towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability

34
¡Abre los ojos, pueblo americano! ORGANIZAN: UC – CIFF – IELAT DOCUMENTOS DE TRABAJO UC-CIFF-IELAT Nº 13 Junio 2013 Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability Guido Zack, Pilar Poncela, Eva Senra y Daniel Sotelsek

Upload: daniel-sotelsek

Post on 11-Aug-2015

106 views

Category:

Economy & Finance


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

¡Abre los ojos, pueblo americano!

OR

GA

NIZ

AN

: U

C –

CIF

F –

IE

LAT

DOCUMENTOS DE TRABAJO UC-CIFF-IELAT Nº 13

Junio 2013

Towards an effective structural budget balance for

economic stability

Guido Zack,

Pilar Poncela,

Eva Senra y

Daniel Sotelsek

Towards an effective structural budget balance for

economic stability

Guido Zack, Pilar Poncela, Eva Senra y Daniel Sotelsek

Estos documentos de trabajo de UC-CIFF-

IELAT están pensados para que tengan la

mayor difusión posible y que, de esa forma,

contribuyan al conocimiento y al intercambio

de ideas. Se autoriza, por tanto, su

reproducción, siempre que se cite la fuente y

se realice sin ánimo de lucro. Los trabajos son

responsabilidad de los autores y su contenido

no representa necesariamente la opinión de

UC-CIFF-IELAT. Están disponibles en las

siguientes direcciones:

http://www.ielat.es/

http://www.ciff.net/

http://www.unican.es/

Centro Internacional de Formación Financiera (CIFF)

Universidad de Alcalá

Plaza de Cervantes, Nº 10

28801 Alcalá de Henares – Madrid

Secretario de redacción:

Guido Zack

Equipo de edición:

Daniel Díaz Fuentes

Pedro Pérez Herrero

Santiago Ramón Torres

Guido Zack

Consultar normas de edición en el siguiente enlace:

http://www.ielat.es/inicio/repositorio/Normas%20

Working%20Paper.pdf

DERECHOS RESERVADOS CONFORME A LA LEY

Impreso y hecho en España

Printed and made in Spain

ISSN: 2174-5501

Consejo Editorial

Diego Azqueta Oyarzún - Universidad de Alcalá

Judith Clifton – Universidad de Cantabria

Belen Díaz Díaz – Universidad de Cantabria

Rubén Garrido Yserte - Universidad de Alcalá

Renaldo Antonio Gonsalves - Pontifícia Universidade

Católica de São Paulo

Pablo Gerchunoff - Universidad Torcuato Di Tella

Maria Alejandra Irigoin – London School of

Economics and Political Science

Alejandro Izquierdo – Banco Interamericano de

Desarrollo

Erika Kraemer Mbula – University of Brighton -

University of Technology

Pilar L´Hotellerie Fallois - Banco de España

José Luis Machinea – Universidad Torcuato Di Tella

Carlos Marichal - El Colegio de México

José Juan Ruiz – Banco Interamericanos de

Desarrollo

Federico Steinberg - Real Instituto Elcano

Daniel Sotelsek – Universidad de Alcalá

Ernesto Talvi - Centro de Estudios de la Realidad

Económica y Social

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 1

Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic

stability Guido Zack

I

Pilar PoncelaII

Eva SenraIII

Daniel SotelsekIV

Abstract

The recession that started in 2008 caused a sharp deterioration of the budget balance

of many developed countries, not only as a result of discretionary policies but also due

to the loss of revenue caused by the decline in gross domestic product. The latter

effect should have been captured by the cyclically adjusted budget balance, but certain

methodological limitations prevented this from occurring. Consequently, in this article

we raise the need to include asset revaluation in the calculation of the cyclically

adjusted budget balance. To do this, we estimate a structural budget balance for Spain

in the years prior to the sub-prime crisis that includes residential investment as an

explanatory variable. This estimate shows that by 2004 the fiscal situation in Spain was

already tenuous, but this fragility was hidden by the extraordinary revenue from the

real estate bubble.

Keywords

Crisis, structural budget balance, real estate bubble, Spain. Resumen

La recesión iniciada en 2008 generó un fuerte deterioro del resultado fiscal de muchos

países desarrollados, no solo por las políticas discrecionales, sino también por los

menores ingresos como consecuencia de la caída del producto bruto interno. Este

último efecto debería haber sido captado por el resultado fiscal cíclicamente ajustado,

pero ciertas limitaciones metodológicas lo impidieron. Es por ello que en este artículo

se plantea la necesidad de introducir la revalorización de activos en su cálculo. Al

respecto, se desarrolla una estimación del resultado fiscal estructural de España en los

años previos a la crisis sub-prime que incluye como variable explicativa la inversión en

vivienda. Esta estimación muestra que la situación fiscal de España era frágil desde

2004, pero que la fragilidad estuvo oculta gracias a los recursos extraordinarios

resultantes de la burbuja inmobiliaria.

Palabras clave

Crisis, resultado fiscal estructural, burbuja inmobiliaria, España.

I PhD Candidate, U. Alcalá. [email protected]

II Department of Economic Analysis: Quantitative Economy, U. Autónoma de Madrid.

[email protected] III

Department of Economics, U. de Alcalá. [email protected] IV

Department of Economics, U. de Alcalá. [email protected]

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 2

1. Introduction

Usually, total or primary budget balance is consulted when the fiscal situation of a

given country needs to be determined. These indicators can be useful for a preliminary

calculation, but they have the drawback of reflecting circumstantial, volatile revenues

and expenditures that are the product of a particular phase in the economic cycle. In

order to determine the long-term fiscal situation, these cyclical components must be

separated from other government transactions.

In order to achieve this, a number of alternative measures have been developed that

aim to capture permanent budget balance components. These estimates have two

main objectives: first, to analyse the cyclical behaviour of discretionary fiscal policies;

and second, to attempt to measure the sustainability of such policies by showing

whether a fiscal balance is the result of the cyclical components of revenue and

expenditure, or whether it is based on a more stable trend (Blanchard, 1990: 5).

The need for a good indicator for the latter objective has been presumed even more

acutely in Europe since the economic and monetary union. Although the Stability and

Growth Pact had, until 2005, based its objectives solely on observable results

(medium-term budgetary balance or surplus with a total deficit limit of 3% of gross

domestic product (GDP) and a public debt-to-GDP ratio of not more than 60%), both

the European Commission (EC) and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) make

estimates of the cyclically adjusted budget balance (CABB). The sub-prime crisis

highlighted certain limitations in these calculations since their values did not differ

significantly from the observed budget balance (OBB), while in many countries the

estimates were subsequently corrected.

A prime example of this is Spain which, in the years leading up to the crisis, seemingly

had one of the most evidently countercyclical fiscal policies in Europe, which

apparently left it in a strong economic position. In 2006 and 2007, it had a surplus of

2% of GDP, while the CABB did not differ substantially from these figures. Public debt,

meanwhile, following the Excessive Deficit Procedure protocol, had fallen from 67.5%

of GDP in 1996 to 36.3% in 2007. Nevertheless, the crisis revealed the fragility of these

improvements, since between 2007 and 2009 the balance fell by 13 percentage points

(p.p.) of GDP, a trend that was echoed in the cyclically adjusted indicators, while debt

had risen to 84.1% of GDP by 2012.

In this article, we show that Spanish structural budget balance (SBB1) was not as solid

as it seemed. The difficulty in using EC and IMF estimates to identify this situation

stems from the fact that they do not consider the effect of asset revaluation on tax

1 In this article we have taken CABB to be the calculation that corrects OBB solely in terms of cyclical

effect, while SBB also corrects OBB in terms of asset revaluation.

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 3

revenue. What made Spain unique is that tax revenue was not only affected by the rise

in housing prices, but also by the great number of homes built. After taking both

effects into consideration, it can be seen that the apparent solvency of the Spanish

economy in the years leading up to the crisis was due to the extraordinary revenue

obtained from the real estate bubble.

To achieve our goal, we have structured the article as follows. The following section

describes the evolution of the Spanish budget in the wider European context,

identifying a particularly volatile OBB trend. This would have been a reflection of the

volatile evolution of residential investment. Although related government revenue and

expenditure, being transitory, should have been differentiated by the CABB, it proved

to be beyond the scope of this indicator. Consequently, in the third section of this

article, we analyse both the approach on which the EC and IMF base their estimates

and the improvements put forward, which mainly involve including asset revaluation in

the formula used to calculate the SBB. The fourth section adapts this methodology to

the particular case of Spain and shows the results obtained. Finally, we present our

conclusions and policy recommendations.

2. Descriptive analysis of the case of Spain in the wider European context

Evolution of public accounts

During the 90s, budgetary policy in Eurozone countries was dominated by compliance

with the Stability and Growth Pact, which established limits on both government

deficit and public debt (3% and 60% of GDP, respectively). In this context, Spain

pioneered a counter-cyclical policy. As shown in Figure 1, the country progressed from

a chronically high deficit in the first half of the 90s to a moderate deficit by the end of

the decade, and finally achieved a surplus of 2% of GDP in the years leading up to the

recession. Up to the beginning of 2000 this consolidation process was the result of

reduced expenditure and slightly higher revenue. From that time on, expenditure more

or less kept pace with GDP, while revenue spearheaded the process. Public debt,

meanwhile, fell from an average of nearly 60% of GDP in the 90s to 36.3% in 2007, the

sharpest reduction of all Eurozone countries. It is particularly interesting to note that

Spain is the only European Union (EU) member state where OBB continued to improve

even after the "dot com" crisis.

Nevertheless, the country apparent solvency disappeared with the "sub-prime" crisis.

Although the recession punished the budgets of all European countries, Spain was

particularly affected. Indeed, between 2007 and 2009 the balance fell from a surplus of

1.9% of GDP to a deficit of 11.1%, in other words, a decline of 13 p.p. in just two years,

when the EU average (15 countries) was just 6 p.p.. Public debt, meanwhile, started to

grow, reaching 84% of GDP by 2012.

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 4

Figure 1. Observed and cyclically adjusted budget balance

(as a % of GDP and potential GDP, respectively)

Source: European Commission

Spanish fiscal decline was the result of the evolution of both expenditure and revenue.

The weight of expenditure in the GDP increased by 7 p.p. due to the combined effect

of discretionary policies aimed at maintaining aggregate demand and automatic

stabilisers in the form of unemployment benefits. Revenue, meanwhile, fell by 6 p.p. of

GDP, from slightly more than 41% in 2007 to less that 35% in 2009, the lowest of all

Eurozone countries. As shown in Figure 2, the main reason for this was the loss of

revenue from corporate tax (CT; 2.4 p.p.), added value tax (VAT; 2.3 p.p.), personal

income tax (PIT; -0.9 p.p.) and capital transfer tax and stamp duty (CTT-SD; -0.9 p.p.)2.

2Although the crisis had a striking effect on the job market, social security contributions (SSC) remained

largely unchanged because unemployment benefits continued to contribute. Therefore, the impact of unemployment on the budget is centred on expenditure.

-12

-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

Differential

Observed budget balance

Cyclically adjusted budget balance

Spain

-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

Differential

Observed budget balance

Cyclically adjusted budget balance

Germany

-8

-7

-6

-5

-4

-3

-2

-1

0

1

2

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

Differential

Observed budget balance

Cyclically adjusted budget balance

France

-8

-7

-6

-5

-4

-3

-2

-1

0

1

2

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

Differential

Observed budget balance

Cyclically adjusted budget balance

Italy

-12

-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

Differential

Observed budget balance

Cyclically adjusted budget balance

Portugal

-12

-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

Differential

Observed budget balance

Cyclically adjusted budget balance

United Kingdom

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 5

Figure 2. Spanish government revenue and expenditure

(as a % of GDP)

Source: Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations

Given the volatility of the Spanish public accounts, however, it is essential to ascertain

what set it apart from other European countries. The answer can be found in the

collapse of residential investment, since the construction sector is mainly responsible

for the loss of employment and, therefore, the increase in related expenditure, while

revenue fell due to the loss of taxes linked directly to this sector (REAF, 2007).

Evolution of residential investment

In the years leading up to the 2007 crisis housing prices rose sharply across most

European countries, particularly in the UK and Spain, where they increased threefold,

and to a lesser extent in other countries such as France, Italy and Portugal (Figure 3).

Although price variations in Spain were among the greatest, this would not seem

enough to explain the notable difference in public accounts.

The greatest difference is found in the number of units built: while the GDP share of

residential investment remained either steady or even declined in most EU countries,

in Spain it rose sharply until 2006 (Figure 4). This is because the increase in housing

prices, instead of discouraging buyers fearful of a reversal of the trend, had the

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

CTT-SD VAT CT

PIT SSC Other revenue

Total revenue Total expenditure

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 6

opposite effect based on the belief that prices would continue to raise, a clear

indication of the creation of a bubble3 (García Montalvo, 2003: 47).

Figure 3. Housing prices in Europe

(1996=100)

Figure 4. Residential investment in

Europe (as a % of GDP, 2005 prices)

Source: European Commission and Central European Bank

Accordingly, residential investment in Spain grew at an average rate of 8% per year in

real terms over the 1998 - 2007 period, twice the rate of the economy as a whole and

accounting for one fifth of the rise in GDP. Thus, by 2006 it accounted for 12.5% of

nominal GDP in Spain, when historically is had stood at around 7%. In the labour

market, the construction sector accounted for 13.5% of all jobs in Spain, and nearly a

quarter of the growth in employment over the same period. When the bubble burst,

residential investment shrank to around 6% of nominal GDP, while the construction

sector was directly responsible for the loss of 60% of jobs between 2007 and 2011.

To sum up, the evolution of the construction sector and the housing market, not only

in terms of prices but also in the number of units built, could be responsible for the

volatility of Spanish public accounts. However, for the past fifty years experts have

been developing fiscal indicators aimed at separating transitory from permanent

components in order to identify a country long-term economic soundness. The most

widely used indicator of this type is the CABB published simultaneously by the EC and

the IMF. We will now analyse the results of this index.

Evolution of the cyclically adjusted budget balance

Figure 1 shows the CABB together with the OBB. At first glance it can be seen that the

indicators do not differ substantially. Over the 1995 - 2012 period, the difference never

exceeds 2 p.p. of GDP in the countries considered, a figure that is not high enough to

change the conclusions reached on both the financial solvency of the countries or the

cyclical nature of the policy in question.

3According to Stiglitz (1990: 13) a bubble exists when the price of an asset grows only because investors

believe it will continue to increase in the future, although fundamental factors do not justify this belief.

80100120140160180200220240260280300320

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

GermanySpainFranceItalyPortugalUnited Kingdom

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

Germany Spain FranceItaly Portugal United Kingdom

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 7

Spain is a particularly interesting case as the volatility of its OBB is hardly diminished by

its CABB. Indeed, from the mid-90s to 2007 the CABB also showed a process of fiscal

consolidation. During this period, the country went from a deficit of over 7% of

potential GDP to a 1% surplus in the closing years. When the sub-prime crisis hit the

market, the CABB returned to negative figures, with a deficit of 9.4% of potential GDP

in 2009. It is a decline of 10.4 p.p., which is similar to the results of the OBB.

This decline can be explained by an increase of 4.5 p.p. of potential GDP in cyclically

adjusted spending, while revenue fell by nearly 6 p.p.. The increase in expenditure,

meanwhile, is less pronounced than in the observed indicator because the cyclical

adjustment does not take into account a large portion of the rise in unemployment-

related expenditure. It is, however, significant to note that the loss of revenue is

identical in comparison with the observed indicator, suggesting that the fall in revenue

has absolutely nothing to do with the cyclical effect.

This is borne out by comparing the observed and cyclically adjusted revenue series as a

percentage of observed and potential GDP, respectively, published by the EC4. As

shown in Figure 5, cyclically adjusted revenue is practically the same as observed

revenue since in no country do these two elements differ by more than 0.3 p.p.. In

other words, the EC methodology is not capable of adjusting revenue by cycle, and

therefore does not capture the transitory revenue derived from the real estate bubble

in Spain. Consequently, the difference between OBB and CABB is due entirely to the

adjustment made to unemployment expenditure, since this is the only outlay

considered cyclical in this methodology (Girouard and André, 2005: 13; Hagemann,

1999: 7-8), and does not usually represent more than 3% of total primary expenditure.

It is also interesting to note that the crisis did not only affect public accounts but also

forced analysts to correct the CABB figures for the years immediately preceding onset.

In most European countries, prior to the collapse of Lehman Brothers CABB projections

for 2008 showed a deficit of no more than 3% of potential GDP, while estimates were

far more pessimistic after the event. Spain is, again, an extreme case, since an

estimated surplus of around 1.5% of potential GDP in the first half of 2008 fell to a

deficit of over 4% just one year later, finally ending up at nearly 5%. Spain accordingly

adopted fiscal measures to fight the crisis based on the belief that the country had a

cyclically adjusted surplus of 1.5% of potential GDP, when in fact it had a deficit of 5%

(Figure 6).

4 Unfortunately the IMF data cannot be disaggregated in the same way as they are not published.

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 8

Figure 5. Observed and cyclically adjusted public revenue

(as a % of GDP and potential GDP, respectively)

Source: European Commission

In other words, the limitations of CABB estimates have driven analysts to put forward

alternative methodologies capable of capturing transitory components in public

accounts. This is the focus in the next section.

-0.15

-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1

32

34

36

38

40

42

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

Differential (right axis)

Observed revenues

Cyclically adjusted revenues

Spain

-0.02

-0.01

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

41

42

43

44

45

46

47

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

Differential (right axis)

Observed revenues

Cyclically adjusted revenues

Germany

-0.03

-0.02

-0.01

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

47

48

49

50

51

52

53

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

Differential (right axis)

Observed revenues

Cyclically adjusted revenues

France

-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

43

44

45

46

47

48

49

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

Differential (right axis)Observed revenuesCyclically adjusted revenues

Italy

-0.15

-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1

36

38

40

42

44

46

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

Differential (right axis)

Observed revenues

Cyclically adjustes revenues

Portugal

-0.15

-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

37

38

39

40

41

42

43

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

Differential (right axis)

Observed revenues

cyclically adjusted revenues

United Kingdom

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 9

Figure 6. Evolution of the 2008 cyclically adjusted budget balance

(as a % of potential GDP)

Source: European Commission

3. From the cyclically adjusted to the structural budget balance

The approaches used by the EC and IMF to estimate CABB are very similar. Both

organisations base their calculation on the cyclical position of the economy, i.e., the

output gap (OG), and on the relationship between the cycle and the different balance

components (revenue and expenditure).

Originally, the cyclical position was obtained by applying a Hodrick-Prescott filter to

the GDP series. The advantage of this method lies in its simplicity and transparency,

but it is criticised for not using information from other relevant macroeconomic

variables, and because it is hard to identify break points in time (Kuttner, 1994: 262).

As a result, analysts are gradually adopting production function-based methods that

attempt to incorporate output fundamentals (Denis et al., 2006; D´Auria et al., 2010).

This approach, however, is not without its drawbacks, particularly its use of the

Hodrick-Prescott filter to calculate trends in total factor productivity, the job offer, and

to soften the non-accelerating wage rate of unemployment (NAWRU), and the fact

that estimates are more sensitive to baseline statistics, which can lead to different

institutions obtaining different results (Corrales et al., 2002).

-7

-6

-5

-4

-3

-2

-1

0

1

2

Alemania España Francia Italia Portugal Reino Unido

Spring-07 Autumn-07 Spring-08 Autumn-08

Spring-09 Autumn-09 Spring-10 Autumn-10

Spring-11 Autumn-11 Spring-12 Autumn-12

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 10

The cycle is linked to the budget through the elasticities between the main revenue

items (direct taxation of individuals and companies, indirect taxes and social security

contributions) and the OG, while in terms of expenditure, only unemployment costs

are considered cyclical. Each elasticity is, in turn, the sum of two elasticities: the

elasticity between the tax base and the OG, and the elasticity of tax collections to tax

base. Then, the cyclically adjusted components are calculated by multiplying the

observed revenue or expenditure by the OG to the corresponding elasticity power. In

the case of expenditure, the IMF approach differs from the EC in that instead of basing

their calculations on the OG and the elasticity, they use a simple proportional rule

between observed unemployment costs, the rate of unemployment and the NAWRU.

Finally, revenue and expenditure is subtracted and the result is divided by the

potential GDP (Girouard and André, 2005; Hagemann, 1999).

Algebraically:

��∗ = �∑ ��∗�� − �∗ �∗ (1)

��∗ = �� ∗ ��∗� ����;�

(2)

���;� = ���;� ∗ ���;��

��: �∗ = � ∗ ��∗� ���;� = � ∗ ��∗

� ���;� (3)

� ;� = � ;! ∗ �!;� = �"� ∗ �!;�

IMF: �∗ = �� − �" + ��" ∗ �∗� � (4)

where superscript "*" is the cyclically adjusted value or the potential GDP; BB is the

budget balance; Ti is the "i" category tax revenue; E is the primary public expenditure;

Eu is the unemployment expenditure; Y is the GDP; U is the unemployment rate; ���;� is

the elasticity of the "i" revenue category with respect to the OG; ���;� the elasticity of

the "i" revenue category tax base with respect to the OG; ���;�� is the elasticity of the

"i" revenue with respect to its tax base; � ;� is the elasticity of the primary public

expenditure with respect to the OG; � ;! is the elasticity of the primary public

expenditure of the unemployment gap; and �!;� is the elasticity of unemployment

with respect to OG.

One of the best features of this calculation is its simplicity, given that the figures can be

easily obtained by purely mechanical rules that can be applied to all countries.

Nevertheless, by 2000 certain errors started to appear in the CABB to explain the

discretionary measures that the tax authorities of various countries claim to have

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 11

taken5 (Larch and Turrini, 2009: 10-11). Two factors are responsible for these

shortcomings. The first is the difficulty of calculating the real time OG, even using

production function methods (Orphanides and van Noorden, 2002). In particular, in

times of economic growth there is a trend to overestimate the potential product,

causing part of cyclical revenue to be considered structural (Girouard and Price, 2004:

6-8; Joumard and André, 2008: 8-11). Therefore, based on real time data, fiscal policies

seem to be counter-cyclical, while after-the-event input suggests pro-cyclicality (Forni

and Momigliano, 2004; Cimadomo, 2008; Golinelli and Momigliano, 2007). The second

is the significant fluctuation of tax elasticities in respect of GDP, partly due to the

failure to consider the effects of the composition of demand through an aggregate

indicator such as the OG (European Commission, 2007: 103).

The variability of OG and elasticity estimates would in part be explained by asset

revaluation, a factor which is not considered in the methodology used by international

organisations. A financial bubble, for example, would raise the price of assets, and

these would affect certain tax bases (capital gains or wealth tax), but would not

directly affect the OG, which is why the elasticities would be affected (Joumard and

André, 2008: 10). Difficulties would also arise in the calculation of the potential

product due to indirect effects on the real economy such as wealth effects on

consumption or the effect of balance sheets on investment and the labour market

(Eschenbach and Schuknecht, 2002a: 11, and 2002b: 13-4). A real estate bubble,

meanwhile, when accompanied by a construction industry boom, would also have a

direct effect on real economy due to the number of units built (Addison-Smith and

McQuinn, 2010).

To avoid bias in OG estimations, the first attempt involved excluding this from CABB

calculations and replacing it with variables more directly related to public finance, such

as the tax bases of the same revenue and expenditure items considered by the EC and

IMF6. In this way, cyclically adjusted tax bases are no longer obtained through an

elasticity that links them to the OG, but are estimated directly (Bouthevillain et al.,

2001; Morris et al., 2009).

This is a better approach because it considers the effects of the composition of

aggregate demand. Nevertheless, it is still hard to identify transitory fiscal revenue,

which is usually derived from an overestimation of the value of assets. Due to this, the

5Spain, between 2007 and 2009, would also illustrate the divergence between the government

discretionary fiscal policy and that shown in the CABB. Indeed, both the Spanish authorities (Informe Presidencia del Gobierno de España, 2010: 40-42) and the OECD (2009) estimated Spanish tax incentives over that period to be around 4% of GDP. However, as discussed above, the CABB declined by 10.4%. 6The average wage and rate of employment is used as the tax base for personal income tax and social

security contributions; a company profit proxy is used for corporate tax; private consumption is used for indirect taxes; while the unemployment rate is used for the cyclic component of expenditure.

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 12

concept of the structural budget balance (SBB) was developed. This differs from the

CABB in that it does not only extract cyclical components from the OBB, but also

transitory components related to the value of financial and property assets.

Eschenbach and Schuknecht (2002a: 31) show the importance of these variables by

including them in the estimated tax revenue of several European countries, thereby

improving the adjustment criteria.

The approach is based on estimating, using an error correction model, the short- and

long-term elasticities of different public revenue and expenditure items to their tax

bases and to the price of financial and property assets. The elasticities thus obtained

are applied to the estimated structural value of the tax bases and asset prices7, to

obtain the SBB. This is usually less volatile than the CABB estimated by the EC and IMF

(Girouard and Price, 2004; Morris and Schuknecht, 2007; Price and Dang, 2011).

These analyses are made for groups of countries, and as such are better in terms of

comparison and regional analysis, albeit at the price of accuracy, since the specificity of

each country is not considered. For this reason, similar specific studies on a country-

by-country basis are called for, as in the case of Ireland (Kanda, 2010; Addison-Smith

and McQuinn, 2010). In the following, we adapt the SBB approach to the case of Spain.

This enables us to more accurately disaggregate tax revenue and to include, as

explanatory variables of these revenue, not only the revaluation of housing, but also

the sharp increase in the number of units built, as discussed above.

4. Estimated structural budget balance for Spain

Methodology

Based on the aforementioned papers, which introduce asset revaluation into SBB

calculations (Girouard and Price, 2004; Morris and Schuknecht, 2007; Price and Dang,

2011), the first step is to disaggregate tax collection into revenue categories. As we are

dealing specifically with Spain in this article, we can achieve a more accurate

disaggregation instead of relying on the EC general categories. Revenue is therefore

disaggregated into: social security contributions (SSC), personal income tax (PIT),

corporate tax (CT), property tax (PT; includes inheritance and gift tax and the

discontinued wealth tax), value added tax (VAT), capital transfer tax and stamp duty

(CTT-SD) and revenue from regional authorities (RA). An error correction model has

been developed for each of these categories that uses the tax base proxies of each

7Generally speaking, filters such as Hodrick-Prescott are used to obtain these structural values. Asset

market fundamentals, such as in Price and Dang (2011), are rarely used.

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 13

category and nominal residential investment as explanatory variables8. This gives us

the short- and long-term collection elasticity of each explanatory variable.

The tax base proxies used for each revenue item are as follows: for the SSC, the

average wage (W), the number of people employed (EM), and unemployment benefits

(UB); for PIT, the gross disposable household income (GDHI) and the average tax rate

(RatePIT); for CT, the gross disposable corporate income (GDCI) and the average tax

rate (RateCT); for VAT, private consumption (PRC). Finally, for the PT, the CTT-SD and

the RA the residential investment (RI) is the only explanatory variable9.

We have included nominal residential investment in all our equations because in real

estate bubbles, unlike their financial equivalent, prices rise very often accompanied by

an increase in the number of units built (Addison-Smith and McQuinn, 2010). As

discussed above, Spain could be a reference case. One way of combining both effects

into a single variable is by using residential investment in nominal terms.

We use error correction models to capture both, short- and long-term relationships.

Accordingly, we have estimated a long-term equation (5) linking the levels of the

variables (in logarithms) for each revenue category. Equation (6) shows the short-term

dynamics between the revenue change of rate, due to long-term deviations from

equilibrium, the change of rate of the respective tax base proxies, and (nominal)

residential investment.

Long-term equation:

'(��,* = +�,- + . /�,0,- ∗ '(��,0,*1�

0+ 2�,- ∗ '(34* + ��,* (5)

Short-term equation:

∆'(��,* = +�6- + . /�,06- ∗ ∆'(��,0,*1�

0+ 2�6- ∗ ∆'(34* + 7� ∗ ��,*8 + 9�,* (6)

where �� is the observed revenue of the “i” revenue category; ��,0 is the “j” tax base

proxy of the “i” revenue category; 34 is the nominal residential investment; subscripts

“lr” and “sr” stand for the long-term and short-term equations respectively; /�,0 is the

elasticity of “i” revenue to the “j” tax base; 2� is the elasticity of the “i” revenue items

to nominal residential investment; 7� is the error correction factor; ∆ is the first

difference operator; and '( is the natural logarithm.

8 Figure A.1 of the annex shows the evolution of residential investment and total public revenue in

Spain. 9 Figures of all public revenue items and their corresponding tax bases are given in the annex.

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 14

Once the elasticities have been obtained, the equation yields the structural value of

each revenue item based on the structural values of the tax base and residential

investment proxies. In the latter case, the structural value is taken to be a fixed

percentage of nominal GDP. Various scenarios are developed based on the evolution

over time in Spain, ranging from 5% to 8%. Based on these, we aimed to capture the

direct effect of residential investment on government revenue. We attempted to

capture indirect effects, meanwhile, by smoothing the proxies using a Hodrick –

Prescott filter. Therefore, the structural value of each revenue item is obtained from

the following equation, adapted from the equation used by the EC to obtain the

cyclically adjusted tax revenue based on the OG (Girouard and André, 2005: 7):

��∗�� = : ;��,0∗��,0 <

=�,>?@1�

0∗ �34∗

34 �A�?@ (7)

where superscript “*” indicates structural value.

Adding up all structural revenue and tax revenue not included in the quantitative

calculation (NIT, basically excise tax, foreign trade and gambling, tax that represent

less than 10% of total revenue and are taken to be unrelated to the evolution of the

construction industry), we obtain the total structural revenue.

�∗ = . ��∗ + B4� (8)

where superscript “*” indicates structural value; T is total revenue; �� is revenue

stemming from residential investment; and B4� are revenue items not related to

residential investment.

Structural expenditure, according to the EC and IMF approach, is obtained by

considering only unemployment expenditure to be cyclical (Girouard and André, 2005:

13 and 19-20; Hagemann, 1999: 7-8). The EC NAWRU estimate is used to calculate the

number of unemployed in structural terms. However, the methodology of this

indicator (Mc Morrow and Roeger, 2000: 10-11) says that it cannot be considered

structural, since it estimates the unemployment rate that stabilises the inflation rate,

while the long-term rate should stabilise both inflation and unemployment.

Consequently our methodology does not use the annual NAWRU value, but rather the

20-year moving average of this rate10. Using the NAWRU average, instead of its annual

value, increases the unemployment expenditure that is considered cyclical because it

allows a greater difference between the long-term and observed unemployment rate.

10

Figure A.4 of the annex shows the unemployment rate, the NAWRU and its corresponding 20-year moving average. It is interesting to note that the results vary very little when longer or shorter averages (10 to 30 years) are used.

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 15

For the sake of simplicity, we have followed the IMF method of calculating cyclical

expenditure, namely, a proportional rule considering the monetary value of

unemployment benefits, divided by the unemployment rate and multiplied by the

NAWRU moving average11.

�∗ = � − �D = � − ��" − �"∗ (9)

�∗ = � − ��" − �" ∗ �3∗�3 � (10)

where superscript “*” indicates the structural value; � is total public expenditure; �D is

cyclical public expenditure; �" is the unemployment expenditure; and �3 is the

unemployment rate.

Finally, SBB is obtained by subtracting revenue from structural expenditures.

BB∗ = T∗ − E∗ (11)

Results

The following section sets out the results for all the revenue items considered. The

sample used comprises annual data from 1986 to 2010. First, we perform Dickey-Fuller

(1981) unit roots tests to identify the order of integration of all the variables. As shown

in Table A.1 in the annex, we did not reject the unit root hypothesis for the levels of

the variables (in logarithms) in any case.

Table 1 shows short- and long-term elasticities obtained from the error correction

model estimated on each tax revenue using as covariates their tax base and nominal

residential investment proxies, together with the error correction term. The annex

shows evidence that confirms the suitability of the models used. Specifically, Table A.2

shows the statistics of the unit root test on the residuals of the long-term equations

and McKinnon's (1991) critical values. It can be seen that, with the exception of the RA

variable, the unit root null hypotheses is rejected for the residuals of all long-term

equations (5), and as such they can be considered stationary. In the case of RA, we

concluded that there is no cointegration relationship between this variable and

residential investment. Table A.3 shows the autocorrelation value of the first two lags

of the residuals from the long-term equations (5) and the error correction models (6).

The Ljung-Box (1978) statistic shows that the residuals in all short-term equations are

white noise, which confirms the suitability of the models. The residuals of the long-

term equations or cointegration relationships can be considered white noise for all

11

Despite the improvement of including a long-term unemployment rate proxy, this calculation continues to be biased because it lacks an estimation of the long-term economically active population (EAP) and total population. Indeed, a real estate bubble does not only bring down unemployment, it also forces up the EAP rate, and even impacts population figures through migratory flows.

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 16

variables, except for IS. In this case, the efficiency of the cointegration vector

estimation can be improved using Stock and Watson's (1993) dynamic ordinary least

squares (DOLS) technique, that shows very similar results12.

Going back to Table 1, it can be seen that residential investment turned out to be a

very significant variable to explain the evolution of all the revenue items considered,

and that the elasticities signs are as expected. Likewise, the remaining variables are

also significant, and their signs as expected too13. Error correction terms, which show

the percentage of deviation corrected for each period, are significant, being in all cases

between 39% and 87%, except for SSC, which seems to over-correct the deviation by

9%.

Table 1. Tax revenue elasticities14

*** significant at 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at 10%

It can also be seen that there are no RA values in either the long-term equation or the

error correction term. This is because, as discussed previously, the residuals from its

long-term equation were not stationary. Therefore, in this case, we supposed that

there is no cointegration relationship between variables, meaning that the elasticity

used to estimate structural revenue is taken from the short-term equation in which no

error correction was included.

Figure 7 shows the evolution of different revenue items and of the total, both in terms

of observed values and the different structural residential investment scenarios. It can

be seen that up to 2002 observed revenue did not differ significantly from structural

revenue as expected. From that year on, however, most of the observed revenue items

already exceeded what was considered to be their long-term values. It is interesting to

12

Results are available upon request. 13

We attempted to include lagged variables, in short-term equations, but none were significant. This was expected since annual data is used. Thus, only contemporary dynamics are shown. 14

The definition of the names of the different revenue items and their respective variables is explained in section 3.1 above (Methodology).

RI W EM UB GDHI RatePIT GDCI RateCT PRC CError

correction term

R2

Short-termSSC 0.15** 0.82*** 0.59** 0.07** 0 -1.09*** 0.90PIT 0.20*** 0.43*** 0.18*** 0.03*** -0.69*** 0.98CT 0.39*** 0.42** 0.33*** 0 -0.39** 0.92PT 0.99*** 0 -0.87*** 0.58VAT 0.73*** 1.58*** -0.11*** -0.89*** 0.99CTT-SD 1.39*** 0 -0.82*** 0.66RA 0.29*** 0.06*** 0 0.47Long-termSSC 0,13 0,87 0,61 0,08 0,16 0.99PIT 0,14 0,90 0,14 -3.62 0.99CT 0,28 0,65 0,38 -1,30 0.98PT 0,85 -0,38 0.93VAT 0,46 0,33 0,00 0.99CTT-SD 1,05 -2.98 0.97RA - - -

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 17

remark that PIT collection only exceeded the structural value from 2005 onwards. With

regard to SSC, the observed value only exceeds what is considered the permanent

value in 2008, and to a lesser extent in 2009. This was due to the fact that the decline

of the revenue derived from loss of jobs was offset by higher contributions from

unemployment benefits, which contribute to social security. Accordingly, the total

revenue from 2002 to 2008 is higher than all the residential investment scenarios,

peaking in 2007 with a difference of 3.3% of GDP compared with the average scenario

(6.5%), and an accumulated difference of 18% of GDP15.

Finally, Figure 8 shows the OBB, the CABB estimated by the EC and IMF, our own

estimate of SBB for the average scenario (where the nominal GDP share of residential

investment is 6.5%) and other estimates from earlier papers (Price and Dang, 2011;

Morris and Schuknetch, 2007). First, it can be seen that all the estimated cyclically

adjusted or structural balances are relatively similar until 1998. From this year

onwards, our own estimate starts to show a downward trend that dips more sharply

after 2001, while the remaining estimations maintain their upward trend for several

more years.

With regard to CABB, it is interesting to note how similar they are to the OBB,

particularly in the case of EC estimates. IMF estimates differ to a certain extent due to

subsequent corrections, but the unrevised estimates are very similar to those of the EC

and the OBB. As discussed above, it is obvious that these indicators must be adjusted,

since the advantage of a structural indicator lies in its capacity to differ from observed

data in order to present an overview of the economy that is unaffected by

circumstantial factors.

This is the aim of the articles written by Price and Dang (2011) and Morris and

Schuknetch (2007). To achieve this, both incorporated the price of financial and

property assets in their balance estimates. As indicated above, the methodology used

is similar to that used in this article. Total revenue is divided in different categories, for

each category an error correction model is developed that includes the tax base of the

different taxes and the asset price as explanatory variables. Price and Dang (2011)

obtain the structural value of the foregoing prices in two ways: one based on

fundamentals, and the other by means of a Hodrick and Prescott filter. Morris and

Schuknetch (2007) only use the filter. Despite these changes, it is interesting to note

that their cyclically adjusted estimates do not differ to any great extent, at least they

are not capable of identifying fiscal difficulties in advance of observed balances.

15

We should clarify that the scenarios used should not be considered fixed as it would be very restrictive to consider the structural value for the GDP share of residential investment constant along time. On the contrary, the structural value of residential investment can change over time, between 5% and 8%.

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 18

Figure 7. Observed and structural observed tax revenue by category

(as a % of GDP and potential GDP, respectively)

Source: Own estimations and Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations

The main advantage of the approach suggested here, therefore, is that it shows that

structural public accounts had started to deteriorate in 1999, with a 3% potential GDP

deficit by 2002, and below 4% from 2004 onwards. This would have identified Spanish

potential fiscal troubles several years in advance, and measures could have been taken

to correct them in real time. The estimation is improved because the general

methodology for all countries is adapted to a particular case. The main feature of Spain

30

33

36

39

42

45

1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010

Observed 8,0%

7,5% 7,0%

6,5% 6,0%

5,5% 5,0%

Total revenue

11,5

12,0

12,5

13,0

13,5

14,0

1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010

Observed 8,0%

7,5% 7,0%

6,5% 6,0%

5,5% 5,0%

Social security contributions

4,5

5,0

5,5

6,0

6,5

7,0

7,5

8,0

1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010

Observed 8,0%

7,5% 7,0%

6,5% 6,0%

5,5% 5,0%

Personal income tax

1,5

2,0

2,5

3,0

3,5

4,0

4,5

5,0

1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010

Observed 8,0%

7,5% 7,0%

6,5% 6,0%

5,5% 5,0%

Corporate tax

0,0

0,1

0,2

0,3

0,4

0,5

0,6

1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010

Observed 8,0% 7,5% 7,0%

6,5% 6,0% 5,5% 5,0%

Property tax

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010

Observed 8,0%

7,5% 7,0%

6,5% 6,0%

5,5% 5,0%

Value added tax

0,4

0,6

0,8

1,0

1,2

1,4

1,6

1,8

2,0

1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010

Observed 8,0%

7,5% 7,0%

6,5% 6,0%

5,5% 5,0%

Capital transfer tax and stamp duty

1,5

2,0

2,5

3,0

3,5

4,0

1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010

Observed 8,0% 7,5% 7,0%

6,5% 6,0% 5,5% 5,0%

Revenue from regional authorities

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 19

over the period studied, as discussed above, is that the real estate bubble was

accompanied by a construction boom, which means that the process not only affected

prices but also the number of units built, a factor that was not taken into consideration

in earlier papers. In other words, instead of discouraging buyers, the rise in housing

prices had the opposite effect due to the belief that upward trend would continue.

This is why it was decided to include nominal residential investment in the SBB

calculation in order to capture the effect of both the prices and units built.

Figure 8. Observed, cyclically adjusted and structural budget balance

(as a % of GDP and potential GDP, respectively)

Source: Own estimations, Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations, EC, IMF and referred papers.

5. Conclusions

This article attempts to address the obvious need to improve CABB estimates, given

the similarity of the latter to OBB and the significant corrections applied. Between

2007 and 2009, Spanish CABB deteriorated by 10.4 p.p. of potential GDP, largely in

parallel with OBB. With regard to corrections, in 2008 both the EC and the IMF

estimated a surplus of around 1% of potential GDP for the 2008-09 period, in line with

the expected fiscal balance. Just 12 months later, however, both institutions reduced

their estimates to a deficit of more than 4% in 2008 and between 5% and 7% in 2009,

to finally stabilise them at deficits of 5% and 9%, respectively.

-14

-12

-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010

Observed Own estimation (6,5%)

European Commission IMF

Price-Dang (2011) Fundamental Price-Dang (2011) HP

Morris-Schuknecht (2007)

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 20

Based on these figures, the Spanish authorities took a series of decisions to fight

against the recession of 2008 on the assumption that public accounts were structurally

sound and had a large enough buffer to allow counter-cyclical policies to be

implemented. However, it later became evident that the buffer was not nearly as

robust as expected, forcing them to withdraw tax incentives before the private sector

was ready to spearhead the aggregate demand.

A review of the literature shows that such situations usually arise due to the failure to

include asset revaluation factors in CABB calculations. Nevertheless, estimates carried

out by other authors who did indeed include such variables in their calculations were

not capable of significantly improving Spanish CABB either, at least not enough to

identify the deterioration of the fiscal situation in time. The main reason for this is that

the studies were carried out for a group of countries or a particular region, and as such

the particular characteristics of each country are not factored in.

In this regard, Spain was in a unique situation because the real estate bubble affected

not only prices but the number of units built, which means that including property

prices as the sole explanatory variable of tax revenue was not enough. In this article

we have used nominal residential investment as a way of including the number of units

built. It is interesting to note that this type of investment has, historically, represented

around 7% of nominal GDP, but it reached 12% in the years leading up to the crisis.

The results obtained confirm the importance of residential investment in Spanish tax

revenue. Indeed, it can be seen that including this variable in the equation, and

assuming different scenarios concerning its long-term share in GDP, reveals that

Spanish tax balance started to show a strong deficit as far back as 2004. Taken this

data into consideration, different fiscal policy decisions would probably have been

taken not only from 2008 onwards, since the start of the crisis, but also in preceding

years.

To achieve this goal in the future, we believe it is essential to include asset revaluation,

both, in terms of prices and number of units, in OBB estimates. It is also important to

draw up a counter-cyclical fiscal rule based on this estimate. This would prevent public

expenditure from deviating so significantly from structural revenue, making far less

likely a new insolvency public position.

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 21

References

Addison-Smyth, D. y McQuinn, K. (2010): “Quantifying Revenue Windfalls from the

Irish Housing Market”, The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 41, No. 2, 201–223.

Blanchard, O. J. (1990): “Suggestions for a new set of fiscal indicators”, OECD

Department of Economics and Statistics Working Papers No. 79.

Bouthevillain, C., Cour-Thimann, P., Van Den Dool, G., Hernández de Cos, P., Langenus,

G., Mohr, M., Momigliano, S., y Tujula, M. (2001): “Cyclically adjusted budget

balances: an alternative approach”, European Central Bank Working Paper Series

No. 77.

Cimadomo, J. (2008): “Fiscal policy in real time”, European Central Bank Working Paper

Series No. 919.

Corrales, F., Varela, J., y Doménech, R. (2002): “Los saldos presupuestarios cíclico y

estructural de la economía española”, Hacienda Pública Española, Vol. 162, Issue 3.

D'Auria, F., Denis, C., Havik, K., Mc Morrow, K., Planas, C., Raciborski, R., Röger, W., y

Rossi, A. (2010): “The production function methodology for calculating potential

growth rates and output gaps”, European Commission Economic Papers No. 420.

Denis, C., Grenouilleau, D., Mc Morrow, K., y Röger, W. (2006): “Calculating potential

growth rates and output gaps -A revised production function approach-”, European

Commission Economic Papers No. 247.

Dickey, D. A. y Fuller, W. A. (1981): “Likehood ratio statistics for autoregressive time

series with a unit root”, Econometrica, Vol. 49, No. 4.

Eschenbach, F. y Schuknecht, L. (2002a): “Asset prices and fiscal balances”, European

Central Bank Working Paper Series No. 141.

__________, (2002b): “The fiscal costs of financial instability revisited”, European

Central Bank Working Paper Series No. 191.

European Commission (2007): “Public finances in EMU 2007”, European Economy No.

3.

Forni, L. y Momigliano, S. (2007): “Cyclical sensitivity of fiscal policies based on real-

time data”, MPRA Paper No. 4315.

García Montalvo, J. (2003): “La vivienda en España: desgravaciones, burbujas y otras

historias”, Fundación de las Cajas de Ahorro (FUNCAS), Perspectivas del Sistema

Financiero No. 78.

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 22

Girouard, N. y André, C. (2005): “Measuring Cyclically-adjusted Budget Balances for

OECD Countries”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 434.

Girouard, N. y Price, R. (2004): “Asset Price Cycles, ´One-Off´ Factors and Structural

Budget Balances”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 391.

Golinelli, R. y Momigliano, S. (2007): “The Cyclical Response of Fiscal Policies in the

Euro Area – Why Do Results of Empirical Research Differ so Strongly?”, Banca

d`Italia Working Papers No. 654.

Hagemann, R. (1999): “The Structural Budget Balance. The IMF´s Methodology”, IMF

Working Paper No. 95.

Joumard, I., y André, C. (2008): “Revenue Buoyancy and its Fiscal Policy Implications”,

OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 598.

Kanda, D. (2010): “Asset Booms and Structural Fiscal Positions: The Case of Ireland”,

IMF Working Paper No. 57.

Kuttner, K. N. (1994): “Estimating Potential Output as a Latent Variable”, Journal of

Business & Economic Statistics, Vol. 12, No. 3, 361-368.

Larch, M., y Turrini, A. (2009): “The cyclically-adjusted budget balance in EU fiscal

policy making: A love at first sight turned into a mature relationship”, European

Commission Economic Papers No. 374.

Ljung, G. M. y Box, G. E. P. (1978): “On a Measure of a Lack of Fit in Time Series

Models”, Biometrika No. 65 (2), 297–303.

Martínez Pagés, J., y Ángel Maza, L. (2003): “Análisis del precio de la vivienda en

España”, Documento de Trabajo del Servicio de Estudios del Banco de España No.

0307.

MacKinnon, J. G. (1991): “Critical Values for Cointegration Tests”, en Engel, R. F. y

Granger, C. W. I. (eds.), Long Run Economic Relationship, Oxford University Press,

267-76.

Mc Morrow, K., y Roeger, W. (2000): “Time –Varying Nairu / Nawru Estimates for the

EU's Member States”, Economic and Financial Affairs (ECFIN) of the European

Commission, No. 145.

Morris, R., Rodrigues Braz, C., de Castro, F., Jonk, S., Kremer, J., Linehan, S., Marino, M.

R., Schalck, C., y Tkacevs, O. (2009): “Explaining government revenue windfalls. An

analysis for selected EU countries”, European Central Bank Working Paper Series

No. 1114.

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 23

Morris, R., y Schuknecht, L. (2007): “Structural balances and revenue windfalls. The

role of asset prices revisited”, European Central Bank Working Paper Series No.

737.

OECD (2009): “The effectiveness and scope of fiscal stimulus”, Economic Outlook,

Interim Report, marzo.

Orphanides, A., y van Norden, S. (2002): “The Unreliability of Output-Gap Estimates in

Real Time”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 84, No. 4, 569-583.

Presidencia del Gobierno de España (2010): “Informe Económico del Presidente de

Gobierno”, Oficina Económica del Presidente de Gobierno, diciembre.

Price, R., y Dang, T. (2011): “Adjusting fiscal balances for asset prices cycles”, OECD

Economics Department Working Paper No. 868.

REAF (Registro de Economistas Asesores Fiscales) (2007): “Costes asociados a la

adquisición, uso y alquiler de viviendas”, disponible en

http://www.unionprofesional.com/index.php/unionprofesional/sala_prensa/notici

as_colegiales/economia_sociedad/costes_fiscales_asociados_a_la_adquisicion_uso

_y_alquiler_de_viviendas_segun_un_estudio_del_reaf

Stiglitz, J. (1990): “Symposium on Bubbles”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 4,

No. 2.

Stock, J. H., y Watson, M. W. (1993): “A Simple Estimator of Cointegrating Vectors in

Higher Order Integrated Systems”, Econometrica, Vol. 61, No. 4, 783-820.

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 24

Annex

Figure A.1. Total public revenue and residential investment in Spain

(in billions of euros at current prices)

Source: Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations and the Spanish Statistics Office

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

Total public revenue

Residential investment (right axis)

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 25

Figure A.2. Public revenue disaggregated into categories

(in thousands of euros at current prices)

Source: Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations and the Spanish Statistics

Office

2.00E+07

4.00E+07

6.00E+07

8.00E+07

1.00E+08

1.20E+08

1.40E+08

1.60E+08

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Social security contributions

0.0E+00

1.0E+07

2.0E+07

3.0E+07

4.0E+07

5.0E+07

6.0E+07

7.0E+07

8.0E+07

9.0E+07

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Personal income tax

0.0E+00

1.0E+07

2.0E+07

3.0E+07

4.0E+07

5.0E+07

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Corporate tax

0

1000000

2000000

3000000

4000000

5000000

6000000

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Property tax

0.0E+00

1.0E+07

2.0E+07

3.0E+07

4.0E+07

5.0E+07

6.0E+07

7.0E+07

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Value added tax

0.00E+00

4.00E+06

8.00E+06

1.20E+07

1.60E+07

2.00E+07

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Capital transfer tax and stamp duty

4.00E+06

8.00E+06

1.20E+07

1.60E+07

2.00E+07

2.40E+07

2.80E+07

3.20E+07

3.60E+07

4.00E+07

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Revenue from regional authorities

2.00E+07

2.50E+07

3.00E+07

3.50E+07

4.00E+07

4.50E+07

5.00E+07

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Other revenue

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 26

Figure A.3. Tax base applied to revenue categories

(in thousands of euros, thousands of people and %)

Source: Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations and the Spanish Statistics

Office

8000

12000

16000

20000

24000

28000

32000

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Average wage

11000

12000

13000

14000

15000

16000

17000

18000

19000

20000

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Number of employed

0.00E+00

5.00E+06

1.00E+07

1.50E+07

2.00E+07

2.50E+07

3.00E+07

3.50E+07

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Unemployment benefits

1.0E+08

2.0E+08

3.0E+08

4.0E+08

5.0E+08

6.0E+08

7.0E+08

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Private consumption

1.0E+08

2.0E+08

3.0E+08

4.0E+08

5.0E+08

6.0E+08

7.0E+08

8.0E+08

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Gross disposable household income

4.8

5.2

5.6

6.0

6.4

6.8

7.2

7.6

8.0

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Average PIT rate

2.00E+07

4.00E+07

6.00E+07

8.00E+07

1.00E+08

1.20E+08

1.40E+08

1.60E+08

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Gross disposable corporate income

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

4.5

5.0

86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Average CT rate

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 27

Figure A.4. Observed and structural unemployment rate

(as a % of EAP)

Source: Spanish Statistics Office and European Commission

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

22

24

26

1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012

Unemployment rate

NAWRU

NAWRU (20 years moving average)

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 1

Table A.1. Unit root tests

(Dickey-Fuller critical values, 1981)

"t" statistic P-value "t" statistic P-value "t" statistic P-value "t" statistic P-value "t" statistic P-value "t" statistic P-valueSocial security contributions 0,277 0,757 -0,777 0,807 -2,525 0,314 -1,157 0,218 -1,826 0,359 -4,665 0,000Personal income tax 3,777 1,000 2,144 1,000 -0,967 0,925 0,513 0,817 -4,266 0,003 - -Corporate tax -0,318 0,560 -1,399 0,566 -1,732 0,697 -3,534 0,001 -2,034 0,271 - -Property tax -0,240 0,589 -1,484 0,524 -2,884 0,185 -4,611 0,000 -4,570 0,002 - -Value added tax 0,958 0,905 -1,011 0,732 -2,850 0,197 -4,001 0,000 -4,008 0,007 - -Capital transfer tax and stamp duty -0,868 0,329 -1,881 0,335 -0,734 0,956 -2,624 0,011 -3,188 0,035 - -Revenue from regional authorities 3,940 1,000 3,622 1,000 1,366 1,000 -0,684 0,408 -2,041 0,268 -5,265 0,000Residential investment 3,340 0,999 1,942 1,000 -0,574 0,971 -1,345 0,160 -4,265 0,003 - -Wage 1,165 0,932 -1,045 0,718 -3,209 0,114 -0,701 0,401 -3,493 0,018 - -Employed 1,580 0,968 -1,380 0,574 -2,869 0,190 -1,794 0,070 -2,721 0,087 - -Unemployment benefits 3,120 0,999 2,078 1,000 0,755 0,999 -2,470 0,016 -2,798 0,074 - -Consumption 2,707 0,997 2,058 1,000 -2,031 0,555 -1,419 0,141 -3,246 0,030 - -Household income 21,120 1,000 6,491 1,000 2,659 1,000 -0,922 0,306 -1,052 0,713 -5,963 0,000Corporate income 3,339 0,999 0,627 0,987 -2,000 0,566 -2,164 0,032 -3,922 0,008 - -PIT rate 0,534 0,824 -1,694 0,421 -2,158 0,489 -6,263 0,000 -6,074 0,000 - -CT rate -0,422 0,520 -1,772 0,385 -2,760 0,225 -4,005 0,000 -3,903 0,007 - -

Variable

Levels First differences Second differencesNo intercept,

no trendWith intercept,

no trendWith intercept

and trendNo intercept,

no trendWith intercept,

no trendNo intercept,

no trend

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 1

Table A.2. Unit root tests of the residuals of long-term equations

(Mac Kinnon critical values, 1991)

Table A.3. Autocorrelations of the first two lags and p-values associated to the Ljung-

Box statistics (1978) for the residuals of the long- and short-term equations

α = 0,05 α = 0,1Social security contributions -4,759 -4,998 -4,567Personal income tax -4,980 -4,564 -4,152Corporate tax -4,562 -4,564 -4,152Property tax -4,218 -3,591 -3,218Value added tax -5,357 -4,098 -3,706Capital transfer tax and stamp duty -3,363 -3,591 -3,218Revenue from regional authorities -1,920 -3,591 -3,218

"t" statisticCritical values

Auto

correlationsP-value

Auto

correlationsP-value

1 -0,021 0,913 -0,042 0,827

2 -0,062 0,939 -0,082 0,887

1 -0,036 0,847 0,223 0,245

2 -0,007 0,981 0,087 0,457

1 0,401 0,040 -0,022 0,911

2 -0,228 0,060 -0,147 0,747

1 0,126 0,504 -0,029 0,879

2 0,266 0,284 0,245 0,422

1 0,070 0,709 0,107 0,577

2 -0,231 0,426 -0,076 0,788

1 0,355 0,060 0,073 0,704

2 -0,142 0,126 -0,282 0,301

1 - - 0,137 0,476

2 - - -0,095 0,682Revenue from regional authorities

Social security contributions

Personal income tax

Corporate tax

Property tax

Value added tax

Capital transfer tax and stamp duty

Equation Lags

Long term Short term

Zack, Poncela, Senra y Sotelsek. “Towards an effective structural budget balance for economic stability” Junio 2013

UC - CIFF – IELAT | 2

Colección de Documentos de Trabajo Conjuntos IELAT-CIFF (UAH) y UC

DTI Nº1: Carlos Marichal, Crisis financieras y debates sobre la globalización: reflexiones

desde la historia económica latinoamericana. Junio 2011.

DTI Nº 2:Renaldo Antonio Gonsalves, A construção dos mercados monetários e

financeiros no Brasil: A história da moeda que transitou da hiperinflação para a

valorização. Agosto 2011.

DTI Nº 3: José Luis Machinea, Desaceleración o recesión global: los márgenes de la

política económica. Octubre 2011.

DTI Nº 4: Alejandro Izquierdo y Ernesto Talvi (coordinadores), One Region, Two

Speeds? Challenges of the New Global Economic Order for Latin America and the

Caribbean. Diciembre 2011.

DTI Nº 5: Rosa Matilde Guerrero, Kurt Focke y Ana Cristina M. de Pereira, Supervisión

con base en riesgos: precisión del marco conceptual. Febrero 2012.

DTI Nº 6: Pablo Sanguinetti, Acceso a servicios financieros, desarrollo y bienestar en

América Latina. Abril 2012.

DTI Nº 7: Pablo López y Marcelo Rougier, Los Bancos de Desarrollo en América Latina

en los años de la industrialización por sustitución de importaciones. Junio 2012.

DTI Nº 8: Manuel Lucas Durán, Fiscalidad y libre circulación de capitales y pagos en el

Derecho de la Unión Europea: análisis jurisprudencial. Agosto 2012.

DTI Nº 9: José Marcelino Fernández Alonso, La República Argentina y las inversiones

extranjeras directas. Análisis sobre el impacto de los procesos de

expropiación/nacionalización sobre la reputación internacional del país (2002-2012). Octubre 2012.

DTI Nº 10: Gilmar Masiero y Luiz Carlos Zalaf Caseiro, State Support for Emerging

Market Multinationals: The Brazilian and Chinese experiences, Diciembre 2012.

DTI Nº 11: Diego Coatz, Política pyme en América Latina a la luz de los cambios

globales, Febrero 2013.

DTI Nº 12: José Esteban Castro, Apuntes para una ecología política de la integración en

América Latina y el Caribe, Abril 2013.

DTI Nº 13: Guido Zack, Pilar Poncela, Eva Senra y Daniel Sotelsek, Towards an effective

structural budget balance for economic stability, Junio 2013.

_______________________________________________________ Todas las publicaciones están disponibles en las páginas Web de las tres instituciones participantes: IELAT, CIFF y Universidad de Cantabria. http://www.ielat.es/ http://www.ciff.net/ http://www.unican.es/ Los documentos de trabajo desarrollados contienen información analítica sobre distintos temas y son elaborados por diferentes miembros de las instituciones participantes u otros profesionales colaboradores de las mismas. Cada uno de ellos ha sido seleccionado y editado por IELAT-CIFF-UC, tras ser aprobado por la Comisión Académica correspondiente. Desde este ámbito de reflexión animamos a que estos documentos se utilicen y distribuyan con fines académicos indicando siempre la fuente. La información e interpretación contenida en los documentos son de exclusiva responsabilidad del autor y no necesariamente reflejan las opiniones del IELAT-CIFF-UC. Universidad de Alcalá Universidad de Cantabria Colegio de Trinitarios C/Trinidad 1 – 28801 Alcalá de Henares (Madrid) España 34 – 91 885 5278 [email protected]

P.V.P.: 20 €

Con la colaboración de: