technology based ventures

Upload: islem-ahlem-khefacha

Post on 07-Jul-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    1/23

    This article was downloaded by: [islem khefacha]On: 03 September 2015, At: 04:39Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954Registered office: 5 Howick Place, London, SW1P 1WG

    Click for updates

    The Journal of InternationalTrade & Economic Development:

    An International and

    Comparative ReviewPublication details, including instructions for authors

    and subscription information:

    http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rjte20

    Technology-based ventures

    and sustainable development:

    Cointegrating and causal

    relationships with a panel data

    approach

    Islem Khefachaa

     & Lotfi Belkacema

    a Laboratory Research for Economy, Management and

    Quantitative Finance, IHEC - University of Sousse 4054,

    Tunisia

    Published online: 15 Jun 2015.

    To cite this article: Islem Khefacha & Lotfi Belkacem (2015): Technology-based venturesand sustainable development: Cointegrating and causal relationships with a panel data

    approach, The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development: An Internationaland Comparative Review, DOI: 10.1080/09638199.2015.1048707

    To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2015.1048707

    PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

    Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the

    information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform.However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make norepresentations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, orsuitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressedin this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not theviews of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content shouldnot be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2015.1048707http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2015.1048707http://www.tandfonline.com/action/showCitFormats?doi=10.1080/09638199.2015.1048707http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rjte20http://crossmark.crossref.org/dialog/?doi=10.1080/09638199.2015.1048707&domain=pdf&date_stamp=2015-06-15

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    2/23

    of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions,claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilitieswhatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connectionwith, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content.

    This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes.Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly

    forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

    http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditionshttp://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    3/23

    The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development , 2015

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2015.1048707

    Technology-based ventures and sustainable development:

    Cointegrating and causal relationships with a panel data

    approach

    Islem Khefacha   ∗ and Lotfi Belkacem

     Laboratory Research for Economy, Management and Quantitative Finance, IHEC - University of Sousse 4054, Tunisia

    ( Received 27 January 2014; accepted 3 May 2015)

    The aim of this article is to provide new empirical evidence on the causality between proxy variables of technology entrepreneurship and proxy variable of sustainable economic performance in a vector error correction model. It coversa sample of 13 countries participated to Global Entrepreneurship Monitor studies under the period 2002–2013. Building on a theoretical background that considers the adoption of new technologies through a dynamic processof creative destruction based on innovation as the most important factor for achieving long-term economic growth, the empirical investigation uses robusteconometric techniques that are capable of estimating long-run cointegrating

    relationships in panel data.Our results support the idea that total entrepreneurship activity related tothe technology sector leads to improve the sustainability of a nation in thelong run. More importantly, our paper helps understand the nature of liaison between the creation of innovative and high-technology business and the presence of favorable social and environmental conditions for the well-beingof a population.

    Keywords:   technology entrepreneurship; sustainable economic growth;GEM; cointegration tests; vector error correction model

    JEL Classification: C32, M13, Q01

    1. Introduction

    It is well known that economic growth is the key to higher living standards. For 

    this, economic theory suggests several key institutions and policy factors that

    are important to make way for sustainable economic growth (see Onipede 2003).

    Recent studies emphasize entrepreneurship as a driver of economic development

    and some authors include entrepreneurship as a fourth production factor in the

    macroeconomic production function (see Audretsch and Keilbach  2004 cited in

    ∗Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]

    C 2015 Taylor & Francis

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2015.1048707mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2015.1048707

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    4/23

    2   I. Khefacha and L. Belkacem

    Szirmai, Naud ́e, and Goedhuys [2011]). Therefore, several economists focused 

    their research on the dynamic role of entrepreneurial activity in promoting inno-

    vation, economic growth and employment.

    In this body of literature, emphasis seemed to be placed on high-potentialtechnology opportunities and technical systems. Within this context, technology

    entrepreneurship – a relatively new field of study – has received increasing atten-

    tion from the scholars of various streams of business and technology disciplines.

    For Abdullah and Ahcene (2011), in the current context of globalization and lib-

    eralization economy, technology entrepreneurship is indeed becoming vital as it

     provides greater opportunities and enables effective optimization of resources to

    attain high profit margins.

    This research leverages on the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) data

    to explore the relationship between investing in technologies and sustainable eco-

    nomic growth. So far, however, the analysis of the link between entrepreneurial

    activity rates as measured by GEM and economic growth has been limited to

     bivariate correlations with short-term GDP rates, with no attempt to control for 

    other factors (see Reynolds et al. 2000, 2001, 2002 cited in Wong et al. [2005])

    related notably with the well-being of a nation.

    The aim of this article is to provide new empirical evidence on the impact

    of investment in technologies and economic welfare in 13 developing countries

     belonging to the Group of Twelve (G12). It covers the period 2002–2013, and car-

    ries out tests for non-stationary panels using the Granger causality and the vector 

    error correction model (VECM) to investigate both the short-run and the long-rundynamic relationship between variables. To the best of our knowledge, there is no

    study that tries to evaluate the evolution of technological entrepreneurship as a

    factor for sustainable economic development.

    The layout of the article is as follows.  Section 2 provides an overview of the

    literature of the two main concepts of this study: technology entrepreneurship

    and sustainable economic growth.   Section 3   provides the model specification,

    definitions of the variables and econometric tools. Section 4 estimates the model

     by panel cointegration techniques and, finally, Section 5 concludes with a summary

    of the main findings and policy implications.

    2. Theoretical background

    2.1. The concept of technology entrepreneurship

    Although over the last years, technology entrepreneurship has developed as a

    distinct stream of research at the nexus of entrepreneurship and the management

    of technology and innovation, this field is in its infancy compared to others such

    as economics, entrepreneurship and management (see Bailetti 2012). Yet, despite

    several special issues and an increased level of interest, no conventional definitionhas been developed so far.

    Several expressions are used in research papers to point out technology en-

    trepreneurship such as technological entrepreneurship, technical entrepreneurship,

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    5/23

    The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development    3

    techno-entrepreneurship, high-tech firm, knowledge-based firm, new technology-

     based firm, technology-based ventures and several definitions are applicable. It

    follows that technology entrepreneurship is basically the merge of two words from

    two disciplines: technology from the innovation discipline and entrepreneurshipfrom the business discipline.

    From the standpoint of economics, there are a number of authors who associate

    entrepreneurship with innovation (see Abdullah and Ahcene  2011). Schumpeter 

    (1950) viewed entrepreneurship as a dynamic process of creative destruction, in

    which he put forward the idea of innovation as the creation, development and 

    introduction of new products, processes, systems and organizational forms that

    change the basic technological and demand parameters of the economy.

    Freeman (1998) recognized that innovation is developed from technology and 

    an outcome of new scientific results. Schumpeter (1912) showed that technology

    is driven by entrepreneurs, and it is the entrepreneur who plays a major role in

    creating inventions through the appropriate implementation of technology. In this

    setting, technology is regarded as one of the crucial components in an innovation

    activity by creating new things and matching it with market needs.

    Technological innovation has long been viewed as an integral part of en-

    trepreneurship (see Drucker  1985). In fact, technology provides the solution of 

    some problems that are generated by innovation. A technological change comes

    from the new and innovative ideas and the firms implement those ideas into reality

    on international level. It is from this point of view that Dopfer (1992) defined 

    technology ‘as an engine of growth, and its application is seen in the branch of  Neo-Schumpeterian research like Technological Paradigm (see Dosi 1988), “fo-

    cusing devices” (Rosenberg 1976), “Technological Trajectory” (see Nelson and 

    Winter  1977), and others’ (cited in Abdullah and Ahcene 2011).

    To develop innovation and to achieve competitiveness, the accent must be

     put on acquiring technological capability that offers the required human skills

    such as entrepreneurial, managerial and technical to set up and operate industries

    efficiently (see Lall 1990) and to deploy and utilize various resources and know-

    how (see Anderson and Tushman 1990; Song et al.  2005;  Khefacha, Belkacem,

    and Mansouri 2014).The question here is what distinguishes technology entrepreneurship from

    entrepreneurship as defined by the traditional managerial literature.

    In fact, the concept of technology entrepreneurship was addressed from various

     perspectives relative to economics, business and management sector.

    Bailetti (2012) makes the widest research on definitions proposed by different

    authors, and in the end, he offers his own definition which identifies and incor-

     porates the various distinctive aspects of technology entrepreneurship discussed 

    above and its links to the existing domains of economics, entrepreneurship and 

    management: ‘Technology entrepreneurship is an investment in a project that as-sembles and deploys specialized individuals and heterogeneous assets that are

    intricately related to advances in scientific and technological knowledge for the

     purpose of creating and capturing value for a firm.’ He adds that technological

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    6/23

    4   I. Khefacha and L. Belkacem

    entrepreneurship can be distinguished from other entrepreneurship types (e.g. so-

    cial entrepreneurship, small business management and self-employment) by the

    collaborative experimentation and production of new products, assets and their 

    attributes, which are intricately related to advances in scientific and technologicalknowledge and the firm’s asset ownership rights.

    Specifically, the technological entrepreneurship process is based on four main

    sets of activities related to the creation of new technologies or the identification of 

    the existing one but not yet previously exploited; the recognition and matching op-

     portunities, thanks to the application of these new technologies to emerging market

    needs; technology/applications development; and business creation. It, therefore,

    follows that technological entrepreneurship occurs at the intersection of technol-

    ogy development (science and engineering) and business creation (management

    and business) involving individuals, businesses and governments that transform

    new ideas into economic and societal values.

    2.2. Technology entrepreneurship as a factor for sustainable

    economic growth

    Several economists focused their research on the dynamic role of entrepreneurial

    activity in promoting innovation, economic growth and employment (see

    Audretsch, Keilbach, and Lehmann   2006; Van Stel   2006;   Fritsch and Mueller 

    2004, 2008). The contribution of technological innovation to national economic

    growth has been well established in the economic literature, both theoretically(see Solow 1956; Romer  1986) as well as empirically (see Mansfield  1972; Nadiri

    1993). These studies have established that the level of technological innovation

    contributes significantly to economic performance, particularly at the firm and 

    industry levels (see Wong et al. 2005).

    Acs and Audretsch (2003), for example, showed that entrepreneurship stimu-

    lates and generates economic growth in several ways. Notably, entrepreneurs may

    introduce important innovations by entering markets with new products or pro-

    duction processes. Namely, Evangelista (2000) and Miles (2005) considered the

    adoption of new technologies through a dynamic process of creative destruction based on innovation as the most important factor for achieving long-term eco-

    nomic growth. Autio, Ho, and Wong (2005) using an augmented Cobb–Douglas

     production to explore firm formation and technological innovation as separate

    determinants of growth showed that only high growth potential entrepreneurship

    is found to have a significant impact on economic growth. More recently, Rado-

    sevic and Yoruk  (2013) state that the introduction of databases such as the GEM

    has enabled research on the impact of entrepreneurship on economic growth to

     be tested at the levels of country, industry or firm (see Yli-Renko, Autio, and 

    Sapienza 2001; Acs and Varga  2005; Minniti, Bygrave, and Autio  2005; Wonget al. 2005).

    However, a closely related concept, technology entrepreneurship, has for a

    long time not found a proper place in mainstream empirical economic research on

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    7/23

    The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development    5

    the sources of sustainable economic growth. Although copious amounts have been

    written theoretically and descriptively on how entrepreneurship affects the eco-

    nomic sustainability (see Fritsch and Mueller  2004, 2008; Radosevic and Yoruk 

    2013; Wong et al.  2005), there is a dearth of evidence based on empirical data.This is partially due to the difficulty in defining the concept of technology en-

    trepreneurship and formalizing its measurement for empirical modeling.

    3. The empirical study

    3.1. Data and variables

    GEM, initiated in 1999, is widely acknowledged to be the best source of compara-

    tive entrepreneurship data in the world (see Shorrock  2008) and has been utilized 

    in studies published in leading journals (see Bowen and De Clercq  2008).A key outcome of the GEM project is the consistent and internationally com-

     parable measures of entrepreneurship, the Total Entrepreneurship Activity (TEA)

    rates.

    TEA captures percentage of adults (aged 18–64) who are either involved in

    the process of starting up a business in two populations: nascent entrepreneurs and 

    young business owners. Nascent entrepreneurs are individuals who have, during

    the last 12 months, taken tangible action to start a new business, would personally

    own all or part of the new firm, would actively participate in the day-to-day

    management of the new firm and has not yet paid salaries for anyone for morethan 3 months. Young business owners are defined as individuals who are currently

    actively managing a new firm, personally own all or part of the new firm and the

    firms in question are not more than 42 months old.

    TEA indices have high validity and reliability (see Reynolds et al.  2005).

    Within TEA, the present study is concerned with harmonized GEM measures

    for technology entrepreneurship and utilizes the following three measures:

    •   TEATEC: Percentage of all TEA business entities reporting business activity

    in a technology sector (high or medium), according to OECD classification.

    1

    •  TEANT1: Percentage of all TEA business entities reporting that they use

    the VERY LATEST technology, not available one year ago.

    •  TEANT2: Percentage of all TEA business entities reporting that they use

    the NEW technology, not available since 1–5 years ago.

    Variables measuring entrepreneurships activities are from GEM (2002–2013)

    and data have been collected for 13 developed countries:2 Australia (2002–2006

    and 2011), Belgium (2002–2013), Canada (2002–2006 and 2013), France (2002– 

    2013), Germany (2002–2010 and 2012–2013), Italy (2002–2010 and 2012–2013),Japan (2002–2013), the Netherland (2002–2013), Spain (2002–2013), Sweden

    (2002–2010 and 2011–2013), Switzerland (2002–2003; 2005; 2007 and 2009– 

    2013), United Kingdom (2002–2013) and USA (2002–2013).

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    8/23

    6   I. Khefacha and L. Belkacem

    Those relating to the sustainable economic growth come from World Bank 

    Indicators (2013) that is the adjusted net saving indicator (ANS) known informally

    as genuine savings (GS). The origin of the approach goes back to Pearce and 

    Atkinson (1993) when they used the term net savings criterion for sustainabledevelopment. These authors showed that the future well-being will be at risk 

    if the gross saving in a given economy shortfalls than the combined value of 

    depreciation on physical capital and depletion on natural capital (see Hamilton

    2010). Technically,3 GS is based on traditional gross national income (GNI) and 

    includes the change rates of the three forms of capital: physical ( K P), human ( K H)

    and natural ( K  N) (Boos and Holm-Müller, 2013):

    Genuine savings = (GNI− CP − CG+ NCT)  GNS

    − δKP

       NNS

    + δKH − δK N

    where GNS is the gross national savings, theoretically seen as gross investment in

     physical capital;  C P  and  C G  are the private and public (governmental) consump-

    tions; NCT is the net current transfers that comprise all exchanges with foreign

    countries of goods and services as well as income and financial items without a

    quid pro quo; NNS is the net national savings, which – at least theoretically – is

    equivalent to net investment in physical capital (δ K P).Investment in human capital is calculated as net educational expenditure (δ K H).

    This includes both capital expenditure as well as current expenditure such as in-

    vestment in school buildings, the purchase of school books or payment of teachers’

    salaries, that are counted as consumption rather than investment in the traditional

    national accounts. Therefore, GS adds current operating expenditures on educa-

    tion as a rather crude approximation for investment in human capital. Finally, net

    depreciation of natural capital (δ K  N) can be divided at a basic level into resource

    extraction, on the one hand, and environmental pollution. The World Bank esti-

    mates resource extraction for a range of fossil fuels (oil, natural gas, hard coaland brown coal), minerals (bauxite, copper, iron, lead, nickel, zinc, phosphate, tin,

    gold and silver), and one renewable resource (forests). These rents demonstrate

    the change in the natural resource asset value associated with their extraction over 

    the accounting period and, therefore, the change in the natural capital stock (see

    Atkinson and Hamilton 2007).

    3.2. Hypothesis

    The paper is based on the following hypotheses for testing the causality and 

    cointegration between the World Bank sustainability indicator and technology

    entrepreneurship:

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    9/23

    The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development    7

    (1) there is bidirectional causality between sustainable economic growth and 

    technology entrepreneurship,

    (2) there is unidirectional causality between the two concepts,

    (3) there is no causality between GS and technology TEA,(4) there exists a long-run relationship between well-being of a nation and 

    TEA related to the technology sector.

    3.3. Econometric specification

    To investigate the relationship between sustainable economic growth and 

    technology-based ventures, we use the following model:

    GSit  = β0i  + β1iTEATECit  + β2iTEANT1it  + β3iTEANT2it  + εit    (1)

    where GSit  is genuine savings in country  i  and year  t  and  ε it  is an error term.

    The test for causal relationship between technology entrepreneurship and sus-

    tainable economic growth in a panel context is usually conducted in four steps.

    3.3.1. Step 1: unit root tests for panel data

    Prior to testing for cointegration and Granger causality, it is necessary to study the

    univariate time-series properties of each variable by performing unit root tests.

    A series is said to be stationary if the mean and the variance remain constant

    over time for all t , and the covariance and hence the correlation between any twovalues taken from different time periods depend on the difference apart in time

     between the two values for all t = s. By contrast, a non-stationary time series will

    have a time-varying mean or a time-varying variance or both. In the first case,

    the variable is described as trend stationary (TS), while for time-varying variance,

    the model is called difference stationary (DS). Hence, for the two models, the

    moments of the stochastic process depend on time and, therefore, the standard 

    assumptions for asymptotic analysis in the Granger test will not be valid. We

    should hence perform tests for unit root in potentially non-stationary time series.

    In fact, a number of unit root tests for panel data have been developed inthe recent literature, including most notably those by Levin, Lin, and Chu (2002)

    (herein referred to as LLC), Im, Pesaran, and Shin (2003) (herein referred to as

    IPS), Maddala and Wu (1999) (herein referred to as MW), Choi (2001) and Hadri

    (2000).

    The basic autoregressive model can be expressed following the basic Aug-

    mented Dickey Fuller (ADF) specification for panel data:

    yit  = αit  + β1iyit −1 + β2i t  +

    m

    j =1 β

    ij yit −j  + εit    (2)

    where   yit  = yit  − yit −1.

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    10/23

    8   I. Khefacha and L. Belkacem

    The lag order for the difference terms ‘m’ is allowed by specification to vary

    across the cross section.

    Using different null and alternative hypothesis, we can distinguish the follow-

    ing three situations:

    Hypothesis (A) : Ho  : βli  = 0 for all i  versus H1   : βli  

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    11/23

    The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development    9

    relationship exists, the most popular developed methodology proposed by Pedroni

    (1999,   2004)   is employed. Basically, the test involves regressing the variables

    along with cross-section-specific intercepts, and examining whether the residuals

    are integrated order one (i.e. not cointegrated). Pedroni proposes two sets of teststatistics as follows:

    •   Four tests are based on pooling the residuals of the regression along

    the within-dimension of the panel ( panel tests):   v-statistic, rho-statistic,

     PP-statistic and ADF-statistic.

    •  Three tests are based on pooling the residuals of the regression along the

     between-dimension of the panel ( group test ): rho-statistic, PP-statistic and 

     ADF-statistic.

    The seven test statistics are distributed as standard normal variates, and diverge

    to negative infinity under the alternative hypothesis of panel cointegration. How-

    ever, these tests are not always unanimous, but a consensus among the statistics

    often is interpreted as evidence in favor of cointegration. As reported in Pedroni

    (2004), the group and panel  ADF -statistics have the best power properties of the

    seven test statistics when  T  <  100, whereas the  panel  ν  and  group rho  statistics

     perform comparatively worse. The  ADF   test statistics also perform better if the

    errors follow an autoregressive process (see Harris and Sollis 2003).

    Unfortunately, testing unit root and cointegration hypotheses by using paneldata instead of individual time series involves several additional complications. As

    a major shortcoming, Taylor and Sarno (1998) have criticized panel unit root tests

    on the grounds that they have a high probability of rejecting the null hypothesis of 

     joint non-stationarity. They explain that given the null hypothesis underlying panel

    unit root tests, the only possible alternative hypothesis is that at least one unit is a

    stationary process. Consequently, we may end up rejecting the null, even if only

    one series is stationary. More recently, Breitung and Pesaran (2008) showed that

    the panel test outcomes are often difficult to interpret if the null of the unit root

    or cointegration is rejected. The best that can be concluded is that ‘a significant

    fraction of the cross-section units is stationary or cointegrated.’ The panel tests do

    not provide explicit guidance as to the size of this fraction or the identity of the

    cross-section units that are stationary or cointegrated.

    3.3.3. Step 3: robustness tests: panel causality test and the error correction

    model (ECM)

    The finding of cointegration between variables indicates the existence of causality

    and an ECM must be estimated. However, cointegration analysis can evaluatewhether the panel variables follow each other’s suit but it does not provide any

    information about the cause and effect, or the direction of causality between the

    variables.

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    12/23

    10   I. Khefacha and L. Belkacem

    For this we will use the Granger causality test. This technique tests short-term

    causality and validates a long-term relationship. Two stages are suggested by Engle

    and Granger (1987) in order to investigate the short-run and long-run relationships

     between these variables. The first stage is to recover the estimated residuals inEquation (1) and the second stage estimates the parameters related to the short-

    run adjustment while incorporating the estimated residuals from Equation (1) in

    the following ECM equations:

    GSit  = α1i  +

    mj =1

    β11ij GSit −j  +

    mj =1

    β12ij TEATECit −j 

    +

    m

    j =1

    β13ij TEANT1it −j +

    m

    j =1

    β14ij TEANT2it −j 

    +λ1iECTit −1 + ε1it    (3)

    TEATECit  = α2i  +

    m j=1

    β21ij GSit −j  +

    mj =1

    β22ij TEATECit −j 

    +

    mj =1

    β23ij TEANT1it −j +

    mj =1

    β24ij TEANT2it −j 

    +λ2iECTit −1 + ε2it    (4)

    TEANT1it  = α3i  +

    mj =1

    β31ij GSit −j  +

    mj =1

    β32ij TEATECit −j 

    +

    mj =1

    β33ij TEANT1it −j +

    mj =1

    β34ij TEANT2it −j 

    +λ3iECTit −1 + ε3it    (5)

    TEANT2it  = α4i  +

    mj =1

    β41ij GSit −j  +

    mj =1

    β42ij TEATECit −j 

    +

    mj =1

    β43ij TEANT1it −j +

    mj =1

    β44ij TEANT2it −j 

    +λ4iECTit −1 + ε4it    (6)

    With α1i  and  α2i  are individual fixed effects,

    denotes the first difference of the variable, GSit , TEATECit ; TEANT1it  and TEANT2it  are the two cointegrated 

    variables; ECT is the error correction term;  m  denotes the lag length determined 

    automatically by the Schwarz Information Criterion; and  ε it  are the error terms.

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    13/23

    The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development    11

    The parameters of the previous equation include the following important short-

    term and long-term implications:  λi   parameters can be thought of as speed of 

    adjustment parameters. If  λi = 0, then there would be no evidence for a long-run

    relationship. This parameter is expected to be significantly negative under the prior assumption that the variables show a return to a long-run equilibrium.

    3.3.4. Step 4: panel long-run estimates

    After having established the existence of a cointegration relationship and the di-

    rection of causality between the dependent variable and the explanatory variables,

    we proceed to estimate the long-term structural coefficients using various methods

    of panel estimation which are more efficient than the ordinary least square (OLS)

    method. Among them, Pedroni (2001) proposed a fully modified OLS (FMOLS)that provides consistent estimates of the  β   coefficients, together with ‘t -ratios’

    that are asymptotically distributed as standard normal variates. A mathematical

    derivation of the estimator is beyond the scope of this paper, but a practical discus-

    sion will inform the interpretation of the results. Roughly explained, the FMOLS

    estimator is constructed by making corrections for endogenity and serial correla-

    tion to the OLS estimator by using the long-run covariance matrices to remove the

    nuisance parameters (see Eberhardt 2009).

    Improved by Kao and Chiang (2000) and Mark and Sul (2003) of the case

    of panel data, the dynamic OLS (DOLS) is another approach of panel esti-mation which consists of adding to the cointegration equation lags of the ex-

     planatory variables in order to clean the error term from any autocorrelation and 

    heteroscedasticity. Monte Carlo testing has suggested it may perform slightly bet-

    ter than the FMOLS estimator (see Eberhardt 2009). One practical issue with the

    estimator is choosing the appropriate lag and lead length, but this may be a less

    serious issue than the non-parametric correction used by FMOLS. It should be

    noted that under both the FMOLS and DOLS regressions, time dummies have

     been added, in order to correct for homogeneous cross-sectional dependence (see

    Pedroni 2001).

    4. Empirical results and discussion

    As mentioned in the previous section, panel cointegration testing requires variables

    integrated in the same order. Since none of the panel unit root test is free from

    some statistical shortcomings in terms of size and power properties (see Hurlin

    and Mignon 2008), it is better for us to perform several unit root tests to infer an

    overwhelming evidence to determine the order of integration of the panel variables.

    Table 1   shows the individual test statistics and   p-values with a lag lengthselection of one. We know macroeconomic variables tend to exhibit a trend over 

    time, thus it is more appropriate to consider the regression equation with constant

    and trend terms at level form.

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    14/23

    12   I. Khefacha and L. Belkacem

        T   a    b    l   e    1 .

        P   a   n   e    l   u   n    i    t   r   o   o    t    t   e   s    t   s .

        M    W

        U   n    i    t   r   o   o    t    t   e   s    t

        L    L    C

        I    P    S

        A    D    F  -    F    i   s    h   e   r

        P    P  -    F    i   s    h

       e   r

        V   a   r    i   a    b    l   e   s

        L   e   v   e    l

        F    i   r   s    t    d    i    f    f   e   r   e   n   c   e

        L   e   v   e    l

        F    i   r   s    t    d    i    f    f   e   r   e   n   c   e

        L   e   v   e    l

        F    i   r   s    t    d    i    f    f   e   r   e   n   c   e

        L   e   v   e    l

        F    i   r   s

        t    d    i    f    f   e   r   e   n   c   e

        G    S

        0 .    4    3    7

       −    7 .    6    7    4

        0 .    3    9    5    3

       −    3 .    2    7    1

        2    5 .    8    8    4

        5    8 .    7    5    9

        2    0 .    8    8    5

        6    1 .    3    1    7

        (    0 .    6    6    9    )

        (    0 .    0    0    0    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    6    5    3    )

        (    0 .    0    0    5    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    4    6    9    5    )

        (    0 .    0    0    2    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    7    4    7    8    )

        (    0 .    0    0    1    )    ∗    ∗

        T    E    A    T    E    C

       −    0 .    9    0    3    9

        1    1 .    0    8    7

       −    1 .    1    0    8

       −    8 .    3    1    0

        3    1 .    3    3    4

        8    8 .    4    3    6

        4    4 .    1    1    1

        1    1    4 .    2    0    0

        (    0 .    1    8    3    )

        (    0 .    0    0    0    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    1    3    3    )

        (    0 .    0    0    0    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    2    1    6    )

        (    0 .    0    0    0    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    0    1    4    )    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    0    0    0    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        T    E    A    N    T    1

       −    4 .    3    3    6

       −    7 .    4    0    3

       −    2 .    4    3    1

       −    4 .    2    3    6

        3    9 .    8    0    4

        5    3 .    7    6    8

        4    5 .    9    3    3

        8    1 .    1    3    1

        (    0 .    0    0    0    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    0    0    0    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    0    5    9    )    ∗

        (    0 .    0    0    0    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    0    3    0    )    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    0    0    0    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    0    3    1    )    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    0    0    0    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        T    E    A    N    T    2

        3 .    2    4    9

       −    7 .    8    9    0

        1 .    4    3    3

       −    2 .    5    8    8

        5 .    4    1    4

        5    6 .    1    4    7

        2    2 .    7    6    5

        1    2    0 .    5    9    2

        (    0 .    9    9    9    )

        (    0 .    0    0    0    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    9    2    4    )

        (    0 .    0    0    4    )    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    9    9    9    )

        (    0 .    0    0    0    )    ∗    ∗

        (    0 .    3    0    0    )

        (    0 .    0    0    0    )    ∗    ∗    ∗

        N   o    t   e   s   :    N   u    l    l    h   y   p   o    t    h   e   s    i   s   :   u   n    i    t   r   o   o    t    (   n   o   n  -   s    t   a    t    i   o   n   a   y    ) .

        T    h   e   p   r   o    b   a    b

        i    l    i    t    i   e   s    f   o   r    t    h   e    F    i   s    h   e   r  -    t   y   p   e    t   e   s    t   s   a   r   e   c   o   m   p   u    t   e    d   u   s    i   n   g   a   n   a   s   y   m   p    t   o    t    i   c   c    h    i  -   s   q   u   a   r   e    (     χ    2    )   a   s   y   m   p    t   o    t    i   c    d    i   s    t   r    i    b   u    t    i   o   n .

        A   u    t   o   m   a    t    i   c    l   a   g   s   e    l   e   c    t    i   o   n    b   a   s   e    d   o   n    S   c    h   w   a   r   z    I   n    f   o   r   m   a    t    i   o   n    C   r    i    t   e   r    i   a    (    S    I    C    ) .

        ‘    ∗    ’ ,    ‘    ∗    ∗    ’   a   n    d    ‘    ∗    ∗    ’    i   n    d    i   c   a    t   e   s    t   a    t    i   s    t    i   c   a    l   s    i   g   n    i    fi   c   a   n   c   e   a    t    1    0    % ,    5    %   a   n    d    1    %    l   e   v   e    l   s ,   r   e   s   p   e   c    t    i   v   e    l   y .

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    15/23

    The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development    13

    Table 2. Pedroni residual cointegration test results (GS as dependent variable).

    Statistic Prob.

    Alternative hypothesis: common AR coefficients (within-dimension)Panel υ -stat   −3.924128 1.0000Panel r-stat 2.414450 0.9921Panel PP-stat   −9.484897 0.0000∗∗∗

    Panel ADF-stat   −8.494431 0.0000∗∗∗

    Alternative hypothesis: individual AR coefficients (between-dimension)Group r-stat 3.496559 0.9998Group PP-stat   −5.288141 0.0000∗∗∗

    Group ADF-stat   −5.649528 0.0000∗∗∗

     Notes: Null hypothesis: no cointegration.‘∗∗’ and ‘∗∗∗’ indicate statistical significance at 5% and 1% levels, respectively.

    The test statistics suggest that the sustainable economic growth as measured by

    genuine savings and two of the three variables measuring technology entrepreneur-

    ship have a unit root which implies non-stationarity. However, when we apply the

    first difference of all variables we can reject the null hypothesis of unit root, and 

    GS, TEATEC and TEANT2 are stationary. It means that these three variables are

    integrated of order one I (1) and are appropriate for cointegration analysis (except

    for TEANT1 which is I (0)).Hence, the variables with the same order facilitate the examination of possible

    long-run relations through cointegration panel tests of Pedroni. Table 2 indicates

    two within-dimension tests and two between-dimension tests providing the pres-

    ence of cointegration. In fact, the null hypothesis of no cointegration is rejected 

    for the two statistical tests panel-ADF  and  group-ADF  at 5% and 1% levels, re-

    spectively. In addition,  panel  and  group PP  statistics are also significant. Due to

    these promising results, it is possible to estimate the long-run relationship between

    the variables.

    The finding of cointegration between variables indicates the existence of 

    causality and an ECM must be estimated based on the following regressions:

    GSit TEATECit TEANT2it 

    =

    α1iα2iα3i

    +

    mj =1

    β11ij  β12ij  β13ij β21ij  β22ij  β23ij β31ij  β32ij  β33ij 

    GSit −j TEATECit −j TEANT2it −j 

    +

    λ1iλ2iλ31i

    ECTit −1 +

    ε1it ε2it ε3it 

    Table 3 reports the short-run and long-run causality results for sustainable eco-

    nomic growth model and indicates that there is evidence of bidirectional causality

     between TEATEC, TEANT2 and GS at 1% level of significance in the short-run.

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    16/23

    14   I. Khefacha and L. Belkacem

    Table 3. Panel Granger causality test results (short-run and long-run causalities).

    Short-run Long-run

    GS

      TEATEC

      TEANT2 ECT

    GS   –    0.109049 0.230188   −0.018125[0.18012] [0.53713] [−2.18653]∗∗∗

    TEATEC 0.061875   –    0.236518   −0.094011[2.12772]∗∗∗ [3.20118] [−3.15969]

    TEANT2 0.067754 0.176450   –    −0.107691[1.67713] [1.21687] [−5.11334]∗∗∗

     Note: ‘∗∗∗’ indicates statistical significance at the 1% level. The  t -statistic is listed in brackets.

    Table 4. Panel DOLS–FMOLS long-run estimates.

    Variables TEATEC TEANT2

    DOLS 0.692409 (0.0034)∗∗∗ −0.053601 (0.8583)FMOLS 0.036999 (0.0013)∗∗∗ 0.110594 (0.1771)

     Notes: Cointegrating equation deterministics: constant and trend.‘∗∗∗’ indicates statistical significance at 1% levels.

     P -value listed in parentheses.

    The error correction term is statistically significant only for percentage of allTEA business entities reporting business activity in a technology sector (high or 

    medium), according to OECD classification and sustainable economic growth at

    1% level. This finding indicates that there is evidence of long-run equilibrium

     between technology entrepreneurship and sustainable development.

    Finally, after having established the existence of a cointegration relationship

    and the direction of causality between sustainable growth and TEA, the last step

    consists in the long-run estimation of Equation (1) where the dependent vari-

    able is genuine savings, and the independent variables the two TEA measures of 

    technology entrepreneurship.The long-run structural coefficients are estimated using the DOLS and FMOLS

     panel approaches (Pedroni, 2001, 2004).

    The results are presented in Table 4 which shows positive relationship between

    technology entrepreneurship measured by the percentage of all TEA business enti-

    ties reporting business activity in a technology sector (high or medium), according

    to OECD classification and sustainable growth.

    These results indicate that technology entrepreneurship is an important de-

    terminant of economic development for the period under study and for the 13

    developed countries. The pace of progress in information technologies, microelec-tronics, robotics, new materials, biomedical sciences, space and other advanced 

    fields continues to quicken, and in turn, to significantly change the way we live

    and work.

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    17/23

    The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development    15

    Particularly, creating business based on new technologies stimulates the wel-

    fare of a nation’s economy by enhancing the social and environmental conditions

    of the living beings.

    Socially, the creation of technology-based ventures by investing in researchand development as well as innovation in the discovery of new technologies or 

    the perfection of existing ones improves the quality of life of people and the

    satisfaction of newly originated needs. It will also underpin economic, social and 

    territorial cohesion. For instance, a greater capacity for technological research and 

    development in the industrial sector promote innovation and knowledge transfer,

    make full use of information and communication technologies, and ensure that

    innovative ideas can be turned into new products and services that create growth,

    quality jobs and global societal challenges. Combined with the increased resource

    efficiency, technological entrepreneurship will also improve competitiveness and 

    foster job creation by pushing the businesses to do what they know best, that is,

    create productive enterprises with high-potential employability.

    Environmentally, the implementation of new and better technologies in differ-

    ent productions could minimize the effects of economic activity on the environ-

    ment. Investing in cleaner and exploiting fully the potential of new technologies

    such as carbon capture and sequestration possibilities would significantly help

    limit emissions and contribute to fighting climate change.

    Many firms do recognize that caring for the environment is good business – 

    energy efficiency, waste reduction and pollution prevention save money which

    can increase profits and boost economic growth by creating new business and employment opportunities.

    Meeting these targets should mobilize our collective attention. All sectors of the

    economy, not just emission-intensive, are concerned: governments, environmental

    experts and industry itself, as the principal source and user of technological knowl-

    edge. Especially, entrepreneurs would do well to heed the lessons of ecology as new

    technologies will be needed to clean up past mistakes and achieve new industrial

    growth safely. Businesses must make the ethic for living sustainably an integral

     part of their corporate goal, taking care that their practices, processes and products

    conserve energy and resources and have a minimum impact on ecosystems.The implication of these findings is that countries that promoted technologi-

    cal entrepreneurship make their economy and businesses more sustainable while

     protecting environmental aspects and improving social conditions. Therefore, the

    government and other stakeholders should put in place measures that develop new

     processes and technologies, including green technologies, accelerating the roll out

    of smart grids using information and communication technologies and creating

    a good business environment that encourages the creation and growth of new

    technology- based firms. This can mean the following:

    •   Adopting practices that take into account not only the well-being of humans

     but also the ecosystem as a whole; practices that avoid damage and require

    consultation with local communities and the public at large;

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    18/23

    16   I. Khefacha and L. Belkacem

    •  Introducing or improving technological innovative processes that minimize

    the use of raw materials and energy, reduce waste and prevent pollution;

    •  Making products that are ‘environmentally friendly’ with minimum impact

    on people and the Earth.

    5. Conclusion

    In this paper, we investigate the causal relationship between sustainable economic

    growth and technology entrepreneurship for an unbalanced panel of 13 countries

     participating in the GEM data-set for the period 2002–2013. This empirical analy-

    sis is interesting because there is no previous study that worked on the causal link 

     between genuine savings as proxy variable of sustainable development and TEA

    rates as proxy variable of entrepreneurship.

    Using robust econometric techniques that are capable of estimating long-

    run cointegrating relationships in panel data, our findings provide a clear and 

    compelling account by establishing that the level of technological innovation

    contributes significantly to economic performance.

    For robustness tests, we have used the error correction approach. Our results

    support the idea that there is evidence of bidirectional causality running from the

     percentage of all TEA business entities reporting business activity in a technology

    sector (high or medium), according to OECD classification to sustainable eco-

    nomic growth in the short-run. In the long-run, we find that the error correction

    term corresponding to the genuine savings equation is negative and statisticallysignificant. It means that there is evidence of long-run relationship running from

    TEA related to the technology sector to sustainable development.

    This is an important area of concern in entrepreneurship which improves our 

    knowledge about the nature of relationship between technological entrepreneur-

    ship and economic welfare.

    The knowledge gained from this research can be helpful in many ways. In fact,

    much of this research will provide concrete and scientific evidence for analyzing

    the relationship between investing in new technologies and sustainability by using

    a cointegration analysis. Thanks to this analysis, we are better able to understand what is happening within the creation of innovative and high-technology business

    and the sustainability of a nation economy.

    We can use this study to push government to promote entrepreneurial activities,

    especially for the ones that constantly innovate in technology sector and that

    ensuring favorable social and environmental conditions for the well-being of a

     population.

    This research can be extended by introducing variables related to the estab-

    lished businesses – the number of adults (18–64 years old) per 100 involved in

    established firm as owner and manager for which salaries or wages have been paid for more than 42 months – and reporting that they use the very latest technology,

    not available one year ago or that they use the new technology, not available since

    1–5 years. We can also use panel cointegration techniques to examine the causal

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    19/23

    The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development    17

    relationship between technology entrepreneurship and sustainability for develop-

    ing countries and make a comparison with the results obtained for developed 

    countries.

    Acknowledgements

    This research has received funding from the Global Entrepreneurship Research Association(GERA), London Business School, Regents Park, London NW1 4SA, UK.

    Disclosure statement

     No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

    Funding

    Global Entrepreneurship Research Association (GERA).

    Notes

    1.   High technology: aerospace, computers, office machinery, electronics communica-tions, pharmaceuticals, scientific instruments. Medium--high technology: motor vehi-cles, electrical machinery, chemicals, other transport equipment, non-electrical ma-chinery.   Medium--low technology: rubber and plastic products, shipbuilding, other manufacturing, non-ferrous metals, non-metallic mineral products, fabricated metal products, petroleum refining, ferrous metals.

    2. Countries belong to the   Group of Twelve   or   G12   which is a group of industriallyadvanced countries whose central banks co-operate to regulate international finance.

    3. Detailed calculation descriptions and definitions can be found in Bolt, Matete, and Clemens (2002), Hamilton (2006) or World Bank  (2011).

    ORCID

     Islem Khefacha   http://orcid.org/0000-0002-1635-5274

    References

    Abdullah, S., and L. Ahcene. 2011. “The Understanding of Technology EntrepreneurshipAccording to Shariah Principles.” Proceeding of International Conference on Businessand Economics Research. Singapore. 144–150.

    Abdullah, S., and M. Amran. 2008. “The Development of Entrepreneurship in Malaysia:State-Led Initiatives.” Asian Journal of Technology Innovation 16 (1): 101–116.

    Acs, Z. 2006. “How Is Entrepreneurship Good for Economic Growth?”   Innovations 1 (1):

    97–107.Acs, Z.-J., and D.-B. Audretsch. 2003. “Innovation and Technology Change.” In  Hand-

    book of Entrepreneurship Researcher , edited by Z.J. Acs and D.B. Audretsch, 55–79.Dordrecht: Kluwer.

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

    http://orcid.org/0000-0002-1635-5274http://orcid.org/0000-0002-1635-5274

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    20/23

    18   I. Khefacha and L. Belkacem

    Acs, Z.-J., and A. Varga. 2005. “Entrepreneurship, Agglomeration and TechnologicalChange.” Small Business Economics 24 (3): 323–334.

    Anderson, P., and M. Tushman. 1990. “Technological Discontinuities and Dominant De-signs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change.”  Administrative Science Quarterly

    35: 604–633.Antoncic, B. 2006. “Impacts of Diversification and Corporate Entrepreneurship Strategy

    Making on Growth and Profitability: A Normative Model.”   Journal of Enterprising Culture 14 (1): 49–63.

    Atkinson, G., and K. Hamilton. 2007. “Progress Along the Path: Evolving Issues in theMeasurement of Genuine Saving.”   Environmental and Resource Economics   37 (1):43–61.

    Audretsch, D.-B., and M. Keilbach. 2004. “Entrepreneurship Capital and Economic Perfor-mance.” Regional Studies 38: 949–959.

    Audretsch, D.-B., M. Keilbach, and E. Lehmann. 2006.  Entrepreneurship and EconomicGrowth. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Autio, E., Y.-P. Ho, and P.-K. Wong. 2005. “Entrepreneurship, Innovation and EconomicGrowth: Evidence from GEM Data.” Small Business Economics 24: 335–350.

    Bailetti, T. 2012. “Technology Entrepreneurship: Overview, Definition, and DistinctiveAspects.” Technology Innovation Management Review 2 (2): 5–12.

    Bolt, K., M. Matete, and M. Clemens. 2002.  Manual for Calculating Adjusted Net Savings.Washington, D.C.: World Bank Environment Department.

    Boos, A., and K. Holm-Müller, 2013. “The Relationship Between the Resource Curse and Genuine Savings: Empirical Evidence.”   Journal of Sustainable Development   6 (6):59–72.

    Bowen, H.P., and D. DeClercq. 2008. “Institutional Context and the Allocation of En-trepreneurial Effort.” Journal of International Business Studies 39 (4): 747–767.

    Breitung, J., and M.H. Pesaran. 2008. “Unit Roots and Cointegration in Panels.” In  The Econometrics of Panel Data: Fundamentals and Recent Developments in Theory and  Practice. 3rd ed. edited by L. Matyas and P. Sevestre, 279–322. Springer Publishers,Ch.9.

    Burgelman, R.A., and R.S. Rosenbloom. 1997. “Technology Strategy: An EvolutionaryProcess Perspective,” In Managing Strategic Innovation and Change, edited by M.L.Tushman and P. Anderson, 273–286. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Burgelman, R.A., M.A. Maidique, and S.C. Wheelwright. 1996. Strategic Management of Technology and Innovation.  http://www.duc.auburn.edu/∼ boultwr/5intstgy.pdf .

    Choi, I. 2001. “Unit Root Tests for Panel Data.” Journal of International Money and Finance20 (1): 249–272.

    Costantini, V., and C. Martini, 2010. “The Causality Between Energy Consumption and Economic Growth: A Multi-sectoral Analysis Using Non-stationary Cointegrated PanelData.” Energy Economics 32 (3): 591–603.

    Dejardin, M. 2000.   Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth: An Obvious Conjunction? Namur: University of Namur.

    Dietz, S., E., Neumayer, and I. Soysa. 2007. “Corruption, the Resource Curse and GenuineSaving.” Environment and Development Economics 12 (1): 33–53.

    Dopfer, K. 1992. “The Phenomenon of Economic Change: Neoclassical vs. Schumpete-rian Approaches.”   Evolutionary and Neo-Schumpeterian Approaches to Economics, Netherlands: Springer, 125–171.

    Dosi, G. 1988. “Sources, Procedures, and Microeconomic Effects of Innovation.” Journal 

    of Economic Literature 26: 1120–1171.Drucker, P. 1985.  Innovation and Entrepreneurship. New York: Harper and Row.Eberhardt, M. 2009. Non-stationary Panel Econometrics and Common Factor Models: An

     Introductory Reader . Oxford: University of Oxford.

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

    http://www.duc.auburn.edu/boultwr/5intstgy.pdfhttp://www.duc.auburn.edu/boultwr/5intstgy.pdfhttp://www.duc.auburn.edu/boultwr/5intstgy.pdfhttp://www.duc.auburn.edu/boultwr/5intstgy.pdfhttp://www.duc.auburn.edu/boultwr/5intstgy.pdf

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    21/23

    The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development    19

    Engle, R.-F., and C.-W.-J. Granger. 1987. “Co-integration and Error Correction: Represen-tation, Estimation, and Testing.” Econometrica 55 (2): 251–276.

    Evangelista, R. 2000. “Sectoral Patterns of Technological Change in Services, Economicsof Innovation.” Economics of Innovation and New Technology 9: 183–221.

    Freeman, C. 1998. “The Economics of Technical Change.” In Trade, Growth and Technical Change, edited by D. Archibugi and J. Michie, 16–54. Cambridge, MA: CambridgeUniversity Press.

    Fritsch, M., and P. Mueller. 2004. “The Effects of New Business Formation on RegionalDevelopment over Time.” Regional Studies 38: 961–975.

    Fritsch, M., and P. Mueller. 2008. “The Effect of New Business Formation on RegionalDevelopment over Time: The Case of Germany.” Small Business Economics 30: 15–29.

    Gaglio, C.M., and J.A. Katz. 2001. “The Psychological Basis of Opportunity Identification:Entrepreneurial Alertness.” Small Business Economics 16: 95–111.

    Granger, C.W.J. 1981. “Some Properties of Time Series Data and Their Use in EconometricModel Specification.” Journal of Econometrics 16: 121–130.

    Hadri, K. 2000. “Testing for Stationary in Heterogeneous Panel Data.”   Econometrics Journal  3 (2): 148–161.

    Hamilton, E. 2010. “Wealth, Saving and Sustainability.” In  Is Economic Growth Sustain-able?, International Economic Association (IEA) Conference Volume 148, edited byGeoffrey Heal. UK: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Hamilton, K. 2006. “Where is the Wealth of Nations? Measuring Capital for the 21st century.” Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.

    Harris, R.I.D., and R. Sollis. 2003. “ Applied Time Series Modelling and Forecasting .”Chichester: J. Wiley.

    Hurlin, C., and V. Mignon. 2008. “Une Synthèse des Tests de Cointégration Sur Donnéesde Panel.” Economie & Pr ́  evision 4: 241–265.

    Im, K.S., M.H. Pesaran, and Y. Shin. 2003. “Testing for Unit Roots in HeterogeneousPanels.” Journal of Econometrics  115: 53–74.Jin, Z. 2002. “Soft Technology – the Essential of Innovation.”  Futures Research Quarterly

    18 (2): 1–24.Johansen, S. 1988. “Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vectors.”  Journal of Economic

     Dynamics and Control  12: 231–254.Johansen, S. 1991. “Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of Cointegration Vectors in Gaus-

    sian Vector Autoregressive Models.” Econometrica 55: 1551–1580.Kao, C., and M.H. Chiang. 2000. “On the Estimation and Inference of a Cointegrated 

    Regression in Panel Data.” In Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration, and Dynamic Panels, edited by B.H. Baltagi. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Khefacha, I., L. Belkacem, and F. Mansouri. 2014. “An Estimated Model of New VentureCreation: Theories and Determinants in Tunisia.”  Journal of Enterprising Culture  22(1): 1–23.

    Lall, S. (1990). Building Industrial Competitiveness in Developing Countries. Paris: OECD.Levin, A., C. Lin, and C.J. Chu. 2002. “Unit Root Test with Panel Data: Asymptotic and 

    Finite-Sample.” Journal of Econometrics  108 (1): 1–24.Licht, A.N. 2007. “The Entrepreneurial Spirit and What the Law Can Do About it.”  Com-

     parative Labor Law & Policy Journal  28 (4): 817–862.Maddala, G., and S. Wu. 1999. “A Comparative Study of Unit Root Tests with Panel Data

    and a New Simple Test.”  Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 61: 631–652.Mansfield, E. 1972. “Contribution of Research and Development to Economic Growth of the

    United States.” Papers and Proceedings of a Colloquim on Research and Development and Economic Growth Productivity. Washington, DC: National Science Foundation.Mark, N.C., and D. Sul. 2003. “Cointegration Vector Estimation by Panel Dynamic OLS and 

    Long-Run Money Demand.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 65: 655–680.

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    22/23

    20   I. Khefacha and L. Belkacem

     Nadiri, I. 1993. “Innovationsand Technological Spillovers.” WorkingPaper 423. Cambridge.MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Miles, I. 2005. “Innovation in Services.” In   The Oxford Handbook of Innovation, edited  by J. Fagerberg, D.C. Mowery, and R.R. Nelson., 433–458. Oxford: Oxford University

    Press.Minniti, M., W. Bygrave, and E. Autio. 2005.   2005 Global Entrepreneurship Monitor .

    Babson Park, MA: Babson College. Nelson, R., and S. Winter. 1977. “In Search of a Useful Theory of Innovation.” Research

     Policy 6 (1): 36–75Onipede, S. 2003. Towards Creating an Environment for Sustainable Eco-

    nomic Growth in Nigeria, International Experience.   http://www.economist.com/countries/Nigeria/profile.cfm?folder = profileEconomic%20structure.

    Pearce, D.W., and G. Atkinson. 1993. “Capital Theory and the Measurement of SustainableDevelopment: An Indicator of Weak Sustainability.” Ecological Economics 8: 103–108.

    Pedroni, P. 1999. “Critical Values for Cointegration Tests in Heterogeneous Panels

    with Multiple Regressors.”   Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics   61: 727– 731.

    Pedroni, P. 2001. “Fully Modified OLS for Heterogeneous Cointegrated Panels.”  Advancesin econometrics 15: 93–130.

    Pedroni, P. 2004. “Panel Cointegration: Asymptotic and Finite Sample Properties of Pooled Time Series Tests with an Application to the PPP Hypothesis.”  Econometric Theory20: 597–625.

    Porter, M. 1990. The Competitive Advantage of Nations. New York: Free Press.Radosevic, S., and E. Yoruk. 2013. “Entrepreneurial Propensity of Innovation Systems:

    Theory, Methodology and Evidence.” Research Policy.Reynolds, P.D., M. Hay, and M. Camp. 1999.   Global Entrepreneurship Monitor 1999

     Executive Report . Babson Park, MA and London: Babson College and London BusinessSchool.Reynolds, P.D., M. Hay, W.D. Bygrave, S. Michael Camp, and E. Autio. 2000. “Global 

     Entrepreneurship Monitor: 2000 Executive Report .” Kansas City: Kaufman Centre.Reynolds, P.D., S. Michael Camp, W.D. Bygrave, E. Autio, and M. Hay. 2001. “Global 

     Entrepreneurship Monitor Global 2001 Executive Report .” Kansas City: KaufmanCenter.

    Reynolds, P.D., S. Michael Camp, W.D. Bygrave, E. Autio, and M. Hay. 2002. “Global  Entrepreneurship Monitor Global 2002 Executive Report .” Kansas City: KaufmanCenter.

    Reynolds, P., N. Bosma, E. Autio, S. Hunt, N. De Bono, I. Servaias, P. López Garcı́a,

    and N. Chin. 2005. “Global Entrepreneurship Monitor: Data Collection Design and Implementation 1998–2003.” Small Business Economics 24: 205–231.Rosenberg, N. 1976. Perspectives on Technology. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Romer, P. 1986. “Increasing Returns and Long Run Growth.” Journal of Political Economy

    94: 1002–1037Ruttan, V.W. 1997. “Induced Innovation, Evolutionary Theory and Path Dependence:

    Sources of Technical Change.” Economic Journal  107: 1520–1529Schumpeter, J. 1912. “The Theory of Economic Development.”  Cambridge. Cambridge,

    Mass: Harvard University Press.Schumpeter, J. 1950. “Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy.” 3rd ed. New York: Harper 

    and Row.

    Shane, S., and S. Venkataraman. 2003. “Guest Editors’ Introduction to the Special Issue onTechnology Entrepreneurship.” Research Policy 32 (2): 181–184.Shorrock, A. 2008. “Opening Address Presented at the, United Nations University-WIDER

    Conference on Entrepreneurship and Economic Development .” Helsinki, Finland.

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5

    http://www.economist.com/countries/Nigeria/profile.cfm?folder=profileEconomic%20structurehttp://www.economist.com/countries/Nigeria/profile.cfm?folder=profileEconomic%20structurehttp://www.economist.com/countries/Nigeria/profile.cfm?folder=profileEconomic%20structurehttp://www.economist.com/countries/Nigeria/profile.cfm?folder=profileEconomic%20structurehttp://www.economist.com/countries/Nigeria/profile.cfm?folder=profileEconomic%20structurehttp://www.economist.com/countries/Nigeria/profile.cfm?folder=profileEconomic%20structurehttp://www.economist.com/countries/Nigeria/profile.cfm?folder=profileEconomic%20structure

  • 8/18/2019 Technology Based Ventures

    23/23

    The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development    21

    Solow, R. 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.”  Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 65–94

    Song M., C. Droge, S. Hanvanich, and R. Calantone. 2005. “Marketing and Technology Re-source Complementarity: An Analysis of their Interaction Effect in Two Environmental

    Contexts.” Strategic Management Journal  26 (3): 259–276.Stam, E., and A. van Stel. 2009. “Types of Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth.”

     Research Paper 2009/47 . Helsinki: UNUWider.Szirmai, A., W. Naud ́e, and M. Goedhuys. 2011. Entrepreneurship, Innovation, and Eco-

    nomic Development . Oxford: Oxford University Press.Tan, S. 2004.   Ecological Perspectives in Entrepreneurship: Science and Sustainability.

    Singapore: Nanyang Technological University.Taylor, M.P., and Sarno, L. 1998. “The Behavior of Real Exchanges During the Post-Bretton

    Woods Period.” Journal of International Economics  46: 281–312.Twiss, B., and M. Goodridge. 1989.   Managing Technology for Competitive Advantage

     Integrating Technological and Organizational Development: From Strategy to Action.

    Aulander, NC: Pitman Publishing.Uysal, A.H. 2010.  CT Development and Economic Growth: An Analysis of Cointegrat-

    ing and Causal Relationships with a Panel Data Approach. Stockholm: School of Architecture and the Built Environment Royal Institute of Technology.

    Van Stel, A.J. 2006. “Empirical Analysis of Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth.” Vol.13 of  International Studies in Entrepreneurship. New York: Springer Science.

    Wong, Po, Kam Ping, Ho Yuen, and A. Erkko. 2005. “Entrepreneurship, Innovation and Economic Growth: Evidence from GEM Data.”  Small Business Economics   24 (3):335–350.

    World Bank. 2011. “The Changing Wealth Of Nations: Measuring Sustainable Development in the New Millennium.” Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

    Wright, M., K.M. Hmieleski, D.S. Siegel, and M.D. Ensley. 2007. “The Role of HumanCapital in Technological Entrepreneurship.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 31(6): 791–806.

    Yli-Renko H, E. Autio, and H.J Sapienza. 2001. “Social Capital, Knowledge Acquisition,and Knowledge Exploitation in Young, Technology-Based Firms.”  Strategic Manage-ment Journal  22 (6–7): 587–613.

       D  o  w

      n   l  o  a   d  e   d   b  y   [   i  s   l  e  m    k

       h  e   f  a  c   h  a

       ]  a   t   0   4  :   3   9   0   3   S  e  p   t  e  m   b  e  r   2   0

       1   5