the second face of appropriability: … investment made tends to be a first-order or primary goal....

22
THE SECOND FACE OF APPROPRIABILITY: GENERATIVE APPROPRIABILITY AND ITS DETERMINANTS GAUTAM AHUJA University of Michigan CURBA MORRIS LAMPERT Florida International University ELENA NOVELLI City University London We distinguish between two forms of appropriability: primary appropriability— effectiveness in exploiting inventions as problem-solving mechanisms and capturing a share of their profits—and generative appropriability—effectiveness in exploiting inventions as concepts and capturing a share of the future inventions they spawn. Recognizing that generative appropriability has two components—cumulative inven- tion and preclusion of others—we identify its key managerially manipulable deter- minants and discuss the implications of the construct for the literature on the re- source-based view and the literature on organizational learning. The issue of appropriability—that is, how firms can appropriate value from their inven- tions—represents a fundamental problem in strategy research (e.g., Teece, 1986). In most ap- propriability research, scholars have focused on the idea that inventions create value for firms by being translated into products or by being li- censed out. However, from the time of Arrow (1962), and possibly earlier, researchers have recognized that there are usually at least two facets to any invention. On the one hand, an invention is a solution to some technoeconomic problem, a source of enhanced utility or lower cost for some set of beneficiaries; on the other hand, an invention is a concept, an idea that adds to our universe of concepts and ideas and that can itself become a seed for future concepts and ideas. Thus, Arrow’s (1962) abstraction sug- gests that any invention potentially creates two types of value: an intrinsic value that relates to the problem-solving aspect of the invention and a fecundity, or generative, value that relates to its potential as a springboard for future inven- tions (Hopenhayn & Mitchell, 1999). It follows, then, that for every invention a firm faces two distinct appropriability issues: (1) how it can capture the greatest share of profits from the problem-solving invention it has devel- oped—that is, benefit from the utility that its invention directly creates for a user—and (2) how it can capture the greatest share of future inventions that are spawned by its invention and thereby benefit from the new element it has added to the universe of ideas (cf. Flem- ing, 2001). The first type of appropriability, “primary” ap- propriability (PA), refers to a firm’s effectiveness in exploiting a given invention by translating it into a product or licensable solution for users (e.g., Teece, 1986)—“primary” because for each generation of inventions, the achievement of profits and, thus, the realization of a return on the investment made tends to be a first-order or primary goal. The second type, “secondary” or (henceforth) “generative” appropriability (GA), refers to a firm’s effectiveness in capturing the greatest share of future inventions spawned by its existing inventions. Future inventions could be enhanced or improved versions of the origi- nal invention (addressing the same needs as the original invention and, hence, potential substi- tutes for it), or derived inventions that use the ideas of the original invention in a related but complementary market (e.g., iPad tablets build- ing on iPhone) or even in unrelated markets All authors contributed equally to this work. Academy of Management Review 2013, Vol. 38, No. 2, 248–269. http://dx.doi.org/10.5465/amr.2010.0290 248 Copyright of the Academy of Management, all rights reserved. Contents may not be copied, emailed, posted to a listserv, or otherwise transmitted without the copyright holder’s express written permission. Users may print, download, or email articles for individual use only.

Upload: buikien

Post on 01-Jul-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

THE SECOND FACE OF APPROPRIABILITY:GENERATIVE APPROPRIABILITY AND

ITS DETERMINANTS

GAUTAM AHUJAUniversity of Michigan

CURBA MORRIS LAMPERTFlorida International University

ELENA NOVELLICity University London

We distinguish between two forms of appropriability: primary appropriability—effectiveness in exploiting inventions as problem-solving mechanisms and capturinga share of their profits—and generative appropriability—effectiveness in exploitinginventions as concepts and capturing a share of the future inventions they spawn.Recognizing that generative appropriability has two components—cumulative inven-tion and preclusion of others—we identify its key managerially manipulable deter-minants and discuss the implications of the construct for the literature on the re-source-based view and the literature on organizational learning.

The issue of appropriability—that is, howfirms can appropriate value from their inven-tions—represents a fundamental problem instrategy research (e.g., Teece, 1986). In most ap-propriability research, scholars have focused onthe idea that inventions create value for firms bybeing translated into products or by being li-censed out. However, from the time of Arrow(1962), and possibly earlier, researchers haverecognized that there are usually at least twofacets to any invention. On the one hand, aninvention is a solution to some technoeconomicproblem, a source of enhanced utility or lowercost for some set of beneficiaries; on the otherhand, an invention is a concept, an idea thatadds to our universe of concepts and ideas andthat can itself become a seed for future conceptsand ideas. Thus, Arrow’s (1962) abstraction sug-gests that any invention potentially creates twotypes of value: an intrinsic value that relates tothe problem-solving aspect of the invention anda fecundity, or generative, value that relates toits potential as a springboard for future inven-tions (Hopenhayn & Mitchell, 1999).

It follows, then, that for every invention a firmfaces two distinct appropriability issues: (1) how

it can capture the greatest share of profits fromthe problem-solving invention it has devel-oped—that is, benefit from the utility that itsinvention directly creates for a user—and (2)how it can capture the greatest share of futureinventions that are spawned by its inventionand thereby benefit from the new element it hasadded to the universe of ideas (cf. Flem-ing, 2001).

The first type of appropriability, “primary” ap-propriability (PA), refers to a firm’s effectivenessin exploiting a given invention by translating itinto a product or licensable solution for users(e.g., Teece, 1986)—“primary” because for eachgeneration of inventions, the achievement ofprofits and, thus, the realization of a return onthe investment made tends to be a first-order orprimary goal. The second type, “secondary” or(henceforth) “generative” appropriability (GA),refers to a firm’s effectiveness in capturing thegreatest share of future inventions spawned byits existing inventions. Future inventions couldbe enhanced or improved versions of the origi-nal invention (addressing the same needs as theoriginal invention and, hence, potential substi-tutes for it), or derived inventions that use theideas of the original invention in a related butcomplementary market (e.g., iPad tablets build-ing on iPhone) or even in unrelated marketsAll authors contributed equally to this work.

� Academy of Management Review2013, Vol. 38, No. 2, 248–269.http://dx.doi.org/10.5465/amr.2010.0290

248Copyright of the Academy of Management, all rights reserved. Contents may not be copied, emailed, posted to a listserv, or otherwise transmitted without the copyrightholder’s express written permission. Users may print, download, or email articles for individual use only.

(e.g., skin cleanser Clarisonic building on theprinciple of ultrasound vibration embodied inan electronic toothbrush, Sonicare).

The strategy literature has focused mainly onPA. However, it is likely that in contexts whereinventions occur with some frequency and exist-ing products are supplanted fairly often, firmsmay seek both to enjoy the profits associatedwith a given invention as above (PA) but also toensure that their research efforts bear fruit inthe form of multiple sequential inventions (GA)that sustain their value creation over time. Inthis article we elaborate the construct of GA,highlighting its theoretical and managerial dis-tinctiveness and significance; identify key man-agerially manipulable determinants of GA; andexplore its implications for the literature on theresource-based view (RBV) and the literature onorganizational learning.

DEVELOPING AND CLARIFYING THEGA CONSTRUCT: THE DISTINCTION

BETWEEN PA AND GA

Imagine a firm that in Period 1 releases Inven-tion 1. At that time the firm faces a PA and a GAproblem. First, it needs to use the problem-solving aspect of Invention 1 to create a profit,identifying the best way to monetize it—as acommercialized product or through licensing.Second, recognizing the conceptual componentof Invention 1, the firm may use the principlesembodied in the current invention to originatenew inventions. Success in this second endeavorwill lead the firm to release an Invention 2 inPeriod 2 that builds on the concepts embodied inInvention 1. This begins a cycle where the firmhas to find (1) how to translate Invention 2 into astream of financial returns and (2) how to buildon the idea in Invention 2 to come up with In-vention 3 in Period 3 (see Figure 1), and so on.Thus, the two appropriability questions ariseiteratively for an initial invention as well as forany subsequent inventions that originate fromit.1

Consider Apple’s invention of the iPod. Interms of PA, the iPod was an extremely success-

ful product, generating significant profits for thecompany. However, Apple’s GA performance isalso notable. Apple took the iPod and combinedthe basic concept with a telecommunicationfunction to create the iPhone. It also created aset of additional products, such as the iPodNano, Shuffle, and so on, where it took the basicidea of the original iPod and developed newversions of products in which key attributessuch as capacity, size, and weight were modi-fied to fit the needs of users with different pref-erences. Subsequently, it took the basic conceptof the iPhone (in itself a very successful productin terms of PA) and expanded its surface areaand computing functions to create yet anothernew product, the iPad. PA and GA are thus twodistinct outcomes reflecting two different as-pects of a firm’s invention performance.

To highlight the added value of GA as a con-struct, we note that building successfully onprior inventions is important for firms for multi-ple reasons. First, initial iterations of most in-ventions are relatively rudimentary. Subsequentversions improve significantly and often havefar greater commercial viability than the origi-nal. Second, even when inventions become com-mercially viable, fully exploiting a firm’s invest-ments in research often entails being able tocreate subsequent generations of inventionsthat are increasingly differentiated for specificuses and market segments (e.g., iPod Nano,Shuffle) or that offer better price/performancevalues (McEvily & Chakravarthy, 2002; Roberts,1999). Third, the most valuable application of agiven invention is often not the application forwhich it was originally conceived. Coupling theconceptual kernel of an invention with newproblems to be solved may then be extremelyvaluable (Hargadon & Sutton, 1997). For in-stance, Corning’s Gorilla Glass product, nowused very successfully for smartphone screens,is derived from a tough glass that was originallydesigned for use in car windshields. Simply put,then, firms need to care about GA to maximizethe returns from their investments in knowledgeand to safeguard against the possibility of be-ing rendered obsolete by improved substitutesthat build on their own prior efforts.

Multiple arguments also suggest that distin-guishing between GA and PA is important. First,factors highlighted in the literature as enhanc-ing appropriability, such as complexity, andcausal ambiguity influence the two forms of ap-

1 Although the GA concept could be expanded to nontech-nological domains in that ideas from marketing or humanresource practices could also be built on to create new ideas,to retain theoretical focus and clarity we limit the scope ofour investigation to technological inventions.

2013 249Ahuja, Lampert, and Novelli

FIG

UR

E1

Prim

ary

and

Gen

erat

ive

App

ropr

iabi

lity

Tim

e

t 1

t 2

New

inve

ntio

n 1

Gen

erat

ive

appr

opri

abili

ty is

sue:

How

can

we

crea

te fu

ture

in

vent

ions

that

are

spa

wne

d fr

om th

is in

vent

ion?

Gen

erat

ive

appr

opri

abili

ty is

sue:

How

can

we

crea

te fu

ture

in

vent

ions

that

are

spa

wne

d fr

om th

is in

vent

ion?

Lead

s to

cho

ices

rela

ted

to p

rofit

crea

tion

in t 1

—i.e

.: Le

ads

to c

hoic

es re

late

d to

pro

fitcr

eatio

n in

t 2—

i.e.:

Lead

s to

cho

ices

rela

ted

to p

rofit

crea

tion

in t n

—i.e

.:

• Pa

tent

or n

ot?

• Li

cens

e or

not

? •

Dev

elop

into

a p

rodu

ct

or n

ot?

Inve

ntio

n 2

(bui

lt on

inve

ntio

n 1)

Inve

ntio

n n

(b

uilt

on s

ome

prev

ious

in

vent

ion)

t n

• Pa

tent

or n

ot?

• Li

cens

e or

not

? •

Dev

elop

into

a p

rodu

ct

or n

ot?

• Pa

tent

or n

ot?

• Li

cens

e or

not

? •

Dev

elop

into

a p

rodu

ct

or n

ot?

Prim

ary

appr

opri

abili

tyis

sue:

H

ow c

an w

e cr

eate

pro

fits

from

this

inve

ntio

n?

Prim

ary

appr

opri

abili

tyis

sue:

H

ow c

an w

e cr

eate

pro

fits

from

this

inve

ntio

n?

Prim

ary

appr

opri

abili

tyis

sue:

H

ow c

an w

e cr

eate

pro

fits

from

this

inve

ntio

n?

Ima

gin

ea

firm

tha

tin

Per

iod

1re

lea

ses

an

Inve

nti

on1.

Att

ha

ttim

eth

efi

rmfa

ces

ap

rim

ary

an

da

gen

era

tive

ap

pro

pri

ab

ilit

yp

rob

lem

,th

efi

rstb

ein

g“H

owca

nw

ecr

eate

prof

its

from

this

inve

nti

on?”

an

dth

ese

con

db

ein

g“H

owca

nw

ecr

eate

futu

rein

vent

ions

tha

ta

resp

aw

ned

from

this

inve

nti

on?”

Ifth

efi

rmsu

cces

sfu

lly

an

swer

sb

oth

qu

esti

ons,

then

inP

erio

d1

itw

ill

earn

ap

rofi

tfr

omIn

ven

tion

1,b

ut

inP

erio

d2

itw

ill

rele

ase

an

Inve

nti

on2

tha

tb

uil

ds

onth

eco

nce

pts

emb

odie

din

Inve

nti

on1.

Bu

ton

cea

ga

inth

efi

rmw

ill

ha

veto

thin

ka

bou

t(1

)how

totr

an

sla

teIn

ven

tion

2in

toa

stre

am

offi

na

nci

al

retu

rns

thro

ug

hp

rod

uct

emb

odim

ent

orli

cen

sin

ga

nd

(2)h

owto

bu

ild

onth

eid

eain

Inve

nti

on2

inor

der

toco

me

up

wit

hIn

ven

tion

3in

Per

iod

3.

propriability differently, making it unlikely thatthe same managerial choices will maximizeboth forms of appropriability (see Table 1). Sec-ond, PA implies focusing immediately and di-rectly on obtaining rents, whereas GA impliesinvesting in creating a future opportunity forrents. Thus, the two forms of appropriabilitysuggest very different (and potentially conflict-ing) foci for organizational resource allocation,systems, staffing, and attention. For instance,maximizing PA entails attention to commercial-ization concerns and requires focusing on theneeds of a given set of existing users and opti-mally configuring the invention to those needs(Christensen, 1997; Christensen & Bower, 1996).In contrast, enhancing GA pushes attention to-ward inventiveness and requires thinking abouthow different groups of potential users mightfind the principle underlying the invention use-ful, or thinking about how that principle may beused to respond to other needs. Failing to explic-itly recognize this trade-off and the accompany-ing distinctions may lead to a loss of competi-tive position. For instance, after its acquisitionby News Corporation, Myspace significantly fo-cused on realizing advertising revenue insteadof allocating resources to develop improvedproducts that incorporated features that couldlead to an enhanced experience for the user.This choice was controversial within the com-pany and even blamed for its decline, as com-petitors constantly upgraded and enhancedtheir offerings but Myspace did not (Gil-lette, 2011).

IDENTIFYING THE DETERMINANTS OF GA

The construct of GA has not been used in theliterature before; however, in three streams ofresearch, scholars have examined related con-cepts: (1) the RBV literature on threats from sub-stitution and imitation (e.g., King, 2007; King &Ziethaml, 2001; McEvily & Chakravarthy, 2002),(2) the organizational learning literature on ex-ploitation and reuse of knowledge (e.g., Flem-ing, 2001; Majchrzak, Cooper, & Neece, 2004), and(3) the economics literature on sequential inven-tion (e.g., Hopenhayn, Llobet, & Mitchell, 2006).Table 2 presents an analysis of how GA and theconstructs emerging from previous literature(imitation, substitution, exploitation, knowledgereuse, and sequential invention) are differenti-ated across multiple dimensions.

For any firm, GA is likely to be driven by twocomponents: (1) the cumulative invention com-ponent, defined as firms’ effectiveness in creat-ing new inventions that build on their own ex-isting inventions, and (2) the preclusivecomponent, defined as firms’ effectiveness inpreventing others from building inventions basedon the firms’ inventions. The two components ofGA can but do not necessarily covary. Firms canoutperform on both components, underperformon both components, or perform well on one andpoorly on the other. For instance, Xerox has cre-ated many inventions but has not necessarilybeen successful in building on many of them(Chesbrough, 2002) or in preventing others fromdoing so. As previously mentioned, Apple is anexample of a firm that has managed to be cre-ative in both building on its own inventions (e.g.,the iPhone and iPad based on the iPod) and inprecluding (or at least delaying) other compa-nies from successfully building on its ideas (Bur-rows, 2009). Conversely, Epilady, the originatorof pull epilators, is an example of a companythat was high on the cumulative invention com-ponent of GA but low on the preclusive compo-nent (Geer, 1990).

Researchers in knowledge management andcognitive psychology have noted that breakinga concept into components and studying thecomponents separately reduces the scope of theproblem being analyzed and, thus, simplifiesthe search for identifying underlying relation-ships (Goldenberg, Mazursky, & Solomon, 1999).Using this approach, we distinguish betweenthe cumulative and preclusive component ofGA, identify determinants of the construct, andarticulate propositions relating GA to these de-terminants. A key assumption we build on isthat a firm’s GA outcomes are likely to dependon access to and usage of the inventive knowl-edge of the firm. Enhancing the access and us-age of the firm’s inventive knowledge by inven-tors inside the firm and reducing the access andusage of the firm’s knowledge by inventors out-side the firm are then natural paths to enhanc-ing GA.

We adopt a strategic, firm-based perspective.In uncovering the determinants of GA, we focusour attention on key levers that lie within thecontrol of management and are commonly usedto influence organizational outcomes: organiza-tion structure, organizational systems and pro-cesses, and organization strategy (Grant, 2007).

2013 251Ahuja, Lampert, and Novelli

TABLE 1Primary Appropriability versus Generative Appropriability

Key ComparisonDimensions Primary Appropriability (PA) Generative Appropriability (GA)

Domain of construct Profits/economic rents (e.g., Teece, 1986): PAis defined in terms of the firm’s share ofprofits from its inventions.

Ideas/inventions: The currency of GA isideas; GA is defined in terms of thefirm’s share of the ideas or inventionsthat are spawned by its earlierinventions.

Relationship betweenconstruct and firmperformance

PA influences the relationship between aninvention and firm financialperformance (i.e., revenues and profitsearned by the firm). Only if the firm isable to translate the invention into avalue proposition for a customer (be itanother firm or the final consumer) canit commercialize the invention andcreate financial returns from it.However, PA is not directly related tofirm invention performance (defined asthe rate of inventions developed by thefirm): a firm with a higher PA willappropriate a higher share of revenuesand profits from each invention butwill not necessarily come up with newinventions.

Conversely, GA (defined as the firm’ssuccess in building on its own priorinventions) influences firm inventionperformance by increasing the rate ofinventions generated from the firm’sprior inventions but may not be directlyrelated to firm financial performance inthe short run.

Possible measures Profits from a new product; incrementalprofits made possible by new processes;licensing income from new products orprocesses

The proportion of inventions/productsspawned by the focal firm’s inventionsthat are created by the focal firm; of thetotal citations of the firm’s patents, theproportion that come from the firm’sown patents

Primary effect of patentingan invention

Generally increases PA for that invention,although the strength of the benefitvaries in different industries, for differenttypes of inventions (e.g., process versusproducts), and under different patentregimes (e.g., Cohen, Nelson, & Walsh,2000; Levin, Klevorick, Nelson, & Winter,1987; Teece, 1986)

May decrease GA because the doctrine ofenabling disclosure enshrined in patentlaw makes building on the focal firm’sinventions easier for others; patent lawdemands that patent disclosures shouldenable a person skilled in the art tocreate the claimed invention

Primary effect of keepingthe invention secret

Generally increases PA, although the effectmay vary across industries and contexts(e.g., Cohen et al., 2000; Levin et al., 1987;Teece, 1986); in a relative sense, though,in many contexts secrecy may leave thefocal firm with weaker protection thanpatents—if competitors figure out how theinvention works and the focal firm hasnot patented it, they could imitate it moreeasily

Improves GA—e.g., by diminishing thelikelihood that somebody else willeasily learn about the innards of afirm’s new product or process

Primary effect of weakproperty rights

Reduces PA by reducing the inventor’sability to prevent imitation by enforcingproperty rights: competitors can moreeasily imitate the firm’s extant inventionswith a reduced risk of being sued (e.g.,Teece, 1986)

Reduces GA by reducing theinventor’s ability to preventimitation by enforcing property rights:competitors can more easily build onthe firm’s extant inventions togenerate new inventions with areduced risk of being sued (effect ofweak property rights is stronger on PAthan on GA)

(Continued)

252 AprilAcademy of Management Review

We recognize that GA is likely to be driven bymany additional factors, including context-specific and idiosyncratic factors such as theintrinsic fecundity potential and complexity in-herent in a given invention, but we leave theseto be identified by future work. Moreover, evenwithin our chosen set of managerial levers, thelist of predictors we identify is illustrative ratherthan exhaustive (see Table 3).

THE CUMULATIVE COMPONENT OF GA

GA and Nearly DecomposableOrganization Structures

Enhancing cumulative invention requires thattwo goals be accomplished simultaneously—that is, that invention be enhanced within thefirm and that the inventions generated build onprior ones. Organization structure, in particularthe decentralization versus centralization pat-tern (Nickerson & Zenger, 2002) of research unitswithin the organization, shapes the primarypaths of information flow inside the firm (Sig-gelkow & Levinthal, 2003) and, thus, plays a keyrole in determining the extent to which the or-ganization succeeds in cumulative invention.

Research activity in an organization can beconducted through multiple decentralized sub-groups or units or through a single centralizedone (Argyres & Silverman, 2004). From the per-spective of enhancing invention and cumula-tiveness, these alternatives both imply a trade-off. Decentralized structures foster invention buthinder cumulativeness, whereas centralizedstructures foster cumulativeness but hinder in-vention. Decentralized structures—modular orfully decomposable in Simonian terms (Sanchez& Mahoney, 1996)—permit each subgroup to spe-cialize in a limited domain of knowledge andbecome highly sensitive and responsive toneeds in that domain (Nickerson & Zenger, 2002;Yayavaram & Ahuja, 2008). This depth of knowl-edge of the domain and the sensitivity to cus-tomer needs within that domain enhance theli-kelihood of breaching the knowledge frontier,fostering invention (Katila & Ahuja, 2002). Yetdecentralization hinders cumulativeness in in-vention. Decentralized structures provide in-adequate coordination across subgroups(Nickerson & Zenger, 2002), since individualsubgroups tend to be isolated from the cre-ations and knowledge flow of other subgroups.Consequently, many potential inventions

TABLE 1(Continued)

Key ComparisonDimensions Primary Appropriability (PA) Generative Appropriability (GA)

Primary effect of complexity Generally increases PA by making imitationdifficult (because it increases the difficultyfor the imitator to comprehend how thesystem works; McEvily & Chakravarthy,2002)

Overall may not enhance GA becausecomplexity may make building oninventions more difficult both from theinventor’s and the competitors’perspectives

Primary effect of causalambiguity

Generally increases PA:Interfirm, generally increases PA of inventor

by making imitation difficult, since thepotential imitator does not understandwhat and how to copy (e.g., King, 2007;Lippman & Rumelt, 1982; Reed &DeFillippi, 1990)

Intrafirm, usually will not affect PA sincethe inventor can profit from its inventionseven if it does not understand theinternal linkages that led to the creationof the invention; where understanding thelinkages in the causal process ofinventing is necessary to the invention’scommercial success, it could reduce PA

May or may not increase GA:Interfirm, enhances GA by making

subsequent invention by competitorsdifficult, since the competitor may findit difficult to understand the innards ofthe focal firm’s prior inventions

Intrafirm, may reduce GA—e.g., byimpeding the understanding of “the linkbetween a competency and itsperformance outcomes” and by blockingthe “ability to learn about and adaptthat competency” (King, 2007: 168),which is required to build on priorinventions (e.g., King, 2007; McEvily,Das, & McCabe, 2000; Reed & DeFillippi,1990)

2013 253Ahuja, Lampert, and Novelli

TABL

E2

Con

stru

ctD

isti

ncti

vene

ssfr

omR

elat

edC

onst

ruct

s

Con

stru

ct/

Out

com

eD

efin

itio

nof

Con

stru

ct

IsTh

ere

aSe

cond

-O

rder

“Inv

enti

on”

Req

uire

dfo

rth

eC

onst

ruct

toBe

Mea

ning

ful?

Sour

ceof

Seco

nd-

Ord

erIn

vent

ion

orPr

oduc

t

Scop

eof

App

lica

tion

ofSe

cond

-Ord

erIn

vent

ion

Sour

ceof

Kno

wle

dge

Buil

ton

inSe

cond

-O

rder

Inve

ntio

nor

App

lica

tion

(inca

seit

isno

tan

inve

ntio

n)

Pers

pect

ive

Ado

pted

byLi

tera

ture

/Nat

ure

ofSo

luti

onto

Add

ress

the

Prob

lem

Illu

stra

tive

Art

icle

sH

ighl

ight

ing

the

Con

stru

ct

Gen

erat

ive

appr

opri

abil

ity

(GA

)

GA

refe

rsto

afi

rm’s

effe

ctiv

enes

sin

cap

turi

ng

ash

are

ofth

efu

ture

inve

nti

ons

spa

wn

edb

yit

sex

isti

ng

inve

nti

ons.

Yes

—T

oob

tain

GA

the

orig

ina

lin

ven

tin

gfi

rmh

as

tocr

eate

an

ewin

ven

tion

ba

sed

onit

sea

rlie

rin

ven

tion

s.

Foc

al

firm

orot

her

firm

s—If

the

foca

lfi

rmis

the

sou

rce

ofth

ese

con

d-o

rder

inve

nti

ona

nd

oth

erfi

rms

ha

ven

otb

een

ab

leto

dev

elop

seco

nd

-or

der

inve

nti

ons

bu

ild

ing

onth

efo

cal

firm

’sin

ven

tion

s,th

efo

cal

firm

ha

sh

igh

GA

.If

oth

erfi

rms

ha

vesu

cces

sfu

lly

bu

ilt

onth

efo

cal

firm

’sin

ven

tion

s,th

efo

cal

firm

ha

slo

wG

A.

Sa

me

ma

rket

ord

iffe

ren

tm

ark

ets—

Th

ese

con

d-o

rder

inve

nti

onco

uld

be

asu

bst

itu

tefo

rth

efo

cal

pro

du

ct(e

.g.,

an

imp

rove

dve

rsio

nof

it),

targ

etin

gth

esa

me

ma

rket

,or

itco

uld

be

aco

mp

lem

enta

ryor

un

rela

ted

pro

du

ctta

rget

ing

dif

fere

nt

ma

rket

s.

Foc

al

firm

—F

orG

A,

the

seco

nd

-ord

erin

ven

tion

bu

ild

son

the

con

cep

tsem

bod

ied

inth

efo

cal

firm

’sp

rece

din

gin

ven

tion

s.

Foc

al

firm

’sp

ersp

ecti

ve—

Th

efo

cus

ison

firm

-le

vel

solu

tion

sto

the

pro

ble

mof

GA

.S

ug

ges

ted

solu

tion

sto

incr

ease

GA

are

the

stra

teg

ies

outl

ined

inth

ea

rtic

le,a

llof

wh

ich

are

wit

hin

the

con

trol

offi

rms.

Th

isa

rtic

le

Imit

atio

nR

efer

sto

con

scio

usl

ya

ssoc

iati

ng

elem

ents

com

mon

toth

eob

serv

ab

lesu

cces

sof

ag

iven

firm

an

dre

pli

cati

ng

them

(Alc

hia

n,1

950)

No—

Imit

ati

onca

noc

cur

wh

enth

ese

con

dfi

rmsi

mp

lyre

pli

cate

sth

eor

igin

al

inve

nti

on.

Th

ere

isn

ore

qu

irem

ent

tha

ta

nim

ita

tor

bu

ild

an

ewin

ven

tion

ba

sed

onth

eor

igin

al

inve

nti

onto

talk

ab

out

imit

ati

on.

Sec

ond

-ord

erin

ven

tion

isn

otre

qu

ired

.Im

ita

tion

isw

hen

aco

mp

etit

orre

pli

cate

sa

nex

isti

ng

pro

du

ctor

serv

ice.

No

nov

else

con

d-o

rder

inve

nti

onis

crea

ted

.

Sa

me

ma

rket

—In

the

con

text

ofim

ita

tion

,th

eco

py

ista

rget

eda

tth

esa

me

ma

rket

as

the

orig

ina

lin

ven

tion

.

Foc

al

firm

—T

ob

eca

lled

imit

ati

on,

the

cop

yn

eed

sto

bu

ild

onth

efo

cal

firm

’skn

owle

dg

e.

Foc

al

firm

’sp

ersp

ecti

ve—

Ca

usa

la

mb

igu

ity,

com

ple

xity

,sca

le,

etc.

are

key

mec

ha

nis

ms

tha

tp

rote

ctth

efi

rmfr

omim

ita

tion

.

Die

rick

x&

Coo

l(1

990)

;Kin

g&

Zeit

ha

ml

(200

1);

Lip

pm

an

&R

um

elt

(198

2);R

eed

&D

eFil

lip

pi

(199

0);

Riv

kin

(200

1);

Tee

ce(1

986)

Subs

titu

tion

Ref

ers

toth

ed

evel

opm

ent

ofa

nin

ven

tion

fun

ctio

na

lly

equ

iva

len

tto

the

foca

lin

ven

tion

Yes

—S

ub

stit

uti

onoc

curs

wh

ena

nin

ven

tion

fun

ctio

na

lly

recr

eate

sth

ep

rod

uct

orse

rvic

eb

enef

its

ofa

nex

isti

ng

inve

nti

on.

Th

ea

uth

orof

the

seco

nd

-ord

erin

ven

tion

isth

esu

bst

itu

tor.

Foc

al

firm

sor

oth

erfi

rms—

Th

efo

cal

firm

can

itse

lfco

me

up

wit

ha

sub

stit

uti

ng

inve

nti

on,o

rsu

cha

nin

ven

tion

can

be

crea

ted

by

an

oth

erfi

rm.

Sa

me

ma

rket

—In

the

con

text

ofsu

bst

itu

tion

,th

ese

con

din

ven

tion

ista

rget

eda

tth

esa

me

ma

rket

as

the

orig

ina

lin

ven

tion

.

Foc

al

firm

orot

her

firm

s—T

he

sub

stit

uti

ng

inve

nti

onco

uld

be

ba

sed

onth

ekn

owle

dg

eof

the

foca

lfi

rmth

at

wa

sth

ecr

eato

rof

the

firs

tin

ven

tion

orco

uld

be

ba

sed

onth

ekn

owle

dg

eof

oth

erfi

rms.

Foc

al

firm

’sp

ersp

ecti

veM

cEvi

ly&

Ch

akr

ava

rth

y(2

002)

;McE

vily

,D

as,

&M

cCa

be

(200

0)

Expl

oita

tion

Exp

loit

ati

onco

nce

rns

the

refi

nem

ent

an

du

seof

afi

rm’s

exis

tin

gca

pa

bil

itie

sa

nd

know

led

ge

ba

ses,

wh

ile

exp

lora

tion

isre

late

dto

the

crea

tion

ofn

ewon

es(L

evin

tha

l&

Ma

rch

,198

1;M

arc

h,1

991;

Win

ter,

1971

).

No—

Exp

loit

ati

onm

ay

not

invo

lve

inve

nti

ona

ta

ll.

For

inst

an

ce,

exp

loit

ati

onm

ay

enta

ilex

pa

nd

ing

sale

sof

an

exis

tin

gp

rod

uct

from

one

geo

gra

ph

yto

an

oth

er.

Foc

al

firm

Sa

me

ma

rket

(e.g

.,B

enn

er&

Tu

shm

an

,200

3;M

arc

h,1

991)

,in

gen

era

l—E

xpa

nd

ing

toa

dif

fere

nt

ma

rket

ma

yb

eco

nsi

der

edex

plo

rati

on.

Foc

al

firm

—E

xplo

ita

tion

imp

lies

usi

ng

afi

rm’s

exis

tin

gca

pa

bil

itie

s.

Foc

al

firm

’sp

ersp

ecti

veB

enn

er&

Tu

shm

an

(200

3);M

arc

h(1

991)

Kno

wle

dge

reus

eK

now

led

ge

reu

sere

fers

tow

hen

know

led

ge

acq

uir

edin

one

situ

ati

onis

ap

pli

edto

an

oth

ersi

tua

tion

(Ma

jch

rza

k,C

oop

er,&

Nee

ce,

2004

).

No—

Kn

owle

dg

eco

uld

be

reu

sed

ina

dif

fere

nt

con

text

wit

hou

t,n

eces

sari

ly,t

he

crea

tion

ofa

new

inve

nti

on.F

orin

sta

nce

,afi

rmco

uld

use

its

rou

tin

esd

evel

oped

from

run

nin

ga

nof

fice

inth

eU

nit

edS

tate

sto

run

an

offi

cein

Eu

rop

e.

Foc

al

firm

orot

her

sS

am

eor

dif

fere

nt

ma

rket

No

dis

tin

ctio

nm

ad

eb

etw

een

the

know

led

ge

ofth

efo

cal

firm

an

dth

at

ofot

her

s

Foc

al

firm

’sp

ersp

ecti

veF

lem

ing

(200

1);

Ma

jch

rza

ket

al.

(200

4);M

urr

ay

&O

’Ma

hon

y(2

007)

.

(Con

tin

ued

)

TABL

E2

(Con

tinu

ed)

Con

stru

ct/

Out

com

eD

efin

itio

nof

Con

stru

ct

IsTh

ere

aSe

cond

-O

rder

“Inv

enti

on”

Req

uire

dfo

rth

eC

onst

ruct

toBe

Mea

ning

ful?

Sour

ceof

Seco

nd-

Ord

erIn

vent

ion

orPr

oduc

t

Scop

eof

App

lica

tion

ofSe

cond

-Ord

erIn

vent

ion

Sour

ceof

Kno

wle

dge

Buil

ton

inSe

cond

-O

rder

Inve

ntio

nor

App

lica

tion

(inca

seit

isno

tan

inve

ntio

n)

Pers

pect

ive

Ado

pted

byLi

tera

ture

/Nat

ure

ofSo

luti

onto

Add

ress

the

Prob

lem

Illu

stra

tive

Art

icle

sH

ighl

ight

ing

the

Con

stru

ct

Sequ

enti

alin

vent

ion

Inve

nti

onor

der

iva

tive

imp

rove

men

tsb

ase

don

an

init

ial

inve

nti

on(G

reen

&S

cotc

hm

er,1

995;

Sco

tch

mer

&G

reen

,199

0)

Yes

—W

ith

out

asu

ccee

din

gin

ven

tion

tha

tb

uil

ds

onth

ep

rior

inve

nti

ons,

the

con

stru

ctis

not

mea

nin

gfu

l.

Foc

al

firm

orot

her

firm

s(G

reen

&S

cotc

hm

er,1

995)

—E

ith

erca

nb

ea

sou

rce

ofin

ven

tion

sth

at

bu

ild

onp

rior

inve

nti

ons.

Sa

me

ord

iffe

ren

tm

ark

ets

(Gre

en&

Sco

tch

mer

,199

5)—

Th

eli

tera

ture

ofte

nfo

cuse

son

the

sam

em

ark

et.

Foc

al

firm

Soc

ieta

lor

pu

bli

cp

olic

yp

ersp

ecti

ve—

Sol

uti

ons

pre

sen

ted

toth

ep

rob

lem

ofse

qu

enti

al

inve

nti

onin

volv

ea

lter

ing

the

des

ign

ofth

ep

ate

nt

syst

emin

term

sof

bre

ad

tha

nd

len

gth

ofp

ate

nts

—va

ria

ble

sth

at

are

bey

ond

the

con

trol

ofin

div

idu

al

firm

s(G

reen

&S

cotc

hm

er,1

995)

.

Gre

en&

Sco

tch

mer

(199

5);H

open

ha

yn,

Llob

et,&

Mit

chel

l(2

006)

;Sco

tch

mer

&G

reen

(199

0)

that lie at the intersection of the knowledgebases of different subgroups and, hence, buildon prior inventions are never created.

In contrast, centralized structures—nonde-composable in Simonian terms—foster buildingcumulatively on a firm’s past inventions butmay reduce inventiveness in the first place. In acentralized research structure, decision makingand authority are concentrated at the centrallevel (Argyres & Silverman, 2004), and decisionsare not optimized for each subgroup (Siggelkow& Levinthal, 2003). Rather, subgroups coalescearound specific compromises and paths andthen prefer not to depart from them to minimizeorganizational and political struggles, facilitat-ing cumulation (Siggelkow & Levinthal, 2003).However, this stickiness around specific com-promises reduces exploration, and that, together

with the bureaucracy associated with central-ization, leads to lower inventiveness (Nickerson& Zenger, 2002; Yayavaram & Ahuja, 2008).

One solution to the trade-off outlined above isprovided by the creation of a small number oflinkages between the subgroups of a decentral-ized research structure, in effect converting adecomposable structure into a nearly decom-posable one (Sanchez & Mahoney, 1996; Simon,1962). Such linkages could consist of internalconsulting (Hargadon & Sutton, 1997), cross-group liaison teams (Fang, Lee, & Schilling,2010), or shared senior management roles acrosssubgroups (Tushman & O’Reilly, 2004). In anearly decomposable structure, structural sepa-ration between the subgroups fosters the infor-mational diversity and local application thatgive decentralization its power to develop in-

TABLE 3Organizational Determinants of Generative Appropriability

Components of GA Proposition

Cumulative component:Firms’ effectiveness in creatingnew inventions that build on theirown existing inventions

Proposition 1: The use of nearly decomposable organization structuresfor research leads to higher GA for firms.

Proposition 2: The use of personalization-intensive approaches toknowledge management leads to higher GA for firms.

Proposition 3: The use of incentive systems fostering stretch goals oninvention, across-group collaboration, and joint problem solvingleads to higher GA for firms.

Proposition 4a: The use of time-paced creative processes leads tohigher GA for firms.

Proposition 4b: The use of semistructured creative processes leads tohigher GA for firms.

Proposition 5: Moderate levels of organizational resource availabilityfor invention lead to higher GA for firms than very high or verylow levels.

Preclusive component:Firms’ effectiveness in preventingor precluding others from buildinginventions on the firms’ inventions

Proposition 6a: Moderate dispersion of firms’ research activitiesacross geographic locations leads to higher GA for firms than veryhigh or very low dispersion.

Proposition 6b: The use of moderately sized research teams leads tohigher GA for firms than the use of very large or very smallresearch teams.

Proposition 7: The use of retention-oriented HR practices leads tohigher GA for firms.

Proposition 8: Focusing inventive activity within a narrow domain orwithin closely related domains leads to higher GA for firms.

Proposition 9: Owning a broader global infrastructure of supportingassets leads to higher GA for firms.

Proposition 10a: Developing inventive knowledge through R&Dalliances (as opposed to through in-house efforts) leads to lower GAfor firms. This effect will strengthen as the number of R&D alliancesincreases.

Proposition 10b: Forming link alliances leads to higher GA for firmsthan forming scale alliances.

2013 257Ahuja, Lampert, and Novelli

ventions and exploit the opportunities in eachlocal ecology. However, the few yet criticalcross-subgroup linkages enable the transfer ofknowledge from one subgroup to another,thereby fostering broad diffusion, assimilation,and reuse of the organization’s inventive knowl-edge (Fang et al., 2010). These arguments sug-gest that nearly decomposable structures fostercumulative invention and, thus, enhance GA.

Proposition 1: The use of nearly de-composable organization structures forresearch leads to higher GA for firms.

GA and Knowledge Management Systems

The organization’s knowledge managementsystems provide another path to bridge time andspace and to transmit knowledge from the orga-nization’s past inventions to future potentialusers of that knowledge (Hollingshead, 2001;Lewis, Lange, & Gillis, 2005; Wegner, 1986).Knowledge management systems can facilitatecumulative invention by making knowledge ofthe firm’s prior inventions more widely and eas-ily accessible within the organization. Twobroad formal approaches to knowledge man-agement have been identified: codification andpersonalization (Hansen, Nohria, & Tierney,1999). Although these approaches have beenconceived in the context of organizationalknowledge in general, they are also meaningfulin the context of inventive knowledge and,hence, are useful for understanding GA.

We suggest that personalization-intensiveknowledge systems will be more useful for thekind of information exchange required by cumu-lative invention than codification-intensiveones. Successfully using the knowledge fromprior inventions to create new inventions oftenrequires information-rich contextual detail (Har-gadon & Sutton, 1997) or “metacontextual” infor-mation from the original invention (Majchrzak etal., 2004). Much information of this type tends tobe tacit, socially embedded, and hard to codify(Hansen et al., 1999; Kogut & Zander, 1992). Cod-ification and personalization approaches varyin their effectiveness in providing access to suchtacit knowledge. We draw on Hansen and col-leagues’ (1999) rich description of these ap-proaches to identify their key characteristics be-low and explore the implications of thesecharacteristics for cumulative invention.

In codification, knowledge is classified usinga people-to-documents approach. Information isextracted from the person who originally cre-ated it, converted into a knowledge object that isindependent of the individual who created it,and stored in an electronic database, makingthe information available to all subsequent us-ers in document form (Hansen et al., 1999). Con-versely, personalization follows a person-to-person logic (Hansen et al., 1999). Although thisapproach also entails embedding basic ele-ments of knowledge in electronic media, it em-phasizes mechanisms for linking people to peo-ple rather than people to documents. Thisfacilitates connections with the actual peoplewho worked on the original project, enabling thetransfer of noncodifiable, tacit knowledgethrough direct person-to-person contacts andenhancing cumulative invention.

In addition, each of these two approaches re-quires a set of complementary components(Hansen et al., 1999). In the codification ap-proach, firms invest in skilled abstraction, cod-ification staff, and sophisticated software formaking connections between previously devel-oped knowledge objects and currently facedproblems. In the personalization approach,firms instead invest in a collegial and coopera-tive culture, enabling capabilities that fosteractivation of the person-person network connec-tion (e.g., videoconferencing), and organiza-tional processes, such as collective brain-storming sessions that are used to convertindividual memories into organizational memo-ries (Hansen et al., 1999; Sutton & Hargadon,1996). Such culture facilitates exchange of priorknowledge and is therefore conducive to cumu-lative invention.

Although most organizations usually use bothcodification and personalization systems (Han-sen et al., 1999), since the complementary invest-ments required for the systems are different,most organizations tend to use one more inten-sively than the other. The prior arguments sug-gest that personalization-intensive knowledgesystems facilitate cumulative invention andthereby enhance GA.

Proposition 2: The use of personaliza-tion-intensive approaches to knowl-edge management leads to higher GAfor firms.

258 AprilAcademy of Management Review

GA and Incentive Systems for Inventors

Three common mechanisms have been iden-tified for controlling and incentivizing researchpersonnel: (1) output control, which directs re-sults and outcomes; (2) input control, which reg-ulates what resources are used in the process;and (3) behavior control, which modulates themeans leading up to the results (Cardinal, 2001).In the context of cumulative invention, all threematter. Specifically, precommitted stretch goals,collaboration across subgroups, and jointproblem-solving behaviors are likely to fosterhigher levels of GA.

Under output control, reward systems incen-tivize the achievement of certain outcomes.Some organizations precommit to certain highinvention output levels through publicly statedpolicies. For instance, 3M has a rule that 30 per-cent of sales must come from products launchedin the last five years (Eisenhardt & Brown, 1998).This public pronouncement creates a strong mo-tivation to invent; failure to successfully launchnew products would imply both lowered finan-cial rewards and a public loss of face. Further,the “stretch” nature of the goal implies that or-ganizational members are likely to feel somepressure in delivering this outcome. Given thelimited availability of time, the stretch goal islikely to encourage further evaluation of avail-able knowledge that can be reused, as opposedto exploration of new knowledge (Majchrzak etal., 2004).

However, reusing knowledge for invention re-quires integration of familiar knowledge with atleast some unfamiliar knowledge or perspective(Hargadon & Sutton, 1997; Majchrzak et al., 2004).This element of novelty can emerge from facili-tating connections across different subgroups orunits of the organization that have developedlocally differentiated knowledge as they servetheir own local contexts (Hansen et al., 1999).Input control systems that encourage collabora-tion between peers in different subgroups canprovide the necessary novelty in knowledge in-puts and cross-fertilization of the organization’sexisting knowledge to create new inventionsbased on past ones.

In addition, firms can foster behaviors thatfavor such internal cross-fertilization, which isconducive to cumulative invention. Incentiviz-ing joint problem-solving behaviors implies thatseeking help from others and providing help to

others become not just legitimate but norma-tively desirable (Hargadon & Sutton, 1997). Helpseeking and providing become perceived jointlyas markers of the organization’s solution-seeking orientation, in which solving the prob-lem is more important than being seen as aself-sufficient, extremely intelligent individual(Hargadon, 1998). These arguments suggest thatincentive systems fostering stretch goals,across-group collaboration, and joint problem-solving facilitate cumulative invention and,hence, enhance GA.

Proposition 3: The use of incentive sys-tems fostering stretch goals on inven-tion, across-group collaboration, andjoint problem solving leads to higherGA for firms.

GA and Creative Processes

Organizations enhance or diminish the abilityof their members to deliver on outcomes throughtheir design of organizational processes androutines (Brown & Eisenhardt, 1997; Eisenhardt &Brown, 1998; Sutton & Hargadon, 1996). We iden-tify two types of organizational creative process-es—time-paced and semistructured creativeprocesses (Brown & Eisenhardt, 1997)—as facili-tating higher GA.

Creative processes in organizations can besubjected to different types of temporal con-straints. For instance, Brown and Eisenhardt(1997) and Eisenhardt and Brown (1998) de-scribed two distinct temporal approaches tolaunching new products: event paced and timepaced. Event-paced launches are driven by ex-ternal occurrences, such as competitive actionsor market developments. In contrast, time-pacedcreative processes are driven by the calendar,with the organization following a rhythmic,time-paced approach (e.g., a new productlaunch every eighteen months).

Time-paced creative processes encourage cu-mulative invention and GA in multiple ways.First, they generate a constant time pressure foreach invention (Brown & Eisenhardt, 1997). Fre-quent invention under these pressures suggeststhat the salience-in-memory of the organiza-tion’s prior inventions will be higher: knowledgeused in the recent past is likely to be recalledmore easily. Further, the time pressure creates“a sense of urgency” and energy (Eisenhardt &

2013 259Ahuja, Lampert, and Novelli

Brown, 1998) as each individual becomes con-scious that his or her failure will hold up others.This enhances individual motivation to find asolution and, thus, leads to invention (Shere-mata, 2000). Second, the use of an internalrhythm decouples the organization from the lesscontrollable changes in the external environ-ment while enhancing its sensitivity to techni-cal changes within the organization (Brown &Eisenhardt, 1997). This reduced importance ofexternal stimuli further encourages inventors tobecome cognizant of invention possibilities pre-sented by the organization’s own portfolio ofpast inventions. Third, the rhythm also makespossible a form of entrainment (Brown & Eisen-hardt, 1997) as the various subgroups within theorganization synchronize their activities to thesame internal clock and even build on each oth-er’s inventions. For instance, Intel’s introductionof a series of time-paced chips throughout the1990s was probably enabled by the fact that ineach case the firm was building on its own pre-vious architecture and could rely on the manu-facturing process for the ever-denser chips to besimultaneously coordinated.

Proposition 4a: The use of time-pacedcreative processes leads to higher GAfor firms.

Creative processes in organizations also varyin their degree of formal structure. Highly struc-tured creative processes that involve tight timeaccountability and costing, resource-gated pro-cedures, and “disciplined problem solving” im-prove the efficiency of invention but may reduceits creativity (Brown & Eisenhardt, 1995; Clark &Fujimoto, 1991). In contrast, less structured cre-ative processes enhance motivation and creativ-ity (Amabile, 1987; Brown & Eisenhardt, 1997),which are beneficial to invention, but may leadto very scattershot invention outcomes ratherthan cumulative invention. Between these two isthe possibility of what we call “semistructuredcreative processes” (see Brown & Eisenhardt,1997, for the broader notion of semistructure),which we argue are likely to support high GA.

Semistructured creative processes foster cu-mulative invention by combining some structurewith some freedom. They provide direction, butwithout explicit fiat, through “unobstrusiveguidance” practices. For instance, policies pro-viding a certain amount of time for inventors topursue their own projects (e.g., 3M’s 15 percent

“personal” time) while restricting the bulk oftheir time to corporate projects, provide bothcorporate direction and individual autonomy.Such “personal” time fractions, while being sub-stantive and thus motivating to inventors whovalue “freedom,” may not be so high as to en-able inventors to go on complete flights of fancy.Given that 85 percent of the scientist’s time isoccupied with corporate projects, it is likely thatsuch “personal” time will be spent in the neigh-borhood of these existing corporate projects, forat least three reasons: (1) the human tendency oflocal search, (2) the constraint of scientists’ ex-pertise and attention being limited to specificareas, and (3) the social context that is likely todirect attention to commonly shared company-wide concerns. Similarly, providing a commonsubsidized cafeteria where all scientists eat(and thereby talk) or bringing together scientistsfrom different units into company-wide inven-tion fairs is a subtle way to encourage workalong certain trajectories of knowledge that uti-lize the organization’s earlier inventions. Theabove arguments suggest that using semistruc-tured creative processes fosters cumulative in-vention and, thus, enhances GA for firms.

Proposition 4b: The use of semistruc-tured creative processes leads tohigher GA for firms.

GA and Resources Available for Invention

The amount of resources available to pursuethe invention process is likely to influence thedirection of inventive effort and, eventually, thefirm’s degree of GA. We suggest that moderatelevels of resource availability should lead tohigher GA, relative to very low or very highlevels of resource availability.

Pursuing inventions is expensive and risky.For exploratory activity to be supported, suffi-cient resources need to be made available to theorganization (Lounamaa & March, 1987; Nohria& Gulati, 1996). As resources for invention areincreased from a very low level, inventive explo-ration is encouraged and inventiveness is en-hanced. However, when the amount of resourcesmade available for invention is very high, theincentives to examine and mine the firm’s exist-ing portfolio of inventions for new possibilitiesmay be limited—exploration is fun and chal-lenging, the money is available, and discipline

260 AprilAcademy of Management Review

is lacking (Nohria & Gulati, 1996). In contrast,moderate levels of resource availability permitsome exploration but also encourage reuse ofexisting inventive knowledge as firms mustmake the most of what is available and adaptexisting knowledge to address new problems(Majchrzak et al., 2004). These arguments sug-gest that cumulative invention and, therefore,GA will be curvilinearly related to the resourcesavailable for invention.

Proposition 5: Moderate levels of orga-nizational resource availability for in-vention lead to higher GA for firmsthan very high or very low levels.

THE PRECLUSIVE COMPONENT OF GA

GA and the Division of Inventive Labor

Hiring away scientists who embody a firm’sinventive knowledge is a potent weapon in en-abling a competitor to build on the firm’s inven-tions. This is especially true in the context oftacit and hard to codify knowledge (Kogut &Zander, 1992). Task design can be used to miti-gate such hazards (Liebeskind, 1996). The prin-ciples of division of labor and task design canbe applied at two different levels within theorganization to limit the degree to which infor-mation can leave the firm: first, to the divisionand distribution of tasks across geographic lo-cations, and, second, to the design of individ-ual jobs.

A firm can strategically limit the degree towhich information can leave the firm by imple-menting a specific geographic distribution ofresearch tasks across the organization (Zhao,2006). Inventions create value through the syn-thesis of inventive knowledge elements withother complementary inventive knowledge ele-ments or assets of the firm (Zhao, 2006). Individ-ual knowledge elements are less valuable in theabsence of their complementary components(Anand & Galetovic, 2004; Zhao, 2006). By effec-tively separating research projects into distinctand mutually complementary components, witheach key component being based in a differentgeographic location, firms can make the act ofrecombination difficult for competitors. Success-fully exploiting these knowledge elements todevelop new inventions would require otherfirms to be able to tap into knowledge frommultiple locations simultaneously, a task that is

significantly more difficult than tapping intoone location. Thus, firms can use the dual mech-anisms of specialization (and differentiation) atthe location level and integration at the organi-zational level to simultaneously enhance theirinventive output while reducing the danger ofknowledge expropriation (Demsetz, 1991;Grant, 1996).

Firms can also limit the degree to which in-formation can leave by implementing a distri-bution of research tasks at the individual levelthrough job design and employee conduct rules.Using larger project teams implies that individ-ual scientists have a proportionately smallerrole in the project. Such a division of labor en-sures that the knowledge available with eachindividual member for each project is smaller.As a result, to reconstruct a given level of knowl-edge about a project at the original firm, thecompetitor must hire away more people (Ahuja,2002). This is likely to be difficult. Further, withthis arrangement the marginal product of eachindividual team member to a given project de-clines. Hence, to extract the maximal value fromhis or her own inventive knowledge, each scien-tist in the focal firm needs more complementaryunits of knowledge (from other scientists), thusmaking his or her departure decision more dif-ficult. Finally, to the extent that some scientistsdo move, this task organization limits the dis-ruption of the focal project since the lost scien-tists represent only a small part of the project’sscientific expertise.

However, while the managerial choices ofgeographically dispersing research activitiesand enlarging the size of the resource team pro-vide a fundamental impetus toward preclusion,these choices can also have a simultaneous im-plication for cumulative invention. Splitting re-search tasks across geographies raises integra-tion and coordination challenges for the focalfirm. Indeed, if tasks are extremely fragmented,these coordination challenges could interferewith the firm’s own ability to invent, reducingGA. Similarly, as team size becomes very large,it is possible that the costs of integrating theknowledge to develop new inventions will in-crease and the coordination complexities willreduce inventiveness. Furthermore, with verylarge teams, the close ties that are necessary forthe transfer of rich information between mem-bers may become more difficult to build andmaintain, limiting the development of a social

2013 261Ahuja, Lampert, and Novelli

community. Such a social community is impor-tant since it can provide a superior work envi-ronment to foster the productivity of the teamand serve as a retention device making it moredifficult for individual inventors to leave (Paru-churi, Nerkar, & Hambrick, 2006).2 These nega-tive implications of the division of labor acrosslocations or teams could limit the firm’s owninventiveness and hurt its GA.

This suggests the existence of an inverted-Urelationship between firms’ division of inventivelabor and their GA:

Proposition 6a: Moderate dispersion offirms’ research activities across geo-graphic locations leads to higher GAfor firms than very high or very lowdispersion.

Proposition 6b: The use of moderatelysized research teams leads to higherGA for firms than the use of very largeor very small research teams.

GA and Retention-Oriented HR Practices

In addition to being hired away by competi-tors, key inventors might leave the firm volun-tarily to start their own companies. In this case anatural knowledge input for the inventive activ-ity of the new-born enterprise would be the in-ventor’s recent inventive knowledge, possiblyoriginated within the context of the employer’sinventive activity (Klepper & Sleeper, 2005). Thissuggests that a path to precluding other firmsfrom building on the inventive knowledge of thefocal firm is to reduce the turnover of researchemployees through retention-oriented HR prac-tices. Moreover, retention also contributes to en-hancing cumulative invention by ensuring thatemployees who developed earlier inventionsstay within the firm and contribute their knowl-edge to later inventions. Common retention-oriented practices include higher relative pay,internal promotion opportunities, provision ofemployment security, and restrictions on em-ployee activity, such as noncompete agree-ments.

Research on retention has emphasized thatlong-term incentives and inducements reduce a

firm’s turnover rate (Batt & Colvin, 2011; Doe-ringer & Piore, 1971). Such long-term incentivesand inducements can help to enhance a firm’sability to preclude others from building on itsinventions. For instance, higher relative pay in-creases the inventor’s opportunity cost of leav-ing the firm. Similarly, noncompete agreementsthat prevent employees from working in areasthat are close to the areas they worked in fortheir employer (Franco & Mitchell, 2008; Marx,Strumsky, & Fleming, 2009) also reduce the at-tractiveness of departure for employees, sincethey reduce employees’ value to other employ-ers and also significantly diminish employees’ability to work in their primary domains of ex-pertise (Marx et al., 2009).

Long-term incentives and perceptions of jobsecurity also facilitate cumulative invention. Forinstance, delayed-vesting option compensationthat provides employees with a right to buyshares of stock at set historical prices and holdthem for a certain number of years inhibits de-partures and, hence, loss of knowledge to otherfirms. It also fosters cumulative invention bymotivating inventors to continue inventing,since subsequent inventions represent both anexercise of their creative capabilities and ameans of enhancing the value of their options.Further, such devices and long-term job securityin general discourage inventors from exten-sively engaging in job searches (Direnzo &Greenhaus, 2011), facilitating the developmentof a longer-term research agenda within the or-ganization, again fostering cumulative inven-tion. The above arguments suggest that the useof retention-oriented HR practices fosters bothpreclusion and cumulative invention and, thus,enhances GA.

Proposition 7: The use of retention-oriented HR practices leads to higherGA for firms.

GA and Invention Domain

Whenever a firm commits resources to the de-velopment of a new invention, it faces a choicebetween building inventions in inventiveknowledge domains that it is already active inor domains that are conceptually similar to thedomains it is active in and building inventionsin new or unrelated knowledge domains. Ourargument draws on the literature on local

2 We are grateful to an anonymous reviewer for this valu-able suggestion.

262 AprilAcademy of Management Review

search and absorptive capacity to predict thatas a firm develops inventions in the same orrelated domains, its GA is enhanced as its abil-ity to build on its inventions increases and theincentives and capability of competitors to buildon its inventions decrease.

Understanding and knowledge are often cu-mulative (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990; Helfat, 1997;Nelson & Winter, 1982). The extent of a firm’sprior experience in an inventive knowledge do-main is, thus, a good predictor of the firm’ssubsequent invention success in that domain(Stuart & Podolny, 1996). Focusing inventive ac-tivities within a narrow domain or withinclosely related domains therefore fosters cumu-lative invention. Further, it is also likely to favorpreclusion of other firms. Entry into a knowledgedomain where the focal firm has been inventingextensively is likely to be unattractive to com-petitors, because as a firm progressively ex-pands its dominance in a specific domain, itsgreater experience in the domain increases itsrelative competence (Cohen & Levinthal, 1989,1990; Lane, Koka, & Pathak, 2006) vis-à-vis otherfirms. Recognizing this relative disadvantage,and given the finite carrying capacity of anydomain, when faced with a firm who dominatesa given knowledge domain, potential entrantswill choose to forgo entry into that domain andto seek other domains where their disadvantageis not as pronounced. The above arguments sug-gest that focusing inventive activities within anarrow domain or within closely related do-mains fosters both cumulative invention andpreclusion and, thus, enhances GA.

Proposition 8: Focusing inventive ac-tivity within a narrow domain orwithin closely related domains leadsto higher GA for firms.

GA and Supporting Assets

Firms can also influence the incentives ofcompetitors to build on their inventions throughownership of the supporting assets necessary tocommercialize the stream of inventions. Manu-facturing facilities, marketing and sales forces,and a global infrastructure to commercialize aninvention are all critical for profiting from inven-tions in general (Teece, 1986). We emphasizethat such assets also retain their value in thecontext of GA. An established global infrastruc-

ture can create a speed advantage for the firmthat owns the infrastructure by enabling thetranslation of a given invention into a marketedproduct or service across the globe in an effi-cient and effective fashion. This speed advan-tage is useful for converting a given invention toprofits and also acts as a deterrent to other com-petitors who want to enter that invention nichewith derivative inventions.

Consider two firms, A and B. Assume that Ahas an infrastructure of supporting assets intwenty countries, whereas B has such an infra-structure in only two countries. Now considerfirm C, which is considering building on an in-ventive opportunity opened up by the inventionsof either firm A or B. Other things being equal,firm C would prefer to build on the opportunitycreated by B’s inventions rather than on the op-portunity created by A’s inventions. The concernfor C would be that if it launched a new deriv-ative invention based on A’s inventions, A couldreplicate C’s efforts and launch a similar prod-uct relatively quickly in the twenty markets inwhich A is currently active. Yet, if C picks B’sideas to build on, it knows that B’s speed advan-tage exists in only two markets. Therefore, otherthings being equal, C would face less competi-tion if it picked B’s ideas over A’s to build on.Based on the above arguments, we suggest thata broader global infrastructure fosters preclu-sion of other firms and, thus, enhances GA.

Proposition 9: Owning a broaderglobal infrastructure of supporting as-sets leads to higher GA for firms.

GA and R&D Alliances

Firms often generate inventive knowledgethrough R&D alliances with other firms. We ar-gue here that this choice of mode for sourcinginventive knowledge has implications for firms’GA. Specifically, developing inventive knowl-edge internally enhances GA more than devel-oping it through joint research projects withother firms. First, in-house development limitsoutsiders’ access to the firm’s knowledge. In con-trast, joint knowledge development efforts withother firms imply that the focal firm risks expos-ing its knowledge core (Thompson, 1967) to itspartners, who may then use that knowledge tobuild on its inventions (Garcia-Canal, Valdes-Llaneza, & Sanchez-Lorda, 2008; Hamel, Doz, &

2013 263Ahuja, Lampert, and Novelli

Prahalad, 1989). Second, in-house developmentallows firms to make idiosyncratic inventivechoices relating to the design and creation ofthe product or process such that their choicesare maximally and uniquely complementaryonly with their own bundle of activities andprior inventions (Anand & Galetovic, 2004). This,in turn, limits the opportunity for other firms touse this knowledge in an effective fashion.

Although, in principle, having many alliancescould also provide an opportunity for the focalfirm to benefit from more knowledge spilloveropportunities, it is likely that this effect may notplay a significant role in increasing its GA. Withmany alliances being enacted simultaneously,given finite absorptive capacity, the firm’s abil-ity to assimilate and absorb knowledge flowsmay be diminished (Burt, 1992). Further, control-ling knowledge flows in alliance settings re-quires tight compartmentalization of individualalliances and tight definition of alliance scope(Khanna, Gulati, & Nohria, 1998; Oxley & Wada,2010). With many alliances, such tight controlmay be difficult. Indeed, in such a contextknowledge may leak from many different pointsof a firm in a sprinkler head fashion (Owen-Smith & Powell, 2004), facilitating the inventiveefforts of others. The above arguments suggestthat developing inventive knowledge throughR&D alliances reduces the preclusion of otherfirms from building on the focal firm’s inven-tions and, thus, reduces GA, an outcome furtherworsened by having many alliances.

Proposition 10a: Developing inventiveknowledge through R&D alliances (asopposed to through in-house efforts)leads to lower GA for firms. This effectwill strengthen as the number of R&Dalliances increases.

When firms do use alliances to develop inven-tive knowledge, different types of alliances havediffering effects on GA; specifically, scale alli-ances entail higher risks to GA than link alli-ances. A scale alliance involves two partnersthat both bring the same capability into the al-liance, with the core objective of facilitatingeconomies of scale (Dussauge, Garrette, &Mitchell, 2004). Thus, Intel and AMD’s forming arelationship to develop a new microprocessorwould be an illustration of a scale R&D alliance,since both firms bring chip development skillsto the alliance. Conversely, in a link alliance the

partners bring different skills to the alliance(Dussauge et al., 2004), as in the case of researchcollaboration between a chip design companyand a chip manufacturing foundry.

Two sets of arguments suggest that the leak-age of inventive knowledge to outsiders is likelyto be worse for scale alliances than for linkalliances. First, given the similarity in theircompetence backgrounds, partners in scale R&Dalliances are likely to have high levels of ab-sorptive capacity for the knowledge of theirpartners (Cohen & Levinthal, 1989; Lane & Lubat-kin, 1998; Park & Russo, 1996). Commonalities ofinterests and competencies between firms inscale alliances (Ahuja, 2000; Dussauge et al.,2004; Koka & Prescott, 2002; Lane & Lubatkin,1998) facilitate information diffusion, and as thenumber of such ties increases, policing them fordiffusion of information may become progres-sively more difficult. In R&D link alliances, in-stead, partners bring different kinds of knowl-edge to the alliance and may not have as strongan absorptive capacity for their partners’ knowl-edge as they did with scale alliances.

Second, unlike scale alliances, which imply ahorizontal relationship between partners, linkalliances reflect vertical ties. The overlap be-tween the interests of partners in link alliancesis lower than that in horizontal ties. Many of theaspects of a firm’s inventive knowledge coreand the trajectories of inventions that are possi-ble from it may be of limited interest to thepartners. For example, a chip foundry firm in analliance with a chip design firm may have lim-ited interest in understanding how higher-orderfeatures can be designed into chips—its interestwould be more in creating new ways of manu-facturing the chips than in new product featuresper se. These arguments suggest that forminglink alliances fosters the preclusion of otherfirms from building on the focal firm’s inven-tions, relative to scale alliances, and, thus, en-hances GA.

Proposition 10b: Forming link alli-ances leads to higher GA for firmsthan forming scale alliances.

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS

In this article we drew a distinction betweentwo notions of appropriability and identifiedsome of the determinants of the less studied one.

264 AprilAcademy of Management Review

We developed the concept of GA as a potentiallyrelevant outcome in assessing the performanceof inventive firms. We identified two paths toinfluencing this outcome— cumulative inven-tion and preclusion of others—and developedpropositions to explain how firms could use ba-sic levers of organizational structure, systems,and strategy to enhance the firm’s GA. In thissection we suggest directions for further re-search based on the identification of caveats tobe considered in the context of GA, and we dis-cuss the managerial and theoretical implica-tions of GA.

Implications for Future Research on GA

We have indicated several reasons why firmsmight want to enhance GA, and we also haveidentified strategies firms may use to do so.However, an issue worth considering is whetherit makes sense for firms to always try to enhanceGA. It is indeed likely that, as with other perfor-mance outcomes for firms, enhancing GA maybe more or less desirable depending on under-lying conditions. We identify several sets of cir-cumstances under which firms would have toevaluate trade-offs before deciding whether ornot to enhance GA. For instance, the value ofenhancing GA may depend on expectationsabout the nature of the spawned inventions.Spawned inventions could be substitutes (theyaddress the same buyer need and render theoriginal invention less competitive), comple-ments to the existing invention (they boost thesales of the original invention), or inventionsunrelated to the existing invention in product-market terms. Prima facie, it would appear thatfirms may have different attitudes toward theimportance of increasing GA depending onwhether the expected subsequent inventionsare substitutes versus complements.

Other trade-offs may emerge because of con-flicts between GA and other desirable outcomesfor a firm. We noted earlier that the strategies toenhance appropriability may be different acrossPA and GA, thus leading to a conflict betweenthe two. Similarly, different environments maycause the relative importance of PA and GA tovary. For instance, in an environment of ferment,where new competitive products are continu-ously being launched (Abernathy & Utterback,1978), being able to develop newer, enhancedproducts may be more important than trying to

figure out how to marginally improve the mon-etization of a given invention. However, in otherenvironments the relative payoff between PAand GA may be reversed. Developing a “contin-gent hierarchy of appropriabilities” and identi-fying the conditions under which a particularform of appropriability is favored over the otherwould indeed be an exciting and useful re-search direction.3

Trade-offs are also associated with the twocomponents of GA: cumulative invention andpreclusion of others. For instance, cumulativeinvention is likely to foster relatively speedyinvention since building on existing inventiveknowledge enables the firm to respond fasterthan entering a knowledge space de novo. Thiscould be advantageous in the short run and indynamic environments where speed is impor-tant. However, such a strategy may also be asource of rigidity in the long run. A firm focusedon building on its existing inventive knowledgemay not adequately experiment with new inven-tive trajectories and may end up not alignedwith the needs of consumers. Similarly, preclud-ing others from building on the firm’s inventionsprovides the focal firm dominance in a knowl-edge domain. However, since great solutionscan emerge from the cross-fertilization of differ-ent and unrelated inventive knowledge bases,knowledge spillovers from one firm to anothermay open new paths to invention and possiblyeven new inventive fields. These potential ben-efits are at risk when the firm pursues preclu-sion very strongly.

Evaluating GA performance gives firms achance to draw managerial attention to a set ofcounterfactuals that are not commonly focusedon in performance reviews. Much performancemeasurement in firms focuses on evaluations ofmanagers and organizations through their real-ized outcomes on certain milestones, such asprofits. However, a case could be made that op-timizing performance may entail examining notjust how well a firm has performed but also howmuch better it could have performed. GA pro-vides an outcome that draws attention to thisaspect of performance. An organization trackingits GA may recognize not only how successful ithas been in commercializing a product but also

3 We are grateful to an anonymous reviewer for suggest-ing the development of a hierarchy of appropriabilities.

2013 265Ahuja, Lampert, and Novelli

how much more could have been possible byrecognizing and exploiting follow-on inventions.This discussion suggests that identifying poten-tial measures of GA would help to push the GAresearch agenda as well as its usage in prac-tice. In industries where patents are meaning-ful, patent data can be used to measure GA.Citations in a patent are markers of its intellec-tual lineage, since they indicate that a particu-lar invention was built upon a prior invention. Asimple archival measure of GA is provided bythe ratio of self-citations to a firm’s patents tothe total citations received by the firm’s patents.In other contexts one could imagine using prod-uct characteristics and features data to tracelinkages between products within andacross firms.

Implications for Theory

Priem and Butler (2001) have noted that spe-cifically identifying “how” resources create sus-tained value and incorporating a temporal com-ponent that relates a firm’s history to its currentoutcomes are two key issues that need to beaddressed for further development of the RBV.This article addresses these issues. The con-struct of GA draws attention to the possibilitythat sustained value creation occurs not justthrough the “defense” plays of protection fromimitation and substitution, already well dis-cussed in the literature, but also through a thirdpath, the “offense” play of creating new inven-tions that lead into new product markets. Fur-ther, by identifying specific strategies throughwhich firms may leverage the power of theirpast inventions into future inventions, this arti-cle also illuminates a temporal link between anorganization’s past successes and its currentoutcomes and shows how resources, instead ofsimply being eroded over time (Priem & Butler,2001), may also lead to new rents. For instance,Apple’s performance over the last decade has insome part been based on protection from imita-tion and substitution in existing product mar-kets. Yet perhaps equally important is its perfor-mance in creating new inventions building onits own prior inventions, which has helped Ap-ple to target completely new product markets.

This article also identifies implications for theliterature on organizational learning. Much ofthe knowledge literature has focused on theidentification of factors that enhance interorga-

nizational learning and facilitate knowledgetransfer across organizations (Grandori & Kogut,2002). GA draws attention to two less studiedaspects of organizational learning. First, GAemphasizes how a firm can enhance the utiliza-tion of its own existing knowledge over time forthe purposes of invention. A distinguishingcharacteristic of knowledge is that, unlike phys-ical inputs, it is not consumed in its usage in theproduction process. Rather, usage may makeprior knowledge even more useful by indicatingdifferent ways that it can be recombined (cf. ourdiscussion of the conceptual component of aninvention). Yet converting this potential for re-use—which is one of knowledge’s most promis-ing and productive features—from being latentto becoming realized requires a better under-standing of how organizations might systemat-ically improve their utilization of their existingknowledge. Although knowledge recombinationis recognized as one of the core functions of afirm (Grant, 1996), there has been limited re-search on the strategies that enable firms torecombine their knowledge into new syntheses,a notable underemphasis in the context of anincreasingly knowledge-driven economy.

In this article we focus directly on the knowl-edge reuse problem and, in the process, high-light an important puzzle: knowledge is valu-able because it can be reused, but it is difficultto store or retrieve in a manner that makes itavailable at the locus where its reuse would bethe most beneficial. The propositions we havepresented identify how elements of organiza-tional structure, systems, and strategy can beused to address this puzzle in the context ofknowledge reuse for invention. Identifying otherstrategies that can be used to address this puz-zle and targeting knowledge reuse contexts be-yond invention are natural directions for furtherresearch.

Second, the learning literature has commonlyfocused on how organizations can increase theirlearning from other organizations. In contrast,this article draws attention to the strategies thatfirms may use to prevent others from learningfrom them. Although prima facie that appearssocially undesirable, a nuanced considerationdraws our attention to the incentive problemunderlying GA—in a for-profit world, activitiesthat do not yield returns to the actor are eventu-ally not undertaken. In that sense, the strategiesreflected here, while appearing undesirable,

266 AprilAcademy of Management Review

may still be better than the alternatives in pro-moting research effort. Theoretically, this articletherefore represents a call to integrate more di-rectly the consideration of incentives and com-petition into the literature on learning (Grandori& Kogut, 2002). For instance, research modelingknowledge spillovers would need to explicitlyrecognize that firms could strategically be at-tempting to minimize such spillovers. This mayimply a need for a more nuanced theoretical andmethodological approach in studying how orga-nizations learn from each other.

Understanding how the two components ofGA (and the managerial choices underlyingthem) might interrelate with each other wouldbe helpful—another task for future research.

REFERENCES

Abernathy, W. J., & Utterback, J. M. 1978. Patterns of indus-trial innovation. Technology Review, 80(7): 40–47.

Ahuja, G. 2000. Collaboration networks, structural holes, andinnovation: A longitudinal study. Administrative Sci-ence Quarterly, 45: 425–455.

Ahuja, G. 2002. When Atlas shrugged: Pre-emption, complex-ity and division of labor in a theory of appropriability.Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Academyof Management, Seattle.

Alchian, A. A. 1950. Uncertainty, evolution, and economictheory. Journal of Political Economy, 58: 211–221.

Amabile, T. M. 1987. The motivation to be creative. In S.Isaksen (Ed.), Frontiers of creativity research: Beyond thebasics: 223–254. Buffalo, NY: Bearly Limited.

Anand, B., & Galetovic, A. 2004. How market smarts canprotect property rights. Harvard Business Review, 82(12):72–81.

Argyres, N. S., & Silverman, B. S. 2004. R&D, organizationstructure, and the development of corporate technolog-ical knowledge. Strategic Management Journal, 25(Spe-cial Issue): 929–958.

Arrow, K. J. 1962. Economic welfare and the allocation ofresources for invention. In The rate and direction ofinventive activity: Economic and social factors: 609–626.Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Batt, R., & Colvin, A. J. S. 2011. An employment systemsapproach to turnover: Human resources practices, quits,dismissals, and performance. Academy of ManagementJournal, 54: 695–717.

Benner, M. J., & Tushman, M. L. 2003. Exploitation, explora-tion, and process management: The productivity di-lemma revisited. Academy of Management Review, 28:238–256.

Brown, J., & Eisenhardt, K. 1995. Product development: Pastresearch, present findings, and future directions. Acad-emy of Management Review, 20: 342–378.

Brown, J., & Eisenhardt, K. 1997. The art of continuouschange: Linking complexity theory and time-paced evo-lution in relentlessly shifting organizations. Administra-tive Science Quarterly, 42: 1–34.

Burrows, P. 2009. Lessons from the Apple-Psystar battle.Bloomberg Business Week, December 2: http://www.businessweek.com/technology/content/dec2009/tc2009121_009697.htm.

Burt, R. S. 1992. Structural holes. Cambridge, MA: HarvardUniversity Press.

Cardinal, L. B. 2001. Technological innovation in the phar-maceutical industry: The use of organizational control inmanaging research and development. Organization Sci-ence, 12: 19–36.

Chesbrough, H. 2002. Graceful exits and missed opportuni-ties: Xerox’s management of its technology spin-off or-ganizations. Business History Review, 76: 803–837.

Christensen, C. M. 1997. The innovator’s dilemma. Boston:Harvard Business School Press.

Christensen, C. M., & Bower, J. L. 1996. Customer power,strategic investment and the failure of leading firms.Strategic Management Journal, 17: 197–218.

Clark, K. B., & Fujimoto, T. 1991. Product development perfor-mance. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. 1989. Innovation and learn-ing: The two faces of R&D. Economic Journal, 99: 569–596.

Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. 1990. Absorptive capacity: Anew perspective on learning and innovation. Adminis-trative Science Quarterly, 35: 128–152.

Cohen, W. M., Nelson, R. R., & Walsh, J. P. 2000. Protectingtheir intellectual assets: Appropriability conditions andwhy U.S. manufacturing firms patent (or not). NBERWorking Paper No. 7552, National Bureau of EconomicResearch, Cambridge, MA.

Demsetz, H. 1991. The theory of the firm revisited. In O. E.Williamson & S. Winter (Eds.), The nature of the firm:159–178. New York: Oxford University Press.

Dierickx, I., & Cool, K. 1989. Asset stock accumulation andsustainability of competitive advantage. ManagementScience, 35: 1504–1511.

Direnzo, M. S., & Greenhaus, J. H. 2011. Job search and vol-untary turnover in a boundaryless world: A control the-ory perspective. Academy of Management Review, 36:567–589.

Doeringer, P., & Piore, M. 1971. Internal labor markets andmanpower analysis. Lexington, MA: Heath.

Dussauge, P., Garrette, B., & Mitchell, W. 2004. Asymmetricperformance: The market share impact of scale and linkalliances in the global auto industry. Strategic Manage-ment Journal, 25: 701–711.

Eisenhardt, K. M., & Brown, S. L. 1998. Time pacing: Compet-ing in markets that won’t stand still. Harvard BusinessReview, 76(2): 59–69.

Fang, C., Lee, J., & Schilling, M. A. 2010. Balancing explora-tion and exploitation through structural design: The iso-

2013 267Ahuja, Lampert, and Novelli

lation of subgroups and organizational learning. Orga-nization Science, 21: 625–642.

Fleming, L. 2001. Recombinant uncertainty in technologicalsearch. Management Science, 47: 117–132.

Franco, A. M., & Mitchell, M. F. 2008. Covenants not to com-pete, labor mobility, and industry dynamics. Journal ofEconomics & Management Strategy, 17: 581–606.

Garcia-Canal, E., Valdes-Llaneza, A., & Sanchez-Lorda, P.2008. Technological flows and the choice of joint ven-tures in technology alliances. Research Policy, 37: 97–114.

Geer, C. T. 1990. Epi-logue? Forbes, August 6: 114.

Gillette, F. 2011. The rise and inglorious fall of Myspace.Bloomberg Business Week, June 22: 1.

Goldenberg, J., Mazursky, D., & Solomon, S. 1999. Towardidentifying the inventive templates of new products: Achanneled ideation approach. Journal of Marketing Re-search, 36: 200–210.

Grandori, A., & Kogut, B. 2002. Dialogue on organization andknowledge. Organization Science, 13: 224–231.

Grant, R. M. 1996. Toward a knowledge-based theory of thefirm. Strategic Management Journal, 17(Winter SpecialIssue): 109–122.

Grant, R. M. 2007. Contemporary strategy analysis (6th ed.).Oxford: Blackwell.

Green, J. R., & Scotchmer, S. 1995. On the division of profit insequential innovation. RAND Journal of Economics, 26:20–33.

Hamel, G., Doz, Y. L., & Prahalad, C. K. 1989. Collaborate withyour competitors—and win. Harvard Business Review,67(1): 133–139.

Hansen, M. T., Nohria, N., & Tierney, T. 1999. What’s yourstrategy for managing knowledge? Harvard BusinessReview, 77(2): 106–116.

Hargadon, A. B. 1998. Firms as knowledge brokers: Lessonsin pursuing continuous innovation. California Manage-ment Review, 40(3): 209–227.

Hargadon, A. B., & Sutton, R. I. 1997. Technology brokeringand innovation in a product development firm. Admin-istrative Science Quarterly, 42: 716–749.

Helfat, C. E. 1997. Know-how and asset complementarity anddynamic capability accumulation: The case of R&D.Strategic Management Journal, 18: 339–360.

Hollingshead, A. B. 2001. Cognitive interdependence andconvergent expectations in transactive memory. Journalof Personality and Social Psychology, 81: 1080–1089.

Hopenhayn, H., Llobet, G., & Mitchell, M. F. 2006. Rewardingsequential innovators: Prizes, patents, and buyouts.Journal of Political Economy, 114: 1041–1068.

Hopenhayn, H., & Mitchell, M. F. 1999. Innovation fertility andpatent design. NBER Working Paper No. 7070, NationalBureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.

Katila, R., & Ahuja, G. 2002. Something old, something new:A longitudinal study of search behavior and new prod-uct introduction. Academy of Management Journal, 45:1183–1194.

Khanna, T., Gulati, R., & Nohria, N. 1998. The dynamics oflearning alliances: Competition, cooperation, and rela-tive scope. Strategic Management Journal, 19: 193–210.

King, A. W. 2007. Disentangling interfirm and intrafirmcausal ambiguity: A conceptual model of causal ambi-guity and sustainable competitive advantage. Academyof Management Review, 32: 156–178.

King, A. W., & Zeithaml, C. P. 2001. Competencies and firmperformance: Examining the causal ambiguity paradox.Strategic Management Journal, 22: 75–99.

Klepper, S., & Sleeper, S. 2005. Entry by spinoffs. Manage-ment Science, 51: 1291–1306.

Kogut, B., & Zander, U. 1992. Knowledge of the firm, combi-native capabilities, and the replication of technology.Organization Science, 3: 383–397.

Koka, B. R., & Prescott, J. B. 2002. Strategic alliances as socialcapital: A multidimensional view. Strategic Manage-ment Journal, 23: 795–816.

Lane, P. J., Koka, B. R., & Pathak, S. 2006. The reification ofabsorptive capacity: A critical review and rejuvenationof the construct. Academy of Management Review, 31:833–863.

Lane, P. J., & Lubatkin, M. H. 1998. Relative absorptive capac-ity and interorganizational learning. Strategic Manage-ment Journal, 19: 461–477.

Levin, R. C., Klevorick, A., Nelson, R., & Winter, S. 1987.Appropriating the returns from industrial research anddevelopment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3:783–831.

Levinthal, D. A., & March, J. G. 1981. A model of adaptiveorganizational search. Journal of Economic Behaviorand Organization, 2: 307–333.

Lewis, K., Lange, D., & Gillis, L. 2005. Transactive memorysystems, learning, and learning transfer. OrganizationScience, 16: 581–598.

Liebeskind, J. P. 1996. Knowledge, strategy and the theory ofthe firm. Strategic Management Journal, 17(Winter Spe-cial Issue): 93–1072.

Lippman, S. A., & Rumelt, R. P. 1982. Uncertain imitability: Ananalysis of interfirm differences in efficiency undercompetition. Bell Journal of Economics, 13: 418–438.

Lounamaa, P., & March, J. 1987. Adaptive coordination of alearning team. Management Science, 33: 107–123.

Majchrzak, A., Cooper, L. P., & Neece, O. P. 2004. Knowledgereuse for innovation. Management Science, 50: 174–188.

March, J. G. 1991. Exploration and exploitation in organiza-tional learning. Organization Science, 2: 71–87.

Marx, M., Strumsky, D., & Fleming, L. 2009. Mobility, skills,and the Michigan non-compete experiment. Manage-ment Science, 55: 875–889.

McEvily, S. K., & Chakravarthy, B. 2002. The persistence ofknowledge-based advantage: An empirical test forproduct performance and technological knowledge.Strategic Management Journal, 23: 285–305.

268 AprilAcademy of Management Review

McEvily, S. K., Das, S., & McCabe, K. 2000. Avoiding compe-tence substitution through knowledge sharing. Acad-emy of Management Review, 25: 294–312.

Murray, F., & O’Mahony, S. 2007. Exploring the foundations ofcumulative innovation: Implications for organizationscience. Organization Science, 18: 1006–1021.

Nelson, R., & Winter, S. 1982. An evolutionary theory of eco-nomic change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard UniversityPress.

Nickerson, J. A., & Zenger, T. R. 2002. Being efficiently fickle:A dynamic theory of organizational choice. Organiza-tion Science, 13: 547–566.

Nohria, N., & Gulati, R. 1996. Is slack good or bad for inno-vation? Academy of Management Journal, 39: 1245–1264.

Owen-Smith, J., & Powell, W. W. 2004. Knowledge networksas channels and conduits: The effects of spillovers in theBoston biotechnology community. Organization Science,15: 5–21.

Oxley, J., & Wada, T. 2010. Alliance structure and the scope ofknowledge transfer: Evidence from U.S.-Japan agree-ments. Management Science, 55: 635–649.

Park, S., & Russo, M. 1996. When competition eclipses coop-eration: An event history analysis of joint venture fail-ure. Management Science, 42: 875–890.

Paruchuri, S., Nerkar, A., & Hambrick, D. C. 2006. Acquisitionintegration and productivity losses in the technical core:Disruption of inventors in acquired companies. Organi-zation Science, 17: 545–562.

Priem, R. L., & Butler, J. E. 2001. Is the resource-based “view”a useful perspective for strategic management re-search? Academy of Management Review, 26: 22–40.

Reed, R., & DeFillippi, R. J. 1990. Causal ambiguity, barriersto imitation, and sustainable competitive advantage.Academy of Management Review, 15: 88–102.

Rivkin, J. 2001. Reproducing knowledge: Replication withoutimitation at moderate complexity. Organization Sci-ence, 12: 274–293.

Roberts, P. W. 1999. Product innovation, product-market com-petition and persistent profitability in the U.S. pharma-ceutical industry. Strategic Management Journal, 20:655–670.

Sanchez, R., & Mahoney, J. T. 1996. Modularity, flexibility,and knowledge management in product and organiza-tion design. Strategic Management Journal, 17(WinterSpecial Issue): 63–76.

Scotchmer, S., & Green, J. 1990. Novelty and disclosure inpatent law. RAND Journal of Economics, 21: 131–146.

Sheremata, W. A. 2000. Centrifugal and centripetal forces inradical new product development under time pressure.Academy of Management Review, 25: 389–408.

Siggelkow, N., & Levinthal, D. A. 2003. Temporarily divide toconquer: Centralized, decentralized, and reintegratedorganizational approaches to exploration and adapta-tion. Organization Science, 14: 650–669.

Simon, H. 1962. A note on mathematical models for learning.Psychometrika, 27: 417–418.

Stuart, T. E., & Podolny, J. M. 1996. Local search and theevolution of technological capabilities. Strategic Man-agement Journal, 17(Summer Special Issue): 21–38.

Sutton, R. I., & Hargadon, A. 1996. Brainstorming groups incontext: Effectiveness in a product design firm. Admin-istrative Science Quarterly, 41: 685–718.

Teece, D. J. 1986. Profiting from technological innovation:Implications for integration, collaboration, licensingand public policy. Research Policy, 15: 285–305.

Thompson, J. D. 1967. Organizations in action: Social sciencebases of administrative theory. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Tushman, M. L., & O’Reilly, C. A., III. 2004. The ambidextrousorganization. Harvard Business Review, 82(4): 74–81.

Wegner, D. M. 1986. Transactive memory: A contemporaryanalysis of the group mind. In B. Mullen & G. R. Goeth-als (Eds.), Theories of group behavior: 185–208. New York:Springer-Verlag.

Winter, S. 1971. Satisficing, selection, and the innovativeremnant. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85: 237–261.

Yayavaram, S., & Ahuja, G. 2008. Decomposability in knowl-edge structures and its impact on the usefulness ofinventions and knowledge-base malleability. Adminis-trative Science Quarterly, 53: 333–362.

Zhao, M. Y. 2006. Conducting R&D in countries with weakintellectual property rights protection. Management Sci-ence, 52: 1185–1199.

Gautam Ahuja ([email protected]) is the Harvey C. Fruehauf Professor of BusinessAdminstration at the University of Michigan. He received his Ph.D. from the Universityof Michigan. His research interests include the strategic management of knowledge,technology, and innovation.

Curba Morris Lampert ([email protected]) is an assistant professor in the Department ofManagement and International Business in the College of Business at Florida Inter-national University. She received her Ph.D. from the University of Texas at Austin. Herresearch interests include technology strategy and innovation, diversification anddivestments, and managing entrepreneurship in large corporations.

Elena Novelli ([email protected]) is a lecturer in management at Cass Busi-ness School, City University London. She received her Ph.D. from Bocconi University.Her research interests include the strategic management of knowledge, technology,and innovation.

2013 269Ahuja, Lampert, and Novelli