cbess discussion paper 09-01exelle+and+riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic...

45
CBESS Discussion Paper 10-15 Directed Generosity and Network Formation: Network Dimension Matters by Ben d’Exelle* and Arno Riedl** * CBESS, University of East Anglia ** University of Maastricht Abstract We explore network effects on generosity for different network dimensions. To this end we elicit multiple network dimensions (friendship, social support, economic exchange, etc.) in a rural village in the Southern hemisphere and measure generosity with a sequence of dictator games conducted in the field. We find that networks of different dimensions differ substantially in density, clustering, and centrality. When relating generosity to networks we observe that social distance only matters for friendship ties but that structural network variables are important in all network dimensions. Importantly, these effects are not invariant across different network dimensions. We also find that individual characteristics are unrelated with generosity per se but that they have strong explanatory power for network formation. JEL classification codes C72, C90, D64, L14, Z13 Keywords Networks, generosity, network formation, experiments Centre for Behavioural and Experimental Social Science CBESS Centre for Behavioural and Experimental Social Science CBESS CBESS University of East Anglia Norwich NR4 7TJ United Kingdom www.uea.ac.uk/ssf/cbess

Upload: others

Post on 26-Jul-2021

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

CBESS Discussion Paper 10-15 Directed Generosity and Network Formation: Network Dimension Matters by Ben d’Exelle* and Arno Riedl** * CBESS, University of East Anglia ** University of Maastricht Abstract We explore network effects on generosity for different network dimensions. To this end we elicit multiple network dimensions (friendship, social support, economic exchange, etc.) in a rural village in the Southern hemisphere and measure generosity with a sequence of dictator games conducted in the field. We find that networks of different dimensions differ substantially in density, clustering, and centrality. When relating generosity to networks we observe that social distance only matters for friendship ties but that structural network variables are important in all network dimensions. Importantly, these effects are not invariant across different network dimensions. We also find that individual characteristics are unrelated with generosity per se but that they have strong explanatory power for network formation. JEL classification codes C72, C90, D64, L14, Z13 Keywords Networks, generosity, network formation, experiments

Centre forBehavioural and ExperimentalSocialScience

CBESSCentre forBehavioural and ExperimentalSocialScience

CBESS

CBESS University of East Anglia Norwich NR4 7TJ United Kingdom www.uea.ac.uk/ssf/cbess

Page 2: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

Directed Generosity and Network Formation:

Network Dimension Matters∗

Ben D’Exelle Arno Riedl

December 4, 2010

Abstract

We explore network effects on generosity for different network dimensions. To this end we

elicit multiple network dimensions (friendship, social support, economic exchange, etc.) in a

rural village in the Southern hemisphere and measure generosity with a sequence of dictator

games conducted in the field. We find that networks of different dimensions differ substantially

in density, clustering, and centrality. When relating generosity to networks we observe that

social distance only matters for friendship ties but that structural network variables are

important in all network dimensions. Importantly, these effects are not invariant across

different network dimensions. We also find that individual characteristics are unrelated with

generosity per se but that they have strong explanatory power for network formation.

Keywords: Networks, generosity, network formation, experiments

JEL Classification: C72, C90, D64, L14, Z13

∗Ben D’Exelle: University of East Anglia, School of International Development, NR4 7TJ, Norwich, United

Kingdom, [email protected]; Arno Riedl: CESifo, IZA, and Maastricht University, Department of Economics

(AE1), P.O. Box 616, 6200 MD Maastricht, the Netherlands, [email protected]. The research

documented in this paper was financed by the Oesterreichische Nationalbank (project number 11429), VLIR-UOS,

and IOB-UA. We thank Guy Delmelle, Ligia Gomez, Miguel Aleman, Francisco Perez, Selmira Flores and Alfredo

Ruız for interesting methodological discussions, Tania Paz Mena, Leonardo Matute, Francisco Paiz Salgado, Edna

Garcıa Flores, Fatima Guevara, Silvia Martinez Arroliga and Will Tellez for support in the field work, Vanessa

Castrillo and Jazmina Andino for their help in the search for sufficient coins of money, Elizabeth Campos and

Manuel Bermudez of the Fondo de Desarrollo Local for offering a safe in one of their local banking offices, and

the community leader Francisco Varela for his local support. We also thank colleagues at Maastricht University

and the University of Antwerp for comments on the experimental design and the many participants in workshops,

seminars, and conferences in Utrecht, Rome, Berlin, Nijmegen and Maastricht for their valuable remarks. We also

benefited very much from comments on an earlier version of this paper by Rebecca Blank, Vincent Buskens, Simon

Gachter, Jean Hagenbach, Matt Jackson, and Michael Woolcock.

Page 3: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

1 Introduction

This paper explores the interrelation between the embeddedness of individuals in networks and

their pro-social behavior in the form of generosity.1 When considering the influence of networks

on behavior it is important to recognize that people are simultaneously embedded in several

network dimensions (or specific networks). Individuals are connected to friends, neighbors,

colleagues at the workplace, business relations and so forth, and it is unlikely that these specific

networks are completely overlapping. In addition, the ties creating these specific networks are

likely having different contents (e.g., emotional versus rational). Different network dimensions

are also important for different activities, may exhibit different structures and, therefore, may

have different effects on economically relevant behavior. For instance, Coleman (1988, 1990)

argues that networks that are locally dense and have high clustering are fostering pro-social

behavior. Friendship networks are often of this type. On the other hand, according to Burt

(1992, 2005), agents with a central position in a network are favored as they have more power

and, hence, are able to pursue their own goals better. Business networks often have such central

players.

In order to investigate the relation between different network dimensions and generosity we

surveyed all household heads in a rural village in Nicaragua and elicited the whole network for

several important network dimensions: friendship, mutual support, public activities, economic

relations, neighborhood. In addition, we measured individual generosity in a controlled way, by

organizing a series of dictator game experiments with the household heads. In the experiment

each ‘dictator’ was matched with known participants from the village as well as a stranger from

another village, where we use the generosity towards the latter as a proxy of the household

1Generosity is a widespread, economically and socially relevant, phenomenon. In controlled experiments it

is repeatedly observed that people are willing to give up money even if the recipient is an anonymous stranger

(see Camerer, 2003, chapter 2, for a survey, and Fisman et al., 2007; List, 2007; Bardsley, 2008; Carpenter et al.,

2008; Konow et al., 2008, for recent evidence). This habit of giving, which is observed across nations and cultures

(Henrich et al., 2005) is not only confined to experimental environments. For instance, generous behavior in the

form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by

private individuals totaled about USD 200 billion in the United States. Similar figures are found in other countries

around the world (cf. Andreoni, 2006). Generosity is also widely observed in every day life in the form of, e.g.,

neighborhood support and volunteering, and is generally perceived as a desirable habit in society.

Among economists it is now also widely recognized that networks play an important role in economic life.

For instance, network effects have been shown to be important for worker productivity Bandiera et al. (2009),

welfare culture (Bertrand et al., 2000), migration and labor markets (Rees, 1966; Granovetter, 1973, 1995;

Montgomery, 1991; Ioannides and Loury, 2004; Munshi, 2003), mutual insurance (Fafchamps and Lund, 2003;

De Weerdt and Dercon, 2006), informal credit markets (McMillan and Woodruff, 1999; Karlan, 2007), and inter-

national trade (Casella and Rauch, 2002).

1

Page 4: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

heads’ general generosity. To the best of our knowledge there are only two other studies that

look into the potential effects of different network dimensions on economic and social behavior.

In the sociological literature Podolny and Baron (1997) seem to be the only authors who have

taken up this issue.2 In economics only Jackson et al. (2010) report network data of relationships

with different contents for villages in India. Neither of these studies relates the specific network

dimensions to individual behavior in a controlled way.

A main objective of our study is to examine in what way the potentially different structures

related to different network dimensions and the accompanied positions of individuals in such

networks influence these individuals’ generosity. More specifically, we explore, first, whether

network structure and network embeddedness can account for the variation observed in individual

generosity and which structural characteristics of the network are important (if any). Second, we

study, whether the influence of network structure and position indeed varies across networks of

different social and economic dimensions. Third, we investigate, whether observable individual

characteristics have explanatory power. Finally, we also explore whether individual background

characteristics influence network formation itself. Finding such an effect would indicate that

these characteristics affect generosity indirectly via the channel of network formation.

There are a few recent studies that are related to ours. Leider et al. (2009) and Goeree et al.

(2010) also combine network elicitation with controlled experiments. The former elicited the

friendship networks among students residing in two dormitories at Harvard University and let

them play variants of the dictator game and a helping-game. The latter authors also elicited

friendship networks and investigate dictator game giving among teenagers in an all-girls school.

Branas-Garza et al. (2010) conduct a similar study with Spanish students.

Our study goes beyond that literature in at least two important aspects. First, we conducted

our research in a rural village in the Southern hemisphere. Therefore, our investigated social

unit is profoundly different from the student groups investigated in the mentioned work. This is

important because recently some scholars have forcefully argued that behavior of wealthy stu-

dents in the Northern hemisphere is special and that it is at least questionable to generalize

to populations with other backgrounds (cf. Henrich et al., 2010). Second, we elicited not only

friendship ties but also a number of other network dimensions people are simultaneously em-

bedded in. This allows us to separately analyze and compare whether and how different specific

networks affect behavior. Importantly, we also elicited the friendship network which makes it

possible to check if the effects of friendship ties identified among students in the U.S. and Europe

2They analyze different contents of social relations of managers first mapped by Burt (1992) and show that the

implications of network structures for manager behavior are not independent of link content. (We thank Saurabh

Arora for providing this information in a personal communication.)

2

Page 5: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

can also be found for friendship ties in a rural village in a developing country. If we find that,

despite the obvious differences in the investigated population, the same network variables are

important determinants of generous behavior, we would have strong suggestive evidence for the

hypothesis that network effects are universally applicable.

Indeed, regarding the network effects of friendship relations we confirm the main result of

the mentioned studies. Social distance matters for generosity also in our very different popu-

lation. Direct friends are treated significantly more generously than people at larger distances

in the friendship dimension. However, this result does not hold for any of the other specific

networks. Hence, the finding that direct contacts are treated better than indirect ones is specific

to friendship relations.

Another main result is that structural network variables reflecting dense embeddedness (i.e.,

clustering) and powerful positions (i.e., centrality) significantly affect generosity towards other

network members. Other existing studies did either not explore these effects or did not find such

strong influences. Importantly, the effects of structural network variables on giving behavior are

not invariant across different network dimensions. In the friendship network and the economic

network generosity towards village recipients increases with the centrality of the dictator and

decreases with the density of her connectedness. In contrast, in the support network dictators

with dense local networks are more generous but centrality plays no role. Not only the dicta-

tors’ but also the recipient’s network position matters differentially for the dictators’ directed

generosity. In the economic network and the network of social-public activities, dictators are

more generous towards recipients who are densely connected. For the network of social-public

activities it also holds that less central recipients are more generously treated. Interestingly, the

structural network variables of recipients do not have an effect in the friendship and support

networks. In summary, our results show that structural network characteristics matter for giving

behavior and that these effects clearly depend on the network dimension.

Regarding observable individual characteristics we find that after controlling for network

effects only gender has explanatory power. Interestingly, and in contrast to most other studies

on gender effects, women are less generous than men, especially when the recipient is male.

We also find that village members are treated better as well as worse than strangers, and that

generosity towards village members is positively related to general generosity towards strangers.

A final finding is that certain individual characteristics are indeed important determinants of tie

formation in the elicited specific networks and that their influence varies across different network

dimensions. This strongly suggests that the influence of observable individual characteristics on

generosity runs indirectly through the network effects and that this channel differs for different

specific networks.

3

Page 6: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we describe our research design,

the network elicitation procedure and report descriptive statistics regarding our investigated

population and the elicited networks. It also presents the procedures applied in the dictator game

experiment. Section 3 presents descriptive statistics of behavior in the dictator game, followed

by regression results explaining dictator giving with observable individual characteristics, social

distance and network effects. The section closes with an analysis of the determinants of link

formation in the different specific networks. Section 4 summarizes and concludes.

2 Research Design, Network Characteristics, and Experimental

Procedures

We collected data from a whole real existing long-grown social unit that profoundly differs

from formerly investigated Northern high-school and student populations (cf. Leider et al., 2009;

Goeree et al., 2010). Specifically, we gathered data of household heads of an entire village in

rural Nicaragua. The investigation of such a social unit is important for several reasons. First,

it delivers very different and more varied individual characteristics than relatively homogeneous

student populations do. This increases the likelihood that socio-economic characteristics can

contribute to the explanation of variation in behavior and, thus, also provides an important

robustness test for any eventually detected social distance and network effects. Second, it reflects

the social structure of a naturally grown and long-lasting small-scale society. In such societies

social ties are potentially of life-long importance and likely to be more pronounced than in units of

associations that have knowingly only a temporary character. This might increase the likelihood

of detecting network effects, which were not found in the mentioned studies on homogeneous and

temporary associations. Importantly, social units as the one studied here are not rare special

cases. In fact, most rural people in the Southern hemisphere live in such small-scale societies.

Third, it allows us to explore different dimensions of networks that may exist within a social unit.

One reason why other studies only investigated friendship networks is that there are little other

important social relations among students. In contrast, in our long-grown social unit people

have all sorts of important social ties. Next to friendship ties there exist, among others, business

relations, histories of giving and receiving help, and simple neighborhood ties. This allows us to

explore whether different network dimensions have differential impacts on giving behavior.

In the data gathering process we, first, organized a questionnaire study for collecting a number

of societal characteristics. Second, we elicited different dimensions of social and economic ties

among (almost) all household heads by means of a network survey. Third, after the survey we

conducted a series of dictator game experiments, measuring generosity between household heads

4

Page 7: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

in the village as well as toward strangers outside the village. At the end of the experiment all

participants answered a post-experimental questionnaire. The socio-economic questionnaire and

network elicitation was carried out in four consecutive days. Immediately thereafter the whole

experiment was conducted in a single day, which minimized potential spill-over and contagion

effects.

In the following we further describe the main elements of our research design and report im-

portant socio-economic facts and characteristics of the elicited networks. For detailed information

beyond that reported in this section we refer the reader to Appendix A.

2.1 Household Survey and Societal Characteristics

With the household survey we gathered data on important economic assets (possession of land

or cattle), family composition, education, age, sex, etc.3 The village consists of 66 households of

which 9 are single-headed and 57 two-headed (i.e., 123 household heads in total). We gathered

data of 58 households (87.9 percent) and at least 100 household heads (81.3 percent).

Table 1: Summary statistics of important socio-economic characteristics

Households mean/percentage st.dev. no. of obs.

Land (percentage of owners) 34.48 − 58

Land (mean in ha.) 8.22 17.33 58

Cattle (percentage of owners) 46.55 − 58

Cattle (mean in no. of animals) 3.55 9.44 58

Household heads

Sex (percentage male) 49.50 − 109

Age (mean in years) 46.05 14.49 109

Education (mean in years) 4.13 3.59 109

Residence in village (mean in years) 33.22 15.63 100

Visits to urban center (mean no. last month) 2.07 3.36 100

Table 1 shows descriptive statistics of important characteristics of the households and house-

hold heads in the village. It indicates a pronounced diversity across households as well as house-

hold heads. Only 34.48 percent of the households own land. Land possession measured in

hectares is also very unequally distributed. The standard deviation is more than twice as large

as the mean of 8.22 hectares. For cattle possession the figures are similar. Only 46.55 percent of

all households possess any cattle, and the average number of cattle per household is 3.55 with a

standard deviation of 9.44. This unequal distribution of land and cattle implies a large variation

3For more detailed geographical and economic background of the village and detailed procedures, see Ap-

pendix A.1 and A.2, respectively.

5

Page 8: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

in wealth across households. The variation in important individual characteristics of household

heads is also considerable. About half of all interviewed household heads are female and the age

varies between 21 and 86 years, with an average of 46.05 years. The average education level of

the household heads, measured in number of years of schooling, is only slightly above 4 years

with also quite some variation. The household heads reside in the village between only half a

year and 70 years with an average of 33.22 years. Another potentially important characteristic

is the frequency of contact with the urban center because it can be interpreted as a proxy for

the strength of ties to people outside the village. It varies between 0 and 26 visits in the most

recent month before we took the survey. In summary, we have considerable variation in socio-

economic characteristics of households and household heads, which is an important precondition

for being able to explain possible variations in generosity in our experiment through individual

characteristics.

2.2 Elicitation and Properties of Networks

An important characteristic of social interactions is that they take place in several dimensions

simultaneously. People may not only be friends, but may also have ties because they support

each other, engage in economic transactions, or because they are neighbors. On the other hand,

these different dimensions will only partly overlap. People who do business with each other may

or may not be friends, friends may or may not be neighbors, and so on. Hence, people tend to

be differentially connected in the different network dimensions. Furthermore, different network

dimensions carry different contents. Friendship and mutual support ties are likely of an emotional

type, where the latter may also comprise forward-looking investment into social capital. One

may hypothesize that these dimensions are both supportive for directed generosity. In contrast,

ties trough economic transactions are based on contractual relations and probably a less fertile

ground of generous behavior. Such differences in ties content and network structure make it

likely that eventual network effects on generosity differ across specific network dimensions.

In order to elicit the different dimensions of relationships of all household heads in the village

we adapted a survey method successfully employed by economic anthropologists and sociologists

for mapping bounded networks.4,5 In brief, to elicit the ties of an interviewee we used a stack

4Bounded networks are networks with clearly defined boundaries, such as networks within villages and

organizations, for which all members are surveyed. For a description of the method see, for instance,

the documents section of Jean Ensminger’s and Joseph Henrich’s Roots of Sociality project web-site at

http://www.hss.caltech.edu/~jensming/roots-of-sociality/docs/Social-Network-Analysis.doc .

5Leider et al. (2009) used an incentivized coordination game procedure for eliciting friendship networks among

Harvard students. There are two reasons why we did not adopt their elicitation method. First, most likely it

would have become too complicated for our often illiterate subjects, who are not used at all to abstract exercises.

6

Page 9: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

of small cards representing all households in the village. Each card held the name(s) of the

household head(s) of a household. For each of the cards the interviewee was first asked whether

he or she knows the household and whether he or she has a “social relation of any kind” with

any of the household heads. In this way we gathered data of general relations that are relations

aggregating all types of social and economic interactions. If the answer to the first question was

affirmative we asked for details on the content of the relation and elicited six specific network

dimensions. First, friendship relations that are relations where a person calls another one a

friend. Second, support relations that are relations where any type of help, e.g., small amounts

of food, cash, or transport manpower, is given to or received from a person. Third, social-

public relations that are relations brought about by public activities related to religion, political

parties, the village school, sports, cooperative organization, development projects or the village

committee. Fourth, economic relations that are relations resulting from an exchange of land or

labor, a commercial activity, a service provision or a lending activity. In addition, we also elicited

neighbor relations, that are relations between two persons who consider themselves as neighbors,

and family relations with parents, brothers, sisters, and children.6,7

We succeeded to gather network data for 100 of the 123 household heads (81.3 percent).8 In

processing the network data we proceeded in the following way. First, as we did not explicitly

capture links between members of the same household, we assume that intra-household relations

between household heads exist for general relations, friendship relations, and support relations,

but not for the other reported relations. The rationale for this data treatment is that household

members tend to be friends and to support each other, but they are never neighbors to each

other and it is unlikely that they have business-like economic relations or that they are related

through social public activities. Second, for each network dimension we symmetrized the resulting

adjacency matrix (i.e, the matrix representing directed ties in the population). That is, in each

network dimension, for each dyad (i.e, pair of household heads), we assume that a relation exists

Second, practically it is only applicable for the elicitation of 1-dimensional networks. One of our main interests

lies in capturing multiple dimensions of networks, however.

6The nature of these family relations differs from the other elicited dimensions (e.g., by its genetic determina-

tion). Therefore, and for the sake of brevity we do not report on these relations in this paper but are planning to

report it elsewhere.

7We are aware of only one other data set that contains a number of different network dimensions. Jackson et al.

(2010) report on a stratified survey sample (about 50 percent) of households in a number of villages in India. They

elicit the dimensions Relatives, Temple Company, Hedonic, and Favors, which are similar to our family, social-

public, friendship, and support relations, respectively.

8Of the missing 23 household heads 21 were not present in the village when we conducted the study; only two

household heads refused to participate. Our success ratio is slightly higher than those of Goeree et al. (2010) and

Leider et al. (2009), who report success rates of 77 and 71 percent, respectively.

7

Page 10: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

if at least one node mentions the relation. In using these so-called OR-networks throughout the

analyses we follow the practices of recent network studies (cf. Leider et al., 2009; Jackson et al.,

2010).

Table 2: Properties of the different networks

Densitya,b Centralitya,c Clusteringa,d

General relation 0.354 0.030 0.254 (0)

Friendship relation 0.186 0.103 0.133 (0)

Support relation 0.032 0.326 0.040 (2)

Social public activities 0.039 0.214 0.085 (23)

Economic relation 0.038 0.389 0.041 (13)

Neighbor relation 0.052 0.167 0.054 (3)

Note: a OR-networks, intra-household relations (not) counted as valid linksin general, friendship, and support relations (neighbor, social public activ-ities, and economic relations); b actual links as fraction of all possiblelinks; c Freeman’s betweenness centrality; d network clustering coefficient,number of isolated nodes in parentheses.

Table 2 shows the standard network measures density, betweenness centrality and clustering

for the different network dimensions. Network density is simply given by the sum of actual ties

divided by the number of all possible ties. It is not surprising that density is highest for general

relations because they aggregate relations across all dimensions. Among the specific networks

friendship relations are relatively dense, whereas the other networks have relatively low densities.

Betweenness centrality (Freeman, 1977, 1979) is based on the notion of the shortest path

between pairs of nodes. Informally, the shortest path between two nodes i and j is the minimum

number of links in the network necessary to reach each other. Betweenness centrality captures

the idea that agents who lie on the shortest paths between many pairs of agents are relatively

more central than those who lie on the shortest paths of only a few such pairs. An intuitive

interpretation of betweenness centrality is that agents who are central have ‘local control’ over

those who have to use them to reach each other (who are ‘locally dependent’). The former

are ‘gatekeeping’ the latter (cf. Wasserman and Faust, 1994). In this sense, high betweenness

centrality is a necessary condition for occupying a ‘broker’ position in the network (Burt, 2005).

Formally, let pjk(i) be the number of shortest paths between nodes j and k that pass through

i, pjk the total number of shortest paths between nodes j and k, and n the total number of

nodes in the network, then the normalized betweenness centrality BC(i) of a node i is given by

[∑

pjk(i)/pjk]/[(n − 1)(n − 2)/2], where the sum is taken over all dyads jk with i 6= j 6= k. On

the aggregate level betweenness centrality is a measure of the distribution of agents’ betweenness

centrality in the network. In takes on the value 1 in the star network, the most centralized

8

Page 11: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

network possible. In a star network there is one center node through which all shortest paths

between any periphery nodes run. The measure takes on the value 0 in case of the complete

network, where everybody is linked with everybody else and, hence, all nodes are equally central

in the betweenness sense.

Table 2 shows that centrality is highest in the network of economic relations, followed by

support networks and networks through social public activities. Interestingly, friendship relations

are relatively low in centrality indicating that friendship ties run through a relatively equal

number of people. The low centrality of neighbor relations suggests that the housing village

structure is not star shaped.

In the sociological literature, network closure (i.e., clustering) is considered important for sus-

taining cooperation, trust, and pro-social behavior in general (cf. Coleman, 1988, 1990). Cluster-

ing coefficients are measures that reflect the extent to which two different nodes that are linked

to another common node are linked to each other. More formally, our clustering coefficient is

based on the notion of triples. A triple consists of three nodes that are connected by either

two (open triple) or three links (closed or transitive triple; sometimes also called triangle). The

network clustering coefficient reported in Table 2 is defined as the ratio of the number of closed

triples over the number of all (open and closed) triples in the network (cf. Newman, 2003).9

The last column in Table 2 reports the network clustering coefficient for the general relations

network as well as the specific network dimensions. It shows that also with respect to clustering

the specific networks differ substantially. Clustering is highest for friendship relations and lowest

for support and economic relations. The low clustering in the economic network in combination

with the high centrality and low density implies that there are only a few transitive relations

and only a few nodes that are economically important for the villagers. Friendship networks are

characterized by relatively high density and clustering but low centrality. Hence, in the sense of

Coleman (1990), they seem ideal for sustaining generosity.

The discussed network measures clearly indicate that networks differ across the different

network dimensions. An alternative way of inferring differences between different network di-

mensions is by examining their overlap. Table 3 shows the percentage of overlap between any

network dimension, measured at the dyad level. It indicates that the pair-wise overlap between

different network dimensions never reaches 50 percent. Furthermore, the overlaps between any

two dimensions widely differ and are highly asymmetric. Specifically, for any network dimension

a dyadic relationship often implies a friendship relation (cf. column Friendship in Table 3) but

not vice versa (cf. row Friendship in Table 3). There is an interesting and intuitive overlap

between support and neighbor relations. About a quarter of all support relations is between

9For completeness we report the number of open and closed triples in Appendix B.2, Table B.2.

9

Page 12: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

Table 3: Overlap of different network dimensions (in percent)

Friendship Support Neighbor Social-public Economic

Friendship 100 6.38 12.67 9.44 8.93

Support 42.93 100 25.54 10.33 15.76

Neighbor 40.15 12.02 100 5.12 5.37

Social-public 40.34 6.55 6.90 100 5.17

Economic 36.75 10.25 7.42 5.30 100

Note: In the table inclusion runs from the row relations to the column relations(for instance, only 6.38 percent of the friendship ties are also support ties, but42.93 percent of the support ties are also friendship ties). Hence, the overlapbetween any two dimensions does not need to be symmetric. Possible intra-household links between household heads are ignored.

neighbors. On the other hand, only about 12 percent of the neighbor relations are also support

relations. There exists also a large discrepancy between friendship ties and economic relations.

On the one hand, more then 36 percent of all economic relations are with friends, but only about

9 percent of all friendship ties also have an economic nature. In summary, the different network

dimensions only show a partial and highly asymmetric overlap and they strongly differ in the

network measures density, centrality and clustering. Figure 1 visualizes the differences between

the friendship network and the economic network. A visualization of all elicited networks can be

found in Appendix B.4.

The discussed differences in the network structures across the different network dimensions

are a result of differences in relations at the dyad level. Therefore, we expect to see these

differences being reflected when relating them to giving behavior in the dictator games, which

also takes plays at the dyad level.

(a) Friendship network (b) Economic network

Note: Household heads of the same household are placed next to each other.

Figure 1: Friendship network and economic network

10

Page 13: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

2.3 The Dictator Game Experiment: Design and Procedures

Each participating household head played six subsequent dictator games with different recipients.

The experimenter explained each participant in the role of a dictator that he or she would

sequentially receive six small cylinder-boxes each containing 20 coins of one Cordoba, c$ (the

Nicaraguan currency), which he or she could share with one other person. For each dictator the

first recipient was a stranger, that is, an unknown person from another village in the region.

The five subsequent recipients were randomly selected village members. The random selection

involved the dictator drawing cards out of a bag containing all 123 household heads. The name

of a recipient was drawn only after the dictator had finished the previous distribution decision.

Dictators were informed of the procedures before they made any decision and, hence, knew that

their maximum possible earnings would be c$ 120,- (USD 6.70 at the time of the experiment),

which corresponded to more than a two days average income in Nicaragua.10

We wanted to conduct the experiment with all households in the village and had to take care

that the chance of contagion and spill-over effects was minimized. Therefore, only one household

head per household was allowed to participate as a dictator. In case of a two-headed household it

was randomly determined who was asked to participate. We did not exclude participation of the

other household head in the role of receiver, but ensured that heads of the same household were

not matched as a dictator-receiver pair. In total 57 household heads participated as dictators.11

We organized the experiment in a decentralized way, by having Nicaraguan research assis-

tants individually visiting each participant at his or her home to conduct the experiment.12 To

minimize behavioral biases due to potential post-experimental side payments or social pressure

we implemented a one-way anonymity design. Each dictator was clearly made aware that, al-

though he or she knows the identity of the recipient, the recipient does not know and also will

not get to know who has distributed the money. When delivering the money to recipients we did

neither reveal the identity of the dictators, nor did we inform them about how many dictators

10We also considered to pay out only one randomly chosen decision, but decided against it because the explana-

tion and implementation of a relatively abstract randomization device would have been very time consuming and

may have also raised suspicion in our subjects who were not used to experiments.

11We targeted all 66 households, but of nine households no household heads were present at the day of the

experiment.

12In doing so we deviated from the often used protocol in studies with participants in small-scale societies,

where experiments are conducted centralized at a public spot (e.g., Cardenas et al., 2000; Henrich et al., 2004).

The reason not to use this standard is that we see some potential problems regarding experimental control coming

along with it. First, it is virtually impossible to avoid self-selection because some people are clearly more inclined

to participate in public events than others. Second, during such gatherings mutual influence among participants

is hard to control.

11

Page 14: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

had participated. Dictators and recipients did also not learn anything about others earnings. All

this was known by the dictators when they made their decisions.

To minimize experimenter effects due to the assistant’s presence we employed the following

three precautionary measures. First, all decisions were made in full privacy. As a rule participants

went inside their house or to a separate room when making a decision. If this was not possible

the assistant turned his or her back when the dictator was handling the coins. The dictators

were also instructed not to make any comments about their decisions. Second, after having taken

the coins they wanted to keep from the box, dictators had to fill the box with metal rings. This

ensured that the weight of the box remained constant irrespective of the amount of coins taken

out. Third, after each decision the box was sealed with tape. The decisions were recorded by

the assistants’ supervisor (one of the principal investigators) who did not have any interaction

with the participants. The dictators were aware of these procedural details before they made

any decisions.13

An important aspect in experiments is that participants trust the researchers. This is espe-

cially true in the field and when participants are not used to experiments. Therefore, to build

trust, we first conducted the household and network survey. This ensured that, when conducting

the experiment, the research assistants were already known to the local people. Another impor-

tant element was the support of the well-respected local community leaders, who presented our

team to each household and asked people to cooperate. After having finished the surveys, which

took four days, we immediately organized the experiment. By conducting the whole experiment

in only one day we minimized possible contagion and spill-over effects. Indeed, from the debrief-

ing we know that 94.5 percent of the participants did not talk about the experiment with other

village members who had already participated before. In addition, the research assistants were

asked to make a subjective evaluation about the participant’s dedication, trust and understand-

ing of the experiment. We did not notice any problems that could have affected the dictators’

decisions.

3 Empirical Results - Generosity and Networks

In this section we report first on dictators’ behavior in the experiment. Thereafter, we explore

with descriptive and regression analyses whether and how individual and network characteristics

are related to giving behavior. Finally, we investigate how individual characteristics influence

network formation and, hence, indirectly giving behavior.

13For more details we refer the reader to the experimental instructions in Appendix A.3. A video showing a

typical decision situation in the experiment can be found here: download and play video.

12

Page 15: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

3.1 Generosity in the Dictator Game

Figure 2a shows the distribution of coins given to village recipients taking all 285 decisions into

account. It shows a dominant mode at the equal split of 10 coins and a second (much smaller)

mode at the selfish decision of 0 coins. What is intriguing is the relatively large share of decisions

where recipients received more than 50 percent of the endowment of 20 coins. The average share

left to recipients is with 48 percent (9.6 coins) also higher than what is mostly observed in

laboratory dictator games. The relatively small size of the community where our experiment was

conducted together with the fact that dictators got to know the names of the recipients when

making their decisions may account for this ‘super fair’ behavior. Indeed, Bohnet and Frey

(1999) showed that revealing the identity of the recipient significantly increases dictator giving

and Henrich et al. (2005) also observe ‘super fair’ proposals in ultimatum game experiments in

some of their investigated small-scale societies.

mean = 9.6 st.dev. = 4.58

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

Per

cent

0 5 10 15 20coins to village recipient

.

(a) Village recipient

mean = 0.4 st.dev. = 4.63

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35P

erce

nt

−10 −5 0 5 10coins to village recipient − coins to stranger

Note: bars to the extreme left and right summarize observation smaller −10 and larger +10

(b) Difference with stranger

Figure 2: Dictator game giving

Besides the five distribution decisions regarding different village recipients our dictators also

had to make a decision regarding a stranger in another village. We consider this dictator giving to

the stranger as ‘baseline’ or ‘general’ generosity (for a similar approach, see Leider et al., 2009).

On average 9.2 coins (46 percent) are left for the stranger. Although, this is only little less than

the average left for village recipients, it does not imply that village recipients and strangers were

treated similarly. Actually, quite the contrary happened. Figure 2b shows the distribution of

differences in coins left to village recipients and strangers. Although, there is a mode at zero, in

the large majority of cases (78.2 percent) dictators give different amounts to village recipients

and strangers. In addition, the distribution shows an intriguing symmetry indicating that village

members receive as often less than strangers as they receive more. Thus, social proximity in

terms of living in the same village does not necessarily imply better treatment than any stranger

13

Page 16: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

would receive. This observation casts new light on the idea of and evidence on in-group favoritism

(see, e.g., Efferson et al., 2008; Chen and Li, 2009). In particular, it indicates that favoritism is

not per-se towards own group members but only towards specific members in the own group. In

addition, it also suggests that social ties are not necessarily positive but may have a negative

load as identified by van Dijk et al. (2002).

We also find quite some variation in giving behavior within the same dictator. Only six

dictators gave the same amount to all village members. Five of them chose the equal split and

one left 8 coins to each recipient. Only four of them gave also the same amount to the stranger.

3.2 Explaining Patterns of Generosity - Individual Characteristics and Net-

work Effects

Although the correlation between giving to the stranger and average (per dictator) giving to

village recipients is positive and significant (Pearson correlation coefficient = 0.674, p < 0.001,

two-sided test), the large variation in giving to these distinct groups of recipients indicates that

general generosity alone is insufficient to explain the complex pattern of giving behavior. In

this section we examine whether observable individual characteristics, network structures and

network positions can account for the observed pattern in generosity directed towards village

members.

We expect differential influences of the different network dimensions on directed generosity

and, thus, investigate the individual and network effects on dictator giving separately for general

relations as well as the various specific relations. Table 4 shows descriptive statistics of dictator

giving as a function of social geodesic distance (i.e., the shortest path) between the dictator and

the recipients for the different relations. Although, absolute differences are small the figures

reported in the table clearly indicate that dictator giving differs across social distances within

a network dimension as well as across network dimensions. However, there are also some simi-

larities. For all relations (except neighbors) dictator giving to directly linked recipients (i.e., at

distance 1) is more generous than giving to strangers. In addition, in most network dimensions

there is also a social distance effect in that direct relations receive more than indirect relations.

This effect is most pronounced for friendship and support relations but absent in neighbor and

economic networks. Interestingly, except for the support network, there seems to be no clear

monotonic relationship between generosity and social distance beyond distance 2.

The reported averages may hide considerable heterogeneity in giving behavior, though. In-

deed, the standard deviations depicted in Table 4 reveal that dictator giving strongly varies

across social distances and network dimensions. To pin down determinants that can explain

these variations we conduct regression analyses. In particular, we estimate regression models that

14

Page 17: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

Table 4: Dictator giving and social distance in different networks

Social geodesic distance of

Network dimension Stranger 1 2 3 4 ≥5

General 9.18 10.07 9.29 9.00

(5.43) (4.40) (4.70) -

[57] [114] [170] [1]

Friendship 9.18 10.80 9.26 9.83

(5.43) (4.80) (4.52) (4.30)

[57] [54] [207] [24]

Support 9.18 11.00 9.90 9.78 9.66 8.66

(5.43) (5.72) (5.25) (4.84) (4.24) (3.59)

[57] [12] [48] [95] [74] [56]

Neighbora 9.18 9.15 10.20 9.44 9.87 5.80

(5.43) (3.98) (4.58) (4.44) (4.66) (5.53)

[57] [20] [80] [112] [63] [10]

Social-publica 9.18 10.35 10.24 8.72 10.05 9.64

(5.43) (4.69) (4.52) (4.83) (3.99) (4.42)

[57] [17] [84] [89] [20] [75]

Economica 9.18 9.67 9.98 9.08 9.40 9.59

(5.43) (5.33) (4.65) (4.74) (2.95) (4.54)

[57] [15] [121] [83] [20] [46]

Note: For each network dimension the first row shows the average numberof coins left to the stranger and the village recipients at different distances,respectively; standard deviations in parentheses; number of observationsin brackets; a possible intra-household links between household heads areignored.

incorporate observable individual characteristics of dictators and recipients, the social distances

between them, dictators’ general generosity, and (local) network characteristics. Specifically, we

estimate the following OLS model:14

Yij = α + βXij + eij , (1)

where Yij denotes the amount of coins dictator i gave to recipient j, α is the intercept, X ij

denotes the vector of explanatory variables which we will discuss in detail below, and eij is

an error term. In the experiment, each dictator made giving decisions regarding five different

village recipients. Due to the presence of specific factors common to all observations involving

a particular dictator, our observations may not be assumed to be independent, implying that

E [eij , eik] 6= 0 for all k. Further, different dictators may have been asked to make a distribution

14We also estimated a Tobit regression model with lower censoring set at zero. Due to the few censored

observations (see Figure 2a) outcomes do not significantly differ from the reported results.

15

Page 18: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

decision with the same recipient, implying that E [eij , ekj ] 6= 0 for all k. To correct standard

errors for these dependencies we apply clustering on both dimensions separately (for a formal

discussion of this issue, see e.g., Fafchamps and Gubert, 2007; Cameron et al., 2010).

Our strategy in estimating individual and network related determinants of dictator giving is

the following. In a first model we include individual characteristics that are likely to influence

dictator giving as explanatory variables. In a second model we control for general generosity,

measured by the number of coins given to the stranger. Finally, in a third and fourth model, we

add social distance and two structural network variables related to closure (Coleman, 1988) and

brokerage (Burt, 2005) as explanatory variables for directed generosity.

In Model 1 we control for gender, age and wealth, for both the dictator and the recipient,

because previous studies have found some evidence that these traits influence pro-social behav-

ior (see, e.g., Eckel and Grossman, 1998; Andreoni and Vesterlund, 2001; Croson and Gneezy,

2009, on gender, List, 2004; Egas and Riedl, 2008, on age, and Eckel and Grossman, 1996;

Branas-Garza, 2006; Cappelen et al., 2008, on wealth). In addition, we also control for the

level of education, years of residence in the village, and the frequency of contact with the nearest

urban center. We also include the differences in these characteristics between the dictator and the

recipient as explanatory variables, in order to capture potential homophily effects. Homophily,

i.e. the tendency to join up disproportionately with similar people, is widely documented in the

sociological literature (see, e.g., McPherson et al., 2001) and it seems not unlikely that people

with similar characteristics are more generous to each other.

In the regression we take female dictator giving to male recipients as the benchmark. The

variables Male→Female, Male→Male, and Female→Female, are dummy variables for the

remaining dictator-recipient combinations, where the first (second) term indicates the gender

of the dictator (recipient). We control for the age of the dictator (Age D) and the absolute

difference in age between the dictator and the recipient (Age ∆). In a similar way, we also control

for the education level of the dictator (Education D) and the absolute difference in education

between the dictator and the recipient (Education ∆), both measured in years of schooling; the

dictator’s years of residence in the village (Residence D) and its absolute difference between the

dictator and the recipient (Residence ∆); and the dictator’s frequency of contact with the nearest

urban center (Urban D), measured as the number of visits in the most recent month before the

interview, and its absolute difference between the dictator and the recipient (Urban ∆).

Clearly, the wealth of the involved agents may play an important role in dictator giving. We

control for this by using dummy variables indicating whether the household of the dictator and

the recipient own cattle and land, respectively.15 In the regressions we take rich households, that

15In the region where the village is located both cattle and land are the most important economic assets and good

16

Page 19: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

is, those where both the dictator and the recipient household own cattle and land, respectively, as

benchmarks. The variables Cattle→NoCattle, NoCattle→Cattle, and NoCattle→NoCattle

are dummy variables for the dictator-recipient pairs where the dictator household owns cattle but

the recipient household does not, the dictator household does not own cattle but the recipient

household does, and both households do not own cattle, respectively. The variables for land are

defined analogously and denoted by Land→NoLand, NoLand→Land, and NoLand→NoLand.

In addition, we also control for whether the decision number in the sequence of the decisions of

a dictator affects giving by including decision fixed effects (Decision#).

In Model 2, we add the amount of coins given to the stranger (GiveStranger) as explanatory

variable. In this way we isolate the effect of general generosity on directed generosity. We expect

that general generosity positively affects directed generosity, but that this relation is not one-

to-one. In Model 3, we study the role of social (geodesic) distance between the dictator and

the recipient by adding a dummy variable (Distant) that takes value 0 when the dictator and

recipient are directly linked, and 1 otherwise.16 The existing studies on student friendship ties

found a positive effect of social closeness on directed generosity. Here we explore whether this

effect can also be found in our very different subject pool, and whether it carries over to specific

networks that are not based on friendships.

Finally, in our Model 4, we add more sophisticated structural network variables that may

influence directed generosity but have not been systematically studied before. First, according to

Coleman (1990) closure (i.e., clustering) facilitates pro-social behavior. Closure is a measure for

how densely a node is embedded in his or her local network. Practically it is defined as the extent

to which any two nodes who are linked to a common node are also linked to each other. Therefore,

to explore the effect of the level of closure around dictators and recipients on generosity, we add,

for dictators and recipients separately, a variable defined as the number of transitive relations

of length 3 (i.e., triangles) they are embedded in. The variables are denoted Closure D and

Closure R for dictators and recipients, respectively. Figure 3 illustrates these variables. Based

on Coleman’s (1990) argument we expect a positive relationship between Closure D and dictator

giving. Whether a dictator will also give more to a recipient who is embedded in a dense cluster

is less clear. On the one hand, recipients who are embedded in dense clusters may be viewed as

pro-social, which could trigger higher dictator giving to such recipients. On the other hand, it is

proxies for the actual wealth of a household. We use dummy variables because more than half of the households

does not own any cattle and almost two-thirds does not own land.

16To test the robustness of the regression results concerning this discrete specification of closeness in the network,

we also estimated an alternative continuous specification. There we replaced the dummy with the inverse squared

distance. All regression results reported below are robust with respect to this alternative specification; see Table B.3

in Appendix B.3 .

17

Page 20: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

B

J

H

G K

M

L

P

I

Q

N

C

D

Dictator A Recipient F

O

E

Note: In the figure all lines represent ties among individuals indicated by letters A through Q. The solidlines originating at Dictator A and Recipient F indicate the transitive relations of length 3 (triangles) ofthese individuals. In the example Closure A = 2 and Closure F = 3.

Figure 3: Illustration of the regression variables Closure D and Closure R

also perceivable that more isolated recipients are viewed as more needy, which may also induce

higher dictator giving. Therefore, we have a priori no clear hypothesis for the sign of Closure R.

Second, Burt (1992, 2005) argues that an agent can pursue her self-interest better if she can

control many other nodes because they have to use her as a ‘broker’ to reach each other (cf.

our discussion in Section 2.2 on betweenness centrality). To examine if there is an influence

of network brokerage on directed generosity in the network we add the variables Centrality D

and Centrality R which are the normalized betweenness centrality measures for the dictator

and recipient, respectively. Based on Burt’s (2005) arguments we expect that for dictators

higher centrality is associated with less dictator giving. We also hypothesize that more central

recipients are receiving higher amounts than less central ones, because betweenness centrality is

likely associated with status and probably power in the village.17

An important aspect of our study is that we have elicited data for a general as well as various

specific networks. When comparing results across the different network dimensions our null

hypothesis is that the individual and network effects do not differ. Alternatively, because the

network structures differ and the ties carry a very different content, one may expect differential

influences of the network variables on directed generosity.

17One may argue that a positive effect of centrality on directed generosity could be an indirect result of being

more generous in general, because this may lead to having more links (e.g., friends) and, hence, to a more

central position in the network. Note, however, that we avoid this issue by controlling for general generosity

(GiveStranger) in the regressions.

18

Page 21: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

Table 5 shows the regression results of all four models for the network of general relations.

The results for model 1, where only observable individual characteristics and decision fixed effects

are taken into account, show a strong and probably surprising gender effect. In our sample female

dictators give significantly less to male village recipients than male dictators give to male and

female recipients. This is in stark contrast to other studies on gender and generosity which

report that women tend to be more generous than men (see, e.g., Eckel and Grossman, 1998;

Konow et al., 2008 and Croson and Gneezy, 2009, for a recent survey). The coefficients of the

variables Male→Female and Male→Male show that both, female and male, recipients receive

2.4 and 2.9 coins, respectively, more from male dictators than male recipients receive from female

dictators. At the same time female dictators also tend to give more to female recipients than to

male recipients, indicating that not only the dictator’s gender affects giving but also the gender

of the recipient. This gender effect is robust across all model specifications (see Table 5 models

2-4).

Age, education and duration of residence in the village do not exert any significant influence on

dictator giving. The frequency of contact with the urban center increases dictator giving, which

is consistent with the finding of Henrich et al. (2005) that stronger market integration tends to

foster pro-sociality. Interestingly, if dictator and recipient differ in the frequency of contact with

the urban center dictator giving decreases. Yet, a larger Urban D could be related to a larger

perceived or actual proximity to strangers and a larger Urban ∆ with a larger social distance

between dictator and recipient. If this is the case, the significant results for these variables

may not be robust. A preview of Models 2 and 3 in Table 5 indeed reveals that adding the

explanatory variables capturing general generosity (GiveStranger) and social distance (Distant)

nullifies these urban contact effects. Some of the wealth variables show interesting and intuitive

(marginally) significant effects. Poor dictators, those who do not own cattle, give about 2 coins

less to recipients than rich dictators, who own cattle, give to rich recipients. However, also these

wealth effects turn out not to be robust when controlling for general generosity, social distance

and other network effects.

Model 2 shows a positive relation between general generosity (GiveStranger) and directed

generosity towards village members. Dictators who give one coin more to the stranger give on

average a little less than half a coin more to recipients in the network. The results for this variable

in Models 3 and 4 also show that it is a robust effect. Note also, that adding general generosity as

an explanatory variable makes the coefficients of all observable characteristics — except gender

— statistically insignificant. Hence, even the widely varying individual characteristics in our

sample do not add to the explanation of the inter-individual variation in directed generosity.

19

Page 22: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

Table 5: Determinants of directed generosity in the general relations network

Dependent variable: Coins given to village recipient

Only individual Giving to Social distance Network variables

characteristics stranger added added added

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4

Male→Female 2.385** (1.173) 2.363*** (0.843) 2.387*** (0.850) 3.059*** (1.128)

Male→Male 2.873** (1.197) 2.794*** (0.887) 2.573*** (0.908) 3.089*** (1.060)

Female→Female 1.056* (0.619) 1.296** (0.617) 1.253** (0.632) 1.411* (0.824)

Age D 0.049 (0.063) 0.049 (0.043) 0.049 (0.042) 0.042 (0.043)

Age ∆ −0.030 (0.022) −0.002 (0.023) −0.001 (0.022) 0.002 (0.020)

Education D 0.004 (0.206) 0.015 (0.135) 0.010 (0.133) 0.042 (0.140)

Education ∆ 0.056 (0.079) −0.029 (0.074) −0.033 (0.074) −0.050 (0.087)

Residence D −0.064 (0.044) −0.039 (0.030) −0.042 (0.030) −0.032 (0.027)

Residence ∆ 0.007 (0.025) −0.008 (0.022) −0.003 (0.022) −0.006 (0.023)

Urban D 0.371** (0.182) 0.128 (0.136) 0.125 (0.134) 0.069 (0.150)

Urban ∆ −0.161*** (0.037) −0.078 (0.050) −0.083 (0.051) −0.073 (0.051)

Cattle→NoCattle −0.465 (0.764) −0.352 (0.614) −0.277 (0.612) −0.205 (0.629)

NoCattle→Cattle −2.005* (1.147) −0.991 (0.710) −0.977 (0.724) −0.554 (0.769)

NoCattle→NoCattle −1.737* (1.025) −0.600 (0.888) −0.637 (0.895) −0.337 (0.819)

Land→NoLand −0.476 (1.110) −0.444 (0.869) −0.333 (0.921) −0.213 (0.916)

NoLand→Land −1.096 (1.560) −0.564 (1.004) −0.464 (1.011) −0.656 (1.038)

NoLand→NoLand −1.216 (1.402) −0.596 (1.019) −0.540 (1.027) −0.822 (1.006)

Distant −0.827* (0.461) −0.938* (0.520)

Closure D −0.003 (0.003)

Centrality D 1.436 (1.214)

Closure R 0.001 (0.001)

Centrality R −0.470 (0.522)

GiveStranger 0.474*** (0.086) 0.474*** (0.086) 0.452*** (0.086)

Decision#a n.s. n.s. n.s. n.s.

Constant 9.450*** (3.458) 3.762 (3.025) 4.301 (2.891) 4.799* (2.903)

R2 0.1691 0.4313 0.4382 0.4498

F-statistics 3.07 9.45 9.12 8.62

Prob > F 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

No. of obs. 273 273 273 273

Note: ***, **, * indicate two-sided significance levels at 1, 5, and 10 percent, respectively; a ... decision fixedeffects are not significant (n.s.); robust standard errors (in parentheses) are obtained by means of two-wayclustering at the level of dictators (57 clusters) and recipients (91 clusters).

20

Page 23: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

The coefficient estimate of the variable Distant in Model 3 shows that there is a marginally

significant negative effect of not being directly linked to a recipient. Recipients who are further

than one link away from the dictator receive on average almost one coin less than recipients who

are directly connected. Model 4 shows that this social distance effect is robust to the addition

of the structural network variables closure and centrality. The network variables themselves are

all insignificant, however (Table 5, Model 4). These insignificances are likely due to the little

variation these variables show across nodes in the general relations network, which is relatively

dense and where almost all nodes are less than three steps apart (cf. Table 4).

Existing studies report mostly insignificant effects of structural network variables in friend-

ship networks of students (cf. Leider et al., 2009; Branas-Garza et al., 2010; Goeree et al., 2010).

This, together with our result of insignificant effects in the general relations network, makes it a

priori unlikely that we will detect any network effects in our specific networks. In the following,

we present the estimation results for each specific network separately, where we focus on the

full fledged model (Model 4). Table 6 shows the regression results for the friendship, support,

social-public activities, and economic network. The results shown in the table reveal four main

insights. First, gender and general generosity are important explanatory variables for directed

generosity independent of the network dimension. Second, observable individual characteristics

other than gender have no or negligible explanatory power in any specific network. Third, social

distance is important only in the friendship network. Fourth, structural network variables play

a significant role in determining giving behavior but the effects clearly differ across the different

specific networks.

More specifically, in all investigated network dimensions female dictators give between 2.4

and 3.1 coins less to male recipients than male dictators do (cf. Male→Male). Moreover, male

dictators give between 1.5 coins and 2.5 coins more to female recipients than female dictators

give to male recipients (cf. Male → Female). The other variables controlling for individual

characteristics are insignificant. The only exception is that in the social-public activities net-

work poor dictators give marginally significantly less to rich recipients than rich dictators do (cf.

NoCattle→Cattle). Overall, and in line with other studies (e.g., Camerer, 2003), the power of

observable individual characteristics in explaining variations in generosity appears very limited.

Indeed, a log-likelihood ratio test, comparing the model with only individual characteristics as

explanatory variables with the reported full model shows that the fit of the latter is signifi-

cantly better (p < 0.0001) for all investigated network dimensions. As in the network of general

relations, general generosity (GiveStranger) is a strong albeit imperfect predictor of directed

generosity in all specific networks. In each network dimension, an additional coin given to the

stranger increases generosity towards the network recipient by a little less than half a coin.

21

Page 24: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

Table 6: Determinants of directed generosity in specific networks

Dependent variable: Coins given to village recipient

Friendship Support Social-public Economic

Male→Female 2.436** (1.179) 2.372*** (0.794) 2.488*** (0.861) 1.512* (0.862)

Male→Male 3.082*** (1.078) 2.793*** (0.900) 2.976*** (0.890) 2.382*** (0.887)

Female→Female 0.708 (0.836) 1.377** (0.651) 1.329** (0.616) 1.081* (0.639)

Age D 0.059 (0.042) 0.058 (0.044) 0.041 (0.045) 0.050 (0.044)

Age ∆ 0.008 (0.022) 0.001 (0.024) −0.004 (0.023) 0.004 (0.022)

Education D 0.038 (0.118) 0.047 (0.143) −0.027 (0.152) −0.044 (0.133)

Education ∆ −0.021 (0.081) −0.016 (0.079) −0.004 (0.078) 0.006 (0.076)

Residence D −0.043 (0.031) −0.037 (0.029) −0.035 (0.031) −0.036 (0.029)

Residence ∆ −0.012 (0.023) −0.008 (0.022) −0.004 (0.021) −0.005 (0.023)

Urban D 0.012 (0.132) 0.151 (0.131) 0.144 (0.143) 0.130 (0.133)

Urban ∆ −0.079 (0.049) −0.062 (0.045) −0.078 (0.048) −0.066 (0.047)

Cattle→NoCattle −0.331 (0.627) −0.364 (0.650) −0.361 (0.655) −0.327 (0.641)

NoCattle→Cattle −0.917 (0.735) −0.880 (0.716) −1.231* (0.744) −0.650 (0.760)

NoCattle→NoCattle −0.421 (0.857) −0.546 (0.926) −0.735 (0.970) −0.304 (0.868)

Land→NoLand −0.076 (0.869) −0.356 (0.876) −0.404 (0.906) −0.465 (0.928)

NoLand→Land −0.134 (0.946) −0.128 (1.065) −0.715 (1.010) −0.684 (1.004)

NoLand→NoLand −0.468 (0.899) 0.018 (1.131) −0.659 (1.035) −0.917 (0.992)

Distant −1.304** (0.660) −0.094 (0.962) 0.630 (1.085) 0.766 (0.862)

Closure D −0.011* (0.006) 0.294* (0.168) −0.020 (0.035) −0.152* (0.080)

Centrality D 0.791** (0.305) −0.189 (0.129) 0.290 (0.402) 0.510*** (0.186)

Closure R −0.004 (0.004) 0.134 (0.117) 0.023** (0.011) 0.068** (0.034)

Centrality R 0.050 (0.229) −0.122 (0.094) −0.099** (0.047) −0.157 (0.098)

GiveStranger 0.432*** (0.087) 0.461*** (0.083) 0.475*** (0.087) 0.454*** (0.086)

Decision#a n.s. n.s. n.s. n.s.

Constant 5.562* (2.929) 3.384 (2.873) 3.243 (3.670) 3.271 (2.694)

R2 0.4627 0.4474 0.4405 0.4915

F-statistics 10.99 9.29 8.20 13.96

Prob > F 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

No. of obs. 273 273 273 273

Note: ***, **, * indicate two-sided significance levels at 1, 5, and 10 percent, respectively; a ... decision fixedeffects are not significant (n.s.); robust standard errors (in parentheses) are obtained by means of two-wayclustering at the level of dictators (57 clusters) and recipients (91 clusters).

In the friendship network social distance has a significant effect on directed generosity. Recip-

ients who are not direct friends receive on average 1.3 coins less than direct friends. Surprisingly,

closure and centrality show (marginally) significant signs opposite to those expected. Note,

however, that the effect of Closure D, although statistically marginally significant, is extremely

22

Page 25: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

small. The significantly positive coefficient of betweenness centrality indicates that structurally

more powerful dictators tend to be more generous. This is in contrast to Burt’s conjecture that

such positions are taken by people who pursue their self-interest. A plausible, albeit speculative,

explanation for our result is that in small-scale societies power tends to be connected to clien-

telism, which can only be maintained if resources are also transferred to the dependent client

(Wolf, 1977).18 If our villagers bring this logic to the experiment, structurally powerful dictators

may more strongly feel the responsibility to share with others than less powerful dictators do.19

The network variables relating to the recipient are insignificant.

In contrast to the friendship network, in the support network social distance does not play a

significant role in explaining dictator giving. Instead the structural network measure Closure D

has a relatively large positive coefficient, which is also marginally significant. This result is

consistent with Coleman’s idea that network clustering fosters pro-social behavior. That this

network variable has a positive influence in support networks, which are used to help each other,

is also very intuitive. All other network variables are insignificant.

In the network created through social-public activities it is only the recipients’ network mea-

sures that exhibit statistical significant effects on the dictators’ giving decisions. The negative

sign of Centrality R indicates that receivers that are more central and, hence, more powerful in

this network receive less than those who are less powerful. At the same time, the positive sign of

Closure R shows that those who are embedded in a denser cluster receive more from dictators

than those only loosely embedded. Note, however, that the size of these effects is relatively small.

Finally, in the network of economic relations social distance does again not affect dictator

giving. However, structural network variables related to the dictator and the recipient do have

(marginally) significant effects on directed generosity. Dictators who are more strongly embedded

in tight economic relationships tend to give less and those being more central give more to

recipients. The former suggests that in dense economic clusters there is less room for generosity,

probably because these economic relationships are based on contractual relations and not on

generosity. As in the friendship network, the latter effect may be explained by power (i.e.,

18At first sight it may seem peculiar to talk about clientelism in friendship networks, but often the difference

between friendship and clientelism is blurred. An interesting historical example for this is provided in Cole (2007)

where it is shown how the friendship between Maffeo Barberini and Michelangelo Buonarroti the Younger slowly

developed into a patron-client relation.

19Branas-Garza et al. (2010) also find a positive effect of betweenness centrality on dictator giving. These

authors’ interpret betweenness centrality as a measure of social integration and conclude that social integration

fosters generosity. We do not follow this interpretation, because the sociological network literature does not suggest

that betweenness centrality captures social integration. According to Wasserman and Faust (1994, p. 189) it rather

measures the “’interpersonal influence’ on others (...) [and] the strategic importance of locations on geodesics.”

23

Page 26: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

centrality in the network) being closely related to clientelism. The regression results also show

that the stronger a recipient is embedded in tight economic relations the more she receives from

dictators. A possible reason for this effect is that having many tight business ties signals many

alternative trading opportunities.

In summary, the results of this section show that, except for gender, observable characteristics

on the individual as well as dyad level do not have explanatory power for dictator giving to recip-

ients, neither in the network of general relations nor in any of the specific networks. Regarding

gender it is surprisingly the female dictators who give less than male dictators. This strongly

contrasts with lab dictator game experiments where either no gender effects are found or where it

is observed that female dictators are more generous than male dictators (cf. Croson and Gneezy,

2009, for a recent survey). A possible reconciliation for this contrasting results is that exper-

iments where a positive female gender effect was found were all conducted in rich countries,

mainly using student subjects. Young female students in these countries are, however, hardly

comparable to relatively poor adult female household heads in rural areas of poor countries

in the South. Indeed, there is some evidence from developing countries that income in female

hands substantially increases children’s health and also increases food shares (Thomas, 1990;

Hoddinott and Haddad, 1995). Therefore, our female dictators may rather have kept the money

for household spending purposes than to give it away.

In contrast to the observable individual characteristics general generosity and the network

variables do explain variation in dictator giving. Importantly, while general generosity exhibits

a significant effect independent of the investigated network, the effect of social distance and the

structural network variables are not constant across networks of different dimensions. In line

with studies examining only friendship networks among students and pupils we find that social

distance matters in friendship networks. Importantly, however, we do not find such an effect

for any other network dimension, implying that social distance may matter only in friendship

networks. Furthermore, structural network variables regarding the dictator and the recipient

are clearly related to dictator giving. However, the actual effects and even the signs of these

variables change across the different specific networks. Hence, for explaining directed generosity

it clearly matters what network one is looking at.

3.3 Determinants of network formation

In the previous section we showed that observable individual characteristics cease to explain

directed generosity, once we control for general generosity, social distance and structural network

variables. However, there may exist an indirect effect of individual characteristics on dictator

giving via network formation. For instance, Glaeser et al. (2002) have shown that such charac-

24

Page 27: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

teristics can explain variations in individuals’ social capital. Since social and economic links can

also be considered as a form of social capital (cf. Lin, 1999) we expect to find an effect of these

variables on the likelihood that ties between nodes exist.

To investigate network formation we explore determinants of linking choices in the following

way. For each network dimension, except neighbor relations, we examine a regression model

that estimates the probability Pij of an undirected link between each pair of nodes ij as a

function of observable characteristics at the individual node level and the dyad level. Let Zi

and Zj be vectors of specific individual characteristics (age, wealth, etc.) of nodes i and j.

For each dyad ij we take the sum, Zi + Zj, as well as the absolute value of the difference,

|Zi −Zj |, as explanatory variables for link formation. The former, denoted by Z Σ, measures a

possible level effect of characteristics whereas the latter, denoted be Z ∆, measures the effect of

a difference in attributes. For Z ∆ we expect to find significantly negative effects because of a

human tendency to team up with similar others, a phenomenon documented extensively in the

sociological literature (see, e.g., McPherson et al., 2001, for a survey). In addition, let W ij be

the vector of other characteristics that may relate nodes i and j, such as being neighbors, having

the same or different gender, etc.

Formally, we estimate the following logistic regression model:20

logit(Pij) = ln

(

Pij

1 − Pij

)

= α + β1|Zi − Zj | + β2 (Zi + Zj) + γW ij . (2)

As explanatory variables we include the same set of observable characteristics as in the

models of the previous section: gender, age, years of education, years of residence in the village,

frequency of contacts to the urban center, possession of cattle and land. In addition, we also

control for being linked by neighborhood at various distances. To study gender, wealth and

neighborhood effects we take male-male dyads, dyads where both nodes possess cattle and land,

and direct neighbors, respectively, as benchmarks. In the regressions, we consider all potential

links between the 123 household heads, save intra-household links.

Table 7 shows the results for friendship and support relations, for relations through social

public activities, and for economic relations. The overall picture is that some observable charac-

teristics are indeed important for link formation throughout all network dimensions, while others

play a role only for some networks, and a third set turns out to be completely unrelated with

link formation in all dimensions.

For all network dimensions, except economic relations, the likelihood of a link between a

female and a male node (Female↔Male) is highly significantly smaller than between two male

20Dyadic observations involving the same node can not be considered independent, that is E [eij , eik] 6= 0 for

all k, and E [eij , ekj ] 6= 0 for all k. To correct standard errors for these dependencies we apply clustering on both

dimensions separately (Cameron et al., 2010; Fafchamps and Gubert, 2007).

25

Page 28: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

Table 7: Determinants of network formation

Dependent variable: likelihood of link between any two nodes ij

Friendship Support Social-public Economic

Female↔Male −1.354*** (0.154) −0.657*** (0.248) −0.729*** (0.235) −0.486* (0.250)

Female↔Female −1.495*** (0.251) −0.414 (0.403) −0.661* (0.385)* −0.150 (0.594)

Age Σ 0.004 (0.006) 0.001 (0.006) 0.014 (0.009) 0.011 (0.010)

Age ∆ −0.009* (0.005) −0.025** (0.012) −0.046*** (0.008) −0.011 (0.014)

Education Σ 0.047** (0.020) −0.018 (0.032) 0.070* (0.041) 0.008 (0.027)

Education ∆ −0.006 (0.017) 0.004 (0.031) 0.047* (0.027) 0.013 (0.028)

Residence Σ 0.006 (0.005) −0.010 (0.010) −0.005 (0.006) −0.012 (0.011)

Residence ∆ −0.008 (0.005) −0.005 (0.013) −0.001 (0.009) 0.009 (0.011)

Urban Σ 0.040 (0.026) −0.010 (0.059) 0.043 (0.037) 0.140*** (0.041)

Urban ∆ −0.048** (0.024) −0.005 (0.060) −0.079** (0.037) −0.104** (0.044)

Cattle↔NoCattle −0.368** (0.147) −0.199 (0.422) −0.029 (0.336) −0.671** (0.274)

NoCattle↔NoCattle −0.570** (0.268) −1.068* (0.578) −0.321 (0.511) −2.007*** (0.662)

Land↔NoLand 0.104 (0.214) 0.013 (0.532) −0.338 (0.427) 1.031* (0.552)

NoLand↔NoLand 0.322 (0.328) 0.001 (0.643) −0.346 (0.599) 1.627* (0.840)

Neighbor Dist2 −0.982*** (0.176) −1.523*** (0.292) 0.025 (0.227) 0.010 (0.338)

Neighbor Dist3 −1.053*** (0.185) −1.708*** (0.302) 0.015 (0.310) −0.186 (0.327)

Neighbor Dist4 −1.294*** (0.227) −1.794*** (0.420)2 −0.220 (0.389) −0.437 (0.326)

Neighbor Dist> 4 −1.942*** (0.315) −2.973*** (0.536) −0.366 (0.567) −0.365 (0.441)

Constant −0.089 (0.781) −0.038 (1.080) −3.021** (1.238) −3.716*** (1.258)

LR χ2 482.95 98.17 118.71 151.33

Prob > χ2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

No. of obs. 4809 4809 4809 4809

Note: ***, **, * indicate two-sided significance levels at 1, 5, and 10 percent, respectively; x↔y assumes value 1

if in a dyad ij node i has characteristic x (y) and j has characteristic y (x), 0 otherwise. Robust standard errors

(in parentheses) are obtained by means of two-way clustering at the dyad level (97 clusters).

nodes. For the economic network this effect is only marginally significant. In the friendship net-

work also ties between two women (Female↔Female) are significantly less likely than between

two men. For social-public relations this effect is still marginally significant, but insignificant for

support and economic relations. Hence, when it comes to link formation gender effects are most

pronounced in the social sphere (friendship relations) but basically non-existent in the business

sphere (economic relations).

Age does not have a level effect, but nodes closer in age are significantly more likely to have

support and social-public links. The latter effect is also marginally significant for friendship ties

but insignificant for economic relations. This suggests that age homophily is relevant for the more

social relations but not for the business-like network. Education, on the other hand, exerts a

significant level effect in the friendship network and a marginally significant effect in the network

of social-public relations. This indicates that better educated people have more friendship ties

and meet more often at social and public events than lower educated ones. The social-public

26

Page 29: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

network is the only network where differences in education exert a (marginally) significant effect

on tie formation. The positive sign probably indicates that such public events play an integrative

role as it makes villagers with different socio-economic characteristics meet each other.

The frequency of contact with the nearest urban center exerts a strong level effect on the

formation of the economic network in the village. People who visit the urban center more often

are also more likely to have business-like relations. Intuitively this makes sense because many

visits to the urban center have a business background. Regarding the frequency of visits to the

urban center, there is also an interesting and strong homophily effect for economic, friendship

and social-public relations. The likelihood of having a tie in these networks gets significantly

larger the smaller the differences in frequencies of visits of the urban center becomes.

The variables approximating wealth are important for forming friendship ties and economic

relations. Relative to wealthy dyads, especially those owning cattle, the chance of a friendship or

economic link is significantly smaller for dyads consisting of a poor and wealthy node. Moreover,

a dyad of two poor nodes is also significantly less likely to have friendship and economic links

than wealthy dyads. This clearly indicates that being poor is strongly associated with exclusion

from social and economic networks.

Finally, we observe that the likelihood of a friendship and a support link significantly decreases

with the distance along the neighbor dimension. This indicates that friendship and support

relations are more likely among close neighbors than among villagers at larger distances.

In summary, we find that many observable characteristics have a significant and intuitive ef-

fect on network formation. Yet, the set of variables with explanatory power only partly overlaps

for the specific networks. Among the different network dimensions the formation of economic

relations appears most ‘rational’ in the sense that mainly economically relevant characteristics

exert a significant effect on link formation. In contrast, tie formation in the more social di-

mensions, especially friendship and support ties, are more strongly influenced by non-economic

variables like age, education, gender and being neighbors. With respect to generosity, the results

in this section strongly suggest that some observable individual characteristics, while not having

a direct effect as shown in Section 3.2, may still exert an indirect influence through their effect

on network formation.

4 Summary and Conclusion

In this paper we report on the individual and network related determinants of directed generosity

in the field. For a rural village in Nicaragua we elicited observable characteristics of villagers

as well as complete networks of different dimensions among (almost) all household heads. This

27

Page 30: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

provided us not only with large variations in socio-economic characteristics but also with widely

varying structural network variables and network positions of villagers. To explore the deter-

minants of directed generosity we implemented a series of dictator games played by household

heads with village recipients as well as with a stranger, and relate it to observable characteristics

and network variables. In addition, we explore the effect of individual characteristics on network

formation for different specific networks.

Existing studies investigating the influence of network variables on generosity relied on the

special subject pool of relatively wealthy students in the Northern hemisphere. Moreover, these

studies confined their network research to friendship ties. In our research, besides friendship

networks we also elicited other specific networks people are simultaneously embedded in, such as

networks through support relations, relations via social-public activities and economic relations.

As a consequence, we obtained a very rich data set that allows us to check the robustness of

results reported in the aforementioned studies and, importantly, whether these results extend to

other network dimensions.

An important first result is that networks of different dimensions exhibit only limited overlap

and differ strongly in structural network variables like density, clustering, and centrality. For in-

stance, friendship networks are very dense and little centralized whereas the network of economic

ties is relatively loose and much more centralized.

Regarding the determinants of directed generosity we find that observable individual char-

acteristics have hardly explanatory power for giving in the experimental dictator games. In

our study, the only characteristic that clearly exhibits influence is gender. We find that female

dictators give significantly less than male dictators, especially when the recipient is male. In

view of the literature on gender differences and social preferences, that usually find the oppo-

site (cf. Croson and Gneezy, 2009), this is surprising. However, recent work shows that cultural

differences can have a strong effect on social behavior of the genders (cf. Gneezy et al., 2009).

Therefore, a reasonable explanation can be found in our very different subject pool. The social

position and responsibilities of adult women in a rural village in Nicaragua are very different from

those of young female students in wealthy countries. In particular, these women are responsible

for keeping up the resources in the family, which may rather make them keep the money than

giving it to male recipients.

Regarding network variables we find that in friendship networks the social geodesic distance

is an important indicator for giving behavior. This is in line with the findings obtained with

student subjects (cf. Leider et al., 2009; Goeree et al., 2010). We consider this an important

observation for network and experimental research because it indicates that social distance is an

important indicator for giving behavior across very different cultures and social groups. However,

28

Page 31: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

in stark contrast to friendship networks, social distance has no explanatory power at all in the

other investigated specific networks, suggesting that friendship ties are special in this respect.

Our data analyses also show that structural network variables affect giving behavior in all

specific networks. Yet, these effects are not constant across the network dimensions. Betweenness

centrality of the dictator exhibits a positive influence on directed generosity in friendship and

economic ties, but is insignificant in the other networks. The positive influence in the mentioned

networks runs counter to Burt’s (1992) idea that those who are central in the betweenness sense

are better equipped to pursue their self interest. We attribute this result to the fact that in

small-scale societies and other relatively small groups power (i.e., centrality) is often connected

to clientelism, which needs occasionally resources to be transferred to the dependent. We also find

that dictators who have a locally dense network tend to be more generous in support networks,

which is in line with Coleman’s (1990) hypothesis that higher clustering facilitates pro-social

behavior. Interestingly, in the economic network this effect is reversed indicating that closure in

business-like relations has a very different meaning than closure in ties of support and mutual

help. One general lesson that can be drawn next to the specific results is that for the explanation

of giving behavior network dimension clearly matters.

In our view this has at least two important implications. First, for empirical and theoretical

network research it implies that one has to be careful in drawing general conclusions regarding the

influence of network positions and structures on behavior from observations and results gained

for networks of a particular dimension. For theory it also means that abstracting completely

from the network content, when analyzing network formation and behavior on networks, may

lead to inaccurate predictions and misleading normative prescriptions. Second, also for policy

design it may matter what network dimensions and structures influence directed generosity. For

instance, a growing number of policymakers and aid donors make use of local communities and

networks to distribute development aid. The World Bank, for example, has increased its portfolio

of projects that follow such an approach substantially over the last decade (cf. Mansuri and Rao,

2004). Based on our results, individuals in highly clustered sub-networks of support relations or

individuals who are central in friendship relations may be more inclined to share aid resources

with other village members. At the same time, social distance in friendship relations may be an

important factor of exclusion. The latter together with the observed lower likelihood of the poor

of having friendship relations identifies an important policy challenge in this area.

Another interesting aspect is that other studies do not find any effects of structural network

variables on giving behavior. For instance, Goeree et al. (2010, p. 193) conclude that their

“three social network structure measures are not statistically significant and represent very weak

effects.” In contrast to these findings, we see that structural network variables do matter for

29

Page 32: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

giving behavior. This is likely the result of the substantial difference in variation of these variables

and related statistical power between our dataset and data used in previous studies. Whereas

these studies relied on relatively homogeneous student groups, we had access to networks of a

long-grown social unit which – as shown in Section 2 – consists of very heterogeneous members.

Although, we do not find direct effects of observable characteristics except gender, we have

strong indications that such characteristics play an important indirect role via the route of

network formation. As is the case for giving behavior, also in network formation these effects

differ across the specific networks. Hence, individual characteristics are affecting generosity

because they determine to whom one is connected and what position one takes in the specific

network.

We have investigated the influence of networks on social decisions in a rural village in a poor

country in the South. However, small-scale networks are ubiquitous in social and economic life.

More often than not, decisions are made by agents embedded in networks of different kinds. For

instance, employees in small firms form small-scale networks, as work units in larger firms, law

offices, and units in financial institutions do. The same holds for research groups and departments

at universities. In all these networks economically and socially linked individuals make decisions

affecting important outcomes. Our study has shown that these decisions are likely influenced

by the network structure and position of individuals in the network and that these influences

differ across different network dimensions. Whether these results carry over to other networks

and other decision situations has to be answered by future research.

30

Page 33: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

References

Andreoni, J. (2006). Philanthropy. In Kolm, S.-C. and Ythier, J. M., editors, Handbook of

Giving, Reciprocity and Altruism, pages 1201–1269. North Holland, Amsterdam.

Andreoni, J. (2008). Charitable giving. In Durlauf, S. N. and Blume, L. E., editors, The New

Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Second Edition. Palgrave Macmillan. The New Palgrave

Dictionary of Economics Online. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0221.

Andreoni, J. and Vesterlund, L. (2001). Which is the fair sex? Gender differences in altruism.

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(1):293–312.

Bandiera, O., Barankay, I., and Rasul, I. (2009). Social connections and incentives in the work-

place: Evidence from personnel data. Econometrica, 77(4):1047–1094.

Bardsley, N. (2008). Dictator game giving: Altruism or artefact? Experimental Economics,

11(2):122–133.

Bertrand, M., Luttmer, E. F. P., and Mullainathan, S. (2000). Network effects and welfare

culture. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3):1019–1055.

Bohnet, I. and Frey, B. S. (1999). The sound of silence in prisoner’s dilemma and dictator games.

Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization.

Branas-Garza, P. (2006). Poverty in dictator games: Awakening solidarity. Journal of Economic

Behavior and Organization, 60(3):306–320.

Branas-Garza, P., Cobo-Reyes, R., Espinosa, M. P., Jimenez, N., Kovarık, J., and Ponti, G.

(2010). Altruism and social integration. Games and Economic Behavior, 69(2):249–257.

Burt, R. S. (1992). Structural holes: The social structure of competition. Harvard University

Press, Cambridge, MA, and London, England.

Burt, R. S. (2005). Brokerage and closure: An introduction to social capital. Oxford University

Press, Oxford, U.K.

Camerer, C. (2003). Behavioral game theory: experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton

University Press, New York and Princeton.

Cameron, A. C., Gelbach, J. B., and Miller, D. L. (2010). Robust inference with multi-way

clustering. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics. forthcoming.

31

Page 34: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

Cappelen, A. W., Moene, K. O., Sørensen, E. Ø., and Tungodden, B. (2008). Rich meet poor -

An international fairness experiment. Discussion Paper TI 2008-098/3, Tinbergen Institute.

Cardenas, J.-C., Stranlund, J. K., and Willis, C. (2000). Local environmental control and insti-

tutional crowding-out. World Development, 28(10):1719–1733.

Carpenter, J., Connolly, C., and Myers, C. K. (2008). Altruistic behavior in a representative

dictator experiment. Experimental Economics, 11(3):282–298.

Casella, A. and Rauch, J. E. (2002). Anonymous market and group ties in international trade.

Journal of International Economics, 58(1):19–47.

Chen, Y. and Li, S. X. (2009). Group identity and social preferences. American Economic

Review, 99(1):431–457.

Cole, J. (2007). Cultural clientelism and brokerage networks in early modern Florence and

Rome: New correspondence between the Barberini and Michelangelo Buonarroti the Younger.

Renaissance Quarterly, 60(3):729–788.

Coleman, J. S. (1988). Social capital in the creation of human capital. American Journal of

Sociology, 94:S95–S120.

Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory. Harvard University Press, Harvard, MA.

Croson, R. and Gneezy, U. (2009). Gender differences in preferences. Journal of Economic

Literature, 47(2):448–474.

De Weerdt, J. and Dercon, S. (2006). Risk-sharing networks and insurance against illness. Journal

of Development Economics, 81(2):337–356.

Eckel, C. C. and Grossman, P. J. (1996). Altruism in anonymous dictator games. Games and

Economic Behavior, 16(2):181–191.

Eckel, C. C. and Grossman, P. J. (1998). Aew women less selfish than men? evidence from

dictator experiments. Economic Journal, 108(448):726–735.

Efferson, C., Lalive, R., and Fehr, E. (2008). The coevolution of cultural groups and ingroup

favoritism. Science, 321(5897):1844–1849.

Egas, M. and Riedl, A. (2008). The economics of altruistic punishment and the maintenance of

cooperation. Proceedings of the Royal Society - B, 275(1637):871–878.

32

Page 35: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

Fafchamps, M. and Gubert, F. (2007). The formation of risk sharing networks. Journal of

Development Economics, 83(2):326–350.

Fafchamps, M. and Lund, S. (2003). Risk-sharing networks in rural Philippines. Journal of

Development Economics, 71(2):261–287.

Fisman, R., Kariv, S., and Markovits, D. (2007). Individual preferences for giving. American

Economic Review, 97(5):1858–1876.

Freeman, L. C. (1977). A set of measures of centrality based on betweenness. Sociometry,

40(1):35–41.

Freeman, L. C. (1978-1979). Centrality in social networks conceptual clarification. Social Net-

works, 1(3):215–239.

Glaeser, E. L., Laibson, D. I., and Sacerdote, B. (2002). An economic approach to social capital.

The Economic Journal, 112(483):437–458.

Gneezy, U., Leonard, K. L., and List, J. A. (2009). Gender differences in competition: Evidence

from a matrilineal and a patriarchal society. Econometrica, 77(5):1637–1664.

Goeree, J. K., McConnell, M. A., Mitchell, T., Tromp, T., and Yariv, L. (2010). The 1/d law of

giving. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 1(1):183–203.

Granovetter, M. (1973). The strength of weak ties. American Journal of Sociology, 78(6):1360–

1380.

Granovetter, M. ([1974]1995). Getting a job: A study of Contacts and Careers. The University

of Chicago Press, second edition.

Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., and Gintis, H., editors (2004). Foun-

dations of Human Sociality: Economic Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen

Small-Scale Societies. Oxford University Press, Oxford U.K.

Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., McElreath, R., Alvard,

M., Barr, A., Ensminger, J., Henrich, N. S., Hill, K., Gil-White, F., Gurven, M., Marlowe,

F. W., Patton, J. Q., and Tracer, D. (2005). “Economic man” in cross-cultural perspective:

Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 28:795–815.

Henrich, J., Heine, S. J., and Norenzayan, A. (2010). The weirdest people in the world? Behav-

ioral and Brain Sciences, 33:61–135.

33

Page 36: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

Hoddinott, J. and Haddad, L. (1995). Does female income share influence household expendi-

tures? Evidence from Cote d’Ivoire. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 57(1):77–96.

Ioannides, Y. M. and Loury, L. D. (2004). Job information networks, neighborhood effects, and

inequality. The Journal of Economic Literature, 42(4):1052–1093.

Jackson, M. O., Rodriguez-Barraquer, T., and Tan, X. (2010). Social capital and social quilts:

Network patterns of favor exchange. mimeo.

Karlan, D. S. (2007). Social connections and group banking. The Economic Journal,

117(517):F52–F84.

Konow, J., Saijo, T., and Akai, K. (2008). Morals and mores? Experimental evidence on equity

and equality from the US and Japan. Technical report, Imstitute of Social and Economic

Research, Osaka University.

Leider, S., Mobius, M. M., Rosenblat, T., and Do, Q.-A. (2009). Directed altruism and enforced

reciprocity in social networks. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(4):1815–1851.

Lin, N. (1999). Building a network theory of social capital. Connections, 22(1):28–51.

List, J. A. (2004). Young, selfish and male: Field evidence of social preferences. The Economic

Journal, 114(292):121–149.

List, J. A. (2007). On the interpretation of giving in dictator games. Journal of Political Economy,

115(3):482–493.

Mansuri, G. and Rao, V. (2004). Community-based and -driven development: A critical review.

The World Bank Observer, 19(1):1–39.

McMillan, J. and Woodruff, C. (1999). Interfirm relationships and informal credit in Vietnam.

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(4):1285–1320.

McPherson, M., Smith-Lovin, L., and Cook, J. M. (2001). Birds of a feather: Homophily in

social networks. Annual Review of Sociology, 27:415–444.

Montgomery, J. D. (1991). Social networks and labor-market outcomes: Toward an economic

analysis. American Economic Review, 81(5):1408–1418.

Munshi, K. (2003). Networks in the modern economy: Mexican migrants in the U.S. labor

market. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(2):549–599.

34

Page 37: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

Newman, M. E. J. (2003). The structure and function of complex networks. SIAM Review,

45:167–256.

Podolny, J. M. and Baron, J. N. (1997). Resources and relationships: Social networks and

mobility in the workplace. American Sociological Review, 62(5):673–693.

Rees, A. (1966). Information networks in labor economics. American Economic Review,

56(1/2):559–566.

Thomas, D. (1990). Intra-household resource allocation: An inferential approach. Journal of

Human Resources, 25(4):635–664.

van Dijk, F., Sonnemans, J., and van Winden, F. (2002). Social ties in a public good experiment.

Journal of Public Economics, 85(2):275–299.

Wasserman, S. and Faust, K. (1994). Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications, vol-

ume 8 of Structural Analysis in the Social Sciences. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

U.K.

Wolf, E. R. (1977). Kinship, friendship, and patron-client relations in complex societies. In

Schmidt, S. W., editor, Friends, Followers and Factions: A Reader in Political Clientelism.

University of California Press, Berkeley.

35

Page 38: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

Appendix

A Village Background, Design Details and Experimental In-

structions

A.1 Brief village background

The investigated village is located in a rural area in the Northern part of the Pacific region of Nicaragua,

close to the border with Honduras. The difficult agro-ecological conditions (dry season, irregular rainfall,

low fertility of soils, etc.) make agricultural activities not very profitable. Cattle breeding is one of the

most lucrative economic activities in the region because it is both an income source and an important

savings instrument that enables local people to bridge the long and harsh dry season. The possession of

cattle is therefore an important indicator of wealth.

A.2 Procedures for household and network survey and the experiment

We conducted the household survey in a standard manner, by visiting the households in the village

and interviewing the household head(s). The following criteria were taken into account when selecting

the experimenter-assistants. We selected assistants with research experience in rural areas. They all

were employees of the research and development institute Nitlapan of the Central American University,

with which we have a close cooperation. This enabled us to screen the researchers with regard to their

dedication, their capacity to work in a systematic way, their trustworthiness and their capacity to radiate

trust towards other people (such as the participants in our experiment).

The training of the assistants was crucial as none of them had any prior experience with conducting

experiments. To make them familiar with experimental methods we let them participate in an ultimatum

game. After explaining the instructions of our dictator experiment we let them play a role-playing game

whereby each assistant acted in the role of dictator and experimenter. The other assistants observed each

role-playing session and were allowed to comment afterwards. The aim of this was to come to a common

understanding of the experimental procedures. Thereafter, we conducted two pilot studies. After each

pilot study the assistants informed the other assistants about their experience, who could then give their

comments or suggestions. One session was recorded on video (download and play video). The video was

shown to the team and allowed us to clarify any remaining open issues.

To build trust with the locals in the village, we first conducted the household survey followed by the

network survey. Our work was supported by the local well-respected community leader who before the

start of our study presented our team to each household and asked people to cooperate. He also explained

the village members that our study was not related with politics, religion or aid projects in any way, and

that we would treat the obtained information in a confidential way.

For the household survey we targeted for all households. If a household head was not present, we inter-

viewed the other household head. For the social network survey we interviewed both household heads (in

case of a two-headed household) of as many households as possible. In case one household head was absent

36

Page 39: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

we asked whether he or she would be available within the time span of our field planning and returned

later to also interview this person. In this way we obtain almost complete coverage of the village. For a

high coverage rate a good timing of our study was also important. When we were conducting our study

most seasonal migrants had already returned to the village and economic activity was still low as villagers

were awaiting the start of the economically more active rain season.

For the social network survey, we used small cards, each representing a household in the village. On each

card we put the names of the household heads. In case of two-headed households the names of both,

husband and wife, were put on the card. We asked for each of these cards whether the interviewed person

knew the household and whether he or she had a social relation of any kind with any of the household

heads. If a social relation was identified we asked for details on the type of social relation. Before the

start of this exercise we had explained the different types of relations (land rental, labor transaction,

religion, politics, school, sports, cooperatives, projects, neighbors, family, friendship, support, commercial

relation), so that each participant would consider the same types of social relations.21

After finishing the household survey and the network survey (which took four days all together), we

immediately organized the experiment on the fifth day. By conducting the experiment in only one day

we minimized contagion and information spill-overs. To explain the instructions, fixed scripts were used

(see Appendix A.3), which were memorized by the assistants. We decided not to read them aloud from

paper as this could make participants loosing interest. After explaining the instructions to the participant,

some pre-play questions were asked to test whether the participant had understood the instructions. We

prohibited our assistants to invent other examples than the ones included in the instructions, to make

references to the daily life of the participants when explaining the instructions, to make jokes (e.g., about

the money the dictator could keep for himself) or to remove the tap of one of the small boxes once they

were sealed.

We tried to conduct the experiment with as many households as possible, but with only one person per

household. Letting two household heads sequentially participate in the experiment would have put the

door open for contagion. If the selected household head was not present (and also could not be expected

to be present on the same day of our experiment) we selected the other household head, in case of a two-

headed household. The assistants also asked some post-experimental questions and made a subjective

evaluation about the participant’s dedication, trust and understanding of the experiment. For this, the

assistants had to answer the following questions for each participant:

1. How dedicated was the participant within the experiment?

1. Well dedicated 2. Neutral 3. Aversive; distrust towards the aim of the experiment

2. Did the participant understand the instructions?

1. No problems 2. Some questions for clarification 3. I have serious doubts about whether he/she

completely understood them.

21For the analysis we summarized the elicited categories in the following way: the dimension economic relation

consists of relations pertaining to land rental, labor transaction, and commercial relations; social public activities

contain religion, politics, school, sports, cooperatives, and projects; the remaining categories neighbors, family,

friendship, and support are not merged.

37

Page 40: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

3. Was he/she reluctant to take a decision?

1. Yes 2. No

4. On average, how much time did he/she take to make a decision?

1. Instantly 2. More than a minute 3. More than three minutes

5. Other personal observations:

A.3 Experimental Instructions

The experimental instructions are originally in Spanish; text between [ ] are instructions for the exper-

imenter assistant. A short movie - recorded during a pilot experiment - showing a sequence with the

instructions and decisions made can be found at: download and play video

We now ask you to participate in an experiment in which you can earn money. The amount of money

you earn is yours, whatever the amount is.

Soon I will give you 20 coins of 1 Cordoba and you will be free to divide this amount between yourself

and another person. For this, we use this small black box [show the box]. In this box, you will find 20

coins of 1 Cordoba [open the box and show the 20 coins]. You are allowed to take as many coins as you

wish. The coins you leave in the box will be given to another person. In particular, we ask you to do the

following:

1. Take the number of coins you want to keep out of the box and leave in the box the coins you want

to give to the other person.

2. Refill the box with these small rings [show metal rings] and put the lid on the box. In this way, I

will not be able to see how many coins you will have left in the box, nor can I get an idea about it

through the weight of the box. The weight of the box will always be the same whatever the amount

of coins you leave in the box.

Thereafter, we put a sticker on the box with the name of the person who will get the coins and we put

some tape on it to seal the box. I will give the box to my supervisor, who waits at the automobile and

who will bring the coins to the other person. Note that you will know the identity of the other person,

whereas that other person will NOT know your identity.

I will now give you some arbitrary examples for further clarification. [Take the coins of one of the boxes

and use them for the examples].

1. You have here 20 coins of 1 Cordoba. Imagine that you decide to take 2 coins out of the box. How

many coins will the other person receive? (20 minus 2 equals 18)

2. I will give you another example. Imagine that you decide to take 10 coins out of the box. How

many coins will the other person receive? (20 minus 10 equals 10)

3. I will give you a final example. Imagine that you decide to take 20 coins out of the box. How many

coins will the other person receive? (20 minus 20 equals 0).

We will repeat this experiment 6 times. Each time, you will be able to take coins and leave coins for the

other person, who will each time be a different one. Thus, I will give you 6 boxes of 20 coins to divide

38

Page 41: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

between yourself and another person. Each time, this person will be a different one. The first time you

will divide the 20 coins with someone from another village in this region. You will not know this person.

The other 5 times you will divide 20 coins with someone from your community. Once again, note that

these other person will NOT know your identity.

To select the five persons of your community, I will ask you to take small cards from this bag. Each card

has a different number, and each number corresponds to a different person in the community. After having

taken a number, I will look up this number on a list and tell you the name of that person. Thereafter, I

will give you a box with coins, so that you can decide on the number of coins you keep and how many

you give to the other person. When taking this decision, I will give you privacy. You can go inside your

house, [if this is not possible, say: I will turn my back so that I will be unable to know your decision; give

me a signal when you are ready]. Please do not tell me the decision you will make or you have taken.

After having taken your decision and having closed the box we will seal the box, and you are not allowed

anymore to change your decision. Thereafter, we will draw another number from the bag and I will ask

you to take the next decision. Do you have any questions at the moment?

39

Page 42: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

B Supplementary Network Data

B.1 Reciprocation Rates

In our analysis we followed recent studies (cf. Leider et al., 2009; Jackson et al., 2010) and used so-called

OR-networks. The alternative would have been to use AND-networks where links are taken to be valid

only if both sides of a dyad mention the relation. There are at least three arguments in favor of the use

of OR-networks, all related to the danger to miss out actually existing links when using AND-networks.

First, generally while it is likely that a person forgets to mention a link, it seems much less likely that

he or she ‘invents’ a link. Second, those who have many links are more likely to forget to mention a link

than those who have only a few links. Third, people may put different emphasis on different network

dimensions, which may make people missing out on other dimensions.

The rate of reciprocation, that is the links where both nodes named each other as a fraction of all

links where at least one mentioned the other, is for general relations with 30.2 percent similar to the

reciprocation rate of 36.7 percent reported by Leider et al. (2009) who elicited only friendship networks.

The rate of reciprocated ties decreases for the more specific network contents. This is not surprising

because there exists a trade-off between capturing multiple network dimensions and reciprocated ties.

Different people likely put different emphasis on different dimensions of relations, lowering the rate of

Table B.1: Reciprocation rates

Reciprocationa

General relation 0.302

Friendship relation 0.115

Support relation 0.021

Neighbor relation 0.145

Social public activities 0.171

Economic relation 0.088

Note: a all two-sided links as a fractionof all one-sided links, intra-household re-lations between household heads are ig-nored.

reciprocated ties when asked to describe their specific relations. As the reciprocation rates in Table B.1

show especially support relations and economic relations have very low reciprocation rates. This can

be explained by the asymmetric nature of such relations. In support relations, givers and receivers of

support are unlikely to put the same emphasis on this type of social relation. That this is indeed the case

is supported by the following observation. Considering all one- and two-sided support relations, we find

that nodes who posses cattle, i.e. potential support givers, mention their relation significantly less often

than nodes without cattle, i.e., potential support receivers (50.5 percent versus 66.2 percent; p = 0.005

two-sided χ2-square test). A similar result holds when comparing nodes with and without land (45.1

percent versus 65.8 percent; p < 0.001 two-sided χ2-square test). A similar argument holds for economic

relations.

40

Page 43: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

B.2 Closed and Open Triples and Clustering

The clustering coefficient reported in Table 2 in the main text is defined as the ratio of the number of

open and closed triples in the network. For completeness we report them here.

Table B.2: Closed and open triples and clustering in the different networks

Number of Number of Clusteringclosed triples open triples coefficient

General relation 22862 67077 0.254

Friendship relation 3982 26059 0.133

Support relation 58 1396 0.040

Social public activities 260 2817 0.085

Economic relation 176 4094 0.041

Neighbor relation 157 2741 0.054

Note: OR-networks, intra-household relations (not) counted as validlinks in general, friendship, extended family, and support relations(neighbor, social public activities, and economic relations).

B.3 Additional Regressions

Table B.3 shows the regression results of an alternative to Model 3 in Table 5 and the specifications shown

in Table 6 in the main text. Here the inverse of the squared number of links between dictator and recipient

is used to measure distance in the networks instead of a dummy variable that takes value zero when the

dictator and the recipient are not directly connected. A comparison of the regression results shown here

with those in Tables 5 and 6 indicates that the results are qualitatively the same.

41

Page 44: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

Table B.3: Determinants of directed generosity in the general and specific networks

(inverse squared distance)

Dependent variable: Coins given to village recipient

General Friendship Support Social-public Economic

Male→Female 3.058*** (1.128) 2.443** (1.181) 2.382*** (0.791) 2.489*** (0.870) 1.507* (0.864)

Male→Male 3.090*** (1.060) 3.106*** (1.081) 2.806*** (0.896) 2.974*** (0.899) 2.367*** (0.891)

Female→Female 1.413* (0.823) 0.761 (0.835) 1.368** (0.658) 1.329** (0.618) 1.080* (0.640)

Age D 0.042 (0.043) 0.058 (0.042) 0.057 (0.045) 0.041 (0.045) 0.050 (0.044)

Age ∆ 0.002 (0.020) 0.007 (0.022) 0.001 (0.024) −0.005 (0.023) 0.004 (0.021)

Education D 0.041 (0.140) 0.037 (0.119) 0.049 (0.145) −0.028 (0.152) −0.041 (0.133)

Education ∆ −0.050 (0.087) −0.021 (0.081) −0.015 (0.078) −0.001 (0.077) 0.006 (0.076)

Residence D −0.032 (0.027) −0.043 (0.031) −0.037 (0.029) −0.036 (0.031) −0.035 (0.029)

Residence ∆ −0.006 (0.023) −0.012 (0.023) −0.008 (0.022) −0.005 (0.020) −0.006 (0.023)

Urban D 0.069 (0.150) 0.011 (0.132) 0.155 (0.132) 0.143 (0.144) 0.134 (0.133)

Urban ∆ −0.073 (0.051) −0.078 (0.048) −0.065 (0.044) −0.079 (0.049) −0.064 (0.048)

Cattle→NoCattle −0.204 (0.629) −0.331 (0.626) −0.344 (0.652) −0.347 (0.664) −0.338 (0.646)

NoCattle→Cattle −0.555 (0.769) −0.916 (0.730) −0.882 (0.713) −1.222 (0.741) −0.660 (0.762)

NoCattle→NoCattle −0.337 (0.819) −0.424 (0.859) −0.535 (0.928) −0.733 (0.972) −0.308 (0.865)

Land→NoLand −0.213 (0.916) −0.091 (0.871) −0.388 (0.878) −0.422 (0.907) −0.442 (0.929)

NoLand→Land −0.657 (1.038) −0.153 (0.946) −0.134 (1.068) −0.716 (1.007) −0.663 (0.993)

NoLand→NoLand −0.823 (1.005) −0.476 (0.898) −0.001 (1.126) −0.668 (1.033) −0.885 (0.984)

1/Distance2 1.246* (0.693) 1.487* (0.882) 0.795 (1.144) −0.785 (1.306) −0.620 (1.142)

Closure D −0.003 (0.003) −0.011* (0.006) 0.294* (0.166) −0.019 (0.034) −0.151* (0.082)

Centrality D 1.435 (1.213) 0.791** (0.307) −0.189 (0.128) 0.291 (0.403) 0.510*** (0.190)

Closure R 0.001 (0.001) −0.004 (0.004) 0.126 (0.117) 0.024* (0.013) 0.067* (0.035)

Centrality R 0.469 (0.522) 0.044 (0.229) −0.119 (0.095) −0.097* (0.049) −0.158 (0.100)

GiveStranger 0.452*** (0.086) 0.433*** (0.087) 0.459*** (0.083) 0.475*** (0.087) 0.455*** (0.086)

Decision#a n.s. n.s. n.s. n.s. n.s.

Constant 3.556 (3.105) 3.894 (2.920) 2.456 (3.308) 3.974 (3.168) 4.048 (3.002)

R2 0.4497 0.4602 0.4469 0.4407 0.4909

F-statistics 8.62 11.01 9.37 8.24 13.30

Prob > F 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

No. of obs. 273 273 273 273 273

Note: ***, **, * indicate two-sided significance levels at 1, 5, and 10 percent, respectively; a ... decision fixed effects are notsignificant (n.s.); robust standard errors (in parentheses) are obtained by means of two-way clustering at the level of dictators(57 clusters) and recipients (91 clusters).

42

Page 45: CBESS Discussion Paper 09-01Exelle+and+Riedl... · form of charity giving is an important economic factor. According to Andreoni (2008), in 2005 charitable giving by private individuals

B.4 Visualization of Different Network Dimensions

(a) Friendship network (b) Economic network

(c) Support network (d) Neighbors network

(e) Network through social public activities

Note: Household heads of the same household are placed next to each other.

Figure B.1: Different specific networks

43