banking concentration, information asymmetries and …

59
Munich Personal RePEc Archive Banking Concentration, Information Asymmetries and Credit Rationing or the Argentinean Case Arroyo, Martín R. CIFF - Centro Internacional de Formación Financiera September 2007 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/61481/ MPRA Paper No. 61481, posted 20 Jan 2015 11:39 UTC

Upload: others

Post on 16-May-2022

6 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

Munich Personal RePEc Archive

Banking Concentration, Information

Asymmetries and Credit Rationing or

the Argentinean Case

Arroyo, Martín R.

CIFF - Centro Internacional de Formación Financiera

September 2007

Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/61481/

MPRA Paper No. 61481, posted 20 Jan 2015 11:39 UTC

Page 2: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

1

‘BANKING CONCENTRATION,

INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND

CREDIT RATIONING OR THE

ARGENTINEAN CASE’

Martín R. Arroyo

MASTER IN FINANCE & BANKING

C.I.F.F.

(Centro Internacional de Formación Financiera)

[email protected]

Madrid, September 2007

Revised July 2013

Page 3: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

2

INDEX

1. INTRODUCTION ................................................................................... 5

2. FRAMEWORK ....................................................................................... 6

3. CREDIT RATIONING ........................................................................... 8 3.1. Credit rationing: Focusing in asymmetric information ....................................... 11 3.2. Asymmetric Information and concentration process ........................................... 12

4. CONCENTRATION ............................................................................. 12 4.1. The ‘Tequila Crises’ ............................................................................................ 12 4.2. Regulation ............................................................................................................ 13 4.3. BASEL II normative and the Size of Banks ........................................................ 18

5. BANK SIZE, ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION AND SMEs ......... 19 5.1. The size of the bank – Economies of scale .......................................................... 20 5.2. The size of Banks – Information type ................................................................. 21 5.3. The Argentinean evidence and information generation problems....................... 25

5.3.1. Credit rationing ............................................................................................. 25 5.3.2. Asymmetric Information .............................................................................. 26

5.4. Measurement systems .......................................................................................... 28 5.4.1. Lending scoring system ................................................................................ 29 5.4.2. Monitoring scoring system ........................................................................... 29 5.4.3. Notes on the scoring system. ........................................................................ 30

6. MICROECONOMICS ......................................................................... 31 6.1. Working Capital .................................................................................................. 31

7. DISCUSSION ........................................................................................ 32

8. CONCLUSIONS ................................................................................... 35

REFERENCES .......................................................................................... 36

ANNEX ....................................................................................................... 41 Simulation. FINANCIAL COST OF WORKING CAPITAL ............................... 41

Comments ................................................................................................................... 45

GLOSARY ................................................................................................. 58

Page 4: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

3

‘BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION

ASYMMETRIES AND CREDIT RATIONING OR THE

ARGENTINEAN CASE’

ABSTRACT

The general idea of this work is to analyse how a banking concentration process can generate information asymmetries causing credit rationing in specific sectors of the economy. To perform this analysis will be used a real and not a theoretical framework as it was the bank concentration process that took place in Argentina in the second half of the 1990s and the specific sector of the economy covered are the SMEs. The work begins with a theoretical introduction and then a description of the process of banking concentration mentioned. In a second part analyses how bank concentration process generates fewer and larger financial institutions and the relationship between the size of these financial institutions and the type of information they handle from their customers, trying to show that the higher the institution the worst is the quality of information obtained on the SME sector or even the lack of information at all, in this second part is also shown the effect of credit rationing caused by this information asymmetry. In the final part of the paper attempts to show the effect of credit rationing in an SME, here is a brief analysis based on a case study that aims to highlight the importance that the financial cost has upon working capital for an SME survival.

Page 5: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

4

‘The Law of Supply and Demand is not in fact a law, nor should it be viewed as an assumption

needed for competitive analysis. It is rather a result generated by the underlying assumptions that

prices have neither sorting nor incentive effects. The usual result of economic theorizing: that prices

clear markets, is model specific and is not a general property of markets-unemployment and credit

rationing are not phantasms.’

Joseph E. Stiglitz and Andrew Weiss, ‘Credit Rationing in Markets with

Imperfect Information’, The American Economic Review, Vol. 71, No. 3. (Jun., 1981)

“…the dream of transforming an idea into a company, without access to the external

financing, will not be more than a dream”

Joakim Winborg, ‘Finance in Small Businesses. A Widened Approach to Small Business

Managers Handling of Finance’, Halmstad University, Sweden (1997).

Page 6: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

5

1. INTRODUCTION

In the present work we will try to analyze the existing relation between the

banking concentration, the information asymmetries in the financial markets, and the

credit rationing to the sector of the small and medium companies (SMEs). As departure

point we’ll based on the several works on asymmetries of information and rationing of

credit published since the already classic work of Stiglitz and Weiss (1981), and we’ll

take as empirical frame the situation of the financial and SME sectors in Argentina after

the called `Tequila Crisis’ (1994) up to year 2001, since we think that this period holds

the necessary conditions to fit the three subjects.

It is well known that the financial markets and the banks in particular are

informational intensive activities and depends critically on their quality and amount,

reason why the information deficiencies have a superlative incidence in their correct

operation. But this correct operation gains even more importance if we consider that this

sector has a vital function as financial intermediary, connecting the savings of the public

with the demand for investment, fulfilling a fundamental role in the growth and

development of any economy. It is normally accepted that the greater it is the amount

and quality of the information the grater will be the resources canalized towards those

opportunities of investment, nevertheless the evidence of the financial markets not

always fulfils the golden rule of equilibrium between the supply and demand.

It is then when the aspects and situations that we’ll mention in the present work

starts to gain relevance. The information deficiencies caused by endogenous factors like

the particular structure of the small company, or exogenous factors like the banking

concentration and the impact of the regulations (as we’re going to see further), leads to

phenomena known as `adverse selection', `moral risk' or `monitoring costs', causing

`credit rationing' on some sectors of the market.

In the first part of this work we will review the basic characteristics of the

process that causes the credit rationing, highlighting the information asymmetries. We’ll

relate them later with the banking concentration that took place and the effects of the

financial regulations applied over the mentioned period.

We will continue getting deeper into the analysis, focusing on the difficulties

that the financial institutions had to solve the problem of `information asymmetries' and

will see the evidences of credit rationing over the most affected sector that was the

small and medium companies one. For this task we will consider the size and structure

Page 7: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

6

of the financial organizations, type of information used and the relation with the SME

sector with their singularities.

In the third part we will try to analyze the microeconomic impact that the credit

rationing had in the small and medium companies. We will lean on empirical evidence

and perform a simulation that allows us to quantify the financial over-cost that the

rationing provokes in a particular company.

In summary, the intention is to relate the general theory of credit rationing' to the

real effect on minor companies, analyzing the agents which somehow fulfil a role of

intermediaries.

Finally it is important to clarify that the present work does not try to demonstrate

the viability of lending to a SME but the costs and obstacles to do it.

2. FRAMEWORK

Towards the end of the 90’s decade a particular debate took place in Argentina

about the financing to the SMEs (Small and Medium Size Enterprises) between

executives of the BCRA1 and some economists of the private sector2. In one of the

positions the authorities of the BCRA argued that the companies had not been affected

by the process of banking concentration that took place after the `Tequila Crisis' in

1994/95, they based their position on a series of research works coordinated by

Guillermo Escudé (Escudé, 2001), at that time chief of the equipment of Economic and

Financial Investigations of the BCRA. On the other sidewalk was the position of some

economists like Leonardo Bleger (researcher of one of the only two cooperative banks

of Argentina, the Credicoop Bank) defending previous financial publications adducing

the worsening situation leaded by this process.

The debate was (and is) even more delicate to analyze due to the ‘slippery’

information handled and the difficulties to obtain it.

Beyond this particular discussion is generally accepted that for one reason or

other the SMEs have been witnesses of an increasingly tighten financial conditions from

the ‘formal financial sector’ (FFS)3 of the economy. Empirical evidence along those

1 BCRA: acronym of Banco Central de la República Argentina (Central Bank of the Argentinean Republic). 2 See Appendix, News 1. 3 For our purposes we’ll consider the ‘formal financial sector’ (FFS) as the financial institutions covered

by the regulation of the BCRA and as ‘informal financial sector’ (IFS) the rest of the financial

intermediaries. This classification is normally used in the academic works related with this subject. The

Page 8: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

7

years (1994-2001) seems to show a ‘credit rationing’ process caused by the bank

concentration situation that we’ll expose in this work.

But in this particular section we believe that is important to mention some

macroeconomic aspects and particularities of the Argentinean economy of those years

as the following ones.

One characteristic not mentioned very often about the financial system in

Argentina is the small participation of the capital market as financial intermediary. The

size in terms of market capitalization to GDP was 19.7% on 1999, quite below the size

of countries like E.E.U.U. (180.8%), Canada (122.4%), Australia (108.5%) or emerging

countries like Malaysia (177.7%) and the Philippines (54.3%) on the same period, but

even in comparison with Latin American countries like Chile (101.1%) or Mexico

(34.5%) the capital market in Argentina was in an embryonic state (see Figure 1). Thus

the Argentinean financial system was very dependent on the banking sector, shrinking

the financing possibilities of the private sector and directly increasing a potential ‘credit

rationing’ process.

But even the financial sector was not enough developed and hadn’t reached the

critical mass necessary to support an efficient system as intermediary. The size of the

Formal Financial Sector (FFS) in the decade grown from 11% on 1990 up to 35 % on

1999 (see Figure 2) calculated as Total Loans/GDP, but was still small on an

international comparison with Germany (145%) and EE.UU. (85%), or even with other

Latin-American countries like Chile (70%), Brazil (53%) or Mexico (37%). This

measure, and the previous mentioned, gives us a general idea of basic restriction in

terms of available resources and a good intuition of the range covered by the FFS, both

factors considered in the credit rationing theory. Moreover, and related with our

concern, if we follow some researches (Berger, Rosen and Udell, 2001) we found that

small business loan rates depends more on the size structure of the market than on the

size of the lending bank.

Along with the mentioned situation of growth on the loan/deposits, undeveloped

capital market and small financial system, the bank concentration process took place

after the ‘Tequila Crisis’ on the second half of the decade.

composition in this case is: FFS formed by the BCRA, Public and Private Banks, Saving Banks,

Cooperative Banks, Savings Societies, Insurance Companies, Pension Funds, Mutual Funds, Stock

Exchange. IFS formed by Credit Cooperatives, Cooperatives in general, Local Mutual Companies,

Professional Associations (lending money to their members), Moneylenders, Loan Companies, Letter

Discount Companies (lending money to the general public), Companies selling durable goods (direct

commercial credit) ‘Non-profit’ Organizations (i.e. sports clubs) and other intermediaries not well defined

that in some cases operates illegally.

Page 9: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

8

This crisis was provoked by the devaluation of the Mexican peso on December

19944 and affected Latin-American emerging economies on different grades; in the case

of the Argentinean economy it suffered a ‘fly to quality’ effect that caused the drainage

of 18% of the total deposits in less than 10 months (The Argentinean case was

particularly virulent due to the fixed exchange rate in force at that moment that pegged

the peso 1/1 to the dollar).

As a result of this the bank sector went through a period of bankruptcies and

acquisitions that reduced the number of total institutions 50% from December 1994

until December 1999. An important aspect of this consolidation process is that the

regional and cooperative banks were the most beaten in terms of total number of

branches, having a decrease of 9.48% and 15.54% respectively5 on their market

participation.

3. CREDIT RATIONING

Following the argument developed by Stiglitz and Weiss (1981) we understand

as credit rationing when relatively profitable projects doesn’t have access to financing

and at the same time the rest of projects with equal apparent profitability does, or when

the changes in interest rates or other credit variables are unable to eliminate the excess

of demand of loans in the market for an specific group of companies or projects6.

A credit rationing as stated before can be the consequence of bankers and

borrowers having different information about the same projects, situation known as

‘imperfect information, residual imperfect information or asymmetric information’

leading to the phenomenon known in economics as ‘adverse selection’ and ‘incentive

effect’7. Focused in the SMEs sector Storey (1993) includes another four factors that are

related with the rationing of credit: the high fixed cost of information research; the

variety in credit conditions (interest rate, terms and other conditions) used by the banks

4 The Mexican peso was planned to be devaluated 15% from 3,4 $/U$S up to 4 $/U$$ at the beginning of 1995 but on the following months after the original devaluation the currency depreciated up to 7-7,7 $/U$S, quotation maintained until the Asian Crisis of 1998. 5 Regional banks (public) decreased their participation from 40.87% down to 31.39% and Cooperative Banks from 20.74% down to 5.20%. 6 Adjustment via prices, this is when the market is automatically adjusted by the free game of demand and supply. 7 Known in the Spanish economic literature as ‘Selección Adversa’ (Adverse selection effect) and ‘Riesgo Moral’ (Incentive effect).

Page 10: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

9

to compete; the variety of attitudes, skills and motivations that entrepreneurs presents8;

the high ‘mortality rate’ that SMEs presents.

This last four factors have directly/indirectly relation with the original two

mentioned by Weiss and Stiglitz (1981).

In order to get a more clear understanding of the credit rationing effect, would be

useful to describe the decision process that a banker applies pursuing the maximizing of

benefits. In order to simplify we’ll assume that the banker takes decisions under free

risk conditions in a competitive market and without imperfect information; finally we’ll

consider the bankers as the only loan supplier.

This maximization implies that the banker has to assign the resources

(compounded by the deposits obtained at the market interest rate and by his available

equity) in between the borrowers trying to make equal expected returns (net of risk)

from of each one of them. In the goods and services market where the information is

accessible and abundant the pricing mechanism plays a superlative role determining the

equilibrium price and eliminating any excess of demand, then the most profitable

expected projects would pay higher interest rates crowding out the less profitable ones.

But in the ‘real market’ the bank has limited information (imperfect

information), and limited control over the borrowers actions (incentive effect), leading

to what is known as ‘Collateral and Limited Liability Theory’ in which the banks use

collaterals as a way to reduce the risk of default and increase the return. This

mechanism (with enormous implication in SMEs financing) by which the bank

increases the liability of the borrower in case the project fails leads to different

perceptions of the risk and return of the project from both parts: the borrower doesn’t

take into account the losses of the bank in case of failure and the bank doesn’t take into

account the profits of the borrower when the project success but only the pay back of

the loan (also because it is not sure about the information). Then the expected return of

the bank will depend on the risk perception that it has from each project in particular.

This risk perception depends as well on the particular conditions of each project and/or

borrower, information that normally is very expensive and difficult to obtain (‘high

fixed costs of information’ and ‘borrower attitudes’). Another effect of the increase in

collaterals required by lenders is that it can stimulate a decrease on the risk aversion of

the borrowers leading them to undertake riskier projects.

The interest rate that the borrower is willing to pay doesn’t represents a reliable

measure of risk as the presence of asymmetric information impede the bankers to know

the profit distribution of the project that indeed is known by the borrower.

8 The importance of this factor has an inverse relation with the size of the company: the smaller the company the bigger the incidence of individual behaviour on the company/project management.

Page 11: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

10

Even more the increase in the cost of credit will reshape the investment portfolio

of the bank in benefit of the most risky projects (and discouraging safer borrowers)

because higher payoffs as these can better afford such increase, but in average have less

probability of success. Nevertheless a situation can occur where the loan is denied due

to wrong risk perception even with higher rates, then the rationing is via volume. This

phenomenon is known as ‘adverse selection’. The other effect perceived is that

borrowers could select more risky projects deviated from the original or manage the

already financed one under risky circumstances not accepted by the bank in order to

afford the increase in the cost of credit. This phenomenon is known as ‘incentive effect’.

The mentioned phenomena imply that the loan supply for a determined group of

borrowers could not increase when the interest rate is increased, even when the offer is

constant (Note figure 5 and Table 6 analyzed further).

In this way, keeping in mind the interest rates paid by other intermediaries and

even under an excess of demand, the bank would not encourage the supply of loans

since it doesn’t implies an increase in the expected return which could allow higher

interest rates paid to the depositors in order to obtain larger deposits.

As Stiglitz and Weiss (1981) analyze, due to the credit rationing, among loan

applicants who appear to be identical some receive a loan and others do not, even if they

offered to pay a higher interest rate; or there are identifiable groups of individuals who

with a given supply of credit are unable to obtain loans at any interest rate, even though

with a larger supply of credit, they would9.

Considering this situation for the whole group of banks competing for deposits

and trying to maximize benefits an equilibrium situation could be found in which the

credit rationing exist: profitable projects/business at the interest rate in force in the

market can not get access to financing even paying higher rates.

The possibility of this type of equilibrium increases with the risk dispersion of

the projects as the asymmetric information increases too. Thus this probability is higher

in between the SMEs sector due to the atomization observed by type of business.

Finally the empirical evidence shows that this situation is less often when the

availability of resources increases (i.e. due to a higher saving ratio of the economy or

the financial system development). In this point we could make a parallelism with the

size of the banking systems of different countries mentioned in the Framework section.

9 Weiss and Stiglitz (1981), ‘Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information’, The American Economic Review, Vol. 71, No. 3, p 395.

Page 12: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

11

3.1. Credit rationing: Focusing in asymmetric information

From the factors mentioned in this work as potential originators of credit

rationings one of the most accepted is the asymmetric information problem and this is in

particular the functional aspect that we’re going to highlight as we consider it the main

problem in the SMEs financing.

In some point the incidence of every factor is affected (or originated) by the lack

of information or by the quality of the available one:

The ‘high fixed cost of information’ talks by himself about this problem: as in a

great extent this costs are independent from the amount of the loan to grant then the

smaller projects (in terms of money) will be more affected, thus this difficulty to reach

economies of scale in the assignment of loan portfolio will discriminate a priori the

smaller firms.

The ‘incentive effect’ has a direct relation with the information available about

the evolution of the project (monitoring) throughout its “period of life”: the less the

monitoring of the project the higher the probability that the borrower would deviate

from the original objectives agreed.

The ‘variety in credit conditions’ is in part consequence of the diversity of

business in between the SMEs sector, which is not a problem in it self but the

difficulties to manage the information in a more effective way, forcing the banks to

make a more segmented effort increasing the costs of evaluation and monitoring10.

The ‘variety of attitudes’ is related with the incentive effect factor and of course

either in this point the effort made by the lender has to be more segmented reducing the

cost efficiency mentioned in the previous point.

The ‘high mortality rate’ of SMEs is part of the ‘intrinsic’ characteristics of this

sector11 and in this aspect the decrease of the mortality not only depends on the

information provided to the bank by the company in order to anticipate financial crisis

situations but also the information that the company obtain (i.e. consultancy) and of

course the commercial aspect of the business.

10 For more information see Williamson, Stephen D. (1986). “Costly Monitoring, Financial Intermediation and Equilibrium Credit Rationing,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 18, 159-179. Not necessarily in coincidence with this work. 11 In the European Union 20% of the SMEs survives after 10 years functioning (FIEL, 1996).

Page 13: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

12

3.2. Asymmetric Information and concentration process

This section will be focused in the reshape of the financial system caused by the

banking concentration process after the Tequila Crisis, highlighting the vanishing of

financial intermediaries that had been typically oriented to SMEs financing and thus had

closer information.

The following analysis has a limitation with respect to the period of time

included, because the effect of the mentioned vanishing can not be easily compared

against the situation before the ’Convertibility Plan’ implementation in 1991. In the

previous decade with periodically high inflation rates, a closed economy resting

importance to competitiveness and an extremely inefficient financial system the cost of

credit or even the access were not the main problems of the SMEs. At that time

alternative sources of financing were used (that disappeared in the next period), like

financing at negative interest rates provided by fiscal agencies and the liquation of

salary costs associated to the inflation. The terms of financing were extremely short and

the information presented by companies and individuals applying for a loan were more

distorted due to the variability in the relative prices and the inflation, interest and

exchange rates.

Something similar happened on the other side with the recurrent support of the

BCRA to maintain the solvency of several institutions including public banks with large

participation in the supply of loans, showing a paternalist behaviour more than a clear

market functioning (The change in this policy was one of the reasons that explain

several mergers and acquisitions in the next decade).

Said this our analysis about the concentration process will include only the

decade of 1990 with starting point at the Convertibility Plan of 1991.

4. CONCENTRATION

4.1. The ‘Tequila Crises’

The concentration began with the `Tequila Crisis' at the beginning of 1995, at

that time the financial system was made up of 168 organizations covered by the

regulations of the BCRA (December 1994), on December 1996 this number had

decreased down to 119 and towards the end of the period analyzed, on December 1999,

Page 14: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

13

the total number of institutions was of 92 (see Table 1). In between this reduction the

only type of entity that increased his number were the foreign private banks from 31 up

to 48. The privatization of public banks and the investment of foreign banks in the

financial industry contributed to reduce the presence of national institutions mainly in

the first year of the period.

Along with this was a deposit concentration from smaller to larger banks: in

1995 the first twelve banks shared the 58% of loans and the 60% of deposits, four years

later in 1999 this amounts increased up to 73% and 72% respectively (Including the first

20 banks the amount of deposits was 83.7% of the total system at June 1999)12.

Another characteristic of this process was the acquisition of the smaller banks by

the larger ones instead of the constitution of larger banks through the merger or

consolidation of several minor entities. For our purposes this event has superlative

importance due to the fact that cooperative and regional banks (included in the minor

segment) were the institutions with higher tendency to SMEs lending and better

information of them.

4.2. Regulation

In a first stage from December 1994 up to October 1995 the concentration was

caused by an outflow and reshape of deposits from small to large entities that provoked

a drastic reduction in their number (almost 50% of the total). From that date the

consolidation process was slower but steady until stopping a year before the crisis of

December 2001. In this second phase the concentration was caused by the financial

regulations implemented by the Argentinean government (see Figure 3).

These regulations were implemented in order to reinforce the solvency and

liquidity of the financial system on accordance with the suggested criteria of the Basel

Committee of Banking Supervision, and determined the minimum capital and liquidity

requirements13.

At this point the empirical evidence has a correlation with the credit rationing

theory formulated by Stiglitz and Weiss, taking into consideration that the regulations of

Basel II had still not been implemented at 1981:

‘There is another form of rationing which is the subject of our 1980 paper:

banks make the provision of credit in later periods contingent on performance in earlier

12 For detailed information see D'Amato (1997). 13 These requirements are especially important because they determine the cost and amount of available resources of the financial system.

Page 15: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

14

period; banks may then refuse to lend even when these later period projects

stochastically dominate earlier projects which are financed.’14

These government regulations consisted mainly in three points that affected the

credit rationing directly.

* In 1993 the minimum capital requirements were established by the BCRA

demanding a segmentation and adjustment of the assets in accordance with the risk

exposure of them. Thus the riskier portfolios have to be supported by a larger amount of

assets. As a consequence the banks were encouraged to increase their size in order to

afford riskier projects with higher expected returns and in the other hand the small

institutions, that had more risk exposure on average, were in some way penalized.

* In 1995 the bank reserve requirements were substituted by the minimum

liquidity requirements which have less costs due to they can be invested in certain

yielding assets specified by the BCRA, furthermore in all the cases they’ve to be high

liquidity assets in order to be used to face urgent situations.

The liquidity requirements were higher for the short term deposits and lower for

the longer ones, thus a deposit for a period up to 89 days had an imposition of 20%, in

between 90-179 days was 15%, 10% for 180-365 and 0% for deposits of more than 365

days. Even considering that these types of requirements could yield interest the smaller

banks were still affected by this measure as the larger banks had relatively more

deposits with longer maturity, probably because the different perception of trust.

* Up to this point the Argentinean regulation was in coincidence with the norms

suggested by the Basel Committee, but going a step further the BCRA modified the

definition of capital risk including the interest rate as a measure of risk factor. Thus the

risk adjustment was increased as the interest rate applied to the loans and other actives

increases. This risk indicator is applied on a range in between 0.8 and 6 (see Vrf

variable below). This norm encourages lending at lower interest rates on the assumption

that the interest rate is related with the risk of the investment, but in other way it

provokes another problem of competition to smaller banks: on average smaller

institutions in Argentina lent to smaller companies at higher interest rates (normally this

kind of borrowers have more risk) penalizing this types of financial intermediaries and

deepening the concentration.

As we can see in Table 2 the tendency to lend to smaller companies was stronger

in smaller financial institutions and in the same chart checking the ‘no collateral’ side

we can have an idea of the average interest rates applied per type of company.

14 Stiglitz J., Weiss A.: ‘Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information’, The American Economic Review, Vol. 71, No. 3, p.395. June 1981.

Page 16: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

15

* Another regulation in order to provide solvency and liquidity to the financial

system was the implementation of the C.A.M.E.L.15 rating system supervised by the

Superintendencia de Entidades Financieras y Cambiarias (Supervision of Financial and

Exchange Entities). This internationally accepted standard (applied by the British

regulation) measures the quality of banks and financial institutions regulated by the

BCRA (formal sector) through a performance evaluation. The rating is compounded of

5 grades: the lower the grade the lower the minimum capital requirement factor, thus

with a grade of 1 the bank has to adjust his capital requirements to a value of 0.97 and

for a grade 5 the value is 1.125 (See the minimum capital formula below).

The regulation COM “A” 2136 of the BCRA determines the formula to calculate

the minimum capital requirement:

Cer = k * [a * Ais + c * (Ci + _Fspn) + r * (Vrf + Vrani)]

Where:

Cer: minimum capital required in function of the risk

K: CAMELBIG factor (1 = 0,970; 2 = 1,000; 3 = 1,050; 4 = 1,100; 5 =

1,150)

a: coefficient determined by the BCRA (from 1995 equal to 0,15, later was

0,10)

Ais: fixed assets

c: coefficient determined by the BCRA (from 1995 was 0,125, at 2006 was

0,08)

15 C.A.M.E.L.: The acronym CAMEL represents Capital adequacy, Asset management,

Management quality and integrity, Earnings quality and stability, and Liquidity. This method was

adopted by the United States regulating institutions in 1978 and evaluates the solvency and stability of the

financial system and financial situation of each entity as it is performed ‘in situ’. From September 2000,

the BCRA started to apply a wider rating system called CAMELBIG considering separately the analysis

of management and business risks (Capital adequacy and quality, Asset management,

Market sensibility, Earnings quality and stability, Liquidity, Business management capacity, internals

controls quality, General management).

Page 17: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

16

Ci: positions in investment accounts

Fspn: financings to the non-financial public sector

r: coefficient determined by the BCRA (from 1995 was 0,115, at 2006 was

0,08)

Vrf: Risk value of loans, other credits due to financial intermediation except

inter-bank operations. Obtained after the sum of the results of the

following expression:

p*Ir*f

where p is the weighed measure as per type of asset (as per Annex I of

the norm), Ir pondered measure as per interest rate (as per Annex II of the

norm) and f is loans, other credits by financial intermediation and other

financings – including guarantees, possible endorsement and other

responsibilities except inter-bank operations)

Vrani: risk value of non-fixed assets not included in ‘f’, ‘Ci’ and ‘Fspn’ after the

sum obtained of applying the following formula:

P*(Ani – f – Ci – Fspn)

Where p is the risk weight (as per Annex I of the norm) and Ani is the

non-fixed assets

As we can see in the formula the interest rate and the type of customer

(measured in the Vrf and Vrani variables) have superlative influence in order to

calculate the provision requirements of the bank, which obviously have direct impact in

the idle resources and profit of the entity.

- For the Vrani variable, in the case of an SME which doesn’t have

collateral the weight can be of 100% of the loan.

- For the Vrf variable, the weight was 0.8 for an investment grade rated

loan going up to 6 for a loan with nominal interest rate higher than 74%

and 78% in dollars and pesos respectively, always on annual term; as

Page 18: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

17

we’re going to see later the SMEs financing are more based on working

capital credit than loans, credit which had interest rates higher than 30%.

In the Table 3 we’ve got a measure of the minimum capital requirements

achieved by the private banking sector at September 1999, clearly we can see that the

system was quite above the Basel suggestions: The requirements of own capital were

12/15% for risky assets and 11,5% for loans, other credits for financial intermediation

and other financings; moreover, and in a broader definition, minimum capital

requirements were 11,5%. As a result of it, the effective integration of minimum capital

of the Argentinean system at 1999/2000 was 37% above the national regulation and

199% above the Basel adequacy. In terms of money the total requirements at the end

1999 were $ 17.600 millions which represented the 21% of deposits; this amount is

quite significant meaning that a reduction would have released considerable resources to

the system. Indeed an approximation calculated on that date affirmed that a reduction of

requirements to a half would’ve represented a liberation of resources equivalent to 13%

of the total loans lent to the non-financial private sector.

* We can mention two more circumstances that added indirectly to the

concentration process:

After the Crisis of 1995 was constituted a deposit insurance fund (similar to the

existent one in the U.S.) managed by SEDESA16 in order to increase the reliance on the

financial system decreasing the risk of deposit running. Nevertheless the particularity of

the Argentinean system was that the insurance covered deposits up to 30.000 pesos or

dollars with an interest rate not higher than 2% of the rate applied by the National Bank

(Banco Nacional de la República Argentina), leaving outside the rest of deposits and the

banks that assumed more risk, making the entities with risky portfolios even more

riskier (i.e. smaller institutions).

Finally the concentration process was encouraged by an institution called Fondo

Fiduciario para el Desarrollo Provincial (Fiduciary Fund for the Provincial

Development). It was created in order to attend liquidity problems of provincial banks

and to support the privatization of them with funds provided by the IMF and the IDB,

this instrument smoothed the privatization process which as mentioned before increased

the concentration effect.

As mentioned previously 10% of the banks in the financial system shared 72%

of deposits at the end of 1999 giving us an idea of the distribution of resources related

with the size of institutions (see Figure 4 for detailed evolution).

16 Seguro de Depósitos Sociedad Anónima.

Page 19: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

18

Note: In some cases, as seems to be the Argentinean one, the ‘systemic risk’ reached

through prudential regulations wouldn’t be a relevant indicator of the decrease in

financing costs of a country, as several sectors of the economy are not included in such

benefits because indeed such benefits have been obtained through their exclusion.

4.3. BASEL II normative and the Size of Banks

The mentioned regulations will be adapted to the norms of BASEL II in order to

be applied in Argentina as of 2010. Without considering the large benefits that would

contribute these norms as far as transparency and financial stability, that in indeed will

be significant, we could also expect certain repercussions with respect to the banking

costs analyzed, as following mentioned.

Among other modifications to the risk measurement systems, the new regulation

put greater emphasis on internal risks management of the bank denominated

`operational risk', that is to say, when the new norm being applied the organizations

must include the risks derived from their operations to calculate its requirements of

capital, and not only the credit risks. In order to confront and to measure this operational

risks the banks will have to apply methods and techniques approved by the Central

Bank, which are fitted in three basic types defined by BASEL II: Basic Indicator

Approach, Standardized Approach, Advanced Measurement Approaches (AMA):

- The basic indicator is calculated with `fundamentals' of the company, like the

annual gross income of the last three years;

- The Standardized Approach divides the activities of the bank in eight lines of

businesses and its relative weight within the organization;

- The Advanced Measurement Approach is the most complex level and requires

the institutions to develop their own internal operational risk measurement

system, in agreement with some general criteria and norms supervised and

approved by the Central bank.

Another indication of BASEL II establishes that the structure or person

responsible of the operational risk will have to be independent of the department of

internal audit, reason why an increase in operative cost could be expected.

Although the new norms do not affect the capital requirements directly, it could

do it on an indirect way mainly to smaller financial organizations, since they modify the

calculation formula:

Page 20: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

19

In first place, the consideration of the operational risk would add another

weighted factor of risk, which would negatively affect the qualification of the portfolio

of SMEs.

Secondly, the implementation of a structure to evaluate the operational risks

could increase as well the operative costs of the banks, reducing the possible economies

of scale in the information generation and increasing the information asymmetries.

According to some analysts (Perrotta, 2007) in the countries that have adopted

these norms, or those which have an advanced implementation, the minimum capital

requirements have increased between 5.5% and 8.9% in Europe and 4% to 13.5% in the

other countries. In general it is considered that the impact will be greater in less

developed financial systems even increasing the requirements until 50%. In the same

way, in the Argentinean case, the financial organizations less prepared to confront these

modifications are the regional banks, the smaller institutions and the branches of foreign

banks with few offices in the country.

5. BANK SIZE, ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION AND SMEs

In the previous sections we’ve analyzed the credit rationing theory and

concentration process taking as main frame the Argentinean case, in this section and the

following ones the work will try to show the empirical evidence found connecting the

credit rationing with the SMEs financing problems but highlighting the importance of

the asymmetric information related with the size of financial entities.

The sequence of relations would be interpreted as:

a) CONCENTRATION � SMALL BANK DECREASE IN NUMBERS

b) ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION INCREASE � TRANSACTIONAL

COST INCREASE (ECONOMIES OF SCALE NOT POSSIBLE)

c) ADVERSE SELECTION � CREDIT RATIONING

Referential frame: a) bank size b) asymmetric information c) SMEs

Page 21: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

20

5.1. The size of the bank – Economies of scale

We can find asymmetric information in all the relations in between the different

agents in the financial system and with different magnitudes: the banks doesn’t have

perfect information about the project, business, profile and intentions of his customers;

the depositors doesn’t have exact information about the risk they’re taking when they

allocate their money; the regulating authorities have difficulties to detect (and

anticipate) bank solvency problems and situations. But in the case of bank/customer

relation, that is our concern, the cost of information is directly related with his

asymmetries, and assuming that banks are intermediaries of information, we’ll accept

the theory developed by Berger and Udell (1995), that ‘the existence of financial

intermediaries are the best evidence that the economies of scale on information are

possible’ in this sector. In other words, we’ll accept that the average cost of information

decreases as the amount of intermediated resources is augmented, which normally

occurs when the size of the entity grows.

This is one of the mechanisms to reach scale economies on information, and can

be achieved by the endogenous growth of the bank or by mergers and acquisitions like

in a concentration process. But what is not very clear despite the synergies that can be

obtained, is if all the information available before the consolidation can be efficiently

absorbed. For example, small banks normally work with an important amount of

informal information that is not completely standardized and even more difficult to

adapt to the complex systems of a large bank. As result of this several information is

lost due to the closing of branches or because is very expensive to include that type of

information.

Is almost impossible to measure this kind of problem but there’re some

anecdotic and empirical evidence (Cuenin, 2000) that would indicate that a large

number of small business profiles have been lost in that period due to the mentioned

closing of branches or due to discrepancies to connect the previous information and the

risk systems applied like Veraz or Credit Scoring.

So far we’ve seen that the economies of scale can be obtained by growth, then

the next question is how small banks can achieve information efficiency, and in this

matter the answer is focused in which kind of information each type of entity, in terms

of size, is based.

Page 22: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

21

5.2. The size of Banks – Information type

The banks normally generates information in order to solve asymmetric

problems through standardized processes, technology investments and formal

procedures (hard information); and personal relations (soft information)17. Each one of

these two different processes has a generation and maintenance costs associated to the

structure of the bank and thus to the scale economies (Berger and Udell, 1995; Ogura

and Uchida, 2007). As mentioned before the fixed costs of information are independent

from the amount of the loan: at the same quality of information the structural costs

needed to support the steps of searching, generating, analyzing and making decision

(e.g. risk department, branches) doesn’t decrease in the same proportion when the

amount of the loan decreases, the situation is the same when the average amount of loan

increases. An example of this is the time spent on a project, that in fact depends on

complexity more than in the amount of the loan involved (the same can be assumed for

other resources spent as personnel or information needed).

Now, we’ve seen in Table 2 that smaller banks had more presence in the SMEs

financing than larger ones, this is explained mainly due to the efficiency information

produced by each institution in relation with his structure. As some empirical studies

suggests (Carter, 2002) the small banks make better choices from the available small

business loans, mainly because they’re better processing credit information than larger

banks. This idea could have correlation with the research of Ogura (2007) in which they

found that smaller banks produces more ‘soft information’ than larger banks, and this

information has more presence in the evaluation of small business (see Table 4).

Our general idea is that larger banks produce more ‘hard information’ and

they’re less able to work with SMEs due to the presence of fixed information costs

(mainly ‘soft info’) which make almost impossible the economies of scale (see Figure

5).

At this point we’re going to make a parallelism with the results of some works:

Carter (2002) found that the smaller banks had higher risk adjusted-yields than large

banks due to their exposure to smaller business but curiously the risk adjusted-yield

decreased as the small business loans increases in the total portfolio, the reason given by

the work was that the smaller banks have a combination of information advantage and

relationship development; in this work we’ll classify these factors as ‘soft information’

(as the definition of Ogura). In the same way Kanatas and Qi (1998, 2003) relates the

17 Scott (2004) and Uchida, Udell, and Yamori (2006).

Page 23: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

22

increase in the cost efficiency of lending as a result of a previous lending relationship

with the customer, ‘as the time increases the information increases’.

The mechanism would be: longer personal relations generates soft information

that decreasing ‘information asymmetries’ provokes a decrease in the interest rates

applied. Then smaller banks due to their particular structure and closer relation with

customer can obtain economies of scale or considerable improvements on cost

efficiency.

The question is which kind of information is effectively used to reach

economies of scale: even recognizing a mixture of hard and soft information in every

entity, we can say that larger banks will be more based on hard information generation

processes and smaller banks in soft information ones. The ‘hard information’ generation

allow economies of scale through formal procedures, complex risk rating systems,

sophisticated computational systems and increasingly complex organizational structures

that are adequate for larger operations but not efficient for small lending and that in

most of the cases are unaffordable for small entities. An anecdotic evidence can be

observed in the Spanish banking system where larger banks policy is focused on the

creation of ‘bank agencies’ not depending directly to the bank (like in the insurance

industry) in order to substitute the traditional branches structure and improve their

efficiency (and profit) through a decrease in fixed costs. In fact this is an inverse process

to concentration in which the bank delegates the managing of regional operations in

third party agencies, which normally manage more ‘soft info’ delegating the ‘hard info’

to the bank.

An evidence of the scale economies obtained through the development of ‘hard

information’ production can be checked in Maudos, Pastor and Quesada (1996) where

they found that due to technological improvements the Spanish Saving Banks obtained

an annual reduction of 0.64% in average costs and 1.93% in operational costs from

1984 up to 1994. In the same way Altunbas and Molyneux (2001) found that this factor

was responsible of an annual reduction of 3% average in the credit costs of the entities

in the UE from 1988 up to 1995.

In resume, smaller banks utilizes proportionally more ‘soft information’ than

larger banks in the lending activity and this kind of information is proportionally more

used by SMEs due to more informal aspects of their business.

Page 24: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

23

Following the theory of Eugene Fama on his ‘Efficient Market Theory’ and the

levels of efficiency18 we’ll present the information efficiency as per bank size in the

following chart:

BANK SIZE

SMALL LARGE

INFORMATION

MARKET

EFFICIENCY

WEAK Hard Info Soft Info

SEMI-STRONG Mix Mix

STRONG Soft Info Hard Info

In our case:

• Size of Bank:

Banks size as per total assets related with the market average.

• Type of Market:

Market with weak information efficiency: we found little information and of bad

quality. `Information asymmetries' are quite abundant and sometimes structural. The

cost of financing are very high and the competence is almost inexistent. An example can

be the market of credit of the SMEs in the sector of largest banks, nevertheless this is

the typical characteristics of the IFS (Informal Market) in marginal regions, in the case

of Argentina is represented by the SME sector of less developed provinces.

Market with semi strong information efficiency: we found a situation

intermediate in which the information can be of good or bad quality, abundant or scarce

or of an intermediate point, in this case will depend almost completely on the

intermediary agent. The gaps between interest rates applied can be significant and the

grade of competition depends on the particular segment or situation. An example we can

find it in the great urban centers within the Argentine market, where the concentration

18 The Efficient Market Hypothesis ("Random Walks in Stock Market Prices," Financial Analysts

Journal, September/October 1965) states that at any given time, security prices fully reflect all available

information. There are three forms of the efficient market hypothesis: 1) The "Weak" form asserts that

all past market prices and data are fully reflected in securities prices. In other words, technical analysis is

of no use. 2) The "Semi strong" form asserts that all publicly available information is fully reflected in

securities prices. In other words, fundamental analysis is of no use. 3) The "Strong" form asserts that all

information is fully reflected in securities prices. In other words, even insider information is of no use.

Page 25: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

24

of capital and information created intermediate situations, some banks obtained

informative efficiency managing the portfolio of SMEs and others not. A peculiar

example is the case of the local mutual companies that, working within the informal

system (IFS) obtained a surprising informative efficiency dealing with apparent very

risky companies.

Market with strong information efficiency: the generation and distribution of

information are obtained at very low cost, in time and suitable form. The interest rate

gap is almost inexistent and the competition is close to perfect. The typical case is

represented by the capital market, nevertheless the credit portfolio of ‘prime’ companies

as the privatized ones are another example within the banking sector.

• Type of Information:

Hard info: Information generated by standardized process and systems, standard

operational procedures, computational mechanisms and other formal procedures. A

typical case is represented by the ‘risk measurement systems’ that large banks are

required to develop and have to be approved by the central banks.

Soft Info: The main source of information is obtained through personal

commercial relations along the time. It’s extremely influenced by the proximity to the

customer and the amount of time, the increase in both factors leads to an increase of

quality and quantity.

Mix Info: The information is generated and maintained by a mixture of both

types. Normally related with geographical factors that allows a centralization of

operations along with a good coverage by branches. The regional banks are a good

example of them, even in some cases they have standardized procedures applied to the

main industry of the covered area and at the same time the commercial department has

close relation with the main producers/customers.

At the end of this section we want to mention some results obtained in recent

works about asymmetric information and requirements of collateral to the SMEs, since

it is directly related to this subject. At the beginning of this decade arose what is called

`Lazy Banks Hypothesis’ according to which the bankers do not monitoring the emitted

loans to SMEs if they have high collaterals from the companies. The idea in general is

that the risk of ‘not monitoring’ is covered by the collateral. Although the hypothesis is

strong, the empirical evidence is not so clear. Some authors like Franks and Sussman

(Franks J. and Sussman O., 2003) supports this theory based in a field work made in the

United Kingdom that threw positive results. Other authors, mainly Japanese (Ono,

Yanagawa, 2003), put in doubt the theory and adduce that the problems are provoked by

Page 26: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

25

deficiencies of the western legislation at the time to face companies financial distress.

Nevertheless from our point of view we’ll suggest as base evidence the work made by

Berger (2007) and people of the Federal Reserve of E.E.U.U., in which they found

strong empirical relation between the availability of information of a borrower and the

collateral required. Over the sample of 14,000 new loans set to SMEs they detected that

the requirements of collateral were smaller as the information gap in between the

borrower and the bank were reducing.

Note: Following the accepted works about credit rationing like Stiglitz and Weiss

(1981), Greenwald and Stiglitz (1986) and Jafee and Stiglitz (1990) we can understand

why a bank classify customers based on imperfect information and the consequent

credit rationing via amount, access or price, but it doesn’t mean that this type of client is

classified in the same way by a small bank since the information available in it causes

that the bank evaluates better the risk that takes, therefore the risk perception can be

smaller shortening ‘information asymmetries’.

5.3. The Argentinean evidence and information generation problems

Based in several studies19 performed on the 90’s in Argentina we can check that

credit rationing and asymmetric information problems had place.

5.3.1. Credit rationing

In first place we can check empirical evidence that shows credit rationing effect

to the SMEs in the Argentinean financial sector. It’s possible to verify an increasing

spread between the amounts lent to SME and the rest of the private sector on the second

half of the decade. It is quite evident the coincidence in between the beginning of the

concentration process and the increase on the spread; over the same period the total

funds lent to the private sector were growing and the amount assigned to SMEs was

stagnated and even decreasing, thus we can say that existed an adjustment via volume

(see Figure 6).

As second empirical evidence we found that the interest rates applied were

constantly high during the same period maintaining an average spread of 13,5% higher

19 FIEL (1996); Yoguel (1999); Cuenin and Busso (2000); Aramburu and Lódola (2000); Arrigoni (2000); Sarghini (2001).

Page 27: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

26

than the rate applied to larger companies, thus there wasn’t a price adjustment via

interest rate (See Table 5 and Figure 7)20.

Finally taking into account that the economy grew at an average rate of 6% and

the participation of the SMEs on the GDP was steady around 30/40% along the same

period, we can assume that the decrease in financing was not followed by a decrease in

the SME participation in the economy, thus the sector maintained his relative size or

even increased it.

This evidence of credit rationing from the point of view of the financial system

(the previous data is collected form banks side) is supported by the results found in the

SMEs sector and even more this situation was recognized by the Institutional sector. A

study performed at the end of the decade (Yoguel, 1999) in between 57 organizations of

different types confirmed that the problems related to credit access were the main factor

that prevented the creation and development of businesses in the SMEs sector. As a

result 77% of the SMEs adduced that interest rates, terms and collaterals required were

the main problem of their business, and most of them had loosed new business

opportunities due to the lack of financing. Confirming this priority the 98% of Official

and Private Institutions recognized that the access to credit were the first problem of the

sector (See Figures 8 and 9).

5.3.2. Asymmetric Information

Up to the mentioned before the SMEs sector suffered ‘credit rationing’ and was

recognized by most of the market agents, now the next point to check is the

‘asymmetric information’ presence.

It is important to remember that a lack of information from the bank increases

the risk perception of a particular customer.

Assuming the results found by Carter (2002) and other researchers, that ‘more

information leads to a decrease in rates applied by the banks’, we couldn’t check in the

Argentinean case the inverse hypothesis that is ‘the interest rates applied didn’t reduce

because the lack of information’, but we’ll present some empirical data that supports the

evidence of information problems in the Argentinean SMEs sector during the second

half of the 90’s in order to obtain an idea of why credit was expensive and not

accessible.

20 13,5% is the average taking the classification of F.I.E.L. (1996) work, our average rate of 17,98% is the result of a simplified measure taking the gap between overdraft current account and ‘Prime’ interest rates, as we can see in Figure 5. Nevertheless in both cases the spread was steady along the period.

Page 28: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

27

The study mentioned found that there were three main problems related with

financing access with the following agreement in between the different agents: excess of

collaterals (85%), high interest rates (81%) and deficient evaluation (57%)

The case of high collateral requirements often occurs when the information

about the company or the project is deficient so the banks use this instrument to cover

potential looses, said in other words, the asymmetric information is intended to be

reduced increasing the responsibility of the borrower. Increasing the information

available the project is less risky then less collateral is required.

The high interest rates were consequence of the risk perception of the business.

The sector indeed has higher dilatoriness rates than the rest of portfolios, nevertheless

what is curious is that the rate didn’t decrease in the period probably because the

information was constant or declining along the time. Following Carter’s position we

would say that increasing the information available along the time would’ve encouraged

the rates declining.

More directly connected with ‘asymmetric information’ problem is the

evaluation deficiencies adduced. This is a direct evidence of ‘credit rationing’ due to

lack of information quantity and quality.

Another circumstance, not mentioned by the SMEs but found as a result on some

studies (FIEL, 1996; Yoguel, 1999), is that the size of the company was the unique

influential characteristic in order to access credit, excluding the rest of factors like

dynamism, belonging sector, external market business, location or age characteristics.

This can be observed as a ‘rationing’ in which smaller companies are not being taken in

consideration due to the costs needed to generate adequate information.

In resume, we’ll say that every aspect of the ‘credit rationing’ factors, i.e.

collateral requirements, interest rates, project/company evaluation, monitoring,

‘incentive effect’, variety of conditions, high mortality, can be positively affected thanks

to an improvement in the information quality and quantity (diminishing ‘asymmetric

information’).

As can be noticed we’ve related the main obstacles of financing with the

‘asymmetric information’ problem, the same process we’ve made at the beginning

under a theoretical frame relating the main causes of credit rationing with the

‘asymmetric information’ one (Section ‘Credit rationing: Focusing in asymmetric

information’).

Page 29: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

28

5.4. Measurement systems

The information available regarding the measurement systems used in this

period by the Argentinean financial system is scarce, imprecise and not very reliable,

thus we’ll base our analysis in a work performed by the BCRA on October 2006

(Pailhé, 2006). We’ve to recognize that the macroeconomic situation suffered

significant changes ten years after the period that occupy our work, but in terms of

internal development of the banking system the techniques and procedures applied to

each customer are quite similar, thus the analysis in this section has to be taken with

some precautions.

The measurement technique was and is based on two basic tools which are the

‘scoring’ and ‘rating’ ones. The ‘scoring’ tool is more used to evaluate individuals and

SMEs; the ‘rating’ tool is applied to larger companies.

• Scoring system

The scoring is a tool that allows classifying the applicants of credits and debtors

based on its risk, assigning them to groups or giving a determined amount of points

(score).

In that process the system uses statistical techniques or artificial intelligence,

assigning to each group or score a risk level (probability of default).

These systems are used in the origination of credits, comparing the minimum

value (cut-off) associated to the risk that the bank would accept and the return expected.

This is known as Lending Scoring System.

They are also used in the monitoring of the clients, to manage credit limits, to

identify profitable accounts, to offer new products, to monitoring risk and to anticipate

collection problems. This is known as ‘Monitoring Scoring System’

• Rating:

Whereas the scores are used mainly for individuals and SMEs, the ratings are

used to evaluate larger companies. This method reflects the credit quality of the

borrower without taking into consideration the type of product that the customer has

taken form the entity.

The rating must represent the evaluation of the bank on the capacity and

will of the borrower to fulfil the contract despite of unfavourable economic conditions

or the occurrence of unexpected events.

Page 30: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

29

These systems in general have more degrees of risk classification than the norms

of the BCRA. In such sense, these organizations declared to have scales up to 26

degrees or levels of risk.

These two systems were the most used by the financial institutions, obviously

not taking into consideration the ‘soft information’ produced by commercial

departments and agents in general. But what is more interesting for our analysis is the

coverage that these techniques had in relation with the SME sector. We’re going to be

focused in the ‘Scoring’ method as was the one applied to evaluate the SME sector.

Again there’s no information available on the period covered by this work, but

we can accept a high grade of similarity with the results obtained on 2006.

5.4.1. Lending scoring system

As a considerable percentage of ‘personal loans’ are in fact ‘SME loans’ we’re

going to consider both in the data obtained. The same showed that 85% of the entities

used some kind of scoring system to ‘personal segment’. In between them only 30%

declared that the ‘score’ result was decisive in the lending decision, the rest of the

entities used this technique along with another kind of decision tools.

Only 15% of the entities declared to have in operation scoring systems for

SMEs, representing around 19% of the commercial credits (see Figure 10).

The ‘scoring systems’ were developed internally in half of the banks considered

in the study, the rest were using systems developed by third parties or even outsourcing

the task. In general in the development of the systems statistical techniques are used

prevailing the logistic regression. The risk of default measure increases as the score

decreases.

At this point we’ve to clear an important point: due to the lack of valuable

collaterals a large percentage of SMEs borrow money as ‘personal loans’, this is not in

the name of the company but in the name of the owner of it.

5.4.2. Monitoring scoring system

Regarding ‘personal segment’ half of the financial institutions counted on a

monitoring scoring system basically to increase the limits of financings granted, thus

half of the entities didn’t used a ‘hard information’ generation system for this purpose.

Page 31: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

30

Half of the systems were internally developed.

On the ‘SME segment’ only 5% of the organizations declared to have in

application a monitoring scoring system for overdraft current accounts, that due to the

type of product is considered applicable for SMEs.

5.4.3. Notes on the scoring system.

Another important circumstance was that most of the entities coincided on the

information regarding customer identification, risk evaluation and legal-economic

information, but regarding the ‘collaterals’ the information dispersion was absolute.

This point can give us an idea of the ‘asymmetric information’ existed between banks

and borrowers at the time of evaluate collateral requirements.

In general terms we’ll consider an intermediate situation in between the

‘personal segment’ and ‘SMEs segment’ at the moment to analyze the ‘hard

information’ generation in the banks on the period 1994/00.

However, it was observed that it would’ve worked as a ‘first filter’, in which

based on score further actions are taken, which they can be the rejection of the request

(low scores), manual revision (scores intervals) or fulfilment of other requirements, like

for example the relation income/quote (high scores).

Following the results obtained by some studies (Sarghini, 2001; Pailhé, 2006)

we can conclude that the information generated in order to evaluate the SME financing

demands was based mainly on ‘soft information techniques’. The ‘hard information’

generation was relatively more used in larger companies through methods like ‘rating’

or ‘scoring system’, but even so the financial system doesn’t seems to have been a ‘hard

info’ based one.

Closing this section we’re going to make a mention to the Latin American

market situation and to an experience evaluated in the United States.

The characteristics of the ‘credit risk’ measurement systems were similar in all

the Latham countries over the same period with different grades. On average the ‘credit

scoring’ was used by 14% of the smaller banks to evaluate SMEs loans and 71% of

them used the ‘case by case’ method, that obviously represents higher evaluation costs.

Curiously the situation wasn’t very different for the rest of banks by size, thus 12% of

medium sized banks used the ‘credit scoring’ and 74% the ‘case by case’ one (see Table

6). So we can conclude that the high information costs were present in most Latham

financial systems of the period.

Page 32: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

31

Finally we’re going to make reference to the work performed by the Federal

Reserve of the United States (Berger, 2007): they evaluated the performance of a new

‘risk measurement’ system called SBCS (Small Business Credit Scoring) on the period

1993/97. In between 14.000 individual newly issued loans to small business they found

that banks using this technology reduced the information gaps, lessened their need for

collateral and furthermore reduced the borrower and lender costs improving the

efficiency of the small business lending market.

6. MICROECONOMICS

Before the conclusion of this work we believe that it is important to give a

microeconomic vision on the cost of financing of a SME. Until now we’ve analyzed the

impact that the information asymmetries cause on the financing costs but from the credit

organization point of view, in this section we will make a brief reference to the impact

of the financing costs on the structure of a SME. In the first part we’ll mention the

importance of the working capital within the company and soon will develop a practical

case to give an idea of the effects of the working capital cost on the SME.

6.1. Working Capital

Most of the works published in the decade of the 90’s in Argentina (FIEL, 1996;

Salloum, 1997; Yoguel, 1999; UIA 1999) agree on the critical importance of the

working capital in the SMEs, although it is certain that this factor is important in any

company the working capital increases it relative incidence as the size in terms of total

sales diminishes. The results of these works showed that the average percentage of

working capital over gross sales that companies had to maintain for its operation was

0/10% for larger companies, 20/40% for medium and 40/+% for smaller ones.

However, another important factor to consider is that the SMEs normally had to

maintain this working capital with own funds in greater proportion than larger

companies, this forced smaller companies to reinvest profits in a greater proportion

which indeed affected their profitability. As evidence, the mentioned works found that

70% of the companies of all sizes confirmed that were using the utilities reinvestment as

financing source.

Page 33: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

32

In summary, due to the lack of information about the liquidity of the business the

banks rationed credit, thus the companies were forced to reinvest profits or turned to the

financing of suppliers in order to maintain their working capital. Another result of

theses works was that this relation reverted as the size of the companies increased.

The mentioned circumstance has already been observed by the governments of some

countries, such the case of E.E.U.U.: the SBA provided financial guarantees on 70/85%

of the amount for working and fixed capital to 180,000 loans, estimated in U$S 31,000

million between 1980 and 1990. The result according to a study of Price Waterhouse

(1992) on the matter, demonstrated that the companies covered by this guarantee had

grown 300% whereas the rest had only grown 37% in the period 1984/8921. This

empirical evidence talks by itself about the superlative importance that the working

capital (liquidity) has in the business of the SMEs.

In the first part of the Annex I developed a practical model in order to somehow

measure the incidence that has an increase of the interest rate in the cost of working

capital.

7. DISCUSSION

The possible solutions to the credit rationing faced by the SMEs are related with

the improvement on the amount and quality of information generated by the sector in

his relation with the financial system.

In the first place the classification in small and medium enterprise has to be

defined according to the special feature of each economy. This is a common mistake

that distorts the analyses and the policies to apply, more even this classification varies

with the time as the economy is developed and its structure changes.

In second term, as far as the specific problems and their possible solution we

could mention:

* The `visibility' problems within the credit market could be improved with the

access of the SMEs to the capital markets, creating a simplified legislation and reducing

entrance costs. The creation of a stock-exchange board for this type of companies is an

instrument used by some markets that usually produce good results if it is sufficiently

21 Another result of the evaluation performed by Price Waterhouse regarding this program was that the employment grew 167% in between the sector covered by this guarantees and no growth was observed in the rest of the companies evaluated. The ILO (International Labour Organization), along with the Office of Financial Attendance, administers and in some cases directs the programs of the SBA for development of exports and the Working Capital of Exporters Program.

Page 34: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

33

supported by the government. The RGC (Reciprocal Guarantee Companies) or MGC

(Mutual Guarantee Company)22 can also be used to improve the entrance on the credit

markets.

* The internal information of the company and audit normally presents

enormous gaps of information and quality. In this sense a possible solution would be to

create accounting norms with specific international standards for the SMEs, as the IAS

developed for large companies. In this case also the simplicity and low costs would

have a fundamental importance to ensure the success of this tool.

* Another problem related to the previous point is the little interest of the credit

rating companies to evaluate the credit quality of the SMEs adducing costs reasons,

which is certain in most of the cases. These qualifications are very useful mainly for the

entrance on the capital market. This situation could be moderated somehow with the

support of the governmental authorities and the financial supervisors to lower the price

of this `qualification cost'. To mention a case, in Germany exist a ‘record of private

debt’ that facilitates the work of the credit rating companies23, in the same way the State

recognizes that the SMEs does not have appropriate cost procedures reason why a large

part of the consultancy subventions are directed to solve this difficulty.

* With respect to the problems of collaterals asked by the banks we’ve seen that

the RGC normally gives good results when there’s a good coordination in between the

agents involved, nevertheless their effects can be very limited towards a specific sector,

thus the benefits of this instrument for the general sector is a little doubtful. In this sense

we must remember that the requirements of collateral have direct relation with the

information available (as we’ve seen on the section `Size of bank - Type of

information'), therefore we could expect for a reduction on collateral requirements if the

information available is improved by the measures mentioned in the previous points,

this way would produce a much more ample effect than the obtained one with the RGC.

* Also it is important to emphasize an endemic problem of the SME sector as it

is the high dilatoriness with respect to the rest of the sectors. This is a characteristic

without solution since it is inherent to his structure, nevertheless it can be reduced. In

many cases the bankruptcy laws of some countries have particularly pernicious

regulations for this type of companies, in this sense the legislation has to be improved

taking into consideration their particular structure and increasing the possibilities of

negotiation and solution previous to the ‘going to concern’ process.

22 In Spanish: SGR (Sociedad de Garantía Recíproca) 23 According to the Section 14 of the German Banking Act, banks have to report every customer with a credit exposure in excess of DM 3 million to the Bundesbank. In response, the Bundesbank informs the bank of the total volume of reported credit exposures recorded for the debtor in question and the number of banks reporting. On the other hand in the U.S., the Federal Reserve Board prohibited banks from transferring non-public information between their lending and underwriting arms until October 31, 1997.

Page 35: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

34

* Finally we think that it is important to mention a structural aspect of the

banking system as it is the reduction of branches, process that may be related to the

banking concentration. If we compared the more developed financial systems we found

in all of them a common pattern which is the high ratio of financial branches per capita,

to mention some cases in the United Kingdom this relation was of 25 branches every

100,000 inhabitants, the same was 98 in Spain, 28 in Greece or 69 in Germany, whereas

in Argentina that relation was of 12 branches by the same proportion of population. In

the 90’s all these systems had some degree of concentration reason why we could say

that the problem is not the concentration itself, but the maintenance of the necessary

structure to efficiently attend the demands of the market. In this sense it is necessary

that the development of medium banks or the correct distribution of the existing ones

were stimulated. This problem in particular can lose relevance in the future if the

technological advances can substitute the function of the branches.

However in the particular case of Argentina, that it is the empirical frame which

we took for this work, some improvements have been performed from the end of the

analyzed period to the present time. The access to the capital market has been

stimulated by the Government and the CNV24 with the creation of the Panel de

Acciones PyME (Chart of SME Equities) on December 2006. With this differentiated

chart of negotiation the companies have access to different instruments like negotiable

obligations emission, financial trusts and deferred payment check negotiation, and is

even encouraging the financing through Venture Capital. The quotation regime has been

simplified for these companies.

The participation of RGC has been also increased in order to canalize resources

from the capital market towards the SME sector (20 RGC on 2007 with an amount of

587 ARG$ million, about U$S 185 million).

Nevertheless, the financial system is still undeveloped in terms of size and the

volumes compromised in the FFS are small: as per official data loans are equivalent to

19,65% and deposits 34,16% of the GDP25. But in this case the situation is not very

clear because the effects of the ‘Tango Crisis’ in 2001 are still latent, thus the actual size

can be transitory and can experiment an important increase if the confidence in the

economy attracts more capitals to the system (see Table 7).

As some other obstacles to mention, the SME sector has to be redefined as the

present parameters exclude several companies from official policy, in example the

24 CNV: Acronym of Comisión Nacional de Valores the equivalent of the NYSE in the United Status. 25 Source: MECON (Ministerio de Economía y Producción – Rep. Argentina), I Semester/2007, constant prices of 1993. Some economist adduce that the real size is smaller.

Page 36: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

35

average gross income considered is ARG$ 42 million (around U$S 14 million) that is

too low for the sector, in the same sense the maximum amount of Negotiable

Obligations for SMEs is ARG$ 5 million (around U$S 1,6 million) clearly insufficient .

8. CONCLUSIONS

Making some final comments on the analyzed subjects, we will say that the

banking concentration in itself is neither bad nor good, but that the economy depends on

the correct operation of the financial system. This correct operation depends as well on

the level of development and critical mass in general, and upon the structure of the

system in particular. Thus we can find concentrated banking systems but with an

efficient operation so the case of Spain, or other very atomized but equally effective in

its relation with the SMEs like the German one.

It is now then where the problem of the information asymmetries starts playing

his role, kind of problem that we tried to highlight in this work relating it to the sector of

the SMEs that indeed is particularly sensible to this phenomenon. The consequences

are even ampler if we only considered the developing countries, since the presence of an

informal economy without access to the FFS aggravates the growth problems. Making

mention to the case of Argentina we will say that according to some studies (Arrigoni,

2000) one out of two SME in Argentina was financed by the informal financial system

(IFS) with a life expectancy considerably smaller. The case is representative for the rest

of emergent economies with different implications but with strong presence of

information asymmetries in all of them.

Thus, and beside direct active policies like the lines of credit or subsidies to

specific sectors, policies would be created in order to diminish the existing information

asymmetries between the financial intermediaries, the investment opportunities and the

money savers in general. Only after reaching an `efficient financial market', that at the

end is an ` efficient information market', then sustainable policies could be generated to

support the productive sectors that really need them.

Even more, any substantial improvement in the information will reduce the risk

of the financial system and it will even be able to reduce the procyclical tendencies of

the economy and other macroeconomic consequences, reinforcing the system to face

external shocks.

Page 37: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

36

REFERENCES

Altunbas Y. and Molyneux P. (2001): ‘Technical change in European Banking’,

Gardener (ed.), Bank Strategies and Challenges in the New Europe, Macmillan Press

Ltd., Wiltshire.

Aramburu P. and Lódola A. (2000): ‘Crecimiento Sostenido y con Equidad: el Rol del

Financiamiento’, Cuadernos de Economía Nro. 52, Ministerio de Economía de la

Provincia de Buenos Aires. Available at

http://www.ec.gba.gov.ar/GIE/Investigacion/Cuadernos.htm

Arrigoni M. (2000): ‘La Banca Informal’, ABA Anual Meeting.

Bebczuk R. (2003): ‘Asymmetric Information in Financial Markets, Introduction and

Applications’, Cambridge University Press.

Bebczuk R. (2004): ‘What Determines the Access to Credit by SMEs in Argentina?’,

UNLP, Documento de Trabajo Nro. 18. Available at www.depeco.econo.unlp.edu.ar

Berger A. and Udell G. (1995): ‘Lines of Credit and Relationship Lending in Small

Firm Finance’, Wharton School, FIC, Working Paper 94-11.

Berger A., Espinosa-Vega M., Frame S. and Miller Nathan. (2007): "Why Do

Borrowers Pledge Collateral? New Empirical Evidence on the Role of Asymmetric

Information", FRB of Atlanta, Working Paper No. 2006-29ª.

Birdsall N., Graham C. and Sabot R.(1998): ‘Beyond Tradeoffs. Market Reforms and

Equitable Growth in Latin America’, Editors, Inter-American Development Bank

Brookings institution Press.

Bleger L. and Rozenwurcel G. (1999): ‘Financiamiento a las Pymes y cambio

estructural en la Argentina. Un estudio de caso sobre fallas de mercado y problemas de

información’, Desarrollo Económico – Revista de Ciencias Sociales, IDES, Buenos

Aires, vol. 40, Nº 157, abril-junio 2000 (pp. 45-71).

Page 38: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

37

Boletín Estadístico, Notas Metodológicas, Gerencia de Coyuntura Monetaria,

Subgerencia de Estadísticas Monetarias, BCRA. Available at

http://www.bcra.gov.ar/pdfs/estadistica/bolmetes.pdf

Burghof H.(1999): ‘Credit and Information in Universal Banking – a Clinical Study’,

University of Hohenheim.

Carter D., McNulty J. and Verbrugge J. (2002): ‘Do Small Banks Have an Advantage in

Lending? An Examination of Small Business Lending Performance for Large and Small

Banks’, Oklahoma State University - Stillwater - Department of Finance , Florida

Atlantic University and University of Georgia - Department of Banking and Finance,

Working Paper Series.

Cuenin F. and Busso M. (2000): ‘La transformación del sistema financiero argentino.

Concentración bancaria, eficiencia y financiamiento’, Cuadernos de Economía Nro. 53,

Ministerio de Economía de la Provincia de Buenos Aires. Available at

http://www.ec.gba.gov.ar/GIE/Investigacion/Cuadernos.htm

D'Amato L., Grubisic, E. and Powell A. (1997): ‘Contagion, Banks Fundamentals or

Macroeconomic Shock? An empirical Analysis of the Argentine 1995 Banking

Problems’, Working Paper Number 2. Available at www.bcra.gov.ar

Dujovne N. and Guidotti P. (2001): ‘El sistema financiero argentino y su regulación

prudencial’, Universidad Torcuato Di Tella, Buenos Aires.

Escudé G., Burdisso T., Catena M., D’Amato L., McCandless G. and Murphy T.

(2001):’ Las MIPyMES y el mercado de crédito en la Argentina’, Gerencia de

Investigaciones Económico Financieras, Banco Central de la República Argentina,

Documento de Trabajo Nro. 15.

F.I.E.L. (1996): ‘Las Pequeñas y Medianas Empresas en la Argentina’, Fundación de

Investigaciones Latinoamericanas, Ed. Manantial.

FELABAN, FOMIN and D’Alessio Irol (2004): ‘Estudio sobre la Predisposición de las

Entidades Financieras de Latinoamérica y Caribe para la Financiación de las Pequeñas y

Medianas Empresas’, Bogotá, www.felaban.com.

Page 39: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

38

Franks J. and Sussman O. (2003): ‘Financial Distress and Bank Restructuring of Small

to Medium Size UK Companies’, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3915.

Galindo Lucas, A. (2005): ‘El tamaño empresarial como factor de diversidad’,

electronic edition. 2005. Available at www.eumed.net/libros/2005/agl3/

Greenwald B. and Stiglitz J. (1986): ‘Externalities in Economies with Imperfect

Information and Incomplete Markets’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, CI, p. 229/264.

Jaffee D. and Stiglitz J. (1990): ‘Credit Rationing’, in Handbook of Monetary

Economics, Vol. II (ed. B.M. Friedman and F.H. Hahn), Elsevier Science Publishers

N.V., C. 16.

Kanatas G. and Qi J. (1998): ‘Underwriting by Commercial Banks: Incentive Conflicts,

Scope Economies, and Project Quality’, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 30 p.

119/133.

Kanatas G. and Qi J. (2004): ‘Dividends and Debt with Managerial Agency and Lender

Holdup’, Management Science p. 1249/1260.

Kanatas G. and Qi J. (2004): ‘Imperfect Competition, Debt, and Exit’, Financial

Management 29 p. 49.

Maudos J., Pastor J. and Quesada J. (1996): ‘Technical progress in Spanish banking:

1985-1994’, IVIE Discussion Paper, WP-EC 96-06.

Ogura Y. and Uchida H. (2007): ‘Bank Consolidation and Soft Information Acquisition

in Small Business Lending’, RIETI Discussion Paper No. 07-E-037, Institute of

Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University and Wakayama University - Faculty of

Economics, Working Paper Series.

Ono A. and Uesugi I. (2005): ‘The Role of Collateral and Personal Guarantees in

Relationship Lending: Evidence from Japan’s Small Business Loan Market’, Mizuho

Research Institute, Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry.

Pailhé C. (2006): ‘Information systems for the management of credit risk: survey in the

Argentine financial system (In Spanish)’, BCRA, Munich Personal RePEc Archive,

Page 40: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

39

MPRA Paper No. 1170, posted 13. December 2006. Available online at

http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/ 1170/

Perrotta D. (2007): ‘Las directrices de Basilea 2 - Nuevo marco para el Mercado

financiero’, Mercado Journal, Finanzas, p. 90/92.

Porto J: (2000): ‘Costo Financiero: Crecimiento o Quiebra de las PyMEs’, MECON,

Centro de Documentación e Información, Working Papers AR-AHA:338.963 Arg.

C666con, Buenos Aires. Available at: http://cdi.mecon.gov.ar/

Rojas-Suárez L. (2005): ‘El Acceso a los Servicios Bancarios en América Latina:

Identificación de Obstáculos’, Senior Fellow, Center for Global Development,

document prepared for the Project ‘Acceso al Crédito y los Servicios Financieros’ of the

Secretaría General Iberoamericana’.

Salloum C., Foco G. and Vigier H. (1997): ‘El sistema financiero informal y la

asistencia a las PyMes: el caso de Bahía Blanca’, Anales de la AAEP, XXXVI Anual

Meeting 2001. Available at http://www.aaep.org.ar/

Sarghini J. (coordinator), Lódola A. and Moccero D. (2001): ‘El Dilema de la Economía

Informal: Evidencias y Políticas’, Cuadernos de Economía Nro. 59, Ministerio de

Economía de la Provincia de Buenos Aires.

Scott J. (2004): ‘Small Business and the Value of Community Financial Institutions’,

Journal of Financial Services Research, 25 p. 207/230.

Uchida H., Udell G. and Yamori N.(2006): ‘Loan Officers and Relationship Lending’,

RIETI Discussion Paper No. 06-E-029. Available at SSRN:

http://ssrn.com/abstract=926981

UIA - Unión Industrial Argentina (1997): ‘Observatorio permanente de las PyMIs

argentinas - Informe a las Empresas sobre el Resultado de la Primera Encuesta

Industrial Estructural’, Buenos Aires, Instituto para el Desarrollo Industrial de la UIA.

UIA - Unión Industrial Argentina (1999): ‘Observatorio permanente de las PyMIs

argentinas - Tercera Encuesta Industrial Estructural: Resultados Preliminares’, mimeo,

Buenos Aires, Instituto para el Desarrollo Industrial de la UIA.

Page 41: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

40

Winborg J. (1997): ‘Finance in Small Businesses. A Widened Approach to Small Business’, Managers Handling of Finance, Halmstad University, Sweden.

Yanagawa N. (2003): “Comments on ‘Financial Distress and Bank Restructuring of

Small to Medium Size UK Companies’ and ‘Bankruptcy Resolution in Japan’”, RIETI

and University of Tokyo, RIETI working papers. Available at

http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/index.html

Yoguel G., Moori-Koening V. (coordinators), Angelleli P., Gutman G., Milesi D.,

Rabetino R., Novak D., Gatto F. and Roitter S. (1999): ‘Los Problemas del Entorno de

Negocios. Desarrollo Competitivo de las PyMEs Argentinas’, Ciepp, Fundes Argentina,

Universidad Nacional de General Sarmiento, Ed. Miño y Dávila.

Page 42: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

41

ANNEX

Simulation. FINANCIAL COST OF WORKING CAPITAL

In first place is important to mention that the model developed here is not

supported by neither and academic nor empirical research nor is representative of any

specific SME sector, nevertheless it is useful to give us a close idea on the real

economic and financial effort that a small-medium enterprise has to confront with

increasing financing costs.

Starting the simulation in the first scenario we’re going to determine the

economic point of equilibrium of the SME, in a second step we’re going to determine

the financial point of equilibrium with a monthly interest rate of 1% and finally with a

monthly interest rate of 3%.

STARTING SCENARIO: Economic and financial data

* Simplifying points: no stock, the business cycle is 90 days (money-goods-money) starting on

January, incomes and outcomes segmented by ‘sales, fixed and variables’, periods of payments

and collection every 30 days, if financial surplus exist we’ll not consider investment

opportunities.

MONTHLY ECONOMIC DATA OF THE SME

Total sales (per unit) 50.000

Price (per unit) 10

TOTAL SALES 500.000

Variable costs (per unit) 7

TOTAL VARIABLE COSTS 350.000

Marginal profit 150.000

FIXED COSTS 135.000

EBITDA 15.000*

BREAK EVEN POINT (per unit) 45.000**

* EBITDA = (50.000 - 45.000) x (10 – 7) = 15.000

** Break Even Point = 135.000 = 45.000

(10 – 7)

Page 43: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

42

BUSINESS CYCLE (purchase-goods production-sales)

VALUES

PAYMENTS / COLLECTIONS

0 days 30 days 60 days 90 days

Sale price 10 0% 33% 33% 34%

Variable C. 7 50% 50%

Fixed C. 135.000 70% 30%

BUSINESS CYCLE - BREAK EVEN POINT - 45.000 units

Units Value Total

U$S 0 days 30 days 60 days 90 days

Total sales 45.000 10 450.000 0 148.500 148.500 153.000

Variable C. 45.000 7 (315.000) (157.500) (157.500) - -

Fixed C. 135.000 (135.000) (94.500) (40.500) - -

Net result 0 (252.000) (49.500) 148.500 153.000

SCENARIO A: Working capital cost at 1% monthly interest rate

Starting point: FINANCIAL COST - 1% INTEREST RATE - 45.000 units

0 days 30 days 60days 90 days

Cash/Banks – Start month - (254.520) (307.060) (160.146)

Net result Payment/Collections (252.000) (49.500) 148.500 153.000

Sub-Total (252.000) (304.020) (158.560) (7.146)

Financial cost (1% monthly) (2.520) (3.040) (1.586)

Cash/Banks – End month (254.520) (307.060) (160.146)

Net result at the end of the cycle = (7.146)

New Sale Price at discounting cash flows (1%) = 9,8023 )01,1(

0,34

(1,01)

0,33

1,01

0,33

1

0,0 x 10

32=

+++

Page 44: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

43

New Variable Cost at discounting cash flow (1%) =

New Fixed Cost at discounting cash flow (1%) =

New Break Even Point at 1% interest rate =

New Break Even Point = 47.445 units

NEW BREAK EVEN POINT (1%) = 47.445 units

Units Value Total

U$S 0 days 30 days 60 days 90 days

Total Sales 47.445 10 474.450 0 156.568 156.568 161.313

Variable C. 47.445 7 (332.115) (166.057) (166.057) - -

Fixed C. 135.000 (135.000) (94.500) (40.500) - -

Net result 7.335 (260.557) (49.989) 156.568 161.313

FINANCIAL COST - BREAK EVEN POINT (1%) - 47.445 units

0 days 30 days 60days 90 days

Cash/Banks – Start month - (263.163) (316.283) (161.312)

Net result Payment/Collections (260.557) (49.989) 156.568 161.313

Sub-Total (260.557) (313.152) (159.715)

Financial cost (1% monthly) (2.605) (3.131.52) (1.597)

Cash/Banks – End month (263.163) (316.283) (161.312)

- In the scenario A to maintain a working capital at a nominal interest rate of 1% (monthly) the

company needs an increase of 5.5% on the total sales to reach the new break even point.

- Note that the net result of U$S 7.335 is used to cover the financial costs

� (2.605) + (3.131) + (1.597) = U$S 7.333

- Nevertheless if we consider the present sales volume the company still has a positive EBIT:

(Total sales unit – B/Even point 1% unit) x Marginal profit = 2.555 units x U$S 3 = U$S 7665

or

(EBITDA – Financial expenses) = U$S 15.000 – U$S 7.333 = U$S 7.667

6,9653 = 1,01

0,50 +

1

0,50 x 7

99134.599,00 1,01

0,30

1

0,70 x 135.000 =

+

units 47.445 6,9653 9,8023

134.599,01 =

Page 45: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

44

SCENARIO B: Working capital cost at 3% monthly interest rate

Starting point: FINANCIAL COST - 3% INTEREST RATE - 45.000 units

0 days 30 days 60days 90 days

Cash/Banks – Start month - (259.560) (318.332) (174.927)

Net result Payment/Collections (252.000) (49.500) 148.500 153.000

Sub-Total (252.000) (309.060) (169.832) (21.927)

Financial cost (3% monthly) (7.560) (9.272) (5.095)

Cash/Banks – End month (259.560) (318.332) (174.927)

Net result at the end of the cycle = (21.927)

New Sale Price at discounting cash flows (3%) =

New Variable Cost at discounting cash flow (3%) =

New Fixed Cost at discounting cash flow (3%) =

New Break Even Point at 1% interest rate =

New Break Even Point = 52.938 units

NEW BREAK EVEN POINT (3%) = 52.938 units

Units Value Total

U$S 0 days 30 days 60 days 90 days

Total Sales 52.938 10 529.380 0 174.695 174.695 179.990

Variable C. 52.938 7 (370.566) (185.283) (185.283) - -

Fixed C. 135.000 (135.000) (94.500) (40.500) - -

Net result 23.814 (279.783) (51.088) 174.695 179.990

9,4259 (1,03)

0,34

(1,03)

0,33

1,03

0,33

1

0,0 x 10

32=

+++

6,8980 1,03

0,50

1

0,50 x 7 =

+

33.820,3881 1,03

0,30

1

0,70 x 135.000 =

+

52.938 6,8980 - 9,4259

8133.820,38 =

Page 46: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

45

FINANCIAL COST - BREAK EVEN POINT (3%) - 52.938 units

0 days 30 days 60days 90 days

Cash/Banks – Start month - (288.176) (349.442) (179.989)

Net result Payment/Collections (279.783) (51.088) 174.695 179.990

Sub-Total (279.783) (339.264) (174.747)

Financial cost (3% monthly) (8.393) (10.178) (5.242)

Cash/Banks – End month (288.176) (349.442) (179.989)

- In the scenario B to maintain a working capital at a nominal interest rate of 3% (monthly) the

company needs an increase of 17.6% on the sales volume to reach the new break even point.

- Note that the net result of U$S 23.814 is used to cover the financial costs

� (8.393) + (10.178) + (5.242) = U$S 23.813

- If the sales volume keeps constant at this interest rate the company will be under looses:

(Total sales unit – B/E point 3% unit) x Marginal profit = (2.938) units x U$S 3 = U$S (8.814)

or

(EBITDA – Financial expenses) = U$S 15.000 - U$S 23.814 = (U$S 8.814)

Note: Simulation based on Porto J. (2000) available at http://cdi.mecon.gov.ar/

Comments

As mentioned previously the simulation performed has indicative character and

it doesn’t has to be taken as irrefutable fact. Nevertheless the financial results obtained

have coherence with the data published in the period:

• The financing of the SMEs depended mainly on working capital which

was based (and it is based) on `overdraft on current accounts' whereas the financing of

‘prime companies’ is guided by the ‘Prime’ interest rate. However, the interest rate

applied for `overdraft on current accounts' was of 32.37% average and the ‘prime’ rate

was of 11.49% on average (see Figure 11) reason why our simulation has coherence

when calculating two scenarios with monthly rates of 1% and 3%.

• According to some works (Yoguel, 1999; UIA, 1997) more than 70% of

the SMES had unsatisfied needs of working capital financing and adduced like main

obstacle the high interest rates.

• Although the rate of 32.37% comes from official data, it does not

represent the total of the sector. According to some works published at the end of the

90’s (Salloum, 1997; Arrigoni, 2000; Sarghini, 2001) half of the SMEs worked with the

Page 47: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

46

informal market of credit (IFS), and the rates applied were quite higher than the ones

published by the central bank normally surpassing 50% annually, reason why it is

possible to expect for more critical situations than the simulated in this section.

NEWS 1. SMEs FINANCING DEBATE. IN THE BCRA THEY ASSURE THAT THE BANKING CONCENTRATION DID NOT HAVE A SLANT AGAINST THE SMEs

Who takes care on the SMEs financing? A work of the BCRA reveals unknown aspects of the financing to the small companies. Not all are in agreement with the conclusions. History between the banks and the SMEs (small and medium enterprises) holds a plot of love and hatred. More hatred than love, will say a small retailer from Buenos Aires that this week found out that a bank charged to him a 50% interest by an overdraft current account with agreement. “But nevertheless we want them”, will said the banks, that knows that it is not good business to ignore a sector that in Argentina generates more than the 70% of the economy added value. In order to get the things even more confusing, the discussion occurs in a field of slippery statistics, with few solid numbers. “The truth is that it is tremendously difficult to obtain information in this area”, explains Miguel Arrigoni, a specialist in corporate finances of Deloitte & Touche. Facing this lack of information, the investigators of the Central bank felt that they were in front of a statistical gold mine when they decided to approach the subject from a source until now virgin: the ‘Central de Deudores del Sistema Financiero’ (a centralized database of debtors in the financial system), a base that contains all the debts greater than 50 pesos (around U$S 16 at 2007). “The amount of information that there is in the database is overwhelming: we’re talking about millions data”, says Guillermo Escudé, manager of the equipment of Economic and Financial Investigations of the BCRA. According to the study ‘Las MIPyMEs y el mercado de crédito en la Argentina’ (see Escudé, 2001 on the Appendix), that recently appeared and that it includes temporary series for period 1998-2000, more than half of the loans of the financial system go to this sector. The work of the BCRA was already circulating around the banks, and caused confronted reactions. The greater controversy occurs by a series of results that favours to the private banks in general, and the foreign ones in particular, and which is against the evidence that was known until now. Leonardo Bleger, an economist of the Credicoop Bank that published investigations on the SMEs financing in the magazine of the IDES and the Techint Bulletin, is not in agreement with almost any of the conclusions of the report of the institution that Roque Maccarone presides over. Bleger is not impressed with the sample size of the centralized database of debtors, and affirms that in the controversy about the SMEs financing each one takes water for its own mill depending the definition that is adopted for small company. “In the centralized database Center they consider like SMEs to companies up to 200 employees, that in many cases are big companies”, he explains. Gray zones and paradoxes The studies of Bleger, that contemplate a different definition of small company, shows that the participation of the SMEs in the credit is much smaller to the one than reveals

Page 48: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

47

the centralized system: it is below 20%. “If we consider that generates 80% of the employment, and that in addition they don’t have access to other instruments of financing like the larger companies, we realize that the SMEs are underrepresented in the banking credit”, he adds. Many of the results of the work of the BCRA revealed facts that were intuited, like that the irregularity and the unrecoverable of the loans portfolio to small companies are greater than the one of the loans to large companies; that between the private banks, those of smaller geographic scope tend to lend relatively more to small companies than the banks of national range; or that the credit to the SMEs tends to lower during a recession. But also, the authors of the report count, appeared a few paradoxes, peculiarities and grey zones. That is to say: - Perverse incentives: Whereas in the private banks the quality of the SMEs portfolio is deteriorated as the company becomes smaller, the case of the public organizations is exactly the opposite. ‘This is an unusual result, different from the international cases observed, where the loans of the bigger companies are safer, they say in the debtors Center, ‘and suggests the existence of perverse incentives in the process of lending between the public banks’. - Foreignization: The BCRA assures that his work refutes the idea that the foreignization of the bank has implicit a slant against SMEs. The temporary series observed on the study of the BCRA shows that the credit to the SMEs does not decrease as the national banks were being bought by foreign hands. ‘Also, it is a process that didn’t finish, and the tendency can change’, Escudé clarifies. The foreign banks granted a 42.7% of the credit to SMEs on the mid 2000, 4% more than two years before, according to the data of the BCRA. ‘It is a typical case in which a priori it is known to what conclusions were wanted to arrive, and soon the statistics comply to size’, Bleger counterattacks regarding the work of the BCRA. The economist, who investigated the financing of the small companies along with the former SMEs secretary Guillermo Rozenwurcel (they share a chair of Money, Credit and Banks in the University of Buenos Aires), thinks that the process of concentration and foreignization was in detrimental for the segment of SMEs: ‘it tends to diminish the proportion of loans in this sector, as a result of the disappearance of small banks, more specialized in the attention to the small companies’. Which is the true map of the credit for the small companies in Argentina? As it is seen, the limits and characteristics vary for each cartographer. Arrigoni thinks that the reality is in an intermediate earth between the conclusions of the BCRA and Bleger. ‘The foreignization was neutral, did not improve nor made worse the thing for the SMEs’, he maintains. For the man of Deloitte, regarding the greater difficulties of the SMEs financing it is necessary to look for it in the system failures that prevents that the supply and the demand are connected. And it mentions examples: ‘the BCRA requests to a SME as much information to him as to a great North American corporation; the banks have less agility, by the existing regulations, that a table of money to discount checks, etc, etc’. This history of love and hatred, according to Arrigoni, also has much of misunderstandings between both members of the pair. ‘There is an infinity of cultural prejudices: the small businessmen think that the banks don’t want to lend them, and that is false’, he says. Escudé agrees: ‘no bank can do without a universe that in Argentina involves a million companies, that is clear’. SEBASTIAN CAMPANARIO

Source: Translated from Campanario S. (2001): ‘¿Quién se Hace Cargo del Crédito PyME?’, Clarín - Suplemento Económico, Sunday July 22,2001. Available at www.clarin.com/suplementos/economico/2001/07/22/n-00211.htm

Page 49: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

48

Figure 1. CAPITAL MARKET SIZE AS PERCENTAGE OF GDP.

* US market capitalization and capital raised includes Amex, NASDAQ and NYSE. ** 1998 data (1999 GDP & GFCF Not Available)

Source: Author. Data from ‘Stock Markets Importance in the National Economy’, World Federation of Exchanges.

Figure 2. LOANS AND DEPOSTIS – ARGENTINA 1990/2000

Source: Author. Data from INDEC and BCRA

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

45%

I/1

990

III/1

99

0

I/1

991

III/1

99

1

I/1

992

III/1

99

2

I/1

993

III/1

99

3

I/1

994

III/1

99

4

I/1

995

III/1

99

5

I/1

996

III/1

99

6

I/1

997

III/1

99

7

I/1

998

III/1

99

8

I/1

999

III/1

99

9

I/2

000

III/2

00

0

Trimester

%/G

DP

Deposits Loans

198,3%

180,8% 177,7%

157,4%

137,6%

122,4%

108,5% 104,7%101,1%

75,2% 72,1%66,1%

54,3%

44,2%

34,5%

20,7% 19,7%

0,0%

50,0%

100,0%

150,0%

200,0%

Un

ited

Kin

gd

om

Un

ited

Sta

tes *

Mala

ysia

Gre

ece

So

uth

Afr

ica

Can

ad

a

Au

str

alia

Jap

an

Ch

ile

Ko

rea

Germ

an

y

Italy

Ph

ilip

pin

es

Th

ailan

d

Mexic

o

Bra

zil *

*

Arg

en

tin

a

% G

DP

Page 50: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

49

Table 1. ARGENTINEAN FINANCIAL SYSTEM – ENTITIES – 1980/2000

Type of entity 1980 1992 1994 1996 1998 sep-99 sep-00

Public Banks 35 36 33 21 18 15 14

National Private Banks 152 59 66 53 45 33 28

Foreign Private Banks 27 31 31 39 38 48 48

Cooperative Banks 41 38 6 4 2 2

Non-bank Entities 255 45 37 21 17

Total deposits 23.824 45.618 51.882 75.530 82.985 85.946

Total Private Banks 179 131 135 98 87 83 78

Total number of Banks 214 167 168 119 105 98 92

Total number of Entities 469 212 205 119 109

Source: Author. Data from BCRA and Aramburu (2000). Figure 3. PHASES OF THE BANKING CONCENTRATION

Source: Author. Adapted from Cuadernos de Cuenin (2000) and data from BCRA.

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

dec-1992 dec-1994 dec-1996 dec-1998 sep-99 sep-00

Date

Nu

mb

er

of E

ntities

dec-95

Savings

Outflow

IIII

Regulations

IIIIIIII

Tequila Crisis

Page 51: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

50

Table 2. LENDING TENDENCY TO SME SECTOR BY SIZE OF BANK. ARGENTINA. 1995/1999

Total Loans / Total Assets No Collateral / Total Assets Dec-97 Dec-98 Dec-99 Dec-97 Dec-98 Dec-99

1º Quartile (smallest banks) Mean 0.5325 0.476 0.463 0.722 0.764 0.736

Standard Deviation 0.1507 0.168 0.175 0.373 0.347 0.37

2º Quartile Mean 0.4813 0.485 0.441 0.629 0.611 0.611

Standard Deviation 0.1239 0.128 0.128 0.241 0.285 0.32

3º Quartile Mean 0.4809 0.486 0.486 0.602 0.58 0.553

Standard Deviation 0.1964 0.166 0.161 0.258 0.263 0.252

4º Quartile (largest banks) Mean 0.5275 0.504 0.478 0.523 0.463 0.448

Standard Deviation 0.1487 0.127 0.139 0.275 0.232 0.204

Source: Translated from Cuenin (2000). Note: The first quartile represents the 25% of the smallest banks considering the assets without taking into account the type of entity; the last quartile represents the 25% of largest banks. The higher the index the higher the tendency to lend. Table 3. MINIMUM CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS. PRIVATE BANKS. ARGENTINA 1994/1999 December 1995 December 1999

Risky Assets (ARG$ million)

Rate (%) Requirement (ARG$ million)

Risky Assets (ARG$ million)

Rate (%) Requirement (ARG$ million)

(1) Basel I 33.691 8.0 2.695 56.863 8.0 4.549

(2) National Regulation 40.823 11.5 4.695 63.195 11.5 7.267

(3) Effective Capital Integration

7.218 9.971

% Variation % Variation

% Variation % Variation % Variation

% Variation

(4) Nat. Reg./Basel I 21.0% 44.0% 74.0% 11.0% 44.0% 60%

(5) Excess over Basel I (3)/(1)

168.0% 119.0%

(6) Excess over Nat. Reg. 54.0% 37.0%

Source: Translated from Aramburu (2000).

Page 52: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

51

Figure 4. EVOLUTION OF LOANS AND DEPOSITS CONCENTRATION.

ARGENTINA 1995/2000.

Source: Translated from Cuenin (2000). Note: Loans: Loans issued by the 10 first private banks, Banco Nación and BAPRO (publics) over the total loans issued. Deposits: Deposits on the 10 first private banks, Banco Nación and BAPRO (publics) over the total deposits of the system. Table 4. TNEDENCY TO GENERATE HARD AND SOFT INFORMATION AS PER BANK SIZE. JAPAN.

Source: Ogura Y., Uchida H.: ‘Bank Consolidation and Soft Information Acquisition in Small Business Lending’, RIETI Discussion Paper Series 07-E-037, Table 3. Japan, May 2007. The index shows the tendency to ‘soft information’ generation, the higher the number the higher the tendency.

300

350

400

450

500

550

600

650

700

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999

Date

HH

I d

ep

osit

s

40%

45%

50%

55%

60%

65%

70%

75%

80%

Perc

en

tag

e/T

ota

l

HHI deposits Loans Deposits

Page 53: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

52

Figure 5. FINANCIAL EXPENSES / SIZE OF BANK RELATION.

ARGENTINA 1999.

Source: Translated from Cuenin (2000). Note: Internal Interest rate: Calculated as Financial Expenses/Total Deposits. Bank Size: Calculated as Total Assets of the entity (natural logarithm). Figure 6. BANKING CREDIT EVOLUTION BY SECTOR. ARGENTINA

1993/1998.

Ind

ex I

V-1

99

3 =

10

0

Period High Participation SMEs Sub-Total Companies

Source: Translated from Aramburu (2000).

0

0,02

0,04

0,06

0,08

0,1

0,12

0,14

0,16

8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17

Bank Size

Inte

rna

l In

tere

st

Ra

te

Page 54: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

53

Note: F.I.E.L. (1996) classification: For the analysis of the banking credit evolution the productive sectors were divided based on the contribution of the SMEs to the added value and the amount of work positions generated on each sector of the economy, according to the National Economic Census of 1994. According to this selection, the branches that these groups compose are the following ones: 1) High participation of

SMEs: on the manufacturing sector are represented by Metallic products, Clothes and footwear, Wood and cork, Furniture and accessories; on the primary sector are Fruits, Vegetables and legumes, Sugar cane, Cotton, Grapevine, and Poultry; on the Service sector is represented by Retail commerce. 2) Medium participation of SMEs: on manufacturing sector are represented by Printing works and editorials, Leathers and Derivative products from the leather, Products of rubber, Non-electrical machinery and Other manufactured products. 3) Low participation of SMEs: on the manufacturing sector are represented by Nutritional products, Drinks, Tobacco, Textile, Paper and Derived products of the paper, Chemical products, Derived products of petroleum and coal, Non-metallic minerals, Basic Industries of Metal, Electrical machinery and devices, and Transportation materials; and on the Service sector Electricity, Gas, Sanitary water and services, Financial Intermediation, Construction and Wholesale Commerce. Table 5. INTEREST RATES BY SIZE OF COMPANY. ARGENTINA -

AVERAGE 1994/2000

SIZE OF COMPANY (number of employees)

INTEREST RATE AVERAGE (%)

(1) 1 / 200 24,53

(2) 201 / 500 23,50

(3) 500 + 10,80

(1) – (3) Interest Rate Gap 13,73 *

* This gap is observed steady along the decade Source: F.I.E.L. (1996).

Note: The spread was calculated over the average rate applied to SMEs and large companies. In coincidence this is the spread observed along the period between the SMEs average and PRIME rates.

Page 55: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

54

Figure 7. EVOLUTION INTEREST RATE SPREAD. PRIME / OVERDRFAT CURRENT ACCOUNT. ARGENTINA 1993/2000.

Source: Author. Data from BCRA. Note: Variation on the spread between the interest rate applied to ‘Prime’ loans and overdraft current account. Prime rate: Is the interest rate that the banks apply to their better subjects of commercial credit and to his greater corporative clients. The banks use the PRIME rate as reference to establish the rates for credit cards, loans to mortgages houses and other types of loans, including loans for small and medium businesses. Figure 8. MAIN DIFFICULTIES MANIFESTED BY SMEs COMPANIES. ARGENTINA 1999.

Source: Translated from FUNDES-UNGS (1999).

-10,00

-6,00

-2,00

2,00

6,00

10,00

14,00

ab

r-93

ag

o-9

3

dic

-93

ab

r-94

ag

o-9

4

dic

-94

ab

r-95

ag

o-9

5

dic

-95

ab

r-96

ag

o-9

6

dic

-96

ab

r-97

ag

o-9

7

dic

-97

ab

r-98

ag

o-9

8

dic

-98

ab

r-99

ag

o-9

9

dic

-99

ab

r-00

ag

o-0

0

dic

-00

Nominal % (ARG$)

Variation

Average Spread

17,98

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90

Great companies do not favor modernization of SMEs

Inadecuate enterprise organizations

Uneffective export promotion

Inadequate consulting and formation services

Corruption and overcosts in transactions

Low use of public support instruments

Bureaucratic proceedings of foreign trade

Concentration of the supply and/or the demand

Inadequate commercial platforms of the banks

Lack of regulation of imports goods

Insecure legislation

Costs of services of infrastructure

Access to the financing

Percentage Hierarchy Agreement

Page 56: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

55

Figure 9. SMEs MAIN DIFFICULTIES MANIFESTED BY THE INSTITUTIONS. ARGENTINA 1999.

Source: Translated from Yoguel (1999). Figure 10. UTILIZATION OF ‘LENDING SCORING SYSTEM’ BY TYPE OF PORTFOLIO. ARGENTINA 2006.

Source: Translated from Pailhé C. (2006).

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100

Access to financing sources

Tax structure

Operation of the markets

Institutional/State support

Access to technology and

technical attendance

Labor market

Belonging sector

Legal and regulatory

Union and entrepreneurial

associations support

Formation offer

Percentage

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Scoring 'personal segment' Scoring 'SMEs segment' Scoring 'companies'

Co

mp

an

ies

in p

erc

en

tag

e

Not in use

Currently in use

Page 57: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

56

Table 6. UTILIZATION OF SCORING SYSTEMS BY SIZE OF BANK. LATINAMERICA 2004. ON PERCENTAGES.

TYPE OF MODEL

TOTAL BANKS BANK SIZE

LARGE MEDIUM SMALL

Credit scoring ex-ante

4 n/a n/a n/a

Credit scoring 15 31 12 14

Case by case 70 44 74 71

Other answers 9 6 9 5

No response 2 n/a n/a n/a

Source: Translated from FELABAN (2005). Figure 11. INTEREST RATES: SMEs (overdraft) VS LARGE COMPANIES (prime). ARGENTINA 1994/2000.

Source: Author. Data from BCRA. Note: Monthly average nominal interest rate in annual terms for the period Jan.94/Dec.00.

-

10,00

20,00

30,00

40,00

50,00

60,00

en

e-9

4

jun

-94

no

v-9

4

ab

r-9

5

se

p-9

5

feb

-96

jul-

96

dic

-96

ma

y-9

7

oc

t-9

7

ma

r-9

8

ag

o-9

8

en

e-9

9

jun

-99

no

v-9

9

ab

r-0

0

se

p-0

0

Date

Inte

res

t R

ate

(%

)

'Prime' Interest Rate Overdraft Current Account

Page 58: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

57

Table 7. FINANCIAL SYSTEM DEVELOPMENT. LOANS TO GDP. APRIL 2007.

COUNTRY LOANS / GDP*

Chile 75%

Greece 67%

Uruguay 50%

Brazil 33%

India 31%

Colombia 23%

Mexico 18%

Argentine 10,5%

* Loans to non-financial private sector.

Source: BCRA and IMF Figure 12. SME EMPLOYEMENT BY GROUP OF COUNTRIES.

Source: Author. Adapted from F.I.E.L. (1994)

50%

64%

72%76%

80%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

U.S. Germany, Belgium,

Canada, U.K.,

France

Total Average Japan,

Switzerland, Chile

Denmark, Italia,

Portugal, Spain,

Greece, Perú,

Argentine, Brazil

Group of Countries (Average)

%

Page 59: BANKING CONCENTRATION, INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND …

58

GLOSARY

BCRA – Banco Central de la República Argentina (Central Bank of the Argentine Republic) CNV – Comisión Nacional de Valores (Similar to the NYSE) FFS – Formal Financial Sector IDB – Inter-American Development Bank IFS – Informal Financial Sector ILO – International Labour Organization IMF – International Monetary Fund MGC - Mutual Guarantee Company RGC - Reciprocal Guarantee Companies SBA – Small Business Administration SBCS - Small Business Credit Scoring SEDESA – Seguro de Depósitos Sociedad Anónima SME – Small and Medium Enterprise