third world debt ewp155

Upload: aquila

Post on 09-Apr-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    1/44

    Still Waiting for the Jubilee:Pragmatic Solutions for the

    Third World Debt Crisis

    D A V I D M A L I N R O O D M A N

    Jane Peterson,Editor

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    2/44

    Table of Contents

    Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5

    Repeating History . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11

    International Debt Today . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

    Where Has All the Money Gone? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

    The Devastating Spiral of Debt and Adjustment . . . . . . . . 30

    Pressure to Lend . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40

    Continental Drift . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51

    The Year of Jubilee?. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56

    What To Do about Lending. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62

    Notes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74

    Tables and Figures

    Table 1:International Debt Crises since 1820 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

    Table 2: Share of Government Spending Covered by Foreign

    Borrowing and Devoted to Foreign Debt Service and Basic Social

    Services, Selected Countries, 199697. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24

    Table 3:Reasons IMF and World Bank Pressure for Structural

    Adjustment Is Weaker Than It Seems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48

    Map:Heavily Indebted Poor Countries. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

    Figure 1: Number of Countries Not Servicing All Their Foreign

    Debts, 18201999 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14

    Figure 2: Cumulative Foreign Debt of Developing and

    Former Eastern Bloc Nations, 197099. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

    THE WORLDWATCH INSTITUTE is an independent, nonprofit envi-

    ronmental research organization in Washington, DC. Its mission is to foster

    a sustainable society in which human needs are met in ways that do not

    threaten the health of the natural environment or future generations. To

    this end, the Institute conducts interdisciplinary research on emerging glob-

    al issues, the results of which are published and disseminated to decision-

    makers and the media.

    FINANCIAL SUPPORT for the Institute is provided by the Compton Foun-

    dation, the Geraldine R. Dodge Foundation, the Ford Foundation, the Richard

    & Rhoda Goldman Fund, the William and Flora Hewlett Foundation, W.

    Alton Jones Foundation, Charles Stewart Mott Foundation, the Curtis and

    Edith Munson Foundation, David and Lucile Packard Foundation, John D.

    and Catherine T. MacArthur Foundation, Summit Foundation, Turner Foun-

    dation, U.N. Population Fund, Wallace Genetic Foundation, Wallace Global

    Fund, Weeden Foundation, and the Winslow Foundation. The Institute also

    receives financial support from its Council of Sponsors membersTom and

    Cathy Crain, James and Deanna Dehlsen, Roger and Vicki Sant, Robert Wal-

    lace and Raisa Scriabine, and Eckart Wintzenand from the many other

    friends of Worldwatch.

    THE WORLDWATCH PAPERS provide in-depth, quantitative and quali-

    tative analysis of the major issues affecting prospects for a sustainable soci-

    ety. The Papers are written by members of the Worldwatch Institute research

    staff and reviewed by experts in the field. Regularly published in five lan-

    guages, they have been used as concise and authoritative references by

    governments, nongovernmental organizations, and educational institutions

    worldwide. For a partial list of available Papers, see back pages.

    REPRINT AND COPYRIGHT INFORMATION for one-time academic

    use of this material is available by contacting Customer Service, Copyright

    Clearance Center, at (978) 750-8400 (phone), or (978) 750-4744 (fax), or

    writing to CCC, 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923. Nonacademic

    users should call the Worldwatch Institutes Communication Department at(202) 452-1992, x517, or fax a request to (202) 296-7365.

    Worldwatch Institute, 2001

    ISBN 1-878071-57-2

    Library of Congress Control Number: 2001087743

    Printed on paper that is 100 percent recycled, 80 percent post-

    consumer waste, process chlorine free.

    The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarilyrepresent those of the Worldwatch Institute; of its directors, officers, or

    staff; or of its funding organizations.

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    3/44

    5

    Introduction

    Imagine the distress of Africa, and the Democratic Republicof Congo is the sort of place that comes to mind. Follow-ing nearly a century of traumatic subjugation by Belgium,

    this European-designed nation eventually won independ-

    ence, in 1960, and sank into violence within a week. After

    five years of conflict, a man named Mobutu took power by

    force with the help of the U.S. Central Intelligence Agencyand began a rapacious, 31-year reign.1

    Though Mobutu skillfully cloaked his rule in the lan-

    guage of African nationalismby giving his nation the sup-

    posedly more authentic name of Zaire, for examplethe

    dynamics of colonialism still held sway. He gave foreign com-

    panies access to Zaires vast natural wealth, which included

    an estimated quarter of the worlds copper and half its cobalt,

    and threw his cold war allegiance to the West. In exchange,

    the dictator won generous support from Western investors

    and governments, including billions of dollars in bank loans

    and half of all U.S. aid to black Africa in the late 1970s. Fromthese funds, and from export earnings, he siphoned off a per-

    sonal fortune of some $4 billion by the mid-1980sa sum

    not unduly diminished by the purchase of a dozen estates in

    Continental Europe and chartered-Concorde shopping trips

    to Paris. It would be wrong to suggest, however, that Mobu-

    tu gave nothing to his country. He imported 500 British dou-

    ble-decker buses, built the worlds largest supermarket, and

    erected a steelworks that one banker said the country needed

    like it needs central heating.2

    The descent into hell began in 1975 when Mobutu,

    ACKNOWLEDGMENTS: I thank Cheryl Goodman, Rob Mills, Joan

    Nelson, Kunibert Raffer, Bruce Rich, Christian Suter, and Carol Welch

    for reviewing early drafts of this paper or the State of the Worldchapter

    from which it grew. I am greatly indebted (the metaphor will not be

    denied) to my colleagues Hilary French, Brian Halweil, Michael Renner,

    and Payal Sampat for their reviews. Thanks also to intern Bryan

    Mignone for his capable assistance during the summer of 2000, to Art

    Director Liz Doherty for turning the manuscript into a Paper with her

    usual competence, and to Denise Warden for shepherding us through

    the process. And I thank Jane Peterson, editor and friend.

    To my wife Hoangmai Pham I owe an unpayable debt, for it is she who

    lost most in my struggle to be writer, father, and husband all at once.

    Last, I thank my little son Benjamin, as my father once thanked me, for

    making sure I got up early every morning to write. To him I dedicate

    this work.

    DAVID MALIN ROODMAN is a Senior Researcher at the Worldwatch

    Institute, where he writes about the economics and political economy

    of sustainable development. Mr. Roodman graduated from Harvard

    College with a degree in theoretical mathematics. His book The Natural

    Wealth of Nations: Harnessing the Market for the Environmentappeared in

    1998 and argued that overhauls of government taxation and spending

    policies are needed to make economic development environmentally

    sustainable. During academic year 199899, Mr. Roodman took leave

    from the Worldwatch Institute to take a Fulbright Scholarship in Viet-

    nam. He now works part-time in order to care for his son.

    Figure 3: Net Transfers on Lending into Developing and

    Former Eastern Bloc Nations, Estimated by Type of

    Lender, 197099. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

    Figure 4:Long-term Official Lending to Low-income Developing

    Countries, 197099. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23

    Figure 5: Gross Domestic Product per Person, Latin America

    and Africa, 195099 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

    Figure 6: Number of Countries Not Servicing All Their Foreign

    Debts, by Region, 197099 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52

    Figure 7:Multilateral Lenders: Total Assets and Cumulative

    Loans to 41 Heavily Indebted Poor Countries, End of 1998. . . . . . 65

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    4/44

    7INTRODUCTION

    Heavily

    Indebted

    Poor

    Countries

    MAP

    ListedbyWorld

    Bank(41)

    Notlisted,butcomparablyindebtedandpoor(6)

    Source:

    See

    endnote

    5.

    6 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    caught short by a plunge in the price of copper, threatened to

    default. For the next 15 years, he used his geopolitical lever-

    age to force his creditors to defer his debt paymentsor to

    cover them with new loans. He then essentially defaulted on

    the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF).

    Meanwhile, Zaire entered a brutal economic slide. By themid-1980s, the swollen bellies of the hungry became a com-

    mon sight. A Belgian volunteer reported seeing a little girl

    eating grass and another one who was eating the waste from

    the brewery.She told me she hadnt eaten for three days.3

    Today, Mobutu is deposed and dead, but his legacies live

    on. His family holds his fortune, and his country holds his $12

    billion debt. In a nation with an annual income of $110 per

    capita, each resident theoretically owes foreign creditors $236.4

    Zaires disastrous involvement with foreign borrowing is

    one of the worst (and earliest) cases of its kind in the post-

    colonial era. It represents, if in caricature, the debt troublesthat dozens of other poor countries have run into in recent

    decades. Currently, to use the World Banks measuring sticks,

    some 47 nations are very poorhaving a gross national

    product (GNP) of less than $855 per personand heavily

    indebted, with their governments owing foreigners the

    equivalent of at least 18 months of export earnings. All but

    10 of the 47 are in Africa. (See Map.) For most people in these

    nations, life is hard. Civil wars, coups dtat, corruption,

    AIDS, famine, illiteracy are all relatively common. And

    almost no one thinks these countries can repay more than a

    small fraction of their foreign debts, which now total some

    $422 billion, or $380 per resident.5

    The debt crisis in low-income nationsit is commonly

    called a crisis, though it is actually a slowly developing,

    chronic syndromeis one of two major strains of debt trou-

    ble that have struck the developing world since the 1970s.

    The first, which broke out suddenly in 1982, mainly

    involved middle-income countries, such as Turkey, Mexi-

    co, and most South American nations, as well as the com-

    mercial banks they borrowed from (though low-income

    countries were not completely immune). It largely spent

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    5/44

    9INTRODUCTION

    halved between 1982 and 1988. In the Philippines, a million

    or more desperate peasants moved into the hills, where they

    cleared erodible slopes of protective trees and farmed to sur-

    vive. And in southeastern Brazil, immunization cutbacks

    opened the way for a measles epidemic that killed thousands

    of babies in 1984.7

    The debt crisis in the poorest nations thus confronts the

    world with a dilemma. Critics on one side of the issue point

    to the theft and waste and ask why taxpayers in rich coun-

    tries should let incompetent or unaccountable governments

    off the hook. Debt is a promise to pay, and a promise is a

    moral obligation. But critics on the other side, represented

    most effectively by the international Jubilee 2000 coalition

    of churches and nongovernmental organizations (NGOs),

    decry the chains of debt that enslave the worlds poorest

    nations to the richest ones and, they submit, choke off gov-

    ernment spending for immunizing poor children or teachingthem how to read.

    In 1999, the leaders of the seven leading industrial

    nations (the G7) announced their latest response to the

    debt crisis, the enhanced Debt Initiative for Heavily Indebt-

    ed Poor Countries (HIPCs). It is easily the most far-reaching

    debt reduction offer yet, and a sign of the power of Jubilee

    2000. The HIPC initiative aims to cut the $205 billion debt

    of 41 qualifying nations by some 45 percent within perhaps

    five years. (Six comparably poor and indebted countries are

    not listed for various reasons.) Additionally, Italy, the United

    States, and the United Kingdom, among others, have prom-

    ised to write off all their loans to the HIPC 41, which could

    bring the total reduction to 55 percent.8

    With the debt reduction initiatives, official creditors

    have taken an important step toward resolving the current

    debt troubles, and with another big push from the likes of

    Jubilee 2000, they might go far enough to succeed. However,

    the initiatives only attack the symptoms of debt crisis. Large-

    ly designed by and for creditors, they do little to highlight,

    much less address, the underlying causes. As a result, they

    will almost certainly invite fresh crises in the poorest

    8 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    itself in the early 1990s as banks and borrowing govern-

    ments finally struck compromises on repayment.

    The second strain spread gradually in low-income

    nationsand has worsened to this day. It is different because

    low-income countries, regarded as risky investments by

    commercial bankers, have mainly attracted official lenders:aid agencies, multilateral lenders such as the World Bank

    and the IMF, and export credit agencies (ECAs, which subsi-

    dize a countrys exporters with cheap credit for their cus-

    tomers). While commercial lenders followed the classic

    manic-depressive cycles of private finance, first overrunning

    countries in their eagerness to lend, then retreating en

    masse, official lenders stayed on a more even keel.

    For all their steadiness, though, official lenders also have

    run aground in the poorest nations, and in a way that is

    undermining the worldwide fight for sustainable develop-

    ment. Hundreds of billions of dollars of official loans havedisappeared into corruption, capital flight, weapons buying,

    white elephants, and projects that worked better on paper

    than in practice. And now the need to service debts has cut

    into government budgets for roads, environmental protec-

    tion, primary education, and basic healthcare. Indeed, many

    low-income debtors spent more servicing debts to the

    worlds richest nations in the late 1990s than giving social

    services to their own impoverished citizens. Meanwhile, pri-

    vate investors and local entrepreneursthe proverbial haters

    of uncertaintyhave been discouraged by doubts about

    what debtor governments, cornered by their creditors, will

    do next. Will they raise tariffs on exports? Or print money,

    thereby feeding inflation?6

    Because debt trouble set in gradually in low-income

    countries, no one can point to a particular child dying in

    Mozambique from tetanus or to a particular plot of forest

    cleared by a poor farmer in Honduras and say with confi-

    dence, Debt caused that. But the experience of middle-

    income countries, where debt crisis developed with a

    suddenness that spotlighted the link between cause and

    effect, offers a vivid picture of its impact. In Mexico, wages

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    6/44

    voked a debt crisis in middle-income nations. The project of

    reform must proceed with realism to stand a chance of serv-

    ing, rather than undermining, sustainable development in

    the poorest nations. If they thrive, the rest of the world can

    only benefit.

    Repeating History

    Progress, far from consisting in change, depends on

    retentiveness....Those who cannot remember the past are

    condemned to repeat it.

    George Santayana,Life of Reason, 19050610

    There can be few fields of human endeavor in which

    history counts for so little as in the world of finance. Pastexperience, to the extent that it is part of memory at all,

    is dismissed as the primitive refuge of those who do not

    have the insight to appreciate the incredible wonders of

    the present.

    John Kenneth Galbraith, A Short History

    of Financial Euphoria, 199311

    These days, the future rushes at us so fast as to make thepast seem irrelevant; and to be sure, many of todays expe-riences are unprecedented in human history. The current

    debt crisis, however, is not one of them. In fact, the history of

    international lending repeats itself with remarkable regulari-

    ty, which suggests that in the world of international finance,

    people have done a poor job of learning from the past. At the

    same time, this cyclicity means that there is much experience

    to learn from as the world tries to do better next time.

    Debt, like the wheel, is a useful invention whose origins

    are lost to history. Unlucky Sumerians may have run up the

    earliest known debts, recording them by etching lines in clay

    tablets. Perhaps they were farmers asking their lords forbear-

    ance on taxes, which were payable in bags of grain. Whatev-

    11REPEATING HISTORYSTILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    nations. Rich governments have made important financial

    contributions to the development of poor nations: they have

    stamped out smallpox, funded family planning programs

    that have dramatically slowed population growth, and built

    rural roads and schools. But as long as lending and borrow-

    ing occur in ways that invite trouble, loans from foreign gov-ernments will probably do as much harm as good. 9

    Several major problems lie at the heart of the debt crisis.

    All reflect hard economic and political realities. Rich coun-

    tries restrict imports of crops and clothing and other exports

    of poor countries, effectively demanding loan repayment

    while refusing the goods offered as payment. Official agen-

    cies often lend to poor countries for reasons that have little

    to do with aiding their development and assuring their abil-

    ity to repay loans, and everything to do with winning geopo-

    litical allegiancesor sales for Lockheed Martin and

    Caterpillar. Loans proffered with more genuine intentions ofaiding the borrower run into another problem: they are sup-

    posed to be repaid regardless of results, even though failure is

    to be expected in the difficult business of development.

    Finally, both the agencies that lend and the ones that borrow

    are often insulated from the consequences of their actions.

    This insularity gives free play to bureaucratic tendencies

    toward arrogance, over-optimism, the pursuit of growth in

    lending and borrowing for its own sake, and even corruption.

    Stating each problem so starkly evokes solutions that are

    simple in theory. Creditor countries need to buy more goods

    from debtors. ECAs and other agencies need to put enhanc-

    ing the borrowers ability to service debt before geopolitics

    and domestic politics. An international bankruptcy process

    is needed to make loan write-offs routine and require lenders

    to bear some costs of failure. And so on.

    In practice, however, reform is a challenge as complex as

    it is vital. Powerful business lobbies, for example, protect

    ECAs and import barriers; it will take an equally organized

    political campaign to overcome them. And if official lenders

    become too accountabletoo afraid of failurethen they

    could fall prey to the very herd mentality that once pro-

    10

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    7/44

    13REPEATING HISTORY

    lending was assuming in economic life. In the 1800s, inter-

    national lending became a central artery of capitalism and

    imperialism, and increasingly facilitated the gains and the

    depredations of the industrial age. Within Europe and the

    Americas, cross-border lending fostered economic develop-

    ment that eventually lifted millions of people out of pover-ty. Countries that began industrializing earliest financed

    canals and railroads and factories in places that began indus-

    trializing later, such as the United States and the Italian

    peninsula. Between 1816 and 1913, net capital exports from

    Great Britain, the dominant international lender of the era,

    climbed from some $80 million a year (in dollars of the day)

    to more than $1.1 billion.15

    One measure of the economic effectiveness of foreign

    lending is that, since 1820, it has profited investors who

    diversified and perseveredmore so than lending at home.

    Foreign bonds, with their higher interest rates to reflect risk,were honored often enough to cover losses. But by the same

    token, international lending facilitated the worst abuses of

    capitalismthe Central American banana plantations or

    South African gold mines or American cigar factories that

    exploited workers in slave or near-slave conditions.16

    If international lending has been a handmaiden to

    industrialism, it has been an unruly one. From the boom and

    bust in tulip bulbs, which sent Holland into an economic

    depression in the 1630s, to the Asian crisis of 1997, the

    volatility of financial markets has frequently exacted a harsh

    economic price. In a review of international lending since

    1820, Swiss sociologist Christian Suter identified four major

    waves of international borrowing, occurring roughly every

    50 years. (See Figure 1.) Each terminated with an outbreak of

    debt service incapacitya widespread inability to keep up

    with interest and principal paymentscausing banks and

    bond investors to beat a hasty retreat. The worlds greatest

    economic setbacks, including those in the 1870s, 1930s, and

    1980s, all began this way.17

    These cyclical shifts of capital into and out of developing

    countries are not fully understood. But human psychology is

    12 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    er the precise meaning of these markings, they reveal the

    essence of debt, which has survived unchanged through the

    bewildering innovations of modern finance: debt is a prom-

    ise to pay. And creditis the acceptance of such a promise.12

    Governments have long been major, if not dominant,

    users of credit. To banks and bond investors, governmentsseem the safest bets around. During the late-twentieth-

    century international lending boom, Citibank president

    Walter Wriston expressed the faith in public borrowers when

    he famously declared that countries dont go out of busi-

    ness. And for governments, borrowing is tempting because

    it offers a means of spending without taxingat least

    until the loans come due. In the early 1800s, for instance,

    governments learned to tap newly invented bond markets to

    build canals or railroads, promising their investors the full

    faith and credit of the rising industrial powerhouse of Penn-

    sylvania, say, or the sovereign nation of Brazil.13

    As the Western world has changed, so have the reasons

    that governments borrow. Before the Industrial Revolution,

    rulers took out loans mainly to support courtly extrava-

    gances or make war. In the early 14th century, for instance,

    King Edward III of England borrowed heavily from the lead-

    ing banks of the day, which operated out of Florence, to fund

    his side of the Hundred Years War against France. (He then

    defaulted.) With industrialization came an important new

    motivation for government borrowing: the pursuit of eco-

    nomic development. This rationale was best articulated in

    the early 1800s by Frenchman Claude-Henri Saint-Simon

    and his disciples. In awe of science and technology, the

    Saint-Simonians envisioned a utopia in which reason had

    transformed not only production but government, in which

    technocrats free from bias and political pressure would

    finance and manage economic development according to

    scientific principles. The Saint-Simonians offspring include

    socialism, Marxism, the World Bank, and the IMFand faith

    in lending for development wherever it is expressed. 14

    The Saint-Simonians were off the mark in their unbridled

    optimism, but not in their appreciation of the role that

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    8/44

    15REPEATING HISTORY

    nect two valleys that already had good transportation con-

    nection via the sea. At the same time, local authorities built a

    road over the mountains. In such cases, the cascade of new

    bonds would temporarily cover payments on the old ones

    (since the projects could not). But once one country default-

    ed, creditors would lose confidence and stop lending to othercountries as well, and the crisis would expand, a pattern that

    has sporadically affected commercial lending ever since.19

    Another source of fragility in international lending

    would then become apparent: the ambiguous legal relation-

    ship between lenders and borrowers. It is hard for a lender to

    enforce the law of contracts against a debtor when the debtor

    is the lawharder still when the debtor is a foreign govern-

    ment, and there is no clearly applicable law. As S.C. Gwynne,

    a former U.S. bank loan officer, has put it, international

    banks cannot collect a power plant in Thailand or a hospi-

    tal in Dubai, or even a Caterpillar tractor in the jungles ofKalimantan. They cannot tag a banana crop in the Philip-

    pines, or grab the copper as it comes out of the mine. 20

    Defaults naturally angered the creditors; but in the end,

    they always had to come to terms with their losses, however

    reluctantly. After several U.S. states defaulted in the 1830s, one

    prominent English bond investor excoriated the United States

    as a nation with whom no contract can be made, because

    none will be kept; unstable in the very foundations of social

    life, deficient in the elements of good faith. Such indignation

    is understandable, but misses the reality that sharing losses is

    the companion of lending overshoot. Bankruptcy codes in

    most nations, honed over centuries, recognize that letting a

    bankrupt survive to do business another day is often in the

    interest of all concerned. They also recognize that forcing

    overeager lenders to take a loss teaches a healthy prudence. The

    hole in international law where a bankruptcy code belongs has

    not made international compromise less necessary. But it has

    forced creditors and debtors to negotiate in ad hoc fashion, to

    the detriment of all concerned, especially debtors. Between

    1820 and 1975, a grueling nine years elapsed on average

    between outbreak of a crisis and its resolution.21

    clearly at work in the wildness of the swings. Ignorant of the

    future, investors often look to each other for cues, and so

    move in herds, through euphoria and panic. In a few years

    in the 1870s, for example, net capital exports from Great

    Britain zoomed from $250 million to $500 million a year

    and then crashed to $100 million after foreign governments

    started defaulting.18

    Then, as now, investors drew confidence from various

    rationales during the upswings, many of which contained

    truthBrazil, for example, with its rich resources, industrious

    immigrants, and modern government, was the next United

    States. But excessive investor enthusiasm made fertile ground

    for waste and fraudand, eventually, default. In the 1920s,

    for instance, Colombias federal government borrowed $150

    million ($1.4 billion in 2000 dollars) to drill a rail link under

    a 3,000-meter (9,000-foot) mountain range in order to con-

    STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE14

    1820 1840 1860 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 20000

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60Number

    Source: See endnote 17.

    Number of Countries Not Servicing All Their ForeignDebts, 18201999

    FIGURE 1

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    9/44

    17REPEATING HISTORY

    ApproximateDebtwith

    Period

    SelectedMajorDebtors

    SelectedMajorCreditors

    PaymentProblem

    s

    (billion2000$)

    182630

    G

    reece,LatinAmerica,Spain

    Britishbondinvestors

    3

    184045

    M

    exico,Portugal,Spain,nineU.S.states

    BritishandFrenchbondinvestors

    6

    187582

    E

    gypt,Greece,LatinAmerica,Ottom

    an

    Britishbondinvestors;

    Germanbanks;

    40

    E

    mpire, 1Spain,Tunisia,10southern

    U.S.states

    Frenchgovernment

    18901900

    G

    reece,LatinAmerica,Portugal,Serbia

    GermanandBritishbondinvestors;

    20

    BaringsBank

    191118

    B

    ulgaria,Mexico,OttomanEmpire, 1

    Russia2

    Frenchbondinvestors

    200

    193140

    C

    hina,France,Germany,Greece,Hungary,

    WorldWarIvictors(owedby

    300

    L

    atinAmerica,Poland,Turkey,United

    Kingdom,

    Germany);U.S.government(owedby

    Y

    ugoslavia

    othervictors);Westernbondinvestors

    1982

    L

    atinAmerica,Philippines,Poland,Africa,

    French,WestGerman

    ,Japanese,U.K.,U.S.

    400

    T

    urkey,Yugoslavia

    banks;G7governments;IMF,WorldBank

    1Predecessorto

    modernTurkey.2A

    ccountedforasmuchas85percentofdefaultedam

    ountinthisperiod.

    Source:Seeend

    note23.

    TABLE1

    InternationalDebtCrises

    since

    1820

    STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE16

    Debtors, too, have usually had to swallow their anger.

    Only on rare occasions has a new government come to power

    and declared the debts of its predecessor to be legally odi-

    ous. In 1898, the United States forcibly took over the Span-

    ish colony of Cuba, but refused to assume its debts. The

    former colonial government had used the money to put downan independence movement, even interring suspects in con-

    centration camps. Loans used against the people, the United

    States asserted, should not be the responsibility of the people.

    In the early 1920s, a new government in Costa Rica refuted

    foreign debts contracted by the just-deposed dictator, Federi-

    co Tinoco Granados. U.S. Chief Justice and former President

    William Howard Taft sat as arbitrator in the dispute and sided

    firmly with Costa Rica. He pointed out that the bank knew

    that Tinoco would squirrel away the money for personal use.

    A few such exceptions aside, however, only great powers, or

    nations exiting the capitalist financial system, such as Chinaand Russia after their communist revolutions, have dared

    repudiate their obligations. Most governments opted to com-

    promise with creditors over old loans, no matter how unfair

    the burden, in order to get new ones.22

    Remarkably, the same nations often held the roles of

    debtor or creditor from crisis to crisis. Since 1820, Latin

    American and East European nations have frequently run

    into debt trouble. (See Table 1.) (Most of Africa was off the

    lending map until the 1960s.) Worldwide, at least three quar-

    ters of the countries that avoided debt problems in any of

    four major lending periods between 1820 and 1979 did so in

    the next one as well. The same persistence held among coun-

    tries that didrun into trouble, except that the Great Depres-

    sion had many one-time defaulters. This pattern holds even

    when comparing 18201929 with 198086, with 64 percent

    of problem debtors in the years between Napoleon and

    Hitler resurfacing to haunt lenders in the era of Reagan and

    Thatcher. Meanwhile, a handful of countriesBritain,

    France, Germany, the United States, and Japanaccounted

    for most overlending.23

    This regularity suggests that the tendency to overborrow

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    10/44

    bloc nations has shot upward with barely a pause in recent

    decades, from $270 billion in 1970 to $2.6 trillion in 1999

    (in 2000 dollars). (See Figure 2.) Private investorsmainly

    commercial banks and bond investorshave led in lending,

    with a cumulative $1.2 trillion in outstanding long-term

    loans at the end of 1999. (Less data is available on short-termloans, which are due for repayment within one year.)24

    Not far behind are official lenders, which generally come

    in two stripes. Bilateral agencies, which belong to individ-

    ual governments, held $550 billion in debts at the end of

    1999. Next, the jointly funded multilateral lenders, includ-

    ing the World Bank, the IMF, and regional development

    banks in Africa, Asia, Europe, and Latin America, were owed

    $440 billion. Official lenders can also be categorized by pur-

    pose: export credit agencies, all of which are bilateral, exist

    to stimulate a nations exports of wheat or weapons or con-

    19INTERNATIONAL DEBT TODAY

    0.5

    1.0

    1.5

    2.0

    2.5

    3.0Trillion 2000 Dollars

    0

    Long-term debt to IMF, World Bank,other development banks

    Long-term debt to governments

    Long-term debt to private lenders

    Short-term debt, mainly to private lenders,due for repayment within one year

    1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 1999

    Source: See endnote 24.

    Cumulative Foreign Debt of Developing and FormerEastern Bloc Nations, 197099

    FIGURE 2

    or overlend emerges from deep within a nations character

    and history. One generalization that seems useful is that the

    most internally divided nations make the most troubled

    debtors. Almost all Latin American states, as well as the

    Philippines, inherited from their colonial rulers Spain and

    Portugal an extreme concentration of wealth in the hands ofthe few, which has been perpetuated down through the cen-

    turies. These powerful elites have generally fought off gov-

    ernment efforts to tax them and help those less well off. For

    leaders of such divided societies, foreign borrowing is tempt-

    ing as a way to aid one group by, say, financing coal plants

    to generate jobs and cheap power, without taxing another

    groupor at least to forestall the day of reckoning.

    The current debt crisis stands apart from past ones in

    that governments have been not only the major borrowers,

    but major lenders. Nevertheless, its roots are deep. In the

    recent lending cycle, as in all those before, many loans havebeen put to good use while others have not. And the awk-

    ward drama of overshoot, crisis, and compromise is once

    again playing itself out on the international stage. The

    cyclicity suggests that only a serious attempt to learn from

    history can prevent yet more troubles in the decades ahead.

    International Debt Today

    Modern international debt troubles are at once a familiartale and a standout in the annals of finance. The latestlending upswing began in earnest in the late 1960s. It was

    punctuated by spectacular international crashes in 1982 and

    1997, as well as numerous smaller crises, from Zaires near-

    default in 1975 to Ecuadors troubles in 1999. Most disturb-

    ing for the present, a chronic debt problem has taken shape

    in the worlds poorest nations. The terrain of modern inter-

    national lending troubles is therefore quite complex, and

    best approached at first through the numbers.

    The cumulative debt of developing and former Eastern

    STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE18

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    11/44

    21INTERNATIONAL DEBT TODAY

    developing and Eastern bloc nations then owed foreigners,

    about $250 billion became problem debt, meaning that the

    countries had to defer or cancel promised payments on it

    during the 1980s.27

    Yet the crisis of 1982 left surprisingly slight marks on the

    overall upward trend in debt: it is just discernible in Figure 2as a tiny dip during 1988. One reason for the deceptively

    smooth rise is that when debtors have fallen behind on their

    interest payments in recent decades, creditors have lent

    more to cover part of the interest and avoid formal default.

    As a result, many nations emitted cash to the rest of the

    world even as they went deeper into debt.

    Official creditors have moved on a far different track

    from the commercial lenders who were at the center of the

    1982 crisis. The contrast appears most sharply in statistics on

    net transfers on lendingthe differences between what

    countries receive in new loan disbursements each year andwhat they spend making principal and interest payments on

    old ones. (See Figure 3.) Net transfers between commercial

    lenders and their borrowers have swung wildly since 1970.

    But net transfers from official lenders rose steadily between

    1970 and 1981, from $8 billion to $45 billion (in 2000 dol-

    lars), then gradually went negative as grace periods expired

    and bills for interest and principal payments came due. Even

    the huge IMF and World Bank bailout packages for Brazil,

    Indonesia, South Korea, and other countries since 1997 only

    sent transfers positive momentarily. As a result, developing

    and former Eastern bloc nations gave official creditors $40

    billion more between 1990 and 1999 than they received from

    those creditors.28

    The lowest-income countries still received more as a

    group from official lenders than they paid in the late 1990s

    but only barely, and some individual countries received less.

    (See Figure 4.) Many low-income countries are only main-

    taining the appearance of fully servicing their debts by bor-

    rowing still morea sure sign that a good share of their debt

    is unpayable. Today, some 47 nations, labeled here the

    Worldwatch 47, are heavily indebted and poor according

    STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE20

    struction services by lending the purchase amounts to for-

    eigners, or by guaranteeing repayment of commercial loans

    for the same purpose. They held $390 billion of the debt of

    developing and former Eastern bloc nations. And aid agen-

    cies, both bilateral and multilateral, aim to help poor coun-

    tries develop.25

    On the borrowing side, official bodies dominate. At the

    end of 1999, governments owed or guaranteed fully 81 per-

    cent of the outstanding foreign debt, in the latter case prom-

    ising to repay if a domestic borrower, such as an electric

    utility, does not.26

    In the ideal, governments and government-backed bor-

    rowers would have invested all this money wiselyin every-

    thing from public railroads to business expansion to

    educationin order to earn enough foreign exchange to

    repay the loans. In practice, however, countries often wasted

    substantial sums through corruption, arms buying, and proj-ects that had as much to do with prestige and politics as eco-

    nomics, such as expensive dams. All these uses weakened

    borrowers ability to repay debts. (See Where Has All the

    Money Gone? below.) To complicate matters, falling prices

    for key exports of many developing countries since the

    1970s eroded their ability to earn foreign exchange.

    The debt crisis that struck in 1982 has been the most

    spectacular symptom of these problems. In 1980 and 1981,

    U.S. Federal Reserve Chairman Paul Volcker hiked short-term

    interest rates to an unheard-of 20 percent in order to fight

    inflation. Volcker won his battle, but only after raising inter-

    est rates on many outstanding international bank loans and

    slowing the global economy. High interest rates and global

    recession lit the dry tinder of a decade of excessive lending

    and borrowing. In August 1982, the Mexican Minister of

    Finance, in the words of a U.S. Treasury Department official,

    showed up at our doorstep and turned his pockets inside

    out. Mexico announced that it was close to defaulting on

    $80 billion it owed to U.S. and other banks. As in Asia in

    1997, the crisis then exploded as commercial banks retreated

    from dozens of countries. Altogether, of the $800 billion that

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    12/44

    23INTERNATIONAL DEBT TODAY

    bilateral creditors 37 percent, and multilaterals 32 percent.

    (Excluding the fallen giant Indonesia, official creditors dom-

    inate even more: bilaterals held 45 percent of the debt and

    multilaterals 38 percent.) These figures may understate the

    problem: debt cancellation campaigners at Jubilee 2000 in

    London have argued that Haiti, Jamaica, Zimbabwe, andsome other nations that exceed the World Banks criteria for

    poor and heavily indebted are also deep in debt trouble. 30

    What is beyond debate is that the countries meeting the

    World Bank criteria are among the most troubled on earth.

    Thirty-seven of the Worldwatch 47 rank in or just above the

    U.N. Development Programmes lowest category of human

    development. This generally means that babies born there

    can be expected to live 4050 years, that fewer than half the

    children and young adults attend school or college, and that

    barely half the adults can read. Despite all the problems,

    1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 19950

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    30

    35Billion 2000 Dollars

    Source: See endnote 29.

    1999

    Long-term Official Lending to Low-income DevelopingCountries, 197099

    FIGURE 4

    Amount consumed by principal andinterest payments on old long-termofficial loans.

    22 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    to criteria set by the World Bank, generally meaning that

    each has a GNP per capita under $855 a year, and that itsgovernments foreign debts are equivalent to at least 18

    months of export earnings.29

    The Worldwatch 47 include most of Africa, as well as

    Bolivia, Guyana, Honduras, and Nicaragua; Afghanistan and

    Pakistan; and Cambodia, Indonesia, Myanmar, and Vietnam.

    Together, these nations owed $422 billion to foreign credi-

    tors at the end of 1999. That is equal to $380 per resident

    on the debtor sidea substantial sum in such poor coun-

    tries, but equivalent to only 11 months of Western military

    spending. Commercial banks held 31 percent of the debt,

    1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000-150

    -100

    -50

    0

    50

    100

    150

    Transfers into Borrowing Countries

    Source: See endnote 28.

    (Billion 2000 dollars)

    Commercial lenders

    Official lenders

    Net Transfers1 on Lending into Developing and FormerEastern Bloc Nations, Estimated by Type of Lender,197099

    FIGURE 3

    Note: The swings in commercial lending have mainly af fected middle-income countries.1Net transfers are disbursements of new loans minus interest and principal payments onold ones.

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    13/44

    25

    their debts. Economist Daniel Cohen at the Organisation for

    Economic Co-operation and Development in Paris has

    drawn on the experience of middle-income debtors in the

    1980s to project how much poor countries will ultimately

    pay on their loans from both commercial and public lenders.

    His techniques suggest that the Worldwatch 47 are political-ly and economically capable of paying back $131 billion, or

    about 31 percent of their $422 billion in debt. The other

    $291 billion, this implies, is gone for good.32

    These stark numbers confront the world with a dilemma.

    Should official creditors cancel most of their loans to coun-

    tries in such desperate straits? Or will annulment only

    reward corruption and dictatorship? The numbers pose the

    dilemma, but they cannot untangle it. Doing thatassessing

    how best to end the official debt crisis and prevent its recur-

    rencerequires peering behind the cold numbers. The next

    three sections present the tragedy in all its dimensionshuman and environmental, economic and political. They

    describe the waste that led to the crisis, and official creditors'

    failed attempts to end it by lending still more. And they

    examine how lenders came to be agents and accomplices of

    the debacle.

    Where Has All the Money Gone?

    After years of studying our foreign aid program, we havelearned that foreign aid is only as good as the recipient

    government. Foreign aid only reinforces the status quo. It

    cannot transform an antidemocratic process working

    against the majority into a participatory government

    shaped in its interests. Where the recipient government

    answers only to a narrow economic elite or foreign cor-

    porations, our aid not only fails to reach the hungry,

    it girds the very forces working against them.

    Frances Moore Lapp, Joseph Collins, and Peter

    Rosset , World Hunger: Twelve Myths, 199833

    WHERE HAS ALL THE MONEY GONE?

    many of these countries are forced to spend more on foreign

    debt service than on basic social services. (See Table 2.) In

    Zambia, the government devoted 40 percent of its national

    budget to foreign debt payments in 1997 and only 7 percent

    to basic health and education, clean water, sanitation, fami-

    ly planning, and nutrition combined. The death rate amongchildren there is rising, partly because a third of those under

    five have not received the vaccines they need, even though

    they are cheap and effective.31

    Also beyond debate is that these countries are so deep in

    debt that most can repay only a fraction of their loans.

    Today, you can buy commercial IOUs of Benin or Rwanda for

    about 10 cents on the dollar. Honduras commercial debt

    goes for 25 cents on the dollar. Private investors, in other

    words, do not expect the Worldwatch 47 to repay most of

    24 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    Share Covered Share Devoted Share Devotedby Foreign to Foreign to Basic Social

    Country Borrowing Debt Service Services

    (percent)

    Belize2 8 6 20Benin3 29 11 10Bolivia3 16 10 17Burkina Faso3 20 10 20Cameroon4 36 36 4El Salvador2 47 27 13Jamaica2 14 31 10Nepal3 33 15 14Nicaragua2 14 14 9Zambia3 13 40 7

    1Basic social services include basic health and education, clean water,sanitation, family planning, and nutrition. 2Data for 1996. 3Data for1997. 4Data for 199697.Source: See endnote 31.

    TABLE 2

    Share of Government Spending Covered by ForeignBorrowing and Devoted to Foreign Debt Service andBasic Social Services, Selected Countries, 1996971

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    14/44

    27WHERE HAS ALL THE MONEY GONE?

    Borrowers spent billions more on weapons. At best, the

    tanks and planes were the economic equivalent of Swiss

    bank accounts: financial sinkholes. At worst, they were tools

    of repression and impoverishment in the hands of despots.

    During 197282, non-oil-exporting developing countries

    spent an amount equal to 20 percent of their borrowings onarms from western exporters, according to the Stockholm

    International Peace Research Institute. Rough estimates indi-

    cate that sub-Saharan Africa imported $7 billion in weapons

    in 1987, and $1 billion in 1997 (the decline being a sign of

    the end of cold war). These imports fed internal or cross-bor-

    der wars involving at least 17 African debtor nations, includ-

    ing Angola, Ethiopia, Liberia, and Uganda. In 1999, the

    Indonesian military, a longtime customer of western lenders

    and arms manufacturers, used British Hawk fighter jets to

    back its violent rampage against East Timorese who had

    voted for independence. As U.N. peacekeeping troops movedin, the country defaulted on $250 million in loans for the

    Hawks. The British government then swooped in to save the

    banks since it had guaranteed the loans. In effect, British tax-

    payers paid for the Hawks used over East Timor.37

    The evidence of the extent of theft and arms buying

    seems to imply that the debt crises in low-income countries

    is a simple matter of despotism run amok. Indeed, few of

    the Worldwatch 47 had mechanisms to hold governments

    accountable to the governed, such as a legislature elected

    through free and fair elections. Their average score on Free-

    dom Houses seven-point political rights scale was a high 5.9

    in the 1970s and 1980s (indicating a lack of political rights)

    and 5.1 in the 1990s.38

    But the truth is more subtle. Following the historical pat-

    tern, debt trouble has arisen most in nations that are deeply

    rivenwhether by wealth, as in Latin America, or by ethnic-

    ity, as in Africa, where colonial powers stamped a coarse

    political map over a finer tribal tapestry. In Bolivia in the

    mid-1980s, the wealthiest fifth of the people earned 15 times

    as much as the poorest fifth; this societal division led to a

    degeneration of politics into...fierce battles of the ins ver-

    26 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    During their annual gathering in 1999, the leaders of theG7 launched the enhanced Debt Initiative for HeavilyIndebted Poor Countries, which set a goal of canceling about

    45 percent of the government debt of 41 eligible poor coun-

    tries. It seemed a generous move, but it was in fact a recon-

    ciliation with reality, since most of the debt will probablynever be repaid. The reconciliation was only partial at that:

    economist Cohen estimates that the HIPC 41 can repay

    roughly $49 billion of their $205 billion debtfar less than

    they would still owe on paper.34

    Such big losses provoke a blunt question: Where did all

    the money go? It is impossible to make a precise accounting.

    In the electronic age, disbursed loan monies move with the

    speed of lightning. And many of the people and organiza-

    tions moving the money cloak their operations in secrecy.

    Among the Worldwatch 47, the 17 included in Transparency

    Internationals (TIs) 2000 corruption survey scored an aver-age of only 2.6 out of 10 (with a lower number indicating

    more corruption). In addition, the relationship between how

    loans are used and how easily they are repaid is complex.

    Some countries, for example, may have put their loans to

    good use, only to encounter debt trouble as the rising price of

    oil consumed their foreign exchange. Conversely, others may

    have wasted much of their borrowings but stayed ahead of

    their debts through strong economic growth.35

    On balance, however, the scale of the debt trouble in the

    poorest nations points to widespread waste, misuse, or fail-

    ure of development projects. For instance, much of the

    money borrowed from abroad in the name of the poor head-

    ed right back out to foreign bank accounts held by rich com-

    patriots. In Latin America, the rise in public foreign debt

    during 197684 was roughly matched by the simultaneous

    outflow of private capital to banks in New York, the Cayman

    Islands, or other financial capitals. In Haiti, dictator Baby

    Doc Duvalier pulled together a private fortune worth $1.5

    billion. Worldwide, according to TIs rule of thumb, 1020

    percent of the spending financed by export credit agencies

    goes to kickbacks.

    36

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    15/44

    29WHERE HAS ALL THE MONEY GONE?

    old Minister. Tanzania spent some $2 billion building roads,

    which disintegrated nearly as fast as they were paved for lack

    of maintenance. According to a World Bank review, 56 per-

    cent of Bank-financed projects in Africa in the 1990s ended

    with satisfactory results. But only 29 percent were seen as

    likely to benefit a countrys development in the long run.41

    Indonesia, the largest debtor among the Worldwatch 47,

    has been home to some of the most financially and ecologi-

    cally ruinous projects. Since the late 1980s, the countrys

    pulp and paper industry has expanded almost eightfold on

    the strength of loans and guarantees from North American

    and European ECAs wanting to stimulate exports of machin-

    ery. The industrial buildup has been financially risky, since

    the companies have not arranged for an adequate, sustain-

    able, legal supply of timber from tree plantations, according

    to Christopher Barr at the Center for International Forestry

    Research in Indonesia. And it has been ecologically destruc-tiveas companies have cleared 800,000 hectares (2 million

    acres) of rainforest to feed the mills, and have established

    vast tree plantations on land inhabited by indigenous

    peoples. The economic crisis in Indonesia has thrown the

    $13 billion in overseas debt of the pulp and paper industry

    into doubt. Foreign bonds of the largest company, Asia Pulp

    and Paper, sold for just 40 cents on the dollar in November

    2000. Yet none of the plants has shut down. Rather, some

    companies are building more plants in order, they say, to

    repay their debts.42

    It would be unrealistic to expect countries to use everypenny of loans perfectly. Sustainable development is

    extremely difficult business. And rich countries have man-

    aged to develop despite their own histories of government

    waste and corruption. But the losses here are large enough

    that the systemic problems cannot be ignored. And they

    have been occurring long enough that lenders also bear part

    of the responsibility: The disappearance of funds is no secret,

    nor is the inability of the poorest countries to repay their

    debt. Yet it is todays debtor governmentsnot the lenders,

    and not, in many cases, the predecessor governments that

    28 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    sus the outs, according to economists Juan Antonio

    Morales and Jeffrey D. Sachs. One effect has been fiscal

    indiscipline, since powerful high-income groups veto the

    income and wealth taxes that would be needed to finance

    public spending to create jobs or aid the poor. In the 1970s,

    Bolivian governments borrowed heavily to expand the pub-lic payroll without raising taxes, and thus defer the underly-

    ing political conflict between the elites and urban workers.

    That made political sense but was consumption from the

    point of view of loan repayment, not investment.39

    Moreover, many authoritarians were genuinely ambi-

    tious for their nations economic development. Unwitting

    heirs of Saint-Simon, they took out loans to build their

    dreams. In many cases, they used the money well. Indeed,

    two big developing-country borrowersBrazil in the 1970s

    and South Korea laterwon the imprimatur of economic

    miracle for their rapid growth in production and exports.Brazil invested its massive foreign borrowings in dams and

    nuclear power, in cement, steel, aircraft, and weapons man-

    ufacture, and more. Whatever their environmental and

    social merits, some of these investments paid off financially.

    And South Korea poured money into everything from

    schools to steel plants, industrialized rapidly, and brought

    down poverty.40

    That said, the vision of development embodied in many

    countries investment programs was unrealistic or politically

    distorted. Especially in the poorest nations, it was unrealistic

    because it naively fixated on the most-visible aspects ofmodernitythe roads and rails, dams and pipelines that

    writer Catherine Caufield calls the talismans of change. In

    fact, these assets all depend on less-visible assets such as

    skilled workers, reasonably competent government, rule of

    law, an intact environment, and a fabric of small and medi-

    um-sized businesses and civic organizations. These assets

    were especially scarce in low-income nations, or were active-

    ly undermined by the projects themselves. After Mozam-

    bique gained independence from Portugal in the 1970s, its

    Ministry of Education had five people, including a 23-year-

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    16/44

    31THE DEVASTATING SPIRAL OF DEBT AND ADJUSTMENT

    tributed to economic crisis. Within these nations, the poor

    and the environment have paid the greatest price.

    The shocks and strains of the global economy during the

    past quarter century have affected nations first by disrupting

    their balance of payments. When countries came to the

    global market to sell their economic harvesttheir copper orcoffee or cocoaand used the proceeds to buy oil, machin-

    ery, or bank credit, their books no longer balanced. Scores of

    developing countries borrowed foreign currency to get by.

    Such balance-of-payments borrowing can make sense for a

    government the way that living off a credit card can make

    sense for a worker laid off in an industry slowdown. If the

    industry recovers quickly, then the worker will get a new job

    before borrowing too much; or if the cutbacks are perma-

    nent, the worker can use the line of credit to invest in train-

    ing for a new career.

    For the East Asian tigers, among others, things workedout well: they rode out the transient shocks, adjusted to the

    longer-term strains, grew fast, and reduced poverty. But for

    most developing countries, borrowing to balance payments

    became the next stage in a dysfunctional relationship with

    foreign credit. Their economies and export earnings did not

    grow fast enough to keep up with the additions to their debt.

    As a result, the borrowing effectively deferred tough eco-

    nomic choices and made those choices more painful when

    they arrived.44

    The year 1982 was a watershed in balance-of-payments

    lending. Before Mexicos fateful announcement, rich-countrybanks were cooperative, if increasingly nervous, providers of

    ample finance to dozens of poorer nations. But afterwards,

    the climate could not have been more different, as nations

    from Argentina to Zambia repeatedly came within a hair of

    defaulting. The worlds most powerful banks, governments,

    and international lending agencies presented debtors with a

    solid front and a stark choice: repudiate some of their debts,

    alienate great powers such as the United States, and risk los-

    ing all ability to borrow abroad for the foreseeable futureor

    accept the debt burdens, and try, in the economists word, to

    30 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    ran up the debtsthat have been expected to absorb the

    costs by repaying loans in full.

    The Devastating Spiral of Debt andAdjustment

    The fact that so much of todays staggering debt was irre-

    sponsibly lent and irresponsibly borrowed would matter

    less if the consequences of such folly were falling on its

    perpetrators.Today, the heaviest burden of a decade of

    frenzied borrowing is falling not on the military or on

    those with foreign bank accounts or on those who con-

    ceived the years of waste, but on the poor who are hav-

    ing to do without necessities, on the unemployed who

    are seeing the erosion of all that they have worked for, on

    the women who do not have enough food to maintain

    their health, on the infants whose minds and bodies are

    not growing properly because of untreated illnesses and

    malnutrition, and on the children who are being denied

    their only opportunity ever to go to school.[I]t is hard-

    ly too brutal an oversimplification to say that the rich got

    the loans and the poor got the debts.

    James P. Grant, Executive Director, UNICEF, 198943

    The years since 1973 have been troubled ones for the glob-

    al economy. Oil prices and interest rates have gyrated attimes. Stock market investors and bankers have stampeded

    into and out of emerging markets from Mexico to Thailand.

    More subtly, rich countries have fortified their trade barriers

    against many principle exports of developing countries, cost-

    ing them billions of dollars. In response to all these pressures,

    developing countries have often borrowed from foreign

    commercial banks, the World Bank, or the IMF, hoping this

    would tide them over the rough spots. But many countries,

    especially in Africa, instead slipped into a downward spiral:

    economic hardship led to borrowing and growing debt con-

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    17/44

    33THE DEVASTATING SPIRAL OF DEBT AND ADJUSTMENT

    and public investment usually plunged. Private investors

    were spooked by doubts about the economic future of debtor

    nations. And governments preoccupied with meeting their

    next debt payments cut back on investment in infrastruc-

    ture, health care, and education. As debtor economies ate

    their seed corn, output fell, unemployment climbed, andpoverty spread.47

    Another source of the growth slowdown was falling

    demand and sagging prices for exports of debtor nations. In

    the first half of 1985, for instance, Thailand exported 31 per-

    cent more rice than a year beforeand earned 8 percent less.

    An index of the terms of trade of non-oil-exporting devel-

    oping countries, which measures how much they could

    import with the earnings from a given volume of their

    exports, fell from 100 in 1970 to 76 in 1985, before recover-

    ing to around 85 by the late 1990s. Prices fell in part because

    1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 20000

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250Inflation-Adjusted, Indexed to 1950

    Source: See endnote 46.

    Latin America

    Africa

    Gross Domestic Product per Person, Latin America andAfrica, 195099

    FIGURE 5

    32 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    adjust. Bowing to the inevitable, each troubled debtor

    negotiated new repayment schedules with its creditors, to cut

    payments in the short run. With support from the U.S. gov-

    ernment, the IMF and the World Bank (which are interna-

    tional financial institutions, or IFIs) then offered the debtors

    new loans. But these adjustment loans were smaller thanthose the commercial banks had once offered, and did not

    relieve most governments financial distress.45

    In return for the new loans, the IFIs demanded that bor-

    rowers make major economic reforms, known as adjust-

    ment, stabilization, or austerity programsin theory,

    the economic equivalent of retraining for the laid-off work-

    er. In practice, the pressure to pay debts drove borrowers

    economic policies as much as any blueprint drawn up by the

    IFIs. For like families fallen on hard times, debtor nations

    had few economic options. To squeeze foreign exchange out

    of their economies, they had to spend less or earn more. Therebalancing had to occur within each governments budget,

    through spending cuts or tax hikes. It also had to occur with-

    in the nations trade flow, through higher export earnings or

    lower import spending.

    For most adjusting countries, already reeling from bal-

    ance-of-payments problems, the full-repayment-through-

    austerity strategy succeeded only in prolonging paralysis.

    Between 1950 and 1980, gross domestic product (GDP) per

    person had risen 105 percent in Latin America and 72 per-

    cent in Africa. But between 1980 and 1999, GDP per capita

    fell in Latin America and then gradually recovered for a netincrease of only 4.3 percent. It fell 6.2 percent in Africa over

    the same period. (See Figure 5.) Statistical analysis by econo-

    mist Daniel Cohen supports the conclusion that debt prob-

    lems figured in the slowdown: the more vulnerable to

    eventual debt trouble a country seemed to be in 1980, judg-

    ing by vital signs such as its ratio of foreign debt to GDP, the

    less it grew from then on, other factors being equal.46

    The fundamental problem with austerity was that it put

    short-term goals before long-term strategies for economic

    development. In countries that practiced austerity, private

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    18/44

    have affected health budgets, but available data did not per-

    mit a clear determination.) Zaire fired a fifth of its school-

    teachers in 1984, according to Susan George of the

    Transnational Institute. Tanzania, a country once known for

    nearly universal primary education, was forced to introduce

    school fees in 1986, thus shutting out the poorest children.

    50

    Some of societys weakest members adjusted with their

    lives. UNICEF estimated that half a million children died

    each year in developing countries in

    the late 1980s as economic hardship

    slowed the long-term decline in child

    mortality. In northeast Brazil, where

    mothers struggled to feed themselves

    and their families, the incidence of low

    birth weight, which had held stable

    around 10.2 percent of births in the

    five years through 1982, jumped to15.3 percent in 1984. Infant mortality

    rose too. In 1982, nine out of every 100

    babies died in their first year, down

    from 16 in 1977. But by 1984, the figure had climbed back

    to 12. Meanwhile, in the southeastern state of So Paulo,

    government immunization cutbacks opened the way for a

    measles epidemic that killed thousands of babies.51

    In many countries, government cutbacks and recession

    caused layoffs and reduced the effective wages of those still

    working. In Mexico, inflation-adjusted wages halved

    between 1982 and 1988. Food prices tripled in the Jamaicancapital of Kingston as subsidies were slashed. Turkeys 1980

    adjustment program led to price increases for goods sold by

    government companies, such as gasoline and fertilizer,

    which effectively cut workers wages by 45 percent between

    1979 and 1985. Most of the burden of adjustment, con-

    cluded World Bank Chief Economist Stanley Fischer in 1989,

    has been borne by wage earners in the debtor countries.52

    The stresses of adjustment have also taken a toll on the

    environment, but again the story is complex. In Thailand,

    the government lowered tariffs to stimulate exports of rice

    35THE DEVASTATING SPIRAL OF DEBT AND ADJUSTMENT

    Most of the

    burden of

    adjustment . . .

    has been borne

    by wage earners

    in the debtorcountries.

    34 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    each nation that tried to bring in more foreign exchange by

    increasing exports of wheat or tropical timber was compet-

    ing with dozens pursuing the same strategy. In addition, rich

    industrial nations spent the 1980s and 1990s raising import

    barriers against shirts and sugar and other exports of devel-

    oping countriesand subsidizing their own exports of thoseproducts. Erasing these barriers today, estimates the World

    Bank, would raise export earnings of developing countries by

    more than $100 billion a yearenough, if it had been accru-

    ing since 1982, to repay all the debts. In effect, rich countries

    have demanded that poor countries repay debts but refused

    the goods offered as payment.48

    Like the benefits of borrowing, the costs of austerity have

    been spread unevenly within debtor nations. In low-income

    nations, where the debt crisis has arisen gradually, and is just

    one cause of poverty, the effects are difficult to pinpoint. In

    contrast, debt trouble arrived suddenly in the early 1980s inmiddle-income nations such as Brazil and Thailand and

    Turkey, which makes the link between cause and effect clear-

    er, and hints at the effects of debt trouble elsewhere. In

    general, constituencies that supported the government

    and gained from the original loans, such as the urban mid-

    dle class and ruling elites, used their influence to shift costs

    of repayment onto those less fortunate. There were excep-

    tions: the poorest of the poorsuch as Guatemalan Indians

    living in the mountains beyond paved roads and power

    lineswere often too isolated from the commercial econo-

    my to notice its ups and downs. And some small land-own-ing farmers who plugged into global markets benefited from

    adjustments stimulus to exports. But they were the excep-

    tions that proved the rule.49

    As a group, for example, the poor appear to have suffered

    disproportionately from adjustment-related government cut-

    backs. Between 1980 and 1993, social spending fell in adjust-

    ing nations, according to a World Bank study. And within

    education budgets, primary educationincluding the one-

    room schoolhouses in dirt-poor hamletstook larger cuts

    than universities serving urban elites. (Similar trends may

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    19/44

    IFIs argued, then investors would take risks again, economies

    would grow, and tax revenues and foreign exchange would

    flow into government coffers. Structural adjustment brought

    the anti-government economics of Reagan and Thatcher to

    the developing world.

    Unfortunately, structural adjustment loans, like thebelt-tightening austerity loans before them, mainly succeed-

    ed in perpetuating paralysis. With respect to core economic

    policy goals, most of the evidence says that IFI-backed

    adjustment programs have reduced investment, left inflation

    unchanged, and given at most a modest boost to economic

    growth and the balance of payments.56

    In contrast with austerity programs, which had a certain

    inexorable logic, structural adjustment stood on shaky theo-

    retical ground. True, countless heavy-handed government

    interventions were hampering economic development in

    many countries in the 1970s. Bloated civil services and cor-rupt leaders drained away revenue. Complex, constantly

    changing import controls bewildered traders. But it did not

    follow that paring government down wholesale would bring

    economic rebirth.

    Historically, what has mattered most for development is

    not whether governments intervened in the workings of the

    economy, but the fine details of how they did so. The

    economies that have grown fastest in the last 200 years

    including China, Japan, South Korea, and the United

    Statessaw extensive government involvement in trade and

    industry. In a statistical survey of developing countries expe-riences with economic growth since 1975, Harvard econo-

    mist Dani Rodrik found that two factors best predicted

    the growth rate of an economy: how much the country

    invested, and whether the government held the domestic

    economy steady amidst the turbulence of the global

    economy. Keeping inflation under control and the currencys

    exchange rate realistic, major goals of basic austerity

    plans, mattered. But the openness to foreign trade and

    investment that structural adjustment aimed forpart

    of globalizationdid not show up as significant by

    THE DEVASTATING SPIRAL OF DEBT AND ADJUSTMENT 3736 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    and rubber. This encouraged farmers to shift toward those

    crops and away from more soil-damaging cassava farming.

    But it also encouraged them to clear rainforests for new rub-

    ber plantations. Economic recession slowed consumerism

    and cut pollution by shutting down factories in many coun-

    tries. But it also drove at least a million desperately poor Fil-ipinos into the forested mountains, where they cleared steep,

    erodible slopes to grow food. Likewise, poor Venezuelans

    splayed out along the tributaries of the Amazon to blast

    rocks for bits of gold.53

    Adjustment has also taken a toll on environmental pro-

    tection agencies. Nine of 12 case studies of adjusting coun-

    tries commissioned by the World Wide Fund for Nature

    found such cuts. In Zambia, Tanzania, and Cameroon,

    wrote project director David Reed, policymakers tried to

    protect government employees while cutting out the funds

    that would allow them to perform their jobs properly.In ElSalvador, environmental institutions were systematically gut-

    ted over the years. Such cuts may hurt more in the long

    term than the short term, since young environmental agen-

    cies in developing countries often wield little effective power,

    but will gain strength over time if properly supported.54

    And the need for foreign exchange has spurred export-

    oriented mining, logging, and agriculture in developing

    countries. Several studies have found a statistical link

    between high debt burdens and deforestation. Debt pressure

    is also one reason many developing countries made their

    laws more inviting to foreign mining companies in the1980s. In Tanzania, the share of mining in the countrys GDP

    climbed 19 percent in the late 1980s.55

    By the mid-1980s, it became clear that austerity was only

    prolonging and deepening most borrowers problems with

    debt and adjustment. In response, the World Bank and the

    IMF increasingly pressed troubled debtors to make still deep-

    er reforms in exchange for new loansto make structural

    adjustments. If governments privatized state enterprises,

    ended subsidies, removed barriers to foreign trade and

    investment, and generally got out of the way of business, the

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    20/44

    39THE DEVASTATING SPIRAL OF DEBT AND ADJUSTMENT

    a-month hyperinflation drove these changes, not the later

    pressure from IFIs. Natural and human disasters also ham-

    pered compliance. In Malawi, in 1986, drought in the south-

    ern half of the country and an influx of 700,000 hungry

    refugees from war in Mozambique pushed the government

    into reversing its commitment to end fertilizer and crop sub-sidies. Then too, lending millions of dollars to governments

    uncommitted to reform bolstered forces protecting the status

    quo. And the IFIs general hesitance to stop lending seriously

    undermined their leverage. (See Pressure to Lend below.)60

    During the 1980s and 1990s, the IFIs made adjustment

    loans to every African nation. But according to a recent World

    Bank report, only twoGhana and Ugandasustained much

    commitment to reform. The authorized history of the World

    Bank published in 1997 concluded: Perhaps the only argu-

    ment that will convince the critics of reform [in Africa] that

    they are wrong will be several cases of definite structuraladjustment successesand these have not yet occurred.61

    The main, if unintentional, effect of adjustment loans,

    thenfor both austerity and structural adjustmentwas not

    to transform economic policy in debt-ridden nations. Rather,

    it was to prolong the hope and insistence among creditors

    that the nations would eventually pay all their debts. This

    insistence left debtors staggering from one payment resched-

    uling agreement to the next. In the end, the pursuit of full

    repayment did not burnish the reputations of debtor nations

    among investors the way the creditors argued it would.

    Instead, it stymied economic growth and exacted a pricemeasured in the misery of those least able to defend against

    it. And it increased the pile of unpayable debts it was meant

    to diminish.

    38 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    themselves.57

    Peering deeper, the key to economic stability was politi-

    cal cohesion. Most governments that stabilized their

    economies amidst oil shocks, gyrating international interest

    rates, and global recession had strong mechanisms for reach-

    ing political consensus and compromise. Those mechanismsincluded democracy, as in South Korea and Thailand during

    the recent Asian economic crisis, and social programs that

    made almost everyone economically secure, as under the

    dictatorship of Singapore. Lack of social cohesion, on the

    other hand, led the likes of Bolivia to print money and court

    hyperinflation rather than confront politically risky choices

    about whose taxes to raise. The paths to high investment

    were also diverse. In some countries, private entrepreneurs

    took much of the initiative; in others, they were closely

    supervised by government planners; in still others, govern-

    ments did much of the investing themselves. What matteredmost was that it happened. The lesson of history, Rodrik

    concludes, is that ultimately all successful countries devel-

    op their own brand of national capitalism. When it comes

    to economic development, one size does not fit all.58

    Not only was the structural adjustment advice of ques-

    tionable value, it was also regularly ignoredor unnecessary.

    In dozens of case studies, independent economists and polit-

    ical scientists have documented how borrowing govern-

    ments typically sidestepped the promises they made in

    adjustment agreements with the World Bank and the IMF, or

    obeyed the letter but not the spirit, or agreed to steps they

    would have taken anyway.59

    The reasons for this surprising record are several. For one,

    as Rodrik suggests, domestic politics mainly determined eco-

    nomic policies. In Zambia, for example, in 198687, strikes by

    government workers and riots over a 120 percent price

    increase for staple foods forced the government to restore

    food subsidies and abandon its structural adjustment pro-

    gram. Bolivia, by contrast, didenact an adjustment program,

    laying off state workers and raising taxes in 198586but

    domestic political support for drastic steps to end 50 percent-

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    21/44

    41PRESSURE TO LEND

    waging geopolitical battles, generating contracts for compa-

    nies back home, or increasing lending for its own sake.

    Economist John Kenneth Galbraith has observed that in

    commercial finance, speculative cycles share certain univer-

    sal ingredients, including the extreme brevity of the finan-

    cial memory and the popular imagination settl[ing] onsomething seemingly new in the field of commerce or

    finance. Both those elements were present in the postwar

    international commercial lending boom. By the late 1960s,

    the retirement of bankers old enough to remember the

    defaults of the 1930s enabled the historical amnesia of big

    banks. And several seemingly new developments in the field

    of finance appeared: the rise of the London-based Eurodol-

    lar marketa regulatory twilight zone in which banks lent

    to each other in a currency from one continent while oper-

    ating on another; an avalanche of petrodollarsdeposits

    from conservative oil sheiks seeking the safety of big banks;and rapid economic growth in countries such as Brazil and

    Kenya. The Eurodollar market became the machinery for

    arranging large international loan deals. Petrodollars provid-

    ed a good share of the fuel. And developing countries that

    were experiencing growth spurts comprised the seemingly

    safe customer base.64

    As the competition for market share heated up between

    the likes of Chase Manhattan and the Bank of Tokyo, man-

    agers pressed their loan officers to get dollars out the door.

    Author Anthony Sampson captured the mood in his descrip-

    tion of the 1980 World Bank-IMF meeting, which, as a gath-ering of the worlds finance ministers, attracted eager

    bankers:

    Through the main entrance more bankers are swarming

    in, whose roving eyes suggest a very practical

    purpose.Across there a pack of Japanese bankersis con-

    verging on a finance minister. Along the corridor a grave-

    looking French bankerlooks as if he is in full pursuit of

    new African prey.Many of them begin to look not so

    much like bankers as financial middle-men, contact men,

    orcould it really be?salesmen.For these men who

    40 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    Pressure to Lend

    Today marks the beginning...of a period that will be

    eventful, perhaps decisive, for us and for the world.

    [T]he United States and other like-minded nations find

    themselves directly opposed by a regime with contraryaims and a totally different concept of life.I believe that

    we should make available to peace-loving peoples the

    benefits of our store of technical knowledge[a]nd

    should foster capital investment in areas needing devel-

    opment.The old imperialismexploitation for foreign

    profithas no place in our plans. What we envisage is a

    program of development based on the concepts of demo-

    cratic fair-dealing.

    Harry S. Truman, inaugural address, 194962

    The first thing a good banker looks for when someoneapproaches her for a loan is reassurance. That is whycredit derives from ancient words for believe, entrust,

    and heart. Typically, a banker will ask a potential borrow-

    er for a credit history, a credible plan for using and repaying

    the loan, and collateral. She will demand this reassurance

    even though she, unlike a stock investor, is supposed to be

    paid regardless of whether the enterprise succeeds or fails, for

    she knows that borrowers sometimes fail so completely that

    they go bankrupt. In the ideal, the responsible caution of the

    lender counterbalances the enthusiasm of the borrower,

    keeping loan losses within safe bounds and helping societymake healthy use of credit.63

    When this balance is upset, however, credit becomes

    dangerously excessive. And that is what has happened dur-

    ing the last several decades in the provision of finance to

    poorer countries. Creditors, public and private alike, knew or

    were capable of learning that much of the money they lent

    was going into financially questionable uses. But creditors

    too often suspended judgment, became too credulous. Com-

    mercial lenders fell prey to the classic go-go psychology of

    financial markets. And official lenders often got caught up in

  • 8/8/2019 Third World Debt EWP155

    22/44

    nesses, and a genuine desire to alleviate suffering through

    economic development.67

    In practice, development frequently lost out. American

    determination to bankroll cold war allies and secure access to

    resources, for example, turned Mobutu, the Philippines Fer-

    dinand Marcos, and Baby Doc Duvalier into billionairesand their governments into billion-dollar debtors. In Haiti,

    the U.S. governments approach was to place maximum

    responsibility on the Haitian government for the selection

    and design of projects even though it estimated that 63 per-

    cent of recorded revenue of the Haitian government was

    being misappropriated. Frances paternalism toward its for-

    mer African colonies had similar results. Jean Bedel Bokassa,

    leader of the Central African Republic from 1966 to 1979,

    explained how it worked there: Everything around here is

    financed by the French government. We ask the French for

    money, get it, and waste it.68

    For lending governments, geopolitics often dovetailed

    with domestic politics. In the United States, the National

    Foreign Trade Council, whose members include Caterpillar,

    John Deere, Phillips Petroleum, and Westinghouse, lobbies

    for government contributions to the World Bank and other

    multilateral lenders, knowing they stand to gain from the

    resulting orders for earth-movers and power plants. But it is

    the bilateral export credit agencies that are the most purely

    political. Even people who run them say that their taxpayer-

    funded, industry-subsidizing loans make little overall eco-

    nomic sense for the lending nationnever mind theborrower. But support from companies headquartered in

    every major industrial nation leads to a sort of export credit

    arms race. If other countries didnt do it, we wouldnt

    either, said the head of the Canadian ECA around 1990.

    Our approach is merely to match others. Worldwide, ECAs

    have been major financers of arms sales. And ECAs today

    help keep nuclear power plant makers in business by subsi-

    dizing exports of a technology that has become uncompeti-

    tive at home.69

    Because they are essentially bankruptcy-proof, bilateral

    43PRESSURE TO LEND42 STILL WAITING FOR THE JUBILEE

    look as if they might have been trained to say No from

    their childhood are actually trying to sell loans. Ive got

    good news for you, I heard one eager contact man telling

    a group of American bankers: I think theyll be able to

    take your money.65

    It is not hard to imagine how such lenders could havefinanced, along with many good investments, much waste as

    well. In 1970, commercial lenders disbursed $967 million in

    long-term loans to countries that are now members of the

    Worldwatch 47. By 1982, disbursements had zoomed to $10.4

    billion11 times as much. But then the crash came, and

    instantly quelled the pressure to lend. Almost every year since,

    commercial lenders have taken more money from these coun-

    tries than they have given. Yet their outstanding commercial

    debt has risen as interest has compounded even faster.66

    The career of the official lenders has never been so dra-

    matic. On the one hand, their slowly changing budgets andcapital quotas have generally saved them from manic

    upswings in lending. On the other, their access to the richest

    treasuries on earth has insulated them from losses and avert-

    ed the depressive downswings.

    Yet among official lenders, an array of goals have histor-

    ically shouldered aside most concern about helping borrow-

    ersand assuring their ability to repay what is lent. Most of

    the tensions were audible in President Trumans inaugural

    address at the dawn of the cold war. In the speech, Truman

    vowed to press forward in what he cast as a biblical batt