the global economy that made the European welfare state possible in

    the 1950s and 1960s is dead and gone. That said, the challenge for a new generation

    of dependency theorists will be to take the micro-logic of the literature on insurance

    and redistribution seriously, combine it with an understanding of how international

    markets work, and produce predictions about redistributive politics that reflect

    contemporary realities in the developing world. Inspired by the literature on risk and

    redistribution (Moene and Wallerstein 2001; Iversen 2005), dependistas might revisitPrzeworski and Wallerstein's (1988) work on the dynamics of capital taxation in

    contexts of class conflict and extend Mosley's (2003) work on the policy preferences

    of international capital managers to examine how the network structure of

    international economic competition conditions domestic conflicts over fiscal policy.

    Conclusion

    We are all just beginning to sort through the lessons of the current globaleconomic crisis. As bailout follows bailout in New York, London, and elsewhere,

    it certainly seems to be the case that the state is structurally dependent on capital.

    But at a more nuanced level, structural dependence has not precluded the failure

    of even very big, powerful firms, and the location of national economies vis--vis

    the global financial centers has had important implications for the depth of their

    crises. To my mind, the most important contribution of Dependency and

    Development was the way in which it unified analysis at the international level

    with analysis of the domestic politics that sustained particular positions in the

    international division of labor. Above, I have recommended two broad bodies of

    literature in political economythat on the new economic geography and that on

    risk and redistributionupon which a reinvigorated dependency theory might

    rebuild. While the former literature provides insight into the emergence of cores and

    peripheries within and between nations, the latter emphasizes the ways in which

    taxing and spending policies help construct governing coalitions. Both literatures are

    built on clear micro-foundations, something that the contributions to this volume

    lack. Aligning those two literatures is no easy task, and it will be a serious challenge

    to take the further step of linking their micro-logics to the broad macro-political and

    macroeconomic outcomes that inspire thinkers in the dependency tradition. But the

    payoffs could very well be hightogether, they might just bring dependency theory

    back to intellectual center stage at a time when much of the world is questioning its

    dependency on the likes of AIG and Bank of America.

    Acknowledgment Erik Wibbels would like to thank Rich Snyder and Patrick Heller for their critical

    engagement with an earlier draft of these pages.

    448 St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441449

  • 7/30/2019 Cores, Peripheries, And Contemporary Political Economy

    9/9

    References

    Adser A, Boix C. Trade, democracy, and the size of the public sector: the political underpinnings of

    openness. Int Organ. 2002;56:22962.

    Evans P. Embedded autonomy: states and industrial transformation. Princeton: Princeton University Press;1995.

    Hirschman A. The strategy of economic development. New Haven: Yale University Press; 1958.

    Iversen T. Capitalism, democracy, and welfare. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2005.

    Iversen, T, Cusak TR. 2000. The Causes of Welfare State Expansion: Deindustrialization or Globalization?

    World Polit. 2000;52:31349.

    Kohli A. State-directed development: political power and industrialization in the global periphery. New

    York: Cambridge University Press; 2004.

    Krugman P. Geography and trade. Cambridge: MIT Press; 1991.

    Krugman P. Technology, trade and factor prices. J Int Econ. 2000;50:5171.

    Lederman D, Maloney W, editors. Natural resources: neither curse nor destiny. Palo Alto: Stanford

    University Press; 2007.

    Lindert P. Growing public. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2004.Mares IM. The sources of business interest in social insurance. World Polit. 2003;55:22958.

    Moene KO, Wallerstein M. Inequality, social insurance, and redistribution. Am Polit Sci Rev.

    2001;95:85974.

    Mosley L. Global capital and national governments. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2003.

    Murphy K, Shleifer A, Vishny R. Income distribution, market size and industrialization. Q J Econ.

    1989;3:53764.

    Pomerantz K. The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world economy.

    Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2000.

    Przeworski A, Wallerstein M. Structural dependence of the state on capital. Am Polit Sci Rev.

    1988;83:1129.

    Rodrik D. Why do open economies have bigger governments? J Polit Econ. 1998;106:9971032.

    Schwartzm H. Dependency or institutions? Economic geography, causal mechanisms, and logic in the

    understanding of development. Stud Comp Int Dev. 2007;42:11535.

    Venables A. Trade, location, and development: an overview of theory. In: Lederman and Maloney, editors.

    Natural resources: neither curse nor destiny. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press; 2007;259288.

    Wright G. Resource based growth, then and now. Manuscript, Stanford University Department of

    Economics; 2001.

    Erik Wibbels is an Associate Professor of Political Science. His research focuses on development,

    decentralized governance and other areas of comparative political economy.

    St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441449 449