university of new south wales school of economics · university of new south wales school of...

67
University of New South Wales School of Economics Honours Thesis Should the United Kingdom leave the European Union? An analysis under different tariff arrangements Author: Luka Raznatovic Student ID: 3418433 Supervisor: Dr. Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho A.Prof Valentyn Panchenko Bachelor of Economics (Honours) 3 rd November, 2015

Upload: hoanghanh

Post on 05-Jun-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

University of New South Wales

School of Economics

Honours Thesis

Should the United Kingdom leave the European Union?

An analysis under different tariff arrangements

Author:

Luka Raznatovic

Student ID: 3418433

Supervisor:

Dr. Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

A.Prof Valentyn Panchenko

Bachelor of Economics (Honours)

3rd November, 2015

Declaration

I hereby declare that this thesis is my own original work, and to the best of my

knowledge, does not contain material or content by other authors except where I

have rightly acknowledged otherwise. This Honours Thesis has not been submitted

for the award of any other degree or diploma at the University of New South Wales,

or at any other educational institution.

Luka Raznatovic

November 2nd 2015

i

Acknowledgements

I would firstly like to thank my dedicated supervisor, Dr. Stanley Cho. His patience,

interest and knowledge in all related to the production of my Honours Thesis has

provided me with the strongest basis to complete this work. I want to specifically

thank him for the time he took out of his day for our meetings, in which he would

assist and guide me with my Thesis. His hard work did not go unnoticed and

has been immensely appreciated. A special thanks goes out to A. Prof Valentyn

Panchenko for his helpful comments and suggestions in the writing of this thesis.

I would also like to thank Dr. Tess Stafford, Dr. Evgenia Dechter, Dr. Scott

French, A. Prof Glenn Otto and Dr. Gabriele Gratton whose critiques and advice

of my presentation provided me with a fresh outlook on the direction of my thesis.

This helped in the expansion and development of the content of my thesis.

With this, I would like to thank the School of Economics for granting me the Honours

Scholarship. This financial help has been greatly appreciated over the course of this

Honours year. To the Economics Honours cohort of 2015, thank you for a great year.

Finally, I would like to thank my family. Their support throughout the year has

been nothing less than astounding and understanding.

ii

Contents

Declaration i

Acknowledgements ii

Table of Contents ii

Abstract viii

1 Introduction 1

2 Background 5

2.1 Possible Exit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5

2.2 The UK-EU Trade Relationship . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5

3 Literature Review 8

3.1 Alternative Trade Scenarios . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8

3.2 Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10

3.3 United Kingdom Study . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

4 Model 14

4.1 Overview . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14

4.2 Domestic production firms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14

4.3 Final production goods firms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

4.4 Consumption goods firms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

4.5 Investment good firm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

4.6 Households . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

4.7 The Domestic Government . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

4.8 The Foreign Trade Partners . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

4.9 Definition of equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

5 Data and Calibration 22

5.1 Sectoral Disaggregation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

5.2 Social Accounting Matrix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24

iii

5.3 Other Parameters . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

5.3.1 Trade Partners’ Income . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

5.3.2 Determination of the Tariff Rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26

5.3.3 Elasticities of Substitution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

5.3.4 Simulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31

6 Results 32

6.1 Overview . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

6.2 Trade War . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

6.3 Free Trade Agreement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39

6.4 Import Elasticities of Substitution Differentiated by Sector . . . . . . 44

6.5 Tariff Revenue Rebate under Trade War . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46

6.6 Optimal Tariff Argument . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47

7 Conclusion 48

A Calibrated Parameters 50

B A2 52

C A3 53

D Bibliography 55

iv

List of Tables

2.1 EU’s Simple average MFN applied . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

5.1 Sectoral Disaggregation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

5.2 Tariff rates in Benchmark Case . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

5.3 Tariff rates in Trade War Scenario . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28

5.4 Tariff rates in FTA Scenario . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

5.5 Import Elasticities of Substitution (pm,j) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31

6.1 Effect of trade war on consumption good prices . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

6.2 Effect of trade war on domestic production . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37

6.3 Effect of trade war on Factor Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37

6.4 Effect of trade war on Welfare . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38

6.5 Effect of trade war on consumption good prices . . . . . . . . . . . . 39

6.6 Effect of a FTA on domestic production . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42

6.7 Effect of a FTA on Factor Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43

6.8 Effect of a FTA on Welfare . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43

6.9 Effect on Consumption Good prices (σm,i 6= σm,j) . . . . . . . . . . . 44

6.10 Effect on Factor prices (σm,i 6= σm,j) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45

6.11 Effect on Welfare (σm,i 6= σm,j) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45

6.12 Effect of trade war with Rebate on consumption good prices . . . . . 46

6.13 Effect of a Trade War with Rebate on Factor Prices . . . . . . . . . . 46

6.14 Effect of Trade War with Rebate on Welfare . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46

6.15 Effect of Trade War with Rebate on Welfare . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47

A.1 Preference parameters θ - aggregate consumer and government . . . . 50

A.2 Domestic goods firm parameters (α, β) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50

A.3 Armington Aggregators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51

C.1 Effect of Trade War on Exports (σm,i 6= σm,j) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53

C.2 Effect of an FTA on Exports (σm,i 6= σm,j) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53

C.3 Effect of Trade War on Imports (σm,i 6= σm,j) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53

C.4 Effect of an FTA on Imports (σm,i 6= σm,j) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54

v

C.5 Effect on Domestic Production (σm,i 6= σm,j) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54

vi

List of Figures

2.1 Export shares of the UK . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

2.2 Import shares of the UK . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

6.1 Effect of trade war on exports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

6.2 Effect of trade war on imports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

6.3 Effect of a FTA on exports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40

6.4 Effect of a FTA on imports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41

B.1 Social Accounting Matrix for the UK, 2011 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52

vii

Abstract

In recent years, the probability that the United Kingdom (UK) might withdraw their

membership from the European Union (EU) has gained momentum. Contingent on

the exit scenario, there will be certain implications on the tariff schedules that the

UK face and impose to the EU and the Rest of the World (RoW). It is precisely

under these tariff adjustments that this thesis will analyse the potential impact on

key economic variables in the UK economy. To conduct the analysis, the model of

choice is the Static Applied General Equilibrium model. Based on the UK’s supply

and use tables, I construct the Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) in order to calibrate

the model. The focus is on two exit scenarios: (1) the pessimistic case, the UK

engages in trade war with the EU, and (2) the optimistic case, the UK are successful

in signing a free trade agreement with the EU. Counterfactual simulations of the

UK withdrawal from the EU are then run by altering the tariff levels associated with

each exit scenario. Furthermore, additional numerical experiments are performed:

sensitivity analysis on the import elasticities differentiated by sector, an alternative

fiscal arrangement under trade war, and the validity of Johnson’s Optimal Tariff

(1954) argument for the UK economy. The results from the trade war scenario

indicate a social welfare loss of around 0.066%, while on the other hand, under a

FTA scenario, a social welfare gain of 0.065% is recorded. In conclusion, only under

a FTA scenario is there evidence that the UK should leave the EU.

viii

Chapter 1

Introduction

By the end of 2017, the United Kingdom (UK) is set to hold a referendum in

regards to their membership with the European Union (EU). Without focusing on

the political arguments, much debate has been centred on the possible implications

on UK’s trade if such a drastic policy transformation were to eventuate. As of 2014,

the EU still proved to be a particularly important trade partner in goods and services

with the UK. It accounted for 45% and 53% of UK’s trade of exports and imports,

respectively.1 However, over the last decade, the EU’s dominance in trade with the

UK is diminishing. This largely reflects the prominent rise of emerging economies in

global trade and the EU’s stagnation in growth after the Global Financial Crisis of

2007-08 (Hanson 2012). With this evident gradual shift towards the RoW in trade,

this prompts the question ‘Is EU membership important anymore?’

The core argument advocated by the UK’s Eurosceptics lies with the belief that

EU membership constrains their trade expansion with non-EU members (Springford

et al. 2014). This conviction stems from the fact that the EU follows a Customs

Union trade model, wherein trade between EU members is tariff-free. However, EU

members such as the UK, have limited influence in conducting their own external

trade policy. As a result, this prevents the UK in tapping the growing markets

outside Europe by signing FTAs whilst being required to impose the EU common

external tariff (CET) to third countries.

In this paper, I investigate two possible exit scenarios: (1) the pessimistic case,

the UK engages in trade war with the EU, and (2) the optimistic case, the UK

successfully signs a FTA with the EU and thereby acquires the ability to sign FTAs

with members of the RoW. One aspect of FTAs is the aim of eliminating tariff levels.

It is generally considered by economists that tariffs are distortionary. Therefore,

by implementing free trade, the efficient reallocation of resources leads to (in an

aggregate sense), a reduction in prices and an increase in domestic production in

that economy (Cho and Diaz 2011). Accordingly in this paper, I adjust the tariff

rates corresponding to each exit scenario and then analyse the potential impact on

key economic variables in the UK economy. It should be noted that other channels

1ONS UK trade data

1

that bring about benefits and costs of withdrawing from the EU are not explored.

The thought of the UK withdrawing from the EU has motivated many economists to

attempt to find the qualitative and quantitative effects of this on the UK economy.

Such examples include Hindley and Howe (2001), Pain and Young (2004), Milne

(2004) and Mansfield (2014). The results are quite mixed and are largely dependent

on the assumptions they assert. Most papers are discussion based and therefore

employ rather primitive methods in attempting to find an answer. On the other

hand, Ottaviano, Pessoa and Sampson (2014) employ a formal model and analyse

the impact of tariff changes on the welfare of the UK if they were to engage in a

trade war scenario with the EU. In the current literature, there is no study to the

best of my knowledge that investigates the potential economic and welfare impact

if the second scenario (FTA) were to occur for the UK. Thus, this will be one of

my contributions to the literature. Furthermore, different to Ottaviano, Pessoa and

Sampson (2014), I will also explicitly observe and analyse the economic agents who

gain and lose under both scenarios.

Whilst Cho and Diaz (2008) have already analysed the different welfare impacts of

Slovenia joining the EU customs union or signing a FTA, my study despite showing

similarities contains many differing aspects. In their paper, Slovenia began from

a position outside the EU. On the contrary, in this paper, the UK is already an

established member of the EU. Consequently, the determination of the tariff rates

(a key parameter) under a FTA scenario are quite different for both studies.

The model that is employed to conduct the analysis, is the Static Applied General

Equilibrium (AGE) model in the tradition of the work by Shoven and Whalley

(1984). The main motivation behind the use of this model is that many economists

have employed such a model for evaluating the impact of changes in trade policy, such

as trade liberalisation. As a point of emphasis, 11 out of the 12 studies presented

at a U.S International Trade conference in 1992 used the AGE model to analyse

the potential impact of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) on

the relevant participating economies (Kehoe and Kehoe 1994b). The underlying

popularity of the model is that they highlight the resulting reallocation of resources

across sectors, thereby enabling the model user to observe and analyse the potential

winners and losers from a change in trade policy (Kehoe and Kehoe 1994a; Sobarzo

1992).

Due to the unavailability of the Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) for the UK, I

construct one myself mainly based on the UK’s supply and use tables. The SAM

2

together with several other data sources, provides the necessary data to calibrate

the parameters of the model to match the UK economy. From here, I conduct two

comparative statics experiments: the benchmark simulations. The first experiment

is the simulation under a trade war scenario, where both the UK and the EU raise

tariffs on each other’s imports. The magnitude of the tariff barriers imposed is based

on the current EU’s CET. The UK tariff rates to the RoW are assumed to remain

the same. The second case is the FTA arrangement, where the UK and EU trade

remains tariff free but the UK now has the power to sign FTAs with members of

the RoW. This new ability effectively reduces the tariff rates the UK impose to the

RoW as a whole. The determination of the FTAs that the UK manage to ratify with

the RoW after EU withdrawal is based on the success of the FTAs that Switzerland

have been able to attain. Under both simulations, once the tariff shock occurs, the

effects on prices, sectoral production, foreign trade and welfare are observed and

analysed.

Most UK sectors are both export and import intensive and as a result, the expected

outcome following either exit scenario is not always clear at times. For the trade war

scenario, the results show that for most sectors, there is moderate increase in the

price of consumption goods. The textiles, footwear and clothing sector experiences

the largest gain in price, rising by 0.59%. This reflects the fact that this becomes

the most protected sector under the trade war scenario, with an effective tariff rate

of 9.22%. Since tariffs rise, imports subsequently become less price competitive in

the foreign market and as a result, we observe a fall in bilateral trade with both the

EU and the RoW by 17% and 2.5%, respectively. In terms of welfare, consumers

experience a welfare loss of 0.47% while on the other hand, the government records

a gain of 1.22%. This gain arises due to the newfound tariff revenue from the EU

imports. Overall, social welfare falls by 0.066%, highlighting the negative impact if

the UK were to participate in such a situation.

Under an FTA scenario, the change in the price of consumer goods are quite small for

most sectors. The explanation is based on the distinction between a final good and

a consumption good in the model. Nevertheless, the textiles, footwear and clothing

sector, which experiences the largest reduction in tariffs with the ROW, records the

largest decline in price by 0.75%. An interesting result from this scenario is that

although bilateral trade grows with both the EU and the RoW, many disaggregated

sectors suffer from trade diversion. This is especially evident from the import side as

UK consumers switch to the more efficient producers in the RoW. As the disposable

incomes of consumers rise, so too does their welfare, which shows a gain of 0.10%.

This time, the government welfare falls by 0.065% as they lose tariff revenue from

3

the RoW imports. Still, the social welfare increases by 0.065%, meaning that the

UK can gain from this trade arrangement with the EU.

In the benchmark simulations, the elasticity of substitution of imports were set to be

the same across the sectors. Thus, I perform a sensitivity analysis where the values

of the import elasticities are differentiated by sector. Following the methodology

employed in Rolleigh (2013), I obtain the data from Martins, Scarpetta, and Pilat

(1996), and then I calculate the import elasticities for the UK. With a higher average

import elasticity, the results from both scenarios in general follow the same pattern

as in the benchmark simulations, but with greater magnitude. Notably, the social

welfare impact becomes insignificant under both scenarios.

Furthermore, two additional scenario-specific experiments are performed. First,

we notice that under a trade war, the government tariff revenue increases by 267%.

Therefore, we conduct a numerical experiment where the government hands over

this additional tariff revenue by lowering the direct aggregate tax rate imposed

on consumers’ income. The results show that the loss in consumers’ and social

welfare is lower when compared to the trade war benchmark simulation. Therefore,

this demonstrates that different fiscal arrangements can be beneficial under a

change in trade policy. The final experiment involves testing the validity of the

Johnson’s Optimal Tariff hypothesis (1954) for the UK under the FTA scenario.

This hypothesis states that optimal tariff should become zero as the parameter

governing the export elasticity approaches one. From the results, we find that the

hypothesis holds for the UK; the social welfare improves as the export elasticity

approaches one.

4

Chapter 2

Background

2.1 Possible Exit

The victory of the Conservative Party at the UK general election of May 2015

reignited the question of the UK’s membership with the EU. It is planned that

by the end of 2017, the United Kingdom (UK) will hold an “In-Out” referendum.

At the time of writing this thesis, the European Union Referendum Bill 2015-16

passed the second reading in the House of Lords at the UK parliament. According

to the YouGov Survey results (the largest UK poll surveyed in 2015 with 11,171

participants), they reported that 40% wish to leave while 38% want to remain in

the EU. Thus, this slight advantage demonstrates that UK withdrawal from the

EU is a real possibility in the near future. The contemporary debate the UK’s

membership with the EU is based on a range of issues such as trade, investment,

EU regulation, EU fiscal contribution and immigration (Springford et al. 2014). In

this paper, the focus will be on trade.

2.2 The UK-EU Trade Relationship

The UK relationship with the EU has always been a bit turbulent. In 1973, the

UK finally entered the European Economic Community (a precursor to the EU).

It was only 2 years later that the UK had a referendum about its membership,

where 67% voted in favour of staying. From there the level of trade integration

between the UK and the EU increased. To truly comprehend this relationship,

it is vital to understand the purpose and characteristics of the EU. Aside from

political motivations inherent in the EU, the EU also aims to bring about economic

integration among its 28 members. Through the EU Single Market, there is free

movement of goods, services, labour and capital. From a trade perspective, the

EU follows a customs union model, which has important implications for the UK.

Trade between custom union members is tariff free. However, in terms of external

trade, members must follow the EU Common External Tariffs (CET). Table X below

shows the average tariff rates EU members apply to nations to which the EU has

no preferential agreement.

5

Sector EU(%)Agriculture 12.2Non-Agriculture 4.2Total 5.3

Source: WTO trade policy review

Table 2.1: EU’s Simple average MFN applied

These tariffs can manipulate the trade pattern of the UK. By placing higher tariffs

towards the RoW, this enables many non-efficient EU producers to gain a larger

market share in imports to the UK. This is especially prevalent in the agriculture

sector where the Common Agricultural Policy is implemented. In fact, prior to 1973,

the UK had stronger trade ties with the RoW than the EU.

Figure 2.1: Export shares of the UK

Figure 2.1 shows the share of UK exports in goods going to the EU and the RoW

from 1996 to 2014. From this graph it is clear the EU dominated this aspect of

trade for most of the years. However we notice the rise of the share of UK exports

going to the RoW. After 2011, the RoW surpasses the EU in terms of the share of

UK exports. There are a number of explanations for this fall in EU dominance. As

documented in Hanson (2012), the global financial crisis (GFC) of 2007-08 brought

into focus the changing nature of global trade. The EU’s stagnation and the rise of

emerging economies such as China has lead to this recent change in trade patterns.

This has been the general trend after the GFC, however, with some highly developed

6

nations, trade with the UK has increased dramatically. For instance, Switzerland,

a European non-EU nation, was a major factor in the sharp rise in the RoW share

of exports from 2013 to 2014.

Figure 2.2: Import shares of the UK

Figure 2.1 shows the share of UK imports in goods from the EU and the RoW

from 1996 to 2014. While the share of imports has been fairly close from the EU

and the RoW, we notice that after the GFC, the RoW share rises. Again, this is in

line with the global trend in trade. Unlike the export side, the EU share of imports

manages to surpass the RoW’s share in 2012. This can be mainly attributed to the

recent growth in imports arriving from Germany and the Netherlands. From both

graphs, we can observe the gradual shift in bilateral trade towards the RoW. This

fall in EU dominance has called into question the EU’s important as a trade market

for the future. As part of a EU Customs Union, the UK cannot sign FTAs with

members of the RoW. Instead, they must wait for the EU to sign such agreements.

As a result, Eurosceptics believe that the EU constrains their trade with the growing

markets around the world.

7

Chapter 3

Literature Review

3.1 Alternative Trade Scenarios

There are a number of different possible trade arrangements the UK can partake

in with the EU at the time of its withdrawal. Based on Springford, Tilford and

Whyte (2014), these scenarios include: membership of the European Economic Area

(EEA), a series of bilateral agreements, membership of the customs union, a free

trade agreement (FTA), or trade under WTO rules (Trade War). In this paper,

I investigate the cases of the UK participating in a Trade War and an FTA with

the EU. These scenarios are regarded, respectively, as the pessimistic and optimistic

case. This will in turn provide valuable information in answering the question,

‘should the UK withdraw from the EU?’ Below, I discuss all five trade arrangements

in further detail with particular emphasis on trade impacts due to the focus of this

paper. Furthermore, in the discussion I also offer reasons as to why trade war is

considered the pessimistic case, and why the FTA is the optimistic and most likely

case to ensue after UK withdrawal from the EU.

UK membership of the EEA (made up of EU members, Norway, Iceland and

Liechtenstein) is a trade option that would require the UK to adopt several EU

policies in order to enable them to have unimpeded access to the EU Single Market

(a notable EU policy exception includes the common agricultural policy). As a

result, UK agricultural exports to the EU would face tariffs. The EEA is not part

of the EU customs union and as a result the UK would be able to conduct their

own external trade policy. However, there are a number of issues with this trade

option. In order to have access to the EU Single Market, the UK would still need to

abide by the EU law and regulations. Yet, the UK will have no formal access to the

EU decision making bodies. As a result, with no input in the EU regulation, they

would suffer from the problem of ‘regulation without representation’ (Springford

et al. 2014, p. 30), an issue, which alone seems quite intolerable for the UK to

accept from a political perspective. Another issue is that the EU rules of origin

would apply to the UK. The rules of origin, as defined by the WTO, encompass

the criteria needed to determine the national source of a product. If a particular

component of the product is produced from a third country (one with no EU trade

agreement) then the EU tariff rates are applied to that component. They can be

8

quite complex and as revealed in Cadot (1992), they can impose substantial costs

to the UK exporters.

Another arrangement proposition would see the UK enter into a series of bilateral

agreements with the EU, similar to the current EU-Switzerland trade relationship.

Based on the particular agreements, this would determine the level of access into the

EU Single Market. Switzerland for example, have free trade in goods with the EU

but have no such agreement in terms of services. This is an important aspect to take

into account for the UK, given the importance of the UK financial sector. Similar to

the EEA scenario, the UK would still have to comply with the EU regulation with

no input. Unlike the EEA, the UK would essentially be able to pick and choose

between the agreements which best suit their interests. The UK would be able

to conduct their own external policy, however, the EU rule of origins would still

apply. A major issue in this trade relationship is that the EU might not permit

such a proposal. This EU-Swiss trade relationship was intended to be a temporary

measure, as it was hoped that the Swiss would one day enter the EU (Fernekess et

al. 2014). The second major reason is that this type of trade relationship needs

constant renegotiation and as a result the EU has become increasingly frustrated

(Springford et al. 2014). Therefore, this option might not even be possible for the

UK.

The third trade option is for the UK to join the EU Customs Union. It needs

to be emphasised that being a member of the EU and a member of the EU Customs

Union are vastly different in definition and entitlements. If a country is an EU

member, they are automatically part of the EU Customs Union however the reverse

is not true. Nations part of the latter category include Turkey, Andorra and San

Marino. Under this arrangement, the UK would have access to the EU Single Market

but would still have to apply the CET to imports from countries with no EU trade

agreements. The disadvantages from the first two options would still hold. Another

disadvantage is that the UK would have to allow free access to goods from countries

with which the EU has an FTA, despite that same country not having to reciprocate

by allowing free access to goods from the UK. This is the one-sided benefit. If the

UK join the EU Customs Union it would seem that this will defeat the purpose of

them leaving in the first place. This instance is also argued by Springford, Tilford

and Whyte (2014) and Fernekess, Paleviciene and Thadikkaran (2014), and thus

seems highly unlikely to occur.

The optimistic trade option involves the UK signing an FTA with the EU on its

withdrawal. An FTA would enable trade with the EU to remain tariff-free. Unlike

9

a Customs Union member, the UK would be free to set its own trade polices to

the RoW without applying the EU CET rates. Even though the EU origin of rules

would apply, the UK would not be required to implement EU laws (Fernekess et

al. 2014, p. 42). One such example is the South Korean-EU FTA. This model of

trade essentially provides lesser integration with the EU, unlike the other models,

whilst it enables the UK to still enjoy free trade. There are number of reasons as to

why this is considered to be the most likely scenario to eventuate. Firstly, the other

models do not exactly solve the issue of the UK leaving the EU in the first place.

Secondly, this option may seem the least desirable to the EU as they allow for the

UK to essentially reap the benefits of EU trade with less integration. However, as

noted in Fernekess (2014, p. 42), the UK is an important import destination for the

EU exports. This, together with the fact that the UK is currently running a trade

deficit with the EU provides evidence that such an agreement would be in their

self-interest to accept in the long term (Mansfield 2014; Hindley and Howe 2001)

Furthermore, as demonstrated, this is considered by Eurosceptics to be the most

preferred case (The Economist 2015).

Finally, the last option suggests that the UK leave the EU without any trade

agreement in place. Consequently, as stipulated by the WTO rules, the UK and

the EU must apply the Most Favoured Nation (MFN) tariff rates on each other’s

imports. Since both nations are raising tariffs on one another, this scenario is labelled

as Trade War. Regardless of their complete freedom in determining their internal

and external policies, the possibility that the UK exporters might face the EU CET

is the reason this case is considered the pessimistic case. It may seem unlikely that

both parties would want such a relationship but as argued by Ottaviano, Pessoa and

Sampson (2014) this is a possibility in the short term and as stated in Mansfield

(2014), there only needs to be one EU member to block the UK from signing an

FTA.

3.2 Methodology

A common model used to study trade policy is the AGE model, as it quantifies the

impact of different trade arrangements. Given the focus of this paper, the model of

choice for my analysis is the static applied general equilibrium (AGE) model. The

general equilibrium model’s theoretical foundation is based on Arrow and Debreu’s

(1954) model that formalised and proved the existence of the Walrasian general

equilibrium structure. In order to evaluate policy, this abstract representation of the

economy needed to be converted through the use of specifying parameters into actual

10

economies that reflected real world data (Shoven and Whalley 1992). The numerical

application started with Leif Johansen (1960), who developed the first empirically

based, price-endogenous model with multiple sectors (Shoven and Whalley 1984).

This model was calibrated to the Norwegian data from 1950, and was employed to

analyse the resource allocation and thereby identify the sources of economic growth

in Norway during the period of 1948-53. Another prominent early work in the

numerical application field was Arnold Harberger (1962). Harberger focused on tax

policy by producing a two sector model calibrated to the US data from the 1950s

(Kehoe and Prescott 1995).

An important development in the field of AGE modelling occurred when Scarf (1967,

1973) successfully formulated a computational algorithm to find the fixed points that

satisfied the conditions of Brouwer’s fixed-point theorem. This essentially enabled

the numerical calculation of economic equilibria. This work was quite influential as

it inspired a whole generation of Yale graduate students to work with AGE models

(Kehoe 1996). Two prominent Yale graduates were Shoven and Whalley, who were

one of the first to employ the computational general equilibrium (see Shoven and

Whalley (1972)). With the advancement in computers, this has made the use of

such a model more widely available at a lesser cost.

An AGE model consists of various artificial economic agents where in the com-

puter simulations, they conduct the same transactions as that observed by their

counterparts in the real world. In this paper, the economic agents will be composed

of consumers, producers, a government and foreigners. The model itself is quite

flexible, enabling many extensions. One such extension is the specification based on

the Armington (1969) assumption. By employing such a specification, this accounts

for the large amount of cross hauling evident in the trade data. If there ceased

to be an Armington assumption (therefore goods are homogenous) then this could

potentially cause extreme results where countries would completely specialise in a

product (Kehoe 1994a). This model can either be calibrated following the likes of

Kehoe (1996) or can resemble the statistical methods employed by Jorgenson (1984)

or Mansur and Whalley (1984). In this paper, I follow the calibration method

due to the unavailability of data for the UK. Once the calibration is completed,

the comparative statics methodology is conducted where the simulation is run by

changing the policy parameter (in this case, the tariff rates) and analysing the post

shock equilibrium. The variables in focus are the prices, sectoral production, trade

and national welfare which are then analysed to determine the move the UK should

appropriate in regards to leaving the EU.

11

The main motivation behind the use of this model is that they highlight the resulting

reallocation of resources across sectors, thereby enabling the model user to observe

and analyse the potential winners and losers from a change in trade policy (Kehoe

and Kehoe 1994a; Sobarzo 1992). Many studies have employed the AGE model to

analyse different forms of trade policy. At the U.S International Trade conference in

1992, 11 out of the 12 studies presented used the AGE model to analyse the potential

impact of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) on the relevant

participating economies (Kehoe and Kehoe 1994b). Other examples include the

evaluation of the Tokyo Round Trade Agreement (Whalley 1982), Morocco signing

an FTA with the EU (Rutherford, Rutstrom, and Tarr 1993) and Australia signing

an FTA with India (Cho and Yoon 2013). Most studies have focused on trade

liberalisation through FTAs. Though I also explore an FTA with the EU in the

second scenario, given that it requires leaving the Customs Union, my situation is

quite different to the above literature.

One study that does explore the issue of Customs Union versus the FTA is Cho

and Diaz (2011). In this paper they look at the case of Slovenia and their entrance

into the EU. What they notice is that for some sectors the EU CETs here higher

than the Slovenian tariff to the RoW. Thus by joining the EU, they would become

more protectionist towards the RoW. As a result, they look at the alternative trade

arrangement where they sign an FTA with the EU while maintaining their initial

tariffs with the RoW. Whilst they find that under both scenarios there is a gain in

Slovenia’s national welfare, the Custom Union case has the higher welfare mainly

due to the additional tariff revenue from RoW imports the government collected.

Thus, the conclusion is that Slovenia should join the EU. This study is similar to

the FTA scenario investigated in this paper however there is one key distinction;

Slovenia is entering the EU, meaning that the level of tariff rates that Slovenia were

using prior to accession, is readily available. In my case, the UK are already part

of the EU so the tariff rates the UK government decides to impose on imports at

withdrawal is not known with certainty. Thus one of my contributions is to develop

a method in which I attempt to work out the tariff rates.

3.3 United Kingdom Study

The thought of the UK withdrawing from the EU has motivated many economists to

attempt to find the qualitative and quantitative effects of this on the UK economy.

Such examples include Hindley and Howe (2001), Pain and Young (2004), Milne

(2004) and Mansfield (2014). The results are quite mixed and are largely dependent

12

on the assumptions they assert. Apart from Pain and Young (2004), there is an issue

with these papers as they do not utilise a formal economic model to support their

claims; they rely on discussion. Pain and Young (2004) assess the macroeconomic

consequences of UK withdrawal from the EU under endogenous fiscal and monetary

policy. They find that due to the predicted fall in the level of inward foreign direct

investment, this will have an adverse impact on the living standards in the UK.

However, in this paper, the emphasis is on the role of tariffs. Ottaviano, Pessoa and

Sampson (2014) employ a formal model and analyse the impact of tariff changes

on the welfare of the UK if they were to engage in a trade war scenario with the

EU. The standard static AGE model with multiple sectors is employed. Their main

finding is that due to an increase in the EU-UK Tradable Tariffs, the prediction is

that the UK will experience a static loss of around 0.14% of GDP.

The analysis conducted in this thesis differs in many ways. In the current literature,

there is no study to the best of my knowledge that investigates the potential

economic and welfare impact if the second scenario (FTA) were to occur for the

UK. This may very well be due to the complexity and uncertainty of the FTA

scenario. Hence this will be my main contribution to the literature. Furthermore, in

Ottaviano, Pessoa and Sampson (2014), the impact on different sectors in the UK

following this policy shock is not explicitly stated. I will investigate this impact and

thereby determine the economic agents who gain and lose under both scenarios.

13

Chapter 4

Model

4.1 Overview

In this paper, the model of choice is the Static Applied General Equilibrium model

in the tradition of the work by Shaven and Whalley (1984). More specifically,

the model follows the framework employed in Cho and Diaz (2008). In order to

quantify the potential sectoral effects if the UK were to leave the EU, I disaggregate

the British Economy into seven sectors, namely: Food and Beverages, Primary

Goods, Textiles, Clothing and Footwear, Machinery, Chemical products, Services

and Other Manufactures.1 In this British model economy, we invent several agents

that interact with each other in order to capture what is observed in the data.

These agents include a representative household, four different types of producers,

a domestic government and two foreign trade partners. The foreign trade partners

are composed of the European Union and the aggregate of the rest of the world2. A

much more thorough explanation of these agents are provided below.

4.2 Domestic production firms

Under the Armington assumption, we assume in this model that the final goods are

produced by combining a locally-produced component and an imported component.

Thus the role of the domestic production firms is to produce this locally-produced

component of the final good. In order to produce such output, these firms’

production function contains two essential ingredients. Through a Leontief-

type production function, the firm uses the intermediate inputs from the seven

disaggregated sectors in fixed proportions and through a Cobb-Douglas Production

function, the firm employs labour and capital. Thus, for the domestic firm producing

good i, the total production function is:

yi,d = min

{xd1,iad1,i

, ...,xdi,iadi,i

, ...,xdn,iadn,i

, βikαii `

1−αii

}(4.1)

1Section 4.1 explains the disaggregation.2For this analysis Croatia is not included because the data is from 2011 and Croatia was not

part of the EU.

14

with 0 < α < 1, ∀i = 1, ..., n ∈ GP ,the set of production goods; yi,d is the output

of the domestic firm i, xdm,i is the amount of intermediate inputs of good m used in

the production of good i, adm,i is the unit-requirement of intermediate good m in the

production of good i, and ki is the capital input and `i is the labour input used to

produce good i. pi,d is the price of the domestic good i.

4.3 Final production goods firms

In this tatic applied general equilibrium model, goods and services are distinguished

by their industry and by their country of origin. In order to take this into account,

the final production good firm produces the final production good i by combining

the locally produced component with the imported component using an Armington

aggregation technology:

yi = γi

[δi,dy

ρm,ii,d +

∑f∈T

δi,fyρm,ii,f

] 1ρm,i

where σm,i = 1/(1 − ρm,i) is the elasticity of substitution between domestic and

imported goods, yi is the output of the final good i, yi,d is the domestic component in

the final good i and yi,f is the imported component from each of the trade partners

mentioned above. It is also worth noting that when ρm,i → 0, the production

function takes a standard Cobb-Douglas form, i.e. yi = γi

[yδi,di,d ×

∏f∈T y

δi,fi,f

].

Imports of good i from country f are subject to an ad valorem tariff rate τi,f . It is this

rate that will be altered in the experiments that we conduct. The price of the final

good i is pi while the foreign prices (p̄i,f )i∈GP ,f∈T are assumed to be exogenous. As

termed by Cox and Harris (1985), this is the almost small-country assumption. This

refers to the case where a country such as Britain, is not large enough to influence

world prices. However with the Armington assumption, domestic UK producers have

some market power, and as a result they can vary the prices of their domestic goods.

4.4 Consumption goods firms

In this model, we differentiate between the goods that the production firms purchase

in their inter-industry transactions to the goods that households purchase. The

latter is labelled as ‘consumption goods’ and it is exclusively bought by households.

Compared to the goods that production firm purchases, we assume that these

15

consumption goods contain a high service component embedded in them. To offer

intuition to such a case, an example is the difference between buying goods from a

retailer to buying directly from a wholesaler. At a retailer, the tomato consumers

buy have a high service component compared to the tomatoes producers buy in

order to produce ketchup. This high service component can be thought of as the

sales assistant contribution in the sale of that product. The consumption goods firms

combine the final production goods using a fixed proportions technology. Thus this

Leontief-type production function for the consumption of good i firm is:

yi,c = min

{xc1,iac1,i

, ...,xci,iaci,i

, ...,xcn,iacn,i

}

where {1, 2, ..., n} are the goods in GC , the set of consumption goods. Moreover, we

make an additional assumption where xCi,j for i 6= j, services. Therefore, this implies

that for consumption good i, the consumption firm only uses final goods of its own

sector and services as inputs. This follows from the fact that consumption goods

contain a high service component in them. The pc,i is the price of consumption good

i.

4.5 Investment good firm

The way savings is incorporated is one of the main differences between a dynamic

and static model. In a dynamic model, agents save in order to be able to purchase

more consumption goods in the future. Given that our model is based on a static

set-up, in order to take account of this savings observed in the data, we include

an investment good that agents can purchase. By purchasing such a good, agents

derive utility similar to the utility derived from the purchase of consumption goods.

The investment good firms combine the final goods as intermediate inputs using a

fixed proportions technology. Thus this Leontief-type production function for the

investment good i firm is:

yinv = min

{x1,inv

a1,inv

, ...,xi,invai,inv

, ...,xn,invan,inv

}

The pinv is the price of the investment good.

16

4.6 Households

In the UK economy, there is a representative household that derives utility from the

purchase of consumption and investment goods. As mentioned above, investment

goods represent household saving in the observed data. Household preferences over

these goods are governed by a Cobb-Douglas utility function. Thus, the household

utility maximization problem of the form:

max∑i∈GC

θilog ci + θinvlog cinv +∑f∈T

θinv,f log cinv,f

s.t.∑i∈GC

pc,ici + pinvcinv +∑f∈T

ef p̄inv,fcinv,f = (1− τd)(w ¯̀+ rk̄)

where ci is the consumption of good i by the representative household and pc,i is the

price of consumption good i. In the budget constraint, the right hand side represents

the disposable income of the household where τd is the direct tax rate imposed on

the household income, w and k are, respectively, the wage rate for labour and the

rental rate of capital, and finally ¯̀and k̄ are, respectively, the endowments of labour

and capital. Given the method of representing household saving in a static model,

then cinv represents the purchases of the investment good while pinv is the price of

the investment good.

In the data, the UK has a trade surplus with on of the trade partners, the rest

of the World. The way we incorporate this into model is by introducing a foreign

investment good. By purchasing this foreign investment good, UK households are

effectively saving abroad. As a result, cinv,f represents the purchase of the investment

good from country f while the price of the foreign investment good p̄inv,f is assumed

to be exogenous, and ef is the bilateral real exchange rate.

4.7 The Domestic Government

The method of incorporating the government in the static applied general equilib-

rium model is by assuming that the government is yet another agent that gains utility

from consuming the production goods and the investment good. The motivation

behind the inclusion of the government in our model is primarily due to the fact

that from the UK national accounts in 2011, the government made purchases of

some goods and ran a fiscal deficit. In order to purchase such goods, the government

17

must finance these expenditures by the revenues collected from three main sources,

namely, direct and indirect taxes, and tariffs imposed on imports. The government

utility maximization problem takes the form of:

max∑i∈Gp

θgi log cgi + θginvlog cginv

s.t.∑i∈GC

picgi + pinvcinv = τd(w ¯̀+ rk̄) +

∑i∈GC

tc,i +∑f∈T

∑i∈Gp

ti,fef p̄i,fyi,f

From the left side of the government budget constraint, the first term represents the

expenditure of final goods while the second term is the purchase of the investment

good. From the right side of the budget constraint, the four terms represent the total

government revenue: the first term is the direct taxes collected from the households’

income; the second and third terms (that make up the indirect taxes) are the

revenues from taxing the domestic and consumption goods firms, respectively; and

the last term represents the tariff revenue collected from the imports of the two UK

trading partners.

4.8 The Foreign Trade Partners

Given the objective of this paper, the disaggregation of foreign trade is composed

of two partners: The European Union (26 members) and the rest of the World.

The way the foreign sector is incorporated in this model is by constructing a

representative household from both trading partners f ∈ T , where T = (EU,ROW ).

This foreign representative household, similar to the domestic representative

household, gains utility by purchasing imported goods xj,f (j ∈ Gp) from Britain,

and from consuming their local good xf,f . Furthermore, if the trade partner has a

trade surplus with the UK (such as the EU according to the data), we model this as

foreign purchases of the UK investment good xinv,f (foreign savings into the domestic

economy). In country f , the problem faced by the representative household takes

the form of:

18

max

∑j∈Gp

θj,fxρxj,f + θinv,fx

ρxinv,f + θf,fx

ρxf,f

− 1ρx

s.t.∑i∈GP

(1 + τ fi )pixi,f + pinvxinv,f + efxf,f = efIf

As mentioned before from the almost small country assumption, the UK is not large

enough to influence the foreign prices and foreign income. Given that all the relevant

variables in the model are not entirely determined exogenously, this effectively means

that this particular model is something less than a full general equilibrium model.

4.9 Definition of equilibrium

An equilibrium for this economy is a set of prices for the domestic goods

(pi,d)i∈GP ; prices for the final goods (pi)i∈GP ; a price for the investment good

pinv; prices for the consumption goods (pc,i)i∈GC ; factor prices w and r; bi-

lateral exchange rates (ef )f∈T ; foreign prices (p̄i,f )i∈GP f∈T ; a consumption plan

for the representative household (ci, cinv, cinv,f )i∈GCf∈T ; a consumption plan for

the government (cgi , cginv)i∈Gp ; a consumption plan for the representative house-

hold in country f (xi,f , xinv,f , xf,f )i∈GP f∈T ; a production plan for the domestic

good i firm (yi,d, xd1,i, ..., x

dn,i, ki, `i); a production plan for the final good i firm

(yi, yi,d, ..., (yi,f )f∈T ); a production plan for the investment firm (yinv, x1,inv, ..., xn,inv);

a production plan for the consumption good i firm (yi,c, xc1,i, ..., x

cn,i); such that, given

the tax rates and the tariff rates:

− The consumption plan (ci, cinv, cinv,f )i∈GCf∈T solves the problem of the repre-

sentative household.

− The consumption plan (cgi , cginv)i∈Gp solves the problem of the government.

− The consumption plan (xi,f , xinv,f , xf,f )i∈GP f∈T solves the problem of the

representative household in country f .

− The production plan (yi,d, xd1,i, ..., x

dn,i, ki, `i) satisfies

19

yi,d = min

{xd1,iad1,i

, ...,xdi,iadi,i

, ...,xdn,iadn,i

, βikαii `

1−αii

}and

(1 + tp,i)pi,dyi,d −∑j∈Gp

pjxdj,i − w`− rk ≤ 0,= 0ifyi,d > 0

− The production plan (yi, yi,d, (yi,f )f∈T ) satisfies

piyi − pi,dyi,d −∑f∈T

(1 + τi,f )ef p̄i,fyi,f ≤ 0,= 0ifyi > 0

where yi,d and (yi,f )f∈T solve

min(1 + τp,i)pi,dyi,d +∑f∈T

(1 + τi,f )ef p̄i,fyi,f

s.t.yi = γi

[δi,dy

ρm,ii,d +

∑f∈T

δi,fyρm,ii,f

] 1ρm,i

− The production plan (yinv, x1,inv, ..., xn,inv) satisfies

yinv = min

{x1,inv

a1,inv

, ...,xi,invai,inv

, ...,xn,invan,inv

}and

pinvyinv −∑j∈GP

pjxj,inv ≤ 0,= 0ifyinv > 0

− The production plan (yi,c, xc1,i, ..., x

cn,i) satisfies

20

yi,c = min

{xc1,iac1,i

, ...,xci,iaci,i

, ...,xcn,iacn,i

}and

(1 + τc,i)pi,cyi,c −∑j∈GP

pjxcj,i ≤ 0,= 0ifyi,c > 0

− The goods market clear:

yi =∑j∈GP

xdj,i +∑j∈GC

xcj,i + xi,inv + cgi +∑f∈T

xi,f

yi,c =ci

yinv =cinv + cginv +∑f∈T

xinv,f

− The factor markets clear:

∑i∈Gp

`i = ¯̀

∑i∈Gp

ki = k̄

− The balance of payments condition for each trade partner country f is satisfied:

∑i∈GP

ef p̄f,iyi,f +∑i∈GP

ef p̄inv,fcinv,i =∑i∈GP

pixi,f + pinvxinv,f

21

Chapter 5

Data and Calibration

5.1 Sectoral Disaggregation

In this paper, I analyse the potential quantitative impact that a UK withdrawal

from the EU would have on the different productive sectors of the UK economy.

Given this objective, finding the correct level of sectoral disaggregation is critical to

our investigation. The procedure that I employed in order to determine the specific

sectors involved forming a criterion. This criterion included: the relative importance

of that sector in the total economy; the relative importance of that sector in total

trade, exports and imports; the level of tariff protection that the sector enjoys; the

tariff rates applied by the trading partners on UK goods and services; and I look at

the different trade scenarios and their associated tariff rates. As a result, the chosen

level of sectoral disaggregation for the UK is shown in Table 5.1. Below provides a

detailed explanation as to why I chose each sector.

Sectors

Food & BeveragesPrimary Goods

Textiles, Footwear & ClothingMachineryChemicals

Other ManufacturesServices

Table 5.1: Sectoral Disaggregation

The first of our disaggregated sectors is the food and beverages sector. When looking

at the trade data, this sector’s total imports are more than twice (214%) their total

exports, and from an import perspective, the EU makes up 75% of the imports.

Furthermore, this is the second most protected sector in the UK, with the average

effective tariff rate of 4.4%.1 When I conduct the second simulation where the UK is

able to sign numerous FTAs with the RoW, the food and beverages sector becomes

the most protected sector in the UK economy. For the primary goods industry, 75%

1Tariff levels shown in Section 4.3.1

22

of the exports arrive to the EU while 70% of imports come from the RoW. In terms

of the HS code, the primary goods industry contains the ‘Mineral fuels, mineral oils

and products of their distillation; bituminous substances; mineral waxes’ (HS code

27) item. This particular trade item is the largest export item to the EU and the

largest import item from the RoW. Another interesting aspect of this sector is that

the the effective UK tariff rate is 0.21% while for the RoW, the tariff rate is 3.12%,

meaning that this sector has the highest tariff rate differential.

The most protected sector in the UK economy is the textiles, clothing and footwear

sector, with an effective tariff rate of 6.6%. In the first simulation (where the EU

place tariffs on UK goods), the EU effective tariff rate for this sector is 9.15%,

making it also the most protected sector in the EU economy. In terms of UK

trade, the total imports are nearly two and a half (245%) times the size of the total

exports. As for the machinery sector, this sector was extracted due to the fact that

it accounts for 26% of total UK imports as well as 24% of total UK exports. In

the HS code, this sector would include items such as: vehicles other than railway

or tramway rolling-stock, and parts and accessories thereof (HS code 87), nuclear

reactors, boilers, machinery and mechanical appliances; parts thereof (HS code 84),

and electrical machinery and equipment and parts thereof; sound recorders and

reproducers, television image and sound recorders and reproducers, and parts and

accessories of such articles (HS code 85). All three of these items are in the top

six export and import items from both the EU and the RoW, highlighting the

importance of these items to UK Trade.

Next, the chemical products sector accounts for roughly 11% of total UK exports

and 9% of total UK imports. The pharmaceutical products (HS code 30) and organic

chemicals (HS code 29) are two significant items under the chemical product sector

with the former item being the third largest export item to the RoW, with the

latter being the sixth largest export item to the EU. The remaining manufacturing

sectors that were not part of the sectors mentioned above were placed under ‘Other

manufactures’. Finally, the services sector was integrated in our analysis due to the

fact that this sector alone makes up 75% of the UK Economy.2 Not only that, it is

also the largest export sector and the second largest import sector for the UK. The

revealed comparative advantage lies in the services sector (BIS 2012). It is worth

noting that under all experiments conducted in this paper, the tariff rates applied

by the UK, EU and RoW are all zero for the services sector.

2ONS Data

23

5.2 Social Accounting Matrix

Once the level of sectoral disaggregation is selected, the next step in the development

of the AGE Model is the use of the Social Accounting Matrix (SAM). The

SAM matrix is an organized matrix representation that records all the economic

transactions that take place within an economy by all the institutional agents. In this

paper, the timeframe that the SAM covers is one year, specifically 2011. Therefore,

this SAM essentially provides a ‘snapshot’ of the UK economy. The design of the

SAM is such that the entries along a row represent the receipts of a particular agent

while the entries down a column display the payments made by these agents.

As presented in section 4, all of the different economic agents are governed by

the parameters of their associated functions. Thus, in order to construct the

AGE Model, these parameters need to be calibrated in such a way that in the

benchmark equilibrium produced, the artificial economic agents conduct the same

transactions as that observed by their real world counterparts according to the SAM

(Kehoe 1994a). By using the optimality and market clearing conditions, most of the

parameters can be directly calibrated from the SAM (Kehoe 1996). The input

shares and total productivity scale parameters in the production functions and the

parameters in the agents’ utility function are such examples. Appendix A shows the

values of the calibrated parameters for the UK economy. For those parameters that

cannot be calibrated from the SAM, we explain in subsection 5.3 how I obtained

those values.

A SAM for the UK that suits my level of sectorial disaggregation is not readily

available. As a result, I construct one myself tailored to the seven disaggregated

UK sectors. The construction of a SAM requires the use of data from a variety of

sources. The main source stems from the supply and use tables. For the UK, the

latest available supply and use table is from 2011 (Timmer et al. 2015). Based on

the OECD definition, the supply table records how the supplies of different kinds

of goods and services originate from domestic industries and imports, with further

information on indirect taxes and margins on goods. On the other hand, the use

table shows how this supply of goods and services are utilised in the economy.

Such uses include: as intermediate inputs in the firm’s production process, as part

of household and government consumption, as investment and as exports to the

world. Next, these tables are then combined to form the balanced input-output

matrix. Developed by Leontief (1941), the input-output matrix provides detailed

information on the inter-industry transactions that occur in the economy and the

payments to factors of production. There are 59 industries and 59 product groups

24

in the input-output table that I aggregate into seven industries.

To further disaggregate certain components of the SAM, other data sources were

exploited. Given the emphasis of UK trade in this model, the foreign sector was

split between the EU and the RoW. This required data on the inter-EU and intra-

EU trade, which I obtained from the Trade Statistics unit produced by the HM

Revenue & Customs. Additionally, from the HM Revenue & Customs database, I

was able to also find the values for the direct tax revenue and the value added Tax

(VAT) revenue. Finally, from the UK Socio-Economic Accounts provided by the the

World Input-Output Database, the payments to the factors of production were split

between Labour and Capital. The completed SAM is presented in Appendix B.3

5.3 Other Parameters

In this section we look at the parameters that could not be explicitly calibrated

from the SAM. Below, we demonstrate how we obtain the values for these particular

parameters.

5.3.1 Trade Partners’ Income

As mentioned earlier, the two trade partners are the EU and the RoW. The Gross

Domestic Product (GDP) is used as a measure of their associated income. This data

is obtained from the International Financial Statistics published by the International

Monetary Fund (IMF). The GDP values are taken from the calendar year of 2011

in order to remain consistent with the data from our SAM. Another issue is that

GDP values are expressed in US Dollars while the data in the SAM are all in British

Pounds. Consequently, adjustment is necessary. In 2011, the US Dollar-UK Pounds

exchange rate was US$1.60360 per British Pound (Timmer et al. 2015). With

this conversion rate, the GDP of EU was £9,667,804.58 million. With World GDP

at £43,659,067.1 million, the GDP of the RoW was calculated as £32,459,104.52

million.

3T construct the SAM for the UK, I followed asimilar approach to Kehoe (n.d.)

25

5.3.2 Determination of the Tariff Rates

The tariff rates are an essential component of this counterfactual analysis. The

policy shock in our model is precisely this change in tariff rates. In this section, we

demonstrate how we derive the tariff rates from the benchmark case and from the

two hypothetical scenarios that we explore.

The benchmark case reflects the current state where the UK is a member of the

EU. As an EU member, the UK has access to the EU internal market (or EU

Single Market). With such access, trade between the UK and the rest of the EU

is tariff-free. To see the tariffs that the UK impose on the RoW imports, it is

important to understand that the EU follows the customs union trade model. In a

customs union, there is internal free trade but externally, members must apply the

EU common external tariff (CET). This means that the UK must impose the EU

CETs to the RoW. From the supply table, if we divide the tariff revenue with the

value of their associated import, we are able to extract implicitly the tariff rates

that the UK impose on the RoW imports. Given this methodology, these calibrated

tariff rates are effective rates rather than nominal rates. For the other tariffs in this

analysis, we cannot use this method to determine their rates (eg the UK tariff rates

in the two counterfactual scenarios). As a result, I employed another method to find

the effective tariff rates.

The distinction between effective and nominal tariff rates plays an important role

in this different methodology. For the nominal tariff rates, I was able to obtain the

2011 EU applied Most Favoured Nation (MFN) tariff rates from the World Trade

Organization (WTO) database. The products with their associated MFN tariff rate,

were classified according to the Harmonised System (HS). Thus, I had to make a

concordance of these products with my seven disaggregated sectors. If we were

to simply apply these rates to the total import value of a particular sector, the

calculated tariff revenue would be overstated. The reason is that these rates are not

applied to all members of the RoW. The EU has numerous FTAs and preferential

arrangements with many members of the RoW. As a result, this needs to be taken

into account in order to receive the effective tariff rates. What follows next is an

outline of the steps I took to determine the effective UK tariff rates for each sector

imposed on the RoW imports.

1. For each product (HS 4-digit level), the country of origin was found in order to

determine the trade value (data from HM Revenue and Customs) and the specific

tariff rate imposed on them by the UK.

26

2. With such information, I was able to determine the trade-weighted tariff rate on

that particular product.

3. As mentioned above, the products were allocated under the seven disaggregated

sectors. Within each sector, the aggregate trade value of each product was used as

weights, which were then multiplied by the tariff rates derived from Step 2.

4. Adding up all the values from Step 3 for a particular sector, we finally derive the

effective tariff rate for that sector.

5. Complete Steps 1-4 for every sector.

It is worth noting that the trade weighted average was preferred to the simple

average in the calculation of the effective tariff rates. In the data, there were some

products that have large tariff rates but with relatively little trade to the UK (eg

Tobacco products had an average of 40%). If the simple average metric was used,

this would overstate the tariff rate in the food and beverage sector.

In calculating the RoW tariffs on imports from the UK, I assume that the tariffs

are a trade weighted average of the tariffs imposed by the top 10 export trading

partners of the UK.4 By descending rank of value, these partners are the United

States of America, Switzerland, China, Hong Kong, Canada, India, Japan, Russia,

United Arab Emirates and Australia. The tariff rates imposed by the UK and the

RoW are shown in Table 5.2.

Sector UK (%) RoW (%)

Food & Beverages 4.4 5.92Primary Goods 0.21 3.12Textiles, Footwear & Clothing 6.6 6.41Machinery 1.95 3.57Chemicals 2.00 3.52Other Manufactures 0.98 2.26Services 0 0

Table 5.2: Tariff rates in Benchmark Case

In the first counterfactual scenario, the UK would leave the EU without any trade

agreement in place. As explained in section 3, this is a possibility, especially in

the short-run. In this paper it is viewed as the pessimistic case. In this situation,

as stipulated by the WTO rules, the UK and the EU must apply the MFN tariff

rates on each other’s imports. As seen in the benchmark case, the current UK and

4Similar assumption employed in Cho and Yoon, 2013

27

EU MFN tariff rates are identical. Therefore, similar to Ottaviano, Pessoa and

Sampson (2014) and as argued by Mansfield (2015), an assumption is made that,

even after an exit, the UK will still apply the same EU MFN tariff rates. However,

the effective sector tariff rates imposed by the UK and the EU in this scenario are

slightly different. The difference stems from the fact that within a sector, the UK

and the EU have different trade weights attached to their products. The new tariff

rates raised by the UK and the EU are shown in Table X.

Sector UK (%) EU (%)

Food & Beverages 5.41 4.2Primary Goods 2.23 0.65Textiles, Footwear & Clothing 9.22 9.15Machinery 3.6 3.3Chemicals 2.72 2.07Other Manufactures 2.6 2.45Services 0 0

Table 5.3: Tariff rates in Trade War Scenario

From the UK-RoW trade perspective, we assume that the UK is successful in keeping

the same FTA with certain members of the RoW as argued by Mansfield (2015).

Therefore, the tariffs that the UK and RoW impose on each other are the same as

shown in the benchmark case.

Under this hypothetical scenario, the UK sign a free trade agreement (FTA) with the

EU on its withdrawal. An FTA would enable trade with the EU to remain tariff-free.

Unlike a custom union member, the UK would be free to set its own trade polices to

the RoW without applying the EU CET rates. By signing new FTAs, this effectively

facilitates the UK to tap in to growing markets around the world. This is actually

one of the more prominent arguments put forward by Eurosceptics (Springford et

al. 2014). This is the optimistic scenario and the one which contributes the most

to literature.

What will be the effective tariff rates that the UK impose on the RoW imports?

To answer this critical question, I considered a number of factors. First, many in

the UK feel that the EU is slow in generating new FTAs with the RoW (especially

FTAs more suited to the UK economy). Accordingly, to see the possible FTAs the

UK might have upon withdrawal, I conducted research on the European Free Trade

Association (EFTA) members, Switzerland, Norway, Iceland and Liechtenstein (The

UK was part of the EFTA original outer seven until 1973), and observed their

28

contemporary FTAs with the RoW. All four members participate in the EU’s Single

Market and have the freedom to participate in FTAs with the RoW (Mansfield,

2014). In fact, the EFTA members have been successful in signing more FTAs with

the RoW compared to the EU.

Out of the EFTA members, I narrowed my focus on Switzerland as they were

the most successful in negotiating FTAs with the RoW. Switzerland managed to

attain FTAs with major economies like China and Japan. In this paper, I assume

that upon exit, the UK will also be able to sign FTA’s with the same nations

as Switzerland. Stanley (2015) argues that the UK can surpass the success of

Switzerland. Switzerland is a highly developed economy with many similarities

to the UK (Mansfield 2015). Both have a revealed comparative advantage in the

services sector, especially that relating to finance (Fourie and Von Fintel 2009).

According to the Global Enabling Trade Report in 2014 (which looks at the quality

of facilitating the free flow of goods over borders and to their destination-definition),

the UK and the Swiss were positioned 5th and 6th, respectively. Furthermore,

looking at the specific countries in the Swiss FTAs, four countries (China, Hong

Kong, Japan and Canada) are in the top 10 bilateral trading partners of the UK. This

highlights the relevance and suitability of these Swiss FTAs for the UK economy.

As in the first scenario, we once again assume that the UK will apply the same EU

MFN tariff rates. Together with UK’s new FTAs, we can determine the effective

tariff rates imposed on the RoW. With this new information, the methodology

follows the same procedure as outlined above. The effect of these FTAs is that

now more countries are excluded from the MFN tariff rate and as a result, the

effective tariff rate will be reduced for that sector. The magnitude of the reduction

depends on the trade weight of the countries involved in a FTA with the UK.

As in the benchmark case, the RoW tariffs on British goods are assumed to be the

trade weighted average of the tariffs imposed by the top 10 export trading partners

of the UK. The data come from most recent editions of the trade policy reviews by

the WTO. The UK will now have FTAs with 5 of the 10 partners (the four news

ones and the old one, Switzerland). Taking this into account, the calculated tariff

rates imposed by the UK and the RoW are shown in Table 5.4.

29

Sector UK (%) RoW (%)

Food & Beverages 4.20 4.53Primary Goods 0.2 2.58Textiles, Footwear & Clothing 3.48 3.36Machinery 1.825 2.15Chemicals 1.03 2.74Other Manufactures 0.88 1.66Services 0 0

Table 5.4: Tariff rates in FTA Scenario

5.3.3 Elasticities of Substitution

A crucial component of the AGE model is the elasticity of substitution for exports

and imports. Given the static nature of this model, we can not directly calibrate the

values of these parameters from the SAM. Therefore, in this paper, we apply different

sets of values for these parameters. As assumed by Cho and Diaz (2011), for the

benchmark case, we set pm,j = 0.8∀j ∈ Gp and px = 0.9, meaning that the elasticity

of substitution of imports and exports take the values of 5 and 10, respectively.

Given that these values are estimates, we conduct a sensitivity analysis for both

parameters by looking at the literature.

As documented by Rolleigh (2013), the econometric estimates (the traditional

method) of these parameters, often produced values that were too low. Taking

a different approach, Rolleigh (2013) calibrated these parameters by choosing values

of the elasticises to match the sectoral gross output mark ups in that sector. In this

article, the US economy is analysed and the estimates of the sectoral gross output

mark-ups are obtained from Martins, Scarpetta, and Pilat (1996). Since the data

for the sectoral gross output mark-ups for the UK are also available from Martins,

Scarpetta, and Pilat (1996), I employ Rolleigh’s (2013) method to calibrate the

values of the pm for each disaggregated sector.

The concordance of Martins, Scarpetta, and Pilat’s (1996) sector specification to

our level of sectoral disaggregation was completed. Next, the simple average of the

sectors within our level of sectoral disaggregation were taken to obtain the UK sector

import elasticity. 5 Furthermore, the values for the services sector was not included

in both articles, and as a result we apply the same values as in the benchmark case.

The final values are shown in Table 5.5.

5This approach is similar to Cho and Diaz (2011)

30

Sector Rolleigh (2013)

Food & Beverages 0.72Primary Goods 0.91Textiles, Footwear & Clothing 0.94Machinery 0.83Chemicals 0.91Other Manufactures 0.89Services 0.8

Table 5.5: Import Elasticities of Substitution (pm,j)

In the sensitivity experiments of the import elasticity, the parameter governing the

elasticity of export substitution px, is fixed to be 0.9 for both cases. In section 5.6,

we conduct a sensitivity analyses of this parameter under the FTA scenario. The

motivation is twofold. First, there is a lack of data for the export elasticity of UK

sectors. Second, we test the Johnson’s Optimal Tariff (1954) argument where the

optimal tariff should be set to zero as the parameter px approaches one.

5.3.4 Simulation

As seen in section 4, the Static AGE model is a system of non-linear equations.

With the use of MATLAB to solve this system, and with the numerical specification

of the parameters of the static AGE model, I was able to produce the benchmark

equilibrium. Given the nature of the static AGE model, the comparative statics

methodology is employed to analyse the impact of the different UK trade policies

following a withdrawal from the EU. The exogenous shock in our analysis is the

change in the tariff schedule associated with the Trade war and FTA scenarios.

With this exogenous shock, a new steady state equilibrium will be produced where

we can observe and analyse the changes in certain endogenous variables. Under

both scenarios, the benchmark equilibrium is the point of comparison (all other

parameters remain the same). Next, we show the results of these simulations.

31

Chapter 6

Results

6.1 Overview

In this section, the simulated results of the UK partaking in alternative trade

arrangements with the EU are presented and analysed. Trade war and the FTA

are the two alternative trade arrangements explored in this paper. The ‘Trade

War’ scenario examines the hypothetical case where the UK withdraws from the

EU without any trade agreement in place. This effectively means that both parties

must abide by the WTO rules and thus apply the effective MFN tariffs on each

other’s goods. With the ‘FTA’ arrangement, the UK is successful in signing an FTA

with the EU and therefore has the power to set their own tariff policy with the

RoW. These two experiments are known as the Trade War and FTA benchmark

simulation, respectively.

With these new tariff rates, we run the simulation and analyse the changes in

consumption and factor prices, domestic production, foreign trade and welfare. The

results are expressed as the percentage deviation from the values in the benchmark

case. In terms of the welfare analysis, economists usually measure welfare by using an

index based on income in order to overcome the problem of utility having no natural

units (Kehoe 1994a). More specifically, in this paper, the welfare measure is based on

an aggregate consumer real index and a government real index that are combined to

form the social real income index. The consumer real income index is given by∏

j cθjj ,

where j ranges over the consumption goods and the investment good. Similarly, the

government real income index is given by∏

j cθg,jg,j , where j ranges over the production

goods and the investment good consumed by the government. The social real income

index is defined as∏

j CΘjj where Cj = cj + cg,j and Θj =

cj+cg,j∑j cj+

∑j cg,j

. This type

of measure, known as the equivalent variation, seeks to find how much additional

income consumers would need when faced with the base prices in order to achieve

the same level of utility as in the benchmark simulation.

Given the hypothetical nature of the FTA scenario, I conduct a sensitivity analysis to

determine the robustness of the benchmark simulation when the UK tariff rates are

altered. The second sensitivity analysis is performed on the elasticity of substitution

of imports. From the benchmark simulation, the Armington import elasticises were

32

set to be the same across the sectors. Now, we repeat the simulation, except this time

allowing the values to be differentiated by sector. These sectoral import elasticity

values were calculated based on the method employed in Rolleigh (2013).

Next, in the trade war scenario, the government tariff revenue will increase

significantly (due to the rise in the tariff rates) which leads to an increase in

government welfare. In this experiment, we look at the case where the government

passes this additional revenue to consumers by reducing their direct tax payments.

This tariff rebate setup can provide policy makers useful insights into different fiscal

arrangements under certain trade arrangements.

Finally, we determine whether the Johnson’s Optimal Tariff (1954) hypothesis is

valid for the UK case. This hypothesis states that optimal tariff should become

zero as the parameter governing the export elasticity approaches one. Thus this

experiment involves conducting a sensitivity analysis where the export elasticity

values are changed, and then observing the reaction of the social welfare index. It is

through this welfare measure that we base our conclusion on whether this hypothesis

holds for the UK.

6.2 Trade War

The table below is a presentation of the results of the Trade War simulation.

Sector Price Change (%)

Food & Beverages 0.578Primary Goods 0.053Textiles, Footwear & Clothing 0.594Machinery 0.532Chemicals -0.157Other Manufactures 0.041Services -0.265

Table 6.1: Effect of trade war on consumption good prices

The percentage change in the price of consumption goods after the UK and the EU

engage in trade war are shown in Table 6.1. For the majority of sectors, there is a

moderate increase in the price of consumption goods. To understand this movement

in prices, it is paramount to recognise the chain of production of the consumption

goods. As explained in Section 4, the consumption goods content is composed of the

final goods from their own sector and the services sector. However, the final goods

33

producer combines the locally produced component with the imported component.

Thus, when trade costs increase (due to tariff rates rises), this effectively increases

the price of imported goods which in turn leads to an increase in the price of final

goods 1. Since final goods are a key input in the production of the consumptions

goods, this rise in input cost adds pressure to increase the price of consumption

goods. The two sectors that become the most protected industries under the trade

war scenario are the textiles, footwear and clothing sector and the food and beverages

sector, as they experience the largest increases in prices, rising by 0.59% and 0.58%,

respectively. The machinery sector, which is the biggest importer sector from the

EU, has the third highest rise in prices.

It is interesting to note that for the services sector there is a modest fall in price.

This is the UK’s main export sector and the only sector where tariff barriers are not

placed. Since the service sector contributes to the production of every consumption

good, this price decline places downward pressure on the price of all consumption

goods. It is for this reason that prices of consumption goods are lower than the

prices of final goods. Furthermore, this is the cause for the chemical sector actually

experiencing a fall in price. Unlike other sectors, where the services component

makes up 25-35% of the consumption good, the service component accounts for

89% of the chemical consumption good (see SAM). Thus, the price decline in the

services sector outweighs the rise in price of the final goods from the chemicals sector.

Figure 6.1: Effect of trade war on exports

1this is corroborated with our results for the percentage change in final goods price

34

From Figure 6.1, every sector (except for services), experiences a significant fall in

exports to both the EU and the RoW. Under this scenario, the EU place tariffs

on UK goods. The effect of such a policy is that now, UK exports have become

effectively more expensive to the EU consumers. This makes UK products less

price competitive in the EU market and consequently EU consumers shift their

consumption to the EU products. As a result of this substitution effect, the level

of UK exports to the EU decline. The largest fall in exports occurs in the Textiles

sector, falling by 62%. This reflects the fact that this sector becomes the most heavily

protected sector in the EU with a tariff rate of 9.15%. Furthermore, the second and

third most protected sectors in the EU, (food and beverages and the machinery

sector), experience the second and third largest fall in exports, respectively. The

only sector to experience a gain in exports to the EU is the services sector. This is

UK’s main export sector and the only sector where tariff barriers are not placed.

UK exports to the RoW fall even though the RoW tariff levels on UK goods remain

unchanged from the benchmark case. The final goods produced by the UK are

the exports to both the EU and the RoW. Since a key input in the final good

production is imports, the increased tariff levels increase the price of final goods.

Such an increase means that these products become relatively less price competitive

in the RoW market. Similar to the EU customers, the RoW customers will switch

to the RoW goods and consequently UK exports to the RoW decrease. From the

prices of final goods, the machinery sector experiences the largest gain in price and

as a result, the largest decrease in exports to the RoW.

Figure 6.2: Effect of trade war on imports

35

From Figure 6.2, every UK sector experiences a significant fall in imports from the

EU. The explanation is quite similar to the case of exports above except now, the

perspective is from the UK consumers. By the UK placing tariff barriers on EU

imports, they effectively raise the price of EU products. Through the substitution

effect, the level of EU imports into the UK fall. The largest fall in imports takes

place in the textiles,clothing and footwear sector, falling by 39%. This reflects the

fact that this sector becomes the most heavily protected sector in the UK with a

tariff rate of 9.22%. Furthermore, the second and third most protected sectors in

the EU (food and beverages and machinery sector) experience the second and third

largest fall in imports, respectively.

From the graph above, we also notice a fall in RoW imports in most sectors, despite

the UK maintaining their tariff policy with the RoW. As shown above, there is an

overall decrease in exports to both trading partners. As a result, UK consumers,

who are the owners of the factors of production, experience a loss in income. With

less income they have less money to spend on imports from the EU and the RoW.

Thus it is through the income channel that RoW imports for many sectors fall.

The food and beverages sector is the only sector that experiences a gain in imports

from the RoW. This trade diversion represents the UK shifting their source of food

imports to the more efficient producer, the RoW. Prior to this scenario by having

no tariffs, the EU (the relatively less efficient producer) were able to export to the

UK (Springford et al. 2014).

Under trade war, the total bilateral trade flow volumes for the UK with the EU

and the RoW decrease by 17% and 2.5%, respectively. In terms of the composition

of goods trade by destination, the share of UK’s export to the EU falls from 53%

to 49%, while the share of import from the EU falls from 48% to 44%. With such

information, this signifies the shift in trade that the UK makes with the RoW even

though there is a loss in trade from both trading partners. On a global scale, the

UK bilateral trade falls by 9.2%, highlighting the overall negative impact of Trade

War on UK trade.

Table 6.2 shows the effect of trade war on domestic production in the UK. The

change in domestic production is influenced by the changes in the demand for final

goods and imports. This is because the final goods producers combine the imported

component with the domestically produced component. For example, in a particular

sector, if there is an increase in the demand of the final good that outweighs the

increase in import value, then this gap is filled by increasing the production of the

36

Sector Change (%)

Food & Beverages 1.041Primary Goods 0.141Textiles, Footwear & Clothing -3.883Machinery -3.622Chemicals -5.293Other Manufactures -1.734Services 0.309

Table 6.2: Effect of trade war on domestic production

domestic firm. In our scenario, the main driver of demand of final goods is exports.

Thus the change in the trade balance plays a major role in determining the change

in domestic production. With the rise of tariff levels, both imports and exports fall

for most sectors, as shown above. As a result, if import value falls by more than the

export value (trade balance improving), then there is upward pressure on increasing

domestic production.

From the results, every sector that experiences an improvement in their total

trade balance also sees an increase in their domestic production and vice-versa.

Additionally, another channel of demand for the final good comes from the

Government spending. With tariff revenue increasing, Governments expenditure

on services increases (governments only purchase services, see SAM) and therefore

domestic production in services, expands. The major ‘winners’ from this trade

environment include the food and beverages, primary goods and services sectors

where the food sector expands by 1.05%. On the other hand, the rest of the sectors

experience a loss in production with the chemicals sector attaining the largest loss

of 5.3%.

Sector Factor Price (%)Rental Rate -0.253Wage -0.561

Table 6.3: Effect of trade war on Factor Prices

Table 6.3 shows the change in the price of the wage rate of labour and the rental rate

of capital. The main determinant of change in factor prices stems from the change

in demand from the domestic production firms. Domestic firms employ labour and

capital to produce their output. Therefore, given that under Trade War, there is

an overall decline in domestic production, these firms in general will demand less

resources which in turn induces a negative change in factor prices. In terms of value,

37

the relatively labour intensive sectors (machinery and other manufactures) display

the largest losses in domestic production. This leads to a disproportionate decrease

in wages compared to the rental rate where wages fall by more than twice the fall

of the rental rate.

Sector Change (%)

Aggregate consumer welfare -0.466Government welfare 1.169Social welfare -0.066

Table 6.4: Effect of trade war on Welfare

Finally, I analyse the impact of trade war on social welfare. As mentioned earlier,

social welfare is a weighted sum of the welfare from the aggregate consumer and the

national government. From the consumer perspective, the fall in disposable income

(as demonstrated by the decrease in rental rate and wages), leads to a loss in welfare

of 0.47%. On the other hand, the government records a significant gain in welfare,

rising by 1.17%. Since tariff rates increase under this scenario, the tariff revenues

collected by the government rise by 267% compared to the benchmark case. This

additional revenue enables the government to expand their expenditure, thereby

facilitating the attainment of a higher welfare. Taking both welfare results together,

social welfare shows a slight loss of 0.07% (more weight is placed on the consumer

welfare). With such a result, this provides evidence that trade war with the EU can

have a negative impact, even if small, on the UK economy as a whole.

Ottaviano, Pessoa and Sampson (2014) measure of welfare was based on the change

of real GDP. They found that in a trade war scenario, the UK would produce a static

loss of 0.14% of GDP. In order to make a comparison, I also measure the change in

real GDP based on my results from the trade war simulation. I find a static loss of

0.128% of UK GDP. With such a small difference compared to Ottaviano, Pessoa and

Sampson (2014), this provides credibility in the results I produced. Furthermore,

this result also corroborates with the result produced by the social welfare measure.

The impact on the UK economy is negative but small.

38

6.3 Free Trade Agreement

In this section, I present the results from the simulation of the FTA setup.

Sector Price Change (%)

Food & Beverages 0.030Primary Goods & -0.021Textiles, Footwear & Clothing -0.748Machinery 0.010Chemicals 0.040Other Manufactures 0.007Services 0.065

Table 6.5: Effect of trade war on consumption good prices

The percentage change in the price of consumption goods after the UK signs a

FTA with the EU are shown in Table 6.5. For many sectors, there is little price

increase which may seem contradictory given that the tariff levels with the RoW

have dropped. To explain this, the chain of production of the consumption goods

outlined in the trade war scenario, needs to be emphasised and reiterated. When

tariff levels decrease, the trade costs drops which in turn places pressure for the

prices of the final goods to decline. For the final good prices, we observe a decline

in every sector (except for the services and food and beverages sector). For the

services sector, there is no reduction in tariff barriers (since it is already zero) and

for the food and beverages sector, not only is it the smallest import sector from the

RoW, but only 25% of imports actually come from the RoW. Similar to study for

the Trade War scenario, the price rise in the services sector places upward pressure

on the price of consumption goods. Since the tariff reductions in many sector are

particularly small, it is for this reason that the prices of consumption goods for many

sectors become positive.

From Table 5.4, we notice that tariffs are not completely eliminated but are rather

reduced to a certain degree. This magnitude of reduction plays a key role in the

determination of prices. The textiles sector experiences the largest fall in tariff level

with the RoW and consequently, experiences a relatively large decline in prices of

0.75%. The chemicals industry experiences the second largest fall in tariff levels,

however records a positive gain in prices. As mentioned earlier, 89% of the content of

the chemical consumption good is made up of services and since the price of services

increases, this outweighs the negative impact from tariff levels and thus increases

in prices (in fact from the final goods price, chemicals record the second largest fall).

39

Figure 6.3: Effect of a FTA on exports

From Figure 6.3, every sector (except for services), experiences a significant rise

in exports to both the EU and the RoW. The manner in which tariffs impact UK

exports, is again similar to the explanation provided under the Trade War scenario.

The difference is that now, under the FTA scenario, the RoW reduce tariffs on UK

goods. By the RoW reducing their tariffs, UK products become more competitive in

the RoW market as they can sell their product at a lower price to the RoW customer.

Consequently, the RoW consumers shift their consumption to the UK products and

thereby increase the level of UK exports to the ROW. The largest rise in exports

occurs in the textiles, clothing and footwear sector, rising by 45%. This reflects the

fact that this sector enjoys the largest reduction in tariffs from 6.41% to 3.36%. The

only sector to experience a loss in exports to the RoW is the services sector. This is

the UK’s main export sector and the only sector where tariff reductions do not occur.

UK exports to the EU rise even though EU tariff levels on UK goods remain zero.

The decrease in the price of the final goods caused by tariff reduction on imports

makes the UK products relatively more price competitive in the EU export market.

Similar to the RoW customers, the EU customers will switch to the UK goods and

thereby increase the level of UK exports to the EU. From the graph, the textiles,

clothing and footwear and chemicals sectors experience the largest rise in exports

to the EU. This can be attributed to the fact that both sectors exhibit the largest

declines in the price of their final goods.

40

Figure 6.4: Effect of a FTA on imports

From Figure 6.4, every UK sector experiences a significant upsurge in imports from

the RoW. By UK reducing tariff barriers on RoW imports, the price of RoW imports

become effectively cheaper. Through the substitution effect, the level of RoW

imports into UK rise. The largest increase in imports takes place in the textiles

sector, rising by 16%. This reflects the fact that this sector enjoys the largest

reduction in tariffs from 6.6% to 3.48%. The chemicals sector, which enjoys the

second largest reduction in tariff from 2% to 1.03%, experiences the second largest

increase in imports from the RoW. This is followed by the machinery sector which

is the biggest import sector from the RoW.

For four sectors, there is a small rise in the level of EU imports. Again, this

arises due to the income effect. As exports increase, this brings in new income

to which the UK consumers are able to extend their purchases of imports from the

EU. However under this scenario, trade diversion is more evident. Three sectors

namely the primary, textiles, clothing and footwear and services, exhibit declines

in imports from the EU. Even if the RoW had a product where they were more

efficient in producing than the EU, the fact that tariffs were applied to the RoW

before and not to the EU, enabled many non-efficient EU producers to hold a large

market share in imports to the UK. Now that we have a reduction in tariff rates,

this advantage to the EU is reduced Hindley and Howe (2001).

Under an FTA, the total bilateral trade flow volumes for the UK with the EU and

the RoW increase by 1.07% and 4.05%, respectively. In terms of the composition

41

of goods trade by destination, the share of UK’s export to the EU falls from 52.5%

to 51.7%, while the share of import from the EU falls from 48.2% to 47.5%. With

such information, this signifies the shift in trade that the UK makes with the RoW.

On a global scale, the UK bilateral trade increases by 2.5%, highlighting the overall

positive impact of a FTA on UK trade.

Sector Change (%)

Food & Beverages 0.381Primary Goods 0.076Textiles, Footwear & Clothing -0.719Machinery 2.462Chemicals 1.399Other Manufactures 0.448Services -0.159

Table 6.6: Effect of a FTA on domestic production

Table 6.6 shows the effect of an FTA on domestic production in the UK. As

demonstrated previously, trade balance plays a major role in determining the change

in domestic production. Unlike the trade scenario, tariff levels drop for most sectors

and consequently both imports and exports rise, as shown above. As a result, if

export value increases by more than the import value (trade balance improving),

then there is upward pressure on increasing domestic production.

From the results, every sector except the primary goods sector that experiences

a deterioration in their total trade balance also sees a decrease in their domestic

production. The primary goods sector on the other hand records a gain in

production. This highlights the fact that the primary goods sector is an important

intermediate good for the domestic production in both the food and beverages and

other manufactures sector. Since domestic production increases for both of these

sectors, this demand on the primary goods outweighs the loss in the deterioration

in their total trade balance.

This time, tariff revenue for the government falls. Consequently, there is a decline in

government expenditure in the services sector which augments the loss in domestic

production for the services sector. The major ‘winners’ arising from a FTA

include the machinery, chemicals, food and beverages and other manufactures. The

machinery sector expands the most, by 2.5%. On the other hand, the rest of the

sectors experience a loss in production with the textiles sector attaining the largest

loss of 0.72%. Analysing the two possible scenario after UK withdrawal from the EU,

42

shows that the food and beverages and primary goods sector will experience a gain

in domestic production while the textiles will experience a loss under both scenarios.

Sector Factor Price (%)Rental Rate -0.001Wage -0.152

Table 6.7: Effect of a FTA on Factor Prices

Table 6.7 shows the change in the price of the wage rate of labour and the rental rate

of capital under an FTA. While we do observe a rise in total domestic production,

the resulting changes in factor prices are mixed. This is mainly due to the change

in disaggregated domestic production patterns. There is a major shift in resources

from the service sector (the second most capital intensive industry) to the more

labour intensive machinery sector. As a result, the wage rate grows while the rental

rate experiences an insignificant fall.

Sector Change (%)

Aggregate consumer welfare 0.105Government welfare -0.065Social welfare 0.065

Table 6.8: Effect of a FTA on Welfare

Finally, I analyse the impact of an FTA on the national welfare of UK. Since wages

make up 70% of consumers’ income, the increase in wages outweighs the loss in the

rental rate, thereby producing a rise in disposable income for consumers. With

additional income, consumers can purchase more which leads to a rise in their

welfare. This time, the government records a loss in welfare, declining by 0.065%.

Since tariff rates are reduced under this scenario, the tariff revenues collected by the

government fall by 20% compared to the benchmark case. With less total revenue,

governments cannot make as many purchases as before. Taking both welfare results

together, social welfare shows a slight gain of 0.07%. Therefore, if the UK were able

to successfully sign a FTA with the EU and the numerous nations in the RoW (as

stated in section 4), then the UK can enjoy a positive but small impact on their

economy. In terms of the welfare measure based on the change of real GDP, I find

a static gain of 0.04% of GDP. Again, corroborating with the social welfare result,

that under this type of trade policy, the impact on the UK economy is positive but

43

fairly small.

Given the nature of this scenario, a sensitivity analysis of the tariff rates was

conducted. To conduct the sensitivity analysis, the difference between the

benchmark tariff and the adjusted tariff was halved. Then I add and subtract

this value from the adjusted tariff rate. The results follow the same pattern as in

the benchmark simulation except with different magnitudes. For every variable it

shows a 50-100% change compared to the FTA benchmark simulation. In terms

of the welfare analysis it records a 0.03-0.10% positive gain. Therefore, the result

seems robust.

6.4 Import Elasticities of Substitution Differentiated

by Sector

In the above benchmark simulations, the elasticity of substitution of imports were

set to be the same across the sectors. Thus, I perform a sensitivity analysis where

the values of the import elasticities are differentiated by sector. Following the

methodology employed in Rolleigh (2013), I obtain the data from Martins, Scarpetta,

and Pilat (1996), and then I calculate the import elasticities for the UK case. The

motivation behind such analysis is to check the robustness of the benchmark results

by using more realistic values. In the benchmark case, the average was assumed

to be 0.8 while with these new values the average is 0.87. In terms of the export

elasticity, this is assumed to be fixed at 0.9 for each case 2

Sector Trade War (%) FTA (%)

Food & Beverages 0.575 0.038Primary Goods 0.044 0.021Textiles, Footwear & Clothing 0.350 -0.784Machinery 0.480 0.029Chemicals -0.139 0.035Other Manufactures 0.030 0.030Services -0.229 0.055

Table 6.9: Effect on Consumption Good prices (σm,i 6= σm,j)

Table 6.9 shows the change in consumption good prices under both scenarios when

2For results of other variables see Appendix C

44

conducting a sensitivity analysis. For both scenarios the pattern is quite similar

to the corresponding benchmark cases. Under a case where tariffs fall, when a

sector has a higher import elastic compared to another one, the impact should be

larger on its price of consumption goods compared to the benchmark simulations.

However, as can be seen from table X, this is not always the case. A possible reason

is that the UK are in many sectors, both export and import intensive. For most

sectors under the FTA scenario, the change in prices are a lot larger in magnitude

compared to the FTA benchmark simulation. The textiles, clothing and footwear

has the largest import elasticity of 0.94. Though it has the largest change in terms

of absolute quantity, the other manufactures experience a 3.54 times larger change

than the benchmark simulation. For the trade war scenario, most changes are lower

compared to the benchmark simulations.

Sector Trade War (%) FTA (%)

Rental Rate -0.189 -0.007Wage Rate -0.483 0.114

Table 6.10: Effect on Factor prices (σm,i 6= σm,j)

For the Trade War scenario, the factor prices for both the rental rate and wage

rate improve when compared to the Trade War benchmark simulation. This result

is mainly driven by improvement in domestic production 3. On the other hand,

the factor prices in the FTA scenario both decrease more than the corresponding

benchmark simulation. This time the domestic production does not grow as much.

Sector Trade War (%) FTA (%)

Aggregate Consumer welfare -0.393 0.077Government 1.201 -0.202Social Welfare -0.003 0.009

Table 6.11: Effect on Welfare (σm,i 6= σm,j)

The most interesting result arising from this experiment is the change in welfare.

While for both scenarios the social welfare heads in the same direction as in their

corresponding benchmark simulation, the result becomes insignificant. As a result,

3See Appendix C

45

the results form the benchmark simulation do not seem as robust as we hoped for.

6.5 Tariff Revenue Rebate under Trade War

From the trade war simulation, I noticed that the UK government tariff revenue

increases by 267% and Social welfare falls by 0.06%. As a result, it would be

interesting to conduct a numerical experiment where the government hands over this

additional tariff revenue to the consumers by lowering the direct aggregate tax rate

imposed on consumers’ income. If the situation improved after such a policy, then

this type of tariff revenue rebate setup can provide policy makers useful insights into

different fiscal arrangements under certain trade arrangements. In order to eliminate

the additional gain in tariff revenue, the direct tax was decreased by 1.95%. Here

we only include the change in prices of consumption goods, factor prices and welfare.

Sector Price Change (%)

Food & Beverages 0.579Primary Goods 0.054Textiles, Footwear & Clothing 0.596Machinery 0.534Chemicals -0.158Other Manufactures 0.043Services -0.266

Table 6.12: Effect of trade war with Rebate on consumption good prices

Sector Factor Price (%)Rental Rate -0.253Wage -0.561

Table 6.13: Effect of a Trade War with Rebate on Factor Prices

Sector Change (%)

Aggregate consumer welfare -0.119Government welfare -0.228Social welfare -0.034

Table 6.14: Effect of Trade War with Rebate on Welfare

In comparison to the benchmark simulation, there are no significant changes in the

price of consumption goods and factor prices. In terms of welfare, consumers’ welfare

46

does not fall to the extent experienced in the benchmark simulation. The reason for

the difference being that consumers under this new fiscal arrangement have less tax

to pay, which improves their disposable income. As for the government, the welfare

improves but not as much as that shown in the benchmark simulation. Overall the

social welfare still experiences a loss of 0.034%. Nevertheless, when comparing to

the benchmark simulation, this indicates an improvement of nearly 48%. Therefore,

this demonstrates that different fiscal arrangements can be beneficial under a change

in trade policy.

6.6 Optimal Tariff Argument

The final experiment involves testing the validity of the Johnson’s Optimal Tariff

(1954) hypothesis for the UK under the FTA scenario. This hypothesis states that

optimal tariff should become zero as the parameter governing the export elasticity

approaches one. Thus this experiment involves conducting a sensitivity analysis

where the export elasticity values increase incrementally, at which point I observe

the reaction of the social welfare index. The motivation behind this test is twofold.

Since we do not have export elasticities for the UK, this test indirectly provides a

sensitivity analysis to this scenario. Second, given the history of the UK’s attitude

towards free trade, this test might provide evidence that the UK should implement

a unilateral free trade policy (Booth and Howarth 2012; Srpingford et al. 2015)

Sector 0.8 0.85 0.9 0.95

Aggregate consumer welfare 0.079 0.090 0.104 0.127Government welfare -0.167 -0.132 -0.064 0.142

Social welfare 0.019 0.036 0.065 0.133

Table 6.15: Effect of Trade War with Rebate on Welfare

From Table 6.15, we do indeed find that the hypothesis holds for the UK; the social

welfare improves as the export elasticity approaches one. As a result, if the export

elasticity of substitution increases, then it would become optimal for the UK to set

tariffs to zero.

47

Chapter 7

Conclusion

This paper analyses the potential quantitative effects of the UK withdrawing from

the EU. The focus is on two possible exit scenarios the UK could face: (1) the

pessimistic case, the UK engages in trade war with the EU, and (2) the optimistic

case, the UK successfully signs an FTA with the EU and thereby acquires the

ability to sign FTAs with members of the RoW. The second scenario in particular is

important as based on the literature it has been done before due to the uncertainty

and complexity of the situation. In order to conduct our analysis, a static AGE

model that is calibrated to the constructed UK SAM is employed. Dependent on

the exit scenario, the tariff parameter is altered and the simulation run. From here,

I find the predicted effects on prices, trade, domestic production, and welfare of the

UK economy.

The results from the trade war scenario, show that overall, prices increase, domestic

production falls and bilateral trade with both the EU and the RoW decline. In

terms of welfare, consumers experience a welfare loss of 0.47% due to the fall in

factor prices, while on the other hand, the government records a gain of 1.22%.

This gain arises due to the newfound tariff revenue from the EU imports. Overall,

social welfare falls by 0.066%, highlighting the negative impact if the UK were to

participate in such a situation. This result is corroborated with Ottaviano, Pessoa

and Sampson (2014).

For the FTA scenario, the overall effect on prices, domestic production and bilateral

trade with the EU and the RoW are the reverse in direction compared to the trade

war scenario. For both scenarios, the primary, food and beverages sector always gain

in domestic production. Furthermore, in most variables the largest impact occurs

on the textiles, clothing and footwear sector due to the fact that it experiences the

largest change in tariff rates from both scenarios. An interesting result from this

scenario is that although bilateral trade grows with both the EU and the RoW, many

disaggregated sectors suffer from trade diversion. This is especially evident from the

import side as UK consumers switch to the more efficient producers in the RoW.

In the FTA arrangement, as the disposable incomes of consumers rise, so too does

their welfare, which shows a gain of 0.10%. This time, the government welfare falls

48

by 0.065% as they lose tariff revenue from the RoW imports. Still, the social welfare

increases by 0.065%, meaning that the UK can gain from this trade arrangement

with the EU. However, this result must be taken with caution. The magnitude is

quite small and as I performed a sensitivity analysis on the import elasticities, the

social welfare showed to be insignificant, highlighting that the magnitude of this

gain is not as robust.

This paper set out to provide an answer to the question ‘Should the UK leave

the EU?’ with a focus on tariff rates. But in reality, membership with the EU

implies many other aspects that need to be considered with which this model does

not capture. For example, due to the static nature of the model, the dynamic

phenomena such as capital flows and foreign direct investment (FDI) under different

trade policies are not captured. For instance, FDI is considered to be major potential

cost to leaving the EU for the UK economy. The City of London is Europe’s largest

financial centre and an integral part of the UK economy. Thus if their position was

threatened due to withdrawal from the EU, this can have substantial costs to the

UK economy. Thus, a model that incorporates these dynamic aspects will provide

a more accurate effect of withdrawal. Other issues not addressed explicitly in this

analysis include the EU rules of origin, EU regulation, UK’s fiscal contribution to the

EU and migration flows. Analysing the impact of these aspects if the UK withdrawal

were to happen are interesting questions for future research.

One limitation of my results is that the actual tariff rates that the UK might impose

on foreign goods are not known with certainty. The results produced are quite

dependent on the assumption made. This is expected given the hypothetical nature

of the alternative scenario. Though a sensitivity analysis was performed, employing

completely different methods in determining the effective tariff rates can show how

robust the results are.

An interesting extension to this analysis that can be studied is the welfare impact a

UK withdrawal from the EU has on differentiated households. In order to conduct

this analysis, the UK Living Costs and Food Survey must be acquired 1. Households

can be differentiated by: age, education and/or income. Specific for the UK,

households can be differentiated by their country (England, Scotland, Wales and

Northern Ireland). Such future research can provide important information and

inform the UK public when the planned referendum arrives.

1Data is only available to UK residents.

49

Appendix A

A1

Sector Price change Government

Food & Beverages 0.0945 0.0000Primary Goods 0.0170 0.0000Textiles, Footwear & Clothing 0.0547 0.0000Machinery 0.0739 0.0000Chemicals 0.0202 0.0000Other Manufactures 0.0936 0.0000Services 0.5120 0.9090Investment Goods 0.1290 0.0910

Table A.1: Preference parameters θ - aggregate consumer andgovernment

Sector α β

Food & Beverages 0.2024 7.7930Primary Goods 0.6485 2.7419Textiles, Footwear & Clothing 0.0029 8.7604Machinery 0.0260 3.9378Chemicals 0.2475 6.7437Other Manufactures 0.1028 5.2029Services 0.3102 3.5703

Table A.2: Domestic goods firm parameters (α, β)

50

Sector γ λdom λEU λRoW

Food & Beverages 2.7395 0.4257 0.3141 0.2601Primary Goods 2.8760 0.3980 0.2656 0.3362

Textiles, Footwear & Clothing 2.9935 0.3616 0.2888 0.3495Machinery 2.9706 0.3592 0.3286 0.3121Chemicals 2.9359 0.3742 0.329 0.2967

Other Manufactures 2.7520 0.4310 0.273 0.296Services 2.2431 0.5197 0.2386 0.2416

Table A.3: Armington Aggregators

51

Appendix B

A2

Pro

du

ctio

nC

on

sum

pti

on

Des

c1

23

45

67

12

34

56

7L

KC

IFI

GX

X (

EU)

X (

RO

W)

Tota

l

Pro

du

ctio

n1

. Fo

od

an

d B

ever

ages

16

17

42

65

91

26

16

10

24

54

30

93

79

65

90

00

00

00

00

01

06

01

77

36

10

86

56

87

11

59

95

9

2. O

ther

Pri

mar

y1

16

89

79

21

31

38

53

22

82

89

32

29

00

70

71

00

00

00

00

02

91

70

28

49

22

13

83

71

09

11

93

41

3. T

exti

les,

Clo

thin

g &

Fo

otw

ear

10

22

43

96

73

54

30

16

75

57

30

04

38

47

00

00

00

00

47

00

11

68

18

06

63

61

56

63

22

4. M

ach

iner

y9

02

12

11

70

51

77

93

90

95

25

80

91

00

04

67

62

00

00

00

04

85

60

01

10

40

34

96

22

60

78

03

19

12

0

5. C

hem

ical

51

21

55

64

23

19

48

16

76

95

70

22

50

52

00

00

22

06

00

00

00

00

49

80

22

77

60

22

04

11

03

97

0

6. O

ther

Man

ufa

ctu

res

68

64

37

37

26

12

89

16

25

89

53

62

47

87

08

00

00

06

81

97

00

00

01

31

90

07

03

06

35

25

43

50

52

32

63

92

7. S

ervi

ces

34

13

91

06

01

20

68

93

90

12

23

36

74

73

23

84

03

56

25

70

53

53

01

92

67

29

51

91

83

57

31

99

15

26

98

10

00

01

55

57

73

47

66

51

66

18

06

60

67

10

01

13

23

40

25

9

Co

nsu

mp

tio

n1

. Fo

od

an

d B

ever

ages

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

11

05

20

00

00

00

11

05

20

2. O

ther

Pri

mar

y0

00

00

00

10

53

64

10

60

16

31

14

76

28

12

05

63

10

01

88

52

69

81

00

19

81

90

00

00

01

98

19

3. T

exti

les,

Clo

thin

g &

Fo

otw

ear

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

63

96

10

00

00

06

39

61

4. M

ach

iner

y0

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

08

64

22

00

00

00

86

42

2

5. C

hem

ical

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

23

66

10

00

00

02

36

61

6. O

ther

Man

ufa

ctu

res

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

10

94

57

00

00

00

10

94

57

7. S

ervi

ces

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

59

84

65

00

00

00

59

84

65

Lab

ou

r2

05

60

16

19

94

22

34

93

86

11

65

65

79

73

80

59

22

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

96

59

20

Cap

ital

52

17

29

88

11

21

31

63

83

36

64

43

62

37

70

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

04

09

28

0

Ho

use

ho

lds

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

96

59

20

40

92

80

00

00

00

01

37

52

01

Go

vern

men

t 2

57

42

-78

49

79

04

51

47

96

04

09

57

-58

92

51

55

92

16

84

71

01

41

30

98

92

68

71

48

40

00

00

00

00

17

61

79

Dir

ect

Tax

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

20

62

80

00

00

00

20

62

80

Ind

irec

t ta

x2

53

26

-79

26

66

02

41

36

66

54

04

82

-58

92

51

55

92

16

84

71

01

41

30

98

92

68

71

48

40

00

00

00

00

17

26

03

Tari

ff(T

ota

l)4

16

77

13

02

10

10

29

54

75

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

03

57

6

Tari

ff(E

U)

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

Tari

ff (

RO

W)

41

67

71

30

21

01

02

95

47

50

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

35

76

Cap

ital

(Sa

vin

gs)

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

15

07

99

00

34

79

33

52

28

35

22

80

22

08

21

CF

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

58

17

00

00

00

0

Imp

ort

(To

tal)

38

00

95

30

64

28

64

61

41

10

14

39

84

84

51

69

46

90

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

48

40

11

Imp

ort

(EU

)2

85

46

16

39

38

92

28

93

02

29

22

33

60

32

45

82

90

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

02

54

24

7

Imp

ort

(R

OW

)9

46

43

66

71

19

72

45

18

00

14

76

14

84

84

48

86

10

00

00

00

00

05

81

70

00

00

23

55

81

Tota

l1

59

81

81

19

20

56

63

23

31

92

58

10

41

09

32

63

92

23

40

26

01

10

51

91

98

17

63

96

18

64

22

23

66

11

09

45

75

98

46

59

65

92

04

09

28

01

37

52

01

58

17

22

08

21

38

24

58

48

98

28

25

42

47

23

55

81

0

Figure B.1: Social Accounting Matrix for the UK, 2011

52

Appendix C

A3

Sector EU (%) RoW(%)

Food & Beverages -40.790 -7.868Primary Goods -10.626 -1.841

Textiles, Footwear & Clothing -61.914 -8.969Machinery -36.019 -9.545Chemicals -25.544 -6.861

Other Manufactures -24.924 -1.571Services -0.658 2.955

Table C.1: Effect of Trade War on Exports (σm,i 6= σm,j)

Sector EU (%) RoW(%)

Food & Beverages 0.179 13.165Primary Goods 0.466 4.806

Textiles, Footwear & Clothing 12.866 49.427Machinery 0.376 14.065Chemicals 1.859 8.746

Other Manufactures 0.327 5.327Services -0.0467 -1.061

Table C.2: Effect of an FTA on Exports (σm,i 6= σm,j)

Sector EU (%) RoW(%)

Food & Beverages -16.693 -0.852Primary Goods -18.899 -0.821

Textiles, Footwear & Clothing -75.265 0.723Machinery -19.472 -3.123Chemicals -24.394 -2.496

Other Manufactures -19.967 -2.493Services 0.727 -1.240

Table C.3: Effect of Trade War on Imports (σm,i 6= σm,j)

53

Sector EU (%) RoW(%)

Food & Beverages 0.536 1.588Primary Goods 0.042 1.270

Textiles, Footwear & Clothing -14.963 41.855Machinery 2.967 4.324Chemicals 0.416 12.910

Other Manufactures 0.658 2.494Services -0.135 0.365

Table C.4: Effect of an FTA on Imports (σm,i 6= σm,j)

Sector EU (%) RoW(%)

Food & Beverages -0.628 0.544Primary Goods 1.199 0.333

Textiles, Footwear & Clothing 3.879 -12.765Machinery -3.504 2.994Chemicals -1.789 0.933

Other Manufactures -1.027 0.713Services 0.185 -0.161

Table C.5: Effect on Domestic Production (σm,i 6= σm,j)

54

Appendix D

Bibliography

Armington, P.S. (1969), ‘A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place

of Production’, International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, 16 March, 159-78.

BIS (2012), ‘Benchmarking UK Competitiveness in the Global Economy’, BIS

Economics Paper No. 19, October 2012.

Booth, S. and Howarth, C. (2012), Trading Places: Is EU Membership still the

best option for UK Trade?, Open Europe, London.

Buckle, R. Hewish, T. Hulsman, J.C. Mansfield, I. Oulds, R. (2015), BREXIT:

Direction for Britain Outside of the EU, The Institute of Economic Affairs, Great

Britain.

Cadot, Olivier, Carrere, C. Melo, J. Tumurchudur, B. (2006), ‘Product-Specific

Rules of Origin in EU and US Preferential Trading Arrangements: An Assessment’,

World Trade Review, 5(2), 199-224.

Cho, S. and Diaz, J. (2008), ‘Trade Liberalization in Latin America and Eastern

Europe: the Cases of Ecuador and Slovenia’, Journal of Economic Integration, 23(4),

1002-1045.

Cho, S. and Diaz, J. (2011), ‘The Welfare Impact of Trade Liberalization’, Economic

Inquiry, 49(2), 379-397.

Cho, S. and Yoon, G. (2013), ‘Sectoral Analysis of an Australia-India Free Trade

Agreement’, Journal of the Asia-Pacific Economy, 19(2), 205-229.

Cox, D. and Harris, R. (1985), ‘Trade Liberalization and Industrial Organization:

Some Estimates for Canada’, Journal of Political Economy, 93, 115-45.

The Data Team (2015), ‘In Graphics: Britain’s referendum on EU Membership:

A Background guide to “Brexit” from the European Union’, The Economist, 19

55

October.

Fernekess, K. Paleviciene, S. and Thadikkaran, M. (2014), ‘The Future of the United

Kingdom in Europe: Exit Scenarios and their Implications on Trade Relations’,

Research Paper, The Graduate Institute Geneva.

Fourie, J. and Von Fintel, D. (2009), ‘World Rankings of Comparative Advantage

in Service Exports’, Stellenbosch Economic Working Papers: 03/09.

Hanson, G.H. (2012), ‘The Rise of Middle Kingdoms: Emerging Economies in Global

Trade’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(2), 41-64.

Harberger, A. (1962), ‘The Incidence of the Corporate Income Tax’, Journal of

Political Economy, 70(3), 215-40.

Hindley, B. and Howe, M. (2001), Better Off Out? The Benefits or Costs of EU

Membership, Rev. edn, The Institute of Economic Affairs, Great Britain.

House of Commons (2013), ‘Leaving the EU’, Research Paper 13/42, 1 July 2013.

International Monetary Fund (2005), Direction of Trade Statistics, IMF, Washing-

ton, D.C.

International Monetary Fund (2005), International Financial Statistics, IMF,

Washington, D.C. Johansen, L. (1960), ‘A Multi-sectoral Study of Economic

Growth’, Amsterdam: North Holland.

Johnson, H.G. (1954), ‘Optimal Tariffs and Retaliation’, Review of Economic

Studies, 21, 142-153.

Jorgenson, D. (1984), ‘Econometric Methods for Applied General Equilibrium

Analysis’, in Scarf, Herbert, E. and Shoven, John B. (eds.) Applied General

Equilibrium Analysis, New York, Cambridge University Press.

Kehoe, T. (n.d.), ‘Constructing a Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) for Ecuador

2001’, http://www.econ.umn.edu/~tkehoe/classes/ConstructSAM(eng).pdf, Ac-

cessed 2015-04-18.

Kehoe, T. (1996), ‘Social Accounting Matrices and Applied General Equilibrium

56

Models’, Working Papers 563, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

Kehoe, T. (2003), ‘An Evaluation of the Performance of Applied General Equi-

librium Models of the Impact of NAFTA’, Staff Report 320, Federal Reserve Bank

of Minneapolis.

Kehoe, P. and Kehoe, T. (1994a), ‘A Primer on Static Applied General Equilibrium

Models’, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 18(1), 2-16.

Kehoe, P. and Kehoe, T. (1994b), ‘Capturing NAFTA’s Impact with Applied

General Equilibrium Models’, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly

Review, 18(1), 17-34.

Kehoe, P. and Kehoe, T. (eds) (1995), Modelling North American Economic

Integration, Boston: Kluwar Academic Publishers. Kehoe, T. and Prescott,

E. (1995), ‘Introduction to the Symposium: The Discipline of Applied General

Equilibrium’, Economic Theory, 6(1), 1-11.

Leontief, W.W. (1941), The Structure of the American Economy, 1919-1929:

An empirical application of Equilibrium Analysis, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard

University Press.

Mansur, A. and Whalley, J. (1981), ‘Numerical Specification of Applied General

Equilibrium Models: Estimation, Calibration, and Data’, Centre for the Study of

International Economic Relations Working Papers, 8106C, University of Western

Ontario, London.

Martins, J.O. Scarpetta, S. and Pilat, D. (1996), ‘Mark-Up Ratios in Manufacturing

Industries: Estimates for 14 OECD Countries’, Economics Department Working

Papers No. 162.

Milne, I. (2004), A Cost Too Far? An Analysis of the Net Economic Costs & Benefits

for the UK of EU Membership, The Institute for the Study of Civil Society, London.

Ottaviano, G. Pessoa, J.P. Sampson, T. and Van Reenen, J. (2014), ‘The Costs

and Benefits of Leaving the EU’, CEP Mimeo.

Pain, N. and Young, G. (2004), ‘The Macroeconomic Impact of UK Withdrawal

from the EU’, Economic Modeling, 21(3), 387-408.

57

Rolleigh, M. (2003), ‘Plant Heterogeneity and Applied General Equilibrium Models

of Trade: Lessons from the Canada-US Free Trade Agreement’, Mimeo, University

of Minnesota.

Rutherford, T.F. Rutstrom, E.E. and Tarr, D. (1993), ‘Morocco’s Free Trade

Agreement with the European Community: A Quantitative Assessment, The World

Bank.

Scarf, H.E. (1967), ‘On the Composition of Equilibrium Prices’, Ten Economic

Studies in the Tradition of Irving Fisher, 207-30.

Scarf, H.E. and Hansen, T. (1973), The Computation of Economic Equilibria, New

Haven: Yale University Press.

Shoven, J. and Whalley, J. (1984), ‘Applied General-Equilibrium Models of Taxation

and International Trade: An Introduction and Survey’, Journal of Economic

Literature, 22, 1007-1051.

Shoven, J. and Whalley, J. (1992), ‘Applying General Equilibrium’, Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press.

Sobarzo, H. (1992), ‘A General Equilibrium Analysis of the Gains from Trade for

the Mexican Economy of a North American Free Trade Agreement’, The World

Economy, 15(1), 83-100.

Springford, J. Tilford, S. and Whyte, P. (2014), ‘The Economic Consequences of

Leaving the EU: The Final Report of the CER Commission on the UK and the EU

Single Market’, Centre for European Reform, June 2014. Stanley, L.W. (2015), ‘A

Case for “the Open Sea”: How EU Membership Constrains Britain’s Free Trade

Potential’, Get Britain Out.

Timmer, M.P. Dietzenbacher, E. Los, B. Stehrer, R. and de Vries, G.J. (2015), ‘An

Illustrated User Guide to the World Input-Output Database: the Case of Global

Automotive Production’, Review of International Economics, 23, 575-605.

Whalley, J. (1982), ‘An Evaluation of the Tokyo Round Trade Agreement Using

General Equilibrium Computational Methods’, Journal of Policy Modeling, 4(3),

341-361.

58