the effects of trade openness and democratic institutions on income inequality cross-national...

Upload: trin-aiyara

Post on 07-Apr-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    1/56

    1

    The Effects of Trade openness and Democratic

    Institutions on Income Inequality: Cross-National

    Analysis and The Case study of Thailand.

    Student Registration Number

    4477022

    A Dissertation Submitted to the School of International Development of

    the University of East Anglia in Part-fulfillment of the Requirements for

    the Degree of Master of Arts in Development Economics

    September 2010

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    2/56

    2

    Word Count: 11996

    (Excluding references and appendix)

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    3/56

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    4/56

    4

    4.2 Methodology.17

    4.2.1 Data.17

    4.2.2 Econometric Specification..18

    4.3 Econometric results..20

    5. Case study of Thailand..29

    5.1 Trade openness.32

    5.2 Democratic institution..35

    6. Concluding remarks...39

    List of references.41

    Appendix 1: List of countries in cross-national analysis.49

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    5/56

    5

    Acknowledgements

    First of all, I am indebted to Dr. Edward Anderson, who is the supervisor of this

    dissertation. I have been usually received invaluable advices and exceptional patient for this

    dissertation from him. Without his helps, I would have much more trouble in writing my

    dissertation. I was also gained his assistances on my coursework, which definitely have

    contributions to the construction of ground idea of this dissertation. I would also like to

    thank Dr. Pieter Serneels, who made a helpful discussion which shaped and formulated the

    structure of this dissertation.

    Additionally, I am appreciated for hospitality and sympathy that people in the school

    of International Development at University of East Anglia gave me during short but

    memorable year. With their kindness, my life in foreign soil would be not too bitter, because

    they not only helped me to deal with difficult academic tasks, but also enjoy with delightful

    social activities. Without their helps, this dissertation would be tortured part of my higher

    education life.

    Also, I would like to thank Isariya Suttakulpiboon, who is my proof-reader. Without

    him, my dissertation will be contains many grammatical errors.

    Finally, I feel deeply thankful with my family who has usually allocated their

    resources to my costly education, which can be one of the most valuable assets in my life.

    Without them, my academic life would not be gone so far like today.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    6/56

    6

    1.IntroductionNowadays, a number of academics and practitioners in the fields of development

    studies widely accept that the goals of development are not only an improvement of the well-

    being or accumulation of prosperity, but also argue that development missions should also

    take mitigation of inequality into account, because the inequality is seen as potentially

    having negative effects on developmental processes. One of the negative effects that often

    mentioned is that higher income inequality could prolong a state of massive poverty, since it

    tends to reduce the ability of economic growth to contribute to poverty reduction (see

    example from Ravallion (2001) for cross-national evidence; Khan and Sen (2006) for evidence of

    Bangladesh). Another negative effect is that higher inequality could cause social unrest, such

    as crime and violence, which could obstruct development process and make social capital

    and trust deteriorate (Wade, 2007).

    At the same time, it has been argued that countries in the world are experiencing the

    third wave of economic globalization, and political globalization, in the form of

    democratization (Haynes, 2008). As perceived by several people, many countries have

    increased their degree of participation in international trade. The increased degree of

    international trade participation could be shownby the fact that world exports of goods andservices have nearly tripled during 1990-2007 moreover, the ratio of trades of the developing

    countries expanded from 34 percent in 1990 to 62 percent in 2008 (World Bank, 2010b).

    Simultaneously, many societies, especially developing countries, have been experiencing

    gradually democratic transitions and a rise in political equality on their own soil. According

    to Freedom House (2003), in the mid 2000s, democratic general elections were held in three

    quarters of the countries in the world. Compared to the end of 1980s, only almost half of

    those countries could be classified as democratic regimes (Huntington, 1991).

    Influentially, these two recognitions construct the main question of this dissertation.

    The main question - do trade openness and democratic transitions affect income inequality at

    national level and if so, how? However, in order to be more precise, this dissertation mainly

    focuses on inequality in terms of income inequality.

    In order to answer the main question, the structure of this dissertation consists of six

    sections. Following the introduction, the dissertation will describe theoretical perspectives

    that relate to the main question. The next section will illustrate previous empirical studiesthat could provide a clearer picture for the main question. Subsequently, an econometric

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    7/56

    7

    analysis will be used for finding systematic relationships of trade openness, democratic

    transitions and income inequality. Thereafter, the case study analysis of Thailand will be

    analyzed, in order to discover how income inequality in Thai society has been affected by

    trade openness and democratic transitions. The time frame of the case study will be the

    periods of the mid 1980s to late 2000s. Finally, the concluding section will summarize the

    main issues in this dissertation.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    8/56

    8

    2. Theoretical perspectives

    This section will discuss about theories that have a potential to answer the question

    that how trade openness and democracy affect inequality, particularly intra-national income

    gap. This section will begin by giving a description of theories on trade openness and

    inequality. Next, the theories on democracy and inequality will be described.

    2.1 Trade openness and income inequality

    2.1.1 Heckscher-Ohlin trade theory

    The Heckscher-Ohlin trade theory (HO) anticipates the change in income distribution

    from greater trade openness by focusing on the income gap of different production factors.

    This theory states that a country tends to export goods, which intensively use relative

    abundant factors, and import more commodities, which intensively use relative scarce

    factors, instead of producing them (Salvatore, 1993). Accordingly, the expansion of export

    activities will increase demand for comparatively abundant production factors, which could

    rise earning of the abundant factors; simultaneously, the demand for comparatively scarce

    production will be decreased that could make earning of the scarce factors lower (Salvatore,

    1993; Wood, 1997; Bourguignon and Morrison, 1989).

    With referring to the simplest version of the HO, when the developing countries

    implement trade liberalization policies, the income inequality in those countries will

    decrease, and vice versa for the developed countries. The reason is that when developing

    countries open their economies, the wage of unskilled worker in those developing countries

    will increase, and vice versa for the wage of skilled labors; the decreased wage gap will

    narrow income inequality (Anderson, 2005; Wood, 1997). This prediction, however, is

    grounded on some assumptions. One main assumption is that developing countries are

    relatively abundant in unskilled labors; another assumption is that unskilled labor may be an

    asset that is most equally distributed among people in developing countries (Anderson,

    2005). In brief, HO predicts that trade liberalization could reduce income inequality in

    developing countries because it decreases the earnings disparity between unskilled workers

    and other production factors.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    9/56

    9

    Nonetheless, according to recent studies, there could be many other factors that make

    HO provide an inaccurate prediction on inequality in developing countries. Theoretically,

    trade liberalization might enable developing countries companies to import more capital

    goods, and adopt more skilled biased technologies (Thoenig and Verdier, 2003; Goldberg

    and Pavcnik, 2007). The changing behaviors of these companies will push demand for

    skilled labors upward in these developing countries, since the utilization of imported capital

    goods requires higher share of skilled labor. Accordingly, higher demand for skilled labors

    will probably make wages of skilled labors higher and income gap will be expanded.

    2.1.2 Spatial inequality and economic geography

    Generally, trade openness not only leads to a change in factors earning gap, but also

    spatial inequality. This could be seen from the situation that when a country participate in

    international trade, some regions, which have greater concentration of international

    economic activities, tend to reach better level of development, e.g., higher income per capita,

    than other regions (Kanbur and Venables, 2007). The unequal concentration of international

    economic activities across different regions could be the causes of inequality (Williamson,

    2002).

    In order to understand the causes of openness-led spatial inequality in domestic level,

    the question - why international economic activities are concentrated in some regions has

    to be answered. The precise answers could be provided by the theory of economic

    geography. This theory states that the concentration of industries can be the result of the first

    and second nature geography (Venables, 2005; Kanbur and Venables, 2007). The first nature

    refers to the condition that some regions are advantaged by their geographical

    characteristics, such as coasts, rivers ports, and borders.

    Apart from the first nature, the second nature could be the positive effects of

    proximity on behaviors and interactions of economic agents in the cluster areas (Venables,

    2005; Kanbur and Venables, 2007). Firstly, firms in densely areas tend to gain benefits from

    technological spillovers from higher technological advanced firms. Secondly, labor market

    in densely area could be more efficient, since firms could easily find suitable specialized

    labors. Meanwhile, labors tend to have incentives to learn and acquire special skills that

    match the employers demand. Thirdly, the densely area firms could gain advantages from

    increasing return to scale, because of the large size of market; simultaneously, the large scale

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    10/56

    10

    of production will attract suppliers of intermediate goods and services. In a nutshell, the

    presence of the first and second nature tends to attract industries to locate in the cluster areas;

    consequently, the concentration of industry in cluster areas will lead to widened spatial gap.

    However, in some cases, trade openness may also reduce spatial inequality in the

    domestic level. A case in point is that, in inward-looking economies, firms prefer to locate

    closer to national center because they can easily access to domestic market; on the contrary,

    when outward-looking policies are implemented, the firms will have less incentive to locate

    in the centre areas, since they could comfortably access to foreign commodity and

    production factor market (Fujita, Krugman and Venables, 1999). As a result, in this kind of

    economies, trade openness will narrow the gap between centre and periphery, because of the

    emergence of new industrial clusters that move away from national centre.

    2.2 Democracy and income inequality

    There is a generally recognition that democracy, which can be the representation of

    political equality, could lead to the establishment of economic inequality1. This recognition

    could be supported by some theories that emphasize the role of democratic institutions.

    Theoretically, democracy tends to mitigate inequality within societies since

    democracy could allow the majority to possess equally political rights, which provide them a

    chance to participate in public policy decisions, through legitimated political movements.

    (Lenski, 1966; Reuveny and Li, 2003; Nel, 2008). As a result, the pro-equity policies, which

    could enhance the well-being of the majority and reduce gap between elites and ordinary

    people, will be implemented.

    1 It has to be mentioned that democracy, theoretically, not only affect inequality, but it can also be affected by

    the existence of inequality; however, this topic is not the main concern of the dissertation. This topic could be

    further read from Muller (1997); Acemouglu and Robinson (2006).

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    11/56

    11

    2.2.1 Median voter theorem

    Particularly, the impacts of democracy on economic inequality are often analyzed via

    median voter theorem. This theorem explains that the majority of voters, who tend to have

    income below the average income level, usually insist political elites to implementredistributive policies by voting in general election (Alesina and Rodrik, 1994; Nel, 2008;

    Acemouglu and Robinson, 2000). It could be said that, in the democratic societies, general

    election can be used by the mass as means to force governments to respond their demand for

    redistribution.

    However, in developing countries, general election might not guarantee the

    realization of redistributive. Nel (2008: 103) argues that democratic regimes in developing

    countries tend to have constraints on political participation of citizens, even there is a general

    election in these countries. The constraints are network of patron-client relationships,

    immature party politics and absence of free press. This could not make citizens effectively

    control elites in the process of public policy decision. As a result, pro-equity policies are less

    likely to be carried out, because elites tend to implement the policies that serve their

    interests. Lack of accountability to citizens is also a contributing factor to this situation as

    well.

    Theoretically, the presence of democratic institutions, i.e. general election, might

    not be the necessary political means of the mass for pressuring governments to respond to

    the peoples demand for redistribution. This point could be seen from the work of Alesina

    and Rodrik (1994: 478), which argues that, in non-democratic regimes, citizens could force

    governments to implement redistributive policies by exploitation of social demands and

    social conflicts. On the contrary to Alesina and Rodrik, citizens in non-democratic societies

    tend to hardly achieve their redistributive demand because citizens in these societies could

    be more easily abused by governments than citizens in democratic state.

    2.2.2 Democracy and size of public sector

    To be more precise, some theories point out that, in the democratic societies,

    expansion of public sector could mitigate income inequality; on the contrary, to non-

    democratic societies, expansion of public sector is associated with higher income inequality.For instance, Lee (2005: 163) explains that consolidated democratic institutions can be an

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    12/56

    12

    important factor to reverse the positive relationship between government size and income

    inequality to become negative. The reason is that expanding democratic government size

    usually goes hand in hand with the realization of subordinate classs demand for

    redistributive policies. Contrarily, in non-democratic regimes, expansion of public sector

    tends to worsen income inequality since states resources are more likely to be used to serve

    elites interests. Shortly, in democratic societies, expansion of public sector could lead to the

    reduction of income inequality.

    However, in developing societies, democratic governments could not expand their

    size due to lack of capacity in generating government revenues (Nel, 2008). The insufficient

    capacity could make government difficult to implement redistributive policies.

    Consequently, these policies may not be implemented by the governments because they

    might not have enough resources to cover huge cost of the policies.

    2.3 Trade openness, democracy and inequality

    Since the beginning of this section, it has shown the theories that separately discuss

    about the effects of solely trade openness or democratic institutions on income inequality,

    yet it has not illustrated the theory, which attempts to answer the following questions. Does

    the effect of trade openness on income inequality depend on type of political institutions?

    How political institutions impact income inequality in the condition of trade openness?

    There are some scholars that attempt to construct the aforementioned theory. Some

    scholars point out that the existence of trade openness could lead to expansion of

    government size, i.e. enlargement of public spending. Initially, trade openness, could bring

    greater volatility to domestic income because greater openness make an economy more

    vulnerable to external shocks (Rodrik, 1998). Consequently, the volatility will stimulate

    demand for expansion of government expenditure in order to deal with greater risks from

    trade openness. Also, trade openness simultaneously creates winners and losers. Thus,

    openness might drive government to implement spending on safety nets, such as

    compensation of employment losses, from the losers for greater trade openness (Adsera and

    Boix, 2002).

    However, greater trade openness may not lead to expansion of public sector in somesocieties, especially authoritarian ones. Theoretically, trade openness could lead to

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    13/56

    13

    minimization of government spending in the authoritarian states (Adsera and Boix, 2002).

    The reason is that authoritarian governments partly lose the ability to generate income,

    because of the reduced income from import tariffs. Meanwhile they could not implement

    higher income tax rate or tax on private property since it will push greater burden to political

    elites. The minimized public spending will lead to degradation of social welfare and thus

    widen income gap.

    Contrarily, in democratic regimes, governments usually expand the compensation

    spending for the losers of trade openness since governments have incentives to implement

    social spending and progressive tax system for gaining political support from the citizens

    (Adsera and Boix, 2002). In summary, it could be said that the effects of trade openness on

    inequality differs between democratic and authoritarian regimes. The reason could be that, in

    the conditions of trade openness, income inequality in democratic societies tends to be lower

    than that in non-democratic ones because democratic governments rather compensate the

    openness-led losers than authoritarian states do.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    14/56

    14

    3.Existing empirical evidences3.1 Cross-national studies

    Intentionally,this part will describe several existing studies using cross-national datathat attempt to discover the systematic effects of trade openness and democracy on income

    inequality. Regularly, the studies assess income inequality, in term of aggregate

    measurement, such as Gini coefficient, the ratio of share of in national income of the richest

    20 per cent, to the share of 20 per cent poorest. These researchers usually calculate data on

    income inequality from many existing sources, e.g. household survey of Deininger and

    Squire (1996) and World Income Distribution (WYD) database, which is a part of Global

    Income Inequality project, by Milanovic (1999).

    3.1.1 Trade openness and income inequality

    There are many researchers that study about the relationship between trade openness

    and inequality. Normally, these researchers indicate degree of trade openness via trade

    intensity, e.g., the ratio of international trade to GDP. In addition, some researchers measure

    the degree of openness from trade policies, such as tariffs or quantitative restrictions. Some

    researchers also employs Sachs-Warner index (1995)2, which takes quantitative restrictions

    and socio-economic structures, e.g., type of economy (capitalist or socialist) and states

    monopoly of major export, into account for measuring degree of openness.

    On the one hand, some studies show that there could be positive relationship

    between trade openness and inequality. For example, Barro (2000), who constructs the

    single-year panel model, which contains sample of 68-84 countries in 1960, 1970, 1980, and

    1990. According to the model, Barro states that greater trade ratio will lead to higher Gini

    coefficient. Likewise, Lundberg and Squire (2003) also conclude that greater trade openness

    could increase inequality for model that include sample of 147 countries during 1960-94, due

    to positive relationship between Gini coefficient and Sachs-Warner index.

    On the other hand, some researchers argue that greater trade openness could lead to a

    decline in income inequality. For instance, Edwards (1997) who constructs the model

    comprises of 44 countries sample data, including 27 developing countries during 1970-80.

    2 Further details of the index can be seen in Sachs and Warner (1995).

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    15/56

    15

    As reported in his paper, Edward claims that implementation of less distorted policies, could

    mitigate inequality. Additionally, Calderon and Chong (2001) point out that trade openness,

    which is shown by trade volume, has a negative relationship with the Gini coefficient, by

    applying the model using unbalanced panel five-year average data in the period of 1960-95.

    Nonetheless, some studies argue that trade liberalization might not affect inequality.

    For example, Dollar and Kraay (2002) attempt to prove the hypothesis that whether greater

    trade liberalization lead to higher income inequality or not. They point out that change in

    trade ratio does not affect change in the Gini coefficient and change in the income share of

    20% poorest for panel data sample of 130 countries.

    Furthermore, to be more advanced, some researchers take endowment factors into

    account, for testing the hypothesis of the Heckscher-Ohlin trade theory, which claims that

    effects of trade openness on inequality depend on endowment factors of an economy.

    Generally, some studies employ level of GDP per capita to be the proxy of endowment

    factors. A case in point is that Ravallions study (2001), applied dataset of Li Squire and Zou

    (1998) that cover 112 countries for the years 1947-94. He attempted to test Heckscher-Ohlin

    theorys hypothesis by creating interactive variables of ratio of export to GDP and initial

    GDP per capita. He found that greater openness will lead to an increase in inequality in

    developing countries, according to the values of coefficient of export ratio and interactivevariable, which are positive and negative, respectively.

    To be more precisely, some studies prove Heckscher-Ohlins hypothesis by directly

    usage of production factors per capita or amount of production factors instead of level of

    GDP per capita. For instance, Spilimbergo, Londono and Szekery (1999), who constructed a

    panel model that covers sample of 320 observations for 34 countries in the period of 1965-

    92. They apply arable land and stock of capital per worker as proxies of endowments in land

    and capital, respectively. They also measure endowment in skilled labors via proportion of

    population over the age of 25 with higher education. In order to prove Heckscher-Ohlins

    hypothesis, they create interactive variable of factors endowment (land, capital and skilled

    labors) and trade volume ratio. According to the model, they claim that greater trade volume

    will lead to an increase in income inequality in skilled labors abundant countries, and a

    decline in income inequality in land and capital abundant countries.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    16/56

    16

    3.1.2 Democracy on income inequality

    Many researchers try to prove the hypothesis whether democratic regimes have

    impacts on economic inequality, especially income disparity. The variables, which are

    usually applied as proxies of the quality of democracy, are index on political regimes fromThe POLITY IV Project dataset, and Freedom Houses index on political rights and civil

    liberties. Usually, some studies employs dummy variable for democratic regimes, instead of

    directly using index to represent political regimes. However, the categorization of this kind

    dummy variable usually refers to score from the mentioned political databases3. Particularly,

    some researchers create their own variable on democracy, for example, Boix (2003) create

    dichotomous variables that ground on his criteria on democracy.

    There are cross-national studies which try to test the hypothesis whether higher level

    of democracy, in term of high value of index on democratic societies, will lead to a lower

    level of inequality. For example, Muller (1988) describes that countries with higher index on

    democracy, tend to reach lower level of income inequality for sample of 55 countries in the

    period of 1965-75.

    Also, there are some researchers, who utilize dummy variable for democratic

    societies for testing the hypothesis that countries, which are consolidated democratic

    societies, tend to reach lower level of income inequality than other kinds of societies do.

    Taking the study of Rudra (2004) as an example, it shows that the level of income inequality

    in developing countries, which are democratic regimes, tends to be lower than that of non-

    democratic developing societies, regarding to the value of dummy variables for democracy.

    Nonetheless, democracy might have no impacts on inequality, according to some

    researchers. For example, Bollen and Jackman (1985) illustrate that the change in level of

    political democracy (Bollens index) has no systematic effect on the change in income

    inequality, by using sample data of 60 countries.

    As stated in theoretical perspective section, the effect of democratic regime on

    income inequality is potentially dictated government sizes. According to this theoretical

    viewpoint, some researches create interactive variables of government size, which can be

    shown by the share of government consumption/spending to GDP or the ratio of current tax

    revenue of the central government to national income, and dummy variable for democratic

    3 The examples could be shown by Rudra (2004), and Lee (2005)

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    17/56

    17

    societies, in order to test the hypothesis whether the expansion of government size in

    developing countries is associated with declining in income inequality.

    A case in point is that the study of Lee (2005), which constructs interactive variable

    of tax revenue ratio (government size) and dummy variables for institutionalized democratic

    regimes. He reports that the sign of coefficient of this interactive variable is negative, while

    the sign of government revenues ratio is positive by applying sample data of 64 countries

    that covering 25 years. Consequently, he affirms that institutionalized democracy could

    reverse the relationship of government size to income inequality from positive to negative. In

    other words, it could be concluded that, in democratic societies, bigger government size

    could be correlated with a decline in income inequality.

    3.1.3 Trade openness, Democracy, and Inequality

    Nowadays, there might be no study that attempt to answer the question that whether

    the effect of trade openness on inequality might be different according to whether a country

    is democratic or not. Concurrently, there seems to be no researchers that attempt to answer

    the question that whether the effect of democracy on inequality might be different according

    to whether a country is open to trade or not.

    Although they might not directly answer to these above questions, there are some

    studies try to answer the question about the effects of trade openness on change in size of

    government whether they are resulted from level of democratic development. Taking Adsera

    and Boix (2002) as an example, in order to answer this question, they construct explanatory

    interactive variables of dummy variable for competitive democratic regimes and ratio of

    trade volume to GDP, and they uses a proportion of government revenues to GDP, which is

    the proxy of government size, as a dependent variable.According to coefficient of the interactive variable, they show that when economy is

    liberalized, government spending in democratic and authoritarian societies increase in

    different rates (5-28% in authoritarian states; 10-33% for democratic societies) by adopting

    sample of 65 countries from 1950 to 1990. With regards to the study of Adsera and Boix, it

    could be concluded that under the conditions of trade openness, democratic countries could

    be less unequal in income distribution than that in authoritarian societies, because of larger

    government spending.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    18/56

    18

    3.2 Case Studies

    There is some research that analyzing the effects of international integration and

    democracy on inequality by application of case study analysis of individual country. The

    case study analysis might provide understanding on channels of effects of trade openness

    and democratic institutions on inequality.

    3.2.1 East Asian countries (South Korea and Taiwan)

    The case study of East Asian countries could provide understanding about the effects

    of trade openness and democracy on inequality. Interestingly, these countries have

    experienced constantly high economic growth (about 7 per cent per annual), as well as

    relatively low levels of income inequality during 1965-90 (Birdsall, Ross and Sabot, 1995).

    In particular, the case of East Asian countries might match with the prediction of

    Heckscher-Ohlin trade theory - trade openness could mitigate income inequality in

    developing countries - because of wage gap reduction. This can be seen from work of Wood

    (1997: 42), which states that after more outward-orientation had been implemented, the wage

    gap between skilled and unskilled labors in South Korea and Taiwan was narrowed. Thenarrowed wage gap could be resulted from outward-orientation policies that stimulated

    demand for unskilled workers, leading to higher wage of unskilled labors (Wood, 1997).

    Additionally, the decline in income inequality in South Korea and Taiwan could be

    resulted from the democratic transitions forcing both countries governments to increase

    their size via expansion of social spending. Empirically, in Taiwan and South Korea, after

    democratization processes took place, the public spending on education and social security

    had increased in terms of absolute dollar per capita expenditure in the periods of 1965-94

    (Chan, 1997). Particularly, in South Korea, the expanded education could also be pro-equity

    policies since the budget on education service has been largely spent to primary and

    secondary education while only 10 percent of the budget has been spent on higher education.

    Additionally, the expansion of education can be prominent roots of income inequality and

    wage gap in South Korea (Birdsall, Ross and Sabot, 1995; Woods, 1997). It could be

    concluded that in both countries, the expansion of public spending tends to be pro-equity.

    In short, it could be said that trade openness and democratic transitions could be the

    roots of a decrease in income inequality in Taiwan and South Korea. The reason is that

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    19/56

    19

    openness and democracy mitigate inequality via reduction wage inequality and expansion of

    social spending on education.

    3.2.2 Post-reformed China

    Although China is located in the same geographical location as South Korea and

    Taiwan, its economic experience tends to be different from those neighbor countries. The

    difference could be seen from the situation that Chinese economy has been experienced

    constantly spread of income disparity since the 1980s when several reformation policies

    were implemented (Kanbur and Zhang, 2005). This situation could be illustrated by the

    increase of the Gini coefficient from 28.6 percent in 1979 to 37.2 in 2000.

    In the case of post-reformed Chinese economy, greater trade openness4, which is one

    of reformation policies, could be one of the important factors of an increase in income

    inequality. The reason could be that greater trade openness led to the widening in regional

    gap, according to some studies. For instance, Zhang and Zhang (2003: Table 2) states that

    the regional gap could be illustrated by the difference in GDP per capita in 1992-1998

    between Eastern coastal areas and inland areas, which reached 3055 and 1489 Chinese Yuan,

    respectively. They also demonstrate that greater trade openness coincides with the change in

    regional Gini coefficient, which increased from 0.19 in 1980, to 0.26 in 1998.

    The openness-led regional inequality in post-reformed Chinese economy could be

    resulted from the unequal participation in international trade activities between coastal and

    inland areas. This statement could be supported by the facts that, during 1992-1998, coastal

    areas are the regions that possess the lion share of international trade (88.08%), while inland

    areas possess small share of international trade (Zhang and Zhang, 2003).

    Also, the change in income inequality in post-reformed China might be determined

    by political factors, which seem to be non-democratic. Although China could be classified asan authoritarian state, there has been an election for village committee since the late 1980s

    (Shen and Yao, 2008). Some studies argue that village committee election could mitigate

    income inequality via expansion of public investment and changing in tax structure. For

    example, Zhang et al (2004: 2869) report that election make village committees tend to shift

    tax burden from households to village enterprises. Concurrently, the committees are forced

    by electoral processes to increase the share of public investment and reduce the wasteful

    4 This could be shown by Zhang and Zhang (2003), who show that during 1978-98, the increasing of trade

    volume ratio from 9.80% to 34.42%.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    20/56

    20

    spending in village expenditures. Accordingly, this kind might lead to a decline in income

    inequality.

    However, election for village committee might not effectively serve demand of

    citizens since the election tend to confront with institutional constraints that imposed by

    authoritarian characteristics of Chinese state (Shen and Yao, 2008). This anticipation might

    correspond with the fact that income inequality in Chinese has been constantly increasing in

    last two decades, despite there have been presence of village election.

    Briefly, the continual increase in income inequality in Chinese economy could be

    resulted by greater participation in international trade because greater participation leads to

    worsened regional inequality. Meanwhile, Chinese political factors might have a little

    contribution to improvement of income distribution since these political factors provide a

    limited chance to citizens to participate in policy decision processes.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    21/56

    21

    4.Econometric analysisIn this section, a set of regressions will be conducted in order to test the hypotheses

    that mainly focus on the relationships between trade openness, political regimes, and income

    inequality. Intentionally, these hypotheses are planned to be means of revealing the answers

    of the dissertations main question. Each hypothesis detail will be shown below.

    4.1 Hypotheses

    These following hypotheses will be tested in this section.

    Hypothesis 1: Greater trade openness is associated with higher income inequality inboth developed and developing countries.

    Hypothesis 2: The effect of trade openness on income inequality depends on incomelevel of countries, regarding Heckscher-Ohlin theory. Greater trade openness could

    mitigate income inequality in relatively low-income countries, but aggravate

    inequality in relatively high-income countries.

    Hypothesis 3: As stated by Heckscher-Ohlin theory, the effect of trade openness onincome inequality depends on the abundant production factors in particular

    economies. Greater trade openness will lead to a decline in income inequality in

    unskilled-labor abundant economies, and vice versa for skilled-labors and land

    abundant economies.

    Hypothesis 4: The presence of democratic institutions (free press, competitiveelection, protected political and civil rights, and stabilized democratic regimes) is

    associated with lower income inequality. On the contrary to democratic societies, the

    presence of authoritarian institutions is associated with higher income inequality.

    Hypothesis 5: On the one hand, in the democratic societies, expansion ofgovernment size tends to be associated with lower income inequality. On the other

    hand, in the authoritarian states, government expansion tends to be associated with a

    rise in income inequality.

    Hypothesis 6: In democratic societies, the negative effects of trade openness onincome distribution will be lowered. On the contrary, in authoritarian states, the

    negative effects of openness on income inequality will be higher. Theoretically,

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    22/56

    22

    democratic governments usually compensate the losers from globalization, via

    expansion of public size, but authoritarian tends to ignore the losers.

    As reported in the existing empirical evidences, Hypothesis 1 to Hypothesis 5 was

    already tested by previous studies, except Hypothesis 6 that might have not been tested. This

    section will test Hypothesis 6 since there might be few studies which try to explain whether

    the effect of trade openness differs between democratic and authoritarian regime.

    4.2 Methodology

    4.2.1 Data

    This section mainly uses the data from the panel (both cross-national and times-

    series) dataset of Dollar and Kraay (2002). This panel dataset provides data on Gini

    coefficient, which cover sample of 137 countries5

    during 1956-99, real GDP per capita6, and

    ratio of trade (exports plus imports) to GDP. The dataset also supplies data on the share of

    government consumption to GDP, average arable land per worker, and average stock years

    of primary and secondary education.

    This section employs index of political regimes data from two reliable sources: The

    POLITY IV Project and Freedom House. Particularly, the score of The Polity IV Project

    dataset mainly focuses on characteristics of governing authority of states. The Polity IV

    Projects score rates the authority characteristics from -10 (hereditary monarchy) to +10

    (consolidated democracy), regarding to CSP and INSCR (2010a). The dataset of The Polity

    IV Project is available online at webpage of Regime Authority Characteristics and

    Transitions Datasets (CSP and INSCR, 2010b)7.

    Unlike Polity IVs score, the score of Freedom House primarily emphasizes on

    political rights and civil liberties. The values of score of Freedom House are rated between 1

    (most free) and 7 (least free) (Freedom House, 2010a). The dataset of Freedom House is

    5 The list of countries is shown in Appendix 1.6 GDP per capita is constant at 1985 US Dollars at purchasing power parity.7 This webpages URL is http://www.systemicpeace.org/inscr/inscr.htm viewed 29/07/2010.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    23/56

    23

    available online at section of Freedom in the World Comparative and Historical Data

    (Freedom House, 2010b)8.

    4.2.2 Economic specification

    Like previous studies,this section utilizes Gini coefficient as the dependent variable

    since Gini coefficient could clearly illustrate the situation income inequality in the domestic

    level. The baseline equation is as follows.

    1 2 3 4 53 51 2 4ct ct ct ct ct ct ctX XY X X X

    Where c and t index countries and years, respectively. is constant term of the

    equation. 1X is proxy of degree of openness. 2X is proxy of government size. 3X is

    proxy of democratic societies. 4X is proxy of authoritarian regimes. 5X is the set of

    controlling variables: economic growth, endowments of production factors.

    On explanatory variables, the dissertation, firstly, employs the ratio of trade volume

    to GDP as a proxy of degree of trade openness, rather than other variables that relating to

    trade restriction policies because, trade volume ratio tends to be more directly indicator of

    degree of participation in international trade9. Secondly, the dissertation uses average

    proportion of government consumption to GDP to be proxy of government size. This usage

    of variable follows the Rodriks study (1998).

    Moreover, this section constructs two separated sets of dummy variables for political

    regimes or societies. The categorization of dummy variables relies on political score of twodatabases: the POLITY IV Project and Freedom House. The reason for application of

    dummy variables instead of score on political regimes/rights from these databases is that the

    value of databases score is bounded in fixed range, so it should be more suitable to use

    dummy variable rather than directly usage of political score.

    The first dummy variable set is the category variables of democratic and

    authoritarian regime. The construction of these dummy variables is relied on the value of

    8 This sections URL is http://www.freedomhouse.org/template.cfm?page=439 viewed 29/07/2010.9 This kind of argument could be seen in Rodriks work (2007: 216-7).

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    24/56

    24

    Polity IV projects score: countries are classified as consolidated democratic regime if their

    Polity scores are rated in the range of 6 to 10; countries are classified as autocrat

    authoritarian regime if their Polity scores are rated in the range of -6 to -10; countries, which

    their Polity scores are not rated in these specified ranges, are neither consolidated democratic

    nor autocrat authoritarian regimes10.

    Likewise, another set of dummy variable is the category variables of free and not-free

    societies. The dissertation classifies societies, which reach combined average Freedom

    Houses score within the range of 1.0 to 2.5, as free societies; additionally, the societies,

    which reach average combined score between 5.5 and 7.0, are classified as not-free societies.

    Nonetheless, societies in which average combined score is not in these specified ranges are

    neither free nor not-free societies

    11

    . Generally, in free societies, political rights and civil

    liberties tends to be higher than not-free societies; therefore, the category of free and not-free

    societies could be used as proxies of democratic and authoritarian regimes, respectively.

    Along with explanatory variables, there are six controlling variables in this section.

    The first controlled variable is GDP per capita, which could represent level of economic

    development of each country at given time. The second controlled variable is squared GDP

    per capita; the dissertation intentionally includes this variable for testing the hypothesis of

    Kuznets curve12

    . The third controlling variable is average arable land per capita, which is

    the proxy of endowments in arable land. The fourth controlling variable is average stock

    years of primary education, which is proxy of endowments in unskilled labors. The fifth

    controlling variable is average stock years of secondary education, which is the proxy of

    endowments in skilled workers.

    Purposively, this section also creates interactive variables as explanatory variables to

    test some particular hypotheses. Particularly, this section generates the interactive variable oftrade volume ratio and GDP per capita, and the interactive variables of trade volume ratio

    and proxies of production factors endowment. These generated variables are planned to test

    10 The classification of dummy variables, to be consolidated democracy or autocrat authoritarian or neither,

    regards to the recommendation of CPS and INSCR (2010a).

    11 The construction of dummy variables for free and not-free societies relies on the classification of in Tables

    and Charts in Freedom in the World 2010 by Freedom House (2010a).

    12

    The hypothesis claims that income inequality will rapidly widen in the early state of economic development,before stabilize for a while; and then, in the later phase of development, income inequality will narrow down

    (Fields, 2001). According to the hypothesis, it could be implied that the relationship between economic growth

    and income inequality is inverted-U curve (Fields, 2001).

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    25/56

    25

    the hypotheses that relate to the Heckscher-Ohlin theory. Besides, the dissertation constructs

    the interactive variables of dummy variables for political regimes and government

    consumption ratio, and the interactive variables of dummy variables for political regimes and

    trade volume ratio13

    . These constructed variables are planned to test the hypothesis 5 and 6.

    In order to test the hypotheses, this section will perform several regressions. The

    coefficient value of these regressions will be estimated by Ordinary Least Square (OLS).

    However, OLS might not produce reliable estimators if its assumptions are violated

    (Gujarati, 2003). Especially, in the case of panel-data regression, there could usually be the

    presence heteroscedatiscity and serial correlation (Reuveny and Li, 2003). Like Reuveny and

    Li, this section applies Huber-White robust standard errors, which are clustered by countries,

    for dealing with these problems.

    4.3 Econometric results

    The values of coefficients and standard errors14

    of each explanatory variable in the

    regressions are illustrated in Table 4.1. All of regressions in Table 4.1 use Gini coefficient as

    a dependent variable.

    However, due to the limitation of page space, this section has to separate the Table

    4.1 into two parts in different pages. Also, this section has to display explanatory variables in

    form of codes, instead of variables full names. The definition of explanatory variables

    codes is shown in the below.

    13 The construction of this variable is partially influenced from Adsera and Boix (2002), which create this kind

    of dummy, but the difference is that they uses government revenues ratio as dependent variable.14 The values of standard error are shown in the brackets that located below coefficient value.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    26/56

    26

    Code = Definition

    Trade = Average ratio of trade volume to GDP

    Govav = Average share of government consumption to GDP

    Democ = Dummy variable for consolidated democratic regimes

    Autho = Dummy variable for autocrat authoritarian regimes

    Freesoc = Dummy variable for free societies

    Notfreesoc = Dummy variable for not-free societies

    TradeGDP = Interactive variable of average trade volume ratio and GDP per

    capita

    TradeLand = Interactive variable of average trade volume ratio and average

    arable land per capita

    TradePri = Interactive variable of average trade volume ratio and average

    stock years of primary education

    TradeSec = Interactive variable of average trade volume ratio and average

    stock years of secondary education

    GovDemoc = Interactive variable of average share of government

    consumption and dummy variable for consolidated

    democratic regimes

    GovAutho = Interactive variable of average share of government

    consumption and dummy variable for autocrat

    authoritarian regimes

    GovFreesoc = Interactive variable of average share of government

    consumption and dummy variable for free societies

    GovNotfree = Interactive variable of average share of government

    consumption and dummy variable for not-free societies

    TradeDemoc = Interactive variable of average trade volume ratio and dummyvariable for consolidated democratic regimes

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    27/56

    27

    TradeAutho = Interactive variable of average trade volume ratio and dummy

    variable for autocrat authoritarian regimes

    TradeFreesoc = Interactive variable of average trade volume ratio and dummy

    variable for free societies

    TradeNotfree = Interactive variable of average trade volume ratio and dummy

    variable for not-free societies

    GDP = GDP per capita

    GDP2 = Squared GDP per capita

    PriEdu = Average stock years of primary education

    SecEdu = Average stock years of secondary education

    Land = Average arable land per capita

    Con = Constant term

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    28/56

    28

    Table 4.1 (First part)

    Regression 1 2 3 4 5 6

    Trade 5.843***

    (3.209)

    4.026

    (3.209)

    119.852*

    (29.709)

    19.124

    (12.025)

    Govav 20.712(18.427)

    6.996(16.198)

    22.903(17.966)

    34.220**(16.550)

    59.461**(25.783)

    Democ -1.068

    (1.791)

    4.891

    (3.960)

    Autho -4.906*

    (1.864)

    -3.446

    (0.453)

    Freesoc

    Notfreesoc

    TradeGDP -13.005*

    (3.293)

    TradeLand -2.414**

    (1.146)TradePri -3.644

    (2.515)

    TradeSec -1.337

    (2.438)

    GovDemoc -50.159***

    (29.329)

    GovAutho -14.041

    (19.718)

    GovFreesoc

    GovNotfree

    TradeDemoc

    TradeAutho

    TradeFreesoc

    TradeNotfree

    GDP 48.005*

    (15.474)

    46.182*

    (15.538)

    28.027***

    (15.364)

    40.898**

    (17.438)

    43.759*

    (15.002)

    38.476**

    (15.524)

    GDP2 -3.072*

    (0.956)

    -2.959*

    (0.960)

    -1.626***

    (0.959)

    -2.654**

    (1.076)

    -2.799*

    (0.927)

    -2.450**

    (0.957)

    PriEdu -2.320**

    (0.931)

    -2.264**

    (0.932)

    -2.51*

    (0.841)

    -1.348

    (1.444)

    -1.970**

    (0.831)

    -1.944**

    (0.837)

    SecEdu -0.029

    (1.263)

    -0.406

    (1.326)

    0.080

    (1.143)

    0.252

    (1.988)

    -1.078

    (1.250)

    -0.918

    (1.209)

    Land 1.124***

    (0.630)

    0.684

    (0.724)

    0.249

    (0.654)

    1.933***

    (1.035)

    0.727

    (0.497)

    0.825***

    (0.494)

    Con -137.768**

    (62.169)

    -132.919**

    (62.235)

    -74.558

    (60.216)

    -113.757***

    (68.111)

    -123.348**

    (60.298)

    -106.56***

    (62.535)

    R2 0.327 0.336 0.399 0.377 0.365 0.376

    *, **, *** = significant at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    29/56

    29

    Table 4.1 (Continued part)

    Regression 7 8 9 10 11

    Trade 1.753

    (2.868)

    18.769*

    (6.728)

    0.943

    (2.9280)

    23.110**

    (8.864)

    Govav 32.020***(17.102)

    25.051(17.107)

    30.493***(18.068)

    59.223**(29.049)

    20.068(16.359)

    Democ -0.403

    (1.882)

    4.348

    (2.948)

    Autho -4.894*

    (1.841)

    -2.110

    (3.403)

    Freesoc -2.106

    (1.835)

    5.352

    (4.055)

    4.272

    (3.498)

    Notfreesoc -4.844**

    (2.380)

    -2.753

    (4.512)

    -2.450

    (4.137)

    TradeGDP

    TradeLandTradePri

    TradeSec

    GovDemoc

    GovAutho

    GovFreesoc -62.088***

    (31.849)

    GovNotfree -18.214

    (31.451)

    TradeDemoc -19.641*(6.661)

    TradeAutho -11.247

    (11.499)

    TradeFreesoc -25.149*

    (8.797)

    TradeNotfree -8.279

    (15.050)

    GDP 46.822*

    (15.701)

    39.884**

    (16.244)

    37.652**

    (16.109)

    26.250***

    (15.484)

    28.201***

    (16.055)

    GDP2 -3.029*

    (0.981)

    -2.572**

    (1.006)

    -2.461**

    (0.995)

    -1.699***

    (0.950)

    -1.860***

    (0.979)

    PriEdu -2.062**(0.845)

    -2.130**(0.856)

    -1.509(0.974)

    -1.470(0.952)

    -1.751***(0.932)

    SecEdu -0.909

    (1.279)

    -1.007

    (1.240)

    -0.978

    (1.322)

    -0.956

    (1.259)

    -0.836

    (1.200)

    Land 1.289***

    (0.740)

    1.169

    (0.744)

    1.222

    (0.741)

    0.925***

    (0.501)

    1.066

    (0.719)

    Constant -132.773**

    (62.535)

    -109.555***

    (64.477)

    -96.760

    (64.861)

    -58.175

    (62.902)

    -63.164

    (64.407)

    R2 0.380 0.404 0.365 0.381 0.406

    *, **, *** = significant at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    30/56

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    31/56

    31

    ratio is greater, the Gini coefficient will lower. This kind of conclusion could also be seen

    from Spilimbergo, Londono and Szekery (1999). Accordingly, this result is partly

    incompatible with hypothesis that Greater trade openness will lead to declining in income

    inequality in unskilled labor abundant economies, and vice versa for skilled labors and land

    abundant economies.

    The result of dummy variables for democratic and authoritarian regimes in

    Regression 5 and 7 could reject the hypothesis that countries with democratic institutions is

    associated with lower income inequality, and vice versa for countries with authoritarian

    institutions. Although the coefficients are negative in both regressions, only dummy variable

    for autocrat authoritarian regimes is significant at 1 per cent level in both regressions.

    Regards to coefficient of dummy variable for authoritarian regime, the Gini coefficient in

    authoritarian countries is lower than expected value by 4.9 and 4.9 point, as seen, in

    Regression 5 and7, respectively. Likewise, in regression 9, coefficients of dummy variables

    for free and not-free societies are negative; nonetheless, only coefficient of dummy for not-

    free societies is significant at 5 per cent level. This means that the value of Gini coefficient

    in the not-free societies is lower than expected value by 4.8 point.

    The results form Regression 5, 7 and 9 seems to be incompatible with the previous

    studies, for example, Muller (1998) or Reuveny and Li (2003). One of the possiblyexplanation of the negative coefficient of dummy for authoritarian regimes and not-free

    societies is that, before 1990s, several low-income-inequality societies were former

    Communist countries in which have priority on economic equality, but tend to neglect

    political freedoms and civil rights.

    Intentionally, Regression 6 and 10 are designed to test the hypothesis that, in the

    democratic societies, expansion of government size tends to be associated with lower income

    inequality, and vice versa for authoritarian regimes. In Regression 6, the coefficient of

    interactive term of dummy for democratic regimes and share of government consumption as

    a proportion of GDP is opposite (negative) to the positive term of coefficient of government

    size at 10 per cent significant level. In democratic regimes 1 per cent increase in government

    consumption share will lead to 0.09 point increasing in Gini coefficient, (equaling 59.461 +

    (-50.159)). Whereas in non-democratic societies, 1 per cent increase in government

    consumption share will lead to 0.59 point in Gini coefficient. From Regression 6, it could be

    said that democratic institutions could reduce the negative effects of government expansion

    on income distribution.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    32/56

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    33/56

    33

    In addition, the coefficients of interactive terms of authoritarian regimes (for

    Regression 8) or not-free societies (for regression 11), and trade volume ratio are positive,

    but statistically insignificant in both regressions. This could not completely accept the

    hypothesis that, in authoritarian regimes, the negative effect of trade openness on income

    distribution will be higher.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    34/56

    34

    5.Case study of ThailandFirstly, this section provides background information on Thailand. Generally,

    Thailand has been widely recognized by several academics as the economy with fast rate of

    economic growth but highly unequal income distribution. Empirically, on the one hand, Thai

    society has constantly experienced decent economic growth rates, which reach

    approximately 6 per cent per annual during 1970-2005 (Warr, 2008); on the other hand,

    Thailand simultaneously experienced with higher income inequality, which could be

    illustrated by increasing in Gini coefficient from 0.413 in 1962 to 0.515 in 2006 (see

    Ikemoto and Uehara (2000) for data in 1962-98, and Laovakul et al (2008) for data in 1988-

    2006). The change in Gini coefficient in past 50 years is shown in Figure 5.1.

    Figure 5.1: Gini coefficient, 1962-2006

    Sources: Adapted from Table 1 in Ikemoto and Uehara (2000) for data in 1962-86,

    and Table 3.1 in Laovakul el al (2008) for data in 1988-2006.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    35/56

    35

    The change in income inequality in Thailand could also be illustrated by the income

    share by quintile. According to Figure 5.2, in 1981, the poorest gained 5.4 percent of

    national income while the richest possessed about a half of national income, but, in 2006, the

    poorest share decreased to 3.8 percent while the richest share increased to 56 percent.

    Moreover, during 1981-2006, the ratio of income shares of quintile 5 (the richest group) to

    quintile 1 (the poorest group) increased from 9.5 in 1981 to 14.7 in 2006 (Laovakul, et al

    2008: Table 3.).

    Figure 5.2: Income share by quintile (percentage of national income), 1981-2006

    Sources: Adapted from table 11 in Warr (2000) for data in 1981-1994, and Table 3.1

    in Laovakul el al (2008) for data in 1996-2006.

    Unlike above studies, the dissertation focuses on the situation income inequality in

    the period of early 1980s to mid 2000s, for two reasons.

    The first reason is that although income inequality gradually increased during early

    1960s to mid 2000s, there was a decline in Gini coefficient between 1992 and 2004, from

    0.536 to 0.493, as presented in Figure 5.1. Likewise, the change of the ratio of income share

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    36/56

    36

    of quintile 5 to quintile 1 tends to be consonant with the change in Gini coefficient. The ratio

    decreased from 15 in 1992 to 12.1 in 2004 (Laovakul, et al 2008: Table 3.).

    The second reason is that, in this period, Thailand increasingly participated in

    international trade, as observed by the dramatic rise in ratio of trade volume to GDP

    dramatically rose from 42 per cent in 1985 to 130 per cent in 2005, as illustrated in Figure

    5.3 below. The enlargement of trade volume ratio could have been an outcome of greater

    liberalized trade policies (Phongpaichit and Baker, 2002). Simultaneously, democratic

    institutions in Thailand has been continually developed between 1992 and 2006, the

    development could be illustrated by introduction of 1997 constitution17

    that attempted to

    establish participatory democracy, which could enable public to control politicians and

    bureaucrats (Klein, 1998).

    Figure 5. 3: Trade volume as percentage of GDP, 1985-2005

    Source: World Databank, World Bank (2010a).

    17 However, this democratic constitution was removed by military coup in 2006 (Connors and Hewison, 2008).

    It can be inferred that democratic development has been impeded since 2006.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    37/56

    37

    According to the above reasons, this section attempts to discover how trade openness

    and democratic transitions affect situations of income inequality in Thailand in the period of

    the 1980s to mid 2000s. The dissertation uses descriptive statistics and a literature study as

    the research methods.

    5.1 Trade Openness

    Greater trade openness could be one of the causes of a change in income inequality in

    Thailand in mid 1980s to mid 2000s, since it could be related with change in earning

    inequality, like other countries.

    According to Ikemoto and Uehara (2000: 434), in the 1980s, Thai economy

    depended on an export of labor intensive commodities, yet still has widened its earning

    disparity as the trade had broadened. Unlike Thailand, Taiwan could be able to narrow its

    income gap by exposing its economy to international trade. One of the reasons could be that

    trade openness increases demand for the skilled labors, i.e., professional, technical and

    administrative officers, of export companies. Ikemoto and Uehara (2000: 434) states that

    increased demand for skilled workers led to a rise in earning of the skilled labors, so the

    risen skilled labor earnings widened wage gap between skilled and unskilled labors,

    especially production workers. According to NSO (2007), in 1992, the income of skilled

    labors was higher nearly 3 times than income of unskilled labors, while in 1986 the income

    of the skilled labors was higher 2 times than the unskilled workers.

    However, although trade openness was expanding, the wage inequality between

    skilled and skilled workers declined in the 2000s. According to the study of Buula-or and

    Kripornsak (2008: Table 1), although the ratio of employment of high-skilled to low-skilled

    workers increased during 2002-06, the relative wage of high-skilled to low-skilled labors

    decreased from 3.04 in 2002 to 2.89 in 2006. Nevertheless, Buula-or and Kripornsak (2008:

    82-84) explains that the decreasing in relative wage might not be related to factors of trade

    openness, since the decreased relative wages could be the consequence of an excess supply

    of high-skilled labors, which was caused by sharp increase in number of degree graduates.

    In addition, as stated in theoretical perspectives section, trade openness might not

    only impact a change in earning inequality, but also impacts inequality between regions. The

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    38/56

    38

    general information on regional inequality in Thailand during the period of early 1980s to

    mid 2000s is illustrated in Table 5.1.

    Table 5.1: Relative per capita household income by regions

    Bangkok = 100

    Region 1981 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

    Greater

    Bangkok18

    100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100

    Centre 59.9 52.2 48.1 44.7 38.7 47.4 42.9 44.8 50.2 48.7 56.7 56.8

    North 49.2 43.6 40.8 38.1 30.3 36.0 34.3 35.0 31.2 31.5 36.2 36.6

    Northeast 34.6 28.5 30.3 24.1 22.4 27.4 26.3 26.8 26.5 29.1 32.3 32.4

    South 52.0 47.6 42.9 36.0 33.2 39.3 36.3 37.3 42.7 42.0 49.4 55.2

    Source: Adapted from Table 4 in Ikemoto and Uehara (2000) for data in 1981-1998

    Calculated from The online version of Household Socio-Economic Survey (2007) of

    NSO for data in 2000, 2002, 2004 and 2006

    According to Table 5.1 above, during 1981-92, a regional inequality between greater

    Bangkok and the other regions widened. A good example can be seen from the disparity

    between Greater Bangkok, which is the capital city, and Northeast, which is the poorest

    region. In 1981, the ratio of income in these two regions was 100 to 34.6. Then, in 1986, the

    ratio increased to 100: 28.5; and later in 1992, the ratio was in peak at 100 to 22.4. The

    widening in regional gap in period of early 1980s to early 1990s tends to be consonant with

    the increasing in income inequality in the same period.

    The widening of regional inequality concurrently emerged with the increase in

    degree of trade openness during 1980s to 1990s. The reason could be that in 1980s, a vast

    majority of export industries, was concentrated in Greater Bangkok region (Kittiprapas,

    1999). It is evidenced that, more than 90 per cent of Japanese export companies, which was

    predominated by textile, was located in Bangkok during 1980s (Tiwari et al, 2003).

    Comparatively, this kind of situation tends to be look like the case of China in which

    openness-led regional inequality could be resulted from the unequal concentration of

    international economic activities.

    18 Greater Bangkok region includes Bangkok and three surrounding provinces (Nonthaburi, Phatum Thani and

    Samut Pakarn).

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    39/56

    39

    The concentration of export industries in Greater Bangkok in 1980s could be

    explained by theory of economic geography that emphasizes role of first and second nature

    in formation of industrial cluster. The first nature of Greater Bangkok could be resulted from

    its geographical location. Greater Bangkok is located in delta Plain of Chao Phraya River in

    which could easily connect to Pacific Ocean through Gulf of Thailand; additionally, Greater

    Bangkok is also the centre of railway links that could make companies easily access to labor,

    input and commodities markets (Kittiprapas, 1999; Dixon, 1999). The second nature of

    Greater Bangkok could be partly produced by densely labor market. The labor market could

    be the product of flow of migration, according to the fact that, during 1970-80, the

    proportion of lifetime migrants in Bangkok increased from 27 per cent to 36 per cent (Dixon,

    1999). Accordingly, the first and second nature of Greater Bangkok could have a

    contribution to emergence of industrial clusters in this region. Nonetheless, the emergence of

    industrial clusters may not solely relate to the first and second nature of Bangkok. The

    clusters could be also the outcome of Thai governments policies that primarily subsidized

    industries which are located in Greater Bangkok region (Dixon, 1999).

    However, regards to Table 5.1, regional gap between Greater Bangkok and other

    regions has been gradually narrowed down during 1992-2006. This could be shown by the

    ratio of income of Greater Bangkok and Northeast which decreased from the peak (100:

    22.4) in 1992 to 100: 32.4 in 2006. In this period, regional inequality between Greater

    Bangkok and other areas (Centre, North and South) also declined. Expectably, a narrow

    down in regional during mid 1990s to early 2000s seems to be parallel with declining in

    income inequality at the same period.

    The narrowed regional gap between might be caused by the moving of industrial

    clusters from Bangkok to the other provinces, especially Eastern provinces, e.g., Chon Buri

    and Rayong. The moving of export industries could be resulted from higher costs of labors

    and lands in the capital city, due to concentration of factory (Lecler, 2002). The moving also

    was also the result of the government policies that promote to companies to locate in remote

    areas (Kittiprapas, 1999; Lecler, 2002). The promotion could be seen from tax exemption to

    companies that locate outside Greater Bangkok, and provision of infrastructure, such as

    highway, deep-sea port and broadband communication in other areas.

    In summary, from above information, even trade openness has constantly increased

    during 1980-2006, wage gap and regional inequality tends to not followed trend of change in

    trade openness, since these kinds of inequality have been also affected by other factors.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    40/56

    40

    Particularly, the reduction of regional disparity during 1992-06 could be partly resulted from

    government policies that attempt to attract companies to locate in other areas that apart from

    Greater Bangkok. From the case of regional inequality, it could be implied that government

    policies could mitigate the effects of trade openness on inequality because they could have a

    potential to fairly share the benefits from free trade.

    5.2 Democratic Institutions

    As mentioned earlier, the presence of well-developed democratic institutions is

    usually associated with a lower income inequality through a pro-equity expansion of public

    sector. The detail of a proportion of government expenditure to GDP and the amount of

    government expenditure is illustrated in Table 5.2 below.

    Table 5.2: GDP, Government expenditure (million of Baht) and a proportion of

    government expenditure to GDP (percentage), 1993-2006

    GDPGovernment expenditure Proportion of government expenditure to GDP

    19933,165,222 316000 9.98

    19943,629,341 354000 9.75

    19954,186,212 414000 9.89

    19964,611,041 478000 10.37

    19974,732,610 477000 10.08

    19984,626,447 512000 11.07

    19994,637,079 533000 11.49

    2000 4,916,505 558000 11.352001 5,133,502 581000 11.32

    2002 5,450,643 604000 11.08

    2003 5,917,369 635000 10.73

    2004 6,489,476 721000 11.11

    2005 7,092,893 839000 11.83

    2006 7,850,193 907000 11.55

    Source: Calculated from Table 1 in Jirayankul and Brahmasrene (2007) for data on

    government expenditure, and NESDB (2009) for data on GDP.

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    41/56

    41

    According to Table 5.2, during the democratic period, a proportion of government

    expenditure to GDP has slightly increased from around 10 per cent in 1993 to about 12 per

    cent in 2006. Meanwhile, the amount of government expenditures rapidly increased from

    about 316,000 million Baht to around 907,000 million Baht in 2006. It could be expected

    that the expansion of government size via increase in public spending tends to be correlated

    with a decline in Gini coefficient during 1992-2004. However, the decline in Gini coefficient

    may not only relate to an increase in the amount of government spending, but the decline

    could also associate with a change in an allocation of expenditure.

    Firstly, during democratic period, expanding government expenditures were allocated

    more to education. With regards to database of World Databank (2010), during 1995-2000, a

    share of public spending on education to total government expenditure rapidly increased

    from 19 per cent to around 31 per cent, but the share of the education spending gradually

    decreased from 28 per cent in 2001 to 25 per cent in 2006. Increased education spending was

    utilized for extension of years of basic education, teacher trainings, school facilities

    enhancement, and student loans (Booth, 1999; Pinijitsamut, 2009).

    Consequently, the utilization of education spending could mitigate inequality in

    education in Thailand. Particularly, utilized education spending could provide higher chance

    for people from lower socio-economic backgrounds to participate in a formal education,regarding to some situations. For example, the gross enrollment ratio at lower secondary

    education in Thailand increased from 50.6 percent in 1992 to 83.9 percent in 1999, because

    of the expansion of education facilities (Jones, 2003). The increased enrolment ratio could be

    interpreted as the poor people have better opportunity to access to secondary education. In

    addition, during 2001-03, the opportunity to participate in higher education for students, who

    are 40 per cent poorest have been enhanced, due to the provision of student loans

    (Pinijitsamut, 2009). Consequently, the utilization of expanding public educational spending

    could be one of the causes of a decrease in income inequality in democratic period since it

    enhance equality of opportunities to resources of human capital development.

    In spite of greater equality of opportunity to access to higher level of formal

    education between the rich and the poor, there seems to be disparity in education

    achievement. The disparity could be shown by the statistical fact that the scores of Ordinary

    National Education Test (ONET) are positively correlated with household resources and

    education level of parents (Mounier and Tangchuang, 2010). This could mean that children,

    who come from upper socio-economical backgrounds, tend to reach higher level of academic

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    42/56

    42

    achievement than children from lower classes. Accordingly, the difference in ONET scores

    could widen opportunities to get well-paid jobs between students from different socio-

    economical classes.

    However, although there is the difference in educational achievement, the

    improvement of the equality to participate in formal education could be prominent processes

    in establishment of educational equality in Thai society, since the majority of Thai people

    are given the chance to be educated.

    Moreover, Thai democratic governments not only expanded public spending in order

    to provide education, but also health-care services. This could be seen from an increase in

    budgets of central governments health-care agency. According to Faramnuayphol et al

    (2008: Figure 6.68), the proportion of budget Ministry of Public Health (MoPH), which is a

    central administration agency, to the overall national budget steadily rose from 5.4 per cent

    in 1992 to 7.7 percent in 1998, but the proportion of MoPH budget fell to 6.7 per cent in

    2001. However, in the 2000s, proportion of MoPH budget slightly rose from 6.7 per cent in

    2001 to 7.9 per cent in 2006.

    Particularly, the increased budget in 1990s could be one of the causes for a decline

    in health-related inequality. The evidence could partly be shown by Vapattanawong et al

    (2007: 852), who claim that, during 1990-2000, five-year mortality gap between the richest

    and the poorest quintile decreased by 55 per cent. They state that one of the causes of

    narrowed mortality gap is government medical welfare scheme in 1993 that was extended to

    cover, elderly, the disabled, and all children under 12 years old.

    Historically, the increased public health budget in the 2000s could be the result of

    implementation of the universal health-care coverage scheme (UC for short), which is

    promised policy in general election campaign of Thai Rak Thai party, who acquired

    majority vote in 2001 (NaRanong and NaRanong, 2006; McGuire, 2008). It could be said

    that the launching of the UC could be resulted from competitive general election.

    Interestingly, the implementation of the UC not only change quantitative amount of Thai

    government health-care spending, but also make health-care services more equitable.

    Particularly, UC enhances chances to receive health-care services to people,

    especially underprivileged ones. Prakornsai, Tangcharoensathien and Tisayatikom (2007:

    S22) claims that during 2001 (before the UC) and 2003 (after hat UC), UC increased ratio of

    health insurance coverage from 71 per cent to 95 per cent. Specifically, the increased

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    43/56

    43

    insurance ratio covered majority of the poor. Accordingly, the increased insurance coverage

    makes the poor people could have a better access to health services. The better access could

    be shown by 159.2 per cent increasing in the usage of ambulatory services at community

    hospitals19

    , and 78.8 per cent in the usage of hospitalization at community hospitals by the

    poorest (Prakornsai, Tangcharoensathien and Tisayatikom, 2007).

    In addition, UC tends to favor the poor over the rich, regards to some studies that

    apply benefit incidence analysis method20

    . For example, Prakongsai, Limwattananon and

    Tangcharoensathien (2009: 71-2) illustrate that, in 2001, the 20 per cent poorest benefited

    from 28 per cent of total public spending on health, while the 20 per cent richest benefited

    only 18 per cent of total spending on health. In 2003, the share of 20 per cent poorest

    increased to 31 per cent, but the share of 20 per cent richest decreased to 15 per cent. The

    pro-poor characteristic of UC could lead to greater equality in health-services.

    In summary, democratic institutions, such as general election or constitution, might

    be one of the explanations of the decline in income inequality in Thailand during early

    1990s to mid 2000s, even trade openness were still expanding in that time. The reason is

    that the institutions encourage Thai government to implement set of redistributive policies

    via expansion of government spending on education and health-care. The case of Thailand in

    democratic periods tends to be similar to Taiwan and South Korea in which an increase of

    social spending concurrently occurred with a decline in income inequality and democratic

    transitions.

    However, it should be mentioned that, in Thailand, the tax income, which one of

    important sources of government funding, is regressive tax structure. Empirically, the more

    than a half of tax income of Thai government relies on income from indirect taxes, i.e.

    consumption tax, which their tax burden tends to coped by the poor, due to their high

    proportion of consumption expenditure to income (Laovakul et al, 2008). In order to make

    tax structure to be more equity, new forms of direct tax, i.e. property and inheritance tax,

    have to be introduced (Laovakul et al, 2008).

    19 Usage of health services is measured in terms of visits per capita per year.20 Benefit incidence analysis is the method that intends to study about distributive effects of public spending on

    different group of people, which are usually grouped by income level. Firstly, the method calculates per unit

    subsidy of particular public service. Then, the method imputes per unit subsidy to each public service users.

    Finally, the method compares how total subsidy is distributed across different groups by calculating totalsubsidy that is received by different groups. However, this method could not evaluate the outcome of public

    service on long-run benefits for users. The further detail of benefit incidence analysis could be seen in Demery

    (2000).

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    44/56

    44

    6. Concluding remarks

    In conclusion, according to the cross-national analysis and the experience of Thailand

    in the 1980s, greater trade openness tends to aggravate income inequality in several

    countries, especially developing ones. The reasons could be that the trade openness may

    widen earning gap between skilled and unskilled labors; moreover, trade openness might

    also lead to an increase in regional inequality. In other words, openness-led inequality could

    be the result of unequal distribution of benefits from trade openness across people in

    different socio-economic classes and regions.

    Nevertheless, the negative effect of openness on income distribution could be

    mitigated by government policies. This could be supported by the econometric analysis in

    this dissertation. The result has shown that when trade openness took place, countries with

    consolidated democratic institutions tend to have lower level of income inequality than that

    of other countries because democratic governments tend to implement redistributive policies

    via expansion of public sector in order to mitigate adverse effects on income distribution

    from trade openness.

    Likewise, the effects of public policies on openness-led inequality could be

    strengthened by the case of Thailand during democratic period, which there was a decline inincome inequality while trade openness was stills expanding. The decline in income

    inequality could be resulted from the implementation of redistributive policies, i.e. social

    spending on education and health-care services. The decline in inequality could be also

    caused by the policies that attempted to promote export industries to locate in the other areas

    that apart from the national centre.

    From the above information, it could be concluded that the emergence of pro-equity

    public policies usually walks hand in hand with the presence of democratic institutions. The

    reason is that the democratic institutions could equally provide opportunities to all people

    from every socio-economic background to participate in the decision-making processes in a

    public policy design and implementation. Consequently, those institutions will encourage

    government to launch the policies that could equally distribute benefits from trade openness

    and compensate the losers from globalization. In summary, the presence of consolidated

    democratic institutions is the necessary condition for making globalization to be fairer.

    However, apart from this dissertation, the studies about the relationships of trade

    openness, democracy and income inequality could be improved. On the cross-national

  • 8/6/2019 The Effects of Trade Openness and Democratic Institutions on Income Inequality Cross-National Analysis and the Ca

    45/56

    45

    studies, the improvement can be conducted by using more recent dataset or applying new

    econometric model. For the case study analysis, there should be more recen