when the political process works wellarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdftrade...

18
132 c H A P T E R 6 The Economics of Collective Decision Making Just as the general does not want his Camp Swampy bud- get cut, most heads of agen- cies want expanded budgets to help them do more and do it more comfortably. Incentives Confronted by the Government Bureaucrat other people, bureaucrats who staff government agencies have na wly focused intere 4 They usually want to see their own agency's goals furthere any bureaucrats believe str ly in what they are trying to do. Furthering these ls, however, usually requires larger gets. In tum, larger budgets lead to more pre ge and career opportuni- ties for the bureauc . Economic analysis suggests ther a strong tendency for gov- ernment bureaucrats a ployees to want to expan eir budgets to sizes well beyond, what is economically efficie Legislative bodies are in cha f overse · g these bureaus, but the individual legis- lators themselves are generally not ve these agencies. This makes it even mo beyond what's economically effie· The political process, w · - begins with voter-dr lections and proceeds to leg- islative decisions and bu ucratic actions, brings about re and displease other e goals of the three major categories rtlctpants-voters, politicians, and b aucrats-frequently conflict with one another. Eac up wants more of the gove ent's limited supply of resources. Coalitions form and the me ers of each coalitio ope to enhance their ability to get the government to do what they w orne- is results in productive activities on the part of the government, and sometim WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELL Under what conditions are voting and representative government most likely to result in productive actions? People have a tendency to believe that support by a majority makes a political action productive. However, if a government project is truly productive, it will al- ways be possible to find a way to allocate the cost so that all voters gain. This would mean that, even if voting rules required unanimity or near-unanimity, all truly productive gov- ernment projects would pass if the costs were allocated in the right manner. Exhibit 4 helps illustrate this point. Column 1 presents hypothetical data on the distribution of bene- fits from a government road construction project. These benefits sum to $40, which exceeds the $25 cost of the road, so the project is productive. But if the project's $25 cost were allocated equally among the voters (plan A), Adams and Chan gain substantially, but Green, Lee, a1,1d Diaz lose. If the fate of the project is decided by majority vote, the project will be defeated by the "no" votes of Green, Lee, and Diaz. The reason why this produc- tive government project fails to obtain a majority vote, however, is because of the way that the costs have been allocated. Because the project is indeed productive, there is an alternative way to allocate its costs so that Adams, Chan, Green, Lee, and Diaz all benefit. This can be accomplished by I THINK WE CAN GET BY ON A COUPLE OF MILLION LE5S THAN LAST YEAR LT. FUZZ, YOU HAVEN'T BEEN IN GOVERNMENT SERVICE VERY LONG, - HAVE YOU? BEETLE BAILEY BY MORT WALKER. REPRINTED BY SPECIAL PERMIS SION OF KING FEATURES SYNDICATE. 4 The economic analysis of bureaucracy was pioneered by William Niskanen. Reprints of some of his classic articles along with recent updated material can be found in William A. Niskanen, Jr., Bureaucracy and Public Economics (Aidershot, U.K: Edward Elgar Publishing, 1994 ), l

Upload: others

Post on 12-Jul-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

132 c H A P T E R 6 The Economics of Collective Decision Making

Just as the general does not want his Camp Swampy bud­get cut, most heads of agen­cies want expanded budgets to help them do more and do it more comfortably.

Incentives Confronted by the Government Bureaucrat

other people, bureaucrats who staff government agencies have na wly focused intere 4 They usually want to see their own agency's goals furthere any bureaucrats believe str ly in what they are trying to do. Furthering these ls, however, usually requires larger gets. In tum, larger budgets lead to more pre ge and career opportuni­ties for the bureauc . Economic analysis suggests ther a strong tendency for gov-ernment bureaucrats a ployees to want to expan eir budgets to sizes well beyond, • what is economically efficie

Legislative bodies are in cha f overse · g these bureaus, but the individual legis-lators themselves are generally not ve these agencies. This makes it even mo beyond what's economically effie·

The political process, w · - begins with voter-dr lections and proceeds to leg-islative decisions and bu ucratic actions, brings about re and displease other e goals of the three major categories rtlctpants-voters, politicians, and b aucrats-frequently conflict with one another. Eac up wants more of the gove ent's limited supply of resources. Coalitions form and the me ers of each coalitio ope to enhance their ability to get the government to do what they w orne-

is results in productive activities on the part of the government, and sometim

WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELL

Under what conditions are voting and representative government most likely to result in productive actions? People have a tendency to believe that support by a majority makes a political action productive. However, if a government project is truly productive, it will al­ways be possible to find a way to allocate the cost so that all voters gain. This would mean that, even if voting rules required unanimity or near-unanimity, all truly productive gov­ernment projects would pass if the costs were allocated in the right manner. Exhibit 4 helps illustrate this point. Column 1 presents hypothetical data on the distribution of bene­fits from a government road construction project. These benefits sum to $40, which exceeds the $25 cost of the road, so the project is productive. But if the project's $25 cost were allocated equally among the voters (plan A), Adams and Chan gain substantially, but Green, Lee, a1,1d Diaz lose. If the fate of the project is decided by majority vote, the project will be defeated by the "no" votes of Green, Lee, and Diaz. The reason why this produc­tive government project fails to obtain a majority vote, however, is because of the way that the costs have been allocated.

Because the project is indeed productive, there is an alternative way to allocate its costs so that Adams, Chan, Green, Lee, and Diaz all benefit. This can be accomplished by

I THINK WE CAN GET BY ON A COUPLE OF MILLION LE5S

THAN LAST YEAR

LT. FUZZ, YOU HAVEN'T BEEN IN GOVERNMENT SERVICE VERY LONG, -

HAVE YOU?

BEETLE BAILEY BY MORT WALKER. REPRINTED BY SPECIAL PERMISSION OF KING FEATURES SYNDICATE.

4The economic analysis of bureaucracy was pioneered by William Niskanen. Reprints of some of his classic articles along with recent updated material can be found in William A. Niskanen, Jr., Bureaucracy and Public Economics (Aidershot, U.K: Edward Elgar Publishing, 1994 ),

l

Page 2: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

r When the Political Process Works Well 1.33

TAX PAYMENT

BENEFITS

RECEIVED PLANA PLANB

VOTER (1) ( (2) (3)

Adams $20 $5 $12.50 Chan 12 5 7.50 Green 4 5 2.50 Lee 2 5 1.25 Diaz 2 5 1.25 Total $40 $25 $25.00

When taxes are levied in proportion to benefits received (tax plan B), any efficient project can pass unanimously (and any inefficient project will fail unanimously). When taxes are not levied in accordance with benefits received (tax plan A), efficient projects can fail to win a majority vote (or inefficient projects can pass in a majority vote).

allocating the cost of the project among voters in proportion to the benefits that they re­ceive (plan B). Under this arrangement, Adams would pay half ($12.50) of the $25 cost, since he receives half ($20) of the total benefits ($40). The other voters would all pay in proportion to the benefits they receive. Under this plan, all voters would gain from the pro­posal. Even though the proposal could not secure a majority when the costs were allocated equally among voters, it will be favored by all five voters when they are taxed in propor­tion to the benefits they receive (plan B).

This simple illustration highlights an extremely important point about voting and the efficiency of government action. When voters pay in proportion to benefits received, all voters will gain if the government action is productive, and all will lose if it is unproductive. 5 When the benefits and costs derived by individual voters are closely re­lated, the voting process will enact efficient projects while rejecting inefficient ones. When voters pay in proportion to the benefits they receive, there will tend to be harmony between good politics and sound economics.

How might the cost of a government service be linked to the benefits received? User charges, which require people who use a service more to pay a larger share of the cost, provide one way. User charges are most likely to be levied at the local level. Local services such:as electricity, water and g_arb~e collection are generally financed with user charg~s. ~ometunes the intensity of the use of a service and the amount paid for it can be linked by specifying that the revenue from a specific tax be used for a designated purpose. For exam­ple, most states finance road construction and maintenance with the revenue collected from taxes on gasoline and other motor fuels. The more an individual drives, the more he or she benefits from the roads-and the more he or she pays. . ~bit 5 provides a useful way to look at the possible linkage between the benefits and costs of government programs. The benefits from a government action may be either wide­spread ~mong the general public or concentrated among a small subgroup (for example, farmers, students, business interests, senior citizens, or members of a labor union). Similarly, the costs may be either widespread or highly concentrated among voters. Thus, as the ex­hibit shows, there are four possible patterns of voter benefits and costs: (1) widespread bene­fits and widespread costs, (2) concentrated benefits and widespread costs, (3) concentrated benefits and concentrated costs, and (4) widespread benefits and concentrated costs.

When both the benefits and costs are widespread among voters (type 1 issue), essen­tially everyone benefits and everyone pays. Although the costs of type 1 measures may not be precisely proportional to the benefits individuals receive, there will be a rough

"The principle that productive projects generate the potential for political unanimity was initially articulated by Swedish econo­mist Knut Wicksell in 1896. See Wicksell, "A New Principle of Just Taxation," in Public Choice and Constitutional Economics, James Gwartney and Richard Wagner (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press, Inc., 1988). Nobel laureate James Buchanan has stated that Wicksell's work provided him with the insights that led to his large role in the development of modern public-choice theory.

l!ser charges Payments that users (con· sumers) are required to make if they want to receive certain services provided by the government.

,' I, . r ·' j' .I,. I·; :·

:!,,

I. 'i . I ~/, I, !.

· ;

Page 3: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

1.34 cHAPTER 6 The Economics of Collective Decision Making

EXHIBIT 5 Distribution of Benefits and Costs among Voters

(f)

(D

~ Ol c 0 E ttl (f)

u; 0 0

0 c 0

~

Widespread

,g Concentrated u; i:5

Distribution of benefits among voters

Widespread Concentrated

It is useful to visualize four possible combinations for the distribution of benefits and costs among voters to consider·how the alternative distributions affect the operation of representative governments. When the distribution of benefits and costs is both widespread among voters (1) or both concentrated among voters (3), representative government will tend to under­take projects that are productive and reject those that are unproductive. In contrast, when the benefits are concentrated and the costs are widespread (2), representative government is biased toward the adoption of inefficient projects. Finally, when benefits are widespread but the costs concentrated (4), the political process may reject projects that are productive.

•.

relationship. When type 1 measures are productive, almost everyone gains more than they pay. There will be little opposition, and political representatives have a strong incentive to support such proposals. In contrast, when type 1 proposals generate costs in excess of ben­efits, almost everyone loses, and representatives will face pressure to oppose such issues. Thus, for type 1 projects, the political process works pretty well. Productive projects will tend to be accepted and unproductive ones rejected.

Similarly, there is reason to believe that the political process will work fairly well for type 3 measures-those for which both benefits and costs are concentrated on one or more small subgroups. In some cases, the concentrated beneficiaries may be the same group of people paying for the government to provide them a service. In other cases, the subgroup of beneficiaries may differ from the subgroup footing the bill. Even in this case, however, when the benefits exceed the costs, the concentrated group of beneficia­ries will have an in.centive to expend more resources lobbying for the measure than those harmed by it will expend opposing it. Thus, when the benefits and costs are both concentrated, there will be a tendency for productive projects to be adopted and unpro­ductive ones to be rejectecl.

WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS POORLY

Although the political process yields reasonable results when there is a close relationship between the receipt of benefits and the payment of costs (type 1 and type 3 projects), the harmony between good politics and sound economics bre~s down when there is not (type 2 and type 4 projects). Inefficiency may also arise from other sources when governments undertake economic activities. In this section, we consider four major reasons why the po­litical allocation of resources will often result in inefficiency.

Page 4: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

Special-Interest Effect ,--

When the Political Process Works Poorly 135

Trade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports stadiums, the arts, and various agricultural products; federal spending on an indoor rain forest in Coralville, Iowa; a tattoo-removal program in San Luis Obispo County, Cali­fornia; the Rock and Roll Hall of Fame in Cleveland, Ohio; a golf awareness program in St. Augustine, Florida; and therapeutic horseback riding in Apple Valley, California. These seemingly diverse programs funded by the federal government have one thing in common: They reflect the attractiveness of special interests to vote-seeking politicians. A special­interest issue is one that generates substantial personal benefits for a small number of constituents while spreading the costs widely across the bulk of citizens (type 2 projects). Individually, a few people gain a great deal, but many others lose a small amount. In ag­gregate, the losses may exceed the benefits.

Special-Interest issue An issue that generates sub­stantial individual benefits to a small minority while imposing a small individual cost on many other citizens. In total, the net cost to the majority might either exceed or fall short of the net benefits to the special-interest group.

How will a vote-seeking politician respond to special-interest issues? Since their per­sonal stake is large, members of the interest group (and lobbyists representing their inter­ests) will feel strongly about such issues. Many of the special-interest voters will vote for or ~ainst candidates strictly on the basis of whether they are supportive of their positions. In addition, interest groups are generally an attractive source of campaign resources-in­cluding financial contributions. In contrast, most other rationally ignorant voters will

---

APPLICATIONS IN ECONOMICS til{! --~-

.:~

';weet Subsidies to Sugar Growers: A Case Study of the Special-Interest Effect

For many years, the price of sugar in the United States has beer:~ twc; or three times as high qS the world price. For ex­ample, in February 2004, the domestic price of sugar was 20 cents per pound while the world price was less than 6 cents a pound. Why? Because the U.S. government se­verely restricts the quantity of sugar imported. This keeps the domestic price of sugar high. As a result, the roughly 60,000 sugar growers in the United ?tates gain about $1.9 billion. That's more than $30,000 per grower! Most of these benefits are reaped by large growers with incomes far above tne national average. On the other hand, these suosidies cost the average American household aoout $20 in the form of higher prices for products containing sugar. Ellen mor~ important, the resources of l\mericans are wa$ted producing a good we are ill-s~ited to produce and one that could be obtained at a substantially lower cost through trade. As a result, Americans are worse off.

Why · does Cong~ess support this program year after year? Given the sizable impactthe restricUons have on the personal wealth of sugar growers, it is perfectly sensible for them, particularly the large ones, to use their wealth and

,r-t>Ofitical Clout to iolelp politicians Wt)0 support their inter­sts. fhis is precisely what they nave done. During the

2000 election cycle, tt'ie sugar loboy contributed al.most '

$13 million to candidates and political action committees. In contrast, it makes no sense for the average voter to in­vestigate this issue or ,give it any significant weight when deciding for whom to vote. lh fact, most voters are unaware that this program is costing them money. Here, as in sev­eral other areas, politicians have a strong incentive to sup­port policies favored by special interests, solicit those par­ties for political contributions, and use the funds to attract the support of other voters, most of whom know nothing about the sugar progran1. Even though the sugar program is counterproduCtive, it is still a political winner.

The sugar growers are not the only ones benefiting· from government programs that are economically [nefficient. Taxpayers and consumers spend approximately $20 billion annually to support grain, cotton, tobacco, peanut, wool, and dairy programs, all of which have structural character­istics similar to those of the _sugar program. The political power of special interests also explain9 tlile presenc~ of tar­iffs and quotas O!l steel, textiles, lumber, and many other products. Federally funded irrigation J!)rojects, sublsidized agricultural grazing rights, subsidized.business loans, nu­merous pork-barrel spending projects (t~e list goes on and on) are all polides· rooted in the· spe.cial-interest effect rather than economic efficiency and net ber:~efit~ to ;Ameri; cans. Although each such ~rogram ir:Jdivitlwally imposes only a small drag on the economy, together they exert a sizeable negative ir11Ract oh our income levels and living standards.

Page 5: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

136 c H A P T E R 6 The Economics of Collective Decision Making

Logrolling The exchange between politi­cians of political support on one issue for political support on another.

Pork-barrel legislation A package of spending proj­ects benefiting local areas financed through the federal government. The costs of the projects typically exceed the benefits in total, but the proj­ects are intensely desired by the residents of a particular district, who get the benefits without having to pay much of the costs.

EXHIBIT 6 Trading Votes · and Passing Counterproductive Legislation

All three projects are ineffi­cient, and would not pass majority vote individually. However, representa-tives from districts A, B, and C could trade votes (logrolling) or put together pork-barrel legislation that . would result in all three projects passing.

either not know or will care little about special-interest issues. Even if voters know about some of these programs, it will be difficult for them to punish their legislators because each politician represents a bundle of positions on many different issues. While there is little to be gained from the support of the disorganized majority, organized interest groups provide politicians with vocal supporters, campaign workers, and, most important, finan­cial contributions.

As a result, politicians have a strong incentive to support legislation giving concen­trated benefits to special-interest groups at the expense of disorganized groups (like the bulk of taxpayers and consumers). Even if supporting such legislation is counterproduc­tive, politicians will often still be able to gain by supporting programs favored by special interests. For a real-world illustration of how the special-interest effect works, see Appli­cations in Economics, "Sweet Subsidies to Sugar Growers: A Case Study of the Special­Interest Effect."

The power of special interests is further strengthened by logrolling and pork-barrel legislation. Logrolling involves the practice of trading votes by a politician to get the nec­essary support to pass desired legislation. Pork-barrel legislation is the term used to de­scribe the bundling of unrelated projects benefiting many interests into a single bill. Both logrolling and pork-barrellegislation will often make it possible for special-interest proj­ects to gain legislative approval, even though these projects themselves are counter­productive and individually would be unable to muster the needed votes.

Exhibit 6 provides a numeric illustration of the forces underlying logrolling and pork­barrellegislation. Here we consider the operation of a five-member legislature considering three projects: construction of a post office in district A, dredging of a harbor in district B, and spending on a military base in district C., For each district, the net benefit or cost is shown-that is, the benefit to the district minus the tax cost imposed on it. The total cost of each of the three projects exceeds the benefits (as shown by the negative number in the total row at the bottom of the table), and therefore each is counterproductive. If the projects were voted on separately, each y.rould lose by a 4-to-1 vote because only one district would gain, and the other four would lose. However, when the projects are bundled together through ei­ther logrolling (representatives A, B, and C could agree to trade votes) or pork-barrellegisla­tion (all three programs put on the same bill), they can all pass, despite the fact that all are inefficient. 6 This can be seen by noting that the total combined net benefit is positive for representatives A, B, and C. Given the weak incentive for voters to acquire information,

NET BENEFITS ( +) OR COSTS (-) TO VOTERS IN DISTRICT

CONSTRUCTION OF DREDGING CONSTRUCTION OF

VOTERS OF POST OFFICE HARBOR MILITARY BASE

DISTRICT a INA INB INC TOTAL

A +$10 ,$ 3 -$ 3 +$4 B -$ 3 +$10 -$ 3 +$4 c -$ 3 -$ 3 +$10 +$4 D -$ 3 -$ 3 -$ 3 -$9 E -$ 3 -$ 3 - $ 3 -$9 Total -$ 2 -$ 2 -$ 2 -$6

8 We assume the districts are of equal size.

6Logrolling and pork-barrel policies can sometimes lead to the adoption o( productive measures. However, if a project is produc­tive, there would always be a pattern of finance that would lead to its adoption even if logrolling and pork-barrel policies were absent. Thus, the tendency for logrolling and pork-barrel policies to result in the adoption of inefficient projects is the more significant point.

Page 6: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

When the Political Process Works Poorly 137

those harmed by pork-barrel and other special-interest policies are unlikely to even be aware of thein. Thus, the incentive to support projects like these is even stronger than is implied by the simple numeric example in Exhibit 6.

Why don't representatives oppose measures that force their constituents to pay for projects that benefit others? There is some incentive to do so, but the constituents of any one elected representative can capture only a small portion of the benefits of tax savings from improved efficiency, since the savings would be spread nationwide among all tax­payers. We would not, for example, expect the president of a corporation to devote any of the firm's resources to projects not primarily benefiting its stockholders. Neither should we expect an elected representative to devote political resources to projects like defeating pork-barrel programs when the benefits of spending reductions and tax savings will be de­rived mostly by constituents in other districts. Instead, each representative has a strong incentive to work for programs that concentrate benefits among his or her own con­stituents-especially organized interest groups that can help the representative be re­elected. Heeding such incentives is a s~rvival (reelection) tactic.

On the other hand, when the benefits of a governmental action are widespread and the costs are highly concentrated (type 4 of Exhibit 5), special-interest groups-those who stand to bear the cost-will strongly oppose and lobby against it. Most other voters will be largely uninformed and uninterested. Once again, politicians will have an incentive to respond to the views of the concentrated interests. A proposal to reduce or eliminate a tar­iff (tax) on an imported good would be an example of this type of legislation. Although many thousands of consumers would benefit from the lower prices that result, the domes­tic firms that compete with the imported good would devote substantial resources toward lobbying to keep the tariff in place. Projects of this type will tend to be rejected even when they are productive, that is, when they would generate larger benefits than costs.

The bottom line is clear: Public-choice analysis indicates that majority voting and representative democracy work poorly when concentrated interests benefit at the expense of the general public. In the case of special-interest issues, there is a conflict between good politics-getting elected-and the efficient use of resources. The special­interest effect helps explain the presence of numerous government programs that increase the size of government and reduce the overall size of the economic pie. As we discuss di­verse topics throughout this text, counterproductive political action that has its foundation in the special-interest effect will arise again and again.

Shortsightedness Effect

Because voters have a weak incentive to acquire information, current economic conditions will have a major impact on their choices at election time. Complex issues, like reforming Social Security or restructuring health care programs that involve future benefits and costs, will be difficult for voters to assess. Thus, incumbent politicians will want to make sure economic conditions look good on election day. To accomplish this, they will favor policies that provide current benefits voters can easily identify at the expense of future costs that are complicated and difficult to identify. Similarly, they will tend to oppose leg­islation that involves immediate and easily identifiable costs (and higher taxes) but yield future benefits that are complex and difficult to identify. Economists refer to this bias in­herent in the political process as the shortsightedness effect.

As a result of the shortsightedness effect, politicians will tend to favor programs that generate highly visible current benefits, even when the true cost of these programs outweighs the benefits. In contrast, their incentive is weak to support efficient programs that generate future benefits but involve current costs.

The shortsightedness effect sheds light on why legislators find debt financing so at­tractive. Debt financing makes it possible for officeholders to provide visible benefits to their constituents without having to levy an equivalent amount of taxes. During the last forty-five years, the federal budget has been in deficit forty times; there have been only five surpluses (1969 and 1998-2001). The bias toward budget deficits is a predictable re­sult; it reflects the shortsighted nature of the political process. Similarly, the shortsighted-

Shortsightedness effect The misallocation of resources that results because public­sector action is biased (1) in favor of proposals yielding clearly defined current benefits in exchange for dif fi­cult-to-identify future costs and (2) against proposals with clearly identifiable current costs that yield less concrete and less obvious future benefits.·

Page 7: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

1.38 c H A P T E R 6 The Economics of Collective Decision Making

When buying and selling

are controlled by legisla­

tion, the first things

bought and sold are

legislators.

-P. J. O'Rourke7

Rent seeking Actions by individuals and groups designed to restruc­ture public policy in a manner that will either directly or indi­rectly redistribute more in­come to ~hem selves or the projects they promote.

'r

Guo~ ~t91e. ~

P/o-..Ji~~ ~-rouJVJ ; tJ WIT ~'C.vff. fcN...: ...

(k..._ 7<>L+•c.J2 Ec..:.AJ4-Y ''­

':&-u.s. Avrlc..JI.hr-e_7

by 8. De.! w "'--!-(, G-o.. v-0 ,.J -e./'--'

ness effect indicates that vote-seeking politicians will find it attractive to promise future benefits without levying a sufficient amount of taxes to finance them. This has been the case with both the Social Security and Medicare programs. The unfunded liabilities of these two programs are nearly three times the size of the official outstanding federal debt. By the time the higher taxes (or benefit cuts) for these programs are confronted, the politi­cians who gained votes from the promised benefits will be long gone.

It is worth taking a moment to consider the differences between the public and private sectors in terms of how future benefits and costs are considered in current decisions. As we explained in Chapter 2, private-property rights provide a means by which the value of future benefits can be immediately captured (or costs borne) by a property owner. Owners who do not invest now to properly maintain their homes or cars, .for example, will bear the consequences of the reduced value of those assets. Correspondingly, the value of a firm's stock will immediately rise (or fall), depending on the shareholders' perception of the ex­pected future benefits and costs of an action taken by the company's executives today. In contrast, the public sector tends to place more weight on current benefits and costs and less weight on the future. In areas where the primary benefits are in the future, and prop­erty rights can be well defined and enforced, there is good reason to believe that the pri­vate sector will do a better job than the government sector.

Rent Seeking

There are two ways individuals can acquire wealth: production and plunder. When indi­viduals produce goods or services and exchange them for income, they not only enrich themselves but they also enhance the ~ealth of the society. Sometimes the rules-or lack of rule enforcement- also allow people to get ahead by taking, or plundering, what others have produced. This method not only fails to generate additional income-the gain of one is a loss to another-but it also consumes resources and thereby reduces the wealth of the society.

Rent seeking is the term economists use when they refer to actions taken by individ­uals and groups seeking to use the political process to take the wealth of others.8 Perhaps "favor seeking" would be a more descriptive term for this type of activity, which generally involves "investing" resources in lobbying and other activities designed to gain favors from the government. The incentive for individuals to spend time and effort in rent seeking will be determined by how rewarding it is. Rent seeking will be unattractive when constitutional constraints prevent politicians from taking the property of some and trans­ferring it to others (or forcing some to pay for things desired by others).

When a government fails to allocate the costs of public-sector projects to the primary beneficiaries (through user fees, for example), or when it becomes heavily involved in transfer activities, people will spend more time organizing and lobbying politicians and less time producing goods and services. Resources that would otherwise be used to create wealth and generate income are wasted as people fight over slices of the economic pie-a pie that is smaller than it could be if they were engaged in productive activities instead. When the government grants favors to some people at the expense of others (instead of simply acting as a neutral force protecting property rights and enforcing contracts), counterproductive activities will expand while productive activities will shrink. As are­sult, the overall income level will fall short of its potential.

There is ample evidence that rent -seeking consumes a substantial amount of resources. Washington, D.C., is full of organizations seeking subsidies and other favors from the fed­eral government. More than 3,000 trade associations have offices in Washington, and they employ nearly 100,000 people seeking to alter the actions of Congress. Of course, business and labor organizations are well represented, but so, too, are agricultural interests, health care providers, trial lawyers, senior citizens, export industries, and many others,

1

iN.(\.._.J.,d \) N:~'S.~\e~.

7Quoted in P. J. O'Rourke, Insight Magazine, Jan. 15-25: 35. 8See the classic work of Charles K. Rowley, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, The Political Economy of Rent-Seeking (Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1988), for additional details on rent seeking.

Page 8: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

When the Political Process Works Poorly 139

As we noted earlier, income transfers have grown substantially during the last several ~ decades. The government now taxes appro~imately one out of every seven dollars citizens

am, and transfers it to someone else. Rent seeking is the political "fuel" for most of these transfer activities. Interestingly, means-tested transfers, those directed toward the poor, constitute only about one-sixth of all transfers. No income test is applied to the other five­sixths of income transfers. These transfers are generally directed toward groups that are either well organized (like businesses and labor union interests) or easily identifiable (like the elderly and farmers). The people receiving these transfers often have incomes well above the ~verage person.

Within the framework of public-choice analysis, the relatively small portion of in­come transfers directed toward the poor is not surprising. There is little reason to believe that transfers to the poor will be particularly attractive to vote-seeking politicians. After all, in the United States, the poor are less likely to vote than middle- and upper-income re­cipients. They are also less likely to be well informed on political issues and candidates. They are not an attractive source of political contributions. Politicians often argue that their proposed policies will help the poor, but there is little reason to believe that this will be a high priority for most of them.

There are three major reasons why government transfer activity will reduce the size of the economic pie. First, income redistribution weakens the link between productive activity and reward. When taxes take a larger share of a person's income, the reward from hard work and productive activity is reduced. Second, as public policy redistrib­utes a larger share of income, more resources will flow into wasteful rent-seeking activ­ities. Resources used for lobbying and other rent-seeking activities will not be available to increase the size of the economic pie. Third, higher taxes to finance income redistrib­ution and an expansion in rent-seeking will induce taxpayers to focus less on income­producing activities, and more on actions to protect their income. More accountants, lawyers, and tax-shelter experts will be retained as people seek to limit the amount of

.--- ··eir income redistributed to others. Like the resources allocated to rent seeking, re­~ources allocated to protecting one's wealth from the reach of government will also be unavailable for productive activity. Predictably, the incentives created by government redistribution policies will exert a negative impact on the level of economic activity.

Page 9: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

~

"VX. E. 13t;vd,-wc1 Ce..~\\').JJ f',-\c. -0 oJ. Pve,\..J~+­

Sl.....<.-f "-Y 1( 'E>,,.,.J,cr Fl<nsV f.-i <-e.

~ py-uJ..Jd SuvfOl\J s

B,"Nd.lt-ra-c.~;L),vcr- 7r,'ct<_ (MA~JDAT£b)

p() I D t {

\ 2 l

\. y /

'5 1--tc~\J-6._ Y-

B,Y..J&,~ Flo<TU ?v-\·ce_ (MA-NDATE: D)

s

Page 10: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

VI. C. Policy Intervention for Rent Seeking Gain (Measuring Surplus Changes Due to Market Intervention and Price Distortion)

C.l.The Analytical/Conceptual Framework

To analyze/determine the efficiency and equity effects of intervention in the market we will generally proceed as follows: We will consider the consumers' surplus, CS, the producers' surplus, PS, and taxpayer impact (outlay/cost), TO, of a no intervention policy (free market) versus that associated with various policy interventions that might be contemplated. That is, we will determine and compare and contrast the CS, PS, and TO under each option. We will define the net social benefit (NSB) of each option as

NSB = CS + PS- TO (if any)

The NSB will be our measure of the efficiency effect or "size of economic pie" associated with each option. By comparing the NSB among the various options, we will be able to say something about the economic efficiency implication of each option. By comparing the respective CS, PS, and TO of each option we can say something about who benefits and who bears the costs of each policy option, i.e., we can say something about the expected distributive or equity effects and also be able to predict which group or groups will be favoring the policy and which groups might be opposed.

C.2. The Geometry for Four Stylized Farm Policy Examples

We'll consider the CS, PS, TO, and NSB implications of four stylized examples-A: Free market (no intervention); B: Price support (binding price floor) without supply control and with government obligation to buy surplus commodity; C: Price support with perfect supply management/control (i.e., marketing quota); and D: Target price with deficiency payment

Consider an agricultural product market, say wheat, as graphed at right:

For Option A: Free Market

CS=p*BE

PS=Ap*E

TO=O

NSB = CS+ PS- TO=ABE

p

Thinking ahead and an important hint for problem sets and exams: You should know from what we've learned so far that in the absence of"market failure" (market power, externalities, or public goods) the NSB (welfare triangle) of the no intervention (free market) option should be larger than for any market intervention option.

Page 11: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

r

2

For Option B: This case presumes a guaranteed price to producers higher than p*, say l. Consumers are required to pay l and accordingly demand/ consume only / . However, in this scenario private market consumers of wheat are not the only "demanders" of wheat-the government is a buyer as well. Producers being rationale profit-maximizers opt to produce y' given p = p0

. This results in a commodity surplus of y' -/, which the government (taxpayers) are obligated to buy (for now let's suppose they just burn the surplus in order to get rid of it).

PS = Ap"F

p j)

A

Under this scenario consumers clearly lose p • p" CE of CS compared to free market. Producers

capture p • p°CH of the lost CS and, in addition, are the beneficiaries of GCF of PS at the

expense of the taxpayers. Producers are clearly better off in total by p • p ° FE . Taxpayers clearly

lose big by y°CFy1•

So, what about NSB:

NSB = CS + PS- TO = p 0BC + Ap°F - / CFy'

Again, since GFC is an income (profit) transfer from taxpayers to producers, then on balance

NSB = ABCG -/GFy'

where /GFy' might be called "net taxpayer loss," i.e., the part of taxpayer outlay that is, in effect, lost-not captured by either producers or consumers of wheat.

Under this bizarre scenario (burn/destroy the commodity surplus), NSB could conceivably be negative if the "net taxpayer loss," /GFy', is greater than ABCG, which it appears to be in our example. Discussion question: What might the government do to ameliorate this troublesome situation? Problem: What to do with the surplus grain other than burn it?

Page 12: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

r

3

For Option C: This option presumes a subsidized price (binding price floor) as in Option B and adds a supply control feature, viz., marketing quotas are rationed out to individual producers such that aggregate supply is set at l in order to eliminate the commodity surplus. That is, the amount that producers are allowed to supply is limited to l rather than /. This case assumes that the supply control mechanism is "perfect" in that the supply is limited to exactly the amount that consumers would be willing and able to purchase at the p 0 price. In effect, the "with supply control" supply curve becomes the kinked line AGC in the graph above, S with quota at/.

CS=p0BC

PS=Ap°CG

TO=O

NSB=ABCG

A

~I

In this case, consumers of wheat are clear losers by p * p° CE (same as for Option B). And,

producers are clear winners, so long as p * p°CH > GHE . Finally, notice that NSB (the size of

the economic pie) shrinks by GCE-the dead weight loss owing to the quota, which restricts

production (and consumption) to y 0 rather than y*.

Marketing quotas have and continue to be used as an agricultural policy tool in the United States. An advantage of marketing quotas compared to other market intervention options, despite the associated dead weight loss, is that there is no taxpayer outlay as in the case of Option B and, as we will see momentarily, as there is with Option D.

Conclusions: Key-- >- means is preferred;- means indifferent. Comparing Options A, B, and C:

• In terms of NSB: Opt. A >- Opt. C >- Opt. B

• In terms of CS: Opt. A >- Opt. B ~ Opt. C

• In terms of PS: Opt. B >- Opt. C >- Opt. A

• In terms of TO: Opt. A ~ Opt. C >- Opt. B

Not surprisingly, society as a whole is better off under the "free market" policy; producers of y would prefer a price subsidy without supply control, followed by price subsidy with supply control, and free market least; consumers of y prefer free market over either price subsidy option; and taxpayers would prefer either the free market or perfect supply control options.

Page 13: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

4

For Option D: Target Price with Deficiency Payment- the most common US farm (commodity) policy mechanism. Involves:

I. Government sets target price, p 0, before farmers make planting decision.

2. Farmers decide how much grain to produce, presumably at y 0 where p 0 intersect the supply

function at point F.

3. After harvest (the supply is now fixed at y 0 ) , farmers sell grain on the private market. Given

y 0, the market clears (demanders/consumers are willing able to pay) a price of p'

4. Consumers pay p' per bushel and the government (taxpayers) write checks (deficiency

payments) to farmers amounting in total to (p 0 - p' )y0

. In terms of geometry, the area

p'p° FG, which is the TO.

NSB = CS+ PS- TO

= p'BG + Ap° F- p'p° FG

Producers are happy because, compared to free market, their

PS has increased by p • p° FE.

Consumers are happy because, compared to free market, their

CS has increased by p'p • EG .

Taxpayers are unhappy becaue, compared to free market, their

cost has gone from 0 to p'p ° FG .

The increase in PS and in CS is a transfer of income (economic pie) from the taxpayers to producers and to consumers-a wash as far as the size of pie (NSB) is concerned.* The net reduction in NSB is the area EFG, which is the "deadweight loss" as a result of the program (the market intervention).

B

fo#-----~~---?.----p* p""---

A

*Note: The combined producer and consumer net gain in surplus is

Thank you taxpayers!

Can we rank all four options in terms of preferences of producers, consumers, taxpayers, and economists? Let's have a whack at it:

D

Page 14: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

C.3. Policies that Result in Demand and Supply Shifts.

C.3 .a. Demand shifts (due to distortions in prices of related goods; due to augmentation of consumer income; through demand enhancement programs; due to demand expansion via favorable international trade policy). Let's look at a demand enhancement example.

For Option A (before demand shift)

CS = p*BE

PS = Ap*E

TO=O

NSB=ABE

For Option B (after demand enhancement)

p 5

B

cs = p'B'E' A

PS = Ap'E'

TO=?

NSB = AB'E' - ?

Conclusions: Producers clearly like demand enhancement programs because PS unambiguously rises. For consumers the matter is unclear- greater quantity is consumed, but at a higher price. The CS situation is ambiguous. Although in the figure above it appears that the new CS triangle is larger than the old CS triangle, it depends on the relative own-price elasticities of the old and new demand curves and of supply and the nature of the demand shift (we will see why later). Also how much weight that policy makers might give to the new CS depends on whether the "new demand" is due to greater domestic consumption or new international customers, in which case the "accounting stance" matters. (Policy makers in "our society" may not care or think the CS accruing to foreign customers should carry much weight.) For taxpayers the matter depends on how costly the demand enhancement program might be and whether it will be privately or publicly financed, i.e., who pays for it.

Finally, in terms of economic efficiency, it is clear that ~AB'E' > ~ABE. So, in terms of the big picture, i.e., for whatever society is represented in Dnew, the size of the economic pie is increased, assuming the demand enhancement effort is costless. If not costless and/or if the increased CS befalls individuals in some larger society that "we don't care about" then all of the CS part of the efficiency gains may not matter to the policy makers.

Page 15: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

~

6

CJ.b. Supply shifts (due to distortions in factor prices; due to public or private investment in research and technology development)

c 5 == Py,BE

p s = A P*E

To::=.. 0

N 5 e:,-=- C:.s + f~ -To

::::. f><; BE +-A ~E:. - G

::::. ABE.

I I c.s == p 51S

I I ps = A P E

To-== ? N 55-::::. C:St-~S -TO

B

p* p'

A

P/5 E/ +-A P'E"- 7

- ABE.1

- '?

~f L-;r..cAT .X:oAJS

{j) c.. o,-05UW\~3 UJ0~10loously WrAJ l pI' 5 E / > p~ 5 E b 'I p I p~ E E

s N Eu.J

@ FIJ"'..) P~~..Q.A_S ~ o0\-~ '1 ~ uNL\e_Gl.A...). G~+ ~

r~~l$-e._ ~ s~\\ f.AA~ d- ) b-$ a_-\- G-.> .1 ow~ r"'" \c_.Q_ "'

Tf;. p~'p"* E C.- > A C... E / . 5

f~..t._y lo~ e... o ( 1-J Lv+-: 'T.:. s~e.. ..u&k_

-1-k-t A f>_,C.. ~~ ~-M..ClV'- +-o foo-\-k. ~''b-e.~''~ ''~.l.RA .. / 1 P S Slic.es .. Ac.r::' is t-J-e...u PSJ bs\- f 1P*r-Ec. b /c.~+-\\c\cqPS.)

(ID rt ·~ 1-.1~ .+e.s ... ~N~\.OCJY Co5-\-~ I e...s~ +k<V'A.) A t::: E. 1

( .f.l.Q.. t ft0 N5B)_,

~ s:ze.. ~ p:e.. Is ll'JC.~~& (:Ltv~ is ~~l~&y

eq:cc,-e..d-)

Page 16: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

7

CA. Who Captures the Rents? [Note: "Rents" is an economist secret code word. In the present context it has to do with who gets (captures) the benefits (economic surplus) owing to a policy change of public investment project.]

C.4.a. Relative price elasticities and who wins and who loses

• First, a key point to remember: When we talk about comparing and contrasting results under differing elasticity assumptions, we mean different relative elasticity at a particular price/quantity point. For our purposes, let's suppose the point of interest is a market equilibrium point. Also, it is important to remember that conclusions we draw, like virtually all economic conclusions, assume ceteris paribus (all other things unchanged).

• Second, supply and demand elasticities matter in virtually all policy analysis applications. For our purposes, let's consider (I) the implications of more inelastic demand and more elastic supply for CS and PS and (2) the implications for the "free-market" and "price­support with perfect supply control" scenarios discussed earlier. And, we' ll limit our consideration to the implication of different own-price elasticity of supply and demand.

Page 17: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

  8  

C.4.b.   Implication  of  parallel  vs.  rotational  supply  shift  for  producer  surplus      

Page 18: WHEN THE POLITICAL PROCESS WORKS WELLarec.arizona.edu/arec304/lecnotessection6rev.pdfTrade restrictions that limit the import of steel and lumber from abroad; subsidies for sports

  9  

VI.D.   Surplus  Calculations  “On  the  Back  of  an  Envelope”  (How  to  do  it  when  all  we  know  is  “before”  price/quantity  levels  and  an  educated  guess  about  the  S  &  D  elasticities)    —finding  slope  from  the  own-­‐price  elasticity  formula  when  we  know  p*  and  y*                                          —finding  the  equation  of  a  linear  supply  or  demand  equation  knowing  slope  and  a  point