threshold paper for bordeaux2

Upload: panji-rizki-maulana

Post on 03-Apr-2018

214 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/28/2019 Threshold Paper for Bordeaux2

    1/27

    Do Banks suffer from Moral Hazard?

    An empirical threshold model of the impact of non-

    performing loans on bank lending

    Yixin Hou and David Dickinson

    Department of Economics

    Birmingham Business School

    University of Birmingham

    Preliminary draft. Please do not quote without the authors permission

    This Draft March 2010

    Corresponding author

    David Dickinson

    Department of EconomicsBirmingham Business School

    University of Birmingham

    Edgbaston

    Birmingham B15 2TTUK

    Tel +44 (0)121 414 8093

    Fax +44 (0)121 414 7380Email: [email protected]

  • 7/28/2019 Threshold Paper for Bordeaux2

    2/27

    Abstract

    This paper examines how non-performing loans (NPLs) affect

    bank lending behaviour. It uses a large multi-country data set of

    banks and investigates the influence of NPLs on the amount of

    credit which banks grant. We use a threshold model to investigate

    this issue and find that lending behaviour is significantly different

    below and above a critical threshold level of NPLs. We find that

    lending is dependent also on the capital ratio. The thresholds are

    different across developed and less-developed financial markets.The paper identifies that the results obtained provide evidence on

    whether banks are subject to moral hazard in lending. The impact

    of capital regulations also influences the risk-taking behaviour of

    banks.

    JEL Codes G21, G18, G11

  • 7/28/2019 Threshold Paper for Bordeaux2

    3/27

    1. Introduction

    Given the recent turbulence in banking and the rise in non-performing loans (NPLs) there is

    renewed interest in the impact of NPLs on banks and their behaviour. Of particular interest is the

    extent to which deterioration in bank performance leads to moral hazard in that there is an

    incentive for banks to take more risk. We investigate this issue by examining the relationship

    between bank lending and NPLs. Specifically we use a threshold approach to identify if and how

    bank lending behaviour changes as the level of NPLs rises above a threshold value (which is

    determined endogenously). By carefully specifying the implications of the moral hazard

    hypothesis we are able to use our empirical findings to understand whether it is an issue. We also

    control for capital adequacy in order to consider the impact of regulatory controls on our results.

    Our study is multi-country and hence we have a number of alterative regulatory regimes in which

    to consider our findings and to explain their significance.

    Much of the research on NPLs to this time has been directed at their implications for bank failure

    and the findings that asset quality is a statistically significant predictor of insolvency and that

    banking institutions always have large non-performing loans prior to failure (e.g. Dermirgue-

    Kunt 1989, Barr and Siems 1994). Literature focusing on the causes of the NPLs problems

    provides a number of explanations for the phenomenon. At the microeconomic level, asymmetric

    information and adverse selection, risk preference, risk measurement, corporate governance, have

    been put forward to try to explain the causes of non-performing loans. From the macroeconomic

    view, the non-performing loans problem is seen to be the consequence of macroeconomic

    inefficiency. For example, the long lasting Japanese bad-loan problem since the bubble burst in

    1990 is viewed as the consequence of a deflationary slump. The experience of Japan, as well as

    that of the 1930s has been the major impetus for the policy responses to the current banking

    crisis.

    It has been argued that the general impact of NPL is to induce reductions in lending and a flight

    to quality (e.g. Bernanke and Gertler, 1994). Hence enterprises, which are financially sound,

    suffer liquidity problems and financial distress resulting in bankruptcy, as a result of the drying-

    up of bank credit channels. Furthermore the need of banks to re-build capital means that they cut

    back more generally on extending credit, causing reduced demand and hence further falls in

    economic activity. Alternatively there is the argument that banks engage in more risky lending as

  • 7/28/2019 Threshold Paper for Bordeaux2

    4/27

    a result of moral hazard when NPLs rise. In other words, there is an incentive for banks to take

    more risks if their financial position is worsening as a result of increased NPLs. This problem

    becomes even more acute if there is a perception that banks will be bailed out if they become

    insolvent (e.g. Boyd et. al, 1998, Nier and Baumann, 2006). Examining the relationship between

    bank lending and their NPLs will provide insights into the potential for credit crunches or moral

    hazard problems to appear since we will be able to identify the extent to which banks increase

    lending as NPLs increase or reduce.

    We start from the premise that the impact of NPLs on bank lending is non-linear. It is quite

    normal for banks to experience bad loans as a normal part of their business and hence we would

    not expect to observe effects on bank behaviour at normal levels. However once NPLs rise

    above this normal operational level banks will need to take action to stabilise their business, by

    building capital and adjusting their credit policies to increase loan quality, or take more risk in

    order to build funds as a way out of potential insolvency problems. This approach leads us

    naturally to adopt a threshold regression technique to model the empirical relationship between

    NPLs and bank lending. We find that such an approach has some empirical success and that

    there is interesting variation in the threshold level across different regions. Since we also apply

    thresholds for bank capital ratios we indentify some interesting interactions between banks

    behaviour and regulatory requirements.

    The rest of this paper is organised as follows. Section 2 explains our definition of non-performing

    loans and highlights why non performing loans can impact on lending behaviour as well as

    discussing consequences of non-performing loans on the economy more generally. Section 3 uses

    the empirical version of the threshold model to test how the non-performing loan affects banks

    loan decision. And section 4 provides interpretation of our results and concluding comments.

    2). A Threshold model of the effect of NPLs on Bank Lending

    In order to understand the relationship between bank lending and NPLs we need to consider why

    it is that NPLs occur. There are both a demand and supply side factors. Clearly not all firms that

    borrow will succeed and defaults and bankruptcy are natural economic selection processes. Banks

  • 7/28/2019 Threshold Paper for Bordeaux2

    5/27

    will typically lend on the basis of information gathered about the borrower, setting the interest

    rate to reflect the risks of lending and any collateral requirements, and managing the risk in a pro-

    active way.

    Clearly if banks dont operate their business well then we would expect to see a higher proportion

    of NPLs. It has been observed that failing banks (those with high NPLs) tend to be located far

    from the efficient frontier (Berger and Humphrey (1992), Barr and Siems (1994), DeYoung and

    Whalen (1994), Wheelock and Wilson (1994)). There is evidence that even among banks that do

    not fail, there is a negative relationship between the non-performing loans and performance

    efficiency (Kwan and Eisenbeis (1994), Hughes and Moon (1995), Resti (1995)). Other empirical

    studies using supervisory data have supported such a negative relationship. For example,

    Peristiani (1996) finds a positive relationship between the cost efficiency and the examiners

    ratings of bank management quality. DeYoung (1997) observes a stronger link between the

    banks management ratings and their assets quality ratings. Some direct measures of bank cost

    and production also show a negative relationships between the NPLs and bank performance

    (Berg, Forsund and Jansen (1992), Hughes and Mester(1993)). So we may observe that banks

    with high NPLs are likely to be low efficiency banks and that NPLs may be associated with poor

    risk management.

    The relationship between NPLs and banks lending decisions is likely to be driven by macro as

    well as micro factors. Thus changes in NPLs may reflect the economic environment. For

    example, an increase in NPLs may signal unanticipated economic deterioration which causes an

    upward revision in the probability of loan default. There may be a natural inclination to tighten

    credit allocation procedures which has the effect of reducing the amount of credit extended and

    an improvement in the quality of assets as bad loans are cleared. Additionally the negative effect

    of NPLs on future lending is often associated with the need of banks to build up capital to protect

    against loan losses. Finally bank managers may be rewarded according to their relative

    performance. If the expectation is that the NPL problem is economy-wide then there will be an

    incentive to avoid further losses in order to be seen to be doing better than the market as a whole.

    So we would expect to see a relationship between NPLs and bank lending decisions driven by

    both market and economy wide factors as well as bank level problems.

  • 7/28/2019 Threshold Paper for Bordeaux2

    6/27

    The particular feature of this paper is to consider the interaction between NPLs and bank lending

    decisions but in the context of a threshold model. Our rationale for using the threshold approach

    is that banks typically make provisions for NPLs up to a specific (normal) level and may also cut

    back on lending in response to increases in NPLs but that when they rise above this point the

    bank begins to respond more aggressively and indeed to start to take more risk. Such a threshold

    will reflect historical factors such as the observed distribution of NPLs (for example banks may

    use a particular confidence interval which implies that they infer a small probability (e.g. 5%) of

    NPLs rising above this level). Alternatively regulations and the actions of the regulatory agencies

    may imply that NPLs up to a certain level require no specific action while beyond the authorities

    start to look more closely at the activities of the particular bank. Of course the appropriateness of

    the threshold model is an empirical matter which we shall take up in the next section.

    The existence of a threshold approach to managing lending may also have implications for the

    credit crunch view of the loans market. If there is a substantial increase in the negative impact of

    NPLs on new lending after a particular level of NPLs are reached then we would expect to see

    credit crunches occurring once this critical level had been reached across the banking sector. In

    other words whilst NPLs are at a level considered normal the possibility of a credit crunch would

    be rather low but once they went generally above this level the chances are significantly

    increased.

    We now turn to the framework in which we shall set up our threshold model. We wish to

    examine the impact of increasing non-performing loans on credit supplies of commercial banks,

    controlling for other factors that affect credit representing demand and supply conditions. For a

    simple commercial bank balance sheet, assets are commercial loans and other earning assets and

    in addition there is cash and other non-earning assets which typically absorb short-term shocks;

    on the liability side, deposits and other short-term funding along with capital are the main

    components. Thus, we can conjecture that the loan growth is affected by deposit growth, capital

    growth and other earning assets growth.

    Thus the supply of loans (Lt) is determined by banks lending capacity, given by deposit growth

    rate and factors that influence banks willingness to provide credits the capital-asset ratio and the

  • 7/28/2019 Threshold Paper for Bordeaux2

    7/27

    risks as measured by NPLs. It might appear that we have ignored revenue considerations but this

    is taken into account through the impact of other earning assets. In other words we would expect

    the growth rate of this element of the portfolio to reflect the relative (to lending) benefits of this

    class of asset in the portfolio. The basic model is as follows:

    1,4,3,2,10, ++++= tititititi NPLGRaOEAGRaCGRaDGRaaLGR (1)

    where the index i is the index for individual banks and t is the index for time period. tiLGR ,

    is the loan growth rate for each bank in each time period t , tiDGR , is the deposit growth rate,

    tiCGR , is the capital growth rate, tiOEAGR , is the other assets growth rate, and 1, tiNPLGR

    is non-performing loan growth rate of the previous time period. The balance sheet constraint

    implies that there will be an adding-up relationship between the growth rates but note that we

    have not included all balance sheet items so this is implicit. In other words shocks to the balance

    sheet are absorbed by the non-included items such as cash and non-deposit liabilities. We have

    argued above that macroeconomic conditions may also affect loan growth. Rather than specify

    the variables we add year dummies to reflect these macro variables which will affect all banks

    but vary over time.

    We can make conjectures about the signs of the coefficients above. As deposits increase at a

    faster rate, lending capacity of the bank increases and hence loan growth should rise. A ceteris

    paribus increase in other earning assets growth would be a signal that they are becoming

    relatively profitable (their return/risk relationship is more favourable). This would reduce lending

    growth. The impact of capital growth would be expected as positive. The reason is that higher

    capital gives the bank more capacity to take risk and hence makes more credit available. Finally

    an increase in NPLs last period would signal worsening lending conditions with higher associated

    risks and a reduction in loan growth as a result.

    As indicated we intend to adopt a threshold approach to our empirical analysis. We can also

    identify how we might expect our responses to be sensitive to the level of NPLs. However as will

    become clear the actual effect is dependent on whether we believe banks are subject to moral

    hazard or not. This is going to be very helpful in establishing the implication of our results.

  • 7/28/2019 Threshold Paper for Bordeaux2

    8/27

    Firstly we consider the case where banks are not subject to moral hazard. Deposit growth is likely

    to exert a smaller positive impact as NPLs rise since banks will use deposit growth to rebuild

    their capital and consequently increase credit less. Similarly when the banks are affected by an

    increasing non-performing loan problem, they are likely to switch to safer assets, such as

    government bonds or treasury bills. As a result of this increased substitution effect, the other

    earning asset growth should have larger negative effect on loan growth. The positive impact of

    capital growth will be moderated as NPLs increase since banks will be concerned to build a

    buffer against loan losses. Finally we would expect that as NPLs increase the NPL growth rate

    has a stronger negative effect.

    Now suppose that banks are subject to moral hazard in that they take more risk as they suffer

    declining performance due to rising NPLs. Increases in deposit growth will now have a larger

    effect on lending since banks will choose to make more risky loans in order to generate higher

    return. The impact of other earning assets will be reduced as the substitution effect fails to

    operate even though there is an increased risk of making loans. Finally we would see an increase

    in lending to be enhanced by capital growth as NPLs increase and banks can offset higher capital

    by taking more risk. Finally we would expect to see a declining effect of NPL growth on credit.

    Beyond this basic specification we also propose to consider an additional threshold based on the

    banks capital ratio. Under the Basle Accord II framework banks are required to adjust their

    capital to reflect the riskiness of the assets they hold. Increases in NPLs would be expected to

    impact on capital requirements as the riskiness of loans increases. According to the Basle Accord

    II, the target ratio of capital to risk weighted assets is set at 8%. Not surprisingly, given the need

    to have a buffer-stock of capital we observe from our data set that the mean capital ratios in our

    samples are all above the required 8%. We define a dummy variable which identifies if the

    capital ratio of the bank is above or below a specific value. We then run an adjusted regression

    equation which is:

    1,,6,5

    4,3,2,10,

    ++

    ++++=

    tititi

    titititi

    NPLGRDummyaDummya

    NPLGRaOEAGRaCGRaDGRaaLGR1-i,t

    (2)

  • 7/28/2019 Threshold Paper for Bordeaux2

    9/27

    The point of equation (2) is that we expect loan growth to be influenced directly by the effective

    capital ratio, as well as allowing the response of lending to growth of NPLs to be influenced by

    whether the bank has met the effective capital ratio. What is exactly this effective capital ratio is

    an empirical question.

    3). The Empirical analysis of Lending and NPLs

    In this paper we use a panel of individual banks balance sheet data across a range of countries.

    We use the standard BIS definition of NPLs1. The argument for this is firstly that the standard

    definition makes it possible to compare the non-performing loan problem across countries and

    banks. Secondly, the BIS definition is a prudential definition for NPLs, which includes loans with

    loss uncertainty as well as those for which a loss has been incurred and hence should be a

    reasonable guide to the banks estimate of how large is the NPL problem.

    Since the variables we use in the regression as explanatory variables are potentially endogenous

    as they are simultaneously determined through banks balance sheet constraints, we apply the

    method of two-stage least squares method using instrumental variables (see Wooldridge (2002)

    for details of this technique in a panel context). We assume banks behaviour is continuous and

    they re-balance the portfolio to the desired level each period (which is reasonable in the context

    of our use of annual data).

    Threshold regression techniques are used to address the question of how bank credit decisions

    relate to the level of NPLs. Threshold models have a wide variety of applications in economics.

    Applications include separating and multiple equilibrium, sample split, mixture models,

    1

    According to the BIS, the standard loan classifications are defined as follows:Passed: Solvent loans; SpecialMention: Loans to enterprises which may pose some collection difficulties, for instance, because of continuing

    business losses; Substandard: Loans for which interest or principal payments are longer than three months in arrears

    of lending conditions. The banks make 10% provision for the unsecured portion of the loans classified as

    substandard; Doubtful: Full liquidation of outstanding debts appears doubtful and the accounts suggest that therewill be a loss, the exact amount of which cannot be determined as yet. Banks make 50% provision for doubtful loans;

    Virtual Loss and Loss (Unrecoverable): Outstanding debts are regarded as not collectable, usually loans to firms

    which applied for legal resolution and protection under bankruptcy laws. Banks make 100% provision for loss loans.

    E use the last three of these classes to define NPLs

  • 7/28/2019 Threshold Paper for Bordeaux2

    10/27

    switching models, etc. Hansen (2000) argues that the understanding of threshold models is a

    preliminary step in the development of statistical tools to handle more complicated statistical

    structures.

    The development of threshold regression models can be traced back to Dagenais (1969). He uses

    the threshold regression technique to analysis the step-like-time-path discontinuous character of

    durable goods. Hansen (1999) develops the panel threshold regression methods for non-dynamic

    panels with individual-specific fixed effects. In the model, the observations are divided into two

    regimes depending on whether the threshold variable itq is smaller or larger than the threshold

    . The two regimes are distinguished by differing regression coefficients 21 , . He shows that

    for any given , the slope coefficient can be estimated by ordinary least squares (OLS). The

    threshold level is identified as the one which generates minimisation of the sum of squared errors.

    Hansens (1999) threshold model is based on a balanced panel. Khan and Senhadji (2001) extend

    the technique to an unbalanced panel. The estimation is carried out using the conditional least

    squares and the threshold is determined at the point that minimises the sum of squared

    residuals. Caner and Hansen (2004) further develop a model with endogenous variables but an

    exogenous threshold variable. We can extend their model to be used for panel data with

    individual-specific fixed effects. The estimation is sequential. The first step is to estimate the

    reduced form parameters by least squares. The second step is to estimate the threshold using

    predicted values of the endogenous variables itz . And the third step is to estimate the slope

    parameters 1 and 2 by 2SLS on the split samples implied by the estimate of . The 2SLS

    estimator for is the minimiser of the sum of squared errors. Caner and Hansen (2004)

    demonstrate that if the threshold variable is exogenous, the estimator is consistent. However, it is

    difficult to know if it is efficient as other estimators are possible and efficiency is difficult to

    establish in nonregular models.

    In our estimation model, there are two thresholds, the non-performing loan rate and capital ratio.

    As both of the two variables are treated exogenous in our model, we can follow Caner and

    Hansen (2004) three step method. In the first step, we estimate the fitted value of

  • 7/28/2019 Threshold Paper for Bordeaux2

    11/27

    tititi CGRDGROEAGR ,,, ,, by using the lagged variables 1,1,1, ,, tititi CGRDGROEAGR as

    the instruments. The second step is to estimate the thresholds using predicted values of the

    endogenous variables''

    ,

    ',, ittiit CGRDGROEAGR . And the third step is to estimate the parameters

    by 2SLS on the split samples implied by the estimates. And the 2SLS estimator is the maximiser

    of QLwhere ==2

    1

    2 )ln(j jj

    nQL .For the full sample, the threshold for itNPLR is chose

    within the interval of ( )%15%,0 with an increment of %1.0 . And for each level of itNPLR , we

    estimate different capital ratio level within the interval of ( )%20%,8 2 with an increment of

    %1.0 . It yields totally 18000 estimated QL s, and the best estimator is chosen by the

    combination of the two thresholds where the QL is maximised.3

    Specifically we determine the thresholds by estimating the models as follows: