the function of a public health system tsiteresources.worldbank.org/intpsia/resources/... · the...

68
Health Sector Reforms Mattias Lundberg and Limin Wang 43 2 THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis (PSIA) is to exam- ine the distributional consequences of sectoral reforms. It is not a review of the impact of reforms on overall sectoral performance. How- ever, the effect of health sector reforms on welfare among the poor and other groups is inextricably linked to the effect of reforms on sectoral per- formance. Reforms are intended to address a wide variety of problems and constraints in the sector and to achieve myriad and often conflicting objectives. Not all of these are explicitly intended to enhance equity, but they will all have distributional consequences. As a prerequisite to examining health sector reforms, understand- ing what the health system is designed to do, how it can achieve its goals, and the context in which it operates is important. Although improved health is a goal in itself and is a requirement for economic growth, to expect that the health system can, on its own, achieve broader welfare or growth objectives is unreasonable. The health system should focus on improving health. According to World Health Report 2000 (WHO 2000a), national health systems have three fundamental objectives: (1) improving the health of the population they serve, (2) responding to people’s expectations, and (3) providing financial protection against the costs of ill health. World The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments and suggestions of Mark Camden Bassett, Shiyan Chao, Shanta Devarajan, David Evans, Deon Filmer, Dave Gwatkin, and George Schieber on this chapter.

Upload: others

Post on 21-Apr-2020

5 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Health Sector Reforms

Mattias Lundberg and Limin Wang

43

2

THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM

The purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis (PSIA) is to exam-ine the distributional consequences of sectoral reforms. It is not areview of the impact of reforms on overall sectoral performance. How-

ever, the effect of health sector reforms on welfare among the poor andother groups is inextricably linked to the effect of reforms on sectoral per-formance. Reforms are intended to address a wide variety of problemsand constraints in the sector and to achieve myriad and often conflictingobjectives. Not all of these are explicitly intended to enhance equity, butthey will all have distributional consequences.

As a prerequisite to examining health sector reforms, understand-ing what the health system is designed to do, how it can achieve its goals,and the context in which it operates is important. Although improvedhealth is a goal in itself and is a requirement for economic growth, toexpect that the health system can, on its own, achieve broader welfare orgrowth objectives is unreasonable. The health system should focus onimproving health.

According to World Health Report 2000 (WHO 2000a), national healthsystems have three fundamental objectives: (1) improving the health ofthe population they serve, (2) responding to people’s expectations, and(3) providing financial protection against the costs of ill health. World

The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments and suggestions of Mark CamdenBassett, Shiyan Chao, Shanta Devarajan, David Evans, Deon Filmer, Dave Gwatkin, andGeorge Schieber on this chapter.

Page 2: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Health Report 2000 goes on to suggest that the second and third goals arepartly instrumental, that is, they contribute to the first goal.

Note that this list says nothing about how these objectives are to beachieved. There is nothing about health or public health that requires a par-ticular mode of organization or delivery. This is distinct from the acknowl-edgment that certain components of health and health care are public goods,which (it is assumed) must be provided or at least encouraged by collectiveaction.

To achieve these goals, health systems perform a number of generalfunctions. Paraphrasing the World Health Report, these can be classifiedas: (1) governance and oversight, (2) investment and training, (3) financeand risk-pooling, and (4) service provision.

One can imagine many hundreds of things that health systems actu-ally do, but they can reasonably be subsumed into these comprehensive cat-egories of activities. This requires a broader view of health systems, such asdescribed in both World Health Report 2000 and World Development Report2004 (World Bank 2003a). Public health is not merely medical care, orhuman resources, or social insurance; similarly, it consists of more thanvertical public campaigns targeted at specific diseases.

To understand the impact of health sector reforms, especially onpoverty and welfare, one must ask how the proposed actions will influencethe performance of the system and the system’s ability to achieve itsfundamental objectives. To make this a bit more concrete, it is importantto ask, for example, not only whether a particular program (say, a programon insecticide-treated bed-nets) is achieving its objectives and not merelywhether the program is pro-poor. It is important also to ask about theopportunity costs of the program: can the objectives of better public healthand better health among the poor be achieved by other means? We can thenask whether the program is best designed to achieve its own objectives. Inthe current jargon, we must first ask whether we are “doing the rightthings” and then whether we are “doing them right.”1 It is also essential tohave some idea of the counterfactual: what is likely to happen in the absenceof any changes or intervention?

We must keep in mind that health is an input to human well-being, andhuman well-being is the goal of public policy. Health is instrumental, even(pace Amartya Sen) fundamental, but it is conceivable that, under certainconditions, welfare will be more enhanced by investments in items otherthan health. The concept of the counterfactual should therefore be broad-ened to encompass nonhealth alternatives. Even if one particular investmentor policy is found to dominate others within the sector, it is possible thatanother nonhealth investment will increase living standards even more.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

44

Page 3: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

These alternative investments can cover items that also improve health, suchas food, shelter, water, sanitation, and transport, but these are usually out-side the purview of health ministries.

Thus, it is important to understand the broader context of health sec-tor reforms. However, it is equally important to maintain the analyticalfocus on the distributional consequences of reforms. This chapter specifi-cally aims to provide a guide for policy practitioners who wish to conductan analysis of the impact of health reform or health policy changes on thewelfare of households, especially poor households (thus, “poverty andsocial impact analysis”).

At a minimum, analysis of proposed reforms in health must addressthe following questions:

m What is needed to enable the health sector to achieve its broaderobjectives?

m What is the potential welfare impact of the proposed reforms acrosssocioeconomic groups?

m What can be done to avoid or minimize possibly adverse consequencesof reforms?

The first of these questions addresses the design and context ofreforms. Understanding the welfare consequences requires that we con-sider the main intended purpose of the reforms. What goals are the reformsintended to achieve, and how can the health system be organized to bestachieve the goals? These questions are addressed in World DevelopmentReport 2004. The third question addresses the design of compensationmechanisms to mitigate the unintended adverse effects of policy changes.While there is little experience with designing mitigation mechanismsspecifically for health reforms, more general guidance is provided in ASourcebook for Poverty Reduction Strategies (Klugman 2002), especiallyPart 5, “Human Development” (pages 163–231) and “Technical Note”(pages 543–76), as well as in A User’s Guide to Poverty and Social ImpactAnalysis (World Bank 2003b).

This chapter focuses on the second issue: the identification of the con-sequences of reforms for the poor and other groups. This information isclearly required for the design of mitigation programs, but mitigationshould be considered a last-best alternative to designing reforms in orderto achieve the best outcomes for all. The identification of impacts is alsoessential for designing effective reforms that enable the sector to achieve itsoverarching goal of enhancing public health.

This chapter proceeds as follows. First, we discuss the rationale for andthe types of reforms that are common in the health sector. We then discuss

Health Sector Reforms

45

Page 4: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

the stakeholders and transmission channels for the impact of reforms.Finally, we turn to the technical aspects: analytical methods, assumptions,data requirements, and so on.

ISSUES SPECIFIC TO THE ANALYSIS OF HEALTH REFORMS

Before we begin, we must deal with a few aspects of reforms that are uniqueto the health sector. Some of these issues arise in other reforms, especiallythose dealing with public or quasi-public goods, such as education. But theyare arguably more complex and more confounding in health reforms thanin reforms in other sectors, and they are all vital to the analysis of the impactof reforms on welfare. These include the definition of equity, moral hazardand agency, asymmetric information and adverse selection, and other con-founding factors.

Health care is not the same as health

One feature of health care that distinguishes it from other public goodsand services is that the consumption of health care is only one input, albeitan important one, in the production of health. As Filmer, Hammer, andPritchett (2000) demonstrate, the connection between public health spend-ing and public health outcomes is rather tenuous. Health is produced inthe household as a function of health care, nutrition, behavior, water, andmyriad other factors. Wagstaff (1999) provides a figure to illustrate theselinks. He points out that not only do health outcomes vary across groups,but there is enormous inequality in the determinants of health outcomesas well (Figure 2.1).

When examining the impact of health reforms on health and welfare,one should understand that these other characteristics will inevitably getin the way of the path from policies to outcomes. It is equally importantthat we understand the interactions between the sectoral reforms andthese confounding factors. Three main questions must be addressed, asfollows:

m What effect will the reforms have on these other confounding factors?m How will these confounding factors influence the impact of reforms

on health?m How will these confounding factors shape the process of reform?

The first of these questions is not intuitive. Reforms may have signi-ficant external (to the health sector) effects, positive and negative. For

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

46

Page 5: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

47

Out

com

es

Hea

lthou

tcom

esHe

alth

and

nutri

tiona

lsta

tus,

and

mor

talit

y

Hou

seho

lds/

Com

mun

ities

Hea

lthsy

stem

and

rela

ted

sect

ors

Hea

lthse

rvic

epr

ovis

ion

Avai

labi

lity,

acce

ssib

ility

,pric

es,

and

qual

ityof

serv

ices

Hea

lthfin

ance

Publ

ican

dpr

ivat

ein

sura

nce,

finan

cing

,an

dco

vera

ge

Supp

lyin

rela

ted

sect

ors

Avai

labi

lity,

acce

ssib

ility

,pric

esan

dqu

ality

offo

od,

ener

gy,r

oads

,wat

er,

sani

tatio

n,et

c.

Gov

ernm

ent

polic

ies

and

actio

ns

Heal

thpo

licie

sat

mac

ro,h

ealth

syst

em,

and

mic

role

vels

Othe

rgov

ernm

ent

polic

ies,

e.g.

,in

frast

ruct

ure,

trans

port,

ener

gy,

agric

ultu

re,w

ater

,an

dsa

nita

tion

Com

mun

ityfa

ctor

sCu

ltura

lnor

ms,

com

mun

ityin

stitu

tions

,soc

ialc

apita

l,en

viro

nmen

t,an

din

frast

ruct

ure

Hou

seho

ldac

tions

and

risk

fact

ors

Use

ofhe

alth

serv

ices

;die

tary

,sa

nita

ry,a

ndse

xual

prac

tices

;life

styl

e,et

c.

Hou

seho

ldas

sets

Hum

an,

phys

ical

,and

finan

cial

Sour

ce:W

agst

aff,

2002

,Fig

ure

2.

FIG

URE

2.1

The

Det

erm

inan

tsof

Hea

lthO

utco

mes

Page 6: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

example, reforms in the health sector may influence community institu-tions. There have been numerous experiments recently to harness com-munity groups to monitor the performance of local public services (see,for example, Loewenson 2000). This may have the added effect of strength-ening local capital and local institutions, which may then collectively bar-gain for (or informally provide) other services that incidentally enhancehealth, such as water and sewage connections.

The second question—on the influence of confounding factors on theoutcomes of the reforms—is related to the issue of transmission channels.In this case, however, the transmission channels are primarily external tothe sector and to the reforms. Clearly, enhanced access to health serviceswill affect health care consumption and possibly health outcomes. Thatis the direct and intended impact. But this impact will differ across areasbecause of, for example, differing access to clean water. Health is not nec-essarily enhanced by the construction of clinics if the local drinking wateris contaminated by sewage. There may be more subtle consequences aswell: for example, the physiological impact of medical treatment may beaffected by illnesses caused by pathogens in drinking water.

Finally, many nonhealth institutions, both private and public, willinfluence the implementation of reforms in the sector. These are externalto the health sector proper, but will shape the process and impact of re-forms. In Mozambique, for example, eight ministries are involved in healthcare finance and policy, six of which are actually providing health services.These include the ministries of public works, education, justice, and inte-rior, as well as health.

Equity

Equity in health has been the subject of enormous discussion and litera-ture. Here, some of the issues are mentioned that will arise in the contextof any health reform. These can be crudely distinguished as equity of what?and what equity? These questions are not trivial: World Health Report 2000placed great emphasis on creating indexes of the equity of health financeand services (see the Statistical Annexes in the report), and these indexeshave been remarkably controversial (for example, see Asada and Hede-mann 2002; Wagstaff 1999). Here, the various concepts of equity are brieflydescribed that are commonly used in health.

Equity in health care can be conceived in terms of access, finance, expen-diture, and outcomes, and health policy has usually distinguished betweenhorizontal and vertical equity, which have specific meanings in each case.Table 2.1 briefly describes these different terms as they are commonly used.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

48

Page 7: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Horizontal equity generally refers to the distribution of costs and ben-efits across groups of similar socioeconomic or health status; vertical equityrefers to the distribution of costs and benefits across groups of differing sta-tus. The underlying assumptions are that unequal health outcomes areunjust, that health services should be provided (or guaranteed) socially,2

and that the distribution of costs and benefits should somehow be relatedto health and wealth status.3 Note that there is one exception: in publichealth finance, equity is usually defined in terms of the ratio of paymentsto income; it is not necessarily defined as the ratio of payments to the con-sumption of health services. It is assumed that those who consume morehealth care are more ill and have greater need for health services.

Moral hazard

The common belief that health care payments need not be related to healthcare consumption presents a moral hazard on the part of the consumer. Thiscan occur both ex ante and ex post. Ex ante moral hazard, that is, occurringprior to the need for health care consumption, leads individuals to engagein riskier behavior than they would do if they were required to bear the totalcost of the health care. Ex post moral hazard, that is, following the appear-ance of the need for health care consumption, is manifest in the over-consumption of health care services or, in other words, the consumption ofservices even when the benefits are less than the total social cost. Health care

Health Sector Reforms

49

TABLE 2.1. Definition of Equity in Health Policy

Concept of equity

Horizontal Vertical

Access

Finance

Expenditure

Outcomes

Source: Compiled by the authors.

Dim

ensi

onof

equi

ty

Those with similar needs have simi-lar access to services.

Those in equal socioeconomic posi-tions pay the same for care.

Those in equal socioeconomic positions or similar health receivethe same value of publicly fundedservices.

Those with greater needs have access tomore care or more intensive care.

Wealthier households pay more than dopoorer households.

Poorer households and households withmore illness receive more than dowealthier, healthier households.

All households experience similar health outcomes, regardless of socioeconomicstatus.

Page 8: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

is different from other public goods and services, such as education, sincegreater consumption is not always beneficial. There exists a point beyondwhich the net social returns to more use of health services are negative.4 Thisis of greater concern in former socialist countries, in which overconsump-tion was common, but it may be troublesome also where publicly providedservices are captured by a (presumably wealthier) minority.

Moral hazard can cause problems on the supply side as well, since doc-tors have no incentive to control costs. For instance, doctors working undera fee-for-service regime have an incentive to provide more services than thepatients would choose to receive if they had complete information. This isalso known as supplier-induced demand. It is not merely a theoretical con-cern, although the evidence is primarily from developed countries. Studieson China (Bumgarner 1992), France (Chiappori, Durand, and Geoffard1998), the Netherlands (Hurst 1992), Taiwan (Cheng and Chiang 1997),and the United Kingdom (Dusheiko et al. 2003) find that fee-for-servicereimbursement leads providers to increase the volume of services.

ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION

Moral hazard arises from the asymmetric distribution of information.Ex ante moral hazard occurs because an insurer (for example) cannotmonitor the behavior of the people he insures. Asymmetric informationcauses, in addition to moral hazard, further problems in health care pro-vision since the quality of care is generally unobservable. Moreover, thecharacteristics valued by the consumer of care are not necessarily relatedto the efficacy or medical quality of care. For instance, a patient mightprefer a pleasant, but ineffectual doctor to an impolite, but effective one.In that case, the preferences of the patient and the public health author-ities conflict.

The quality of care is unobservable partly because we cannot see clearlythe effort that physicians and other providers expend in producing healthcare. Even if they show up for work (which is not always the case; seeChaudhury and Hammer 2003), it is difficult to monitor the attention pro-viders give to patients. To use the economics jargon, the interests of theprincipals (the patients and the public health authorities) differ from thoseof the agent (the provider) who is hired to supply the services. The princi-pals want greater health; the agents may want that, too, but they also wantto avoid working long hours for low pay. This leads to lower levels andquality of service than the principals would like.

A good deal of research has gone into the design of incentives and pay-ment schemes to minimize the difference between the interests of princi-

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

50

Page 9: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

pals and agents, or, at least, to reduce the cost of controlling the agencyproblem. Since the agent’s behavior is expensive to monitor, the principalmust design a contract such that the provision of the services the principalwants is in the interest of the agent (Eggleston and Hsieh 2004; Hammerand Jack 2001; Jack 2001a; McGuire 2000).

This is not merely of academic interest, but has great impact on the dis-tribution of services, since physicians may neglect poorer patients in favorof those who can pay, or may direct patients away from public services toalternative, fee-paying services. This issue of “dual practice” is rather con-troversial and has received considerable attention from reformers. On theone hand, dual-practice doctors can induce demand, reduce effort and qual-ity in their public sector jobs, and steal other resources from public facilitiesto benefit their private practices. On the other hand, dual practice can be away for the public sector to retain skilled doctors at low wages and for thedoctors to target public services more effectively to those who cannot payprivately (Bir and Eggleston 2003; Ferrinho et al. 2004; Gruen et al. 2002).

The provision of health insurance and prepayment systems may be ren-dered inefficient or unsustainable by the problem of adverse selection. Thisrefers to the observation that those who expect to have high health costs aremore likely to seek insurance. The problem for insurance arises because theinsurer cannot sort (and price-discriminate among) consumers accordingto health risks (or rather, that screening and monitoring are expensive), andhigh-risk consumers drive up the costs of care insurance.

HEALTH SECTOR REFORMS: MOTIVATION AND TYPOLOGY

Motivation

Health sector reforms have been a focus of policy debates in both devel-oped and developing countries at least since the 1970s. In response toplainly deteriorating morbidity and mortality (for instance, see Bennett1979), the Alma Ata Declaration of September 1978 established, amongother points, that health is a fundamental human right and that peopleare entitled to take part in health care planning and implementation.

In principle, health sector policies in developing countries haveemphasized equity and focused on delivering services to the poor, but, inpractice, the basic goals of the Alma Ata Declaration have not beenachieved in the intervening 25 years. According to some, the ideals havebeen abandoned; according to others, the ideals were unrealistic andunattainable in the first place (for example, see Hall and Taylor 2003).

In addition, recent research has demonstrated the weak links betweenpublic health policies and expenditures on the one hand and health services

Health Sector Reforms

51

Page 10: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

and outcomes on the other (see Filmer, Hammer, and Pritchett 2000 andWorld Development Report 2004). More money is clearly not sufficientand may not even be necessary to achieve better health outcomes. Sur-veys and case studies in low-income countries reveal a rather disappointingpicture. Wagstaff (2000a) and Wang (2003) present data from more than40 low-income countries in the 1990s showing that children in poor house-holds had a much higher probability of dying before age 5 and that survivalrates improved much less among these children than they did among chil-dren in more well off households.

Some of the reasons for continuing inequities and poor health out-comes are external to health policy. Thus, civil wars, natural disasters, andthe AIDS crisis have overwhelmed public health services, and political com-mitment to the rhetoric of the Alma Ata Declaration has proven easier thancommitting the resources required to achieve the declaration’s goals.

But some of the reasons for poor outcomes involve governance, cap-ture, and mismanagement in the sector itself. Public spending intendedfor services to poor households has been captured by the non-poor (seeCastro-Leal et al. 2000); large shares of limited public spending on health(about 1 percent of gross domestic product) have been devoted to curativeservices, which mainly benefit the more well off. Griffin (1992) found thatthe distribution of central government health resources to the provincesin many Asian countries was often inversely correlated with need as mea-sured by infant mortality. Health programs that are designed specificallyto benefit the poor (such as the expansion of primary health care) were notreaching the poor effectively. Poor children are much less likely to receivesimple curative care such as oral rehydration salts, and they are muchless likely to be immunized than are children from wealthier households(Gwatkin et al. 2000).

In a comprehensive review, the World Health Organization (WHO2000a) categorized three generations of health sector reforms. As inmany other areas, the first generation of reforms concentrated on cut-ting bloated budgets and encouraging the private sector.5 The secondwave of reforms emphasized public sector efficiency, human resourcemanagement, and decentralization. More recently, the approach hasbeen to take a broader, “sectorwide” view to improve both service deliv-ery and outcomes (see World Development Report 2004). This has meantthat the aims of health reform have become—in principle, at least—more clearly defined and openly shared among policymakers and donorcommunities. The reforms reflect changes in thinking about health sys-tems and their links to health outcomes, as well as to broader develop-ment objectives.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

52

Page 11: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Very often, health system reforms are imposed from the outside. Forexample, in response to structural adjustment programs and imposed pub-lic sector reform, many African countries engineered partial changes inhealth system financing, such as the introduction of user fees. In CentralAmerica, the devolution of some management functions to district orregional health offices was a direct response to macroeconomic reformsbecause of fiscal crisis and government decentralization (Bossert 1998).These imposed reforms included the promotion of the private sector deliv-ery of health services (mainly by nongovernmental organizations), whichwas often part of a nationwide privatization movement (McPake 1997).

Recent years have seen popular reaction against health sector reforms,with the common perception that reforms have adversely affected the pro-vision of services, particularly for the vulnerable. The list of perceived fail-ures associated with reforms has included inequity due to the introductionof user fees, the damage done to vertical immunization and family plan-ning programs by decentralization, and the reduction of access to qualityservices by the poor caused by inadequately designed insurance schemes(Berman and Bossert 2000). In spite of this backlash, it is clear that contin-ued reforms are essential both to enhance the performance of the sectorand to expand coverage to poor and vulnerable groups (for example, seeWorld Development Report 2004).

Typology of reforms

The scope of the health reforms implemented in developing countriesvaries substantially. It is useful, albeit crude and imprecise, to distinguishthe reforms into those affecting the supply side and those affecting thedemand side of the health sector, that is, those involving the financing, man-agement, and provision of services on the one hand and, on the other hand,those involving the demand for and consumption of services. The vastmajority of reforms have focused on the supply side. Table 2.2 presents ahighly stylized selection of reforms and their potential consequences forwelfare and poverty. These are not necessarily comparable: some are ambi-tious and comprehensive, and some are relatively minor.

The list is not exhaustive, nor is the taxonomy perfect, but it shows themajority of issues that will come up during health sector reforms. In thetable, supply-side reforms include governance, organization, management,provider payments, human resources, and such issues. Primarily for con-venience, the table combines demand-side issues with those dealing withsources of funds for the health sector. This chapter cannot deal with all thesereforms in great detail, but the table does present a fairly representative

Health Sector Reforms

53

Page 12: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

54

TAB

LE2.

2.Ty

polo

gyof

Sele

cted

Hea

lthSe

ctor

Refo

rms

Wha

tare

the

poss

ible

Refo

rmW

hati

sit?

cons

eque

nces

fore

quity

?Re

fere

nces

Supp

ly-s

ide

refo

rms

Com

mun

itypa

rtici

patio

n,m

onito

ring,

and

gove

rnan

ce

Sect

orw

ide

appr

oach

es

Defin

ing

and

prov

idin

g“e

ssen

tialp

acka

ges”

ofse

rvic

es

Man

agin

gth

e“p

urch

aser

-pro

vide

rspl

it”

Loca

lpar

ticip

atio

nin

the

desi

gnof

polic

y,he

alth

prom

otio

nan

dpr

even

tive

care

,res

ourc

em

obili

zatio

n,an

dre

sour

ceal

loca

tion

(ser

vice

deliv

ery)

,as

wel

lasm

onito

ring

toov

erco

me

agen

cypr

oble

ms.

Coor

dina

ted

polic

y-se

tting

amon

gag

en-

cies

,und

ergo

vern

men

tlea

ders

hip;

agre

edm

ilest

ones

and

targ

ets;

alls

up-

porte

dby

am

ediu

m-te

rmex

pend

iture

fram

ewor

k.

Form

alize

din

Wor

ldBa

nk(1

993)

;ide

nti-

fiesm

ost“

cost

-effe

ctiv

e”in

terv

entio

ns(d

efine

dby

aver

age

cost

s);d

oesn

otco

n-si

derm

argi

nalc

osts

.

Sepa

ratin

gth

epu

rcha

sero

fcar

efro

mth

epr

ovid

erof

care

;in

prin

ciple

,thi

sena

bles

com

petit

ion

amon

gpr

ovid

ersa

ndm

ini-

mize

sthe

ince

ntive

toov

ersu

pply

care

(and

indu

ceex

cess

cons

umpt

ion)

.

Posi

tive,

inpr

inci

ple,

with

the

cave

ats

that

loca

lins

titut

ions

are

vuln

erab

leto

capt

ure

bylo

cale

lites

and

that

loca

lrev

-en

uem

aybe

insu

ffici

ent,

ineq

uita

ble,

and

unsu

stai

nabl

e.

Depe

ndso

nth

eco

mpo

nent

soft

here

form

prog

ram

;suc

cess

fuls

ecto

rwid

eap

proa

ches

have

focu

sed

onco

nstra

ints

toth

eac

cess

and

cons

umpt

ion

ofse

r-vi

ces;

can

impr

ove

coor

dina

tion

acro

ssm

inis

tries

.

May

beef

fect

ive

forc

hose

nin

terv

en-

tions

,but

reso

urce

sare

ofte

nin

ade-

quat

e;do

esno

tdea

lwith

syst

emic

cons

train

ts;m

aybe

rigid

and

unre

spon

-si

veto

loca

lnee

ds.

The

grea

tere

ffect

will

be(in

prin

ciple

)on

effic

ienc

y.Th

edi

rect

effe

cton

dist

ribu-

tion

isne

utra

land

depe

ndso

nth

eex

tent

tow

hich

the

purc

hase

rcan

targ

etfu

nd-

ing

topr

o-po

orse

rvice

sorp

oorr

egio

ns.

Brin

kerh

off2

003;

Corn

wal

l,Lu

cas,

and

Past

eur2

000;

Geor

ge20

03;J

ohns

ton,

Faur

e,an

dRa

ney1

998;

Loew

enso

n20

00.

Fost

eran

dM

acki

ntos

h-W

alke

r200

1;Je

ffery

sand

Wal

ford

2003

.

Enem

arka

ndSc

hlei

man

n19

99;W

orld

Bank

1993

.

Gerd

tham

,Reh

nber

g,an

dTa

mbo

ur19

99;J

ack2

001a

;McP

ake

etal

.200

3.

Page 13: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

55

Dece

ntra

lizat

ion

Hum

anre

sour

cem

anag

emen

t,do

wns

izing

Reso

urce

allo

catio

n

Phar

mac

eutic

alsp

olic

yan

dm

anag

emen

tiss

ues

and

tech

nica

liss

ues

(fore

xam

ple,

the

cold

chai

n)

Phar

mac

eutic

als,

trade

-rela

ted

aspe

ctso

fin

telle

ctua

lpro

perty

right

s,an

dth

eW

orld

Trad

eOr

gani

zatio

n

This

isa

vast

topi

c,in

cludi

ngtra

nsfe

rring

the

man

agem

ento

fser

vice

prov

ision

,po

licyf

orm

atio

n,an

dre

venu

ege

nera

tion

tolo

calo

rreg

iona

laut

horit

ies.

This

refe

rsto

refo

rmso

fhum

anre

sour

cepo

licy,

asop

pose

dto

the

impa

ctof

refo

rmso

nth

ehe

alth

wor

kfor

ce.I

tin

clud

estra

inin

gan

dde

ploy

men

t,as

wel

lasr

educ

ing

the

wor

kfor

ce.

Argu

ably

aso

rely

negl

ecte

dis

sue

inhe

alth

refo

rms.

The

grea

terp

ortio

nof

heal

thbu

dget

sar

eal

loca

ted

tose

cond

arya

ndte

rtiar

yca

re,w

here

asth

epo

orco

nsum

ere

la-

tivel

ymor

epr

imar

ycar

e.

The

avai

labi

lityo

fmed

icin

es,e

spec

ially

vacc

ines

,iso

ften

ham

pere

dby

inad

e-qu

ate

lines

ofsu

pply

tolo

calc

linic

s,as

wel

lasb

ylea

kage

.

Trad

ean

dpa

tent

sare

the

subj

ecto

fhe

ated

deba

tean

dar

ege

nera

llybe

yond

the

scop

eof

the

min

istry

ofhe

alth

inm

ostc

ount

ries.

Mix

ed.G

reat

erlo

calr

espo

nsiv

enes

sis

posi

tive,

butr

equi

resl

ocal

adm

inis

tra-

tive

capa

city

;may

exac

erba

tere

gion

alin

equa

lityi

fins

titut

ions

are

wea

kand

ifre

venu

eis

base

dso

lely

onlo

calf

undi

ng.

Posi

tive

whe

nin

cent

ives

can

bede

sign

edto

enco

urag

egr

eate

rdel

iver

yof

serv

ices

toth

epo

or.C

anbe

nega

tive

ifm

oral

ean

dm

otiv

atio

nar

edi

min

ishe

d.Ca

refu

lcon

side

ratio

nof

wor

king

cond

i-tio

nsan

dth

ein

tere

stso

fthe

wor

kfor

cear

ees

sent

ial.

Impl

icat

ions

of“d

ualp

rac-

tice”

uncl

ear.

Reor

ient

atio

nis

gene

rally

pro-

poor

,but

itis

nots

uffic

ient

;con

sum

ptio

nam

ong

the

poor

isco

nstra

ined

byot

herf

acto

rs,

such

aslo

wqu

ality

.

Expa

ndin

gim

mun

izatio

nco

vera

ge(fo

rex

ampl

e,th

eex

pand

edpr

ogra

mon

imm

uniza

tion)

isge

nera

llypo

sitiv

e.

Deba

tabl

e.Ad

voca

tesa

rgue

that

pate

ntsi

ncre

ase

barri

erst

otre

atm

ent

amon

gth

epo

or.

Atki

nson

and

Hara

n20

04;B

osse

rt20

00;

Colli

ns,A

rauj

o,an

dBa

rbos

a20

00;

Gils

on19

98;J

üttin

get

al.2

004.

Bira

ndEg

gles

ton

2003

;Dus

saul

tand

Dubo

is20

03;F

errin

hoet

al.2

004;

Hum

anRe

sour

cesf

orHe

alth

.

Cast

ro-L

eale

tal.

2000

;Did

eric

hsen

2004

;Pea

rson

2002

.

Cain

esan

dLu

sh20

04;F

airb

anke

tal.

2000

;Gra

ce20

03;L

aing

,Hog

erze

il,an

dRo

ss-D

egna

n20

01;W

HO20

00b.

Baile

y200

1;Dr

uce

2004

;Lan

jouw

2002

,20

04.

( con

tinue

d)

Page 14: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

56

Regu

latio

nan

dsu

ppor

tof

priv

ate

sect

orpr

ovid

ers

Qual

itym

onito

ring,

cont

rol,

enha

ncem

ent

Publ

ic-p

rivat

epa

rtner

ship

s

Paym

ents

topr

ovid

ers:

ince

ntiv

e-an

dpe

rform

ance

-bas

edco

ntra

cts

Paym

ents

topr

ovid

ers:

capi

tatio

n

TAB

LE2.

2.Ty

polo

gyof

Sele

cted

Hea

lthSe

ctor

Refo

rms

(Con

tinue

d) W

hata

reth

epo

ssib

leRe

form

Wha

tis

it?co

nseq

uenc

esfo

requ

ity?

Refe

renc

es

The

maj

ority

ofca

reis

prov

ided

byth

epr

ivat

ese

ctor

;mos

toft

heca

reco

n-su

med

byth

epo

oris

priv

ate.

Poor

cons

umer

sare

affe

cted

atle

asta

sm

uch

byth

equ

ality

ofca

reas

byth

epr

ice.

Enga

ging

the

priv

ate

sect

orto

prov

ide

the

right

mix

ofse

rvic

esto

the

targ

etpo

pula

tion;

can

incl

ude

clin

ical

care

,as

wel

lasn

oncl

inic

alse

rvic

es.

Usin

gco

ntin

gent

cont

ract

sto

pay

prov

ider

s;th

ese

are

beco

min

gpo

pula

r,es

peci

ally

sinc

eth

eap

pear

ance

ofW

orld

Deve

lopm

entR

epor

t200

3(W

orld

Bank

2002

).

Popu

latio

n-ba

sed

paym

ents

topr

ovid

ers;

may

bew

eigh

ted

byde

mog

raph

icch

ar-

acte

ristic

sand

may

spec

ifyth

ese

rvice

sto

bepr

ovid

ed.

Mon

itorin

gis

vita

l,bu

texp

ensi

ve,e

spe-

cial

lyam

ong

unor

gani

zed

indi

vidu

alpr

ovid

ers.

The

poor

ofte

nus

ein

form

alor

even

illeg

alpr

ovid

ers,

who

may

play

impo

rtant

role

s,bu

treq

uire

train

ing.

Ther

eis

cons

ider

able

evid

ence

that

the

poor

will

resp

ond

toqu

ality

enha

nce-

men

tsev

enif

pric

esal

soris

e.

Can

bepo

sitiv

eif

ince

ntiv

esar

em

an-

aged

care

fully

.

Can

bepo

sitiv

eif

ince

ntiv

esar

ede

sign

edan

dm

anag

edca

refu

lly;c

anbe

used

tode

liver

targ

eted

orsu

bsid

ized

serv

ices

.

Can

incr

ease

acce

ssto

serv

ices

amon

gth

epo

or;m

usta

ccou

ntfo

rvar

iatio

nsac

ross

com

mun

ities

;the

reis

anin

cen-

tive

forc

ream

-ski

mm

ing

and

cost

-cu

tting

,sin

ceth

epr

ovid

er’s

profi

tist

here

sidu

albe

twee

nhi

scos

tsan

dth

eca

pi-

tatio

ngr

ant.

Benn

ett,

McP

ake,

and

Mill

s199

7;Ku

mar

anay

ake

etal

.200

0;M

illse

tal.

2002

;Sm

ith,B

rugh

a,an

dZw

i200

1.

Colli

er,D

erco

n,an

dM

acki

nnon

2002

;M

onta

gu20

03;M

wab

u,Ai

nsw

orth

,N

yam

ete

1993

;QAP

and

PAHO

2003

.

Cain

esan

dLu

sh20

04;E

ngla

nd20

02,

2004

;Liu

etal

.200

4;N

ieve

s,La

Forg

ia,

and

Ribe

ra20

00.

Barn

um,K

utzin

,and

Saxe

nian

1995

;Bi

trán

and

Yip

1998

;Egg

lest

onan

dHs

ieh

2004

;Jac

k200

1a;L

avad

enz,

Schw

ab,

and

Stra

atm

an20

01;L

eona

rd20

00;

Loev

inso

hn20

01,2

002;

Mac

eira

1998

.

Bitrá

n20

01;B

itrán

and

Yip

1998

;M

acei

ra19

98;T

elyu

kov2

001.

Page 15: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

57

Dem

and-

side

refo

rms,

sour

ces

ofre

venu

e

Sour

ceso

frev

enue

Gene

ralg

over

nmen

tre

venu

e,ta

xes

Prep

aym

ents

chem

es

Med

ical

savi

ngs

acco

unts

Insu

ranc

ean

dris

k-po

olin

gsc

hem

es

Form

alse

ctor

,em

ploy

men

tbas

ed

From

gene

ralg

over

nmen

trev

enue

such

asin

com

eta

xes,

valu

e-ad

ded

taxe

s,du

ties,

and

soon

;the

sem

aybe

ear-

mar

ked

forh

ealth

care

(fore

xam

ple,

ciga

rette

taxe

s).

Gene

ralt

erm

fors

chem

esin

clud

ing

insu

ranc

eth

atin

volv

eco

ntrib

utio

nsex

ante

;spe

cific

ally

,asc

hem

eto

payi

nad

vanc

efo

rser

vice

s.

Thes

ear

eno

tins

uran

ce;t

heya

rege

ner-

ally

self-

finan

cing

and

dono

tpoo

lris

ks.

Can

bepr

ivat

elyo

rpub

licly

man

aged

;co

ntrib

utio

nsus

ually

paid

thro

ugh

pay-

roll

dedu

ctio

ns.

Orga

nisa

tion

forE

cono

mic

Co-o

pera

tion

and

Deve

lopm

ente

vide

nce

that

tax-

base

dsy

stem

sare

mor

epr

ogre

ssiv

e.Th

elim

ited

taxb

ase

inm

ostc

ount

riesi

sin

adeq

uate

tofu

ndad

equa

tese

rvic

es;

dire

ctta

xesc

anbe

prog

ress

ive,

but

requ

irefu

nctio

ning

taxs

yste

ms;

indi

rect

taxe

sare

less

prog

ress

ive.

Inpr

incip

le,t

hesc

hem

esca

npr

otec

tpar

-tic

ipan

tsfro

mth

efin

ancia

lcon

sequ

ence

sof

care

forc

atas

troph

icev

ents

;the

ymay

exac

erba

tedi

ffere

nces

betw

een

parti

ci-pa

ntsa

ndno

npar

ticip

ants

.

No

pool

ing,

excl

ude

nonp

artic

ipan

ts;

cont

ribut

ions

may

be(re

gres

sive

ly)t

ax-

dedu

ctib

le;w

illca

use

insu

ranc

epr

emi-

umst

oris

e.

Excl

udes

peop

leno

tin

the

form

alse

ctor

;cr

oss-

subs

idiza

tion

ispo

ssib

le,b

utdi

fficu

lt.

Benn

etta

ndGi

lson

2001

;Bird

sall

and

Jam

es19

93;W

agst

affe

tal.

1999

;W

orld

Bank

1993

.

LaFo

rgia

1990

;Mac

eira

1998

;Sch

neid

eran

dDi

op20

01;S

chne

ider

,Dio

p,an

dBu

cyan

a20

00.

Hanv

orav

ongc

hai2

002;

Hsia

o20

01;

Hurle

y200

1;M

oon,

Nic

hols

,and

Wal

ls19

97;N

icho

ls,P

hua,

and

Pres

cott

1997

.

Abel

-Sm

ithan

dRa

wal

1994

;Ja

ck20

01b;

Kutz

in19

97.

( con

tinue

d)

Page 16: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

58

Cove

ring

the

info

rmal

sect

or

Soci

alhe

alth

insu

ranc

e(b

road

base

d)

Com

mun

ityhe

alth

insu

ranc

e(lo

cally

base

d)

TAB

LE2.

2.Ty

polo

gyof

Sele

cted

Hea

lthSe

ctor

Refo

rms

(Con

tinue

d) W

hata

reth

epo

ssib

leRe

form

Wha

tis

it?co

nseq

uenc

esfo

requ

ity?

Refe

renc

es

Prov

idin

gin

sura

nce

tope

ople

outs

ide

form

alem

ploy

men

t.Ex

trem

elyd

ifficu

ltto

doei

ther

asa

com

mun

ity-b

ased

ora

prov

ider

-bas

edsc

hem

e.

Serv

ices

are

paid

fort

hrou

ghco

ntrib

u-tio

nsto

ahe

alth

fund

,mos

tcom

mon

lyth

roug

hth

epa

yrol

l;en

rollm

entc

anbe

man

dato

ry.

Volu

ntar

y,no

npro

fitin

sura

nce

sche

me;

pool

sres

ourc

esan

dris

ks.

Evid

ence

that

prog

ram

sare

excl

usiv

ean

dno

tsel

f-sus

tain

able

;the

ymay

best

bead

ded

topo

verty

redu

ctio

npr

ogra

ms

orex

istin

gas

sist

ance

sche

mes

such

ascr

opin

sura

nce.

Deba

tabl

e:ad

voca

tesa

rgue

that

itpr

o-vid

esse

lf-su

stai

ning

,equ

itabl

epr

otec

-tio

n;de

tract

orsa

rgue

that

itex

acer

bate

sdi

spar

ities

betw

een

parti

cipan

tsan

dno

npar

ticip

ants

,tha

titm

ayno

tred

uce

out-o

f-poc

ketc

osts

,nor

incr

ease

acce

ss,

that

itre

quire

s“so

lidar

ity,”

man

ager

ial

capa

city,

econ

omic

grow

th,a

ndso

on(N

orm

and

and

Web

er19

94).

Prom

isin

g,bu

tmix

edre

sults

:can

pro-

vide

grea

tera

cces

sand

finan

cial

prot

ec-

tion,

and

loca

lcon

trolm

aym

inim

izem

oral

haza

rd,b

utsm

allfi

nanc

iala

ndris

kpoo

l,an

dth

epo

ores

tmay

still

beex

clud

ed;r

equi

rese

xter

nalf

undi

ng.

Benn

ett,

Cree

se,a

ndM

onas

ch19

98;

Gum

ber2

002.

Carri

n,De

smet

,and

Basa

za20

01;

Gertl

eran

dSo

lon

2000

;Jim

enez

1987

;N

orm

and

and

Web

er19

94.

Atim

1999

;Bin

am,N

kam

a,an

dN

kend

ah20

04;C

riel,

Van

derS

tuyf

t,an

dVa

nLe

r-be

rghe

1999

;Jak

aban

dKr

ishn

an20

01;

Prek

eret

al.2

002a

.

Page 17: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

59

Fees

fors

ervi

ce

User

fees

Unde

r-the

-tabl

epa

ymen

ts

Targ

etin

g:ta

riffs

,fe

ew

aive

rs

Hotly

deba

ted

topi

ctha

tmay

bem

issi

ngth

epo

int;

“fre

e”do

esno

tmea

naf

ford

-ab

le(th

ere

may

beun

der-t

he-ta

ble

pay-

men

ts),

and

dem

and

isco

nstra

ined

byot

herf

acto

rs,s

uch

asqu

ality

.

Paym

ents

requ

ired

ofcl

ient

sand

patie

nts,

inad

ditio

nto

offic

ialp

oste

dfe

es.T

hese

may

bein

form

al,n

egot

iate

dat

the

poin

tofs

ervi

ce,o

rhig

hlys

truc-

ture

d;th

eyus

ually

godi

rect

lyto

the

prov

ider

rath

erth

anth

efa

cilit

y.

Pric

edi

scrim

inat

ion:

char

ging

diffe

rent

pric

esto

diffe

rent

grou

ps;c

anbe

byfia

t(d

ecid

edby

anad

min

istra

torb

ased

once

rtain

char

acte

ristic

soft

here

cipi

ent)

orby

self-

targ

etin

g(w

here

byth

ere

cipi

-en

tdec

ides

whe

ther

toap

plyb

ased

onth

ech

arac

teris

ticso

fthe

good

orse

rvic

ebe

ing

prov

ided

).

The

poor

are

mor

epr

ice

sens

itive

than

the

rich:

mos

toft

heev

iden

cesu

g-ge

sts

that

user

fees

are

regr

essi

ve,b

utth

epo

orar

eal

som

ore

sens

itive

toot

herf

acto

rs.U

serf

ees,

plus

bette

rqu

ality

,can

incr

ease

utili

zatio

n.

Gene

rally

regr

essi

ve.B

oth

the

leve

lsan

dth

eun

certa

inty

ofpr

ices

disc

oura

geus

eof

serv

ices

amon

gth

epo

or.B

utth

ere

isev

iden

ceof

bette

rper

form

ance

and

high

erut

iliza

tion

amon

gpr

ovid

ers

who

char

geun

der-t

he-ta

ble

paym

ents

.

Subj

ectt

oty

pe-I

(inco

rrect

lyde

nied

)and

type

-II(in

corre

ctly

acce

pted

)erro

rs;

adm

inis

trativ

eta

rget

ing

isex

pens

ive,

requ

iring

mea

nste

stin

gan

den

forc

e-m

ent,

but,

inpr

inci

ple,

iten

able

smor

ere

sour

cest

ogo

toth

epo

or(o

roth

ergr

oups

)tha

ndo

unta

rget

edbe

nefit

s.

Abel

-Sm

ithan

dRa

wal

1992

;Ald

erm

anan

dLa

vy19

96;A

rhin

-Ten

kora

ng20

00;

Bitrá

nan

dGi

edio

n20

03;C

rees

ean

dBe

nnet

t199

7;Ge

rtler

and

van

derG

aag

1990

;Gils

on19

98;G

wat

kin

2003

;Kha

n20

05;L

awso

n20

04;L

itvac

kand

Boda

rt19

92;N

ahar

and

Cost

ello

1998

.

Bloo

m,H

an,a

ndLi

2001

;Cha

krab

orty

etal

.200

2;En

sor2

004;

Killi

ngsw

orth

2002

;Kill

ings

wor

thet

al.1

999;

Lew

is20

00;M

cPak

eet

al.1

999;

Vian

etal

.200

4.

Bitrá

nan

dGi

edio

n20

03;B

itrán

and

Muñ

oz20

00;C

haud

hury

,Ham

mer

,an

dM

urru

garra

2003

;Gel

bach

and

Pritc

hett

1995

.

( con

tinue

d)

Page 18: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

60

Vouc

hers

Othe

riss

ues

“Sca

ling

up”o

fpi

lotp

rogr

ams

Sour

ce:

Com

pile

dby

the

auth

ors.

TAB

LE2.

2.Ty

polo

gyof

Sele

cted

Hea

lthSe

ctor

Refo

rms

(Con

tinue

d) W

hata

reth

epo

ssib

leRe

form

Wha

tis

it?co

nseq

uenc

esfo

requ

ity?

Refe

renc

es

“Ent

itlem

ents

”to

the

purc

hase

orre

ceip

tofs

peci

ficse

rvic

es;h

asbe

enus

edfo

rgen

eral

heal

thse

rvic

esor

spe-

cific

good

s(fo

rexa

mpl

e,tre

ated

bed-

nets

)for

spec

ifict

arge

tgro

ups(

for

exam

ple,

sexu

ally

trans

mitt

edin

fect

ion

serv

ices

fors

exw

orke

rs).

Man

yhea

lthpo

licie

sare

draw

nfro

msu

cces

sful

pilo

tpro

gram

s,an

da

grea

tde

alof

atte

ntio

nha

sbee

npa

idto

the

prob

lem

sofr

eplic

atio

nan

dsc

alin

gup

tona

tionw

ide

leve

ls.

Gene

rally

posit

ive;c

anbe

expe

nsive

toes

tabl

ishan

dm

aint

ain;

impa

ctpa

rtly

depe

ndso

nco

paym

ents

;mus

tdea

lwith

the

issue

ofse

cond

arym

arke

ts;v

ouch

ers

seem

tope

rform

bette

rfor

spec

ificg

oods

and

serv

icesr

athe

rtha

nge

nera

lly.

Depe

ndso

nth

ebe

nefit

sand

char

acte

r-is

ticso

fthe

prog

ram

;inc

entiv

esan

dco

mm

itmen

tare

diffi

cult

tore

plic

ate;

mus

tbe

care

fult

oco

nsid

erin

crea

sing

mar

gina

lcos

ts.

Bitrá

nan

dGi

edio

n20

03;E

nsor

2003

;En

sora

ndCo

oper

2004

.

Berto

zzie

tal.

2001

;Joh

nsan

dBa

ltuss

en20

04;J

ohns

and

Torre

s200

5;W

yss,

Mot

o,an

dCa

llew

aert

2001

.

Page 19: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

selection of references—neutrally empirical, advocatory, or critical—towhich the reader can refer for more information. Below, we highlighttwo of the most commonly undertaken reforms: decentralization andcommunity-based health insurance.

In practice, reforms are generally not implemented independently orpiece by piece. They are often ambitious and far reaching, comprising abroad range of different actions. This has implications for the analysis,since it is difficult convincingly to identify the impact of components ofreform programs. Table 2.3 presents a few of these comprehensive reform

Health Sector Reforms

61

TABLE 2.3. Health Sector Reforms in Selected Countries

Country Reform Description

Zambia

Colombia

Chile

Czech Republic

Hungary

China

Sources: Berman and Bossert 2000; Tang and Bloom 2000.

Health financingand decentralization

Health financingand health delivery

Health financing,health insurance,and privatization ofservices

Health insuranceand privatization

Privatization, healthinsurance, anddecentralization

Health financingand devolution (in afew localities)

Initiated in 1991–2; involved significant decentralization todistrict health-management teams and health boards, theintroduction of user fees for publicly provided health ser-vices, and a nationally defined benefits package.

Started in 1993; included the establishment of social insur-ance schemes designed to allow managed competitionbetween public and private health insurance plans and thecontracting of both public and private providers for servicedelivery.

Started in early 1980s; involved the establishment of privateinsurance, the decentralization of primary health care, anduser charges in public health facilities.

Started in the early 1990s; covered the rapid privatization ofstate-owned public services, the creation of multiple state-linked and private health insurance funds, and the introduc-tion of a new payment mechanism and regulationorganization.

Included the privatization of primary care, the introductionof a centralized social insurance system, and decentraliza-tion of health facility ownership to the municipal level.

Driven by economic reform; involved the decentralization ofhealth services to local health centers, hospital financialautonomy, and the introduction of community medicalschemes with three-tier financing (central, local governmentmatching funds, and households).

Page 20: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

programs. The reforms in Chile, begun in the early 1980s, are typical ofsuch ambitious and comprehensive restructuring efforts (de la Jara andBossert 1995). This involved all the principal “control knobs” discussed byHsiao (2000): the creation of a private insurance system funded largelythrough social insurance contributions, the decentralization of primarycare facilities, the introduction of user charges and per capita payments,and new regulation regimes and new programs to alter health behavior andhelp address preventable conditions.6

Health reforms commonly include changes in health financing andchanges in health system organization and management. Changes in healthfinancing may involve cost recovery and user charges for publicly providedservices, community-based financing schemes, insurance schemes (socialand private), and changes in public expenditure and allocation. Changes inhealth system organization and management may entail decentralization(authority, responsibilities, and functions) and changes in the ownershipof service provision and delivery (privatization or a public-private mix).Here, two types of the more commonly implemented reforms are high-lighted: community-based health financing and the decentralization ofhealth services.

Community-based health financing

Community-based health financing broadly covers financing schemes thathave three key features: community control, voluntary membership, andprepayment for health care by community members (Hsiao 2004). It doesnot include compulsory regional or national social insurance plans.Community-based schemes have been implemented with increasing fre-quency since the early 1990s as a means to raise resources for health care,to overcome insurance market failures, and to promote the inclusion of thepoor (Table 2.4).

In most low-income countries, the scope for raising public revenue tofinance health services through general taxation is narrow.7 The amountthat can be allocated from the government budget to public health activ-ities is limited, and providing primary health care to all is not sustainablethrough general government revenue alone. Other avenues, such as fees forservice or some sort of prepayment, are required to raise the funds neededto provide care.

As noted in the section on issues specific to the analysis of healthreforms, information problems lead to insurance market failures in bothdeveloped and developing countries so that health insurance is insuffi-cient or even absent. Community-based health financing is seen by many

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

62

Page 21: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

as a powerful tool to extend health care coverage and financial protectionto a larger number of low-income households in rural or poor urbanlocalities by avoiding the problems associated, on the one hand, with com-prehensive social insurance and, on the other, with private insurance.8

Evidence suggests that community-based financing is effective inmobilizing resources for health care provision among the poor and that itcan spread risks and ease the burden associated with the high cost of illness.Still, such financing requires significant local capacity to implement andmonitor, and it is usually not self-sustaining: the local financing pool is toosmall to provide sufficient revenue to operate the financing independently(see, for example, Bennett, Creese, and Monasch 1998). In addition, thepoorest in the community are often excluded from the schemes, andwealthier households select themselves out, thus reducing the financingpool even further. It is important to note that, although community-basedfinancing has gained in popularity and exposure, there is rather little evi-dence of the impact. In a review of 45 studies of such schemes, Jakab andKrishnan (2001) find many examples describing the design and intent ofthe schemes, but very few systematic reviews of outcomes.

Health Sector Reforms

63

TABLE 2.4. Archetypal Community-Based Health Financing in Africa and Asia

Scheme Example

AsiaCooperative health care

Community-based third-party insurance

Provider-sponsored prepayment

AfricaCommunity health fund

Village insurance scheme

Community-financed health insurance

Sources: Hsiao 2004; Arhin-Tenkorang 2004.

Financing and provision are integrated at the village level (for example,China’s cooperative medical system)

Insurance plan; the insured pay a significant copayment when using localhealth services (for example, Sichuan province, China)

Insurance plan operated at local health facilities (for example, Dhakahealth card program)

Uses three financing mechanisms: user fees, insurance contributions,and government subsidies; decision about the use of funds is made atthe subdistrict level (for example, Tanzania community health fund)

Requires prepayment for essential drugs and the provision of primaryhealth care at the village level (for example, the Abota system in Guinea-Bissau)

Provider-insurance model; management and health care are provided byhospitals (for example, Nkoranza insurance scheme in Ghana)

Page 22: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Despite the limited amount of rigorous evidence of beneficial outcomes,there is no shortage of suggestions for the design of community-basedfinancing schemes. Advocates have proposed numerous modifications toenhance sustainability and performance. These include (1) targeted sub-sidies for the poorest, (2) reinsurance to enlarge the effective size of therisk pool, (3) improved prevention interventions, (4) technical supportto strengthen management capacity, and (5) strengthening links with for-mal financing and provider networks (Preker et al. 2002a, 2002b). Inaddition, community-based financing must take care to deal with (1) thelevels of the insurance premium, (2) moral hazard and adverse selection,(3) “covariant risks” (the phenomenon that health problems are corre-lated within a population), (4) community participation, (5) the qualityof care, (6) the referral system, and (7) cultural concepts of illness,among many other factors (Wiesmann and Jütting 2000). In addition,Jakab and Krishnan (2001) find that successful schemes take into accountthe nature of the incomes of the membership population, allowing mem-bers to pay premiums at irregular intervals and even through in-kindarrangements.

Community-based health financing is not a panacea. But broadbasedsocial insurance is not a viable option for a typical poor country with a lim-ited tax base and a small formal sector workforce, and private insurance isinsufficient to provide for poor and vulnerable groups. Expanding healthcare to underserved populations will most likely require community par-ticipation in resource mobilization and in the management of care.

Decentralization of health services

Like community financing, decentralization comes in many forms. Theterm is applied to myriad diverse policies, from increasing hospital auton-omy to local revenue generation. The impact of decentralization on thepoor depends to a large extent on what is being devolved, to whom, andunder which circumstances. The consequences of the decentralization of ser-vices are quite different from the consequences of the decentralization ofrevenues; empowering a local community group to monitor performanceis different from entrusting medical training to a regional government; alarge city will have a different set of management skills than a small ruralcouncil. It is also important to pay attention to the consequences of devo-lution for the management of the health system and the coordination ofhealth policy, and it is important to be concerned about the people who arenot in areas involved in the decentralization, as well as those who are insuch areas.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

64

Page 23: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Decentralization in health systems is justified on the basis that it willcorrect the information-related problems of agency and moral hazard dis-cussed in the section on issues specific to the analysis of health reforms. Inprinciple, local communities have better knowledge of local needs and con-ditions and can make better decisions if they are granted the authority tomanage resources and organize and supply health services. Decentraliza-tion promotes accountability and participation among the local popula-tion, makes health service providers accountable to the local community,and boosts the responsiveness of the providers to the local demand for ser-vices. Decentralization is expected to improve the efficiency, equity, andquality of health service delivery and management.

Decentralization has been widely implemented in Latin America sincethe 1980s, in Africa since the 1990s, and elsewhere (China, Eastern Europeand Central Asia) more recently, but the ambitious goals presented abovehave only rarely been realized. A recent study of 19 country cases (Jüttinget al. 2004) found that decentralization had “somewhat negative” or“negative” consequences for poverty and that all but one of the positiveperformers were middle-income countries.9 The study concluded that“one has to be very cautious in promoting decentralisation for povertyreduction.”

Decentralization will improve service delivery for the poor if the healthsystem and other services and infrastructure are already performing well.When conditions are favorable, local participation and control may well beused to improve both the performance and targeting of services. But if thereare problems with coordination and performance at the national level,decentralization may merely make things worse. Studies of the experienceof rural China (Tang and Bloom 2000) and Nigeria (Khemani 2004) foundthat there is little enforcement or accountability at the local level. Decen-tralization will not, by itself, solve problems of governance. It is unlikely thatlocal governments will function any better than national governments. Ifthe national health system is performing poorly, local health systems areprobably no better. Decentralization may simply reinforce local patronagesystems (Brinkerhoff 2000).

In their review of country experiences, Jütting et al. (2004) present alist of the factors they found to be correlated with successful, pro-poordecentralization. These include:

m sufficient and stable local financesm sufficient local human capital and managerial capacitym political commitment at the national level

Health Sector Reforms

65

Page 24: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

m donor supportm the free flow of informationm participation and accountabilitym policy coherence, especially between the national government and

donors

There is broad agreement that the constraints of poor governance andpoor performance must be dealt with before attempting decentralization.Atkinson and Haran (2004) found that, in Ceará, Brazil, good managementpractices led to successful decentralization rather than vice versa.

Any apparent association between decentralization and performance seems to bean artifact of the informal management, and the wider political culture in which alocal health system is embedded strongly influences the performance of local healthsystems (Atkinson and Haran 2004: 822).

STAKEHOLDERS

One of the primary obligations of the health sector in any country and amajor justification for reforms is that the system must be responsive tothe needs of citizens. This is generally taken to mean the clients—actualand potential—of health services. A quick review of the literature, on theother hand, suggests that most of the focus has been on the “humanresource” aspects of reform, that is, the impact of reform on health sec-tor workers. There is even a professional journal devoted exclusively tothis topic.10

Any policy change will affect different groups in different ways de-pending on their relationship to the sector, and reforms often reflectcompromise among various stakeholders. It is important to understandthat different stakeholders exercise different degrees of control and influ-ence over the reforms.

Table 2.5 presents a list of stakeholders, distinguishing between thoseon the supply side and those on the demand side of health care. Again, thedistinction is not perfect. Individuals can be both providers and consumersof services: employees of the local health ministry have children who needvaccinations and become ill. But it makes sense heuristically to considerthese as two separate groups. The doctor who is ill becomes a patient. Thehousehold that consumes health services is concerned with efficiency whenthe time comes to pay taxes. Below, two categories of stakeholders arediscussed in detail: health workers on the supply side and women on thedemand side.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

66

Page 25: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Health care workers

The attention paid to health workers in the design of reforms is not mis-placed. As noted in the section on issues specific to the analysis of healthreforms, one significant motivation for reform is to improve the efficiencyof service provision, and the behavior of providers is one of the key deter-minants of productivity. In addition, the response of providers is probablythe single most important ingredient in the success of reforms. So, it isnecessary to understand not only the role of the workforce in providingservices, but also to anticipate their response, to design incentives toencourage behavior that advances public health goals, and to engage theactive support of the workforce in implementing the reforms.

Reforms must deal with the factors that motivate health sector work-ers. To some extent, workers in the sector are driven by a genuine desire toimprove public health in general and the health of patients in particular.11

Reforms that engage providers by promoting issues and policies that pro-viders can “rally around” (Dussault and Dubois 2003) are more likely tosucceed. But providers are discouraged by low wages, inadequate resources,poor working conditions, and the general lack of support from govern-ments. Studies suggest that reforms have ignored these factors and thathealth sector workers resent being treated as “mere production tools”(Dussault and Dubois 2003). In spite of that rhetoric, health providers arenot so different from the rest of us. Notwithstanding the anecdotal evi-dence, more money does matter to health workers (see, for example, thecontracting studies cited in Table 2.2), but so do trust, autonomy, and pro-fessional recognition.

Health Sector Reforms

67

TABLE 2.5. Stakeholders in the Health Reform Process

Supply side Demand side

International donor agencies General population as consumersNational government WomenProvincial government Children and familiesCentral ministry of health ElderlyLocal ministry of health Ethnic and racial minoritiesOther ministries Poor householdsPublic sector providers Rural householdsPrivate sector providers Transhumant and migrant householdsInformal practitioners People living with HIV/AIDSDrug companiesInsurers, private and publicGeneral population as taxpayers

Source: Compiled by the authors.

Page 26: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

The unfortunate consequences for the poor of these human resourceissues are well known, but difficult to resolve. There are few incentives inplace to enhance service provision to poor, rural, or otherwise underservedcommunities. To improve the distribution of services, governments gen-erally combine the carrot and the stick, that is, incentives and compulsion.The health system can provide supplements to wages or other financialincentives, funding for travel, or assistance to families. The government canalso make certain services compulsory for medical graduates, as well aspaying them more, as is the case in China, India, and Indonesia (Chomitzet al. 1997; Hindu April 7, 2005).

Reforms, especially those that introduce competition, tighten moni-toring, or change payment regimes, will inevitably produce winners andlosers. Successful reforms will require political strategies to address the con-cerns of different groups of providers. Reforms that threaten job securityand incomes may lead—as they did in Zimbabwe—to strikes, theft, highturnover, and low morale among workers (Mutizwa-Mangiza 1998).

Finally, the AIDS epidemic is taking its toll among health workers.The perceived risk of contracting HIV is quite high among health work-ers, the demand for and complexity of care continue to outstrip the avail-able resources, and workers are confronted daily with wards full of dyingpatients.12 These factors contribute to stress and “burnout,” leading toincreased absenteeism and attrition (Aitken and Kemp 2003; Marchal, DeBrouwere, and Kegels 2005; Tawfik and Kinoti 2003; World Bank 1997b).The human and financial demands of the AIDS crisis reduce the resourcesthat might be otherwise available for expanded care for the poor.

Women as consumers of care

To some extent, treating women as a distinct and coherent categoryamong consumers is to obscure enormous differences among women.Clearly, women can be disaggregated by health status, geography, casteand ethnicity, wealth, and myriad other factors. However, even if they donot always speak with one voice, they arguably share concerns and con-straints in health care that are often neglected (Cornwall 2000). Men andwomen are often not treated equally even when they have commonhealth needs, and, when their health needs are different, these differencesare not addressed equitably (Mensch 1993; see also the papers cited inLakshminarayanan 2003a).

There are few empirical studies of the impact of reform on women,especially poor women, and this section derives primarily from anecdo-tal evidence and advocacy. But there are some regularities, even among

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

68

Page 27: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

the anecdotes. One common concern is the effect of user charges on poorwomen. Although there is little robust evidence on the impact of userfees, women may have less disposable income and less control over pur-chasing decisions within households (Nanda 2002). Reforms that pur-port to increase access to care by poor women must take into accountgender inequalities in purchasing power and decisionmaking.

Financial constraints are exacerbated where women do not havethe right to travel alone or to be in the company of men, includinghealth care providers, outside their immediate family. Where femalehealth workers are not available, women may be forced to go withoutcare. The opportunity costs of medical treatment may also be greaterfor a woman. If she becomes ill at harvest time, for example, there maybe no one who will take her place in the fields or at home. The visit toa health worker might thus impose unacceptable burdens on the house-hold (WHO 1998).

Women are the main health caregivers in the household. The firstoption for the treatment of children’s diseases such as malaria is hometreatment by the mother. The mother will buy over-the-counter med-ication, possibly on the advice of the shopkeeper, but lack of informationcan lead to ineffective treatment and accelerated drug resistance. A pilotstudy in Kenya found that training shopkeepers in appropriate drug usehad a large impact on both the use and the adequate dosing of chloro-quine (Marsh et al. 2004).

Women’s health services have focused on the reproductive needs ofwomen, especially contraception and safe childbearing, and the majorityof studies on the impact of reforms on women have also focused on theconsequences of reforms for reproductive health. These studies empha-size the importance of participation, openness, and flexibility in thereform process and in the management of health care, especially at thelocal level. They also emphasize the need to understand the constraintsfacing women and their consumption of health services (Futures GroupInternational 2000; Lakshminarayanan 2003b; Langer, Nigenda, andCatino 2000).

TRANSMISSION CHANNELS

In this section, we examine the way households are connected to thehealth sector and the mechanisms through which the impact of reformsis felt by stakeholders. The PSIA guidebook (World Bank 2003b) lists fivemain transmission channels: labor markets, prices, assets, access to goodsand services, and transfers and taxes. In health, there are a number of

Health Sector Reforms

69

Page 28: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

other factors through which the impact of reforms is experienced by thepoor. First, because health is often publicly provided, some decision mustbe made on which services the public health system will supply. Thisincludes determination of the “basic package” of services. Second, thedemand for services will greatly influence both the level and the efficiencyof supply. Third, the perceived quality of services is a major determinantof the consumption of services.

Table 2.6 presents a description of the major transmission channels.They are mostly supply side in that they transmit signals from producers toconsumers. However, the links from those paying for services to those whoproduce services may be thought of as a demand-side transmission, and, inaddition, the supply of services certainly responds to demand. The ultimatewelfare impact of a reform depends also on how households and con-sumers respond to changes in policy, supply, prices, and so on. These chan-nels do not operate in isolation: the effects of one (say, public-privateinteractions) will have an effect on others (for example, prices), and the dis-tributional impact of reform can be transmitted through all of them.

Defining the service package is a major task for policymakers. Thisinvolves setting priorities based on information about the current bur-den of disease of the population and choosing the most cost-effectivesolutions. It depends on changes in available health financing, whetherthrough fees for service, public health spending allocations, or insuranceschemes. Changes in health financing, meanwhile, also have a directimpact on the incentives offered to service providers and on consumerbehavior, which determines the level and distribution of health serviceprovision and use. The ownership structure of service provision anddelivery (private versus public, for instance) also has implications forhealth financing, as well as for the quality and equity of health services.

The health financing reform in Jamaica that involved a government-supported expansion of private insurance to the urban formal sector pro-vides a useful illustration of these transmission channels (Gertler andSturm 1997). The expansion of private insurance coverage can lead to areduction in public health expenditure by inducing those who are betteroff to switch to private providers. The insurance scheme will lower the out-of-pocket price of health care at the point of use by smoothing paymentsacross individuals and time, and it will reduce cost differentials betweenpublic and private providers. Both factors will encourage those covered bythe insurance to opt out of public care in favor of private care. Indeed,Besley and Coate (1991) demonstrate theoretically that, in a quality-based separating equilibrium, individuals above some income level chooseto purchase services from a higher-quality, higher-priced private sector,

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

70

Page 29: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Health Sector Reforms

71

TABLE 2.6. Health Reform Transmission Channels

Channel Impact on the poor

Labor markets

Public-private interactions

Finance and revenue

Risk-sharing and insurance

Transfers and taxes

Package of services

Prices

Assets

Reforms will have an impact on workers in the health sector. Ideally, reformswill allow health workers to focus effort and resources on health care for thepoor. But reforms will affect working conditions and motivation among workers.Some workers may be forced out if budgets are cut or if there is a drive forgreater efficiency; rules against theft and opportunistic behavior, including dualprivate practice, may be tightened. In most countries, there will be little impacton general employment.

Reforms are often intended to strengthen the private sector and provide incen-tives for private provision to the poor. These incentives are difficult to design,and public services may be more easily targeted. Conversely, increased publicprovision of services may crowd out private provision. Better regulation andtraining of private sector (especially informal) providers will enhance the qualityof services for the poor.

The cost of defined insurance contributions is clearly outweighed by the benefitsfrom participating in an insurance plan. The same is true for local communityinsurance and prepayment plans. Self-insurance is far more expensive thanalmost any risk-sharing arrangement. Finance and payment mechanisms will, in turn, influence provider behavior.

Risk-sharing, whether through community or social arrangements, allowsgreater coverage (of people and services) at lower cost than self-insurance.

Tighter targeting will increase type-I errors (false negatives); the general taxburden is usually borne by the middle and wealthy classes.

What services are to be included, whether provided publicly or paid for publicly,has a significant impact on the welfare of beneficiaries. Different populationshave different requirements: reproductive health, maternal and child health,treatment of infectious diseases, inpatient treatment, and so on, all have differ-ent constituencies. There is some discussion that the health system should pro-vide insurance (that is, pay for services) rather than provide the services directly.This reduces, but does not eliminate, the pressure to define the package.

As noted in Table 2.2, the poor are more price sensitive than are the non-poor,and, so, all else being equal, they will consume more if user fees are reduced oreliminated. But all else is not equal: prices can be a signal of quality, and thepoor are at least as sensitive to quality as to prices. In addition, opportunisticbehavior among providers means that “free” services are not truly free.

Health sector reform will have no effect on asset values. To the extent thatinsurance is extended to cover the poor, the poor will have less need toliquidate assets to cover health expenditures.

(continued )

Page 30: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Access to services

Quality

Demand

Source: Compiled by the authors.

while individuals below that level of income opt for the lower-quality,lower-priced public sector.

Private insurance can also affect the distribution of the services pro-vided. Public subsidies will shift away from curative care (consumed moreby the wealthy) toward preventive care, which disproportionately bene-fits the poor. However, private insurance can have deleterious effects onpublic services. As households that are more well off opt out of the pub-lic system, the support for improving public services may be considerablyeroded. When government initiatives to change health policy are politi-cally motivated and heavily influenced by the interests of those who aremore well off (as observed in many developing countries), policies suchas the promotion of private insurance plans for the more well off may, inthe long term, significantly worsen the welfare of poor households andincrease inequities due to wider quality differentials between the privateand the public services.

IMPLEMENTATION MECHANISMS

Two stages in the reform process are distinguished here: policy formationand policy implementation.

Policy formation

It is widely accepted that successful reforms are characterized by open-ness and consultation with the main stakeholders. Among the mostobvious stakeholders are clients, but also public and private sector pro-

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

72

Access is here defined in terms of physical distance to providers. Distance andthe time and cost required to cover distance can be more important than theprice charged for services. Expanding services can have a great impact onconsumption among the poor.

As noted in Table 2.2, the poor respond to quality, as well as to prices. Improve-ments in quality will encourage greater consumption of services.

Demand is key to the consumption of services and to health status. Understand-ing the determinants of demand and the constraints to greater consumption ofservices is an essential component in the design of pro-poor reforms.

TABLE 2.6. Health Reform Transmission Channels (Continued)

Channel Impact on the poor

Page 31: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

viders, including for-profit and nonprofit, charity, and nongovernmental-organization providers. This is because reforms are not merely technicalblueprints, but are value laden and frequently conflict ridden (Gilson1997). In other words, it is necessary to build collegial support for thereforms and to anticipate and deal with disagreements that might derailthe reform process.

There must be coordination among international and bilateraldonors and funders, as well as other ministries within the national govern-ment. This ensures that policies are consistent with medium-term plans,sectorwide approaches, the Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper, and thePoverty Reduction and Growth Facility.

There is often more talk about openness and consultation than there isactual openness, especially in the planning stage. In his study of participa-tion in Tanzanian reforms, Semali (2003) found that, although the processof policy formation was supposed to follow the guidelines for consultationestablished in World Development Report 1993 (World Bank 1993), theactual consultation consisted of meetings of Ministry of Health officials inWashington, a meeting of the “consultative group” of donors in Paris, andtwo workshops comprising ministry officials, donors, and the World Bank.13

Policies must also be internally consistent. For example, it is importantthat one set of policies does not encourage private sector providers toexpand services, while another set of policies simultaneously discouragesthem from expanding. While this seems obvious on paper, sectoral policiescan, in principle, be quite complex; to coordinate sectoral policies withthose of, for instance, the tax authorities or policies regulating small busi-nesses is even more difficult. In addition, the stated objectives of policyreform and the instruments proposed to achieve these objectives canappear to conflict, for instance, expanding private sector provision by tight-ening licensing restrictions (Gilson 1997).

Policy implementation

Successful reforms require a functioning and capable public sector at boththe national and local levels. This again raises the unfortunate point thatreforms—such as decentralization—cannot, in principle, be expected tosolve problems of governance and stewardship.

Similarly, the reforms must define the responsibilities of all partici-pants in the process. The government must have a clear conception of itsrole in the sector. This may simultaneously include the roles of policy-maker, regulator, purchaser, and, possibly, provider of health services.On the other hand, the public sector need not actually supply the services.

Health Sector Reforms

73

Page 32: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

The private sector dominates primary care provision in many countries,and many health ministries contract with private providers to deliver ser-vices to the poor (for example, Bangladesh, Mozambique, and Uganda).

The government must also have a firm commitment to achieving thegoals set out by the reform process. This includes the will and ability toprovide adequate funding. Policy statements and intentions are meaning-less unless sufficient resources are allocated to fulfill the required tasks.Similarly, public expenditures and, more importantly, changes in sectoralinstitutions and structures must be supported by an appropriate legal andregulatory framework. For example, if the reforms are intended to encour-age the participation of the private sector, the appropriate legal institu-tions should be established to define and protect both the rights and theresponsibilities of private providers in health (Kumaranayake et al. 2000;Mills et al. 2002).

A number of studies have highlighted the importance of paying atten-tion to the process of reforms and not merely the goals (Gilson 1997; Waltand Gilson 1994). It is not simply a matter of “knowing which directionto move in, but paying attention to how to get there: in essence, recog-nizing that policy implementation is as much a process as it is content”(Brinkerhoff 1996: 1395). Thus, it is important to develop a commonunderstanding, to build consensus for the reforms, and to obtain input andsupport from a wide and inclusive selection of government people (includ-ing politicians), health providers, and civil society (Aga Khan Health Ser-vices 2004). This requires openness and consultation not only during theimplementation, but during the process of policy formation as well.

TOOLS AND DATA FOR ANALYSIS

Once a potential set of reforms has been proposed to advance nationalhealth goals, a PSIA should aim to provide evidence to address the basicquestion posed at the beginning of this chapter: what is the potential wel-fare impact of the identified reforms across socioeconomic groups? Inparticular, how are disadvantaged households affected? As a requirementof PSIA, the identification of reform options is absolutely essential. In thissection, we discuss how distributional analysis can be conducted on anidentified policy change.

The choice of tools for analyzing the distributional impact on house-hold welfare of health sector policy changes is determined by four basicconsiderations:

m the nature of the policy changem the type of questions to be addressed

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

74

Page 33: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

m the available datam the constraints on time, resources, and analytical capacity

While the last two considerations are straightforward, the first tworequire some explanation. The policy itself will have an influence on thechoice of analytical method. In general, health is not a tradable good, so itis usually not necessary to resort to economy-wide models with externalaccounts (such as computable general equilibrium models). On the otherhand, if the reforms are broadly based, if they involve not only the healthsector, but also other sections of the economy, some understanding of thelink between health and (for instance) labor markets will be required. Inaddition, reforms will always have general equilibrium or multiplier effects,that is, any policy change will induce behavioral responses on both the sup-ply side and the demand side. These responses, in turn, will affect eachother: a change in finance policies will affect the demand for services, whichwill affect the supply of services, which will have further demand effects,and so on.

Second, the nature of the question to be asked will have an effect on themethods used. On one level, a policy analyst would like to examine the long-run consequences of reforms through all possible transmission channels andfor all groups. But this will clearly not be possible in practice, nor is it neces-sarily desirable in all cases. In practice, the policy analyst may be interestedin only one particular aspect of the reforms. For example, what are the directeffects of subsidized antiretroviral treatment on food consumption amonghouseholds in which someone is infected with HIV? This very narrow ques-tion can be examined through econometric analysis of household expendi-tures. Nonetheless, the analyst must be aware that an approach that is toonarrow might miss some important effects. In the case of antiretroviralmedication, treatment may improve the health of the person with HIV tothe extent that he can continue working or resume working, so that house-hold income increases. Or the burden of caring for the ill household mem-ber will be diminished, so that other members of the household can increasethe time they spend at school or in work. These factors might be missed bya narrowly defined and static econometric approach.

One can crudely distinguish the available analytical methods asquantitative and qualitative. A clear distinction between the two is noteasy to draw, although Bamberger (2000) provides a useful summary ofthe methods in terms of the selection of units of analysis, the researchprotocol, and data collection. When time and data permit, a combina-tion of the two methods (that is, “mixed” methods) is preferable. Quali-tative methods can provide hypotheses to be tested by the quantitative

Health Sector Reforms

75

Page 34: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

methods, and the qualitative methods also supply a way of validating theresults of the rather more abstract quantitative methods.

The following discussion centers on four topics: the choice of out-come indicators, data and sources, qualitative methods, and quantitativemethods.

Choice of indicators

There are two factors to consider in the choice of indicators. Recalling thediscussion in the section on issues specific to the analysis of healthreforms, these can be thought of as “the distribution of what?” and “whatdistribution?” First, what dimension of outcomes are we interested in?Do we care about the distribution of health status or about the distribu-tion of the financial burden of illness? Second, how do we measure thedistribution of this outcome? The two issues are discussed here in turn.

The distribution of what?

How do we define and measure the changes in welfare among householdsor individuals because of health policy changes? Sen’s (1984) capabilityapproach has led to the recognition that welfare is multidimensional, sothat human capital outcomes, such as those in health and education, arevalid measures of welfare, as much as consumption and income. In thehealth literature, indicators such as child mortality, morbidity, life ex-pectancy (often adjusted for disability), and self-reported health statusare the most widely used.

Understanding the impact of health policy changes is complicated bya number of factors. First, as noted in the section on issues, health out-comes are determined by factors both inside and outside the health sector.14

Second, health status is a lagging indicator of health investments and poli-cies. The impact of health policy changes on health outcomes will only bemanifest after some time even in the case of major policy changes. Third,self-reported health status indicators are often not independently reliable:they are determined partly by expectations and sensitivity to illness, whichvary systematically with factors such as income. The poor are less likelythan the more well off to report sickness. The poor are not healthier thanthe rich, but they are more likely to underreport, partly because they areless able to do anything about it (Schultz and Tansel 1997; Strauss andThomas 1998).

These complications leave two options for analysis. The first is tochoose a set of “proximate determinants” of health outcomes, that is, nothealth outcomes per se, but the factors that are closely (preferably causally)

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

76

Page 35: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

correlated with health outcomes. These include measures of the access toand utilization of health services, the incidence of public spending, and thedegree of financial protection represented by various health financingprograms. Second, the analysis can examine indicators of process. Sincereforms are time consuming and since the impact of reforms will notbe observed in health outcomes for even longer, choose indicators ofthe direction and progress made in the implementation of the reforms.Table 2.7 lists a range of possible indicators of both outcomes and process,but organized more thematically, that is, as measures of access, quality, out-puts and outcomes, and finance and sustainability.

Again, this is not an exhaustive list, and some (especially the outcomevariables) may be only tenuously related to the short-term consequencesof reforms. In brief, access refers to the absence of barriers to receiving care,including prohibitive costs; quality refers both to the quality perceived by

Health Sector Reforms

77

TABLE 2.7. Indicators of Health Sector Reforms

Access Outputs and outcomes

Proximity to services: distance, time, costPrimary services, hospitalPharmacy, dispensary, drug shop

Hours of service, primary careOut-of-pocket service cost, inpatient and outpatient

Medical and drug costs“Hotel” costsFee schedule: targeted tariffs, waiversUnder-the-table fees, gratuities

Waiting times for outpatient servicesWaiting lists for inpatient services

Finance and sustainability

Household levelFinancial protection, household expendituresSpending on regular and catastrophic care

Sources of financeShare from taxes, fees for service, and so onIncidence of payment for services

ExpendituresOut of pocketInsurance premiums and copaymentsInsurance coverageIncidence of expenditures

Source: Adapted from Hutton 2000, Table 1.

UtilizationImmunization coverageSupervised deliveriesOutpatient visits, inpatient days

Facility performance criteriaIncidence, morbidity, and mortality

MalariaHIV/AIDSDiarrheal diseasesMaternal and postpartum healthMalnutrition

Demographic indicatorsTotal fertility rateCrude birth and death rate

Quality

Staff: number and qualificationsAvailability of equipment and suppliesProtocols: whether they exist and are followedCleanlinessSupervisionClient satisfactionClient participation in governance, monitoring

Page 36: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

the clients and to the technical, medical quality of the care provided; out-puts and outcomes are combined here and include the volumes of servicesprovided (from the supply side) and population-level and household-levelindicators; finance and sustainability also encompass both systemwide andhousehold-level variables, including financial protection among house-holds and sources of finance for the system.

What distribution?

The most commonly used measure of equity in public services is benefitincidence, that is, how much of a given benefit (or cost) accrues to whichfraction or group within the population.15 The usual practice is to rank thepopulation by some welfare measure, such as income, and then ascertainthe value of public benefit that each member of the population receives.Evaluation of the incidence of health care finance requires examination ofall sources of health sector funding, not only the direct payments that aremade exclusively for health care. In addition to out-of-pocket payments,health insurance contributions, and earmarked health taxes, the distribu-tional burden of all direct and indirect taxes may be examined where thesecomprise a significant part of total health sector revenue.

Alternatively, one can calculate the concentration index, which is asummary measure describing benefit incidence. The advantage of theindex is that one can also easily compute standard errors, which permitrobust comparisons of statistically significant differences across classes ofindividuals or households.

One important advance is the computation of marginal benefit inci-dence analysis.16 This is used to examine the distribution of the marginalcosts and benefits of program expansion across different incomegroups. This is a more informative measure than average benefit inci-dence, since policy changes often involve the scaling up of existing pro-grams. Recent research indicates that the benefits of public programscan be initially captured by the non-poor, but that the poor will bene-fit more as a program is expanded. For example, the rich may demandpayoffs in return for their taxes to cover a social program’s start-upcosts, and only once the program has expanded (and the marginal costsof program expansion have been lowered) will it be politically feasiblefor the government to concentrate services in poor, remote areas (seeLanjouw and Ravallion 1999).

Data

The data required for the distributional analysis of health reform dependmainly on the nature and scale of the policy change, the question to be

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

78

Page 37: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

addressed, and the choice of methods. Lindelöw and Wagstaff (2003)offer a comprehensive review of the data sources commonly used inhealth analysis. Only a selection of the more widely available data are dis-cussed here.

Demographic and Health Survey (DHS)

These surveys are among the most widespread sources for data on healthstatus and policy. Funded by the U.S. Agency for International Develop-ment, nearly 200 of these household-level surveys have been collectedsince 1985 (see http://www.measuredhs.com). The DHS attempts to becomparable across countries and over time and includes a wide range ofindicators, such as basic household characteristics, fertility, child nutritionand health status, access to environmental services (safe water, sanitation,and electricity), and utilization of basic health and education services. Atypical DHS collects detailed information on reproductive history, edu-cational attainment, knowledge about common childhood illnesses, HIV/AIDS, and sexually transmitted infections, as well as knowledge about thetreatment of these illnesses. The DHS is useful for assessing health knowl-edge and practices, health status, and the consumption of health services.

One of the limitations of the DHS data is that they include only verylittle information on wealth and generally no information on income andexpenditure. This information is traditionally used for measuring livingstandards and is essential for distributional analysis. A number of recentstudies using DHS data have constructed a wealth index as a proxy measureof living standards in order to address distributional issues (see, for exam-ple, Filmer and Pritchett 1998).

The surveys and the methods are being continually updated andexpanded; for example, surveys of providers are now being conducted.These facility-based provider surveys gather information on health servicedelivery, including quality, infrastructure, utilization, and availability, andcan be linked to household surveys in order to identify relationshipsbetween behavior and outcomes on the household side and the supply ofhealth services.

Living Standards Measurement Study (LSMS)

More than 50 LSMS surveys have been conducted in low-income coun-tries to measure levels and changes in living standards. These are largeand comprehensive household surveys that collect rich information onsocioeconomic characteristics, especially on household consumption andincome. They frequently include health modules to gather information on

Health Sector Reforms

79

Page 38: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

the health status of household members, service utilization, and accesscosts. The LSMS surveys that have an added health module are useful datasources for analyzing the impact of health policy changes (for example, usercharges, health financing programs, or publicly financed health projects)on health demand, as well as for the distributional impact analysis of pub-lic spending.

For some, the LSMS and DHS datasets (which are narrow, but deep)can be combined with census data (which are broad, but shallow) to pro-duce maps of poverty, health status, and access to services and infrastruc-ture. The availability of such tools at the disaggregated level can be valuablein helping policymakers target poor localities accurately. Elbers, Lanjouw,and Lanjouw (2003) have developed a methodology to combine census andhousehold-survey data to create reliable district-level poverty maps. Anongoing research project at Macro International (http://www.orcmacro.com) is exploring the possibility of replicating the methodology to producemaps on key health indicators. Similar work is being conducted elsewhere.Fujii (2003), for example, has developed anthropometric maps using DHSand census data on Cambodia.

Other household-level data sources

Other agencies conduct internationally comparable and valuable surveys,sometimes with a health focus. For example, the Multiple Indicator Clus-ter Surveys sponsored by the United Nations Children’s Fund focus onwomen and children; about 50 country reports are available. Hundredsof other household surveys are conducted throughout the world everyyear, usually in an ad hoc fashion. There are periodic attempts to stan-dardize and codify survey methods. The Paris 21 Initiative, for instance,was established by the United Nations to develop survey techniques andto build a “culture of evidence-based policymaking” (see http://www.paris21.org). The World Bank’s Africa Household Survey Databank con-tains more than 400 surveys, and surveys are available for other regionsas well.

Quantitative service delivery surveys and Public Expenditure Tracking Surveys

Quantitative service delivery surveys focus on the service facility and fac-tors affecting quality of services. It is a technique for surveying serviceproviders, resource availability, and performance. Public ExpenditureTracking Surveys measure problems in the budget execution process, suchas leakage, delays, and the reallocation of resources, but they can also be

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

80

Page 39: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

used to examine incentives for service providers and the quality and quan-tity of services. These two are often linked, and the distinction betweenthem is becoming smaller. About 30 of these two types of surveys had beencarried out by the Bank and its clients as of early 2005 (see Dehn, Reinikka,and Svensson 2003).

Experimental and quasi-experimental data

Rigorous evaluation of the impact of a specific health intervention mayrequire data collected from a policy experiment. This is because theimpact of an intervention can be affected by factors that are impossibleto disentangle exclusively through ex post evaluation. For example, a pro-gram may be put in a particular place for reasons that also affect the pro-gram’s outcomes. If we were only to look at outcomes, we would beunable to determine the impact of the program and the impact of theseother factors.17

Experimental analysis is complex and generally expensive; it requiresboth baseline and follow-up data, preferably including supply-side (healthfacility) and demand-side (household) surveys. However, surveys to ana-lyze policy experiments generally use simpler instruments on smaller sam-ples relative to the DHS or LSMS, especially if the intervention is a pilotprogram. See the section on quantitative methods hereafter for a morecomplete description of the method.

Qualitative data

Qualitative data differ from survey or experiment data because of the for-mat of the data and the process through which the data are generated (see,for example, Chung 2000). For instance, focus-group interviews are oftenconducted during small meetings using open-ended questions about a spe-cific topic. The information collected is often contextual and providesinsights about the process and implementation of the reform program thatare particularly valuable for confirming an evaluation based on experimentor survey data. See the section on analytical methods below for a morecomplete description.

National health accounts

National health accounts describe in great detail all the sources and usesof funds and other resources within the health system, private and pub-lic. These are an excellent source of information on the functional classi-fication of the sources and the allocation of expenditures; they less often

Health Sector Reforms

81

Page 40: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

disaggregate the information by income or other household categories.National health accounts have so far been prepared for about 75 countries.Since 1999, the World Health Organization has been undertaking a sys-tematic exercise to develop health expenditure data for all its 191 memberstates, based on the United Nations System of National Accounts (seeWHO 2003).

Analytical methods

The methods used to examine the consequences of health reforms (or anyreforms) are often distinguished as either qualitative or quantitative. Inmany ways, this is a false and unproductive dichotomy. Faute de mieux, wemaintain this distinction and discuss a few of the methods in detail.

Qualitative methods

“Qualitative methods” generally refers to the use of case studies and in-depth, open-ended interviews and discussions to analyze the distribu-tional impact of health reforms. The methods most commonly mentionedin the literature include social impact analysis, participatory beneficiaryassessments, and stakeholder analysis. Each of these methods is de-scribed in A User’s Guide to Poverty and Social Impact Analysis (WorldBank 2003b).

One major strength of qualitative methods is that they provide a muchdeeper understanding of the processes underlying policy implementation,including the interactions among the various stakeholders, than can beelicited in a structured, impersonal questionnaire. This information is crucial for gauging the benefits and costs of a reform for different stake-holders. It can offer valuable insights into the reasons for the failure or success of a reform program in reaching the intended objectives. Findingsfrom studies using this approach can also supply information that can beapplied to improve the design of household surveys and interpret theresults of quantitative analyses. It can also be employed to validate the out-comes of quantitative analysis.

For the analysis of the distributional impact of policy reform, thesequalitative methods have a few limitations. First, they cannot quantify thewelfare gains or losses due to a health policy change. Thus, they are notvaluable as guides in the design of explicit compensation measures to mit-igate any adverse impact (that is, the “willingness to pay” or “willingness toaccept” a sum as equivalent to the welfare change caused by the policy).Indeed, very few empirical studies that use the qualitative method havetouched upon the distributional aspect of reform. Two empirical examples

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

82

Page 41: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

of attempts to use qualitative methods to address equity issues are Bossert(2000), on the decentralization of health system organization in Bolivia,Chile, and Colombia, and Tang and Bloom (2000), on health servicedecentralization in rural China.18 Second, findings from the qualitativeapproach are not usually generalizable; they are strongly dependent onlocal conditions (indeed, that is a strength of the method). This means thatit is more difficult to apply the lessons learned in one case to another caseand that any attempt to do so must carefully account for these differencesin local conditions.

Table 2.8 summarizes several studies that have used qualitative toolsto evaluate health reforms.

Quantitative methods

The majority of PSIA cases will involve some quantitative analysis. Thisis not to say that the information produced by these tools is always prefer-able to the information derived from the qualitative methods discussedabove. In fact, the richest and most robust story will derive from mixedmethods.19 In this section, two of the quantitative methods are describedthat are commonly used to examine the distributional impact of healthreforms. These are conventional econometric welfare analysis and experi-mental evaluation. These are illustrated in greater detail in A User’s Guideto Poverty and Social Impact Analysis (World Bank 2003b).

The first method, econometrics, derives from a model of householdwelfare in which welfare (utility) is determined by health status and theconsumption of other goods and services. Health outcomes, in turn, aremodeled through a “production function,” with individual, household,community, and other characteristics as inputs. Households maximizeutility, subject to a budget constraint, by choosing the optimal combina-tion of health services and other goods. From this solution can be deriveda (“reduced-form”) health-demand equation that can be estimated empiri-cally as a function of prices and individual, household, and communitycharacteristics.

A regression of the health-demand function using information com-monly collected through household surveys and health-facility surveysprovides an estimation of the marginal impact of policy changes. For ex-ample, the demand equation can be used to examine the impact of changesin user fees, improved access to health facilities, changes in quality, or anyother quantitatively measurable policy change.

There are three main advantages to the econometric welfare ap-proach. First, this method has a strong theoretical foundation, including

Health Sector Reforms

83

Page 42: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

84

TAB

LE2.

8.Q

ualit

ativ

eA

naly

sis

ofH

ealth

Sect

orRe

form

s

Refo

rmca

ses

Tool

sDa

taso

urce

sEx

ampl

esCo

mm

ents

Expa

ndin

gth

ero

leof

the

priv

ate

sect

or

Phar

mac

eutic

alpo

licy

refo

rm

Dece

ntra

lizat

ion

ofhe

alth

serv

ices

Dece

ntra

lizat

ion

ofhe

alth

serv

ices

Sour

ce:

Com

pile

dby

the

auth

ors.

Stak

ehol

der

anal

ysis

,ins

titu-

tiona

land

polit

i-ca

lana

lysi

s

Polit

ical

eco-

nom

ymod

els

Inst

itutio

nal

anal

ysis

Stak

ehol

der

anal

ysis

Focu

s-gr

oup

inte

rvie

ws

Case

stud

ies

Adm

inis

trativ

eda

taon

publ

iche

alth

faci

litie

san

dut

iliza

tion,

focu

s-gr

oup

inte

rvie

ws

Focu

s-gr

oup

inte

r-vi

ews,

case

stud

ies

Gonz

ález

-Ros

setti

and

Boss

ert

(200

0)on

Chile

,Col

ombi

a,an

dM

exic

o

Reic

h(1

995)

onph

arm

aceu

tical

polic

yref

orm

inBa

ngla

desh

,the

Phili

ppin

es,a

ndSr

iLan

ka

Tang

and

Bloo

m(2

000)

onru

ral

heal

thse

rvic

ede

cent

raliz

atio

nin

Chin

a

Boss

ert(

2000

)on

dece

ntra

liza-

tion

inBo

livia

,Chi

le,a

ndCo

lom

bia

Iden

tifies

stak

ehol

ders

,the

irin

terp

lay,

thei

rpo

tent

ialt

oin

fluen

ceth

epr

oces

s,an

dth

est

rate

-gi

esus

edby

refo

rmer

sto

purs

uere

form

s.

Exam

ines

the

polit

ical

dyna

mic

sofh

ealth

sect

orre

form

thro

ugh

aco

mpa

rativ

est

udyo

fpha

rma-

ceut

ical

polic

yref

orm

inth

ree

coun

tries

.

Focu

seso

nth

eim

pact

ofth

ede

volu

tion

ofhe

alth

serv

ices

onhe

alth

serv

ice

perfo

rman

ce.T

hefin

d-in

gsin

dica

teth

atat

tem

ptst

oim

plem

entr

apid

dece

ntra

lizat

ion

with

outa

ddre

ssin

gth

efin

anci

alan

din

stitu

tiona

lcap

acity

oflo

calg

over

nmen

tsca

nha

vene

gativ

eco

nseq

uenc

es,a

sillu

stra

ted

byth

eCh

ina

case

stud

y.

The

findi

ngsi

ndic

ate

that

dece

ntra

lizat

ion

seem

sto

impr

ove

utili

zatio

nan

deq

uity

inhe

alth

expe

n-di

ture

over

time

inbo

thCh

ilean

dCo

lom

bia.

InBo

livia

,the

impa

ctof

dece

ntra

lizat

ion

depe

nds

onlo

cali

nstit

utio

nalc

apac

ity.

Page 43: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

a clearly defined concept of welfare, which provides an analytical base forconducting distributional impact analysis. It is generally agreed whatthese methods measure, and the results are therefore comparable acrossstudies and settings. Second, the method allows us to examine the mar-ginal impact rather than the average impact of a policy change, that is, wecan see the incremental value of the next dollar spent on a particular pol-icy, rather than of the average dollar spent. This is important becausethere is no reason to believe that the impact of the next dollar will resem-ble the impact of an average dollar.20 Third, this method can provide abasis for policy simulations of various reform scenarios. In other words,we can use these results to ask “what if?” for any number of changes topolicy or social and environmental conditions. This can be extremelyuseful in designing policies and projecting the consequences of reforms.

The disadvantages to this approach revolve mainly around the fact thatthe reliability of the empirical results depends crucially on data quality andthe correct specification of the health-demand function. Unfortunately,obtaining good data is difficult, and perfect data may be impossible to col-lect. Microbehavior is driven partly by nonmonetary costs and benefits,which are very hard to measure (Das and Hammer 2004). Analysis of themicrolevel impact of health reforms therefore requires data that we cannothave or for which we must rely on imperfect proxies. In addition, the resultsare often driven by methods rather than by the data or by the question thatneeds to be answered. Different methods can yield different results. Pleasenote that this does not mean that all econometric methods are equallysuspect: differences may reflect problems in one method that can be cor-rected by another.

Addressing the misspecification of the health-demand function posesother formidable challenges to the analysis. The econometric evaluationof program impact suffers from the problems of omitted variables gen-erally and endogeneity and sample selection problems specifically. Forexample, the impact of a child health intervention will depend on themotivation and behavior of the household in which the child lives. Chil-dren whose mothers are more able and willing to seek public health ser-vices and follow advice on the prevention of illness and disease are morelikely to experience better child health outcomes. These households arealso more likely to participate in government-promoted health programs.A naive evaluation runs the risk of ascribing to the intervention the bene-fits to the child of having a motivated mother. This problem would beminimized if we could measure the mother’s motivation, but these vari-ables (ability, knowledge, and willingness of mothers) are not directlyobservable.

Health Sector Reforms

85

Page 44: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

These problems (omitted variables, sample selection, and measure-ment error) can yield misleading conclusions. Thus, the estimated coeffi-cients of the health-demand function cannot be interpreted as a causaleffect (that is, health policy changes generate changes in health outcomes);at best, they imply associations between the two sets of variables. Policydesigns based on a misspecified health-demand function could produceserious, unintended welfare consequences. The push for introducing userfees to finance improvements in health services in developing countries inthe 1990s provides a good illustration of the way invalid empirical resultscan bring about adverse welfare consequences. Box 2.1 presents a summaryof studies on user fees and their impact on policy design.

Two econometric strategies can potentially correct the model-specification problem, but both are very data demanding. First, when paneldata are available, taking the first difference of the demand function elim-inates the time-invariant unobserved confounding factors. In practice,panel data are rare and expensive to collect, and they do not exist for manycountries. Second, when selection into a program is unobserved, it is pos-sible, in principle, to estimate the impact of the intervention using instru-

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

86

BOX 2.1 Econometric Research on User Charges

Early work on user charges was based on a regression framework of the health-demand func-tion. This research found that prices were not an important determinant of demand, the rele-vant coefficients generally showing up as statistically insignificant or even positive in sign(Akin et al. 1984, 1986; Birdsall and Chuhan 1986; Heller 1982; Schwartz, Akin, and Popkin1988).

Subsequent research indicated that the earlier results were mainly due to poor data qualityand the misspecification of the estimation equation (Feldstein 1974; Gertler and van derGaag 1988, 1990). More recent studies have found that prices are an important determinantof health demand in developing countries, with statistically significant negative price elas-ticities (Alderman and Gertler 1989; Cretin et al. 1988; Gertler, Locay, and Sanderson 1987;Mwabu 1986).

The policy implications and the potential welfare impact of user charges derived from theabove two sets of research are clearly divergent. However, the understanding that the poorare price sensitive does not by itself imply that services should be provided free or at subsi-dized prices. The weight of empirical studies to date suggests that the benefits of subsidieswill flow primarily to those who are better off rather than to the poor for whom the servicesare intended (Gwatkin 2003). Moreover, there is substantial evidence that consumers pay sig-nificant out-of-pocket charges for nominally “free” services (see, for example, Khan 2005).

Page 45: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

mental variables. This requires the identification of a variable that deter-mines the household’s decision to participate in the program, but is notindependently correlated with health outcomes. Valid instrumental vari-ables are difficult to find. To some extent, good knowledge about programplacement and implementation can help in identifying potential instru-mental variables (see Baker 2000).

Table 2.9 presents a few examples of the use of quantitative econo-metric methods to simulate the impact of policies on health outcomes. Thisis clearly only suggestive: the list of references to this chapter and, indeed,most of the citations in Table 2.2 provide many examples of the use ofquantitative econometric methods. Some of the studies presented inTable 2.9 are conducted ex ante, that is, prior to the introduction of policychanges, and some are conducted ex post, that is, following the policychanges. But they all share the same basic method, whereby demand param-eters are derived econometrically, and then these are used to simulate theimpact of the proposed policy change on behavior.

The search for solutions to the problems associated with cross-sectional econometric evaluation methods has led to the increased use ofexperimental and quasi-experimental techniques, especially to control forbias caused by nonrandom sample selection. These techniques are basedon a simple comparison of differences between (usually two) subsamplesdrawn from the same population, one of which has received an interven-tion, while the other has not. In the scientific jargon, the first group is thetreatment group, and the second is the control. The control group playsthe role of counterfactual, permitting policy analysts to see what would havehappened if the reform had not taken place.

There are two main strands to this literature, which can be distin-guished by the underlying basis for the comparison between the treatmentand control groups. In the first, the control group is selected ex post; in thesecond, the control and treatment groups are selected ex ante. Each isbriefly described hereafter, and a few examples are presented.

The first method is often referred to as “quasi-experimental” evalua-tion and consists primarily of variants of matching methods. This involvescreating the control group ex post, that is, from a sample that contains bothtreatment and control individuals (or households); one then selects thesubsample of untreated individuals who most closely resemble the treatedindividuals. This is most commonly done by the method of propensity-scorematching (see Cochrane and Rubin 1973; Rosenbaum and Rubin 1983).The propensity score is an estimate of the probability that any individual(treated or untreated) will receive the treatment, as a function of the indi-vidual’s observed characteristics. Each treated individual is then matched

Health Sector Reforms

87

Page 46: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

88

TABLE 2.9. Quantitative (Econometric) Studies of Health Sector Reforms

Case Reference Tools Comments

Introduction of user charges in Peru

Distribution of government spending on education in India

Determinants of health care demand in Uganda

Placement of doctors in rural areas of Indonesia

Social insurance in Hungary

Community-based health insurance in Senegal

Government subsidies for a health insurance program in Egypt

Source: Compiled by the authors.

Gertler, Locay, andSanderson 1987

Lanjouw and Ravallion 1999

Lawson 2004

Chomitz et al. 1997

Ravallion, van deWalle, and Gautam 1995

Jütting 2001

Yip and Berman 2001

Demand elasticitiesfrom the reduced-form health-demandfunction

Marginal benefit inci-dence analysis

Reduced-form health-demand functions fordifferent segments ofthe population

Estimation ofrevealed preferenceand stated preferencefor location choices ofphysicians

Simulations of thedistribution of con-sumption over time

Estimation of theimpact of participationon consumption andfinancial protection

Estimation of theimpact of a school-based health insur-ance program onconsumption andfinancial protection

The poorest two quintiles aremore price sensitive than areother quintiles.

Marginal incidence is significantlyhigher among the poor than it isamong the non-poor, and mar-ginal incidence among the poor ismuch higher than average inci-dence among the poor.

Reducing travel time willincrease the consumption ofhealth care among all; reducinguser fees will encourage con-sumption by women.

Compensation and bonuses arelikely to be more effective thancompulsory postings, and morestudents from rural areas shouldbe encouraged to train.

Cash benefits introduced to com-pensate for other policy reformsprotected many from poverty, butpromoted few out of poverty.

Although the program reachesotherwise excluded people, thepoorest in the communities arenot covered.

The program increased visitrates and reduced out-of-pocketexpenditures, especially amongthe poor, but only middle-income children benefited fromthe reduced financial cost.

Page 47: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

with one or more untreated individuals who are most closely similar basedon the estimated propensity score. The control group is then the subsam-ple of untreated individuals who are otherwise nearly identical (that is,“matched”) to the treated individuals. The impact of the treatment can beseen as the difference in mean outcomes between the treated group and thematched, untreated control group.21

The main advantage of matching methods is that they can draw onexisting datasets and are often more rapid and less expensive to implement.22

The principal disadvantage of this method is that it may not completelysolve the problem of selection bias: selection into the treatment group maybe a function of unobserved characteristics. In addition, matching methodscan be statistically complex, requiring considerable expertise in the designof the evaluation and in the analysis and interpretation of the results.

The second method involves experimental, randomized controlledtrials. These studies require a sample of individuals equally eligible andwilling to receive treatment. One subsample is randomly assigned to thetreatment group, and the remainder is assigned to the control group,which does not receive the treatment. This is generally considered themost robust evaluation method. The random assignment process createscomparable treatment and control groups that are statistically equivalentto one another, given appropriate sample sizes. In principle, control groupsgenerated through random assignment serve as a perfect counterfactual,free from the problems of selection bias that plague evaluations.

The benefits of this technique are the robustness and simplicity of theresults: the impact of the intervention can be measured simply as the dif-ference between the mean measured outcomes of the samples of the treat-ment group and the control group. Although experimental designs areconsidered the ideal approach to estimating project impact, there are sev-eral problems in practice:

m Randomization may be unethical or may be perceived as unethical.m It can be politically difficult to provide an intervention for one group

and not another.m Nationwide programs or policy changes leave no room for a control

group.m Circumstances and the behavior of participants may change during

the experiment: people move or may seek alternative treatment.m Assignment may not be truly random: program administrators may

exclude high-risk applicants to achieve better results.m Experimental designs can be expensive and time consuming in cer-

tain situations, particularly in the collection of new data.

Health Sector Reforms

89

Page 48: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

90

TABLE 2.10. Experimental and Quasi-Experimental Evaluations in Health

Case Reference Findings

Method: quasi-experimental, matchingPrivatization of water services in Argentina

Water and sewerage provision in Ecuador

Piped water in rural India

Method: randomized controlled trialDeworming, health externalities, and education in Kenya

Progresa (cash-transfer and incentive program) and health outcomes

Deworming and child growth in Uganda

Early childhood nutrition program in Uganda

Source: Compiled by the authors.

Galiani, Gertler, andSchargrodsky 2005

Galdo and Briceno2004

Jalan and Ravallion2003

Miguel and Kremer2001

Gertler 2000

Alderman, Sebuliba,et al. 2004

Alderman, Britto, et al. 2004

Increase in connections was greater, andchild mortality was significantly lower in privatized municipalities.

Impact was significant on child mortality;among the poor, the decrease was signifi-cant only among households in whichwomen had at least primary education.

Drop was significant in diarrhea incidenceand duration; among the poor, thedecrease was significant only amonghouseholds in which women had at leastprimary education.

Deworming led to more rapid growth andlower anemia among treated children andhad significantly positive external effectsamong untreated children and neighboringnonparticipating schools.

Progresa increased consumption of primarycare, lowered hospitalization, and improvedhealth among both children and adults.

Deworming led to more rapid weight gainamong treated children.

Program significantly prolonged breastfeed-ing; increased consumption of milk,legumes, porridge, fruits, and vegetables;there was greater frequency of primary carevisits and greater school enrollment.

An important extension of these methods involves conducting theevaluation not on a static comparison of levels or outcomes between thetreatment and control groups, but as the “difference in differences”between groups, that is, examining the difference in the changes in out-comes across groups. This will eliminate the influence of those unob-served characteristics that are time invariant (the characteristics that do

Page 49: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

not change during the period of the study).23 This requires a baselineand follow-up surveys (panel data for comparisons across individuals).

Table 2.10 presents some examples of both experimental and quasi-experimental (matching) evaluations. They are primarily evaluations ofspecific interventions rather than large-scale multifaceted programs. Thatis not to say that these methods are not applicable to larger programs.Rigorous evaluation was key to the design of the Progresa program inMexico and has been ongoing since before the program’s launch in 1997.Fundamental to these types of evaluations, however, is the existence of acontrol group. Without external controls, it is only possible with thesemethods to conduct a “before and after” comparison within the treat-ment group itself. While some confounding unobservable characteristicsmay be controlled through instrumental variables, it is likely that theresults will be biased by selection problems.

NOTES

1. In the literature on health sector reforms, it is common to equate these withallocative and technical efficiency, respectively.

2. Health care is seen as a merit good, that is, a good that we have decided isbeneficial for people to consume, regardless of their own feelings in the matter. Health has external effects, that is, one person’s health behavior andstatus affect the health and welfare of others.

3. See, for example, Wagstaff (2002) for a summary of inequality in the healthsector.

4. The RAND health care experiment in the United States found that highercopayments reduced health care consumption, but had little impact onhealth, implying that people seek unnecessary care when the cost per visit islow (Newhouse and the Insurance Experiment Group 1993).

5. See, for instance, World Development Report 1997 (World Bank 1997a).6. Hsiao (2000) specifies a set of “control knobs”—financing, payment, orga-

nization, regulation, and consumer behavior—that capture the full range ofhealth reforms.

7. Developing-country tax revenue is about 18 percent of gross domestic prod-uct, compared to 38 percent among countries of the Organisation for Eco-nomic Co-operation and Development (Tanzi and Zee 2001).

8. In addition to the references cited in Table 2.2, see Atim (1998) and Stinson(1982).

9. The exception was West Bengal.10. Human Resources for Health, http://www.human-resources-health.com/.11. It must be noted that these two goals are sometimes in conflict: what is good

for any one particular patient may not be in the best public interest.

Health Sector Reforms

91

Page 50: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

12. There is little evidence that the actual risk of HIV infection is higher amonghealth workers. See Marchal, De Brouwere, and Kegels (2005).

13. Once this group had decided on a package of reforms, these were pilot tested,partly to gauge the reaction of communities to the proposed reforms.

14. The factors include better nutrition, mother’s education, access to safe waterand sanitation, access to electricity, and so on, in addition to health sectoroutputs such as immunization and basic health services.

15. For excellent introductions and instructions for these measures, see the tech-nical notes, especially 7, 12, and 16, at http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/EXTHEALTHNUTRITIONANDPOPULATION/EXTPAH/0,,contentMDK:20216933~menuPK:460204~pagePK:148956~piPK:216618~theSitePK:400476,00.html.

16. See Lanjouw et al. (2002); Lanjouw and Ravallion (1999); Younger (2003).17. To make this a bit more concrete, imagine that a group of highly motivated

parents lobby successfully for a child health intervention. Comparing thechildren who had received this intervention to a group of other childrenwould conflate the beneficial consequences of the motivation of the par-ents on their children with the benefits of the intervention. The benefits ofmotivation are likely to be high, perhaps even higher than the benefits ofthe intervention itself. See Newman et al. (2002); Newman, Rawlings, andGertler (1994).

18. Tang and Bloom (2000) indicate that rapid decentralization that does notaddress weaknesses in the financial and institutional capacity of local govern-ments can have an adverse impact on the quality of health services, andpoor areas are likely to be disproportionately affected. However, distribu-tional issues are not explicitly analyzed. According to Bossert (2000), localstakeholders perceive that decentralization has improved service quality;but Bossert acknowledges that these findings are based on rather limitedinformation.

19. See, for example, Bamberger (2000); Hentschel (1999); Rao and Ibanez(2003); and Woolcock (2001).

20. This is most clearly illustrated by the universal phenomenon of nonlinear costs.In a program to vaccinate 1 million children, for instance, the marginal cost ofreaching the millionth child is likely to be much higher than the cost of reach-ing the thousandth child. Also see the discussion on marginal benefit incidenceanalysis in the section titled “What distribution?”.

21. Becker and Ichino (1999) and Ravallion (2003) provide excellent explana-tions of the steps involved in the propensity-score-matching method.

22. This and the following three paragraphs draw on Baker 2000.23. This includes factors such as the education of the parents of the included

adults, ethnicity, religion, and place of birth, and other unobserved character-istics that might influence health behavior. However, the influence of un-observed individual characteristics that change during the study may beincreased by differencing.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

92

Page 51: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Abel-Smith, B., and P. Rawal. 1992. “Can the Poor Afford ‘Free’ Health Services?:A Case Study of Tanzania.” Health Policy and Planning 7 (4): 329–41.

———. 1994. “Employers’ Willingness to Pay: The Case for Compulsory HealthInsurance in Tanzania.” Health Policy and Planning 9 (4): 409–18.

Aga Khan Health Services. 2004. “Health Facility Committees: The GovernanceIssue.” Policy Brief 4, Best Practices in Community-Based Health Initiatives,Community Health Department, Aga Khan Health Services in Kenya, Nairobi.

Aitken, J.-M., and J. Kemp. 2003. “HIV/AIDS, Equity, and Health Sector Per-sonnel in Southern Africa.” Equinet Discussion Paper 12, Network for Equityin Health in Southern Africa, Harare, Zimbabwe.

Akin, J., S. C. Griffin, D. K. Guilkey, and B. M. Popkin. 1984. The Demand forPrimary Health Care in Developing Countries. Totowa, NJ: Littlefield, Adams.

———. 1986. “The Demand for Primary Health Care Services in the Bicol Regionof the Philippines.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 34 (4): 755–82.

Alderman, H., P. Britto, P. Engle, and A. Siddiqi. 2004. “Longitudinal Evaluationof Uganda Nutrition and Early Child Development Program.” Unpublishedmanuscript, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Alderman, H., and P. J. Gertler. 1989. “The Substitutability of Public and PrivateHealth Care for the Treatment of Children in Pakistan.” Living StandardsMeasurement Study Working Paper 57. World Bank, Washington, DC.

Alderman, H., and V. Lavy. 1996. “Household Responses to Public Health Services:Cost and Quality Trade-Offs.” World Bank Research Observer 11 (1): 3–22.

Alderman, H., I. Sebuliba, J. Konde-Lule, and A. Hall. 2004. “Increased WeightGain with Mass Deworming Given during Child Health Days in Uganda.”Unpublished manuscript, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Arhin-Tenkorang, D. 2000. “Mobilizing Resources for Health: The Case for UserFees Revisited.” CMH Working Paper Series WG3: 6, Commission on Macro-economics and Health, World Health Organization, Geneva.

———. 2004. “Experience of Community Health Financing in the African Re-gion.” In Health Financing for Poor People: Resource Mobilization and Risk Shar-ing, ed. A. S. Preker and G. Carrin. Washington, DC: World Bank; Geneva:World Health Organization; Geneva: International Labour Office.

Asada, Y., and T. Hedemann. 2002. “A Problem with the Individual Approach inthe WHO Health Inequality Measurement.” International Journal for Equityin Health 1 (2). http://www.equityhealthj.com/content/1/1/2.

Asenso-Okyere, W. K., A. Anum, I. Osei-Akoto, and A. Adukonu. 1998. “CostRecovery in Ghana: Are There Any Changes in Health Care Seeking Behav-ior?” Health Policy and Planning 13 (2): 181–88.

Atim, C. 1998. “Contribution of Mutual Health to Financing, Delivery, and Accessto Health Care: Synthesis of Research in Nine West and Central African Coun-tries.” Technical Report 18, Partnerships for Health Reform Project, Abt Asso-ciates Inc., Bethesda, MD.

Health Sector Reforms

93

Page 52: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

———. 1999. “Social Movements and Health Insurance: A Critical Evaluationof Voluntary, Non-Profit Insurance Schemes with Case Studies from Ghanaand Cameroon.” Social Science and Medicine 48: 881–96.

Atkinson, S., and D. Haran. 2004. “Back to Basics: Does DecentralizationImprove Health System Performance?: Evidence from Ceará in North-EastBrazil.” Bulletin of the World Health Organization 82 (11): 822–32.

Bailey, M. 2001. “Priced Out of Reach.” Briefing Paper 4, Oxfam International,Washington, DC.

Baker, J. L. 2000. Evaluating the Impact of Development Projects on Poverty: AHandbook for Practitioners. Directions in Development. Washington, DC:World Bank.

Bamberger, M. 2000. “Opportunities and Challenges for Integrating Quantitativeand Qualitative Research.” In Integrating Quantitative and Qualitative Researchin Development Projects, ed. M. Bamberger, 3–36. Washington, DC: WorldBank.

Barnum, H., J. Kutzin, and H. Saxenian. 1995. “Incentives and Provider PaymentMethods.” Human Resources Development and Operations Policy WorkingPaper 51, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Bassi, L. 1983. “Estimating the Effects of Training Programs with NonrandomSelection.” Review of Economics and Statistics 66: 36–43.

Becker, S. O., and A. Ichino. 1999. “Estimation of Average Treatment EffectsBased on Propensity Scores.” The Stata Journal 2 (4): 358–77.

Beegle, K. 1995. “The Quality and Availability of Family Planning Services andContraceptive Use in Tanzania.” Living Standards Measurement StudyWorking Paper 114, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Bennett, F. 1979. “Primary Health Care and Developing Countries.” Social Scienceand Medicine 13A (5): 505–14.

Bennett, S., A. Creese, and R. Monasch. 1998. “Health Insurance Schemes forPeople Outside Formal Sector Employment.” ARA Paper 16, Division ofAnalysis, Research, and Assessment, World Health Organization, Geneva.

Bennett, S., and L. Gilson. 2001. Health Financing: Designing and ImplementingPro-Poor Policies. London: Health Systems Resource Centre, Department forInternational Development.

Bennett, S., B. McPake, and A. Mills, eds. 1997. Private Health Providers in Devel-oping Countries: Serving the Public Interest? London: Zed Books.

Berman, P. A., ed. 1995. Health Sector Reform in Developing Countries: MakingHealth Development Sustainable. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press;Health Policy 32 (1–3).

———. 1997. “National Health Accounts in Developing Countries: AppropriateMethods and Recent Applications.” Health Economics 6 (1): 11–30.

Berman, P. A., and T. J. Bossert. 2000. “A Decade of Health Sector Reform inDeveloping Countries: What Have We Learned?” Paper prepared for the Datafor Decision Making Project Symposium, “Appraising a Decade of Health Sec-tor Reform in Developing Countries,” Washington, DC, March 15.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

94

Page 53: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Bertozzi, S. M., B. Aracena, L. Cahuana, A. Corcho, K. Rely, and V. Zurita. 2001.“Study on Costs of Scaling-Up Health Interventions for the Poor in Latin-American Settings: Final Report.” Working Group 5, Commission on Macro-economics and Health, World Health Organization, Geneva.

Besley, T., and S. Coate. 1991. “Public Provision of Private Goods and the Re-distribution of Income.” American Economic Review 81 (4): 979–84.

Bhushan, I., S. Keller, and B. Schwartz. 2002. “Achieving the Twin Objectives ofEfficiency and Equity: Contracting Health Services in Cambodia.” ERD Pol-icy Brief 6, Economics and Research Department, Asian Development Bank,Manila.

Binam, J. N., A. Nkama, and R. Nkendah. (2004). “Estimating the Willingnessto Pay for Community Health Prepayment Schemes in Rural Areas: A CaseStudy of the Use of Contingent Valuation Surveys in Central Cameroon.”Unpublished manuscript, Institute of Agricultural Research for Develop-ment, Farming Systems, Economy and Rural Sociology Division, Yaoundé,Cameroon. http://www.csae.ox.ac.uk/conferences/2004-GPRaHDiA/papers/4h-Binam-CSAE2004.pdf.

Bir, A., and K. Eggleston. 2003. “Physician Dual Practice: Access Enhancementor Demand Inducement?” Working Paper 2003-11, Department of Econom-ics, Tufts University, Boston.

Birdsall, N., and P. Chuhan. 1986. “Client Choice of Health Treatment in RuralMali.” Unpublished manuscript, Population and Rural Resources Depart-ment, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Birdsall, N., and E. James. 1993. “Health, Government, and the Poor: The Casefor the Private Sector.” In The Epidemiological Transition: Policy and PlanningImplications for Developing Countries, ed. J. N. Gribble and S. H. Preston.Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

Bitrán, R. 2001. “Paying Healthcare Providers through Capitation in Argentina,Nicaragua, and Thailand: Output, Spending, Organizational Impact, and Mar-ket Structure.” Major Applied Research 2, Technical Paper, Partnerships forHealth Reform Project, Abt Associates Inc., Bethesda, MD.

Bitrán, R., and U. Giedion. 2003. “Waivers and Exemptions for Health Services inDeveloping Countries.” Social Protection Discussion Paper 0308, Social Pro-tection Unit, Human Development Network, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Bitrán, R., and C. Muñoz. 2000. “Targeting Methodologies: Conceptual Approachand Analysis of Experiences.” Partnerships for Health Reform Project, LatinAmerica and Caribbean Regional Health Sector Reform Initiative. http://www.lachsr.org/documents/targetingmethodologiesconceptualapproachandanaly-sisofexperiences-EN.pdf.

Bitrán, R., and W. C. Yip. 1998. “A Review of Health Care Provider PaymentReform in Selected Countries in Asia and Latin America.” Major AppliedResearch 2 Working Paper 1, Abt Associates Inc., Bethesda, MD.

Bloom, G., L. Han, and Xiang Li. 2001. “How Health Workers Earn a Living inChina.” Human Resources for Health Development Journal 5 (1–3): 25–38.

Health Sector Reforms

95

Page 54: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Blundell, R., and M. Costa-Dias. 2000. “Evaluation Methods for Non-Experimental Data.” Fiscal Studies 21 (4): 427–68.

Blundell, R., M. Costa-Dias, C. Meghir, and J. van Reenen. 2000. “Evaluatingthe Employment Impact of Mandatory Job-Search Assistance: The UKNew Deal Gateway.” Unpublished manuscript, Institute for Fiscal Studies,London.

Bossert, T. J. 1998. “Analyzing the Decentralization of Health Systems in Devel-oping Countries: Decision Space, Innovation, and Performance.” Social Sci-ence and Medicine 47 (10): 1513–27.

———. 2000. “Decentralization of Health Systems in Latin America: A Com-parative Analysis of Chile, Colombia, and Bolivia.” Latin America and theCaribbean Health Sector Reform Initiative Working Paper, Harvard Schoolof Public Health, Boston.

Brenzel, L. 1993. “Selecting an Essential Package of Health Services Using Cost-Effectiveness Analysis: A Manual for Professionals in Developing Countries.”Population and Human Resources Sector, Population, Health, and NutritionDepartment, World Bank, Washington, DC; Data for Decision Making Proj-ect, Department of Population Studies and International Health, HarvardSchool of Public Health, Boston.

Brinkerhoff, D. 1996. “Process Perspectives on Policy Change: HighlightingImplementation.” World Development 24: 1395–401. Quoted in Gilson (1997).

———. 2000. “Democratic Governance and Sectoral Policy Reform: TracingLinkages and Exploring Synergies.” World Development 28 (4): 601–15.

———. 2003. Accountability and Health Systems: Overview, Framework, andStrategies. Bethesda, MD: Abt Associates Inc.

Bumgarner, J. R., ed. 1992. China: Long-Term Issues and Options in the HealthTransition. World Bank Country Study. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Caines, K., and L. Lush. 2004. “Impact of Public-Private Partnerships Address-ing Access to Pharmaceuticals in Selected Low- and Middle-Income Coun-tries: A Synthesis Report from Studies in Botswana, Sri Lanka, Uganda, andZambia.” Initiative on Public-Private Partnerships for Health, Global Forumfor Health Research, Geneva.

Carrin, G., M. Desmet, and R. Basaza. 2001. “Social Health Insurance Develop-ment in Low-Income Developing Countries: New Roles for Government andNon-Profit Health Insurance Organizations.” In Building Social Security: TheChallenge of Privatization. International Social Security Series, vol. 6, ed. X.Scheil-Adlung, 125–53. London: Transaction Publishers.

Cassels, A., and K. Janovsky. 1996. “Reform of the Health Sector in Ghana andZambia: Commonalities and Contrasts.” SHS Paper 11, WHO/SHS/CC/96.1,Division of Strengthening of Health Services, World Health Organization,Geneva.

Castro-Leal, F., J. Dayton, L. Demery, and K. Mehra. 2000. “Public Spending onHealth Care in Africa: Do the Poor Benefit?” Bulletin of the World HealthOrganization 78 (1): 66–74.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

96

Page 55: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Chakraborty, S., R. Gatti, J. Klugman, and G. Gray-Molina. 2002. “When is ‘Free’Not So Free?: Informal Payments for Basic Health Services in Bolivia.”Unpublished manuscript, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Chaudhury, N., and J. S. Hammer. 2003. “Ghost Doctors: Absenteeism inBangladeshi Health Facilities.” Policy Research Working Paper 3065, WorldBank, Washington, DC.

Chaudhury, N., J. S. Hammer, and E. Murrugarra. 2003. “The Effects of a Fee-Waiver Program on Health Care Utilization among the Poor: Evidencefrom Armenia.” Policy Research Working Paper 2952, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Cheng, S., and T. Chiang. 1997. “The Effect of Universal Health Insurance onHealth Care Utilization in Taiwan.” Journal of the American Medical Associa-tion 278: 89–93.

Chiappori, P. A., F. Durand, and P. Y. Geoffard. 1998. “Moral Hazard and theDemand for Physician Services: First Lessons from a French Natural Experi-ment.” European Economic Review 42 (3–5): 499–511.

Chomitz, K. M., G. Setiadi, A. Azwar, N. Ismail, and Widiyarti. 1997. “What DoDoctors Want?: Developing Incentives for Doctors to Serve in Indonesia’sRural and Remote Areas.” Policy Research Working Paper 1888, World Bank,Washington, DC.

Chung, K. 2000. “Issues and Approaches in the Use of Integrated Methods.” InIntegrating Quantitative and Qualitative Research in Development Projects, ed.M. Bamberger, 37–46. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Cochrane, W., and D. Rubin. 1973. “Controlling Bias in Observational Studies.”Sankyha 35: 417–46.

Collier, P., S. Dercon, and J. Mackinnon. 2002. “Density versus Quality in HealthCare Provision: Using Household Data to Make Budgetary Choices inEthiopia.” CSAE Working Paper 2002-17, Centre for the Study of AfricanEconomies, Oxford University, Oxford.

Collins, C., J. Araujo, and J. Barbosa. 2000. “Decentralizing the Health Sector:Issues in Brazil.” Health Policy 52: 113–27.

Cornwall, A. 2000. “Beneficiary, Consumer, Citizen: Perspectives on Participa-tion for Poverty Reduction.” SIDA Studies 2, Swedish International Devel-opment Cooperation Agency, Stockholm.

Cornwall, A., H. Lucas, and K. Pasteur, eds. 2000. “Accountability through Par-ticipation: Developing Workable Partnership Models in the Health Sector.”Institute of Development Studies Bulletin 31 (1).

Creese, A., and S. Bennett. 1997. “Rural Risk-Sharing Strategies.” In Innovationsin Health Care Financing. Proceedings of a World Bank Conference, March10–11, 1997, ed. G. Schieber. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Cretin, S., E. Keeler, A. Williams, and Y. Shi. 1988. “Factors Affecting TwoTown-Countryside Differences in the Use of Health Services in Two RuralCounties in Sichuan.” Unpublished manuscript, Rand Corporation, SantaMonica, CA.

Health Sector Reforms

97

Page 56: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Criel, B., P. Van der Stuyft, and W. Van Lerberghe. 1999. “The Bwamanda Hospi-tal Insurance Scheme: Effective for Whom?, A Study of Its Impact on Hospital-isation and Utilisation Patterns.” Social Science and Medicine 48 (7): 879–911.

Das, J., and J. S. Hammer. 2004. “Which Doctor?: Combining Vignettes and ItemResponse to Measure Doctor Quality.” Policy Research Working Paper 3301,Public Services, Development Research Group, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Deaton, A., and J. Muellbauer. 1980. Economics and Consumer Behavior.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Dehn, J., R. Reinikka, and J. Svensson. 2003. “Survey Tools for Assessing Perfor-mance in Service Delivery.” Unpublished manuscript, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Deininger, K., and P. Mpuga. 2004. “Economic and Welfare Effects of theAbolition of Health User Fees: Evidence from Uganda.” Policy ResearchWorking Paper 3276, Rural Development, Development Research Group,World Bank, Washington, DC.

de la Jara, J. J., and T. J. Bossert. 1995. “Chile’s Health Sector Reform: Lessonsfrom Four Reform Periods.” Health Policy 32 (1–3): 155–66.

Demery, L. 2003. “Analyzing the Incidence of Public Spending.” In The Impactof Economic Policies on Poverty and Income Distribution: Evaluation Techniquesand Tools, ed. F. Bourguignon and L. Pereira da Silva, 41–68. Washington,DC: World Bank; New York: Oxford University Press.

Demery, L., S. Y. Chao, R. Bernier, and K. Mehra. 1995. “The Incidence of SocialSpending in Ghana.” PSP Discussion Papers 82, Poverty and Social PolicyDepartment, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Diderichsen, F. 2004. “Resource Allocation for Health Equity: Issues and Meth-ods.” Health, Nutrition, and Population Discussion Paper, World Bank,Washington, DC.

Diop, F., A. Yazbeck, and R. Bitrán. 1995. “The Impact of Alternative CostRecovery Schemes on Access and Equity in Niger.” Health Policy and Plan-ning 10: 223–40.

Druce, N. 2004. “Access to Medicines in Under-Served Markets.” OverviewPaper, Health Systems Resource Centre, Department for International Devel-opment, London.

Dusheiko, M., H. Gravelle, R. Jacobs, and P. Smith. 2003. “The Effects of Bud-gets on Doctor Behaviour: Evidence from a Natural Experiment.” DiscussionPaper 2003/04, Department of Economics, University of York, York, UnitedKingdom.

Dussault, G., and C.-A. Dubois. 2003. “Human Resources for Health Policies: ACritical Component in Health Policies.” Human Resources for Health 1 (1).http://www.human-resources-health.com/content/1/1/1.

Eggleston, K., and C.-R. Hsieh. 2004. “Health Care Payment Incentives: A Com-parative Analysis of Reforms in Taiwan, Korea and China.” Working Paper2004-2, Department of Economics, Tufts University, Boston.

Egypt, Ministry of Health and Population, Department of Planning. 1995.“National Health Accounts for Egypt.” Data for Decision Making Project,

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

98

Page 57: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Department of Population Studies and International Health, Harvard Schoolof Public Health, Boston.

Elbers, C., J. Lanjouw, and P. Lanjouw. 2003. “Micro-Level Estimation of Povertyand Inequality.” Econometrica 71 (1): 355–64.

Enemark, U., and F. Schleimann. 1999. “Financing Health Services in PoorCountries: Feeding a White Elephant?” Discussion Paper 1, Danish Inter-national Development Agency, Copenhagen.

England, R. 2002. Contracting and Performance Management in the Health Sector:Some Pointers on How to Do It. London: Health Systems Resource Centre,Department for International Development.

———. 2004. Experiences of Contracting with the Private Sector: A Selective Review.London: Health Systems Resource Centre, Department for InternationalDevelopment.

Ensor, T. 2003. Consumer-Led Demand Side Financing for Health and Education: AnInternational Review. Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford Policy Management.

———. 2004. “Informal Payments for Health Care in Transition Economies.”Social Science and Medicine 58 (2): 237–46.

Ensor, T., and S. Cooper. 2004. “Overcoming Barriers to Health Service Access:Influencing the Demand Side.” Health Policy and Planning 19 (2): 69–79.

Fairbank, A., M. Makinen, W. Schott, and B. Sakagawa. 2000. “Poverty Reduc-tion and Immunizations: Considering Immunizations in the Context of DebtRelief for Poor Countries.” Abt Associates Inc., Bethesda, MD. http://www.gaviftf.info/forum/bb2/7-21_hipc.pdf.

Feldstein, M. 1974. “Econometric Studies of Health.” In Four Frontiers ofQuantitative Economics, vol. 2, ed. M. Intriligator and D. Kendrick, 377–442.Amsterdam: North-Holland.

Feng, X. S., S. L. Tang, G. Bloom, M. Segall, and X. Y. Gu. 1995. “Cooperative Med-ical Schemes in Contemporary Rural China.” Social Science and Medicine 41 (8):1111–18.

Ferrinho, P., W. Van Lerberghe, I. Fronteira, F. Hipólito, and A. Biscaia. 2004.“Dual Practice in the Health Sector: Review of the Evidence.” Human Resourcesfor Health 2 (14). http://www.human-resources-health.com/content/2/1/14.

Filmer, D., J. S. Hammer, and L. Pritchett. 2000. “Weak Links in the Chain: A Diagnosis of Health Policy in Poor Countries.” World Bank Research Observer15 (2): 199–224.

———. 2002. “Weak Links in the Chain II: A Prescription for Health Policy inPoor Countries.” World Bank Research Observer 17 (1): 47–66.

Filmer, D., and L. Pritchett. 1998. “Estimating Wealth Effects without ExpenditureData or Tears: With an Application to Educational Enrollments in States ofIndia.” Policy Research Working Paper 1944, Development Research Group,Poverty and Human Resources, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Foster, M., and S. Mackintosh-Walker. 2001. “Sector Wide Programmes andPoverty Reduction.” Centre for Aid and Public Expenditure Working Paper157, Overseas Development Institute, London.

Health Sector Reforms

99

Page 58: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Fujii, T. 2003. “Maps of Anthropometric Indicators: Using Cambodia DHS andCensus.” Unpublished manuscript, Agricultural and Resource Economics,University of California, Berkeley, CA.

Futures Group International. 2000. “Health Reform, Decentralization, and Partici-pation in Latin America: Protecting Sexual and Reproductive Health.” PolicyProject, Futures Group International, Washington, DC.

Galdo, V., and B. Briceno. 2004. “Evaluating the Impact on Child Mortality of aWater Supply Project and Sewerage Expansion in Quito, Ecuador.” Unpub-lished manuscript, Office of Evaluation and Oversight, Inter-American Devel-opment Bank, Washington, DC.

Galiani, S., P. J. Gertler, and E. Schargrodsky. 2005. “Water for Life: The Impactof the Privatization of Water Services on Child Mortality.” Journal of PoliticalEconomy 113 (1): 83–120.

Gelbach, J. B., and L. H. Pritchett. 1995. “Does More for the Poor Mean Less forthe Poor?: The Politics of Tagging.” Policy Research Working Paper 1523,World Bank, Washington, DC.

George, A. 2003. “Accountability in Health Services: Transforming Relationshipsand Contexts.” HCPDS Working Paper Series 13 (1), Harvard Center for Popu-lation and Development Studies, Cambridge, MA.

Gerdtham, U.-G., C. Rehnberg, and M. Tambour. 1999. “The Impact of InternalMarkets on Health Care Efficiency: Evidence from Health Care Reforms inSweden.” Applied Economics 31 (8): 935–45.

Gertler, P. J. 1998. “On the Road to Social Health Insurance: The Asian Experi-ence.” World Development 26 (4): 717–32.

———. 2000. “Final Report: The Impact of Progresa on Health.” Unpublishedmanuscript, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, DC.

Gertler, P. J., L. Locay, and W. C. Sanderson. 1987. “Are User Fees Regressive?:The Welfare Implications of Health Care Financing Proposals in Peru.” Jour-nal of Econometrics 36 (1–2) (supplement): 67–88.

Gertler, P. J., and O. Solon. 2000. “Who Benefits from Social Health Insurance?:Evidence from the Philippines.” NBER Working Paper XXX, Haas School ofBusiness, University of California at Berkeley, Berkeley, CA.

Gertler, P. J., and R. Sturm. 1997. “Private Health Insurance and Public Expen-ditures in Jamaica.” Journal of Econometrics 77 (1): 237–57.

Gertler, P. J., and J. van der Gaag. 1988. “The Willingness to Pay for Social Ser-vices in Developing Countries.” Living Standards Measurement Study Work-ing Paper 45, World Bank, Washington, DC.

———. 1990. The Willingness to Pay for Medical Care: Evidence from Two Devel-oping Countries. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Gilson, L. 1997. “Implementing and Evaluating Health Reform Processes: Lessonsfrom the Literature.” Major Applied Research 1 Working Paper 1, Partnershipsfor Health Reform Project, Abt Associates Inc., Bethesda, MD.

———. 1998. “In Defense and Pursuit of Equity.” Social Science and Medicine 47(12): 1891–96.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

100

Page 59: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

González-Rossetti, A., and T. J. Bossert. 2000. “Enhancing the Political Feasibility ofHealth Reform: A Comparative Analysis of Chile, Colombia, and Mexico.” Datafor Decision Making Project and the Latin American and Caribbean Health Sec-tor Reform Initiative, Department of Population Studies and InternationalHealth, Harvard School of Public Health, Boston.

Gorter, A. 2003. “Competitive Vouchers for Health.” Background paper, Insti-tuto CentroAmericano de la Salud, Managua, Nicaragua; World Bank, Washington, DC.

Grace, C. 2003. “Equitable Pricing of Newer Essential Medicines for DevelopingCountries: Evidence for the Potential of Different Mechanisms.” Unpublishedmanuscript, London Business School, London.

Griffin, C. C. 1992. Health Care in Asia: A Comparative Study of Cost and Financing.World Bank Regional and Sectoral Studies. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Gruen, R., R. Anwar, T. Begum, J. R. Killingsworth, and C. Normand. 2002. “DualJob Holding Practitioners in Bangladesh: An Exploration.” Social Science andMedicine 54 (2): 267–79.

Gumber, A. 2002. “Health Insurance for the Informal Sector: Problems andProspects.” Working Paper 90, Indian Council for Research on InternationalEconomic Relations, New Delhi.

Gumber, A., and V. Kulkarni. 2000. “Health Insurance for the Informal Sector:Case Study of Gujarat.” Economic and Political Weekly, September 30: 3607–13.

Gwatkin, D. R. 2003. “Free Government Health Services: Are They the Best Way to Reach the Poor?” Unpublished manuscript, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Gwatkin, D. R., S. Rutstein, K. Johnson, R. P. Poande, and A. Wagstaff. 2000.“Socioeconomic Differences in Health, Nutrition, and Population.” Health,Nutrition, and Population Discussion Paper, Health, Nutrition, and Popula-tion Family, Human Development Network, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Hall, J. J., and R. Taylor. 2003. “Health for All Beyond 2000: The Demise of theAlma-Ata Declaration and Primary Health Care in Developing Countries.”Medical Journal of Australia 178 (1): 17–20.

Hammer, J. S. 1993. “The Economics of Malaria Control.” World Bank ResearchObserver 8 (1): 1–22.

Hammer, J. S., and W. Jack. 2001. “The Design of Incentives for Health CareProviders in Developing Countries: Contracts, Competition, and Cost Con-trol.” Policy Research Working Paper 2547, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Hanvoravongchai, P. 2002. “Medical Savings Accounts: Lessons Learned fromInternational Experience.” EIP/HFS/PHF Discussion Paper 52, World HealthOrganization, Geneva.

Heller, P. 1982. “A Model of Demand for Medical and Health Services in Penin-sular Malaysia.” Social Science and Medicine 16: 267–84.

Hentschel, J. 1999. “Contextuality and Data Collection Methods: A Frameworkand Application to Health Service Utilisation.” Journal of Development Studies35 (4): 64–94.

Health Sector Reforms

101

Page 60: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Hindu (Chennai, Madras, India). 2005. “Law on Service in Rural Areas forDoctors Likely,” April 7. http://www.hindu.com/2005/04/07/stories/2005040708310400.htm.

Hope, R. L. 2003. “Paying in Potatoes: Community-Based Health Insurance forthe Rural and Informal Sector.” The Lancet 362 (938): 827–29.

Hsiao, W. C. 2000. “Inside the Black Box of Health Systems.” Program on HealthCare Financing, Harvard School of Public Health, Boston.

———. 2001. “Commentary: Behind the Ideology and Theory, What is theEmpirical Evidence for Medical Savings Accounts?” Journal of Health Politics,Policy and Law 26 (4): 733–37.

———. 2004. “Experience of Community Health Financing in the Asian Region.”In Health Financing for Poor People: Resource Mobilization and Risk Sharing, ed.A. S. Preker and G. Carrin. Washington, DC: World Bank; Geneva: WorldHealth Organization; Geneva: International Labour Office.

Human Resources for Health (various). http://www.human-resources-health.com/.

Hurley, J. 2001. “Medical Savings Accounts in Publicly Financed Health Care Sys-tems: What Do We Know?” Research Working Paper 01–12, Centre for HealthEconomics and Policy Analysis, McMaster University, Hamilton, Ontario,Canada.

Hurst, J. W. 1992. “The Reform of Health Care: A Comparative Analysis of SevenOECD Countries.” OECD Health Policy Studies 2, Organisation for Eco-nomic Co-operation and Development, Paris.

Hutton, G. 2000. “Indicators for Monitoring Health Sector Reform and theSector-Wide Approach.” Presentation at Sector-Wide Approach in HealthConference, “Moving from Policy to Practice,” Royal Tropical Institute, Ams-terdam, November 27–28.

INEI (Instituto Nacional de Estadística e Informática). 1986. “Encuesta nacionalde nutrición y salud, ENNSA” (Survey of Nutrition and Health), NationalStatistics Institute, Lima.

Jack, W. 2001a. “Purchasing Medical Care: A Conceptual Framework.” Unpub-lished manuscript, Georgetown University, Washington, DC.

———. 2001b. “Health Insurance Reform in Four Latin American Countries:Theory and Practice.” Policy Research Working Paper 2492, World Bank,Washington, DC.

Jakab, M., and C. Krishnan. 2001. “Community Involvement in Health CareFinancing: A Survey of the Literature on the Impacts, Strengths, and Weak-nesses.” Health, Nutrition, and Population Discussion Paper, September,Health, Nutrition, and Population Family, Human Development Network,World Bank, Washington, DC.

Jalan, J., and M. Ravallion. 2003. “Does Piped Water Reduce Diarrhea for Chil-dren in Rural India?” Journal of Econometrics 112 (1): 153–73.

Jefferys, E., and V. Walford. 2003. “Mapping of Sector Wide Approaches inHealth.” Institute for Health Sector Development, London.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

102

Page 61: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Jimenez, E. 1987. Pricing Policies in the Social Sectors: Cost Recovery for Educationand Health in Developing Countries. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Johannesson, M. 1995. “The Relationship between Cost-Effectiveness Analysisand Cost-Benefit Analysis.” Social Science and Medicine 41 (4): 483–89.

Johannesson, M., and M. Meltzer. 1998. “Some Reflections on Cost-EffectivenessAnalysis.” Health Economics 7 (1): 1–7.

Johns, B., and R. Baltussen. 2004. “Accounting for the Cost of Scaling-Up HealthInterventions.” Health Economics 13 (11): 1117–24.

Johns, B., and T. T. Torres. 2005. “Costs of Scaling-Up Health Interventions:A Systematic Review.” Health Policy and Planning 20 (1): 1–13.

Johnston, T., S. D. Faure, and L. Raney. 1998. “The World Bank and the HealthSector in Mali.” Report 18112, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Jütting, J. 2001. “The Impact of Community-Based Health Financing on Finan-cial Protection in Africa: Case Study Senegal.” Unpublished manuscript,Health, Nutrition, and Population Family, Human Development Network,World Bank, Washington, DC.

Jütting, J., C. Kauffmann, I. McDonnell, H. Osterrieder, N. Pinaud, and L. Wegne.2004. “Decentralisation and Poverty in Developing Countries: Exploring theImpact.” Working Paper 236, Development Centre, Organisation for EconomicCo-operation and Development, Paris.

Khan, S. H. 2005. “Free Does Not Mean Affordable: Maternity Patient Expendi-tures in a Public Hospital in Bangladesh.” Cost Effectiveness and Resource Allo-cation 3 (1). http://www.resource-allocation.com/content/3/1/1.

Khemani, S. 2004. “Local Government Accountability for Service Delivery inNigeria.” Development Research Group, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Killingsworth, J. R. 2002. “Official, Unofficial, and Informal Fees for HealthCare.” Draft Discussion Note 13, Third Health Sector Development Techni-cal Advisory Group Meeting, “Health Care Financing in the Western PacificRegion,” Manila, February 17–19.

Killingsworth, J. R., N. Hossain, Y. Hedrick-Wong, S. Thomas, A. Rahman, andT. Begum. 1999. “Unofficial Fees in Bangladesh: Price, Equity, and Institu-tional Issues.” Health Policy and Planning 14 (2): 152–63.

Klugman, J., ed. 2002. A Sourcebook for Poverty Reduction Strategies. 2 vols. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Kremer, M. 1995. “Research on Schooling: What We Know and What We Don’t(A Comment on Hanushek).” World Bank Research Observer 10 (2): 247–54.

Kumaranayake, L., S. Lake, P. Mujinja, C. Hongoro, and R. Mpembeni. 2000.“How Do Countries Regulate the Health Sector?: Evidence from Tanzaniaand Zimbabwe.” Health Policy and Planning 15 (4): 357–67.

Kutzin, J. 1997. “Health Insurance for the Formal Sector in Africa: ‘Yes but . . .’.”Current Concerns ARA Paper 14, Division of Analysis, Research, and Assess-ment, World Health Organization, Geneva.

La Forgia, G. M. 1990. Health Services for Low-Income Families: Extending Cov-erage through Prepayment Plans in the Dominican Republic. Bethesda, MD:Health Financing and Sustainability Project, Abt Associates Inc.

Health Sector Reforms

103

Page 62: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Laing, R. O., H. V. Hogerzeil, and D. Ross-Degnan. 2001. “Ten Recommenda-tions to Improve Use of Medicines in Developing Countries.” Health Policyand Planning 16 (1): 13–20.

Lakshminarayanan, R. 2003a. “Gender and Health Sector Reform: An AnnotatedBibliography.” Unpublished manuscript, International Women’s HealthCoalition, New York.

———. 2003b. “Decentralisation and its Implications for Reproductive Health:The Philippines Experience.” Reproductive Health Matters 11 (21): 96–107.

Langer, A., G. Nigenda, and J. Catino. 2000. “Health Sector Reform and Repro-ductive Health in Latin America and the Caribbean: Strengthening the Links.”Bulletin of the World Health Organization 78 (5): 667–76.

Lanjouw, J. O. 2002. “Intellectual Property and the Availability of Pharmaceuti-cals in Poor Countries.” Working Paper 5, Center for Global Development,Washington, DC.

———. (2004). “Drug Patents: Taking the Poorest Out of the Fight.” MilkenInstitute Quarterly Review. http://are.berkeley.edu/∼lanjouw/milken.pdf.

Lanjouw, P., M. Pradhan, F. Saadah, H. Sayed, and R. Sparrow. 2002. “Poverty,Education, and Health in Indonesia: Who Benefits from Public Spend-ing?, Volume 1.” Policy Research Working Paper 2739, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Lanjouw, P., and M. Ravallion. 1999. “Benefit Incidence, Public Spending Reforms,and the Timing of Program Capture.” World Bank Economic Review 13 (2):257–73.

Lavadenz, F., N. Schwab, and H. Straatman. 2001. “Decentralized and Commu-nity Health Networks in Bolivia.” Pan-American Journal of Public Health 9 (3):182–89. (In Spanish).

Lawson, D. 2004. “Determinants of Health-Seeking Behaviour in Uganda: Is itJust Income and User Fees that are Important?” Unpublished manuscript,University of Manchester, Manchester, United Kingdom.

Leonard, K. L. 2000. “Moral Hazard in Health Care: An Empirical Investigationin Rural Cameroon.” Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics,Columbia University, New York.

Lewis, M. 2000. “Who Is Paying for Health Care in Eastern Europe and CentralAsia?” Europe and Central Asia Region, Human Development Sector Unit,World Bank, Washington, DC.

Lindelöw, M., and A. Wagstaff. 2003. “Health Facility Surveys: An Introduction.”Policy Research Working Paper 2953, Public Services, Development ResearchGroup, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Litvack, J. I., and C. I. Bodart. 1992. “User Fees Plus Quality Equals ImprovedAccess to Health Care: Results of a Field Experiment in Cameroon.” SocialScience and Medicine 37 (3): 369–83.

Liu, X., D. R. Hotchkiss, S. Bose, R. Bitrán, and U. Giedion. 2004. Contracting forPrimary Health Services: Evidence on Its Effects and Framework for Evaluation.Bethesda, MD: Partners for Health Reformplus Project, Abt Associates Inc.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

104

Page 63: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Loevinsohn, B. 2001. “Contracting for the Delivery of Primary Health Care inCambodia: Design and Initial Experience of a Large Pilot Test.” Manuscript,World Bank, Washington, DC.

———. 2002. “Practical Issues in Contracting for Primary Health Care Delivery:Lessons from Two Large Projects in Bangladesh.” World Bank, Washington, DC.

Loewenson, R. 2000. “Participation and Accountability in Health Systems: TheMissing Factor in Equity?” Equinet Discussion Paper 1, Network for Equityin Health in Southern Africa, Harare, Zimbabwe.

Maceira, D. 1998. “Provider Payment Mechanisms in Health Care: Incentives,Outcomes, and Organizational Impact in Developing Countries.” MajorApplied Research 2 Working Paper 2, Partnerships for Health Reform Project, Abt Associates Inc., Bethesda, MD.

Marchal, B., V. De Brouwere, and G. Kegels. 2005. “Viewpoint: HIV/AIDS andthe Health Workforce Crisis, What are the Next Steps?” Tropical Medicine andInternational Health 10 (4): 300–4.

Marsh, V. M., W. M. Mutemi, A. Willetts, K. Bayah, S. Were, A. Ross, and K. Marsh. 2004. “Improving Malaria Home Treatment by Training DrugRetailers in Rural Kenya.” Tropical Medicine and International Health 9 (4):451–60.

McFadden, D. 1981. “Econometric Models of Probabilistic Choice.” In StructuralAnalysis of Discrete Data with Econometrics Applications, ed. C. Manski andD. McFadden, 114–78. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

McGuire, T. G. 2000. “Physician Agency.” In Handbook of Health Economics, ed.A. J. Culyer and J. P. Newhouse, 461–536. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.

McPake, B. 1997. “The Role of the Private Sector in Health Care Provision.” InPrivate Health Providers in Developing Countries: Servicing the Public Interest?,ed. S. Bennett, B. McPake, and A. Mills. London: Zed Books.

McPake, B., D. Asiimwe, F. Mwesigye, M. Ofumbi, L. Ortemblad, P. Streefland,and D. Turinde. 1999. “Informal Economic Activities of Public HealthWorkers in Uganda: Implication for Quality and Accessibility of Care.” SocialScience and Medicine 49: 849–65.

McPake, B., F. J. Yepes, S. Lake, and L. H. Sanchez. 2003. “Is the ColombianHealth System Reform Improving the Performance of Public Hospitals inBogotá?” Health Policy and Planning 118: 182–94.

Mensch, B. 1993. “Quality of Care: A Neglected Dimension.” In The Health ofWomen: A Global Perspective, ed. M. Koblinsky, J. Timyan, and J. Gay. Boulder,CO: Westview Press. Cited in WHO (1998).

Miguel, E., and M. Kremer. 2001. “Worms: Education and Health Externalitiesin Kenya.” Econometrica 72 (1): 159–217.

Miller, K., R. Miller, I. Askew, M. C. Horn, and L. Ndlovu, eds. 1998. “Clinic-Based Family Planning and Reproductive Health Services in Africa: Findingsfrom Situation Analysis Studies.” Population Council, New York.

Mills, A., R. Brugha, K. Hanson, and B. McPake. 2002. “What Can Be Done aboutthe Private Health Sector in Low-Income Countries?” Bulletin of the WorldHealth Organization 80 (4): 325–30.

Health Sector Reforms

105

Page 64: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Montagu, D. 2003. “Accreditation and Other External Quality Assessment Sys-tems for Healthcare: Review of Experience and Lessons Learned.” Health Sys-tems Resource Centre, Department for International Development, London.

Moon, M., L. M. Nichols, and S. Walls. 1997. “Winners and Losers under Medical Savings Accounts.” Spectrum 70 (1): 26–29.

Murray, C. J. L., A. D. Lopez, C. D. Mathers, and C. Stein. 2001. “The Global Bur-den of Disease 2000 Project: Aims, Methods and Data Sources.” ResearchPaper 01.1, Harvard Burden of Disease Unit, Center for Population and Development Studies, Cambridge, MA.

Mutizwa-Mangiza, D. 1998. “The Impact of Health Sector Reform on Public Sec-tor Health Worker Motivation in Zimbabwe.” Major Applied Research 5Working Paper 4, Partnerships for Health Reform Project, Abt Associates Inc.,Bethesda, MD.

Mwabu, G. 1986. “Health Care Decisions at the Household Level: Results of aRural Health Survey in Kenya.” Social Science and Medicine 22 (3): 315–19.

Mwabu, G., M. Ainsworth, and A. Nyamete. 1993. “Quality of Medical Care andChoice of Medical Treatment in Kenya: An Empirical Analysis.” Journal ofHuman Resources 28 (4): 838–62.

Nahar, S., and A. Costello. 1998. “The Hidden Cost of ‘Free’ Maternity Care inDhaka, Bangladesh.” Health Policy and Planning 13 (4): 417–22.

Nanda, P. 2002. “Gender Dimensions of User Fees: Implications for Women’sUtilization of Health Care.” Reproductive Health Matters 10 (20): 127–34.

Newhouse, J. P., and the Insurance Experiment Group. 1993. Free for All? Lessonsfrom the RAND Health Insurance Experiment. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Uni-versity Press.

Newman, J. L., M. Pradhan, L. B. Rawlings, G. Ridder, R. Coa, and J. L. Evia.2002. “An Impact Evaluation of Education, Health, and Water Supply Invest-ments by the Bolivian Social Investment Fund.” World Bank Economic Review16 (2): 241–74.

Newman, J. L., L. B. Rawlings, and P. J. Gertler. 1994. “Using Randomized Con-trol Designs in Evaluating Social Sector Programs in Developing Countries.”World Bank Research Observer 9 (2): 181–201.

Nichols, L. M., K. H. Phua, and N. M. Prescott. 1997. “Medical Savings Accountsfor Developing Countries.” In Innovations in Health Care Financing. Pro-ceedings of a World Bank Conference, March 10–11, 1997, ed. G. Schieber.Washington, DC: World Bank.

Nieves, I., G. M. La Forgia, and J. Ribera. 2000. “Large-Scale Government Con-tracting of NGOs to Extend Basic Health Services to Poor Populations inGuatemala.” World Bank, Washington, DC.

Normand, C., and A. Weber. 1994. Social Health Insurance: A Guidebook for Plan-ning. Geneva: World Health Organization.

Pearson, M. 2001. “Demand Side Financing for Healthcare.” Unpublished manuscript, Health Systems Resource Centre, Department for InternationalDevelopment, London.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

106

Page 65: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

———. 2002. “Allocating Public Resources for Health: Developing Pro-PoorApproaches.” Health Systems Resource Centre, Department for InternationalDevelopment, London.

Preker, A. S., G. Carrin, D. Dror, M. Jakab, W. C. Hsiao, and D. Arhin-Tenkorang.2002a. “Health Care Financing for Rural and Low-Income Populations: TheRole of Communities in Resource Mobilization and Risk Sharing.” Backgroundreport, Commission on Macroeconomics and Health, World Health Organi-zation, Geneva.

———. 2002b. “Effectiveness of Community Health Financing in Meeting theCost of Illness.” Bulletin of the World Health Organization 80 (2): 143–50.

QAP (Quality Assurance Project) and PAHO (Pan American Health Organiza-tion). 2003. “Maximizing Quality of Care through Health Sector Reform: TheRole of Quality Assurance Strategies.” Working draft, Quality AssuranceProject, Bethesda, MD. http://www.qaproject.org/pubs/PDFs/PAHO.pdf.

Rannan-Eliya, R. P., C. Blanco-Vidal, and A. K. Nandakumar. 1999. “The Dis-tribution of Health Care Resources in Egypt: Implications for Equity, AnAnalysis Using a National Health Accounts Framework.” Data for DecisionMaking Project, Department of Population Studies and International Health,Harvard School of Public Health, Boston.

Rao, V., and A. M. Ibanez. 2003. “The Social Impact of Social Funds in Jamaica:A Mixed-Methods Analysis of Participation, Targeting, and Collective Actionin Community-Driven Development.” Policy Research Working Paper 2970,World Bank, Washington, DC.

Ravallion, M. 2003. “Assessing the Poverty Impact of an Assigned Program.” InThe Impact of Economic Policies on Poverty and Income Distribution: Evalua-tion Techniques and Tools, ed. F. Bourguignon and L. Pereira da Silva, 103–22.New York: Oxford University Press.

Ravallion, M., D. van de Walle, and M. Gautam. 1995. “Testing a Social SafetyNet.” Journal of Public Economics 57 (2): 175–99.

Reich, M. R. 1995. “The Politics of Health Sector Reform in Developing Coun-tries: Three Cases of Pharmaceutical Policy.” Health Policy 32 (1–3): 47–77.

Rosenbaum, P. R., and D. B. Rubin. 1983. “The Central Role of the PropensityScore in Observational Studies for Causal Effects.” Biometrika 70 (1): 41–55.

Sandiford, P., A. Gorter, and M. Salvetto. 2002. “Vouchers for Health: UsingVoucher Schemes for Output-Based Aid.” Public Policy for the Private Sec-tor, Viewpoint 243, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Schmeer, K. 2000. “Stakeholder Analysis Guidelines.” In Policy Toolkit forStrengthening Health Sector Reform, ed. S. Scribner and D. Brinkerhoff, 2:1–43. Bethesda, MD: Abt Associates Inc., Bethesda, MD.

Schneider, P., and F. Diop. 2001. Impact of Prepayment Pilot on Health Care Uti-lization and Financing in Rwanda: Findings from Final Household Survey.Bethesda, MD: Partners for Health Reformplus Project, Abt Associates Inc.

Schneider, P., F. Diop, and S. Bucyana. 2000. “Development and Implementa-tion of Prepayment Schemes in Rwanda.” Technical Report 45, Partnershipsfor Health Reform Project, Abt Associates Inc., Bethesda, MD.

Health Sector Reforms

107

Page 66: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

Schultz, T. P., and A. Tansel. 1997. “Wage and Labor Supply Effects of Illness inCôte d’Ivoire and Ghana.” Journal of Development Economics 53 (2): 251–86.

Schwartz, J., J. Akin, and B. M. Popkin. 1988. “Price and Income Elasticities ofDemand for Modern Health Care: The Case of Infant Delivery in the Philip-pines.” World Bank Economic Review 2 (1): 49–76.

Semali, I. A. J. 2003. “Understanding Stakeholders’ Roles in the Health SectorReform Process in Tanzania: The Case of Decentralizing the ImmunizationProgram.” PhD dissertation, University of Basel, Basel, Switzerland.http://pages.unibas.ch/diss/2003/DabsB_6803.pdf.

Sen, A. 1984. “Poor, Relatively Speaking.” In Resources, Values, and Development,ed. A. Sen. New York: Basil Blackwell.

Smith, E., R. Brugha, and A. Zwi. 2001. “Working with Private Sector Providersfor Better Health Care: An Introductory Guide.” Options and London Schoolof Hygiene and Tropical Medicine, London.

Stinson, W. 1982. Community Financing of Primary Health Care. Washington,DC: American Public Health Association.

Strauss, J., and D. Thomas. 1998. “Health, Nutrition, and Economic Develop-ment.” Journal of Economic Literature 36 (2):766–817.

Tang, S., and G. Bloom. 2000, “Decentralizing Rural Health Services: A Case Studyin China.” International Journal of Health Planning and Management 15 (3):189–200.

Tanzi, V., and H. Zee. 2001. “Tax Policy for Developing Countries.” EconomicIssues 27, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

Tawfik, L., and S. N. Kinoti. 2003. “The Impact of HIV/AIDS on Health Systemsand the Health Workforce in Sub-Saharan Africa.” Unpublished manuscript,Support for Analysis and Research in Africa Project, Office of SustainableDevelopment, Bureau for Africa, U.S. Agency for International Development,Washington, DC.

Telyukov, A. 2001. “Guide to Prospective Capitation with Illustrations fromLatin America.” Abt Associates Inc., Bethesda, MD.

Thomason, J. A., W. C. Newbrander, and R.-L. Kolehmainen-Aitken, eds. 1991.“Decentralization in a Developing Country: The Experience of Papua NewGuinea and Its Health Service.” Pacific Research Monograph 25, NationalCentre for Development Studies, Australian National University, Canberra.

van de Walle, D. 2002. “The Static and Dynamic Incidence of Vietnam’s PublicSafety Net.” Policy Research Working Paper 2791, Public Services, Develop-ment Research Group, World Bank, Washington, DC.

van de Walle, D., and K. Nead, eds. 1995. Public Spending and the Poor: Theoryand Evidence. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Vian, T., K. Gryboski, Z. Sinoimeri, and R. Hall Clifford. 2004. “Informal Pay-ments in the Public Health Sector in Albania: A Qualitative Study.” Partnersfor Health Reformplus Project, Abt Associates Inc., Bethesda, MD.

Wagstaff, A. 1999. “Measuring Equity in Health Care Financing: Reflections on(and Alternatives to) the World Health Organization’s Fairness of FinancingIndex.” Policy Research Working Paper 2550, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

108

Page 67: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

———. 2000a. Presentation to London Meeting on Health and Equity, Departmentfor International Development, London. Cited in Bennett and Gilson (2001).

———. 2000b. “Socioeconomic Inequalities in Child Mortality: Comparisonsacross Nine Developing Countries.” Bulletin of the World Health Organization78 (1): 19–29.

———. 2002. “Poverty and Health Sector Inequalities.” Bulletin of the WorldHealth Organization 80 (2): 97–105.

Wagstaff, A., and E. van Doorslaer. 2002. “Catastrophe and Impoverishment inPaying for Health Care: With Applications to Vietnam, 1993–98.” Unpub-lished manuscript, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Wagstaff, A., E. van Doorslaer, H. van der Burg, et al. 1999. “Equity in theFinance of Health Care: Some Further International Comparisons.” Journalof Health Economics 18 (3): 263–90.

Walsh, J. A., and K. S. Warren. 1979. “Selective Primary Health Care: An InterimStrategy for Disease Control in Developing Countries.” New England Journalof Medicine 301 (18): 967–74.

Walt, G., and L. Gilson. 1994. “Reforming the Health Sector in DevelopingCountries: The Central Role of Policy Analysis.” Health Policy and Planning9 (4): 353–70.

Wang, L. 2003. “Determinants of Child Mortality in LDCs: Empirical Findingsfrom Demographic and Health Surveys.” Health Policy 65 (3): 277–99.

Whitehead, M., G. Dahlgren, and T. Evans. 2001. “Equity and Health SectorReforms: Can Low-Income Countries Escape the Medical Poverty Trap?” TheLancet 358 (9284): 833–36.

WHO (World Health Organization). 1998. “Gender and Health: A TechnicalPaper.” World Health Organization, Geneva. http://www.who.int/docstore/frh-whd/GandH/GHreport/gendertech.htm.

———. 2000a. The World Health Report 2000: Health Systems, Improving Per-formance. Geneva: World Health Organization.

———. 2000b. How to Develop and Implement a National Drug Policy. 2nd ed.Geneva: World Health Organization.

———. 2003. Guide to Producing National Health Accounts. Geneva: World HealthOrganization.

Wiesmann, D., and J. Jütting. 2000. “The Emerging Movement of CommunityBased Health Insurance in Sub-Saharan Africa: Experiences and LessonsLearned.” Afrika Spectrum 2/2000: 193–210.

Woolcock, M. 2001. “Social Assessments and Program Evaluation with LimitedFormal Data: Thinking Quantitatively, Acting Qualitatively.” Social Develop-ment Briefing Note 68, World Bank, Washington, DC.

World Bank. 1993. World Development Report 1993: Investing in Health. NewYork: Oxford University Press.

———. 1997a. World Development Report 1997: The State in a Changing World.New York: Oxford University Press.

———. 1997b. Confronting AIDS. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Health Sector Reforms

109

Page 68: THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM Tsiteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/... · THE FUNCTION OF A PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM T he purpose of Poverty and Social Impact Analysis

———. 2002. World Development Report 2003: Sustainable Development in aDynamic World. New York: Oxford University Press.

———. 2003a. World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for PoorPeople. New York: Oxford University Press.

———. 2003b. A User’s Guide to Poverty and Social Impact Analysis. Washington,DC: Poverty Reduction Group and Social Development Department, WorldBank.

Wyss, K., D. D. Moto, and B. Callewaert. 2001. “Improving Health Outcomes ofthe Poor: Constraints to Scaling Up Health Interventions, Country CaseStudy, Chad.” Working Group 5, Commission on Macroeconomics andHealth, World Health Organization, Geneva. (In French).

Xu, K., D. Evans, K. Kawabata, R. Zeramdini, J. Klavus, and C. Murray. 2003.“Household Catastrophic Health Expenditure: A Multicountry Analysis.” TheLancet 362 (9378): 111–17.

Yazbeck, A. S., and M. Wenner. 1994. “Social Financing in Niger.” MajorApplied Research Working Paper 15. Health Financing and SustainabilityProject, Abt Associates Inc., Bethesda, MD.

Yip, W., and P. A. Berman. 2001. “Targeted Health Insurance in a Low-IncomeCountry and Its Impact on Access and Equity in Access: Egypt’s School HealthInsurance.” Health Economics 10 (3): 207–20.

Younger, S. D. 2003. “Benefits on the Margin: Observations on Marginal Bene-fit Incidence.” World Bank Economic Review 17 (1): 89–106.

Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms

110