unit 2: microeconomics: understanding the canadian market economy

89
Unit 2: Microeconomics: Understanding the Canadian Market Economy Chapter 4: Demand and Supply Chapter 5: Applications of Demand and Supply Chapter 6: Business Organization and Finance Chapter 7: Production, Firms, and the Market Chapter 8: Resource Economics: The Case of Labour Economics

Upload: dusty

Post on 25-Feb-2016

44 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Unit 2: Microeconomics: Understanding the Canadian Market Economy. Chapter 4: Demand and Supply Chapter 5: Applications of Demand and Supply Chapter 6: Business Organization and Finance Chapter 7: Production, Firms, and the Market Chapter 8: Resource Economics: The Case of Labour Economics. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Unit 2: Microeconomics: Understanding the Canadian

Market EconomyChapter 4: Demand and Supply

Chapter 5: Applications of Demand and SupplyChapter 6: Business Organization and FinanceChapter 7: Production, Firms, and the Market

Chapter 8: Resource Economics: The Case of Labour Economics

Page 2: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Chapter 5: Applications of Demand and Supply

• Overview• Elasticity of demand• The total revenue approach to elasticity• Factors affecting demand elasticity

• Elasticity of supply• Factors affecting supply elasticity

• Utility Theory• Government intervention in markets

Page 3: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Introduction

• This chapter deals with the practical application of the demand and supply concepts discussed in Chapter 4

• The ways businesses and governments can use these concepts as a guide in making sound economic judgments

Page 4: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Demand• Elasticity is the responsiveness of quantities

demanded and supplied to changes in price• In Chapter 4, we learned that consumers buy

more of a product when its price falls and less of it when its prices rises• What we did not learn is how much more they

will buy or how much less• Economists have developed a formula to measure

the actual change in quantity demanded for a product whose price has changed

Page 5: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Demand

• The effect of the change is in the numerator (people buying more or less) while the cause is in the denominator (the change in price that affects people’s buying decisions)

Page 6: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Demand: Gas Station Example

• Suppose a large gas station sells 10 million liters of gasoline a month at a price of $0.50 per liter

• If the station’s owners raise their price to $0.54 per liter, the quantity demanded by the station’s customers falls to 9.5 million liters

Page 7: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Demand: Gas Station Example

• First, let’s calculate the percent change in price• Between the original price of $0.50 and the

new price of $0.54, the change is $0.04• Which of these percentages should we use in

our calculations? We should compromise by using the average price, which is $0.52

• This figure of 7.69 percent will serve as the denominator of our equation

Page 8: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Demand: Gas Station Example

• To determine the percent change in quantity demanded, we use the average between the original of liters sold and the quantity after the price change• Since the quantity demanded fell from 10 to 9.5

million liters, the average quantity demanded is 9.75 million liters.

• The change in quantity is -0.5 million liters. Therefore, the percent change in quantity demanded is:

Page 9: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Demand: Gas Station Example

• This figure of 5.13 percent will serve as the numerator of our equation

• The value of ∆Qd is negative because the quantity demanded falls• We ignore the negative sign because we are

interested in the amount of change, not the direction

• We can now use the general formula to determine the coefficient of demand

Page 10: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Demand: Gas Station Example

• Any coefficient between 0 and 1 is called an inelastic coefficient

• This is because a given percent change in price causes a smaller percent change in quantity demanded• A 7.69 percent change in price causes a 5.13

percent change in quantity demanded

Page 11: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Demand: Gas Station Example

• Staying with our gasoline example, we find there is a different coefficient for a different set of prices and quantities demanded

• This is the case even if the change in price ($0.04) and the change in quantity demanded (0.5 million liters) are the same• Copy Figure 5.1 into your notes

Page 12: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Price per Litre of Gasoline

Quantity Demanded (million litres)

Coefficient of Demand

$0.50 10.00.67

$0.54 9.5$0.58 9.0$0.62 8.5$0.66 8.0

1.1$0.70 7.5$0.74 7.0$0.78 6.5$0.82 6.0

Table 5.1: The changing market for gasoline

Page 13: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Demand: Gas Station Example

• Between $0.66 and $0.70, we find the percent change in price is 5.88 per cent

• We calculate the percent change in quantity demanded as 6.45 percent

• The coefficient therefore is 1.1

Page 14: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Demand: Gas Station Example

• Note here that any coefficient greater than 1 is called an elastic coefficient

• A given percent change in price causes a greater percent change in quantity demanded• A 5.88 percent change in price causes a 6.45

percent change in quantity demanded

• A coefficient that is equal to 1 is called a unitary coefficient because a given percent change in price causes an equal change in quantity demanded

Page 15: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

The Total Revenue Approach to Elasticity

• It’s extremely useful for economics and business people to know whether total revenues will rise or fall when prices rise or fall

• Will a rise in price mean increased revenues of our gas station owner in spite of the fall in quantity demanded?• If the elasticity coefficient is inelastic, then the

answer is yes• Let’s refer consider whether total revenues rise

when owners hike the price per liter of gas from $0.50 to $0.54

Page 16: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

The Total Revenue Approach to Elasticity

• At the original price of $0.50 per liter, the owners sell 10 million liters of gas• Total revenue is 10 million liters X $0.50 = $5 million

• At $0.54, revenues are 9.5 million liters X $0.54 = $5.13 million

• As always happens with an inelastic demand coefficient, when the price of gasoline rises, the quantity demanded falls at a lower rate (5.13 percent) than the rate at which price rises (7.69 percent)• Although people buy less gasoline at the higher price, this

potential loss of revenue is compensated for by the greater percent increase in price

Page 17: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

The Total Revenue Approach to Elasticity

• If the price falls again to $0.50, revenues will fall• Though people buy more gas at the lower price, this

potential revenue increase is offset by the greater percent decrease in price

• This changes when the coefficient is elastic• When prices rise from $0.66 to $0.70 per liter,

revenues fall from $5.28 million to $5.25 million• The percent rise in price (5.88 percent), with its

potential to raise revenues, is undercut by an even greater percent fall in quantity demanded (6.45 percent)

Page 18: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

The Total Revenue Approach to Elasticity

• When price falls with an elastic coefficient, total revenues will rise• The percent decrease in price is less than the

percent increase in quantity of gasoline purchased

• When the coefficient is unitary, total revenues are not affected by an increase or decrease in price• The percent increases or decreases in price and

quantity demanded are the same

Page 19: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

In Summary

• Goods with inelastic demand coefficients:• When price rises, total revenues rise• When price falls, total revenues fall

• Goods with elastic demand coefficients:• When price rises, total revenues fall• When price falls, total revenues rise

• Goods with unitary demand coefficients:• When price rises or falls, total revenues stay the

same

Page 20: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Factors Affecting Demand Elasticity

• Availability of substitutes• Goods that have substitutes tend to be more

elastic than goods that do not

Page 21: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Factors Affecting Demand Elasticity

• Nature of the item• Goods that are necessities tend to be more

inelastic than goods that are considered luxuries

• A necessity such as bread is inelastic. Price changes do not significantly change the quantities consumers purchase

• A luxury such as a vacation cruise will be quite elastic because if prices rise, people can do without this kind of vacation

Page 22: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Factors Affecting Demand Elasticity

• Fraction of income spent on the item• Goods that are expensive and take up a large

part of the household budget will be elastic• If prices rise for big ticket items like houses, cars,

or furniture, people either do without the item entirely, postpone the purchase, or search for substitutes

• An item that takes up a smaller percentage of the budget (ex: shoelaces) is inelastic and may rise in price without registering a significant decline in the amount purchased

Page 23: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Factors Affecting Demand Elasticity

• Amount of time available• Over time, some goods may become more

elastic because consumers eventually find substitutes for them

• In the short term, however, demand for these goods can be quite inelastic because consumers may not know what substitutes are available immediately after the price rises

Page 24: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Supply

• As market prices rise, suppliers want to supply more so their profits will increase

• Can a supplier increase output as easily as consumers decrease demand, or is it more difficult to increase quantity supplied to take advantage of higher prices?

• Elasticity of supply measures how responsive the quantity supplied by a seller is to a rise or fall in price

Page 25: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Supply

• The formula to determine the coefficient of supply is:

Page 26: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Supply: Steel Manufacturer Example

• Suppose the market price of steel rises from $120 per tonne to $140

• Wishing to take advantage of the higher price, the manufacturer expands production immediately from 1 million tones a day to 1.2 million tones

• What will the coefficient of supply be?

Page 27: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Supply: Steel Manufacturer Example

• First, we calculate the percent change in price• Just with demand elasticities, we have to find

the average of the two prices, which in the case of the steel manufacturer is $130 per tonne

• The change in price is $20, thus the percent change is:

Page 28: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Supply: Steel Manufacturer Example

• We must also find the average of the two figures for quantity supplied, which is 1.1 million tonnes

• The change in quantity supplied is 0.2, thus the percent change is:

• Using the supply elasticity formula, we can now calculate the coefficient of supply:

Page 29: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Supply: Steel Manufacturer Example

• The same rules apply to supply coefficients as to demand coefficients

• Any supply coefficient less than one is classified as inelastic, equal to one is unitary, and more than one is elastic

Page 30: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Supply: Steel Manufacturer Example

• The steel manufacturer’s ability to increase production supply is elastic within this price range• This means that when price increases by a certain

percentage (15.38 percent in this case), the manufacturer is able to increase quantity supplied at an even greater rate (18.18 percent)

• A seller with an elastic supply is better positioned to take advantage of an increase in demand for the product• Quantity supplied can easily and quickly be increased

to meet demand, resulting in an increase in revenues

Page 31: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Elasticity of Supply: Steel Manufacturer Example

• A price range that has inelastic supply has a supply coefficient of less than one• The seller can’t increase the quantity supplied

by a greater percentage than the percent increase in price

• A price range that has a unitary supply elasticity has a coefficient equal to one• The seller is just able to match a price increase

by the same percentage increase in quantity supplied

Page 32: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Factors Affecting Supply Elasticity

• Time• The longer the time period a seller has to

increase production, the more elastic the supply will be

• In the short term supply is inelastic, and in the long term it is elastic

Page 33: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Factors Affecting Supply Elasticity

• Ease of storage• When the price of a product drops, sellers

have 2 choices:• They can sell the product at the new lower price• They can put some of their inventory into storage

and sell it after the price rises again

Page 34: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Factors Affecting Supply Elasticity

• Cost factors• Increasing supply may be costly depending on

the industry• Manufacturers may be able to increase

production in the short term by requiring workers to put in more overtime

• A permanent increase in production, however, may entail building new factories, which is a far more costly move on the part of the manufacturer

• Supply is more elastic in industries that have lower input expenses

Page 35: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Making Consumption Choices: Utility Theory

• In Chapter 4, we saw how a market demand curve is the sum of the many individual demand curves of the consumers who buy a particular product

• But what factors determine the demand for the products that each of us buys?

• Is there a rational way of explaining the decisions we make about buying and consuming?

• Alfred Marshall “the father of supply and demand”put forth the theory known as the marginal utility theory of consumer choice, or utility theory for short

Page 36: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Making Consumption Choices: Utility Theory

• Lisa has the choice of buying either a veggie burger or frozen yoghurt• What factors might influence Lisa in making her choice?

• First she would probably consider how many veggie burgers she’s had lately• If she has had several, she would gain little extra

satisfaction from consuming another• The economic term for “satisfaction” or “usefulness” is

utility• The economic term for extra is marginal• So the marginal utility Lisa would receive from yet

another veggie burger is low

Page 37: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Making Consumption Choices: Utility Theory

• However if she has bought little frozen yoghurt in the past week, the extra satisfaction she would gain from buying more yoghurt would be higher

• Since the marginal utility of buying more yoghurt is greater for Lisa than the marginal utility of eating another veggie burger, Lisa would most likely buy the yoghurt

Page 38: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Making Consumption Choices: Utility Theory

• Suppose, however, that Lisa wanted both veggie burgers and frozen yoghurt

• We assume that, like most consumers, she wants to maximize her satisfaction, or utility, for the income she has available to spend on these items• Suppose she has $10 to spend this week on these

two items• The burgers cost $2 and the frozen yoghurt costs $1• How should she determine how much of each she

should buy?

Page 39: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Veggie Burgers

Total Utility

Marginal Utility

Frozen Yoghurt

Total Utility

Marginal Utility

1 10 10 1 11 112 18 8 2 18 73 24 6 3 22 44 28 4 4 25 35 30 2 5 26 1

Table 5.10: Lisa’s monthly consumption of veggie burgers and frozen yoghurt

Page 40: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Making Consumption Choices: Utility Theory

• It arbitrarily assigns numerical values called utils, or units of satisfaction to the burgers and yoghurt

• We see that the utility Lisa receives from consuming one veggie burger or one frozen yoghurt is high• Total utility is 10 utils for one burger and 11

utils for one frozen yoghurt

Page 41: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Making Consumption Choices: Utility Theory

• For the first unit of the item in question, the marginal utility is always the same as total utility• Lisa is gaining 10 utils of extra satisfaction by consuming one veggie

burger instead of none and similarly, 11 utils of extra satisfaction by consuming one frozen yoghurt instead of none

• If Lisa buys a second veggie burger or a second frozen yoghurt, the extra satisfaction she experiences drops slightly to 8 utils for the second burger and 7 for the second frozen yoghurt• Her total satisfaction is now 18 utils for two veggie burgers and also 18

utils for the two frozen yoghurts – a total of 36 utils

• We see the same pattern for the third and fourth veggie burger or frozen yoghurt: marginal utility steadily falls as Lisa consumes one more of either product• Total utility continues to rise as more is consumed, but not as quickly

Page 42: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy
Page 43: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Making Consumption Choices: Utility Theory

• If Lisa’s budget were unlimited, she could maximize her utility by consuming 5 veggie burgers and 5 frozen yoghurts• This would cost her (5 X $2) + (5 X $1) = $15• This combination produces 30 + 26 = 56 utils,

which is the highest total utility achievable (as shown in Table 5.10)

Page 44: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Making Consumption Choices: Utility Theory

• Since she has limited herself to $10, Lisa must find another combination that will yield her the highest satisfaction, or total utility possible

• Which combination of veggie burgers and frozen yoghurt will give her the most satisfaction?

• The formula that yields the answer is the utility maximization formula:• MU = marginal utility• MU/price signifies the amount of satisfaction

received per dollar

Page 45: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Veggie Burgers

Marginal Utility

MUPrice

Frozen Yoghurt

Marginal Utility

MUPrice

1 10 5 1 11 112 8 4 2 18 73 6 3 3 22 44 4 2 4 25 35 2 1 5 26 1

Table 5.12: Lisa’s marginal utility/price of veggie burgers and frozen yoghurt

Page 46: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Making Consumption Choices: Utility Theory

• We can now determine Lisa’s best combination for maximizing her satisfaction• She can do so by purchasing 3 veggie burgers and 4 frozen yoghurts

because, at these positions, the MU/price is equal for both items

• Since Lisa is receiving the same amount of satisfaction per dollar for each item, she has no reason to buy more of one and less of the other• An economist would say she is in a condition of consumer equilibrium

• She has spent 3 X $2 = $6 on veggie burgers and 4 X $1 on frozen yoghurt for a total of $10• More importantly, she has maximized her total utility by amassing 49

utils• No other combination will give her more total utils within her $10 budget

Page 47: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Applications of Utility Theory

• The Demand Curve• Recall from Chapter 4 that the demand curve

slopes downward from top left to bottom right• Consumers will buy more only if price falls

• The theory of marginal utility supports this• People consume more, the extra satisfaction they

receive declines• If people receive less satisfaction as they

consume more of a product, they will want to pay less for that product the more they buy it

Page 48: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Application of Utility Theory

• Adam Smith’s paradox• Smith wrestled with an economic problem he was

never able to solve, one he called the paradox of value

• Why, he wondered, are diamonds more costly than water, when water is essential to human life and diamonds are not?

• Smith could not understand why the demand for a necessity should not be high enough to assure the price is as high as the price for luxury items

• This paradox remained unsolved until the development of utility theory

Page 49: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Application of Utility Theory

• The key to unlocking the paradox lies in the difference between the total and marginal utility for water and diamonds• Water has greater total utility than diamonds• Diamonds are scarce compare to water• Satisfaction received from a diamond is extremely high

• The marginal utility buyers receive from purchasing a diamond means they are willing to pay a high price for something that has little total utility

• In comparison, the very abundance of water means that most people can consume so much of it that its marginal utility is pushed very low

Page 50: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Application of Utility Theory

• Consumer Surplus• If we examine the concept of marginal utility

closely enough, we come to a surprising conclusion: we get a bargain on everything we buy!• Economists call this result a consumer surplus

• Let’s suppose we asked Lisa how many cases of bottled water she would buy at different prices

Page 51: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Price Number of Cases of Water

Consumer Surplus

$9 1 $9 - $6 = $3$8 2 $8 - $6 = $2$7 3 $7 - $6 = $1$6 4 $6 - $6 = $0

Table 5.13: Lisa’s consumer surplus for bottled water

Page 52: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Application of Utility Theory

• Lisa would buy only 1 case if the price per case was $9• However, if after consuming this 1 case the price

dropped to $8, she would buy another• A total of 2 cases in one month and a total cost of $17

• Lisa would continue to buy 1 more case of water each time the price fell further until, when the price reached $6, she would have bought 4 cases

• This is a perfect illustration of marginal utility because it demonstrates that Lisa would buy more cases of water only if the price fell

Page 53: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Application of Utility Theory

• The sellers of bottled water do not drop their prices throughout the month to encourage Lisa to buy more of their product• They charge a constant price, say $6 a case• Lisa actually receives a surplus for the first 3

cases of bottled water she buys• This surplus is calculated by subtracting the

amount she would have paid for each case of water from the amount she actually paid

Page 54: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy
Page 55: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Government Intervention in Markets

• The market engines of demand and supply automatically produce the vast range of goods and services that consumers want and then distribute these goods and services with a minimum of waste or shortages

• All this is done without the benefit of any individual or group providing direction for the economy

• Governments do intervene extensively in the market• Why do they do this?• Are they threatening the “magic of the market” by

intervening?

Page 56: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Government Intervention in Markets

• Three examples of controversial government actions:• If the government believes the people are paying

too much for an item, it will introduce a ceiling price

• If the government believes sellers are receiving too little for a product, it will introduce a floor price

• If the government believes it must intervene in a market for social or environmental reasons, it will introduce a subsidy or a quota as a solution

Page 57: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Ceiling Prices

• A ceiling price is a restriction placed by a government in order to prevent the price of a product from rising above a certain level• If the ceiling price is set below the equilibrium

price, a shortage will result

Page 58: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy
Page 59: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Ceiling Prices• Suppose an international crisis has interfered with oil

supplies and prices start to climb• The government, concerned by the hardship these price

increases have caused for motorists, places a price ceiling (PC) on gasoline

• The equilibrium price was $0.65 per litre, with 100 million litres per month demanded and supplied

• The price ceiling prohibits prices from rising above $0.60 per litre• At this price, 110 million litres (QD1) are demanded, and 90 million

litres (QS1) are supplied• This creates a shortage of QD1 – QS1 = 20 million litres

Page 60: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Ceiling Prices• There are three possible outcomes of price ceilings:• First, the shortages can cause long lineups for the product• Second, price ceilings may create a black market for certain

goods• A shortage of a product encourages some people to buy up as

much of it as they can at the ceiling price, stockpile it, and then sell it at a higher price to people who can’t get enough for their own use

• Third, price ceilings may cause the quality of a product to suffer if sellers try to reduce their costs in order to make more money• This is less likely to occur with natural resource products, but it

occurs more frequently for products like rental accommodations

Page 61: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Floor Prices

• A floor price is a restriction that prevents a price from falling below a certain level• If the floor price is set above equilibrium price,

it will cause a surplus

Page 62: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy
Page 63: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Floor Prices• Suppose the government believes that milk producers

are making too little profit on milk, priced at $0.50 a litre

• The government may set a floor price of $0.60 per litre, below which prices are not allowed to fall

• The line PF is the floor price of $0.60 per litre• At that price, 10 million litres will be supplied• The higher floor price cuts the quantity demanded to 8

million litres• The result, QS1 – QD1, is a surplus of 2 million litres of

milk

Page 64: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Floor Prices• Maintaining the floor price causes two problems:• First, there is the problem of what to do with the surplus• In order to keep the floor price at $0.60 per litre, the

government must buy the surplus of milk (using taxpayers’ money)• Little chance that the surplus will generate a return• Cannot be sold within the country at prices below the floor price

without undercutting the floor price• Surpluses can be sold on the world market or donated to

less developed countries• Since milk is perishable, it is turned into products that can

be stored, such as powdered milk, butter, and cheese

Page 65: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Floor Prices

• Second, consumers pay a higher price for the product and receive less• Consumers in an unregulated market would

probably have paid the equilibrium price of $0.50 per litre and would have received 9 million litres of milk

• With the floor price set by the government, they pay $0.60 per litre ($0.10 more) and receive 8 million litres (1 million litres less)

Page 66: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Subsidies and Quotas

Subsidies• Both price ceilings and price floors share a

common problem:• Less of the product is actually transacted between

sellers and buyers when these policies force the price away from its equilibrium price

• In order to avoid this problem, governments sometime enact subsidies• A subsidy is a grant of money to a particular

industry by the government

Page 67: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy
Page 68: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Subsidies

• Figure 5.18 shows how the milk market will be affected by a subsidy of $ 0.10 per litre• The supply line increases by the amount of the

subsidy since producers turn out more milk because they are receiving an extra $0.10 per litre

• The new equilibrium price of $0.45 is lower than the old equilibrium price of $0.50, and the quantity sold is increased by 3 million litres (from Q1 to Q2)

Page 69: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Subsidies• A subsidy has the advantage of benefiting buyers

with lower prices and sellers with extra revenue• More of the product is exchanged between buyers

and sellers with extra revenue

• A subsidy has a couple of drawbacks:• The taxpayer pays for the program• Some critics charge that subsidies keep inefficient

producers in business• In the global economy, subsidies are often seen as a

barrier to fair trade

Page 70: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Subsidies and Quotas

Quotas• A quota is a restriction placed on the

amount of a product that individual producers are allowed to produce

• Administered by organizations called marketing boards composed of representatives from the government and from the producers

Page 71: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy
Page 72: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Quotas

• Figure 5.19 illustrates what happens when a provincial marketing board enforces a reduced quota on all milk producers in the province• S2 shows the shift in supply to the left• P2 is the new, higher price, and Q2 is the new,

smaller amount of milk that is actually sold

Page 73: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Quotas• Quotas set by marketing boards raise farmers’ incomes

mainly because food is an inelastic commodity• When prices rise on an inelastic product, sales revenue also

rises because quantity demanded does not fall by much

• Farmers were given the authority to establish marketing boards years ago because governments believed that their incomes were, on average, very low

• Farmers are producing an essential commodity, and if too many of them go out of business, Canadians will wind up paying more for their food

Page 74: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Quotas

• Critics claim that marketing boards raise prices above equilibrium, with the result that less of the product is actually produced and exchanged

• The fact remains that most of the Canadian meat, vegetables, and dairy products we buy in supermarkets are sold to the stores by marketing boards

Page 75: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Rent Controls

• A rent-control program is a good example of a price ceiling• Most Canadian provinces and many American

states have enacted such programs, and the controversy that surrounds them never seems to end

• Rent is the price people pay for accommodation• Like any other market price, it is determined by

demand and supply

Page 76: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy
Page 77: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Rent Controls• Figure 5.20a shows the rent the market sets for

the quantity of apartments demanded and supplied in a particular building

• At $500 for a one-bedroom apartment, the owner will supply 50 apartments

• The supply line is vertical because the owner can’t increase supply immediately• That would involve building more units• The supply of apartments is fixed, or perfectly

inelastic, in the short term

Page 78: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Rent Controls• Suppose an increase in renters occurs, shifting

demand upwards• This encourages the owner to raise rents to $600 a

month

• This increase has 2 effects:• Those who can afford the higher rent will stay and pay• Those who can’t will have to find less expensive

accommodation elsewhere

• Higher rents mean more profits for the owner, who is therefore encouraged to build more units

Page 79: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy
Page 80: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Rent Controls• Figure 5.20b illustrates the effect of this long-

term decision to construct another apartment building• The supply curve shifts to the right

• This long-run supply curve, with greater elasticity, also has beneficial effects for renters• The supply of apartments is increased, and the

rental price, at least in theory, falls to $550• This is how a free rental market works, and both

renters and apartment owners appear to win in the long run

Page 81: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Rent Controls• Suppose that in response to the increase in

demand that caused rents to rise to $600 in the short term, the government comes under pressure to alleviate the economic hardship renters are experiencing

• The government introduces a rent-control program: a law that freezes, reduces, or controls the amount of rent that owners can charge• We’ll assume that a freeze on rent for one-bedroom

apartments will be fixed at $500

Page 82: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy
Page 83: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Rent Controls• Figure 5.21 shows that if demand continues to rise to

D2, there will be a shortage of supply of 10 units• If this kind of shortage is occurs in buildings everywhere,

people will have difficulty finding essential accommodation• People looking for an apartment will be tempted to offer

building owners more money “under the table” in hopes of beating others to a vacancy

• Owners, with no incentive to keep buildings in good repair to attract new tenants, may stop making essential repairs and renovations• With rental prices fixed, they will also be disinclined to build

more units

Page 84: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Rent Controls

• While many people wonder whether rent controls are worth these costs

• However, without rent control owners are able to raise rent prices to whatever they can get and hold bidding wars between interested tenants

Page 85: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Minimum Wages• Governments also intervene

to establish floor prices when they believe the price sellers are receiving is too low

• A wage is the price a worker receives for supplying labour to a business with a demand for it

• Figure 5.22a shows that 100,000 workers are receiving wages of $5 an hour

Page 86: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy
Page 87: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Minimum Wages• Suppose the government responds to public pressure to raise

the low wages of these workers by setting a minimum wage• A wage that is higher than the one set by the forces of demand

and supply

• Figure 5.22b shows the results of the government’s efforts• The minimum wage is set at $6 an hour• Businesses adjust to this by employing only 70,000 workers• The higher wage rate attracts an additional 30,000 workers into

the labour market• This is a total of 130,000 workers who are willing to work

• This means the minimum wage has created an unemployment problem 60,000 workers who can’t find jobs

Page 88: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy
Page 89: Unit 2: Microeconomics:  Understanding the Canadian Market Economy

Minimum Wages

• Floor prices tend to create surpluses• Minimum wages create surpluses of potential

workers who cannot find jobs

• The minimum wage also increases the wages of thousands of people at the low end of the wage scale• These people receive a more substantial

paycheque than they would have if wages had been set solely by supply and demand