the optimality of uniform pricing in ipos: an optimal...

37
The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction Approach October 4, 2005 Abstract This paper provides theoretical support to the use of the uniform pricing rule in the Initial Public Oerings of shares. By using an optimal auction approach, we are able to show that the optimality of a uniform price in IPOs crucially depends whether the seller has full descretion on the use of quantity discrimination. This in turn depends on two main dimensions of the IPO game: the institutional investors’ preferences and existence or not of budget constraint on retail investors. Specically, we show that in the standard case, with risk neutral institutional investors and cash constrained retail investors, the optimal IPO is implemented by a uniform price. Keywords: Initial Public Oering, Price Discrimination, Rationing, Optimal Auc- tion. JEL Classication: D8, G2. 1

Upload: others

Post on 13-Mar-2020

8 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: AnOptimal Auction Approach

October 4, 2005

Abstract

This paper provides theoretical support to the use of the uniform pricing rule in the

Initial Public Offerings of shares. By using an optimal auction approach, we are able to

show that the optimality of a uniform price in IPOs crucially depends whether the seller

has full descretion on the use of quantity discrimination. This in turn depends on two

main dimensions of the IPO game: the institutional investors’ preferences and existence

or not of budget constraint on retail investors. Specifically, we show that in the standard

case, with risk neutral institutional investors and cash constrained retail investors, the

optimal IPO is implemented by a uniform price.

Keywords: Initial Public Offering, Price Discrimination, Rationing, Optimal Auc-

tion.

JEL Classification: D8, G2.

1

Page 2: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

1 Introduction

The literature on Initial Public Offerings (IPOs) has been growing remarkably in the last

decade. Most of this literature, both theoretical (e.g. Rock, (1986), Allen and Faulhaber,

(1989), Benveniste and Spindt, (1989)) and empirical (e.g Beatty and Ritter, (1986), Ritter

(1987) Cornelli and Goldreich, (2001), Derrien and Womack (2003)) has particularly focused

on the explanation of some apparent market anomalies surrounding IPOs, such as under-

pricing, long-term underperformances and hot issues markets.1 Much less attention has been

devoted to understand whether the current IPO format which imposes uniform pricing is

efficient or not. Virtually all papers simply assumes uniform pricing to be consistent with

the current practice of IPOs. As a matter of fact, the only paper addressing this issue (Ben-

veniste and Wilhelm, (1990)) challenges the efficiency of the current regulatory constraints

and suggests that firms could improve on the IPO performance (raise the IPO proceeds) if

allowed to price discriminate across investors.2

This paper investigates more closely this issue, i.e. whether uniform price restrictions

lead to inefficient outcomes. The first result we obtain is to show that in the standard IPO

set up with risk neutral institutional investors and cash constrained retail investors uniform

pricing is the optimal pricing rule. However. the main contribution of the paper is to show

that the optimality of the uniform pricing rule crucially depends on two main dimensions

of the problem: the institutional investors’ preferences and the existence or not of budget

constraint on retail investors. Specifically, we find that as long as retail investors are not cash

constraint - i.e. they can buy all the shares - the optimal IPO can always be implemented

by a uniform price. Conversely, when retail investors are cash constraint, the institutional

investors’ preferences become determinant: price discrimination is needed in addition to

quantity discrimination if institutional investors are risk averse. The reason for this is that, if

the seller enjoys full discretion on how to allocate shares, then there is no need to also employ1Ritter and Welch (2002) provide a handy review of the IPO literature, whereas for a fully comprehensive

review of the theory and evidence on IPO activity we refer to Jenkinson and Ljungquist (2001).2Brisley (2003) in a note shows that Benveniste and Wilhelm’s result holds only when regular investors

are, on average, less informed than retail investors. Otherwise, the uniform price restriction does not affectIPO proceeds.

2

Page 3: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

price discrimination to achieve optimality. The absence of cash constraint on retail investors

ensures the seller enough leeway on the allocation of share independently of the institutional

investors preferences. When instead institutional investors are cash constrained, the seller

may still have enough leeway on the allocation rule if institutional investors are risk neutral,

but not if they are risk averse. In this latter case quantity discrimination alone is not enough

to achieve optimality and the seller needs to employ also price discrimination.

The methodology we employ, which exploit the tools of optimal auction and mechanism

design theory for information gathering (Myerson, 1981; Maskin and Riley, 1989), represents

by itself one of the contributions of this paper.

There are few others papers in the IPO literature using the same approach (Biais, Bossaert

and Rochet (2002), Biais and Faugeron-Crouzet, (2002), Maksimovic and Pichler, (2002)).

Our paper differ from each of them in several respects, the most important of which is that,

as anticipated, all of them assume uniform pricing whereas we do not put any restriction ex

ante on the pricing rule. We endogenously derive the optimal pricing rule and show that it is

uniform. In addition to this, Bias, Bossaerts and Rochet (2002) focus on IPOs in which the

intermediary acts in the best interest of the institutional investors instead of the firm. They

derive the optimal selling mechanism that enables the seller to extract all the information

from the coalition intermediary-institutional investors and find that this mechanism specifies

a price schedule decreasing in the quantity allocated to retail investors. This price schedule

on one hand eliminates the winner’s curse for the uninformed investors and on the other hand

exhibits underpricing (in the form of informational rents) to institutional investors.

Biais and Faugeron-Crouzet instead compare the performances of alternative IPO proce-

dures and find that in general auction-like mechanisms such as Mise en Vente and Bookbuild-

ing are more informationally efficient and can lead to price discovery. They also show that

pure auction mechanisms might lead to tacit collusion among the bidders and, consequently,

to inefficient outcomes.

Maksimovic and Pichler (2002) look at the optimal amount of information gathering

by comparing private and public offering with a particular attention to the determinants of

3

Page 4: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

underpricing. They find that in absence of any allocation constraint and under risk neutrality,

the seller is able to design a selling mechanism with zero underpricing (no rents to the informed

investors). We prove a similar result in a particular subcase of our model. Taking this result

as a benchmark, the authors then link the existence and magnitude of underpricing to various

constraint eventually imposed on the bookbuilding procedure.

In our IPO a firm wants to place a fixed number of shares. Two groups of investors take

part in the IPO: n institutional investors and, a group of atomistic investors (retail investors).

The latter typically participate only occasionally in the offering. Institutional investors have

superior information about the market value of the asset because each of them receives a

private signal, whereas retail investors have no information about the value of the asset on

sale .

The seller designs the IPO mechanism in order to elicit the information from institutional

investors and maximize the IPO proceeds. Deriving the optimal IPO means deriving the

optimal allocation rule and the optimal pricing rule. We start by looking for the optimal IPO

in the standard IPO set up where institutional investors are assumed to be risk neutral and

retail investors cash constrained.

In this context we prove that uniform pricing is the optimal pricing rule and furthermore

there exists a multiplicity of uniform prices implementing the optimal IPO. We next move

away from the standard IPO set up by challenging the assumption of risk neutral institutional

investors. We instead analyze how the optimal IPO changes if institutional investors are risk

averse, where the risk aversion we have in mind is an aversion to the inventory risk. The

results we obtain suggest the optimality of the uniform pricing rule crucially depends on

two dimensions of the problem, the existence of budget constraint to retail investors and

the institutional investors’ preferences. In particular, as long as retail investors are not

cash constrained the uniform pricing rule always supports the optimal IPO allocation no

matter what the preferences of institutional investors are. When instead retail investors

are cash constrained then institutional investors’ preferences play a role and, specifically, we

can restore the optimality of the uniform pricing rule only if they are risk neutral (but not

4

Page 5: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

necessarily when they exhibit risk aversion). In other words, for the uniform price to be

optimal, it must be that the seller can freely choose the allocation rule, i.e. he is not subject

to any restriction on how to allocate the shares, a condition which is clearly not satisfied when

retail investors are cash constrained. Therefore, in this case, he needs to gain some leeway

elsewhere and this is achieved when informed buyers’ preferences offer sufficient flexibility

(i.e. the case of risk neutrality).

The paper is organized as follows. In the next section we set up the model and the IPO

design problem for the seller in the standard case of risk neutral institutional investors and

cash constrained retail investors. The results are presented in Section 3. The case of risk

averse institutional investors is analyzed in Section 4. Some concluding remarks are discussed

in the last section. All the proofs are presented in the Appendix.

2 The Model

A firm wants to sell Q shares in an IPO, with Q fixed and, without loss of generality, nor-

malized to 1. An intermediary is in charge of marketing the issues. He is assumed to act in

the firm’s best interest, so, hereafter, we will simply refer to the seller to denote the coalition

firm-intermediary. This is a standard way of modelling the role of intermediary in the IPO

literature. The seller wants to maximize the proceeds from the sale. He faces n(> 2) large,

institutional investors with private information about the firm’s market value, and a fringe

of retail and uninformed investors.

Institutional investors’ preferences are described by the following utility function:

ui(pi, qi, v) = z(qi, v)− qipi for all i ∈ 1, 2, ....n

where qi is the quantity assigned to investor i and pi is the price per share investor i has to

pay. We denote by Ti = piqi the total payment from investor i to the seller. v is the value of

new shares. Notice that, the above utility function is linear in the transfer Ti.3 We assume

that the valuation function z for investors satisfy some standard assumptions (subscripts are3This kind of utility functions exhibiting linearity in the total payment, are very common in the auction

literature. (See for instance Crèmer and McLean, 1988).

5

Page 6: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

for derivatives with respect to variables): 1) z1 > 0 and z2 > 0; 2) z11 ≤ 0; 3) z(0, v) = 0 for

all v; 4) z12 > 0 (single-crossing condition); 5) z122 ≤ 0 and z112 ≥ 0; and 6) z12(0, v) ≥ 1

(see Fudenberg and Tirole, 1991).

Institutional investors have private information in that each of them receives a signal si

about the valuation of the firm by the market value. The value of the shares v is given by

the average of all the signals, that is

v(s) =1

n

Xi

si

Our choice of the informational structure is very common in auction theory (e.g. Bulow

and Klemperer, 1996, 2002). Additionally and more importantly, our informational structure

is a straightforward generalization of the simple binomial informational structure adopted

in other papers on IPOs (e.g. Benveniste and Wilhelm, 1996; Biais and Faugeron-Crouzet,

2002).4

Signals are i.i.d. according to a uniform distribution defined on Ωi = [s; s], so the cu-

mulative distribution function is Fi(si) =si − s∆s

, and the density function fi(si) =1

∆s. Let

us also denote by f(s) the joint density function so that f(s) = f(s1, ..., sn) =Qifi(si),

with s = (s1, ..., sn) ∈ Ω =NiΩi = [s, s]

n.

We assume a continuum of competitive, risk neutral retail bidders. The total mass of

these retail bidders is normalized to one. We assume that they face a cash constraint so

they cannot absorb the whole issue. In the following sections we will analyze the effect of

the existence of this cash constraint on the implementation of optimal IPO procedure with

a uniform price. We denote by qR the quantity they receive in equilibrium; by pR the price

per unit of share they are asked and by TR = qRpR the total transfer to the seller. Budget

constraint for uninformed agents stipulates that

qRpR ≤ K.4These papers assume that the signal investors receive can be either good or bad and the stock market

value is monotonic in the number of good signals. With continuous signals, as we assume, our specification of vpreserves this monotonicity property, i.e. higher signals lead to higher market value of the stock. Furthermore,our results are robust to a generalization of this function to a generic v = Ψ(s) with Ψ increasing in s . Wechose however not to use this specification because it makes notation and computation much heavier withoutadding anything in terms of insight.

6

Page 7: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

Retail investors as the seller do not have any private information about the market value

of the asset and only observe the density f(s) of signals.

In order to extract the information from the institutional investors, the seller designs a

contract specifying the quantity and the price per share to pay to each institutional investor

and to retail investors. By using the revelation principle, we can focus on direct mechanisms

in which the firm asks each investor to announce his signal and then fixes the quantity and

the price as a function of their announcements in such a way to induce them to truthfully

reveal their information (see Fudenberg and Tirole, 1991).

We assume that all the shares issued must be allocated between institutional and retail

investors. Consequently, by choosing the vector qii the firm implicitly determines the

number of shares to allocate to retail investors, which is given by:

qR = 1−Xi

qi

The contract the seller proposes can thus be written in the following way:

Γ = pi(bsi, bs−i), qi(bsi, bs−i); pR(bsi, bs−i), qR(bsi, bs−i) for all i and all (bsi, bs−i) ∈ Ωwith bsi being institutional investor i0s announcement and bs−i the vector of the announcementsof all the other investors. The optimal IPO mechanism for the firm is the solution to the

following optimization program:

maxqi

UF = Es

"Xi

Ti(bsi, bs−i) + TR(bsi, bs−i)#

subject to the standard constraints (see Fudenberg and Tirole, 1991):

• Retail Investors’ Participation Constraint (RPC):

ES [qR(si, s−i)(v − pR(si, s−i)] ≥ 0

which requires their expected payoff to be larger than their reservation utility which,

without loss of generality, may be set equal to zero.

7

Page 8: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

• Institutional Investors’ Participation Constraint (IPC):

Ui(bsi, bsi) = Es−i z(qi(bsi, s−i), v(bsi, s−i))− qi(bsi, s−i)pi(bsi, s−i) ≥ 0 for all si and i

which has the same meaning as the RPC. Note however that the expected profits of

participation for each informed investor is conditional on his signal.

• Institutional Investors’ Incentive Compatibility Constraint (IIC):

Ui(bsi, si) ≤ Ui(si, si) for all si, bsi and i,with

Ui(bsi, si) = Es−i z(qi(bsi, s−i), v(si, s−i))− qi(bsi, s−i))pi(bsi, s−i)which ensures that institutional investors do not have incentive to misrepresent their

type - the signal they receive - to the firm.

• Last, the Full Allocation Constraint (FAC):

Xi

qi(si, s−i) + qR(si, s−i) = 1,

the feasibility constraint:

qi(si, s−i) ≥ 0 for all i, si and s−i

and the budget constraint for uninformed investors:

qR(si, s−i)pR(si, s−i) ≤ K for all s

Also notice that the monotonic hazard rate condition is trivially satisfied by the uniform

distribution function, i.e.∂

∂si

∙fi(si)

1− Fi(si)

¸=

1

(s− si)≥ 0.

The next Lemma shows how to simplify the above maximization program.

8

Page 9: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

Lemma 1 The seller’s optimal IPO design problem can be rewritten in the following way:

maxqin1

(v +

Xi

∙z(qi(s), v)−

1

n(s− si)z2(qi(s), v)− vqi(s)

¸)f(s)ds

s.t :Ui(s, s) = 0 for all i

1nEs−i

∙z12(qi(s), v)

∂qi(s)

∂si

¸≥ 0 for all i and all si

qi(s) ≥ 0 for all i and all sPiqi(s) ≤ 1 for all s.µ1−

Piqi(s)

¶pR(si, s−i) ≤ K for all s

where the second constraint is the monotonicity constraint which ensures that the SOC are

met and the mechanism is implementable.

Proof: See the Appendix.

The seller’s program in this set-up is quite different from a standard auction design prob-

lem where an uninformed seller faces usually only informed bidders. The participation to the

auction of a class of uninformed bidders, makes the problem quite different and interesting

because it mitigates the adverse selection problem and, thus, lowers the cost for the seller

to extract the informed investors’ private information.5 Furthermore, notice that prices are

present in the seller’s program only in the budget constraint of uninformed investors.

3 Risk neutral institutional investors and cash constrainedretail investors.

We start by analyzing a case similar to Benveniste and Wilhelm (1990) where institutional

investors are supposed to be risk neutral and retail investors cannot afford to buy the whole

quantity of shares, i.e. are budget constrained. Notice that this is also the most common set

up in the IPO literature.

Assume that the valuation function of informed investors is z(q, v) = vq, so that the5See Bennouri and Falconieri (2005) for a careful analysis of this issue.

9

Page 10: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

utility function of investor i is

ui(v, qi) = v(s)qi(s)− pi(s)qi(s)

and additionally, that retail investors are subject to the following cash constraint

pR(s)qR(s) ≤ K for all s.

We assume also that K ≤ s so that the budget constraint matters. The seller’s program

becomes then

maxqin1

(v −

Xi

∙1

n(s− si)qi(s)

¸)f(s)ds

s.t :Ui(s, s) = 0 for all i

Es−i

∙∂qi(s)

∂si

¸≥ 0 for all i and all si

qi(s) ≥ 0 for all i and all sPiqi(s) ≤ 1 for all s.µ1−

Piqi(s)

¶pR(si, s−i) ≤ K for all s

Notice that the seller’s objective function is decreasing in qi(.) for each i. This implies

that at the optimum, the seller will allocate as much as possible to retail investors, i.e. up

to their budget constraint. The proposition below formalizes the result about the optimal

allocation rule.

Proposition 1 With risk neutral institutional investors and cash constrained retail investors,

the optimal IPO is such that retail investors are satisfied first up to their budget constraint

whereas institutional investors get the remaining share.

So in the optimal mechanism, retail investors get priority in the allocation (see also

Biais and Faugeron-Crouzet, 2002). This result highlights the important role played by the

uninformed investors in the IPO process. Their presence mitigates the adverse selection

problem vis-a-vis the institutional investors and, consequently, allows the seller to lower the

10

Page 11: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

cost to extract their private information. The intuition for this is that the seller can always

threaten the institutional investors to allocate the shares to retail investors although in this

specific situation, the effectiveness of this threat might be limited by the fact that retail

investors are subject to cash constraint.

For the pricing rule, we know that retail investors’ budget constraint should be binding

in equilibrium, i.e.

pR(s)qR(s) = K for all s

So we now focus on the optimal pricing rule which, for each institutional investor must

satisfy the following equation:ZΩ−i

pi(s)qi(s)f−i(s−i)ds−i =

ZΩ−i

½v(s)qi(s)−

1

n

∙Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desi¸¾ f−i(s−i)ds−i

for all si and all i (1)

and for uninformed investors the following

ZΩpR(s)qR(s)f(s)ds =

ZΩv

Ã1−

Xi

qi(s)

!f(s)ds = k

We can show that the next result holds:

Proposition 2 With risk neutral institutional investors and cash constrained retail investors,

the optimal IPO can be implemented with a uniform pricing rule.

Proof: see the Appendix.

The intuition behind this result is very simple. Since asymmetric information in the model

in one-dimensional, the seller needs only one tool to discriminate the informed investors. In

other word, quantity discrimination (and rationing) alone is sufficient to allow the seller to

gather information and thus achieve an optimal performance. For this to be true, however, it

must be that the seller enjoys enough discretion on how to allocate shares among investors.

In this specific case, the seller is partly limited on the use of the allocation rule because retail

investors are cash constrained, but this is offset by the flexibility gained from the institutional

investors’ risk neutrality. This is strengthened by the following Corollary:

11

Page 12: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

Corollary 1 With risk neutral institutional investors and cash constrained retail investors,

the uniform price implementing the optimal IPO is not unique.

The fact that there are multiple uniform prices that can implement the optimal IPO

confirms the large leeway the seller has on how to design the sale.

In conclusion, the above results together suggest that in the presence of cash constraint

on retail investors, institutional investors’ preferences become crucial in order to ensure the

seller enough leeway with respect to the use of the allocation rule and, thus, make unnecessary

the use of price discrimination. We shall see more in the Section 4 how cash constraints on

retail investors and institutional investors’ preferences interact to determine the optimality

of a uniform pricing rule in IPOs.

As we know, most of the IPO literature is devoted to understand whether and why

underpricing occurs. Although this is not the focus of this paper, our model has implications

for the existence of underpricing as shown in the next proposition.

Proposition 3 The optimal IPO mechanism is characterized by underpricing, i.e. for all s,

shares are priced below their expected value v.

Proof: see the Appendix.

Our definition of underpricing is the same as in Benveniste and Spindt (1989) and Rock

(1986). The rationale for the existence of underpricing in our model is the same as in Ben-

veniste and Spindt (1989), i.e. the seller underprices the shares to lower the cost of eliciting

information from the institutional investors.

No cash constraint on retail investors

The case of risk neutral institutional investors and no cash constraint is particularly

interesting. Because of what we said before, in this case the seller has full discretion with

respect to the choice of the allocation rule, the consequence of this is stated in the next

corollary.

Corollary 2 When informed investors are risk neutral and retail investors are not cash

constrained, i.e. they could buy all the shares on sale, then the optimal offering is such that

12

Page 13: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

all the shares are sold to retail investors irrespective of the signal reported by the informed

investors, at a marginal price equal to pR = v .

The above results implies that risk neutral institutional investors would get zero rent

in equilibrium because the seller would optimally choose to exclude them from the offering.

In other words, the institutional investors are always excluded from the offering and this is

driven by the fact that informed investors compete against uninformed investors (Bennouri

and Falconieri, 2005).

4 Risk aversion and no cash constraint

Although the benchmark IPO in the literature has always considered institutional investors to

be risk neutral, there is no reason to exclude the possibility that even institutional investors

may exhibit some kind of risk aversion. Specifically, we think it is not unreasonable that

institutional investors exhibit and aversion to the, so called, inventory risk, that is the risk

associated to the composition of their portfolio. As a matter of fact, this is well recognized

by the market microstructure literature or the foreign exchange market literature (see for

instance O’Hara (1996), Lyons (2003)). Therefore in this section we analyze how the optimal

IPO and the optimal pricing rule is affected by this assumption. In Section 3 we have

already anticipated that the optimality of the uniform pricing mostly depends on the degree

of freedom the seller has with respect to the allocation of the shares, thus, intuitively, we

might expect that the institutional investors’ risk aversion will reduce the seller’s freedom.

We shall show that this is not necessarily the case.

For the time being we will assume instead that retail investors do not bear any cash

constraint. The institutional investors’ risk aversion is interpreted as we said as an aversion

to the so called inventory risk, and is modeled, similarly to Benveniste and Wilhem (1990),

by assuming that their preferences are concave in the quantity, i.e. z(qi, v) = qi(αv− δ2qi). Our

function z is a variant of a standard Mean-Variance utility function in which the expected

value v is weighed more than the transfer Ti. The parameter α > 1 measures the regular

investor’s aggressiveness: the higher α is, the more aggressive the investor is in the IPO

13

Page 14: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

procedure. The intuition is that, despite their risk aversion, institutional investors are very

much interested in the sale and, therefore, they will bid aggressively in the IPO. If α = 1

then the problem would be equivalent to having risk neutral institutional investors and, in

this case, we know that the optimal IPO is such that all the shares will be allocated to retail

investors no matter the information reported by the institutional investors.6

The next proposition derives the optimal allocation rule. For the details of the proof the

reader can refer to Bennouri and Falconieri (2004)

Proposition 4 The optimal IPO is characterized by the following allocation rule: there exists

a threshold value of the signals si (v−i), with v−i =Pj 6=is−j , such that,

• If all the informed investors report signals below this threshold, all the shares are awarded

to the uninformed investors; otherwise

• all the institutional investors reporting a signal below si (v−i) get zero, whereas the

others get a positive quantity which is equal to

— eqi = (α− 1)nv − α (s− si)nδ

, if the issue is not oversubscribed, with retail investors

receiving the remaining shares;

— bqi < eqi if the issue is oversubscribed, with bqi(s) = eqi(s) − β(s)/δ where β(s)/δ is

the amount of shares by which they are rationed. Retail investors get nothing.

The institutional allocation rule is such that the optimal quantity eqi(s) is increasingin the signal si reported by the institutional investor. In other words, the seller rewards

better information with a larger quantity. This is in line with the existing literature on

bookbuilding (Benveniste and Spindt (1989) and Cornelli and Goldreich (2001)), which shows

that institutions receive more shares in ”hot” issues, i.e. IPOs with strong pre-market demand

and also with the traditional Rock’s argument according to which institutions always try to

avoid ”lemons”. In a recent paper, Aggarwal et al. (2002) also provide some empirical6 In addition, the assumption reflects the practice of IPO underwriters to surround themselves of a core of

regular investors who repeatedly take part into IPOs (Benveniste and Spindt, 1989).

14

Page 15: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

support to these predictions, confirming that institutional allocations are indeed larger in

better performing IPOs.

We can also show that the optimal mechanism obtained above satisfies the SOC as rep-

resented by the monotonicity condition. We omit the proof for the sake of simplicity.7

Previous results in the auction literature ((Maskin and Riley (1984), Eso (2005)) have

highlighted that introducing risk aversion for informed bidders generally creates a trade-off

because, on the one hand, the informed buyers must be compensated for the risk they bear in

the auction8 and the cost of screening which might instead be reduced by exposing them to

some risk. For this reason, it is interesting to see what happens to the optimal price schedule

when informed investors are risk averse.

We can however show, that despite the risk averse institutional investors, the optimal

IPO can be implemented by an uniform pricing schedule as in the standard case. The result

is stated in the next proposition.

Proposition 5 The optimal IPO mechanism can be implemented by a uniform price schedule

to all investors.

Proof: (See the Appendix).

To give an idea of the reasoning behind the proof of this Proposition, first recall that

the optimal price for institutional and retail investors must satisfy, respectively, the following

integral equationsZΩ−i

pi(s)qi(s)f−i(s−i)ds−i =

ZΩ−i

½z(qi(s), v)−

1

n

∙Z si

sz2(qi(esi, s−i), v(esi, s−i))desi¸¾ f−i(s−i)ds−i;

(2)

and

ZΩpR(s)qR(s)f(s)ds =

ZΩv

Ã1−

Xi

qi(s)

!f(s)ds

7See Bennouri and Falconieri (2005) for a detailed proof in a more general auction framework.8The risk comes from the fact that the payment of each bidder depends on the announcements of the other

bidders (Eso, 2005).

15

Page 16: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

The proof is then articulated in two steps. The first step consists in proving a preliminary

result, i.e. we show the existence and uniqueness of a uniform price schedule satisfying

Equation (2) for all institutional investors. Next, we show that the same price schedule also

solve the participation constraint of retail investors.

The rationale for the above result is that, although the institutional investors’ risk aversion

may impose restrictions on the seller in how to allocate shares, the fact that retail investors are

instead not cash constrained warrants him with enough leeway. More generally, the result

implies that as long as retail investors are not cash constrained, the seller enjoys enough

discretion on how to allocate the shares no matter what institutional investors’ preferences

are. As a consequence, there will not be any need to use price discrimination in combination

with quantity discrimination to support the optimal mechanism.

To fully understand this, in the next Section we consider the case in which institutional

investors are risk averse and retail investors are cash constrained. This is the only case in

which the optimality of the uniform pricing rule breaks down.

Risk aversion and cash constraint

Let us now assume that retail investors are now budget constrained. Notice that for the

sake of tractability, in this case, we write this constraint as a quantity constraint, i.e. we

assume that retail investors can buy a maximum quantity of shares K < 1, i.e.9:

qR(s) ≤ K < 1, for all s ∈ Ω

which implies that retail investors cannot buy all the shares on sale. The quantity con-

straint on retail investors modifies the seller’s optimization problem as follows:9For the sake of tractability, we assume quantity constraint instead of a more general budget constraint.

Notice that if anything this constraint is more restrictive than the general cash constraint given that we loseone degree of freedom (the price dimension).

16

Page 17: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

maxqin1

(v +

Xi

∙qi(s)

µ(α− 1) v − δ

2qi(s)−

α

n(s− si)

¶¸)f(s)ds

s.t :

U i(s, s) = 0∂qi(s)

∂si≥ 0 for all i and all s

qi(s) ≥ 0 for all i and all sPiqi(s) ≥ 1−K for all s

Piqi(s) ≤ 1 for all s.

The solution to the second problem is given in the following theorem.

Proposition 6 The optimal IPO is characterized by the following allocation rule: there exists

a threshold value of the signals bsi (v−i), with v−i = Pj 6=is−j , such that,

1. Informed investors reporting the lowest signal s get no shares;

2. All institutional investors with sufficienly high signals get a positive quantity eqi(s) =(α− 1)nv − α (s− si)

nδprovided that 1 − K ≤

Pieqi(s) ≤ 1 with the remaining shares

allotted to retail investors. If insteadPieqi(s) < 1−K, then K shares are allocated to

retail investors and all insitutional investors with a signal above the lowest one, s, get

a positive quantity eqKi (s) 6= eqi(s);3. In the case of oversubscription, all institutional investors with sufficiently high signals

are rationed and retail investors get nothing.

Proof: (See the Appendix).10

The above result is very intuitive. Whenever retail investors’ quantity constraint is hit,

the seller is forced to allocate informed investors more shares than what would be otherwise

optimal, in particular he is forced to allocate some shares also to institutional investors with

relatively bad signals (below the threshold).10We can also prove that this mechanism is implementable that is it satisfied the SOC (monotonicity

constraint).

17

Page 18: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

Given the optimal allocation schedule we can derive the optimal pricing rule and by using

the same arguments as in Proposition 5 we can prove the following result:

Proposition 7 If retail investors are subject to quantity constraint and institutional in-

vestors are risk averse, the optimal selling mechanism as derived in Proposition 6 can be

implemented only by a discriminatory pricing schedule for all investors, such that each class

of investors pays the same price.

The proof is very much like the proof of Proposition 5. We start by showing that an

optimal uniform price exists for informed investors and that this cannot be applied to retail

investors as well because it would violate their participation constraint. The result is not

surprising: whenever the issuer faces a situation in which the quantity constraint on retail

investors is hit he will be forced to allocate to informed investors more shares than what

would be otherwise optimal for him to do and this, in turn, requires to adjust downward the

share price. However, it is important to notice that institutional investors all pay the same

price, so, in some sense, there exists a uniform price for each class of investors.

Despite the fact that the introduction of budget constraint on retail investors weakens

our result on the optimal of uniform pricing, it must be noticed that assuming that retail

investors are not budget constrained is not that restrictive for two main reasons. First,

they might be cash constrained individually but not in the aggregate (Ellul and Pagano,

2003). Secondly and most importantly, it is important to understand that it is a simplifying

assumption because in practise the seller can regain flexibility in other ways, by for instance

withholding shares whenever it is not optimal to allocate them to informed investors and

retail investors do not have the capacity to absorb them; or alternatively by using a firm-

commitment contract of underwriting, which is a common practise in the US and through

which the underwriter commits to buy all the shares not sold during the offering. It is easy to

show that incorporating this situations in our IPO framework would lead to the same result

as with no cash constraints.

18

Page 19: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

5 Conclusions and Remarks

In this paper, we adopt an optimal auction approach to analyze the functioning of initial

offerings with the focus on the choice by the seller of the optimal instrument to allocate

efficiently the issues, this choice being price versus quantity discrimination (rationing).

Our results highlight that the seller does not need price discrimination to achieve an

optimal performance. Instead, the optimal IPO can always be implemented through a uniform

price schedule. This result holds very generally. In particular, we show that it holds in the

standard IPO framework with risk neutral institutional investors and cash constrained retail

investors.

A deeper investigation shows that as a general rule, as long as the seller can fully rely on

the allocation rule, i.e. no constraint is imposed to him on how and to whom to allocate the

shares, then uniform pricing is enough to achieve an optimal performance. The discretion

in the allocation rule in turn depends on two main dimensions: the existence or not of cash

constraints on to retail investors and the institutional investors’ preferences. In particular,

retail investors appear to play a very important role in the offering since, as long as they

are able to buy the whole quantity then rationing alone is enough to support the optimal

IPO mechanism. When this is not the case, then institutional investors’ preferences start to

matter.11 This suggests that an important empirical question is to investigate whether and to

what extent retail investors are actually cash constrained especially in the light of the recent

debate and empirical evidence which indicate distortions in the allocation of new issues due

to the intermediaries’ will to favor institutional investors at the expenses of retail investors.

Similarly, the issue of whether institutional investors may exhibit some kind of risk aversion

and the extent of it definitely deserves more empirical investigations. From a theoretical

point of view, the central role of uninformed investors in IPOs has been recently studied, in

a very similar framework, by Malakhov (2004). The author shows that the seller’s revenues11This also explains the difference between our result and the Benveniste and Wilhelm one. In their paper,

the underwriter is not able to freely ration regular investors. He can only apply a discrete rationing scheme,i.e. either he fills the full order or he gives nothing. Therefore, price discrimination is needed in addition torationing to allow the underwriter to elicit the information from the regular investors.

19

Page 20: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

are increasing in the the number of uninformed investors participating into the offering, the

reason being that a larger number of uninformed investors lowers the outside option of the

informed ones.

6 Appendix

Proof of Lemma 1:

By the RPC and the maximand we know that the seller’s profit is increasing in the retail

investors’ payments, therefore at the optimum he will make the RPC binding. We can then

rewrite the RPC in the following way:ZΩpR(s)qR(s)f(s)ds =

ZΩvqR(s)f(s)ds =

ZΩv

Ã1−

Xi

qi(s)

!f(s)ds (3)

where we have put s = (si, s−i) and replaced to qR(s) from the FAC.

Now, let us consider the IPC which can be rewritten as follows:ZΩ−i

pi(s)qi(s)f−i(s−i)ds−i =

ZΩ−i

z(qi(s), v)f−i(s−i)ds−i − Ui(si, si) ≥ 0

for all si and i. (4)

by integrating over Ωi ( that is taking the expectations over si) we find:ZΩpi(s)qi(s)f(s)ds =

ZΩz(qi(s), v)f(s)ds−

ZΩi

Ui(si, si)fi(si)dsi. (5)

Let us now consider the IIC. By applying the envelope theorem to the IIC, we have:

U 0i(si, si) =1

n

ZΩ−i

z2(qi(s), v)f−i(s−i)ds−i (6)

thus,

Ui(si, si) = Ui(s, s) +

Z si

s

(1

n

ZΩ−i

z2(qi(esi, s−i), v(s))f−i(s−i)ds−i)desi. (7)

For the IPC to be satisfied we can simply set Ui(s, s) = 0 which means that the seller

leaves zero rents to the informed traders with the lowest evaluations.

20

Page 21: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

Applying Fubini’s theorem to equation (7) yields:

Ui(si, si) =1

n

ZΩ−i

½Z si

sz2(qi(esi, s−i), v(s))desi¾ f−i(s−i)ds−i.

Integrate over Ωi, and apply again Fubini’s theorem to get the following

ZΩi

Ui(si, si)fi(si)dsi =1

n

ZΩ−i

½ZΩi

∙Z si

sz2(qi(esi, s−i), v(s))desi¸ fi(si)dsi¾ f−i(s−i)ds−i.

Last, integration by parts of the integralRΩi

hR sis z2(qi(esi, s−i), v(s))desii fi(si)dsi, yields

the following equation:

ZΩi

∙Z si

sz2(qi(esi, s−i), v(s))desi¸ fi(si)dsi =

∙½Z si

sz2(qi(esi, s−i), v(s))desi¾ (Fi(si)− 1)¸s

s

−ZΩi

z2(qi(s), v)(Fi(si)− 1)dsi.

which can be rewritten as follows:ZΩi

Ui(si, si)fi(si)dsi =1

n

ZΩ(s− si)z2(qi(s), v)f(s)ds. (8)

where (s− si) is the inverse of the hazard rate.

By replacing equation (8) into equation (5) and using equation (3) we get the seller’s

objective function. Last, in order to show the prevalence of the monotonicity condition,

notice that the (IIC )s may be written as follows

si ∈ argminbsi [Ui(bsi, bsi)− Ui(si, bsi)] for all si and i.

Writing the SOC for this problem and using equation (6) gives the result.

Proof of Proposition 2

In order to make the reasoning in the proof clear, we split out the proof in three steps. In

the first step, we derive conditions for the existence of a uniform price for informed investors.

In step 2 we derive conditions for the existence of a uniform price for all investors. Finally,

21

Page 22: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

we show the existence of a mechanism (allocation and pricing function) satisfying these

conditions.

Step 1: The linear transfer for the institutional investors must satisfy equation (1). Now,

consider the following price function

p0i (s) = v −1n

hR sis qi(esi, s−i)desii

qi(s)(9)

for each si and each qi(s) such that qi(s) 6= 0.12

Any price satisfying equation (1) can also be written as pi(s) = p0i (s) + Φi(s) with Φi is

such that ZΩ−i

Φi(s)qi(si, s−i)f−i(s−i)ds−i = 0, for all i and si.

A uniform price function exists if and only if it satisfies the following partial differential

equation∂pi(s)

∂si=

∂pi(s)

∂sjfor all i and j

which is equivalent to∂p0i (s)

∂si+

∂Φi(s)

∂si=

∂p0i (s)

∂sj+

∂Φi(s)

∂sj. (10)

with,∂p0i (s)

∂si=

∂qi(s)

∂si

£−p0i (s) + v

¤qi(s)

(11)

and∂p0i (s)

∂sjqi(s) =

∂qi(s)

∂sj

£−p0i (s) + v

¤+1

n

∙qi(s)−

Z si

s

∂qi(esi, s−i)∂sj

desi¸ . (12)

Multiplying both sides of equation (10) by qi(s) and from equations (11) and (12) yields

1

n

∂qi(s)∂si

×R sis qi(esi, s−i)desi[qi(s)]2

− 1n+

∂Φi(s)

∂si=

∂Φi(s)

∂sj+1

n

∂qi(s)∂sj

×R sis qi(esi, s−i)desi[qi(s)]2

− 1n

Z si

s

∂qi(esi, s−i)∂sj

desiqi(s)

(13)

yet

1

n

∂qi(s)∂si

×R sis qi(esi, s−i)desi[qi(s)]2

− 1n= − 1

n

∂si

"R sis qi(esi, s−i)desi

qi(s)

#12Otherwise p0i (s) = 0.

22

Page 23: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

and

1

n

∂qi(s)∂sj

×R sis qi(esi, s−i)desi[qi(s)]2

− 1n

Z si

s

∂qi(esi, s−i)∂sj

desiqi(s)

= − 1n

∂sj

"R sis qi(esi, s−i)desi

qi(s)

#

Substitution in equation (13) gives

∂si

"Φi(s)−

1

n

R sis qi(esi, s−i)desi

qi(s)

#=

∂sj

"Φi(s)−

1

n

R sis qi(esi, s−i)desi

qi(s)

#

This is a partial differential equation in Φi(s) −α

n

Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desiqi(s)

. A generic solution for

this PDE is given by

Φi(s) = ϕ(s1 + ...+ sn) +1

n

R sis qi(esi, s−i)desi

qi(s), forall i

where ϕ(·) is a twice differentiable function defined on the set [ns, ns] = nΩ.

Summing up, so far we have shown that the optimal mechanism may be implemented by

a uniform price schedule for informed investors if and only if

pi(s) = p0i (s) + ϕ(s1 + ...+ sn) +1

n

Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desiqi(s)

(14)

= v(s) + ϕ(s1 + ...+ sn) = v(s) + ϕ(v)

where ϕ is a twice differentiable function satisfying the following integral equation

ZΩ−i

⎡⎢⎢⎣ϕ(s1 + ...+ sn) + 1

n

Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desiqi(s)

⎤⎥⎥⎦ qi(si, s−i)f−i(s−i)ds−i = 0.or alternatively Z

Ω−i

ϕ(s1 + ...+ sn)qi(si, s−i)f−i(s−i)ds−i =

− 1n

ZΩ−i

∙Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desi¸ f−i(s−i)ds−i = g(si). (15)

The existence of a uniform price function across all informed investors is then equivalent to

the existence of the function ϕ as a solution to the integral equation defined in equation (15).

23

Page 24: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

Step 2: Let now turn to derive the conditions for a uniform price function for all in-

vestors . For uninformed agents, the uniform price function should satisfy their participation

constraint as well as their budget constraint. This gives the following conditionsZΩv

Ã1−

Xi

qi(s)

!f(s)ds = K (16)

and

(v(s) + ϕ(v))

Ã1−

Xi

qi(s)

!= K for all s (17)

This latter equation allows to write ϕ as follows:

ϕ(v) =K

(1−Pi qi(s))

− v for all s (18)

Therefore, proving the existence of a uniform price function is equivalent to prove the existence

of a set of functions (qi(s))i=1,...,n that is the solution to equation (16) andZΩ−i

½∙K

(1−Pi qi(s))

− v¸qi(si, s−i) +

1

n

∙Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desi¸¾ f−i(s−i)ds−i = 0

for all si and all i(19)

Notice that we can re-write equation (19) as a partial differential equation. Equation (16)

simply defines a final condition for this partial differential equation.

Additionally, from equation (17) it must be that (1−Pi qi(s)) is also a function of v as

ϕ, so in what follows we denote by

ξ(v) = 1−Xi

qi(s) = qR(s) (20)

Step 3: The remaining of the proof consists in showing the existence of functions qi and

ξ satisfying the sufficient conditions for the existence of a solution to equations (16), (19) and

(20).

A trivial solution to equation (19), after replacing 1 −Pi qi(s) by ξ(v) is obtained by

setting the value of the integrand equal to zero in each point, i.e. 13∙K

ξ(v)− v

¸qi(si, s−i) +

1

n

∙Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desi¸ = 0 for all s and all i

13This condition reduces substantially the set of possible solutions to our equations. In a more general set

24

Page 25: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

rearranging terms yields the following differential equation inZ si

sqi(esi, s−i)desi

qi(si, s−i)Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desi =

1

nhv − K

ξ(v)

iand the solution is

ln

µZ si

sqi(esi, s−i)desi¶ = H(v) + C(v−i) (21)

where, H(v) is such that∂H(v)

∂si=

1

nhv − K

ξ(v)

isimple computations lead to

qi(si, s−i) =Li(v−i)

nhv − K

ξ(v)

i exp(H(v)) (22)

where L(v−i) = exp(C(v−i) is an arbitrary continuously differentiable function. Now sum-

ming up over i and using the fact that 1−Pi qi(s) = ξ(v) yields

1− ξ(v) =1

nhv − K

ξ(v)

iR(v) exp(H(v)) (23)

where14 R(v) =Pi Li(v−i). Let us take the derivatives with respect to v and use equation

(23) to substitute [1/n(v − Kξ(v))]R(v) exp(H(v)) by 1− ξ(v) and we finally get the following

differential equation

− ξ0(v)

1− ξ(v)+

Kξ0(v)

ξ(v)[vξ(v)−K] =R0(v)

R(v)(24)

We now need to determine the solution of the last differential equation in ξ in order to

construct the optimal allocations to informed investors. Note that equation (24) depends on

the “arbitrarily” chosen function R(.) and it is possible to choose such function so that the

solution of equation (24) satisfies equation (16). Then from the chosen function R we can

up we can consider the following differential equation∙K

ξ(v)− v

¸qi(si, s−i) +

1

n

∙Z si

s

qi(esi, s−i)desi¸ = zi(si, s−i) for all s and all i

where zi(.) is such thatZΩ−i

zi(si, s−i)f−i(s−i)ds−i = 0. Since we need just to prove the existence of a solution,

and in order to simplify the presentation, we restrain our analysis to the homogenous differential equation.14From equation (23) and the fact that ξ is a function of v, then R should also be a function of v.

25

Page 26: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

construct individual Li(v−i) for each i and finally the allocations for each informed investor

(qi(s)) by using equation (22). These quantities satisfy by construction equation (19) and

equation (16) [q.d.e.]

Proof Proposition 3:

From equations (14), (18) and (20), the uniform pricing function is equal to kξ(v) . In order

to check for underpricing we just need to compare v and kξ(v) . From equation (22), we know

that (v− kξ(v)) and Li(v−i) have the same sign. However, form the definition of Li(v−i) derived

implicitly in equation (22) we have that Li(v−i) > 0 and so (v − kξ(v)).

Proof Proposition 4:

We consider the relaxed problem, i.e. we drop the monotonicity constraint in Lemma ??

and check it ex post. In this way, the objective function becomes an ordinary maximand with

the constraints defined in each point and can be maximized pointwise on Ω. The amount of

shares, qi(s), the firm must assign to investor i in order to elicit his information must solve

the following maximization problem, for each s ∈ Ω:

maxqii=1,..n

Pi

∙qi(s)

µ(α− 1) v − δ

2qi(s)−

α

n(s− si)

¶¸s.t :Ui(s, s) = 0 for all i

qi(s) ≥ 0 andPiqi(s) ≤ 1 for all i and s.

The Kuhn-Tucker conditions of this maximization program are the following:

⎧⎪⎪⎪⎪⎪⎨⎪⎪⎪⎪⎪⎩

(α− 1)v − δqi −α

n(s− si) + λi(s)− β(s) = 0, for all i

λi(s)qi(s) = 0

β(s)[1−Piqi(s)] = 0.

(25)

with λi and β are the Kuhn-Tucker multipliers associated respectively to the feasibility con-

straint and to the FAC.

Now let us denote by H(q, v) our objective function, that is:

26

Page 27: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

H(q, v) =Xi

∙qi(s)

µ(α− 1) v − δ

2qi(s)−

α

n(s− si)

¶¸

with qi ∈ [0, 1] and s ∈ Ω = [s, s]n. This function is concave in qi for all i, since∂2H

∂q2i≤ 0 by

assumptions (2) and (5). Now let consider si(v−i) =αs−(α−1)v−i

(2α−1) for all i and v−i and define

the following sets for all s ∈ Ω

N−(s) = i ∈ N | si ≤ si(v−i)

N+(s) = i ∈ N | si > si(v−i)

We can easily show that for each i ∈ N−(s) it must be that qi(s) = 0. Then, for each

i ∈ N+(s), define the quantity eqi as the one solving the equation below,(α− 1)v − δeqi(s)− α

n(s− si) = 0

By the concavity of function H (with respect to qi), eqi(s) is strictly positive (for each i ∈N+(s)). Now, if

•P

i∈N+(s)

eqi(s) ≤ 1the quantity eqi(s) is the solution of our mechanism.15

•P

i∈N+(s)

eqi(s) > 1,this case corresponds to a situation of oversubscription of the new shares. The quantity

eqi(s) cannot thus be the optimal solution because it violates the FAC, so the optimalmechanism is given by the solution of the following system of equations that we denote

by bqi(s): ⎧⎪⎪⎪⎨⎪⎪⎪⎩bqi(s)[(α− 1)v − δbqi(s)− α

n(s− si)− β(s)] = 0X

i∈N+(s)

bqi(s) = 1; β(s) > 0,

which implies that bqi(s) is either zero or is positive and solves the following equation(α− 1)v − δbqi(s)− α

n(s− si)− β(s) = 0

15 In this case, the equation defining eqi(s) is the FOC of our objective function H, since the Kuhn-Tuckermultipliers, λi(s) and β(s) are both zero.

27

Page 28: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

Clearly, in this case, all the shares are allotted to institutional investors. Retail investors

get nothing in equilibrium.

Proof of Proposition 5:

This proof is constructed in the same way as Proposition 2. We divide the proof in three

steps. In the first step, we derive conditions for the existence of a uniform pricing rule among

institutional investors. Then in step 2, we show existence of a unique pricing rule satisfying

these conditions. Finally, in step three, we show that the optimal uniform pricing rule may

be applied to retail investors.

Step 1: The linear transfer for the institutional investors must satisfy the following

equation

ZΩ−i

pi(s)qi(s)f−i(s−i)ds−i =

ZΩ−i

½z(qi(s), v)−

1

n

∙Z si

sz2(qi(esi, s−i), v(esi, s−i))desi¸¾ f−i(s−i)ds−i;

(26)

Then, consider the following price function

p0i (s) =z(qi(s), v)− 1

n

hR sis z2(qi(esi, s−i), v(esi, s−i))desii

qi(s)(27)

for each si and each qi(s) such that qi(s) 6= 0.16 Any price satisfying equation (26) can be

also written as pi(s) = p0i (s) + Φi(s) with Φi satisfies the following equationZΩ−i

Φi(s)qi(si, s−i)f−i(s−i)ds−i = 0, for all i and si.

After characterizing uniform pricing as in Proposition 2 (see equation (10)), we can show

that the optimal mechanism may be implemented with a uniform price if

¡−p0i (s) + αv − δqi(s)

¢µ∂qi(s)∂si

− ∂qi(s)

∂sj

¶− α

n

∙qi(s)−

Z si

s

∂qi(esi, s−i)∂sj

desi¸+∂Φi(s)

∂siqi(s) =

∂Φi(s)

∂sjqi(s). (28)

16Otherwise p0i (s) = 0.

28

Page 29: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

We can easily show from Proposition 4 that the optimal quantities allocated to institutional

investors is such that∂qi(s)

∂si− ∂qi(s)

∂sj=

α

for each s and each i. This allows us to re-write equation (28) as follows

α

n

⎧⎪⎪⎪⎨⎪⎪⎪⎩£−p0i (s) + αv − δqi(s)

¤δqi(s)

− 1 +

Z si

s

∂qi(esi, s−i)∂sj

desiqi(s)

⎫⎪⎪⎪⎬⎪⎪⎪⎭+∂Φi(s)

∂si=

∂Φi(s)

∂sj.

Replacing p0i (s) by its value as defined by equation (26) yields

α

n

⎧⎪⎪⎪⎨⎪⎪⎪⎩−3

2+

α

Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desi[qi(s)]2

+

Z si

s

∂qi(esi, s−i)∂sj

desiqi(s)

⎫⎪⎪⎪⎬⎪⎪⎪⎭+∂Φi(s)

∂si=

∂Φi(s)

∂sj.

By replacingα

nδby

∂qi(s)

∂si− ∂qi(s)

∂sjand after some simple computations, we get

∂si

⎡⎢⎢⎣Φi(s)− α

n

Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desiqi(s)

⎤⎥⎥⎦ = ∂

∂sj

⎡⎢⎢⎣Φi(s)− α

n

Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desiqi(s)

⎤⎥⎥⎦+ α

2n, (29)

for each i and each j. This is a partial differential equation in Φi(s) −α

n

Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desiqi(s)

whose generic solution is given by

Φi(s) = ϕ(s1 + ...+ sn) +α

n

R sis qi(esi, s−i)desi

qi(s)+

α

2nsi, for all i

where ϕ(·) is a twice differentiable function defined on the set [ns, ns] = nΩ.

Summing up, so far we have shown that the optimal mechanism may be implemented by

a uniform price schedule if and only if

pi(s) = p0i (s) + ϕ(s1 + ...+ sn) +

α

n

Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desiqi(s)

2nsi

where ϕ is a twice differentiable function satisfying the following integral equation

ZΩ−i

⎡⎢⎢⎣ϕ(s1 + ...+ sn) + α

n

Z si

sqi(esi, s−i)desiqi(s)

2nsi

⎤⎥⎥⎦ qi(si, s−i)f−i(s−i)ds−i = 0.29

Page 30: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

or alternatively ZΩ−i

ϕ(s1 + ...+ sn)qi(si, s−i)f−i(s−i)ds−i =

−ZΩ−i

⎡⎢⎢⎣αnZ si

sqi(esi, s−i)desiqi(s)

2nsi

⎤⎥⎥⎦ qi(si, s−i)f−i(s−i)ds−i = g(si).(30)

Henceforth, proving the existence of a uniform price schedule is equivalent to prove the

existence of such a function ϕ.

STEP 2: We first show that equation (30) can be written as a Volterra integral equation

of the first kind.17 Then, by simply applying the general properties of this kind of integral

equations we can prove the existence and the uniqueness of a function ϕ.

To do this, we first need to transform equation (30) into a simple integral equation, i.e.

with the support defined on R.

Notice that, since qi(si, s−i) = 0 when si ≤ s0i (v−i), the support of the integral equation

(30) is equal to Ω0−i = (s1, s2, .., si−1, si+1, .., sn) |Pj 6=i sj = v−i > v0−i(si) where v0−i(si) is

defined as the inverse of s0i (v−i), i.e.

v0−i(si) =αs− (2α− 1)si

α− 1

Also, by using the definition of the optimal quantity, the LHS term of equation (30) is

equivalent toRΩ0−i

ϕ(si + v−i)qi(si, v−i)f−i(s−i)ds−i.

Now, by applying the Generalized Change Variable Theorem (GVCT) we can set v−i =

γi(s−i) for each i, which finally implies that γi(Ω0−i) = [v

0−i(si); (n− 1)s] ∈ R.18

A main implication of the GVCT is that, there exists a measure λ defined over [v0−i(si); (n−

1)s] such thatZΩ0−i

ϕ(si + v−i)qi(si, v−i)f−i(s−i)ds−i =

Z (n−1)s

v0−i(si)ϕ(si + v−i)qi(si, v−i)λ(dv−i).

17A Volterra integral equation of the the first kind is defined in the following way:Z τ(x)

y0

f(x, y)h(x, y)dy = g(x)

in other words, one of the integral extreme must depend on the variable x.18See Dunford and Schwartz (1988, 3rd Ed.), chapter 3, lemma 8, page 182.

30

Page 31: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

Last, by applying the Radon-Nikodým theorem19, we are also able to prove the existence

of a density function ρ associated to the measure λ such thatZΩ0−i

ϕ(si + v−i)qi(si, v−i)f−i(s−i)ds−i =

Z (n−1)s

v0−i(si)ϕ(si + v−i)qi(si, v−i)ρ(v−i)dv−i.

By using the result above, the integral equation (30) reduces toZ (n−1)s

v0−i(si)ϕ(si + v−i)qi(si, v−i)ρ(v−i)dv−i = g(si)

This is a Volterra integral equation of the first kind which ensures that, as far as the

function g is well behaved, a solution in ϕ always exists. This shows the existence of a unique

uniform pricing rule for institutional investors. We denote in the following by pI(s) such

pricing rule.

Step 3:

To complete the proof we are left to show that the uniform price for institutional investors

is also applicable to retail investors. This is equivalent to show that pI(s) satisfies the retail

investors’ participation constraint. Notice that the problem is relevant only in those cases

in which both retail and institutional investors receive a positive amount of shares at the

optimum.

We start by defining the following sets:

Ω− = s | qi = 0 for all i, i.e. all the quantity is distributed to retail investors;

Ω\Ω− = s | qi(s) 6= 0 for at least one i

Recall that, retail investors’ participation constraint writes as followsZΩpR(s)qR(s)f(s)ds =

ZΩv

Ã1−

Xi

qi(s)

!f(s)ds

Then, proving that the pricing rule is uniform to all investors is equivalent to show the

existence of a price function pR(s) solving the above integral equation and such that:

pR(s) =

(p−(s) for all s ∈ Ω−

pI(s) for all s ∈ Ω\Ω−19See, for example, Dunford and Schwartz (1988), chapter 3, theorem 2, page 176 in the third edition.

31

Page 32: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

which requires that retail investors are charged different prices depending on whether they

get the whole quantity or not. The problem then boils down to prove the existence of a price

p−(s) such thatZΩ−p−(s)f(s)ds+

ZΩ\Ω−

pI(s)

Ã1−

Xi

qi(s)

!f(s)ds =

ZΩv

Ã1−

Xi

qi(s)

!f(s)ds

or equivalentlyZΩ−p−(s)f(s)ds =

ZΩv

Ã1−

Xi

qi(s)

!f(s)ds−

ZΩ\Ω−

pI(s)

Ã1−

Xi

qi(s)

!f(s)ds (31)

Then we prove the following:

Lemma 2 A price function p−(s) as defined above exists if and only if it satisfies the fol-

lowing equationZΩ−p−(s)f(s)ds =

ZΩv +H(q, v)f(s)ds−

ZΩ\Ω−

pI(s)f(s)ds. (32)

where the function H(q, v) defines the seller’s payoff at the optimum (see the proof of Propo-

sition 4).

Proof of Lemma 2:

=⇒ Suppose there exists a price p−(s) which verifies the participation constraint of the

retail investors. This implies that the seller’s expected payoff at the optimum are given byZΩ−p−(s)f(s)ds+

ZΩ\Ω−

pI(s)f(s)ds =

ZΩv +H(q, v)f(s)ds

because of the uniform pricing rule and the fact that all the shares are always sold.

⇐= Consider the condition satisfied by the price to the institutional investors. Summing

over si and over i we getZΩ

Xi

pi(s)qi(s)f(s)ds =

Xi

½z(qi(s), v)−

1

n

∙Z si

sz2(qi(esi, s−i), v(esi, s−i))desi¸¾ f(s)ds

using the fact that institutional investors all pay the same price and adding −RΩ pI(s)f(s)ds

andRΩ v (1−

Pi qi(s)) f(s)ds to both sides yields the followingR

Ω p(s) (1−Pi qi(s)) f(s)ds−

RΩ v (1−

Pi qi(s)) f(s)ds =R

Ω p(s)f(s)ds−RΩv +H(q, v)f(s)ds.

32

Page 33: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

If the uniform price exists then the RHS of the above equation is equal to zero which imme-

diately implies that the retail investors’ participation constraint, on the LHS of the equation,

is met. This ends the proof of Lemma 2

Notice that the right hand side of equation (32)does not depend the agents’ signals and

so the integral equation defined over p−(s) has many solutions. This proves that the seller

could find a pricing function where a uniform pricing rule for all investors may be applied at

the optimal mechanism. Note finally that the seller may choose among different pricing rules

that may be applied for retail investors when s belongs to Ω−.

Proof of Proposition 6

Let us define the following three sets:

N−(s) = i ∈ N | si ≤ si(v−i)

N+(s) = i ∈ N | si > si(v−i)

Ω+(s) = i ∈ N | si 6= s

and $+ = Card(Ω+(s)).

The solution of the relaxed problem is very similar to that of Proposition 4. Pointwise

maximization leads to the following Kuhn-Tucker conditions:

⎧⎪⎪⎪⎪⎪⎪⎪⎪⎨⎪⎪⎪⎪⎪⎪⎪⎪⎩

(α− 1)v − δqi −α

n(s− si) + λi(s)− β(s) + γ(s) = 0, for all i

λi(s)qi(s) = 0

β(s)[1−Piqi(s)] = 0

γ(s)[1−Piqi(s)−K] = 0

(33)

where λi,β and γ are the Kuhn-Tucker multipliers associated to the three remaining con-

straints. Note that β and γ cannot be different from zero at the same time. If we consider

that γ = 0, then we get the same problem as in the case without budget constraints and

proves point (1), (2) and (4) of the Proposition.

33

Page 34: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

For the third point, suppose thatP

i∈N+(s)

eqi(s) ≤ 1−K. So in this case β(s) = 0 and λi(s)for all i should be equal to zero otherwise some shares will remain unsold. In this case, retail

investors receive K shares and the optimal allocation rule for informed investors is the one

satisfying the following FOC:

(α− 1)v − δqi −α

n(s− si) + γ(s) = 0

for all i ∈ Ω+(s) with γ(s) solving the equation below:

γ(s) =δ(1−K)$+

ns− α

n$+

Xj∈Ω+(s)

sj − (α− 1)v

By replacing γ(s) into the previous FOC, we finally obtain that the optimal quantity to

informed investors is equal to

eqKi (s) = 1

δ$+

⎧⎨⎩δ(1−K) + α

n($+ − 1)si −

α

n

Xj∈Ω+(s), j 6=i

sj

⎫⎬⎭

34

Page 35: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

References

[1] Aggarwal R., Prabhala N. and M. Puri, 2002, “Institutional Allocations in Initial Public

Offerings: Empirical Evidence”, Journal of Finance, 57: 1421-42.

[2] Allen F. and G. Faulhaber, 1989, “Signaling by Underpricing in the IPO Market”, Jour-

nal of Financial Economics, 23 (2): 303-323.

[3] Beatty R. and J. Ritter, 1986, “Investment Banking, Reputation, and the Underpricing

of Initial Public Offerings”, Journal of Financial Economics, 15: 213-232.

[4] Bennouri M. and S. Falconieri, 2005, “Optimal Auctions with Asymmetrically Informed

Bidders”, forthcoming Economic Theory.

[5] Bennouri M. and S. Falconieri, 2004, “ Optimal Rationing in IPOs with Risk Averse

Institutional Investors”, mimeo, Tilburg University.

[6] Benveniste L.M. and P.A. Spindt, 1989, “How Investment Bankers Determine the Offer

Price and the Allocation of New Issues”, Journal of Financial Economics, 24: 213-323.

[7] Benveniste L.M. and W.J. Wilhelm, 1997, “Initial Public Offerings: Going by the Book”,

Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 10 (1): 98-108.

[8] Benveniste, L.M. and W.J. Wilhelm, 1990, “A Comparative Analysis of IPO Proceeds

under Alternative Regulatory Environments”, Journal of Financial Economics, 28: 173-

207.

[9] Biais B. and A.M. Faugeron-Crouzet, 2002, “IPO auctions: English, Dutch, ... French

and Internet”, Journal of Financial Intermediation, 11: 9-36.

[10] Biais B., P. Bossaerts and J-C. Rochet, 2002, “An Optimal IPO Mechanism”, Review of

Economic Studies, 69: 117-146.

[11] Brisley, Neil, 2003, “A Comparative Analysis of IPO Proceeds under Alternative Regu-

latory Environments: A Comment”, Economics Bulletin, 7: 1-7

35

Page 36: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

[12] Bulow J. and P. Klemperer, 1996, “Auctions vs. Negotiations”, American Economic

Review, 86: 180-94.

[13] Bulow J. and P. Klemperer, 2002, “Prices and the Winner’s Curse”, Rand Journal of

Economics, 33 (1): 1-21.

[14] Cornelli F. and D. Goldreich, 2001 “Bookbuilding and Strategic Allocation”, Journal of

Finance, 56: 2337-69.

[15] Cremer J. and R.P. McLean, 1988, “Full Extraction of the Surplus in Bayesian and

Dominant Strategy Auctions”, Econometrica, 56: 1247-57.

[16] Derrien, F and K.L. Womack, 2003 “Auctions vs Bookbuilding and the Control of Un-

derpricing in Hot IPO Markets”, Review of Financial Studies, 16 (1): 31-62.

[17] Dunford and J.T. Schwartz: Linear Operators: Part I: General Theory ; John Wiley and

Sons, New York, Third Edition

[18] Eso, P., 2005, “An Optimal Auction with Correlated Values and Risk Aversion”, forth-

coming, Journal of Economic Theory

[19] Ellul A. and M. Pagano, 2003, ”IPO Underpricing and After-Market Liquidity”,Working

Paper CSEF.

[20] Fudenberg D. and J. Tirole, 1991, “Game Theory”, MIT Press.

[21] Jenkinson T. and A. Ljungqvist, 2001, Going Public: The Theory and Evidence of How

Companies Raise Equity Finance, Oxford University Press.

[22] Kremer, I. and K. Nyborg, 2004, ”Divisible-Good Auctions: The Role of Allocation

Rules”, Rand Journal of Economics, 35 (1):147-159.

[23] Lyons R., 2003, “The Microstructure Approach to Exchange Rates”, MIT Press

[24] Maksimovic V. and P. Pichler, 2002 “Structuring the Initial Offering: Who to Sell To

and How to Do It”, mimeo Boston College.

36

Page 37: The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal ...neumann.hec.ca/pages/moez.bennouri/papers/IPO-JFIsub1.pdf · The Optimality of Uniform Pricing in IPOs: An Optimal Auction

[25] Malakhov, A., 2004, ”The Role of Uninformed Buyers in Optimal IPO Mechanisms”,

mimeo Kellog School of Management, Northwestern University.

[26] Maskin, E. and J.Riley, 1984, “Optimal Auctions with Risk Averse Buyers”, Economet-

rica, 52, 1473 - 1518

[27] Maskin E. and J. Riley, 1989, “Optimal Multi-Unit Auctions”, in The Economics of

Missing Markets, Information and Games, ed. by F.Hahn, Oxford: Oxford University

Press, 312-35.

[28] Myerson R., 1981, “Optimal Auction Design”, Mathematics of Operations Research, 6:

619-32.

[29] O’Hara M., 1995, “Market Microstructure”, Blackwell Publishers

[30] Ritter J. , 1987, “The Costs of Going Public’; Journal of Financial Economics, 19:

269-281.

[31] Ritter J. and I. Welch, 2002, “A Review of IPO Activity, Pricing, and Allocations”,

Journal of Finance, 57 (4): 1795-1828.

[32] Rock K, 1986, “Why New Issues Are Underpriced?”, Journal of Financial Economics,

15: 197-212.

37