sunk costs and exporting behavior: a sectoral analysis

25
1 Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis Kurmaş Akdoğan 1 & Laura M. Werner 2,3 11 June 2019 ABSTRACT: This article examines the hysteresis behavior due to sunk costs in exports of the Turkish manufacturing sector. The results of the analysis using the Preisach method for 2006Q1 to 2018Q2 reveal hysteresis for only one sector: The manufacturing of wearing apparel, dressing and dyeing of fur (clothing). To shed more light on this result we provide detailed information on the multi-layered production structure of the clothing sector. We argue that the sub-contracting capacity of intermediaries with their previous export experience and established connections, low importance of plant size in the entry decision, easier financing conditions and price advantage due to a real exchange rate depreciation are the main determinants of relatively lower sunk costs in this sector. KEYWORDS: Nonlinearity, Path-dependency, Exports. JEL: C19, F14, L60 1 Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, Structural Economic Research Department, Ulus, 06050, Ankara, Turkey, [email protected]. 2 FernUniversität in Hagen, Faculty of Business Adminstration and Economics, 58084 Hagen, Germany, [email protected]. 3 The views and opinions presented in this study belong to the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey. The authors would like to thank to Cihan Yalçın, Şeref Saygılı, Etkin Özen, Orhun Sevinç, Hülya Saygılı, Saygın Şahinöz and Yusuf Emre Akgündüz as well as the seminar participants at Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey and Eastern Mediterranean University.

Upload: others

Post on 07-Dec-2021

8 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

1

Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

Kurmaş Akdoğan1 & Laura M. Werner2,3

11 June 2019

ABSTRACT:

This article examines the hysteresis behavior due to sunk costs in exports of the Turkish

manufacturing sector. The results of the analysis using the Preisach method for 2006Q1 to 2018Q2

reveal hysteresis for only one sector: The manufacturing of wearing apparel, dressing and dyeing of

fur (clothing). To shed more light on this result we provide detailed information on the multi-layered

production structure of the clothing sector. We argue that the sub-contracting capacity of

intermediaries with their previous export experience and established connections, low importance of

plant size in the entry decision, easier financing conditions and price advantage due to a real

exchange rate depreciation are the main determinants of relatively lower sunk costs in this sector.

KEYWORDS: Nonlinearity, Path-dependency, Exports.

JEL: C19, F14, L60

1 Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, Structural Economic Research Department, Ulus, 06050, Ankara, Turkey, [email protected]. 2 FernUniversität in Hagen, Faculty of Business Adminstration and Economics, 58084 Hagen, Germany, [email protected]. 3 The views and opinions presented in this study belong to the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey. The authors would like to thank to Cihan Yalçın, Şeref Saygılı, Etkin Özen, Orhun Sevinç, Hülya Saygılı, Saygın Şahinöz and Yusuf Emre Akgündüz as well as the seminar participants at Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey and Eastern Mediterranean University.

Page 2: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

2

I. Introduction

In much of the literature on foreign trade, export demand is determined as a function of the relative

prices and external demand. The former determinant could be captured by prices at the product

level (in domestic or foreign currency, depending on the specification) or by using the real effective

exchange rate (REER) at the aggregated (sectoral or country) level. An increase in REER implies lower

competitiveness and hence is expected to decrease exports. However, as documented in the

previous literature, this presumed theoretical negative relationship between exports and the real

exchange rate does not hold (or is not stable over time) for many countries. Instead, aggregate

exports are mostly driven by external demand conditions.

Among alternative rationales provided by the literature to account for the aforementioned inability

of real exchange rates in explaining exports, this article highlights the sunk costs of entry and exit. As

the argument goes, existence of sunk costs would imply threshold level(s) of exchange rate for the

firms to enter into (and exit from) the export market. In between these thresholds, there is a band of

inaction where the firm does not change its export status. For example, an exporting firm with high

sunk costs might bear with temporary losses as long as the variable costs are covered. This wait-and-

see behavior of individual firms would result in hysteresis in export markets at the aggregated level.

In economics, hysteresis would suggest permanent effects of temporary shocks and is usually

characterized by path-dependent multiple equilibria. Nevertheless, measuring hysteresis is not

straightforward since the adjustment of exports could differ in size and speed depending on the firm

characteristics. Firms might have different exchange rate thresholds beyond which their export

market activity would change. This article employs Preisach method to aggregate the impact of the

aforementioned wait-and-see behavior of individual firms on exports, taking cognizance of different

threshold levels.

The empirical exercise includes 17 subsectors of the Turkish manufacturing sector. In this sense and

to the best of our knowledge, this study is the first one that tests for the existence of export market

hysteresis in Turkey. Turkey is a developing country with increasing export orientation in the last

couple of decades and provides an interesting case study for the aforementioned export market

hysteresis phenomenon. On the one hand, higher integration of Turkish firms into the global value

chains increases their export survival rate and suggests a weaker role for exchange rates in their

entry-exit decisions to the export market. On the other hand, the enduring depreciation of the

domestic currency in real terms in the last years (Figure 1) renewed interest on the relationship

between the exchange rate and exports at the sub-sectoral level. In particular, this exercise puts into

test whether taking cognizance of the hysteresis behavior in the export market would help us signify

the relationship between exports and exchange rates in certain sectors.

INSERT FIGURE 1 ABOUT HERE

Our empirical exercise includes two-stages. In the first stage, we conduct the conventional export

equation with REER and a global growth variable and show that REER could not explain exports in any

subsectors. In the second stage, we replace the REER with the Preisach variable (PV), a variable that

filters the small changes in the exchange rate calculated á la Piscitelli et al. (2000). A significant PV

would imply the existence of hysteresis in the export market. The results of this second stage point

out a single subsector for which such a nonlinear filter improves the significance of the exchange rate

in export estimations: The manufacturing of wearing apparel, dressing and dyeing of fur (henceforth

Page 3: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

3

referred to as clothing). 4 This result indicates that once the hysteresis behavior in the export market

is taken into account, the theoretical relationship between exports and the exchange rate holds in

this sector.

To shed more light on the results, the dynamics of the production and export behavior in the clothing

sector is analyzed in depth. Consequently, a number of factors are suggested for the hysteresis in the

Turkish clothing sector: the sub-contracting capacity of intermedieries determined with their

previous export experience and established connections, the low importance of plant size in entry

decision, easier financing conditions and price advantage due to a real exchange rate depreciation.

The plan of the study is as follows. Next section presents a review of the literature on the export

market hysteresis methods as well as a brief review of the historical evolution of Turkish export

dynamics followed by the corresponding literature on the Turkish exports. The third section

describes the Preisach method in detail. The fourth section describes the data and the fifth section

documents the results. The sixth section discusses the policy implications of the results and

concludes.

II. Literature Review on Export Market Hysteresis and the Dynamics of the Turkish

Exports

II.a. Literature on export market hysteresis

There are many occasions a firm may face sunk costs when entering an export market. For example

information about foreign demand, or health and security standards of destinations have to be

gathered (Bernhard and Wagner, 2001; Roberts and Tybout, 1997). Transporting, distribution and

selling have to be organized (Baldwin, 1990; Bernhard and Wagner, 2001). There may be costs for

advertising and establishing a brand name as well as for hiring and training additional workers

(Baldwin, 1990). Exiting a market can also involve sunk costs as e.g. severance payments. Dixit

(1989a), Dixit (1989b), and Baldwin and Krugman (1989) studied the impacts of sunk costs for market

entry and exit theoretically. They lay also the foundation for the hysteresis literature in international

trade.

Roberts and Tybout (1997) test if sunk cost hysteresis effects the exporting decisions of Colombian

firms and indeed find evidence that prior market experience influences the export decision. Other

factors which affect exporting behavior are macroeconomic conditions, observable plant costs and

demand variables as well as unobserved time-invariant plant heterogeneity. Lieberman et al. (2015)

show that sunk costs for market entry and exit decrease if the investment, such as a new build plant

or specially trained workers, can be used in a related existing business earned by the investor.

Timoshenko (2015) begins her framework with the same hysteresis model of non-ideal relay as we

do. She aims to identify the source of state dependence and therefore distinguishes between sunk

costs and learning-by-exporting which could both be reasons for hysteresis. Studying Colombian

plant-level data from 1979 to 1989 she finds that learning, i.e. being exporting in previous periods,

has a stronger effect on export persistence than sunk costs especially in differentiated-products

industries. She argues that exporters continue exporting because export experience depreciates

rapidly. Roberts and Tybout (1997) also state that a Colombian firm with two years absence of

exporting has to pay similar reentry costs than a new exporter.

Meinen (2015) controls for aspects like learning and finds that destination specific sunk costs matter.

However, they matter differently across sectors. In addition, import experience from a specific

4 Both “clothing” or “garment” terms are used in a mixed manner for this sector in previous studies.

Page 4: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

4

market is able to facilitate exports to this destination. Studying the Danish furniture industry, Meinen

(2015) shows that a firm which already exports has a higher probability of a further export market

expansion than a non-exporting firm. However, the latter result depends on the characteristics and

the number of developed export markets. Gullstrand and Persson (2015) distinguish core and

peripheral export markets and give reasons for core markets having higher entry costs, e.g. for

marketing. Thus, they find theoretical and empirical evidence, testing Swedish food chain data from

1997 to 2007, that firms stay longer on core markets in line with hysteresis literature but are more

willing to exit peripheral markets as is analyzed by trade duration literature. Padmaja and Sasidharan

(2017) analyze Indian firm-level data of manufacturing firms and find also evidence that sunk costs

matter for the export participation decision. They are able to control for firm characteristics and

show that large firms, foreign owned firms and multiproduct firms face less sunk costs than small

firms, single product firms or firms owned by Indians. Beneath a dynamic discrete choice model they

also apply discrete-duration survival analysis and find persistence in exports. The longer a firm

exports, the lesser is the risk of exit from the export market.

Kemp and Wan (1974) lay the foundation of hysteresis in trade studies. They found out that adding

adjustment costs of hiring and firing induce multiple long-run equilibria in a closed economy, two

industries model with only one mobile factor, labor. Thus, they found hysteresis as it is known in

physics e.g. in magnetics. Hysteresis in trade, on the other hand, is usually caused by sunk costs. It is

referred to as export persistence, meaning that exporters stay in export markets despite unfavorable

conditions such as home currency appreciations. A further characteristic of a hysteresis system is

that large shocks which neutralize each other do not bring the system back to its initial point. This

characteristic property is called remanence (Piscitelli et al. 2000). The starting point for research in

the eighties (Baldwin and Krugman, 1989; Baldwin, 1990; Dixit 1989a; Dixit 1989b) was that an

appreciation of the US dollar from 1980 to 1985 resulted in market entries in the USA of foreign firms

which did not abandon the US market after the exchange rate shock was over. These foreign firms

stayed on the US market because they had already paid sunk market entry costs, e.g. invested in

distribution networks and marketing. On the other hand, US firms abandoned export markets during

this time span and did not re-enter these markets only because of the following dollar depreciation

(Baldwin and Krugman, 1989). Other competitors may have filled the gap and a re-entry may have

been costly. Thus, the exchange rate period of dollar appreciation changed the market structure of

US and former US export markets. A temporary shock had long-lasting effects. Thus, path-

dependence combined with non-linearity is another characteristic property of hysteresis.

After Roberts and Tybout (1997) showed that sunk costs influence the decision to export, Belke and

Göcke (1999) examine the effects of exchange rate changes on employment if costs for hiring and

firing matter. In Belke and Göcke (2001) they provide an estimation procedure with which they also

test for hysteresis in trade (Belke et al. (2013); Belke et al. (2014); Belke et al. (2015)). They derive a

hysteresis variable from the exchange rate and include it in an empirical estimation model. The

advantage of this approach is the sufficiency of aggregated export data which are more available

than firm-level data. Piscitelli et al. (2000) apply another approach which builds on the algorithm of

Preisach (1935) to derive a hysteresis variable. In Hallett and Piscitelli (2002) both methods are

compared and the latter one is favored. However, in Belke et al. (2013), Belke et al. (2014), and Belke

et al. (2015) an improved version of the algorithm is used and hysteresis is found for German and

other European Area member countries’ exports. Werner (2017) examines European wine exports to

the US applying the method of Belke and Göcke (2001) as well as the Preisach method published by

Piscitelli et al. (2000) and receives similar results with both approaches. De Prince and Kannelbey

Junior (2013) study hysteresis in prices and quantities of Brazilian imports and combine the Piscitelli

(2002) method with panel cointegration testing.

Page 5: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

5

Using Spanish firm-level data, Campa (2004) and Manez et al. (2008) find hysteresis in Spanish

manufacturing exports due to sunk costs which affect small firms in particular.

Other researchers use time series methods to search for hysteresis. Kannebley (2008) applies e.g.

threshold cointegration analysis and identifies hysteresis in Brazilian exports. However, many time

series analysts define hysteresis as zero-root dynamics. In this case all past events influence the

current state of the output variable. In contrast to this we use the term hysteresis as it is defined in

physics which means there is a selective memory. Thus, the output depends only on the non-

dominated past extremum values of the input. This phenomenon will be described later in section IV.

Amable et al. (1994), Amable et al. (2004), O’Shaughnessy (2000) or Setterfield (2009) discuss the

differences of these approaches in more detail.

II.b. Historical review of Turkish exports dynamics and the corresponding literature on

export market entry-exit decisions

The Turkish industrialization strategy during early 1930s to 1980s could be characterized by import-

substitution policies with protection of certain sectors aiming to expand their industrial base. While a

handful of export promotion schemes were adopted especially after 1960s, the industrial and trade

policies as a whole did not create a favorable environment for enhancing exports and the country has

suffered serious balance of payments problems in the 1970s. Accordingly, 1980s marked a shift from

the earlier policies of reducing imports to the low level of exports towards a broader policy of import

liberalization along with export promotion. These policies were accompanied by a more liberalized

exchange rate regime during the decade whereas the capital account has been fully liberalized in

1989. This outward-oriented policy initially led to a sharp increase in exports of the manufacturing

sector at the first half of 1980s, partially owing to the excess capacity of the sector following the

import shortages and recessions of the previous decade (Şenses, 1989). However, these export

promotion policies were not accompanied with sufficient investments in the manufacturing sector

and hence could not generate a profound accumulation pattern for sustainable growth for the

following decades5 (Özcan et al., 2001). Accordingly, the productivity gains in the leading export

sectors of 1980s were relatively limited (Voyvoda and Yeldan, 2001). Then again, lower labor costs

due to wage suppression and real depreciation of the domestic currency led to a competitive export

market in most parts of 1980s and 1990s.

Turkey signed a customs union agreement with the European Union in 1996. Afterwards, the export

performance in the first decade of the 2000s were relatively strong compared to the previous

decades. Exports show a fivefold increase from 2002 to 2017 in US dollar terms while their share of

GDP oscillates between 20 and 25 percent during the same period (Figure 2). Moreover, the

composition of exports has shifted from the sectors that produce consumption goods towards the

sectors that produce intermediate goods (Figure 3).

INSERT FIGURE 2 AND FIGURE 3 ABOUT HERE

An assessment of the structural change in Turkish exports in the last two decades should also take

cognizance of the change in world trade patterns in this same period. According to OECD (2018a), 70

percent of the current global trade consists of production through global value chains (GVC’s) where

means of production are exchanged across countries during the different stages of production. The

trade in value added (TİVA) analysis which considers this fragmented production structure suggests

5 In their comparative study where they focus on Turkish and Korean export-oriented growth strategies, Onaran and Stockhammer (2006) show that investments are stimulated by export competitiveness in Korea while they are driven mostly by domestic demand in Turkey.

Page 6: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

6

that the foreign content of Turkish exports fluctuates between 15 to 20 percent in the last decade,

which is lower than the OECD average of 25 percent (OECD, 2018b).

The increasing role of GVCs is particularly relevant for our original question for a couple of reasons.

First, higher participation in GVC increases the export survival rate for firms thanks to the lower

uncertainty, higher cooperation, strategic partnership among foreign firms as well as knowledge of

foreign markets (Diaz et al., 2018a)6. Accordingly, Türkcan (2016) shows higher export survival rates

for Turkish firms producing machinery equipment with higher engagement in GVCs. Second, as OECD

(2018a) points out, even small trade barriers (such as a low tariff rate) could have recurring patterns

along the value chains, hence could accumulate into substantial costs. This could be considered as a

factor increasing the entry costs to the export market. Third, this recurrence in production also

implies a lower exchange rate elasticity for exports [Ahmed et al. (2015), Soyres et al. (2018)]7.

Recent studies on Turkish exports suggest that the external demand is the main determinant of

exports while relative prices are mostly insignificant, in line with the literature on many other

countries, as discussed in the introduction. Uz (2010) and Saygılı and Saygılı (2011) studies both show

that exchange rate sensitivity of Turkish exports is very low. The latter study further argues that the

impact of external demand is not stable over time. In particular, foreign demand elasticity of exports

is higher for the 2000-2008 period in comparison to the 1987-2000 period. Bozok et al. (2015) use

disaggregation among export regions and show that while income is significant for all regions,

relative prices are only significant for selected regions. Similarly, Çulha and Kalafatçılar (2014) show

that exports to developed countries have a significant relationship with foreign income while exports

to emerging markets are more responsive to real exchange rate changes. Berument et al. (2014)

focus on the variation in income elasticities among sectors. They suggest that the income elasticity is

high in Motor Vehicles, Basic Metals and Radio-TV while it is either insignificant or low for food

products and the beverages sector8.

The literature on the export market participation decisions of Turkish manufacturing sector consists

of a number of sectoral as well as firm-level analyses. Özler et al. (2009) examines Turkish

manufacturing firms for the 1990-2001 period and show that sunk costs of entry are higher than that

of re-entry, indicating a positive but diminishing effect of the export history on export entry

decisions. Aldan and Günay (2008) results provide support for the self-selection hypothesis in the

sense that the presence of larger and more productive firms in export markets would be an outcome

of their higher capability to bear the sunk costs of entrance. Recently, Demirhan (2016a) further

underlines the existence of a learning effect, in addition to the self-selection hypothesis for Turkish

exporters. Corroborating with the findings of Özler et al. (2009), she also suggests the significance of

previous export experience in export propensity.

Demirhan (2016b) further delves into the entry and exit decisions of exporting firms in Turkish manufacturing sectors, using duration models. She shows that firms waiting time to be an exporter gets smaller with size, productivity, quality-orientation, ease of financing and capital intensity. Interestingly, profitability is suggested to lower the export incentive which is suggested as an implication of the risk-averse behavior of these firms. However, partially in contrary to these results,

6 Diaz et al. (2018b) also shows that manufacutring export flows with higher foreign services lead to longer export duration. 7 In line with this view, Eichengreen and Gupta (2013) argues that the exchange rate elasticity of services is higher than the manufacturing sector since the service sector employ fewer imported inputs. 8 One contrary evidence to the insignificant relationship between exchange rate and exports is recently provided by Toraganlı and Yalçın

(2016). They show that the firms with higher foreign exchange denominated debt to exports are more sensitive to the changes in the

exchange rate, pointing out the importance of liability dollarization and currency mismatch in financing decisions of, in particular, the small

and medium sized firms.

Page 7: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

7

Gezici et al. (2018) argues that financing constraints of Turkish manufacturing firms do not present a significant obstacle for export market entry. Demirhan and Ercan (2018) analyze the impact of economic crises on export behavior of the Turkish

manufacturing firms. According to their results, export propensity increased in 1994 due to

devaluation and contracting demand. However, while similar conditions resulted in an increase in

export volume, accompanying credit crunch was a major obstacle for new entrants in 2001 crisis. The

2008 crisis, on the other hand, highlights a contraction both in export propensity and export volume

due to the collapse in global trade.

III. Data

The quarterly sectoral export volume indices which are classified in Broad Economic Classification are

taken from Turkish Statistical Institute for 2006Q1-2018Q2 period. The manufacturing sector has 17

subsectors as presented in Table 4.

The CPI based real effective exchange rate (REER) is measured as the weighted geometric average of

the domestic prices relative to the prices of the principal trade partners and taken from the Central

Bank of the Republic of Turkey (CBRT) database. An increase in REER suggests appreciation of the

domestic currency in real terms, indicating higher value of Turkish goods in terms of foreign goods.

Hence, the expected sign of the coefficient in the export specification is negative.

The foreign demand variable is the export-weighted global growth. This index is calculated by

multiplying the real growth of country i with the weights of this country in Turkish exports (wi) at

time t (Çıplak et al., 2011).

𝐺𝐺𝑒𝑥𝑝,𝑡 = ∑ 𝑤𝑖𝑦𝑡,𝑖

𝑛

𝑖=1

In the export estimation, higher global demand would indicate higher exports and hence the

expected sign of this coefficient would be positive.

The quarterly real GDP is calendar adjusted, measured as a chain linked volume index and provided

by Turkish Statistical Institute (TURKSTAT).

Most of our series suffer from the unit root problem and display seasonal patterns. Taking

cognizance of these problems, we employed year-on-year changes for all dependent and

independent variables in our estimations.

IV. Method

We apply the Preisach procedure (Preisach, 1935) provided by Piscitelli et al. (2000) to derive a

hysteresis variable, namely, Preisach variable, (PV). This variable is kind of a filtered exchange rate

which only reflects the large changes. More precisely, the non-dominated local minima and maxima

are described by this variable.

To derive the PV variable, we start with the non-ideal relay which displays the simplest hysteresis

model. We assume that the depending variable can take only two states: exporting (1) and not

exporting (0). The independent variable which causes these two states is the exchange rate.

Fluctuations of the exchange rate are expressed by back and forth movements on the horizontal axis.

Movements to the right are interpreted as depreciations of the home currency. Therefore if the

exchange rate comes from a low value and increases steadily, it will, at some point in time, reach the

Page 8: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

8

export market entry trigger 𝛼 thus incentivize the firm to start exporting (Figure 4). We assume that a

firm which enters an export market has to pay sunk costs. If the exchange rate increases/depreciates

further, the firm will stay in the export market. However, despite the exchange rate appreciates

afterwards and falls below the entry trigger the firm will stay in the export market because it has

already paid the irrevocable market entry costs. However, if the exchange rate decreases more and

more, there will be a value at which the variable costs of exporting are not covered anymore and the

firm will pay the market exit costs and abandon the market. This value is the exit trigger 𝛽 at which

the firm switches from state 1 to state 0 (Figure 4). Thus, between the exit trigger and the entry

trigger there is a band of inaction. Knowing that the exchange rate is currently in this band does not

suffice to determine if the firm is exporting or not. It is important to know in which state the firm has

been in the previous period because if the firm has been in state 0, a movement in the band of

inaction which does not exceed the entry trigger, lets the firm stay in its non-exporting state.

Analogous considerations can be done if the exchange rate alters within the band of inaction and the

firm was in state 1 in the previous period. As long as the exchange rate is not less than the exit

trigger, the firm still exports. Mathematically we can express the non-ideal relay 𝐹𝛼,𝛽(𝑥(𝑡)) which

depends on the market entry trigger 𝛼 and the market exit trigger 𝛽 < 𝛼, as well as on the exchange

rate x(t) at time t as:

𝐹𝛼,𝛽(𝑥(𝑡)) = {1, if 𝑥(𝑡) ≥ 𝛼 − (𝛼 − 𝛽)𝐹𝛼,𝛽(𝑥(𝑡 − 1))

0, otherwise,

see Timoshenko (2015).

INSERT FIGURE 3 AROUND HERE

Therefore, the non-ideal relay is able to model the exporting hysteresis behavior of one firm in a

simple way. The next step is to aggregate many heterogeneous firms of which everyone has different

entry and exit trigger values.

𝑃𝑉(𝑥(𝑡)) = ∬ 𝜔(𝛼, 𝛽)𝐹𝛼,𝛽(𝑥(𝑡))𝑑𝛼𝑑𝛽𝛼≥𝛽

This aggregation procedure was invented by Preisach (1935). We assume that the different entry and

exit triggers of the firms are distributed uniformly among the Preisach triangle which is depicted in

Figure 4. This assumption is technically convenient as we assume that the weight function 𝜔(𝛼, 𝛽) ≡

1 for all 𝛼 and 𝛽, but does not alter the results meaningfully as was shown by Piscitelli et al. (2000).

We write the exit trigger values on the horizontal axis and the entry trigger values on the vertical

axis. Then, all firms lie in the Preisach triangle which is bordered by the entry = exit trigger line, the

vertical axis and the maximum of the exchange rate in the considered period because for all firms the

entry trigger exceeds the entry trigger i.e. 𝛽 < 𝛼. To illustrate the aggregation process, let us assume

we start at a low value of the exchange rate at which no firms export. An increase of the exchange

rate up to a local maximum M1 therefore will exceed entry triggers of some firms. These firms will

now export and they can be identified by the triangle which arises when we move upwards on the

vertical axis (Figure 5a).

Next, the exchange rate will decrease to a local minimum value m1. Firms whose exit triggers are

undercut will exit the export market. They can be found in Figure 4 by projecting the previous local

maximum M1 from the vertical axis by the entry = exit trigger line to the horizontal axis. Next, the

movement from this local maximum value to the local minimum value is retraced on horizontal axis.

Page 9: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

9

The exiting firms are represented by the small triangle which is cut from the previous triangle of

active firms. i.e. the active firms are now depicted by a trapezoid (Figure 5b).

INSERT FIGURE 5 AROUND HERE

The next example shows how local maxima and minima are erased from the memory process. A

strong increase of the exchange rate, retraced by a vertical move on the vertical axis up to a higher

local maximum than the last one M2 > M1, erases all previous local maxima and minima from the

memory process. A large upwards movement means a huge shift to the right in all firm’s non-ideal

relays which means that all the firms which entry triggers are exceeded will now start to export or

remain in the export market, see Figure 5c. The next decrease of the exchange rate results in a

trapezoid of active firms as described above, see Figure 5d. The following increase which is assumed

to be not as strong as the second one up to M3, adds a further triangle to the trapezoid when moving

upwards on the vertical axis again. Following fluctuations of the exchange rate results in the end in a

staircase function which divides the Preisach triangle in two parts. In the upper part 𝑆− lie the firms

which are not active in the export market whereas in the lower part 𝑆+ all exporting firms are

pictured. As 𝐹𝛼,𝛽(𝑥(𝑡)) = 0 for all inactive firms in 𝑆−, it is sufficient to integrate over all active firms

in 𝑆+ where 𝐹𝛼,𝛽(𝑥(𝑡)) = 1, thus:

𝑃𝑉(𝑥(𝑡)) = ∬ 𝜔(𝛼, 𝛽)𝐹𝛼,𝛽(𝑥(𝑡))𝑑𝛼𝑑𝛽𝑆+

+ ∬ 𝜔(𝛼, 𝛽)𝐹𝛼,𝛽(𝑥(𝑡))𝑑𝛼𝑑𝛽𝑆−

= ∬ 𝜔(𝛼, 𝛽)𝑑𝛼𝑑𝛽𝑆+

≈ ∑ ∬ 𝜔(𝛼, 𝛽)𝑑𝛼𝑑𝛽𝑄𝑘(𝑡)

𝑛(𝑡)

𝑘=1= ∑ 𝑄𝑘(𝑡)

𝑛(𝑡)

𝑘=1

Every step of the staircase function is built by a trapezoid 𝑄𝑘(𝑡), thus the Preisach variable PV at time

t is the sum of all 𝑛(𝑡) trapezoids which represent the active firms at time t. Only non-dominated

local extremum values matter for the memory process which is selective, non-linear and with

remanence (Hallett and Piscitelli, 2002).

In our analysis, the set of equations are estimated for each subsector of the Turkish manufacturing

sector:

Xti, yoy = C + α1 REERt ,yoy+ α2 GGt,yoy + α3 GDPt-1,yoy + εti (1)

Xti,yoy = C + α1 PVt,yoy + α2 GGt ,yoy+ α3 GDPt-1,yoy + εti (2)

In the equations, X stands for the export volume, C is the constant term, REER is the real effective

exchange rate, GG is the export-weighted global growth, GDP is the gross domestic product, PV is the

Preisach variable and ε is the error term where subscript t and i denote the time and sector

components. The impacts of crises are captured by two dummies in our estimations. One of them is

the 2008 global crises (denoted by FC) which reduced both the export volume and new entrance in

export markets (Demirhan and Ercan, 2008) as mentioned in the literature section. We also use a

dummy for 2016Q4 to capture the impact of the Russia-Turkey jet crisis: When Turkey shot down a

Russian jet, Russia decided to ban some Turkish export products until the issue has been solved

Page 10: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

10

through diplomacy9. This dummy is shown as DP16_4 in the estimations. For each subsector, the first

equation is the benchmark equation with REER. In the following equation, we replace REER with the

aforementioned PV variable.

The motivation for using the explanatory variables, REER and GG, are discussed in previous sections

in line with the previous literature. The literature also suggests including variables capturing

domestic growth measuring the impact of two counteracting forces in export supply estimations

(Goldstein and Khan, 1985). On the one hand, an increase in trend income could result in an increase

in total factor productivity or would indicate better infrastructure. Moreover, assuming that there is

excess capacity for exporting firms, higher income would lead to more abundant factor supplies. All

these factors would result in higher supply of exports. On the other hand, if domestic demand is the

leading factor for higher income, then exporting firms might prefer to direct their sales towards the

domestic market to reap potential profits, resulting in lower exports. Hence, the coefficient of GDP

could be positive or negative depending on which of these counteracting factors would dominate.

There are two nuisances that should be handled in PV estimations as stated by previous literature.

First, as documented above, all of our dependent and independent variables suffer from non-

stationarity indicating time-dependent means or variances. However, usual remedy of taking

differences is problematic in PV analysis since the procedure deals with path-dependent effects

determined by the levels of the forcing variable (exchange rate) (Belke et al, 2013). One solution to

this problem is using fully modified least squares (FM-OLS) proposed by Phillips and Hansen (1990),

and implemented by Mota et al. (2012). However, as Belke et al. (2013) reports the problem still

remains for identification of play width in this framework. Instead, in our analysis we employ a two-

stage process, different than the previous literature. In the first stage, the PV variable is derived from

the level of the exchange rate. In the second stage, we take year-on-year (y-o-y) difference of this

variable and use it in our estimation. The y-o-y difference would also help us to account for the

seasonality problem in the export series.

The second nuisance is on the correlation between the PV variable and the forcing variable. As

described above, the PV variable is a filtered version of the exchange rate and could reveal high

correlation if the band of inaction is small. Taking cognizance of the impact of correlation between

independent variables on the results, unlike the previous literature, we do not use REER and PV

variables in the same equations.

V. Results

The estimation results for the manufacturing sector and its subsectors are provided in Tables 1-3. For

each subsector, the first column includes the estimations with REER and the second column the

estimations with PV.

The estimation results for the manufacturing sector as a whole (Columns 1 and 2 of Tables 1-3)

suggest that the global growth variable is significant while the domestic demand indicator is

insignificant. On the other hand, the real effective exchange rate coefficient has an unexpected

positive sign. These results are in line with the previous literature stating that the main determinant

of the exports in the manufacturing sector is the global growth and the exchange rate is mostly

insignificant (Uz, 2014; Saygılı and Saygılı, 2011; Bozok et al., 2015; Çulha and Kalafatçılar, 2014;

Berument et al., 2014.).

9 See news in the link https://www.bbc.com/news/world-europe-35209987.

Page 11: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

11

The rest of Tables 1-3 present the sectoral results. The REER is either positive or not significant in all

subsectors, as shown in the first columns of each subsector. At this point we ask whether this result

changes once we consider the band of inaction due to sunk costs. To answer this question, we

replace the REER with the PV variable. The results are documented in the second column of each

subsector. The results indicate that for only two sectors, this new filtered exchange rate (PV variable)

is significant: manufacturing of wearing apparel, dressing and dyeing of fur; and manufacture of

radio, television and communication equipment and apparatus (abbreviated as clothing and radio,

respectively for the rest of the text). In our analysis, we only focus on the clothing sector,

disregarding the relatively unreliable results for radio. For the radio sector the insignificance of the

global growth variable and the significance of the crisis dummy suggest that the estimation would

take into account the structural breaks in the period. However, without a longer data set, the result

of such an analysis would not be reliable.

First of all, the absence of the significance of PV in most sectors could be the result of very large sunk

costs (hence very large band of inaction). As the argument goes, the main determinant of export

entry behavior for many developing countries is the “trust” of the foreign correspondent to the

domestic firm for sustainable production. If the foreign buyer could not tolarate an interruption in

any stage of her production, she would be very selective on including a domestic firm into the

production chain. This kind of confidence could only be provided by large and experienced firms.

These firms, on the other hand, are usually less credit-constrained, in the sense that they can raise

funds in foreign currency and could hedge themselves against changes in the exchange rate. Hence,

the production processes for many of these large and capital-intensive firms are less dependent on

exchange rate changes. This argument is in line with the self-selection hypothesis in export entry

decision as described in the second section (Aldan and Günay, 2008; Demirhan 2016a).

The significance of the PV variable for the clothing, on the other hand, could be motivated with an in-

depth analysis of the production layers specific to this sector. To this aim, we first provide a general

description of the sector and depict the historical developments over time. Later on, we discuss the

presence and the scope of sunk costs in this particular sector in four premises.

As of 2017, clothing constitutes the sixth largest subsector of the total manufacturing sector,

producing 6 percent of the total manufacturing sector value added. On the other hand, the share of

employment in clothing sector in total manufacuring sector is 18 percent while the average wages in

clothing is 28 percent lower than the average wage level in Turkey. 10 These figures indicate that

clothing is a relatively labor-intensive sector with low productivity.11

Initially, the aforementioned comparative advantage in clothing (and textiles as well) makes it one of the locomotive sectors for the export boom that started in the 1980s. However, the 2000s revealed a global shift of production towards China and neighbouring Asian developing economies in these sectors due to relatively lower production costs and preferential trade agreements with major importer economies (MD, 2014). The share of Turkey in total world clothing exports was around 3.5 percent between 2006-201412. However, as Figure 6 depicts, the share of exports of clothing in the

10 Employment and wage figures are taken from 2016 Labor Force Survey (LFS). Value added is the 2017 figure. The source for both datasets are TURKSTAT. 11 Unfortunately, all around the world, this sector is one of the most problematic ones in terms of the working conditions. OECD (2018c)

provides a due dilligance report specifically designed for the enterprises and subcontractors in this sector to meet their responsibilities

against their workers and the society. 12 The data source is ITCTradeMap (https://www.trademap.org).

Page 12: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

12

exports of the total manufacturing sector in Turkey displayed a steady decline in the last two decades, going down from 24 percent in 1996 to 7 percent in 2018. In contrast to the lowering share of clothing in total manufacturing exports, Figure 7 shows that the

number of firms in the clothing sector has a steady increase with the exception of two years after the

GFC. This surge is consistent with the result of Özler et al. (2009) indicating that sunk costs are lower

in textile and clothing industries relative to other sectors. This provides support for our hypothesis in

the following manner: We argue that low costs of this sector let the exchange rate to be determinant

of entry and exit in this sector. If the exchange rate depreciates above a certain level, the firm might

find it profitable to enter in the market in textile and clothing sector. However, the sunk costs are

extremely high in other sectors that even a big change in the exchange rate would not matter much

for the entry-exit behavior. Below, we discuss the entry-exit behavior of the exporters in the clothing

sector in relation with the previous literature.

INSERT FIGURE 6 AND FIGURE 7 ABOUT HERE

First, the textile and clothing sector has a multi-layered production structure in Turkey. Many major foreign brands have strong connections with some middle / large sized Turkish firms. These firms with large-scale production units also act as intermediaries which might, at times, extend the production process to some subcontractors in their region. Once the foreign demand increases, these large firms can either increase production via intensive margin or pass some of the excess demand to these subcontractors. If the foreign demand is high enough, these intermediaries, with their expertise and network connections, could initiate the establishment of new small enterprises with employment below 20 workers. Furthermore, most of the employment of the new subcontractors consists of previous workers / employers in the sector. Hence, as Özler et al. (2009) and Demirhan (2016a) suggest, some of these new establishments could be a re-entry in the sector indicating that previous export experience is important in export propensity. As discussed before, textile and clothing were the main sectors of the export boom starting at 1980s. Furhtermore, as Şenses (1989) argues, the government was active in these years in bilateral trade agreements to increase exports of the manufacturing sector which helped these firms to establish relations with foreign firms. Hence, most of these firms have very long experience and network connections (foreign as well as domestic) in this sector, supporting our hypothesis that these intermediaries could help to initiate new companies against a rise in foreign demand. Second, compared to other sectors, according to Özler et al. (2009), the importance of plant size is relatively lower in export propensity in the textile and clothing industry in comparison to others. This increases the probability of establishing a new small firm to benefit from exporting. Third point that would help us to motivate lower sunk costs in the last decade would be related to financing conditions. In fact, Özler et al. (2009) show that the role of imported machinery and equipment is relatively important in the textile and clothing sector for capital stock, in comparison to other sectors. This dependency on foreign inputs was less of a significant obstacle for Turkish firms in the last decade for two reasons. The first one is the presence of a relatively low interest rate environment in the period which might have led to easier financing conditions for new firms. The second one is the availability of leasing opportunities which constitutes around 6-7 percent of the total machinery and equipment in textile sector. 13 The fourth point is directly related to our analysis of exchange rates. The significance of the PV variable suggests that the exporting behavior in the intensive and extensive margin depends on the

13 Detailed data on sectoral leasing is available at Association of Financial Institutions (www.fkb.org.tr).

Page 13: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

13

exchange rate, once we consider the sunk costs. The increase in foreign demand might be a result of the price advantage due to a depreciation of Turkish lira in real terms over the last decade (Figure 1). Note that, in order to benefit from this price advantage, the foreign firms should have alternative producers / intermediaries in different countries. As discussed before, after the increase in the share of Asian countries in textile and clothing production around the world in the first decade of the century, many important brands have suppliers in Asian countries in addition to the previous exporters such as Turkey. These brands observe the exchange rate developments all over the world and easily direct their production from one country to the other by their already established intermediary contractors in these countries and their market power in this low cost, labor intensive industries.

VI. Conclusion, Discussion and Policy Recommendations

To sum up, this article argues that taking cognizance of sunk costs would help us to observe the

impact of exchange rate changes in the export behavior of Turkish firms in the clothing industry. The

potential determinant of this relationship is suggested as the sub-contracting capacity of experienced

intermediaries with strong connections; insignificance of plant size in the establishments of new

firms, better financing conditions in the period and a price advantage observed by a depreciation of

the domestic currency.

One problem for developing countries is that the deferred consumption might result in higher

domestic demand once the economy is above its long-term trend. In an economy mainly led by

domestic demand, many firms can make profit by producing for the domestic market and not have

strong incentives to export. However, moving to export markets in good times would be easier since

credit conditions are usually more relaxed in the higher phase of the economic cycles. On the other

hand, when the economy turns into a negative state, usually domestic demand goes down and the

firms might have higher benefits from exporting. However, the financing conditions also deteriorate

in these periods so it is harder to cover the costs of entry into export markets. This suggests that the

exporting behavior should follow a countercyclical pattern: Invest in exporting during “good times”

when the marginal benefit from exporting is lower compared to the “bad times”, but when the

financing conditions allow you to cover the cost of entry.

The aforementioned countercyclical behavior could also be supported by government incentives.

However, this would require a detailed analysis in many different respects. Our analysis tells that the

level of the exchange rate could determine the affordability of sunk costs. However, one caution

could be on the optimal plant size for the future productivity of this sector. A recent report published

by Turkish Clothing Manufacturing Association (TGSD, 2016) documents that while the need for

flexibility and speed justifies the need for small firms, the value-added of middle / large size plants is

higher in the sector. They suggest that the investments would also be channeled towards increasing

the average firm-size in the sector. Obviously, increasing automation in the last decade would have

immediate impacts on employment in this sector, once such a path would be followed. Hence, the

optimal policy would require a comprehensive analysis including the impact of incentives on both the

production and employment in the sector.

Page 14: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

14

References

Ahmed, S., Appendino, M., & Ruta, M. (2015). Depreciations without exports? Global value chains and the exchange rate elasticity of exports. The World Bank. Aldan, A., & Günay, M. (2008). Entry to Export Markets and Productivity: Analysis of Matched Firms in Turkey. Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey Working Papers, 08/05. Amable, B., Henry, J., Lordon, F., & Topol, R. (1994). Strong hysteresis versus zero-root dynamics. Economics Letters, 44(1-2), 43-47. Amable, B., Henry, J., Lordon, F., & Topol, R. (2004). Complex remanence vs. simple persistence: are hysteresis and unit-root processes observationally equivalent?. In Economic Complexity (pp. 67-89). Emerald Group Publishing Limited. Baldwin, R. (1990). Hysteresis in trade. In Hysteresis Effects in Economic Models (pp. 19-34). Physica-Verlag HD. Baldwin, R., & Krugman, P. (1989). Persistent trade effects of large exchange rate shocks. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(4), 635-654. Belke, A., Göcke, M., & Günther, M. (2013). Exchange rate bands of inaction and play‐hysteresis in German exports—Sectoral evidence for some OECD destinations. Metroeconomica, 64(1), 152-179. Belke, A. H., Göcke, M., & Werner, L. (2014). Hysteresis Effects in Economics–Different Methods for Describing Economic Path-dependence. Belke, A., Göcke, M., & Werner, L. (2015). Exchange Rate Volatility and other Determinants of Hysteresis in Exports-Empirical Evidence for the Euro Area. Review of Economic Analysis, 7(1), 24-53. Bernard, A. B., & Wagner, J. (2001). Export entry and exit by German firms. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 137(1), 105-123. Berument, M. H., Dincer, N. N., & Mustafaoglu, Z. (2014). External income shocks and Turkish

exports: A sectoral analysis. Economic Modelling, 37, 476-484.

Bozok, İ., Dogan, B. S., & Yunculer, C. (2015). Estimating Income and Price Elasticity of Turkish Exports

with Heterogeneous Panel Time-Series Methods (No. 1526).

Campa, J. M. (2004). Exchange rates and trade: How important is hysteresis in trade?. European

Economic Review, 48(3), 527-548.

Çıplak, U., Eren, O., Öğünç, F., & Saygılı, M. (2011). Turkiye’nin Ihracati Icin Alternatif Dis Talep Gostergeleri (No. 1107). CBRT Economic Notes, Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey.

Çulha, O. Y., & Kalafatçılar, M. K. (2014). A Glance at Income and Price Elasticity of Turkey‟ s Exports:

the Importance of Regional Disparities. CBT Research Notes in Economics, 5, 1-14.

Demirhan, A. A. (2016a). Export Behavior of the Turkish Manufacturing Firms. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 52(11), 2646-2668.

Page 15: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

15

Demirhan, A. A. (2016b). To be exporter or not to be exporter? Entry–exit dynamics of Turkish manufacturing firms. Empirical Economics, 51(1), 181-200. De Prince, D., & Kannebley Junior, S. (2013). Strong hysteresis in Brazilian imports: a panel cointegration approach. Journal of Economic Studies, 40(4), 528-548. Díaz-Mora, C., Gandoy, R., & Gonzalez-Diaz, B. (2018a). Strengthening the stability of exports through GVC participation: The who and how matters. Journal of Economic Studies, 45(3), 610-637. Díaz-Mora, C., Gandoy, R., & González-Díaz, B. (2018b). Looking into global value chains: influence of foreign services on export performance. Review of World Economics, 154(4), 785-814. Dixit, A. (1989a). Hysteresis, import penetration, and exchange rate pass-through. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(2), 205-228. Dixit, A. (1989b). Entry and exit decisions under uncertainty. Journal of political Economy, 97(3), 620-638. Eichengreen, B., & Gupta, P. (2013). The real exchange rate and export growth: are services different?. The World Bank. Gezici, A., Orhangazi, Ö., & Yalçın, C. (2018). Exports and Financing Constraints Evidence from Turkey. Review of Middle East Economics and Finance, 14(1). Goldstein, M., & Khan, M. S. (1985). Income and price effects in foreign trade. Handbook of

international economics, 2, 1041-1105.

Gullstrand, J., & Persson, M. (2015). How to combine high sunk costs of exporting and low export

survival. Review of World Economics, 151(1), 23-51.

Hallett, A. H., & Piscitelli, L. (2002). Testing for hysteresis against nonlinear alternatives. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 27(2), 303-327. Kannebley Jr, S. (2008). Tests for the hysteresis hypothesis in Brazilian industrialized exports: a threshold cointegration analysis. Economic Modelling, 25(2), 171-190. Kemp, M. C., & Wan, H. Y. (1974). Hysteresis of long-run equilibrium from realistic adjustment costs. In Trade, Stability, and Macroeconomics (pp. 221-242). Lieberman, M. B., Lee, G. K., & Folta, T. B. (2017). Entry, exit, and the potential for resource redeployment. Strategic management journal, 38(3), 526-544. Máñez, J. A., Rochina-Barrachina, M. E., & Sanchis, J. A. (2008). Sunk costs hysteresis in Spanish manufacturing exports. Review of World Economics, 144(2), 272-294.

MD (Ministry of Development). (2014). Report on Textile-Fur and Wearing Apparel Prepared for the

Tenth Development Plan of Turkey, Ankara, ISBN 978-605-9041-08-9

Meinen, P. (2015). Sunk costs of exporting and the role of experience in international trade. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique, 48(1), 335-367.

Page 16: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

16

Metin-Ozcan, K., Voyvoda, E., & Yeldan, A. E. (2001). Dynamics of macroeconomic adjustment in a globalized developing economy: growth, accumulation and distribution, Turkey 1969–1999. Canadian Journal of Development Studies/Revue canadienne d'études du développement, 22(1), 219-253. OECD (2018a), Trade Policy Implications of Global Value Chains, OECD Publishing, Paris (available at http://www.oecd.org/sti/ind/measuring-trade-in-value-added.htm) ______(2018b), Trade in Value Added: Turkey, OECD Publishing, Paris (available at http://www.oecd.org/sti/ind/measuring-trade-in-value-added.htm) OECD (2018c), OECD Due Diligence Guidance for Responsible Supply Chains in the Garment and Footwear Sector, OECD Publishing, Paris. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264290587-en Onaran, Ö., & Stockhammer, E. (2006). Do profits affect investment and employment? An empirical test based on the Bhaduri-Marglin model. In Wages, Employment, Distribution and Growth (pp. 206-222). Palgrave Macmillan, London. O’Shaughnessy, T. (2000). Hysteresis in an open economy model. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 47(2), 156-182. Özler, Ş., Taymaz, E., & Yilmaz, K. (2009). History matters for the export decision: Plant-level evidence from Turkish manufacturing industry. World Development, 37(2), 479-488. Padmaja, M., & Sasidharan, S. (2017). Sunk Costs, Firm Heterogeneity, Export Market Entry and Exit: Evidence from India. Journal of Quantitative Economics, 15(2), 367-393. Piscitelli, L., Cross, R., Grinfeld, M., & Lamba, H. (2000). A test for strong hysteresis. Computational Economics, 15(1-2), 59-78. Preisach, F. (1935). Über die magnetische Nachwirkung. Zeitschrift für Physik, 94(5-6), 277-302.

Roberts, M. J., & Tybout, J. R. (1997). The decision to export in Colombia: an empirical model of entry

with sunk costs. The American Economic Review, 545-564.

Saygılı, H., & Saygılı, M. (2011). Structural changes in exports of an emerging economy: Case of

Turkey. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 22(4), 342-360.

Setterfield, M. (2009). Path dependency, hysteresis and macrodynamics. In Path dependency and macroeconomics (pp. 37-79). Palgrave Macmillan, London. Soyres, D., Raphael, F. M. M., Frohm, E., Gunnella, V., & Pavlova, E. (2018). Bought, Sold, and Bought Again: The Impact of Complex Value Chains on Export Elasticities. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, (8535). Şenses, F. (1989). The Nature and Main Characteristics of Recent Turkish Growth in Export of Manufactures. The Developing Economies, 27(1), 19-33.

TGSD (Turkish Clothing Manufacturing Association), 2016. Horizon 2030: A Toadmap for Turkish

Clothing Sector, In Turkish), İstanbul

Page 17: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

17

Timoshenko, O. A. (2015). Learning versus sunk costs explanations of export persistence. European Economic Review, 79, 113-128.

Toraganlı, N., & Yalçın, C. (2016). Exports, Real Exchange Rates and External Exposures: Empirical Evidence from Turkish Manufacturing Firms, Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey Working Papers, 16/24. Türkcan, K. (2016). On the role of vertical differentiation in enhancing survival of export flows: Evidence from a developing country. Uz, I. (2010). Bilateral trade elasticities of Turkey. International Journal of Applied Economics, 7(1), 28-46. Voyvoda, E., & Yeldan, A. E. (2001). Patterns of productivity growth and the wage cycle in Turkish manufacturing. International Review of Applied Economics, 15(4), 375-396. Werner, L. M. (2017). Identifying hysteresis non-linearities in trade: Evidence from European wine exports to the U.S.. AMERICAN ASSOCIATION OF WINE ECONOMISTS Working paper No. 215, 1-37. Werner, L. M. (2018). Hysteresis losses in the Preisach framework. Empirical Economics, 1-30. (https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-018-1547-z)

Page 18: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

18

Figure 1: Real Effective Exchange Rate (8-quarters moving average)

Figure 2: Total Exports

Source: Turkstat

Figure 3: Percentage Share of Sectors in Total Exports

Source: Turkstat

60

70

80

90

100

110

120

130

06

-4

07

-3

08

-2

09

-1

09

-4

10

-3

11

-2

12

-1

12

-4

13

-3

14

-2

15

-1

15

-4

16

-3

17

-2

18

-1

Page 19: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

19

Figure 4: Non-ideal relay hysteresis model

not exporting 0

exporting 1

state of exporting

exchange rate

export

market entry

trigger

export

market exit

trigger

band of inaction

𝛼 𝛽

Page 20: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

20

Figure 5: Preisach triangle and aggregation procedure

(a) (b)

(c)

(e) (f)

m2

M3

m1 M1

M1

entry = exit trigger

entry trigger

exit trigger

M1

entry = exit trigger

entry trigger

exit trigger

M1

entry = exit trigger

entry trigger

exit trigger

M2

M1

entry = exit trigger

entry trigger

exit trigger M1 M2 m2 m1

M1

entry = exit trigger

entry trigger

exit trigger

M1

entry = exit trigger

entry trigger

exit trigger

(d)

𝑆+

𝑆+ 𝑆+

𝑆+ 𝑆+

𝑆+

𝑆−

Page 21: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

21

Figure 6: Share of Exports of Clothing in Exports of Total Manufacturing Sector

Source: Turksat

Figure 7: Number of Firms in Clothing Industry

Source: Ministry of Industry, Enterprise Information System

12000

13000

14000

15000

16000

17000

18000

19000

20000

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

0

5

10

15

20

25

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

20

12

20

13

20

14

20

15

20

16

20

17

20

18

Page 22: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

22

Table 1: Outcomes of hysteresis estimations of manufacturing and five subsectors

Dependent variable:

manufacturing manuFoodBev manuTobacco manuTextiles manuDressing manuWood

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

REER 0.206*

-0.164

-0.057

0.211**

0.232*

-0.229

(0.110)

(0.127)

(0.380)

(0.097)

(0.136)

(0.270)

PV

0.009

0.001

-0.017

0.003

-0.023***

-0.017

(0.006)

(0.007)

(0.021)

(0.006)

(0.007)

(0.015)

GG 1.449** 1.413** -0.663 -1.023 0.923 1.669 0.516 0.787 0.208 1.868*** 2.046 2.460*

(0.543) (0.604) (0.624) (0.695) (1.870) (2.031) (0.478) (0.548) (0.667) (0.681) (1.326) (1.442)

GDP 0.164 0.140 0.611* 0.777** 0.819 0.548 0.441 0.300 0.447 -0.222 -0.319 -0.433

(0.305) (0.317) (0.350) (0.365) (1.048) (1.066) (0.268) (0.287) (0.374) (0.357) (0.743) (0.757)

FC 1.758 1.985 4.850** 4.899** 9.346 8.847 -0.029 0.022 -0.508 -1.258 4.376 3.902

(1.637) (1.676) (1.881) (1.929) (5.632) (5.636) (1.440) (1.520) (2.009) (1.889) (3.994) (4.001)

DP16_4 0.226 0.158 5.364 6.790* -26.010** -28.586*** 1.492 0.337 1.942 -4.135 1.372 0.132

(2.988) (3.129) (3.434) (3.601) (10.281) (10.521) (2.630) (2.838) (3.668) (3.526) (7.292) (7.469)

Observations 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50

R2 0.617 0.603 0.600 0.586 0.329 0.337 0.523 0.476 0.263 0.358 0.250 0.258

Adjusted R2 0.574 0.559 0.556 0.540 0.254 0.263 0.469 0.417 0.182 0.287 0.167 0.176

Residual Std. Error (df = 45) 6.664 6.778 7.660 7.800 22.932 22.789 5.865 6.146 8.180 7.638 16.264 16.177

F Statistic (df = 5; 45) 14.468*** 13.680*** 13.526*** 12.725*** 4.408*** 4.577*** 9.850*** 8.165*** 3.218** 5.016*** 3.006** 3.135**

Note: *p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01. Numbers in parentheses are standard errors.

Page 23: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

23

Table 2: Outcomes of hysteresis estimations of six further subsectors

Dependent variable:

manuPaper manuCoke manuChemicals manuRubber manuOther manuMetals

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

REER 0.296*

-0.060

0.103

0.066

0.201*

0.293

(0.160)

(0.380)

(0.140)

(0.119)

(0.107)

(0.708)

PV

0.016*

0.026

-0.002

-0.001

0.014**

0.037

(0.009)

(0.021)

(0.008)

(0.007)

(0.006)

(0.040)

GG 0.561 0.306 5.163*** 3.677* 1.281* 1.571** 1.608*** 1.798*** 0.356 0.050 1.161 -0.197

(0.788) (0.863) (1.870) (2.012) (0.689) (0.758) (0.584) (0.640) (0.526) (0.566) (3.485) (3.780)

GDP 0.500 0.542 -0.945 -0.373 0.355 0.226 0.299 0.215 0.072 0.150 -0.922 -0.463

(0.442) (0.453) (1.048) (1.056) (0.386) (0.398) (0.327) (0.336) (0.295) (0.297) (1.954) (1.984)

FC 7.151*** 7.598*** -3.622 -2.803 1.079 1.010 1.247 1.200 1.023 1.406 8.832 9.928

(2.373) (2.394) (5.635) (5.583) (2.076) (2.102) (1.760) (1.777) (1.586) (1.570) (10.498) (10.490)

DP16_4 3.037 3.655 -24.466** -19.166* 5.809 4.688 0.533 -0.201 5.083* 5.972** -12.980 -8.471

(4.332) (4.470) (10.286) (10.422) (3.791) (3.925) (3.212) (3.318) (2.895) (2.931) (19.165) (19.583)

Observations 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50

R2 0.612 0.610 0.306 0.328 0.579 0.574 0.655 0.653 0.279 0.304 0.029 0.044

Adjusted R2 0.569 0.567 0.229 0.253 0.532 0.527 0.616 0.614 0.199 0.226 -0.078 -0.062

Residual Std. Error (df = 45) 9.662 9.681 22.942 22.574 8.455 8.502 7.164 7.186 6.457 6.348 42.745 42.417

F Statistic (df = 5; 45) 14.198*** 14.105*** 3.967*** 4.393*** 12.363*** 12.128*** 17.070*** 16.910*** 3.491*** 3.925*** 0.273 0.416

Note: *p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01. Numbers in parentheses are standard errors .

Page 24: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

24

Table 3: Outcomes of hysteresis estimations of six further subsectors

Dependent variable:

manuFabricMetal manuMachinery manuElectric manuRadio manuVeh manuFurniture

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

REER 0.183

0.057

0.019

-0.301

0.359

0.145

(0.133)

(0.108)

(0.143)

(0.526)

(0.223)

(0.459)

PV

0.012

-0.003

0.004

-0.073**

0.009

0.008

(0.008)

(0.006)

(0.008)

(0.028)

(0.013)

(0.026)

GG 0.458 0.227 1.074** 1.324** 2.006*** 1.821** -1.118 2.063 4.367*** 4.606*** -1.746 -1.850

(0.655) (0.712) (0.533) (0.584) (0.701) (0.764) (2.588) (2.649) (1.099) (1.228) (2.257) (2.468)

GDP 0.934** 0.987** 0.855*** 0.750** 0.203 0.270 1.935 0.789 0.239 0.083 1.071 1.084

(0.367) (0.374) (0.299) (0.306) (0.393) (0.401) (1.451) (1.390) (0.616) (0.644) (1.265) (1.295)

FC -1.218 -0.899 -1.228 -1.318 -1.600 -1.472 -14.191* -16.374** -4.951 -4.733 3.966 4.172

(1.973) (1.977) (1.607) (1.620) (2.112) (2.121) (7.797) (7.351) (3.310) (3.408) (6.801) (6.849)

DP16_4 4.585 5.227 2.396 1.460 -5.463 -4.829 0.777 -10.159 9.274 8.089 6.340 6.567

(3.601) (3.691) (2.933) (3.024) (3.856) (3.959) (14.234) (13.724) (6.043) (6.362) (12.415) (12.786)

Observations 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50

R2 0.602 0.606 0.750 0.750 0.512 0.515 0.094 0.206 0.690 0.676 0.086 0.086

Adjusted R2 0.558 0.562 0.722 0.722 0.458 0.461 -0.007 0.118 0.656 0.640 -0.016 -0.016

Residual Std. Error (df = 45) 8.032 7.994 6.543 6.550 8.601 8.576 31.748 29.725 13.479 13.781 27.690 27.694

F Statistic (df = 5; 45) 13.608*** 13.826*** 27.011*** 26.929*** 9.457*** 9.564*** 0.935 2.332* 20.068*** 18.808*** 0.847 0.843

Note: *p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01. Numbers in parentheses are standard errors.

Page 25: Sunk Costs and Exporting Behavior: A Sectoral Analysis

25

Table 4: Description of abbreviations

Abbreviation (Sub-)sector

manufacturing Manufacturing manuFoodBev Manufacture of food products and beverages manuTobacco Manufacture of tobacco products manuTextiles Manufacture of textiles manuDressing Manufacture of wearing apparel; dressing and dyeing of fur manuWood Manufacture of wood and of products of wood and cork, except furniture;

manufacture of articles of straw and plaiting materials. manuPaper Manufacture of paper and paper products manuCoke Manufacture of coke, refined petroleum products and nuclear fuel manuChemicals Manufacture of chemicals and chemical products manuRubber Manufacture of rubber and plastics products manuOther Manufacture of other non-metallic mineral products manuMetals Manufacture of basic metals manuFabricMetal Manufacture of fabricated metal products, except machinery and equipment manuMachinery Manufacture of machinery and equipment n.e.c. manuElectric Manufacture of electrical machinery and apparatus n.e.c. manuRadio Manufacture of radio, television and communication equipment and apparatus manuVeh Manufacture of motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers manuFurniture Manufacture of furniture; manufacturing n.e.c.