separating issuers from acquirers and profit limitations...

443
1 The Faculty of Law The Zvi Meitar Center for Advanced Legal Studies Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations In Payment Card Networks with Interchange Fees By: Ori BarAm Supervisor: Professor David Gilo Thesis for the title "Doctor of Philosophy" Submitted to the Senate of Tel Aviv University on August 3, 2017

Upload: others

Post on 29-Jun-2020

5 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

1

The Faculty of Law

The Zvi Meitar Center for Advanced Legal Studies

Separating Issuers from Acquirers

And Profit Limitations

In Payment Card Networks with Interchange Fees

By: Ori BarAm

Supervisor: Professor David Gilo

Thesis for the title "Doctor of Philosophy"

Submitted to the Senate of Tel Aviv University on August 3, 2017

Page 2: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

2

פקולטה למשפטיםה

מרכז צבי מיתר ללימודי משפט מתקדם

פיצול סליקה והנפקה ומגבלות על רווחים

ברשתות כרטיסי חיוב עם עמלה צולבת

מאת: אורי ברעם דיויד גילה מנחה: פרופ'

חיבור לשם קבלת התואר "דוקטור לפילוסופיה"

2017 אוגוסטב 3יום אביב ב-הוגש לסנאט של אוניברסיטת תל

Page 3: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

3

INDEX 1. INTRODUCTION .................................................................................................................................... 6

PART I - BACKGROUND ................................................................................................................................ 10

2. BASIC TERMS ................................................................................................................................... 10 2.1.THE CARDS .......................................................................................................................................... 10

Credit Cards ..................................................................................................................... 10 Bank Cards ..................................................................................................................... 11 Prepaid Cards ..................................................................................................................... 13

2.2.THE PARTIES ........................................................................................................................................ 14 Issuer ..................................................................................................................... 14 Acquirer ..................................................................................................................... 15 Merchants and Cardholders ..................................................................................................................... 17

2.3.THE FEES ............................................................................................................................................. 18 Cardholder Fee ..................................................................................................................... 18 The Merchant Service Fee (“MSF”) ....................................................................................... 19 The Interchange Fee ..................................................................................................................... 20 The Acquiring Fee ..................................................................................................................... 23

2.4. OPEN AND CLOSED NETWORKS .......................................................................................................... 23 “On-Us” Transactions ..................................................................................................................... 25 Price Level and Price Structure ..................................................................................... 25 The International Organizations ............................................................................................. 26

3. PAYMENT CARDS MARKET DATA ................................................................................................................................ 30 3.1.ISRAEL ........................................................................................................................................ 30 3.2.WORLDWIDE ......................................................................................................................................... 34

4. HISTORY OF PAYMENT CARDS AND INTERCHANGE FEES ........................................................................................... 38 4.1.HISTORICAL DEVELOPMENT OF OPEN NETWORKS ............................................................................. 41 4.2 HISTORY OF DEBIT CARDS AND ATMS ......................................................................................... 50 4.3.INTERIM SUMMARY ............................................................................................................................... 58

PART II - ECONOMIC ANALYSIS .................................................................................................................... 59

5. COSTS AND BENEFITS OF PAYMENT INSTRUMENTS ................................................................................................... 59 5.1.COSTS OF PAYMENT INSTRUMENTS ..................................................................................................... 60 5.2.BENEFITS OF PAYMENT INSTRUMENTS ................................................................................................ 66 5.3. CASH .................................................................................................................................................... 71 5.4.PAYMENT CARDS ................................................................................................................................. 74

Costs ..................................................................................................................... 74 Benefits ..................................................................................................................... 75

6. THE ECONOMIC MODELS ................................................................................................................................... 78 6.1.INTRODUCTION ..................................................................................................................................... 78 6.2. THE MODEL OF BAXTER - BALANCING COSTS .................................................................................................................... 81 6.3. INTERCHANGE FEE TO BALANCE DEMANDS ........................................................................................ 84 6.4.ROCHET & TIROLE – STRATEGIC CONSIDERATIONS ........................................................................... 87

The Restraining Role Of The Interchange Fee .................................................................... 96 Concern of Oversupply ..................................................................................................................... 98 Additional Developments And Criticism ................................................................................ 99

6.5 NEUTRALITY, SURCHARGE AND MERCHANT RESTRAINTS ............................................................ 103 The Literature In Favor Of NSR .................................................................................. 107 Other Models ................................................................................................................... 110

6.6. PAYMENT CARD COMPETITION .......................................................................................................... 119 Multihoming Analysis ................................................................................................................... 123 Multihoming Merchants And Singlehoming Customers .................................................... 125 Competition on Issuers ................................................................................................................... 132 Competition Between Open And Closed Networks ........................................................... 134

6.7. CARDHOLDER FEES AND REWARDS .................................................................................................. 137 6.8. DEBIT V. CREDIT ................................................................................................................................. 148 6.9. DETERMINATION OF THE OPTIMAL INTERCHANGE FEE ..................................................................... 155

Defining The Standard For Optimal Interchange Fees ..................................................... 158 Privately Optimal Interchange fee ........................................................................................ 159 Socially Optimal Interchange fee ......................................................................................... 163

Page 4: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

4

Consumer Welfare Optimal Interchange Fee .................................................................... 167 7. THE SPECIAL FEATURES OF THE INTERCHANGE FEE .................................................................................................. 171

7.1. TWO-SIDED NETWORK PRODUCTS ................................................................................................... 171 Network Products ................................................................................................................... 171 Two-Sided Products ................................................................................................................... 174

7.2.EXTERNALITIES ................................................................................................................................... 175 Network Externality ................................................................................................................... 176 Usage Externality ................................................................................................................... 177

7.3.INTERCHANGE FEE AS A MECHANISM TO INTERNALIZE NETWORK EXTERNALITY ........................... 178 7.4. NEGATION OF THE NETWORK EXTERNALITY JUSTIFICATION ........................................................... 187 7.5. USAGE EXTERNALITY JUSTIFICATION ................................................................................................ 192

PART III – REGULATION AND LEGAL ANALYSIS ............................................................................................................. 200 8.REGULATION OF INTERCHANGE FEES AROUND THE WORLD .................................................................................... 200

8.1.ISRAEL ................................................................................................................................................ 200 Criticism Of The Cost-Based Methodology ........................................................................ 208 Regulation of Isracard ................................................................................................................... 215 Categories Of Interchange Fees .......................................................................................... 219 Debit Cards In Israel ................................................................................................................... 226 No Smart Acquiring (EMV) ................................................................................................................... 231 Market Concentration ................................................................................................................... 231 Single Routing Option ................................................................................................................... 233

8.2. EUROPE ........................................................................................................................................ 235 The Tourist Test ................................................................................................................... 244 Criticism Of The Tourist Test ................................................................................................ 246

8.3. UNITED STATES ............................................................................................................................ 248 Market Power ................................................................................................................... 250 Cost Coverage ................................................................................................................... 253 The interchange Fee As Internal Transfer .......................................................................... 254 Bilateral Agreements ................................................................................................................... 255 Issuers’ Extortion Position ................................................................................................................... 256 The Elimination Of Issuing Prohibitions .............................................................................. 258 Partial Cancellation Of The HAC Rule ................................................................................ 259 Interchange Fee Settlement ................................................................................................................... 261 The Durbin Amendment And Other Reforms ..................................................................... 262

Routing Reform ................................................................................................................... 267 Cancelation Of Merchant Restraints ................................................................................... 268 The Effects Of The Reform ................................................................................................... 269

8.4.AUSTRALIA .......................................................................................................................................... 271 8.5.ROMANIA ............................................................................................................................................ 276 8.6.NEW ZEALAND .................................................................................................................................... 277 8.7.OTHER COUNTRIES ............................................................................................................................. 279

9. THE RESTRICTIVE ARRANGEMENT – LEGAL ASSESSMENT ........................................................................................ 282 9.1. “BYLAWS” INTERCHANGE FEE ............................................................................................................ 288 9.2. ADAPTATION TO EXISTING INTERCHANGE FEE ................................................................................. 291

10. THE COMPETITIVE CONCERNS ................................................................................................................................. 293 10.1. PRICE INCREASE ................................................................................................................................ 293 10.2. CROSS-SUBSIDIZATION ...................................................................................................................... 294 10.3. OVERUSE AND OVER-ISSUANCE ....................................................................................................... 297

Over-Usage ................................................................................................................... 298 Over-Issuance Of Cards ................................................................................................................... 301

10.4. RAISING ENTRY BARRIERS ................................................................................................................ 302 11. WHY MERCHANTS DO NOT SURCHARGE ................................................................................................................ 303

11.1. UNCERTAINTY AS TO THE APPROPRIATE SURCHARGE .................................................................... 304 Surcharging The Difference Between Price And Benefits ............................................... 305 Surcharging The Difference Between Price And Costs .................................................... 306 Free Surcharging ................................................................................................................... 306

11.2. MERCHANT RESTRAINTS .................................................................................................................... 308 NSR ................................................................................................................... 309 HAC ................................................................................................................... 311

Page 5: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

5

11.3 STRATEGIC CONSIDERATIONS ................................................................................................................. 313 11.4. SURCHARGING IS COSTLY ................................................................................................................. 314 11.5. PSYCHOLOGICAL REASONS ............................................................................................................... 315 11.6. SMALL COST DIFFERENCES DO NOT JUSTIFY SURCHARGES .......................................................... 316 11.7. OTHER REASONS ............................................................................................................................... 317

12. ALTERNATIVES TO THE INTERCHANGE FEE ............................................................................................................. 319 12.1. BILATERAL INTERCHANGE FEE .......................................................................................................... 319 12.2. ZERO INTERCHANGE FEE ................................................................................................................... 322 12.3. SPLIT .................................................................................................................................................. 324 12.4. MULTI-CARDS ..................................................................................................................................... 326

PART IV – NEW PROPOSALS ........................................................................................................................ 329

13. NOVELTY #1 – STRUCTURAL SEPARATION .............................................................................................................. 329 13.1. THE DE FACTO PREVALENCE OF THE NAWI RULE ......................................................................... 330

Israel ................................................................................................................... 330 Europe ................................................................................................................... 333 United States ................................................................................................................... 335 Other Countries ................................................................................................................... 336 NAWI Rule in the Bylaws of the International Organizations ........................................... 338

13.2.PROPOSAL TO SEPARATE ACQUIRERS FROM ISSUERS ..................................................................... 339 13.3.MITIGATING COMPETITIVE CONCERNS .............................................................................................. 353 13.4. DIVESTITURE AS PART OF REGULATION ........................................................................................... 357 13.5. DIVESTITURE AS AN ANTITRUST REMEDY ........................................................................................... 363 13.6. FINAL REMARKS .................................................................................................................................. 368

14. NOVELTY # 2 PROFIT LIMITATION ........................................................................................................................... 369 14.1.PAR CLEARANCE OF CHECKS ............................................................................................................ 370 14.2.PROFIT LIMITATION ............................................................................................................................. 374 14.3. PRECEDENTS ...................................................................................................................................... 385 14.4. ADDITIONAL REMARKS ....................................................................................................................... 389 14.5. RECIPROCAL RELATIONS BETWEEN MY PROPOSALS ....................................................................... 394

15. SUMMARY ................................................................................................................................. 395

Page 6: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

6

1. Introduction

1. Payment cards, like cash and checks, are payment instruments. Payment instruments are not an

ordinary commodity, but rather an important production factor in the economy.1 Payment

instruments enable the execution of transactions and can be considered as the “plumbing” of

the economy.2 Enhancing the efficiency of payment instruments reduces transaction costs and

improves market performance.3

In the past, cash was the only way to preform transactions. As a result, many efficient

transactions never took place because of liquidity constraints. People often did not carry

substantial amounts of money. This situation incentivized the development of alternative

payment methods, particularly promissory notes and checks.4

2. During the second half of the twentieth century a new payment instrument evolved, the credit

card. Credit cards were a revolution in the field of payments. They enabled customers to pay

without the need for cash. Compared to checks and promissory notes, in which the risk of

default falls on the merchant (the beneficiary in the note), credit cards offered merchants

guaranteed payment, convenience, documentation, control and monitoring of transactions.

Credit cards enabled customers to purchase products and services with future money that they

did not yet possess at the time of the transaction.

3. Payment card networks have improved over the years and become more sophisticated.

Distribution of payment cards has grown worldwide, and a steep rise in usage has occurred.

As opposed to cash, which is a legal tender, produced and distributed by the state, there is no

obligation to accept payment cards, which are private payment instruments. No merchant is

obligated to accept them, and no customer is required to pay with them. To survive, payment

1 JACOB CHERTOF AND AMI TZADIK, CREDIT CARDS MARKET: ANALYSIS, REGULATION AND INTERNATIONAL

COMPARISON, KNESSET RESEARCH CENTER, at 1 (2010); Leo Van Hove, Central Banks and Payment Instruments: A

Serious Case of Schizophrenia, 66 COMMUNICATIONS & STRATEGIES 19, 19 (2007). 2 M. Charles Kahn & William Roberds, Why Pay? Introduction to Payment Economics, 18 J. FIN. INTERMEDIATION 1

(2009): "Payment systems are the plumbing of the economy"; Bank of Israel, Press Release, Speech of Governor Karnit

Flug in a Convention Money and Technology (March 26, 2014). 3 Iftekhar Hasan, Emmi Martikainen & Tuomas Takalo, Promoting Efficient Retail Payments in Europe, 20 Bank of

Finland Research Discussion Papers, at 1 (2014): “[A]s in the case of other infrastructures, the effects of more efficient

retail payment infrastructure are not limited to direct cost savings: there is evidence that such efficiency would also

yield indirect benefits by improving the supply chain, facilitating trade, boosting consumption, and enhancing bank

sector performance”. 4 For expansion see Alan S. Frankel, Monopoly and Competition in the Supply and Exchange of Money 66 ANTITRUST

L.J. 313 (1998); William F. Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper: Legal and Economic Perspectives 26

J.L. ECON. 541 (1983).

Page 7: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

7

cards had to reach a critical mass among both cardholders and merchants. Payment cards have

managed not only to survive, but also to thrive in this evolutionary process, by using their two-

sided network features. Payment card networks succeeded by extracting money from

merchants, who are considered less elastic (i.e., more eager to accept them), and by subsidizing

the adoption and usage of cards by the side with the higher elasticity, the cardholders.

Payment cards developed and gained market power without disruption for decades until

complaints about their high fees, particularly from merchants, invited scrutiny by regulators.

Authorities began to inspect the arrangements and the fees charged by payment card networks.

The main arrangement that regulators and competition authorities worldwide regulated was the

interchange fee that acquirers pay to issuers.

4. In every transaction made through a payment card, the merchant pays a fee to its acquirer. This

is the merchant service fee (“MSF”). The acquirer remits a major part of the MSF to the issuer

of the card, through which the transaction was performed. This is the interchange fee. The

interchange fee is the tool designed to deliver funds from the side of merchants to the side of

cardholders, but it also sets a floor for the MSF. Interchange fees alone account for billions of

dollars each year.

The interchange fee is a price which is set in a concerted agreement between issuers and

acquirers. As such, it falls under the category of a minimum price-fixing agreement between

competitors.5 Generally, antitrust regulators all over the world seek out and forbid minimum

price-fixing agreements between competitors. Nevertheless, payment cards have unique

features that entail different treatment under the law. Payment cards are two-sided network

products.6 The implication of their features yields a substantially different result compared to

other price fixing agreements.

Applying antitrust law to two-sided products, especially payment cards, as would be done to

“regular” products, can cause absurd consequences.7 To avoid such consequences, authorities

and regulators worldwide have approved interchange fees, even though they stem from

horizontal minimum price-fixing agreements between competitors.

5 Infra ch. 0. 6 Infra ch. 7. 7 Julian Wright, One-Sided Logic in Two-Sided Markets 3 REV. NETWORK ECON. 44 (2004); Jean-Charles Rochet &

Jean Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1, at 1 (2006): "It is now

well-understood that the implementation of competition policy must be amended in order to reflect two-sidedness".

Page 8: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

8

Acknowledgement of the special characteristics of payment cards is not the end of the story,

but rather its beginning. A distinction must be made between the “right” to charge an

interchange fee and the “rate” of that interchange fee.8 Even protection on basic rights is not

unlimited, all the more so the right to charge interchange fees does not mean that absolutely

any rate is legally protected. Even when the law accepts a restrictive arrangement, it may well

limit the size of it.9

Today, there appears to be a consensus that allowing payment card networks to privately

determine the rate of the interchange fee, results in a higher than optimal interchange fee.10 The

interchange fee is a cost for merchants. It is passed through to the prices of products and services

that merchants sell. Increase in the interchange fee causes a small but market-wide increase in

the final prices of goods. The interchange fee raises additional concerns.11

5. The consensus about the competitive concerns that the interchange fee raises disappears when

solutions to these concerns are considered. A wide variety of opinions and ideas exist as to the

best way to accomplish this. The topic is highly contentious.12

The simple approach suggests capping the interchange fee. In Europe, the cap is based on

demand features, primarily the alternative benefit to merchants from not having to accept cash

(avoided costs of cash or the "tourist test").13 In Israel, Australia and in the U.S. (for debit and

deferred debit cards), the cap is based on supply features, which are mainly the cost of the

payment guarantee and processing of transactions.14 Another approach to deal with the antitrust

concerns raised by the interchange is to allow merchants to surcharge card payments. This, in

8 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card

Associations, 33 RAND J. ECON. 549, 550 (2002): “Even if one accepts the existence of an interchange fee, one may still

be legitimately concerned that it might be set too high”. 9 For the difference between coverage and protection of rights in a different context, see HCJ 2194/06 Shinui Party v.

Head of Election Committee, para. 8 (Mar. 12, 2006). 10 Infra ¶ 395. 11 Infra ch. 10. 12 Wilko Bolt, Pricing, Competition and Innovation in Retail Payment Systems: A Brief Overview, 1 J. FIN. MARKET

INFRASTRUCTURE 73, 79 (2013): “While most economists agree – based on two-sided logic – that an interchange fee

may be necessary to balance the demands of consumers and merchants resulting in higher social welfare, the “right”

level of the fee remains a subject of debate”. See also ch. 8.3 for recent developments in interchange fee litigation in the

U.S.". 13 Infra ch. 8.2. 14 Infra chapters 8.1, 8.1.1 (Israel), 8.3.9 (U.S.), 8.4 (Australia).

Page 9: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

9

theory, neutralizes the interchange fee.15 However, surcharging is not a common phenomenon

for reasons discussed below.16

6. My contribution to the burgeoning literature is to offer two independent ways to reduce, if not

eliminate, the antitrust concerns that the interchange fee raises. My first proposal is to separate

acquirers from issuers, and disconnect any interest of acquirers in the issuing side of payment

cards and vice versa. This proposal would eliminate the inherent conflict of interest of acquirers

that are also issuers, and enforce entrance of independent acquirers. Regulators and competition

authorities throughout the world try to enable such entrance but without success.17 My second

proposal is to condition approval of interchange fee on limitation of issuers' profits.18

Part I of this work is background. Chapter 2 explains the basic terms of the payment card

industry. Chapter 3 includes payment card market data. Chapter 4 describes the history of

interchange fee in credit, debit and prepaid transactions. Part II of the work is the economic

part. Chapter 5 introduces an analysis of the costs and benefits of payment instruments. Chapter

6 informally surveys relevant economic models, from the first model of Baxter, via the strategic

considerations of Rochet & Tirole, models of neutrality and surcharging, models of network

competition, models of the relations between rewards and cardholder fees, models of credit vs.

debit and models describing the determination of the optimal interchange fee. Chapter 7

explains the distinctive features of payment cards as a two-sided network product, and the

phenomena of network and usage externalities which entail the approval of interchange fee,

despite being a horizontal price fixing agreement between competitors. Part III is the legal part

of the work. Chapter 8 describes the existing regulation of the interchange fee in Israel and

around the world. Chapter 9 is a legal analysis of interchange fees. Chapter 10 explains the

competitive concerns interchange fee raises. Chapter 11 explains why merchants do not tend to

impose surcharges on expensive payment instruments. Chapter 12 investigates solutions to the

competitive concerns raised by the interchange fee. In part IV of the work I present my new

proposals. Chapter 13 presents my first innovation, i.e., separating issuers from acquirers.

Chapter 14 presents my second novelty, to limit profit of issuers who charge interchange fee.

Chapter 15 concludes the work.

15 Infra ch.6.5. 16 Infra ch.11. 17 Infra ch. 0. 18 Infra ch. 13.614.

Page 10: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

10

It must be emphasized that my proposals are alternatives, and do not have to be implemented

together. The proposal to divest issuers from acquirers is a legislative proposal that would break

up the interchange fee from being a restrictive arrangement (apart from the minor joint

negotiation). The proposal to limit profits alleviates the competitive concerns from the

interchange fee. Each of the proposals suffices on its own.

Part I - Background

2. Basic Terms

2.1. The Cards

7. Israel's Payment Cards Law 5746 - 1986 defines a payment card as a plate or object for purchase

of assets (including services and rights). The common feature for all payment cards is that they

are all for reuse. Technology has made this definition anachronistic. A payment card can be

used in a completely virtual way, combined as software or hardware in smartphones or

electronic wallets.19

8. Common payment cards are plastic cards with a magnetic stripe that contains identification of

the cardholder and the issuer. There are few kinds of payment cards. The main difference

between them is the billing date of the cardholder, and the crediting date of the merchant.

Credit Cards

9. Credit cards are payment cards intended for purchase of assets without immediate payment.

Credit transactions enable cardholders to pay with money they are not carrying or even money

they do not yet have. A purchase with a credit card enables the cardholder to overcome liquidity

constraints.

In Israel, the main usage of credit cards is as deferred debit cards (known in the U.S. as charge

cards).20 The cardholder is charged for all purchases during a month, on a certain date in the

19 European Commission, Green Paper, Towards an Integrated European Market for Card, Internet and Mobile

Payments, at 1, COM (2011) 941 final (Jan. 11, 2012): “[T]he mass take-up of smart phones is changing the payments

landscape and is leading to new payment applications, for example electronic purses, replacing wallets and physical

cards, or virtual public transport tickets stored in a mobile phone”. 20 BANK OF ISRAEL, MARCHOT HATAHSLUMIM VEHASLIKA BEISRAEL, HASEFER HADOM (PAYMENT AND ACQUIRING

SYSTEMS IN ISRAEL, THE RED BOOK FOR 2014), at 29 (Nov. 8, 2015) (deferred debit is the most common card).

Page 11: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

11

following month. Cardholders do not pay interest for the free funding period, which is, on

average, 17 days.21 Cardholders who defer payment are charged interest on their balance.22

10. Recent years have seen an increase in the dispersion of revolving cards. These are credit cards

on which the cardholder pays a monthly sum on part of the balance. The rest is postponed with

interest to later periods.23 In a revolving transaction, the merchant receives the sum of the

transaction in one payment. Thus, the issuer (and not the merchant), is the cardholder's credit

grantor.

11. Installment transactions are unique to Israel. These are credit transactions in which the

cardholder pays the sum of the transaction in monthly payments without interest. The merchant

also receives payment in the same monthly installments. Installment transactions are therefore

equivalent to as many regular transactions as the number of the installments. The merchant is

the one to extend credit to the cardholder in this kind of transaction.

Bank Cards

12. A bank card, as defined in the Payment Cards Law, enables the cardholder to purchase assets

by charging the account of the cardholder and correspondingly crediting the merchant’s

account. A bank card is a “pay-now” instrument. It immediately debits the related account and

credits the merchant’s account in the exact amount of the transaction. A transaction with a bank

card is similar to a transaction made with an ATM positioned at the cashier, in which the

cardholder withdraws the exact amount of the transaction and remits it immediately to the

merchant.

The law does not define “bank cards” properly because the main characteristic that

distinguishes a bank card from a credit card is not a “bank”, but rather the charge date. A better

definition is debit card.24

21 IAA, ISRAEL ANTITRUST AUTHORITY, HAGBARAT HAYEILUT VEHATAHARUT BETHUM KARTISEI HAHIUV

[ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR], FINAL REPORT, at 13, Antitrust

500680 (Sept. 8, 2014) (free funding period of 17 days on average). 22 Bank of Israel, THE RED BOOK, supra note 20; HAVAADA LEBHINAT TZIMZUM HASHIMUSH BEMEZUMAN BAMESHEK

HAISRAELI [THE COMMITTEE FOR EXAMINING REDUCTION OF CASH USAGE IN THE ISRAELI MARKET] (THE LOCKER

COMMITTEE), FINAL REPORT, at 48 (July 17, 2014); Sumit Agarwal et al., Regulating Consumer Financial Products:

Evidence from Credit Cards, at 5, SSRN eLibrary (Aug. 2014): “If an account holder pays off her purchase volume

completely, interest charges typically fall within a “grace period” and are not assessed by the bank. If the account holder

does not pay her balances in full, she is charged interest starting from the date of purchase”. 23 ISRACARD, 2014 ANNUAL REPORT, at 11, available at https://www.isracard.co.il/report/120021424.pdf . 24 BANK OF ISRAEL, RECOMMENDATIONS FOR ENHANCEMENT OF COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR, FINAL

REPORT, at 9 (Feb. 2015); Santiago Carbo Valverde et al., Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation,

Page 12: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

12

13. In Israel, debit card usage is negligible. Debit transactions amount to 1.4% of the volume of all

payment card transactions.25 The situation worldwide is opposite. Debit cards are widely used

in almost all countries.26 Even in the U.S., traditionally a "credit" nation, debit transactions

exceeded credit transactions.27

14. There are two main types of debit cards: signature debit and PIN debit. Only PIN debit

transactions are "pure" debit, in the sense that the transaction is completed immediately upon

payment. With signature debit transactions remittance to merchants occur after 1-3 days.28

The short delay of payment in signature debit makes signature debit a little riskier for issuers

than PIN debit transactions.29 PIN debit is a cheaper, faster and safer payment instrument than

at 19 (Fed. Res. Bank of Chicago Working Paper No. 09-11, 2009): "Debit cards allow consumers to access funds at

their financial institutions that are transferred to the merchants’ financial institutions and may be referred to as “pay

now” cards". 25 IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note

21, at 8. 26Infra ¶ 67. 27 Brad G. Hubbard, The Durbin Amendment, Two-Sided Markets, and Wealth Transfers: An Examination of

Unintended Consequences Three Years Later, at 11, SSRN (2013): “In the past decade, debits cards have been the

fastest growing payment method among noncash, retail, payment methods. Debit card usage was negligible in the early

nineties and represented 11.6 percent of all noncash payments by 2000. From 2000 to 2009, debit card usage grew by a

factor of 4.75… By 2009, debit cards ranked first in the total volume of noncash, retail payment methods, representing

35 percent of all payments... In 2003, for the first time, the aggregate dollar volume of Visa debit exceeded that of Visa

credit... Debit’s household penetration has also been extensive; in 1995 only 20 percent of households had debit cards;

by 2007, that number had increased to 71 percent. Perhaps most strikingly, in 2009, debit cards were used in 29.3

percent of all transactions, rendering them the most frequently used method of payment, eclipsing cash, credit cards,

and checks”. 28 FUMIKO HAYASHI ET AL., A GUIDE TO THE ATM AND DEBIT CARD INDUSTRY, Fed. Res. Bank of Kansas, at 8 (2003):

"[C]onsumer accounts are debited one or two days after the transaction".

Ron Borzekowski & Elizabeth k. Kiser, Consumers’ use of Debit Cards: Patterns, Preferences, and Price Response, 40

J. MONEY, CREDIT & BANK. 149 (2008); U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., GAO-10-45, RISING INTERCHANGE FEES

HAVE INCREASED COSTS FOR MERCHANTS, BUT OPTIONS FOR REDUCING FEES POSE CHALLENGES, at 4 (2009); BANK OF

ISRAEL, THE RED BOOK, supra note 20 at 29 n. 37. 29 Robert M. Hunt, An Introduction to the Economics of Payment Card Networks, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 80, 83

(2003): "This delay creates some credit risk for the issuing bank because the cardholder may have insufficient funds in

her account at the time the transaction clears. So, unlike with ATM cards, banks offer signature debit cards only to

account holders that meet minimum credit standards".

Page 13: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

13

signature debit.30 Also, empirical studies have found that fraud in signature debit is higher than

in PIN debit.31 All debit cards are less risky than credit cards.32

15. Until April 2016 Israel presented a distorted exception, as merchants were paid for debit

transactions after an average delay of 20 days (as if the transactions were deferred debit

transactions). Since April 1, 2016, this evil was corrected by Bank of Israel. Merchants are

credited for debit transactions within 1-3 days.33

16. Strictly speaking, signature debit cards are not “bank cards”, as defined in the Payment Cards

Law, because the cardholder is not debited immediately upon transaction. According to the

Law's precise definition, only PIN debit cards are bank cards. Signature debit cards are actually

accelerated charge cards.

In this work, I will use the term debit cards, as it is used in the literature, to describe signature

and PIN debit altogether, unless the context requires a distinction between them.

Prepaid Cards

17. Prepaid cards are also “a plate or object for reuse”. However, unlike debit or credit cards, in

which the cardholder pays after the transaction (credit) or in parallel with the transaction (debit),

with prepaid cards, the cardholder pays in advance.34 Prepaid cards can be used, like credit and

30 Fumiko Hayashi, The New Debit Card Regulations: Effects on Merchants, Consumers, and Payments System

Efficiency, 1 FRB KANSAS Q. REV. 89, 107 (2013): "PIN debit is less costly, more secure, and more preferred by

consumers than signature debit." Bank Of Israel, Chain of Transaction in Payment Card, at 43 (July 2016) 31 Board of Governors of the Fed. Res. System, Debit Card Interchange Fees and Routing, Final Rule, 77 Fed. Reg.

46258, 46261 (Aug. 3, 2012) (codified at 12 C.F.R. pt. 235): “Of the approximately $1.34 billion estimated industry-

wide fraud losses, about $1.11 billion of these losses arose from signature debit card transactions and about $181

million arose from PIN debit card transactions... on a per-dollar basis, signature debit fraud losses were approximately 4

times PIN debit fraud losses”;

FUMIKO HAYASHI ET AL., A GUIDE TO THE ATM AND DEBIT CARD INDUSTRY, 2006 UPDATE, at 21: "PIN debit

traditionally has been regarded as safer than signature debit, and three recent studies show that PIN debit has less fraud

than signature debit";

Oz Shy & Zhu Wang, Why do Payment Card Networks Charge Proportional Fees?, 101 AM. ECON. REV. 1575, 1577

(2011): "[D]ebit cards do not provide credit float and bear very small fraud risk, so there appears to be no cost basis for

charging proportional fees." 32 David A. Price & Zhu Wang, Why do Debit Card Networks Charge Percentage Fees?, footnote 3 (13-02 Fed. Res.

Bank of Richmond, 2013): “Fraud risk is much less for debit cards than for credit cards. According to industry studies,

the average net fraud loss to card issuers is 0.08 percent for credit card transactions, 0.05 percent for signature debit

card transactions, and 0.01 percent for PIN debit card transactions”. 33 Bank of Israel, Communication 2498-06-ח, Acquiring Payment Cards (Banking Proper Procedure, Instruction 472),

§13 (May 1, 2016). See also infra ¶ 18 and Ch. 8.1.4 (Debit Cards in Israel). 34 Mark Furletti, Prepaid Card Markets & Regulation, Fed. Res. Bank Phil., at 2 (2004): “Unlike credit cards, which

draw their value from a line of credit, or debit cards, which draw their value from a checking account, the value on a

prepaid card typically comes from money given to the card’s issuer (or a designee) prior to its use”;

Julia S. Cheney, Prepaid Cards: An Important Innovation in Financial Services, Fed. Res. Bank Phila. (2006): “Based

on a different business model than traditional credit and debit cards, prepaid cards require cardholders to “pay early” for

Page 14: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

14

debit cards, for purchase of assets and also, like ATM cards, for withdrawal of money.35 Prepaid

cards are often used as a platform for specific purchases, such as transportation, restaurants,36

and gift cards.37 Prepaid cards are not linked to a bank account. The card itself is the account,

to which money is loaded. Purchases are limited to the amount that was (re)loaded into the card.

The definition in Article 1 to the Payment Cards Law explicitly states that usage of prepaid

cards cannot obligate the bank account of the cardholder.

18. A major anomaly in Israel with respect to debit and prepaid cards was that until April 2016,

interchange fee for debit and prepaid transactions was the same as the interchange fee for credit

transactions. The Israeli Antitrust Authority and Bank of Israel have taken steps to change this.38

On August 23, 2015 a Banking Decree finally ordered that interchange fee in debit and prepaid

transactions would be 0.3% (instead of 0.7% in credit transaction) effective April 1, 2016.39

2.2. The Parties

Issuer

19. An issuer is the financial institution that enters a contract with cardholders ("Cardholder

Agreement"). Cardholder agreement regularizes the terms of joinder and participation of a

cardholder in a payment card scheme.

The main responsibility of the issuer in the cardholder agreement is defined in Article 7 of the

Payment Cards Law. Issuer is liable to remit merchants the consideration for assets bought with

future purchases of goods and services as opposed to debit-card holders, who pay at the time the purchase is made, or

credit-card holders, who pay after the purchase has been made”. 35 Stephanie M. Wilshusen et al., Consumers’ use of Prepaid Cards: A Transaction-Based Analysis, at 6 (Fed. Res.

Bank of Phil. Discussion Paper 2012): "Most of the prepaid cards… are used for both cash withdrawals and purchases

of goods and services"; Fumiko Hayashi & Emily Cuddy, General Purpose Reloadable Prepaid Cards: Penetration,

use, Fees and Fraud Risks (FED. RES. BANK KANSAS, Feb. 2014). 36 Phillip Keitel, Federal Regulation of the Prepaid Card Industry: Costs, Benefits, and Changing Industry Dynamics,

at 27 (Conference Summary of the Payment Cards Center of the Fed. Res. Bank of Phil., April 8-9, 2010): “[P]repaid is

best viewed as a platform that supports a wide variety of products, each with a different business model”;

Phillip Keitel, A Prepaid Case Study: Ready Credit’s General-Purpose & Transit-Fare Programs (Fed. Res. Bank Phil.

Discussion Paper, 2012). 37 James McGrath, General-use Prepaid Cards: The Path to Gaining Mainstream Acceptance (Fed. Res. Bank Phil.,

2007). 38 For expansion see infra ch. 8.1.4 (Debit in Israel). 39 Banking Decree (Service to Customer) (Supervision on Service Issuer Gives Acquirer inConnection with Interchange

Acquiring of Debit Transactions) (Temporary Order), 2015 [(Tsav Habankaut (Sherut Lalakoach) (Pikuach al Sherut

Shenoten Manpik Lesolek Bekesher Leslika Tzolevet Shel Iskaot Hiuv Miadi) (Horaat Shaa) sec. 3, (2015)].

Page 15: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

15

payment card it issued. The cardholder has a corresponding duty to pay the issuer for all

purchases made with the card.

20. In Israel, there are three issuers: Isracard, LeumiCard and C.A.L. These firms are bank

subsidiaries. Isracard is under the sole ownership of Bank Hapoalim. LeumiCard is under the

control of Bank Leumi (80%) and the Azrieli Group (20%).40 CAL is held jointly by Israel

Discount bank (72%) and First International bank of Israel (28%).41

In Israel, Isracard is the sole issuer and acquirer of American Express cards. Isracard is also the

only issuer of its proprietary brand cards that carry the name "Isracart". CAL is the sole issuer

of Diners Club cards in Israel. Isracard, LeumiCard and CAL are all issuers and acquirers of

Visa and MasterCard by virtue of licenses from those international organizations.

21. Most payment cards in Israel have been issued with the cooperation of the bank in which the

cardholder’s account is managed. However, during recent years, more cards are issued without

the cooperation of the bank in which the cardholder holds an account.42 Non-bank cards are

issued directly by one of the issuing firms (Leumicard, Isracard or CAL) or, more often, as a

cooperation of an issuer and a consumption club, such as big retailers e.g., Supersal, Lifestyle

for Super-Pharm customers, "Hever" for defense arms employers, "Members" for lawyers and

CPAs.43 The club operates as a marketing branch of the issuer. The club shares with the issuer

the income that the cards yield. Non-bank payment cards often offer rewards and rebates to

their holders. The merchant also enjoys higher loyalty of customers who possess cards issued

with its cooperation.44 In the U.S., many large retailers issue private cards that bypass the

payment card networks entirely.45

Acquirer

22. Acquirer is the financial institution that contracts with merchants (“The Merchant

Agreement”). The merchant agreement regulates the terms of joinder and participation of

40 LEUMICARD, 2014 ANNUAL REPORT, at 13 (2015). 41 CAL, 2014 ANNUAL REPORT, at 8 (2015). 42 BANK OF ISRAEL, THE BANKING SYSTEM IN ISRAEL, 2015 ANNUAL REVIEW, at 28 (2016) (substantial increase in

issuance of non-bank cards in the last decade). See also infra ¶ 57. 43 ISRACARD, 2014 ANNUAL REPORT, at 11 (2015). 44 Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, para. 713 (Dec. 19, 2007): “By buying again at a shop the

customer typically gets rebates which are counted on the store cards. The shop in turn wins the loyalty (and often a

home address of the client to mail advertisements)”. 45 Steve Worthington, Affinity Credit Cards a Critical Review, 29 INT. J. RETAIL & DISTRIBUTION MANAGEMENT 485

(2001); Marc Bourreau & Marianne Verdier, Private Cards and the Bypass of Payment Systems by Merchants, 34 J.

BANK. FIN. 1798 (2010).

Page 16: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

16

merchants in a payment card scheme. The Merchant Agreement regulates the commercial

relations between the acquirer and the merchant. The merchant agreement governs the way

merchants should act when accepting cards, e.g., identifying the cardholder, verifying signature,

passing the cards through magnetic stripes etc. The Merchant Agreement also stipulates the

duties of the acquirer, to pay the consideration for transactions acquired, minus the MSF.

Acquiring, as defined by the Israeli law, consists of remitting the consideration of a transaction

to the merchant against receiving it from the issuer.46 A merchant who wishes to accept payment

cards must contract with an acquirer, and install equipment and point of sale ("POS") terminal

suited to read payment cards. The acquirer is responsible to connect the cashiers of the merchant

to the infrastructure of the payment card network. The acquiring process involves processing

and routing transactions through the infrastructure of the payment card network, clearing and

settlement. Acquirers also provide merchants statements with information of their services.47

Acquiring can carry credit and fraud related risks, especially if the merchant does not perform

after being remitted. If a remitted merchant defaults and the cardholder cancels the transaction,

then acquirers assume the risk of chargeback (without being able to off-set against the

merchant). Chargeback disputes arise between issuers and acquirers without involvement of

cardholders or merchants.48 Generally, in chargeback disputes, acquirers are liable to

merchants' fraud and default whereas issuers are liable to cardholders' fraud and default.

Acquiring activities typically include underwriting merchants' applications including anti

money laundering and fraud checks; recruiting merchants; deployment of equipment, including

leasing or selling terminals and POSs; support and service to merchants; handling merchants'

46 Article 36(i) of the Banking Law (licensing) (1981) that was added in 2011. 47 Ann Kjos, The Merchant-Acquiring Side of the Payment Card Industry: Structure, Operations, and Challenges, at 3

(F.R.B Phil' Discussion Paper 2007): “[M]erchant acquirers generally perform four key functions: (1) signing up and

underwriting merchants to accept network-branded cards, (2) providing the means to authorize valid card transactions at

client merchant locations (3) facilitating the clearing and settlement of the transactions through the payment network,

and (4) providing other relevant information services, such as sending out statements”. 48 European Commission, Payment card chargeback when paying over Internet, at 3, MARKT/173/2000 (Jul. 12, 2000):

"Chargeback » is the technical term used by international card schemes to name the refunding process for a transaction

carried out by card following the violation of a rule. This process takes place between 2 members of the card scheme,

the issuer of the card and the acquirer (the merchant’s bank). The final customers of these 2 scheme members, the

cardholder for the issuer and the merchant for the acquirer, do not have any direct relationship in the chargeback

process."

Page 17: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

17

accounts and chargebacks. Card networks monitor Acquirers' performance in areas such as

fraud and chargeback volumes. If parameters are breached, the acquirer can be fined.

23. Infrastructure of payment card network is comparable to roads. Communication and money

"travel" on this infrastructure. The infrastructure enables communication from the merchant's

POS to cardholders' accounts, and also allows remittance in the opposite direction. Acquirers

sometimes use outsourcing services offered by third parties, which are called "back-end" or

"back-office" acquirers.49

Often, an additional intermediary is situated between the acquirer and the merchant, a factoring

firm. Acquirers usually pay merchants once a month for credit and deferred debit transactions.

Factoring firms offer merchants the option to advance sums due in consideration for (factoring)

fee.50 For merchants, factoring firms make deferred transactions closer to debit, in return for a

larger MSF. In Israel, until April 2016, the delay in remittance of debit and prepaid

transactions,51 brought factoring firms to give their services also to debit and prepaid

transactions.

Merchants and Cardholders

24. Firms, individuals, institutions, shops, businesses, agencies and anyone who engages with an

acquirer in a Merchant Agreement to accept payment cards, will be referred to in this work as

"merchant". For example, as the state accepts payment cards for fines, taxes and other

mandatory payments, the state, in this sense, is a merchant. Landlords who receive rent via

payment cards are also considered merchants.

25. Consumers or customers that possess payment cards will be referred as “cardholders”. A

cardholder is defined by the holding of a payment card, without considering the level of usage.

49 Id. at 23: “It has become a common practice to outsource such back-office services as terminal deployment and setup,

underwriting, training, chargeback processing, fraud monitoring, customer services, and the point-of-sale help desk”.

Ramon P. Degennaro, Merchant Acquirers and Payment Card Processors: A Look Inside the Black Box, FRB ATLANTA

ECON. REV. (2006): “Some merchant acquirers perform the processing themselves; others resell the services of a third-

party processor. That is, they are merchant acquirers who resell front- and back-end processing services but do not provide

those services themselves. Most of the larger merchant acquirers also function as processors, but almost all of the smaller ones

are resellers”. 50 IAA, Press Release, Antitrust General Director Conditioned a Merger between Yatzil and CAL in Opening the

Factoring Markets, Antitrust 3018872 (2003); Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Social Costs of Credit Card Merchant

Restraints, at 7, SSRN (2008), available at http://ssrn.com/paper=973970 : “In all networks there is often an additional

party, the merchant service provider, that links the merchant and the acquirer". 51 Supra ¶ 18 and note 33.

Page 18: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

18

2.3. The Fees

26. Issuers are connected to cardholders. Acquirers are connected to merchants. Issuers have no

direct relationship with merchants and acquirers have no direct relations with cardholders. The

income of issuers and acquirers stems from their contractual partners, with one exception – the

interchange fee.

Issuers charge a Cardholder Fee and acquirers charge a MSF. The MSF consists of two parts

– the acquirer fee and the interchange fee.

Cardholder Fee

27. The cardholder fee is the net amount a cardholder pays the issuer for the payment card, after

deduction of discounts, rewards and rebates. Typically, the cardholder fee consists of both fixed

and variable (negative) components.

The fixed component is usually a monthly payment. In Israel, following a reform in banking

fees,52 this payment is regarded as a banking fee, and is subject to regulation of the Governor

of the Bank of Israel.53 Not all cardholders pay a fix component. Issuers regularly exempt

cardholders, wholly or partially, from the fixed fee for an initial period, or against minimum

usage, which is measured either in number of transactions or in the amount spent.54

The variable fee is zero or negative. Cardholders do not pay for transactions. On the contrary,

the variable fee can be considered as negative for two reasons: the first is the free funding period

between the date of purchase and the future charge date, which exists in both credit and deferred

debit. The second reason is rewards to cardholders that usually increase with usage. This means

that issuers actually pay cardholders for usage. Rewards are mostly in the form of discounts,

flight mileage rewards, stars/points for future purchases, and sometimes even direct cash-

back.55

52 Amendment 12 to the Banking Law (Service to Customer), 1981 53 Banking Rules (service to customer) (fees), 2008 54 Tim Westrich & Malcolm Bush, Blindfolded into Debt: A Comparison of Credit Card Costs and Conditions at Banks

and Credit Unions, WOODSTOCK INST. (2005): "Introductory rates or “teaser rates” are promotional offers that keep one

or all of the credit card’s rates low, often at 0 percent, for a specified number of billing cycles". 55 Infra ch. 6.7; see also Oren Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, 98 N.W.L.R. 1373, 1391 (2004): "In fact, when

considering the benefits or rewards programs associated with most credit cards, issuers are setting negative per

transaction fees.";

Page 19: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

19

Both the positive fixed cardholder fee and negative transaction (variable) fee, affect the level

of usage by cardholders. The fixed fee is a lump sum. After payment of the fixed fee, the

cardholder sees only the benefits associated with extensive usage. These benefits grow with

usage and incentivize cardholders to use cards.56 Interchange fees play a vital role in this

inducement process, by funding it, as will be explained more extensively in this work.

28. Bank of Israel encourages customers to be aware of the fees they pay. As part of the Bank’s

efforts in this field it published on its web-site the official tariff of the cardholder fee and the

actual cardholder fee. The cardholder fee in practice is about half of the tariff, because of the

above explained "teaser rate" system of rebates and rewards.57 In this work, I use the term

“cardholder fee” as the actual fee, after the deduction of all rewards.

29. Apart from cardholder fees, issuers have other sources of income from their customers. They

charge interest on unpaid credit balances beyond the free funding period. This interest is usually

higher than the interest on bank loans,58 and is a main source of income to issuers.59 Another

source of income to issuers is interest charged on loans to the public, even to borrowers who

are not their cardholders, e.g., loans to purchase motor vehicles.60

The Merchant Service Fee (“MSF”)

30. The MSF is the price a merchant pays to the acquirer for transactions made with payment cards.

In the case of credit cards, the MSF is a percentage of the transaction (ad valorem). For example,

if the transaction sum is 100 and the MSF is 2%, the merchant receives 98 and the MSF is 2.

Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Must-Take Cards: Merchant Discounts and Avoided Costs, 9 J. EUR. ECON. ASS'N

462 (2011): "We allow Pb to be negative, in which case the cardholder receives a payment from his bank, in the form of

interest-free period, cash back bonuses or air miles awarded to the buyer every time he uses his card". 56 Infra ¶ 727. 57 Bank of Israel, Supervision of Banks, the Fee Reform, (Oct. 30, 2010) 58 ITAMAR MILRED, TEUR SHUK KARTISEI HASHRAI VENITUAH HAMIMSHAKIM BEIN HEVROT KARTISEI HASHRAI LEBEIN

HABANKIM (DESCRIPTION OF CREDIT CARD MARKET AND ANALYZING INTERFACES BETWEEN CREDIT CARD FIRMS AND

THE BANKS), THE KNESSET CENTER FOR RESEARCH AND INFORMATION, at 16 (Feb, 2014). Wilko Bolt & Sujit

Chakravorti, Digitization of Retail Payments (DNB Working Paper 270. 2010): "The empirical literature on credit cards

has suggested interest rate stickiness along with above market interest rates, although some have argued that the rate is

low compared with alternatives such as pawn shops."; Bank of Israel, the Supervision of Banks - Banking

Consumerism, Advantages and Disadvantages of Revolving Credit

http://www.boi.org.il/he/ConsumerInformation/ConsumerIssues/Pages/RevolvingCreditCard.aspx . 59 Infra ¶ 463. See also Steven Semeraro, Assessing the Costs & Benefits of Credit Card Rewards: A Response to Who

Gains and Who Loses from Credit Card Payments? Theory and Calibrations, at 9 (2012): “[C]ardholders account for

well over half of the revenue that card-issuing banks earn. Approximately 70% of a typical card issuer’s revenue comes

from interest paid by cardholders for financed purchases";

United States v. Am. Express Co., 2015 U.S. Dist. Lexis 20114, at 36 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015): "[I]nterest charged on

revolving balances… generate more than half… revenue". 60 LEUMICARD, 2014 ANNUAL REPORT, at 20; BANK OF ISRAEL, 2010 ANNUAL REPORT, at 121.

Page 20: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

20

With debit cards, the MSF is sometimes fixed and sometimes ad valorem.61

The MSF is composed of two components. One of them is the interchange fee.

The Interchange Fee

31. A major part of the MSF collected by the acquirer does not remain with the acquirer. It is paid

by the acquirer to the issuer. This is the interchange fee.

By definition, the interchange fee is a payment that an acquirer of a transaction remits to the

issuer of the card used for the transaction when the acquirer and the issuer are not the same

institution.62 When the issuer and the acquirer are the same, the interchange fee is only notional,

and the transaction is called “On-Us”.63 The interchange fee is therefore another source of

income for issuers, in addition to cardholder fees and interest on credit and loans. As opposed

to the cardholder fee, which is a direct fee, the interchange fee is an indirect fee. Merchants pay

it, but they are not a party to the arrangement that sets it. Interchange fee is hidden for them as

undistinguished part of the MSF.

32. The Interchange fee makes up the bulk of the MSF. Although current regulation in some

countries has reduced interchange fees, it still makes up a major part of the MSF.64

61 Infra ¶ 33. For expansion see infra ch. 0. 62 REFORM OF CREDIT CARD SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA, FINAL REFORMS AND REGULATION IMPACT STATEMENT, at 5

(RBA, 2002): “The interchange fee is the fee paid to the financial institution which issues the card (the “issuer”) by the

financial institution which provides services to the merchant (the “acquirer”) whenever the merchant accepts credit

cards for payment”. 63 Infra ch. 2.4.1. 64 Motion 34/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, at 3 (Dec. 22, 2002) ; David Balto, The Problem of Interchange

Fees: Costs without Benefits? E.C.L.R 215 (2000): "[C]redit card interchange fees comprise over 90 per cent of the

merchant discount";

Price & Wang, Why do Debit Card Networks Charge Percentage Fees?, supra note 32: “Merchants that accept debit

cards pay fees known as merchant discounts, which are composed mainly of interchange fees paid to card issuers”;

Steve Semeraro, Credit Cards Interchange Fees: Three Decades of Antitrust Uncertainty, 14 GEO. MASON L.REV 941

(2007): "Generally, in the Visa and MasterCard systems, the issuer receives about 75 percent of the total merchant

discount, leaving 25 percent for the acquiring bank";

Robin A. Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks: Economics, Industry Developments, and Policy

Issues, at 12 (F.R.B. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 23-09, 2009): "An interchange fee typically comprises a

large fraction of the merchant discount for a particular card transaction";

Alan S. Frankel & Allan L. Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 627 (2006):

"Interchange fees establish the major component of acquirers’ marginal costs for processing transactions and account

for most of the fees paid by merchants to acquirers for processing credit card transactions—the “merchant discount”;

Fumiko Hayashi, A Puzzle of Card Payment Pricing: Why are Merchants Still Accepting Card Payments? 5Rev.

NETWORK ECON. 144 (2006): "Typically the interchange fee accounts for more than 75 percent of the merchant fee";

Tim Mead, Renee Courtois Haltom & Margaretta Blackwell, The Role of Interchange Fees on Debit and Credit Card

Transactions in the Payments System, 11-05 FED. RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND (2011): “Each time a consumer makes

a purchase using a credit or debit card, the merchant is assessed fees associated with processing the transaction. The

Page 21: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

21

33. Interchange fee in credit card transactions is ad valorem. Regarding debit transactions, the

interchange fee is sometimes proportional (ad valorem), sometimes fixed, and sometimes a

combination. In Israel and the E.U. interchange fee for all card transactions is proportional.65

In the U.S., since 2011, interchange fee for debit, prepaid and deferred debit is a fixed sum of

approximately 22 cents, uncorrelated to the transaction size, plus an additional 0.05% of the

transaction amount, for issuers who take certain steps of fraud prevention.66

Fixed interchange fee increases merchant resistance in small transactions, whereas a

proportional MSF increases merchant resistance to accept cards in large transactions.67 Shy &

Wang argue that acquirers prefer to charge proportional fees because it increases their profits.68

34. Worldwide, interchange fee for debit transactions is lower than that of credit. As mentioned

above, Israel presented a distortion, which was amended only on April 2016.69

In Israel, the interchange fee is determined in a Trio Agreement between the three acquirers and

issuers: Isracard, LeumiCard and CAL ("The Trio Agreement"). The first Trio Agreement was

signed in 2006, when Isracard joined a previous bilateral interchange agreement between CAL

and LeumiCard. According to the Trio Agreement, each of the three companies may acquire

MasterCard and Visa cards that each of them issues.70 Since 2012, all three firms may acquire

Isracard payment cards that only Isracard issues, and pay Isracard a similar interchange fee as

in Visa and MasterCard transactions.71

largest of those fees is the “interchange” fee, which is set by the card network that processes the transaction and is

ultimately paid to the bank that issued the card”; Bank of Israel, The Banking System in Israel, 2015 Annual Review, at

30, diagram #3 (2016). 65 Infra ¶ 34 (Israel), ¶ 576 (Visa Europe), ¶ 579 (MasterCard in Europe). 66 Infra ¶ 638. 67Ann Borestam & Heiko Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, ECB Occasional Paper Series 131, at 22

(2011): "[A] fixed interchange fee that has to be paid by merchants has the potential to discourage the acceptance of

cards for payments of small amounts. On the other hand, an ad valorem fee for higher transaction values or for highly

taxed purchases such as petrol could result in the perception at the merchant that the merchant service charge to be paid

and the service offered are not connected to one another". 68 Shy & Wang, supra note 31 at 1585: “The card network earns higher profits by charging proportional fees compared

with fixed per-transaction fees”; Price & Wang, Why do Debit Card Networks Charge Percentage Fees?, supra note 32:

"[T]his type of fee structure, a linear ad valorem fee, maximizes profits for card networks by allowing price

discrimination."; See also Zhu Wang & Julian Wright, Ad-Valorem Platform Fees and Efficient Price Discrimination

(2012). 69 Supra ¶¶15, 18; for expansion see infra ch. 8.1.4 (Debit Cards In Israel). 70 Infra ¶ 493. 71 Infra ¶ 322.

Page 22: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

22

Since July 2014, the interchange fee rate in Israel is 0.7%.72 There is a narrow exception for a

category of lower-rate interchange fee of 0.5% for the state and the Israeli Electric Company. I

will elaborate on the various categories of interchange fees in Chapter 8.1.3 infra.

35. The interchange fee is a “price” fixed by competitors. Isracard, LeumiCard and CAL are all in

competition with each other. They compete on the issuing side for cardholders. They compete

on the acquiring side for merchants. Since the interchange fee is a major part of the MSF, fixing

it means setting a minimum floor to the MSF. No acquirer can offer an MSF that is lower than

the interchange fee, if it does not want to suffer a loss.

Setting the MSF below the interchange fee would mean that the interchange fee the acquirer

pays, would be larger than all of the acquirer's income from that transaction. The acquirer would

necessarily lose money. Therefore, the interchange fee is a restrictive arrangement equivalent

to fixing a minimum price between competitors.73

36. When Isracard, LeumiCard and CAL negotiate the interchange fee, each of them wears two

hats, one in its role of issuer and the other in its role of acquirer. In a free negotiation between

a willing acquirer to a separate willing issuer, one might assume that acquirers would bargain,

attempting to reduce the price they pay. Such bargaining is in line with pro-competitive

principles of vertical arrangements, in which the interest of the buyer (acquirer) to pay low price

(interchange fee), merge with interest of consumers to pay low prices for final goods.74

However, this is not the case with interchange fees. The negotiation is a "self-negotiation"

between the payers (functioning as acquirers) and themselves as payees (functioning as issuers).

The outcome does not resemble the result of a free arm’s length negotiation.75 The buyer

(acquirer) willingly "gives up" and agrees to pay the issuer (i.e., to itself in another transaction),

a high interchange fee, which is ultimately passed through to the merchant via the MSF. The

acquirer knows that in another transaction, where it will function as the issuer, things will be

72 Infra ¶ 499. 73 For expansion see infra ch. 0. 74 See generally DAVID GILO & YOSSI SPIEGEL, VERTICAL RESTRAINTS, IN A LEGAL AND ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF

ANTITRUST LAW 323, 327 (2008) (As long as the supplier is not a partner to the profits of the retailer through royalties

or fixed fees, the supplier prefers low prices for final consumers, to maximize number of transactions, i.e., purchases

from the supplier). 75 Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 44, para. 499: “[T]he setting of interchange fee

rates is not akin to a contentious process such as a price negotiation where opposing interests of buyers and sellers

meet”.

Case T-111/08 MasterCard v. Comm'n, para. 32( May 24, 2012): “[I]t was not in the acquiring banks’ interest to exert

any downward competitive pressure on the MIF since they benefit from it, directly or indirectly”.

For an amusing illustration, see Monty Python, Life of Brian, The Haggle, directed by Terry Jones (1979), http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=3n3LL338aGA.

Page 23: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

23

the opposite, and the acquirer will be the party to receive the interchange fee, in its capacity as

an issuer.

The previous paragraph explains in short why the interchange fee is a restrictive arrangement,

and why privately set interchange fees (between issuers and acquirers) tend to be higher than

optimal.76

37. The overall income that the interchange fee yields is distributed according to the market share

of each issuer. Thus, even a large acquirer, which is a small issuer, enjoys the expansion of the

pie according to its share on the issuing side.77

The Acquiring Fee

38. The acquiring fee is the gap between the interchange fee and the MSF. This gap is the income

of the acquirer. The consideration for that fee is the acquiring services acquirers give to

merchants. The main services are remittance of transaction funds, connecting merchants to the

payment card network, and processing, authorizing and settling transactions.

39. In the past, acquiring services were performed manually. The product of card transactions was

paper slips, which the acquirer had to collect, process, authorize and remit their value to the

merchant, minus the MSF. Currently, the acquiring process is paperless and is provided by

electronic means. Generally, acquirers do not guarantee payments owed by cardholders to

merchants. Issuers incur the payment guarantee. Thus, as opposed to issuers’ cost of payment

guarantee, which is proportional to the transaction size, costs of supplying acquiring services

are generally fixed, and are not dependent on the sum of the transaction.

2.4. Open and Closed Networks

40. Open networks are payment systems in which there is multiplicity of acquirers and issuers. In

Israel, local networks of Visa and MasterCard are comprised of only three firms that operate

both on the issuing and acquiring sides. Internationally, networks like Visa and MasterCard

have thousands of issuers and acquirers. Any financial institution can join the network.78 There

are four parties to an open network: issuer, acquirer, cardholder and merchant. Therefore, open

76 For expansion see infra ch. 0 (interchange fee as a restrictive arrangement) and ch. 6.9.2 (why privately set

interchange fees are biased). 77 Infra ¶ 781. 78 Marc Rysman & Julian Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, at 4 (2015): “The systems are open in the sense

that any bank or equivalent financial institution can join.”

Page 24: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

24

networks are sometimes called "four-party" networks. Examples of open networks are Visa and

MasterCard.

41. Closed networks are payment systems in which the issuer and the acquirer are the same entity.

Closed networks are also known as "three-party" networks, because they involve only three

parties in each transaction: the payment system, which acts as sole issuer and acquirer,

cardholder and merchant.79 Closed networks set both the MSF to merchants and the cardholder

fee. A closed network that distinguishes in its accounts between issuing and acquiring costs

might attribute a notional interchange fee from the acquiring side to the issuing side, but the

interchange fee will remain notional. It is possible to think of the interchange fee in closed

networks as part of the MSF, which is allocated to the issuing side.80

Examples of closed networks in Israel are American Express and Diners Club.81 Until 2012

Isracard operated as a closed network. In 2012 Isracard was compelled, to open its network,

and let LeumiCard and CAL acquire its proprietary Isracard cards.82 In the U.S., American

Express and Diners sometimes give third parties licenses to issue their cards, in a structure that

resembles open networks.83

79Id. at 4 (2015): “Closed systems, or three-party systems, such as Discover and American Express typically issue cards

to consumers and acquire merchants to accept the card. They set fees to both sides, which largely consist of an annual

fee, an interest rate (for credit cards) and a rewards program for consumers, and a fee for merchants (termed the

merchant discount in the industry). A closed card platform can choose any structure of prices that it so desires between

cardholders and merchants.”;

EC INTERIM REPORT I PAYMENT CARDS SECTOR INQUIRY UNDER ARTICLE 17 REGULATION 1/2003 ON RETAIL

BANKING, at 88 (Apr. 12, 2006): “The industry generally distinguishes between “open” or “four-party” card payment

systems and “closed” or “three-party” card payment systems, where the scheme owner also engages in the financial

aspects of the payment card business by issuing cards and acquiring merchants. This is the case for American Express,

Citibank (Diners Club) and JCB, which (mainly) issue and acquire cards themselves. These systems are also referred to

as “proprietary” systems, as the scheme owner typically is the proprietor of the technical network used for routing,

switching, clearing and processing the transactions”. 80 Rysman & Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, supra note 78, at 6: “[T]he closed system sets fees directly to

the consumer and merchant, and does not use an interchange fee. However, there is an implicit interchange fee.”;

Jean Tirole, Payment Card Regulation and the use of Economic Analysis in Antitrust, 4 Toulouse School Econ., at 18

(2011): “Three-party systems use an implicit interchange fee, defined as the difference between the merchant discount

and the acquiring cost”. 81 DAVID BOAZ, THE CREDIT CARD MARKET IN ISRAEL, GENERAL ANALYSIS, CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS,

at 6 (Dec. 2009); IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL

REPORT), supra note 21, at 6 n. 16. 82 Infra ch. 8.1.2. 83 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 64, at 35: “In recent years, both American

Express and Discover have begun to allow bank issuance of their respective brands’ credit cards.”;

Semeraro, Credit Cards Interchange Fees: Three Decades of Antitrust Uncertainty, supra note 64, at 980: “American

Express and Discover now also issued credit cards nationally through banks”.

Page 25: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

25

“On-Us” Transactions

42. In open networks, acquirer of a transaction and issuer of the card in which the transaction was

executed, are not necessarily the same, but occasionally they are the same entity. Transactions

in which the acquirer and the issuer is the same entity, are called “On-Us”.84 In “On-Us”

transactions, the acquirer (which is also the issuer) keeps all the MSF for itself. The interchange

fee in On-Us transactions is virtual, as in closed networks.

43. Statistically, as more issuers and acquirers participate in an open network, the probability that

a transaction is "On-Us" decreases. When numbers of issuers and acquirers in a network

increase, the occurrence of transactions with interchange fees is more frequent.

Price Level and Price Structure

44. Price Level is the total sum of the MSF and the cardholder fee in a card transaction. In this

work Pm stands for MSF (price for the merchant), and Pc stands for cardholder's fee. Issuers

collect Pc and acquirers collect Pm. The price level is therefore the sum Pm+Pc.

Price structure is the distribution of the price level between cardholders and merchants. The

price structure is the ratio between the price each side pays and the total price level. Formally,

if the price level is Pm+Pc then the price structure is Pm/ (Pc+Pm): Pc/ (Pc+Pm). For example, if the

MSF is Pm=5 and Pc is 1 then the price level is 6, and the price structure is 1:5. The merchant

pays 5/6 of the price and the cardholder pays 1/6.

45. The price structure is a concept that presents a major difference between ordinary products and

two-sided products like payment cards.85 In ordinary products the price level influences the

demand for the product. When the price increases, demand decreases, and vice versa. In two-

sided markets, a major additional factor that affects demands is the price structure between the

different customers who consume the asset.86

84 Visa core rules and visa product and service rules, at 758 (October 2014): “On-Us Transaction - A Transaction where

an individual Member, represented by one Visa Business ID (BID), both: ● Holds an issuing license and has issued the

Visa Card used in the Transaction ● Holds an acquiring license and acquired the corresponding Merchant volume". 85 For expansion on two sided products see infra ch. 7.1.2. 86 Id., see also ¶¶ 446-447.

Page 26: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

26

46. Firms that operate in the payment card industry must determine not only the price level, but

also the price structure i.e., how much cardholders pay compared to merchants.87 The

interchange fee is a major component in this decision, as will be elaborated widely below.

The International Organizations

47. Branded cards carry the logo of international organizations such as Diners Club in closed

networks or Visa and MasterCard in open networks. The brand ascribes the card to the

international network of the organization, and thus expands the borders of acceptance to every

merchant around the globe that accepts that brand’s cards.

48. Visa and MasterCard both operated until about a decade ago as not-for-profit associations that

granted financial institutions licenses to issue and acquire cards. Legally, Visa and MasterCard

were joint ventures between competitors.88

Both Visa and MasterCard changed their structures and became public companies. In 2006,

MasterCard Inc. issued its shares on the New York Stock Exchange ("NYSE").89 In 2008, Visa

amalgamated its operations in the U.S. and Canada into a public company, Visa Inc., registered

in San Francisco and traded in New York.90 Visa Europe continued to operate as a not-for-profit

association, owned by its member banks. However, in November 2015 Visa Inc. acquired Visa

Europe for a total value of up to €21.2 billion.91 After their re-organization, both Visa and

MasterCard claimed that interchange fee is no longer a product of collusion, but a unilateral

decision. Their claims were rejected. The structural changes to a unilateral entity have not

allowed Visa or MasterCard to escape the scope of antitrust law with respect to interchange

fees.92

87 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets, 1 J. EUR. ECON. ASS'N 990 (2003):

"Under multi-sidedness, platforms must choose a price structure and not only a price level for their service". 88 United States v. Visa, 163 F. Supp. 2d 322 (S.D.N.Y 2001): "MasterCard and Visa are structured as open, joint

venture associations with members (primarily banks) that issue payment cards, acquire merchants who accept payment

cards, or both... They do not have stock, or shareholders; just members and membership interests… MasterCard and

Visa are operated as not-for-profit associations and are supported primarily by service and transaction fees paid by their

members". 89 MasterCard Corporate Overview http://phx.corporate-ir.net/External.File?item=UGFyZW50SUQ9NjQ1MzZ8Q2hpbGRJRD0tMXxUeXBlPTM=&t=1 90 http://corporate.visa.com/about-visa/our-business/visa-inc-and-visa-europe.shtml (last visited 5.7.15). 91 Visa Europe, Press Release, Visa Inc. to Acquire Visa Europe (Nov. 2, 2015) 92 See infra ¶ 690.

Page 27: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

27

49. American Express was established in 1850. It is a public company traded in the NYSE.93 Diners

Club was purchased in 2008 by Discover Financial Services Inc., whose shares are also traded

on the NYSE. Before this merger, Discover operated a payment card network under the brand

name “Discover”.

50. The international organizations do not engage directly with either cardholders or merchants.

They grant licenses to financial institutions to issue and acquire payment cards that bear the

brand’s name.94 Both Visa and MasterCard have over 20,000 licensees worldwide, which are

permitted to issue and acquire their cards.95

Isracard, LeumiCard and CAL are licensees of Visa Europe to issue and acquire Visa cards,

and are also licensees of MasterCard Inc. to issue and acquire MasterCard cards.96 Licensees

are members of the international organizations. Their relations with the international

organizations are stipulated in the rules of the international organizations, to which sometimes

a direct and specific agreement is added. Generally, the international organizations do not

intervene in the commercial relations of members with their customers, i.e., cardholders and

merchants. The discretion to shape the commercial relations with merchants and cardholders is

determined by the licensees.97

51. International organizations operate infrastructure systems designed to process, route, connect

and authorize transactions between different members who are not directly linked, such as in

international transactions. Transactions between issuers and acquirers who are not from the

same country are executed via the international infrastructure of the organization that integrates

93 DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND

BORROWING, 13 (2d ed. 2005). 94 Ibid: "MasterCard does not actually issue cards to anyone nor does it sign up merchants itself. Its customers are

banks-some issue cards, some service merchants, and some do both". 95 EC, INTERIM REPORT, supra note 79, at 96: “Visa has over 21000 member banks worldwide and over 5000 members

in Europe. MasterCard reports approximately 25300 member banks worldwide." 96 Annual reports of Isracard for 2014, at 7, https://www.isracard.co.il/report/120021424.pdf LeumiCard Annual Report for 2014, at 12 https://www.leumi-card.co.il/he-il/GeneralPages/Documents/100331424.pdf CAL Annual Report for 2014, at 18. 97 Dennis W. Carlton & Alan S. Frankel, The Antitrust Economics of Credit Card Networks, 63 ANTITRUST L.J. 643

(1995): "Visa and MasterCard members collectively set rules on how they can communicate with each other and how

they can settle financial transactions. The members also collectively set membership rules and the interchange fee they

will charge each other. There are no collectively set rules on what merchant discount a merchant bank can charge. Nor

are there any rules on what a card-issuing bank can charge a customer for finance charges or annual fees, or on how

aggressive the banks can be in promotional activity to acquire new customers from other card-issuing banks or from the

general population.";

Christian Ahlborn, Howard H. Chang & David S. Evans, The Problem of Interchange Fee Analysis: Case without a

Cause? 2 PAYMENT CARD REV. 183, 187 (2004): "Members compete with each other for services to cardholders and

have total discretion in setting card fees and interest rates, as well as other parameters of their service; in the same way,

members compete for services to merchants for which they set their prices (merchant discounts)".

Page 28: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

28

with the local infrastructure. In Israel, the sole infrastructure for routing local transactions

belongs to SHVA.98 In countries that do not have their own internal infrastructure, the

international organization itself also provides the internal infrastructure.99

52. The international organizations determine default interchange fees. The default interchange fee

applies unless agreed otherwise in a specific agreement.100 Therefore a cardholder that holds a

card issued by a bank in country A can purchase assets from a merchant in country B, whose

acquirer has no direct relations with the issuer.

53. Bylaws of the international organizations set rules that govern transactions. Those rules apply

by default unless issuers and acquirers decide otherwise. The rules shape the framework of card

transactions, such as the duty of the issuer to remit to the merchant (via the acquirer) the

consideration for transactions made by a holder of a card issued by the issuer.101 The bylaws

also set forth the duty of the acquirer, which is assigned to the merchant (in the merchant

agreement),102 to honor all cards that bear that brand’s name. This rule is called the “Honor All

Cards Rule” or in short: “HAC”.103 Another rule prohibits merchants from surcharging

customers that wish to pay with the brand’s card. This rule is called “No Surcharge Rule” or in

short: “NSR”.104 These rules apply by default unless determined otherwise. I will elaborate on

these merchant restraints in Chapter 11.2 below.

54. The international organizations provide additional services to their members, especially

regarding characteristic common to all members. The international organizations dictate

98 Infra ch. 8.1.7. 99 IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note

21, at 6 n.14. 100 U.S GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., GAO-08-558, CREDIT AND DEBIT CARDS: FEDERAL ENTITIES ARE TAKING

ACTIONS TO LIMIT THEIR INTERCHANGE FEES, BUT ADDITIONAL REVENUE COLLECTION COST SAVINGS MAY EXIST, at 2

n.4 (2008): "The default interchange rates apply when there are no other interchange fee arrangements in place between

an issuer and an acquirer". 101 For example, article 7.3 of Visa International Operating Regulations Core Principles, available at http://corporate.visa.com/_media/visa-international-operating-regulations-core-principles.pdf determines: "Issuers are financially responsible for transactions that are accepted by the merchant as defined in the Visa

Operating Regulations, and properly processed by the acquirer”. See also supra ¶ 19. 102 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 64, at 13: “Although contracts are written

only between the network and its issuers and acquirers, merchants and processors must also comply with the network

rules or risk losing access to that network”. 103 Visa International Operating Regulations Core Principles, supra note 101, Article 6.2: "Visa merchants may not

refuse to accept a Visa product that is properly presented for payment, for example, on the basis that the card is foreign-

issued, or co-branded with the merchant’s competitor's mark". See also Article 9.11 of MasterCard Merchant Rules

(Apr. 7 2006). 104 Visa International Operating Regulations Core Principles, Id. article 6.3: "Visa merchants agree to accept Visa cards

for payment of goods or services without charging any amount over the advertised price as a condition of Visa card

acceptance, unless local law requires that merchants be permitted to engage in such practice". See also article 9.12 of

MasterCard Merchant Rules.

Page 29: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

29

uniform standards for the magnetic stripe on the card. They also set other measures to prevent

fraud, such as the EMV standard.105 Sometimes services are performed in the international

marketing and advertisement arena, like MasterCard's sponsorship of the European soccer

champions league.106

The Graph below depicts a payment card transaction in an open (four party) network. The

example presents purchase of an asset worth 100, an interchange fee of 1 % and a MSF of 1.3%.

Explanation

• The cardholder buys an asset for 100 (horizontal top arrow between

merchant and cardholder). The issuer charges the cardholder 100 (vertical

right arrow pointing downward). Actual charging can be before the

transaction (prepaid) or parallel to the transaction (debit) or after it (credit).

The issuer remits to the acquirer 99 and keeps 1 as interchange fee for itself

(lower horizontal arrow between issuer and acquirer). The acquirer remits

to the merchant 98.7, meaning that 1.3 is the MSF and 0.3 is the acquiring

fee (left vertical arrow between merchant and acquirer).

• If the scheme above were to depict a transaction in a closed network or an

On-Us transaction, the two rectangles of the issuer and acquirer would

unite to one. The interchange fee would then become notional.

105 Infra ch. 8.1.5. 106 Ahlborn et al., The Problem of Interchange Fee, supra note 97, at 187: “The co-operative (the Visa or MasterCard

organization) is responsible for managing aspects of the card system from which all members can benefit and which no

member could do on its own.”;

Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 64, at 13: “Network operating rules cover a

broad range of activities, including merchant card acceptance practices, technological specifications for cards and

terminals, risk management, and determination of transaction routing when multiple networks are available for a given

transaction”.

Merchant

cardholder

Issuer Acquirer

100P=

100

99 – issuer to acquirer

interchange fee=1 acquirer to issuer

98.7

0.3+1

MSF

Page 30: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

30

• When there is no direct connection between the issuer and the acquirer,

such as in a tourist transaction, the horizontal arrow between them passes

through the switch and the infrastructure of the international organization

(not depicted in the graph).

3. Payment Cards Market Data

3.1. Israel

55. The number and the volume of card transactions in Israel are growing by an average rate of

more than 6% annually.107 About one third of the private consumption in Israel is made with

payment cards.108 The increase in card usage exceeds the growth in consumption, meaning that

some of the increase comes as a substitute for using cash and checks.109

56. The number of card transactions in Israel in 2015 was 1.1 billion, with a total volume of NIS

262 billion.110 Israeli cardholders use their cards for an average of 157 transactions per year

(2015).111 Average credit card transaction was of NIS 220 (2015).112 The average monthly

expense in credit cards was NIS 2,881 in 2015.113

The distribution by size and volume of transactions for the four quarters ending on June 30,

2016, is as follows:

Table 1 – Distribution of card payments by size (2015-2016)114

Number of transactions Volume of transactions (millions)

Up to NIS 50 407,623,371 10,178

NIS 50 to 100 264,398,672 19,492

NIS 100 to 200 234,781,912 34,106

NIS 200 to 500 210,519,621 63,845

NIS 500 to 1000 53,404,173 36,368

Over NIS 1000 38,969,938 98,718

Total 1,209,697,687 262,707

107 BANK OF ISRAEL, THE BANKING SYSTEM IN ISRAEL, 2015 ANNUAL REVIEW, at 29 (2016); MILRED, supra note 58, at

7; Bank of Israel, THE RED BOOK, supra note 20, at 30 & 56. 108 IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note

21, at 3. 109 BANK OF ISRAEL, THE BANKING SYSTEM IN ISRAEL, 2015 Annual Review, at 28 (2016); MILRED, supra note 58, at 1. 110 BANK OF ISRAEL, THE BANKING SYSTEM IN ISRAEL, 2015 Annual Review, at 29 (2016); Bank of Israel, Data on

banks, Chapter J (10) – credit card information, table j-6, last update 21.8.16, available at

http://www.boi.org.il/he/BankingSupervision/Data/Pages/Tables.aspx?ChapterId=9 111 BANK OF ISRAEL, THE BANKING SYSTEM IN ISRAEL, 2015 Annual Review, at 29 (2016); MILRED, supra note 58, at 2

(table 1). 112 BANK OF ISRAEL, THE BANKING SYSTEM IN ISRAEL, 2015 Annual Review, at 29 (2016). 113Id. see also MILRED, supra note 58, at 7 (table 3). 114 Bank of Israel, Data on banks, Chapter J (10) – credit card information, table j-6

http://www.boi.org.il/he/BankingSupervision/Data/Pages/Tables.aspx?ChapterId=9

Page 31: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

31

57. By the end of 2015 there were 7.6 million active payment cards in Israel (a card is considered

active if used at least once a quarter).115 In recent years the market share of non-bank cards has

increased. About 30% of cards are currently non-bank cards.116 CAL estimates that more than

90% of the adult population is holding payment cards. Average is two cards per adult.117

According to the Central Bureau of Statistics, 14% of cardholders hold 3 cards or more.118

The number of points of sale (POS) in which a payment card transaction can be executed has

increased more than 5% annually. In 2008, card payments could be performed at 99,793 points

of sale in Israel. By the end of 2014, the number of POSs jumped to 133,985 at about 70,000

card-accepting merchants.119 This means that most merchants who accept payment cards use a

single point of sale (POS). Large merchants usually have multiple points of sale.

58. Isracard is the Israel's largest payment card firm, with a combined market share of 45%

(including American Express (5%) and Isracart (15%)). CAL (including Diners Club (4%) and

Leumi Card possessed market shares of 27% and 28% respectively.120 The volumes of

transaction for each firm are shown at table 2.

Table 2 – transactions volume for (millions NIS, 2014)121

Volume of transactions %

LeumiCard 63,932 28

CAL 61,578 27

Isracard 100,916 45

Isracard, LeumiCard and CAL all issue and acquire both MasterCard and Visa cards. Isracard

used to operate its own proprietary card, "Isracart", as a closed network. In 2012 Isracard was

forced to "open" Isracart to cross-acquiring by LeumiCard and CAL.122 American Express (5%)

and Diners Club (4%) operate as closed networks. American Express is operated solely by

Isracard and Diners solely by CAL.123

115 BANK OF ISRAEL, THE BANKING SYSTEM IN ISRAEL, 2015 ANNUAL REVIEW, at 28 (2016). 116 Ibid, see also Bank of Israel, Data on banks, Chapter J (10) – credit card information, table j-1 117 CAL, 2014 Annual Report, at 8. 118 Central Bureau of Statistics, Financial Literacy Survey: The Financial Situation of Israelis and how they Manage it

(Sept. 11, 2012), available at http://www.cbs.gov.il/reader/newhodaot/hodaa_template.html?hodaa=201225240 . 119 Bank of Israel, THE RED BOOK (2014), supra note 20, at 56 (table 6); THE COMMITTEE FOR REDUCING THE USE OF

CASH (LOCKER COMMITTEE), INTERIM REPORT, at 10 (may 2014); C.A.L Annual Report for 2014, at 8. 120 MILRED, supra note 58, at 7 (table 4). 121 2014 annual reports of the Israeli payment card firms. 122 Infra ch. 8.1.2 (Regulation of Isracard). 123 DAVID BOAZ, CREDIT CARD MARKET IN ISRAEL, GENERAL ANALYSIS, CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, at 6

(Dec. 2009)

Page 32: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

32

59. By the end of 2014, LeumiCard had issued 2.359 million valid cards, of which 1.946 million

were active.124 CAL had issued 1.422 million valid cards, of which 1.212 million active

cards.125 Isracard had issued 3.638 million valid cards, of which 2.924 million were active.126

This is summarized by the table below:

Table 3 - number of cards (2014) in thousands

Number of valid cards Of which, number of active cards

LeumiCard 2,359 1,946

CAL 1,422 1,212

Isracard 3,368 2,924

Total 7,149 6,082

60. The payment card sector is very profitable, even relative to other profitable sectors in the

financial industry. Payment cards are responsible to a substantial part of the total profits of their

controlling banks. In 2012, the average ROE (return on equity) of the payment card firms was

20.8% (after correction due to over-payments to their controlling banks). This rate of return

was more than double the ROE in the financial sector, which was only 8.9%.127 Former Study

also found that the payment card sector yields more than double the rate of profits than the

average in the financial industry.128

61. The total income of the three payment card companies in 2014 exceeded NIS 4 billion, of which

almost NIS 1 billion was profit:

Table 4 –income, expenses and profit for 2015 (NIS millions)129

Total Income Total Expenses Profit

CAL 1,240 999 241

Leumi Card 1,052 796 258

Isracard (+Poalim express) 1,905 1,541 416

Total (all firms) 4,197 3,336 915

62. Out of the total income (NIS 4,197 million), the total income from cardholders was NIS1,619

million and from merchants NIS 1,919 million and together NIS 3,538 million. The remainder

is mainly interest on loans to cardholders and merchants. All three firms report that interest on

credit to cardholders is a growing source of income.130 The income of the issuing side (including

interchange fee) was NIS 3,106 million. The income of the acquiring side (after deducting the

124 LeumiCard 2014 Annual Report, at 15. 125 CAL Annual Report for 2014, at 13. 126 Isracard Annual Report for 2014, at 12. 127 MILRED, supra note 58, at 9 (table 9). 128 CHERTOF & TZADIK, supra note 1, at 11. 129 Bank of Israel, Data on banks, Chapter J (10) – credit card information, tables j-11, j-12, available at

http://www.boi.org.il/he/BankingSupervision/Data/Pages/Tables.aspx?ChapterId=9 130 CAL annual report, at 11 (2014); LeumiCard annual Report, at 17 (2014); Isracard annual Report, at 13 (2014).

Page 33: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

33

interchange fees) was NIS 935 million.131 However, without deducting the interchange fees, the

MSF makes up the bulk of the income of the payment card companies. Despite reduction from

77% in 2005, still 65% of payment card firms' income in 2015 came from merchants.132 The

MSF in 2015 was approximately NIS 2.5 billion (NIS 2,420,000,000).133

The interchange fee (including the notional interchange fee in On-Us transactions) is a major

part of the MSF, as can be seen in the table below.

Table 5- MSF and interchange fee for 2014 (NIS millions)134

MSF Interchange fee135

CAL 587136 418

Leumi Card 596137 431

Isracard 1,376138 778

Total (all firms) 2,559 1627

63. The average annual cardholder fee in Israel for 2013 was NIS 81.6, with Isracard being the

cheapest (56.4 NIS), CAL being the most expensive (NIS 114), and LeumiCard close to the

average with an average annual cardholder fee of NIS 80.4. It is interesting to note that the

cardholder fee varies significantly according to the bank in which the cardholder manages her

account. Generally, cardholders who belong to Discount Bank or Bank Hapoalim or Bank

Leumi, pay more than cardholders who manage their accounts in other banks. The probable

reason is that the firms treat cardholders who manage their accounts in the controlling bank of

the issuer, as "captive" customers.139

131 Bank of Israel, Data on banks, TableX-13 consolidated income statements 2014-2015, available at

http://www.boi.org.il/he/BankingSupervision/Data/Pages/Tables.aspx?ChapterId=12 132 BANK OF ISRAEL, THE BANKING SYSTEM IN ISRAEL, 2015 Annual Review, at 33, diagram 7 (2016). 133 Bank of Israel, Data on banks, table X-5 (last visited October 29, 2016) 134 Ibid and annual reports of the payment card companies for 2014. 135 Interchange fee out of the MSF, including notional interchange fee in on-us transactions. 136 Sheet L65 of C.A.L Annual Report for 2014, CAL Annual Report for 2014 137 Sheet L65 of LeumiCard Annual Report for 2014. LeumiCard 2014 Annual Report 138 Sheet L65 of Isracard and Hapoalim Express 2014 annual reports 139 MILRED, supra note 58, at 10-11 (table 10, diagrams 2-5).

Page 34: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

34

3.2. Worldwide

64. The picture worldwide is not very different, and reveals that payment cards are flourishing

worldwide. Their adoption and usage are increasing yearly.140 A major difference between

Israel and the world is that worldwide debit cards are much more popular.141

According to Visa's 10-K (annual report for the year ending Sept. 2014), Visa is the largest

payments network, far ahead of its competitors:

Table 6 – world market shares142

Payments Volume ($ billions)

Number of transactions (billion)

Number of cards (million)

Visa 4,383 89.7 2,219

MasterCard 2,991 52.7 1,281

American Express 940 6.4 107

Discover 127 2.2 64

JCB 176 1.9 83

Diners Club 26 0.2 6

65. According to the 2015 Nilson Report, Visa has a worldwide market share of 58% ($112.1

billion). MasterCard has a market share of 26% ($51.52 billion). The world's third largest

payment card is Chinese UnionPay, with 10% market share. Union-Pay licensed LeumiCard to

acquire its cards beginning in 2015.143 American Express has a market share of 3%. The next

table illustrates these market shares:

Table 7 – Purchase Transaction Worldwide (billions, 2014)144

140 Wilko Bolt & Heiko Schmiedel, SEPA, Efficiency, and Payment Card Competition (DNB Working Paper 239/2009);

Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 67, at 8-9; RONALD J. MANN, CHARGING

AHEAD: THE GROWTH AND REGULATION OF PAYMENT CARD MARKETS, 52 (2006); Committee on Payment and

Settlement Systems, Statistics on Payment, Clearing and Settlement Systems in the CPSS Countries, (Sept. 2014)

http://www.bis.org/cpmi/publ/d120.pdf ; Market data can be also found at Ben Woolsey & Matt Schulz, Credit Card

Statistics, Industry Facts, Debt Statistics 2011, available at http://www.creditcards.com/credit-card-news/credit-card-industry-facts-personal-debt-statistics-1276.php; see also http://www.paymentssource.com ;

http://www.statista.com/topics/1598/debit-cards/ ; http://www.euromonitor.com/financial-cards-and-payments (Last visited Oct. 28, 2016). 141 IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note

21, at 8 (table); Andrew T. Ching & Fumiko Hayashi, Payment Card Rewards Programs and Consumer Payment

Choice, 34 J. BANK. FIN. 1773, 1773 (2010): "Most consumers in the United States already have both credit and debit

cards” 142 Visa Inc. Annual Report (Form 10-k) for the Fiscal Year Ended on Sept. 30, 2014, at 10

http://investor.visa.com/files/doc_downloads/annual%20meeting/2014/817762_BMK1.pdf 143 LeumiCard 2014 Annual Report, at 12. 144 http://www.nilsonreport.com/publication_chart_and_graphs_archive.php?1=1&year=2015

Page 35: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

35

66. In 2013 Visa debit had a market share of 38.3%. Visa credit had a market share of 22.1%.

MasterCard debit had 12.4%. MasterCard credit had 14.4%, as illustrated below:

Table 8 – Market Shares Transactions by Types of Cards (2013)145

67. Debit is the fastest growing payment instrument. In the U.S., since 2005, debit transactions have

exceeded those of credit.146 The total value of debit card transactions was $1.8 trillion in 2011.147

The Nilson Report predicts that Visa credit will grow in the next years from $ 26.2 billion to $

66 billion, whereas Visa debit will grow from $42.6 billion to $114.1 billion. MasterCard credit

will grow from $17.5 billion to $43.1 billion, whereas MasterCard debit will grow from $10.7

billion to $47.8 billion:148

Table 9 – Predicted Growth in Transactions

145 http://www.nilsonreport.com/publication_chart_and_graphs_archive.php?1=1&year=2014 146 Kjos, The Merchant-Acquiring Side, supra note 47, at 16: “[T]he number of Visa and MasterCard offline debit

transactions exceeded the number of credit card transactions in 2005”. 147 Hayashi, The New Debit Card Regulations: Effects on Merchants, Consumers, and Payments System Efficiency,

supra note 30, at 114: "According to the Fed. Res. Board (2012), the total value of debit card transactions was $1.8

trillion in 2011". 148 Nilson Report, 2015.

Page 36: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

36

68. Payment card transactions are used in Israel for about a third of total private consumption. This

puts Israel at a relatively high level of card usage. However, debit usage in Israel is negligible,

compared to credit cards. In Israel, debit consists only 1.4% of total card transaction. This is

contrary to its wide dispersion in other countries, as the Israeli Antitrust Authority has found.149

Table 10 – Overall payment card usage out of private consumption (left axis) and level of

debit usage out of all payment cards (right axis)

69. Among Visa and MasterCard credit and debit cards, the top issuers in 2013 by purchase volume

were all American banks: (1) Chase (2) Bank of America (3) Wells Fargo (4) Citi (5) Capital

One.150

149 IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note

21, at 8. 150 Nilson Report, 2013. See also: http://www.relbanks.com/rankings/top-credit-card-issuers ;

http://www.cnbc.com/id/36471668

Page 37: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

37

70. The acquiring side is less concentrated. All acquirers are financial institutions that are also

issuers or connected by ownership bonds to issuers. First Data, which is a major acquirer, is

connected to Wells Fargo and several other banks.151 Vantiv, top international acquirer which is

a public company, is an affiliate of Fifth Third bank,152 a major payment card issuer.153 Other top

international acquirers are shown below:154

151 Kjos, The Merchant-Acquiring Side, supra note 47, at 15: “JP Morgan Chase’s merchant-acquiring business, Chase

Payment Solutions, Sun Trust, PNC, and Wells Fargo are a few of First Data’s partners”; First Data 2014 Annual

Report (10-K), at 16: “Under the alliance program, a bank or other institution form an alliance with us, either

contractually or through a separate legal entity.”; id. at 74: “A substantial portion of the Company’s business within the

Merchant Solutions and International segments is conducted through merchant alliances. Merchant alliances are

alliances between the Company and financial institutions. The formation of each of these alliances generally involves

the Company and the bank contributing contractual merchant relationships to the alliance and a cash payment from one

owner to the other to achieve the desired ownership percentage for each"; id. at 97: “The alliance acquires credit and

debit card transactions from merchants”; at 147: “Wells Fargo Merchant Services, LLC (the “Company”) is a joint

venture between First Data Merchant Services Corporation (“FDMS”) and Wells Fargo Bank, N.A. (“Wells Fargo”)...

The Company is engaged in processing and funds transfer related to the authorization, processing, and settlement of

credit and debit card transactions for merchants... The Company is operationally dependent on both FDMS and Wells

Fargo... The Company’s funding and settlement are primarily conducted through Wells Fargo. The majority of the bank

accounts used for daily operations are with Wells Fargo”. 152 Fifth Third Bank Affiliated Companies https://www.53.com/about/affiliated-companies/ 153 Fifth Third Bank > Home >Bank >Credit Cards https://www.53.com/personal-banking/credit-cards/ 154 Nilson Report, 2015 http://www.nilsonreport.com/publication_chart_and_graphs_archive.php?1=1&year=2015 . See

also

http://webcache.googleusercontent.com/search?q=cache:http://www.thestrawgroup.com/sites/default/files/downloads/T

SG-Directory-of-U.S.-Acquirers-Preview.pdf ; http://www.thestrawgroup.com/sites/default/files/downloads/TSG-

Directory-of-U.S.-Acquirers-Preview.pdf

Page 38: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

38

71. Revenues from global credit card issuing are estimated to increase from $328 billion in 2011 to

$445 billion in 2016.155

4. History of Payment cards and Interchange Fees

72. The history of payment cards, as well as the history of money in general - coins, bills,

promissory notes and checks - albeit fascinating, exceeds the scope of this work.156 I will focus

on the historical aspects of the interchange fees that are relevant to this work.

All payment instruments must overcome a basic problem. They must be attractive to both

buyers and sellers. A payment instrument that is attractive to buyers, but which sellers do not

accept, is ultimately worthless, and vice versa. There must be a critical mass of both buyers and

sellers, who find it worthwhile to use a certain payment instrument, in order for it to become

viable. As for national currency, the law mandates that it be accepted as payment. This is the

foundation of its attractiveness to both buyers and sellers. Thus, the law prevents any lack of

attractiveness to the national currency. The Bank of Israel Law determines that the NIS is legal

tender in Israel according to its par value.157 Any buyer should be able to pay with legal tender

and any seller must accept the legal tender.

In the U.S., the Federal Reserve Act states that Federal Reserve notes shall be receivable by all

155 SRIKANTH VERMA & SATYANARAYANA REDDY, GLOBAL CREDIT CARD INDUSTRY: ISSUES AND CHALLENGES, at 22

(July 2014): "The revenues from global credit card issuing will increase from $328 billion in 2011 to $445 billion in

2016". 156 For expansion, Alan S. Frankel, Monopoly and Competition in the Supply and Exchange of Money 66 ANTITRUST

L.J. 313 (1998); William F. Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper: Legal and Economic Perspectives 26

J.L. ECON. 541 (1983); EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND

BORROWING, supra note 93. 157 Bank of Israel Law (2010), article 41(b)

Page 39: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

39

banks, for all uses.158 However, this obligation is not imposed on private businesses, unless

there is a state law which says otherwise.159

73. Other payment instruments, which are not so lucky to have the law as their promoter, must fight

for their place in the payments arena to maintain viability and survive the evolutionary process

of competition.

Payment cards are private payment instruments. No seller or buyer is under any obligation to

accept, hold or use them. To be viable, payment cards must reach a critical mass and be

sufficiently attractive to both buyers and sellers. The simultaneous appeal to two target groups

of customers has been the key to the progress of all kinds of payment instruments since ancient

coins were minted, through promissory notes, bank notes and eventually, payment cards.160

74. Credit cards were the first kind of payment cards. They were developed in the U.S. in the middle

of the 20th century. Credit cards were actually a development of store credit that merchants

gave their trusted customers.161

In 1950, Diners Club presented the first closed (3-party) credit card payment network. Diners

Club contracted in issuing agreements with cardholders on one side, and in acquiring

agreements with merchants on the other side. The target cardholders were mostly affluent

customers. Merchants were mostly hotels and travel agencies. Diners Club cards were honored

by numerous merchants in the New York vicinity. Diners did not charge cardholder fee for an

initial period. After introductory period with zero cardholder fees, Diners Club charged a fixed

annual cardholder fee of a few dollars. Diners Club did not impose any per-transaction fee on

cardholders. Usage fee was zero. On the other side, merchants paid a MSF of 7%.162

158 Section 31 U.S.C. 5103, entitled "Legal tender" determines: "United States coins and currency (including Federal

reserve notes and circulating notes of Federal reserve banks and national banks) are legal tender for all debts, public

charges, taxes, and dues; See also Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, available at

http://www.federalreserve.gov/faqs/currency_15197.htm : "The Act states that Federal Reserve notes "shall be

obligations of the United States and shall be receivable by all national and member banks and Federal reserve banks and

for all taxes, customs, and other public dues". 159 Board of Governors Fed. Reserve System, http://www.federalreserve.gov/faqs/currency_12772.htm: "There is,

however, no Federal statute mandating that a private business, a person, or an organization must accept currency or

coins as payment for goods or services. Private businesses are free to develop their own policies on whether to accept

cash unless there is a state law which says otherwise". 160 For expansion on two sided network products see infra ch. 7.1. 161 Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper, supra note 156, at 572; Semeraro, Credit Cards Interchange

Fees: Three Decades of Antitrust Uncertainty, supra note 64, at 965; "Merchants had long extended a month or two of

interest-free credit to their regular customers." 162 EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND BORROWING, supra note 93,

at 54.

Page 40: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

40

75. American Express entered the market in 1958. American Express too, derived the bulk of its

revenues and profits from merchants. That same year, Bank of America, which is the ancestor

of Visa, also began to operate a closed network.163

76. Cardholders of the first networks were required to pay for their purchases approximately one

month after the purchase.164 Cardholders, who paid their full balance on time, were effectively

being paid a sum which reflected the free funding period between the date of their purchases

and the date on which they actually paid for them. Cardholders who repaid their balance over

longer periods paid interest on the balance.165 Until today, worldwide, to attract new cardholders

and encourage card usage, most card schemes set a teaser price structure whereby cardholders

do not pay for the cards, especially for an initial period, and receive rewards for card usage.166

Among the main benefits cards yielded merchants were the payment guarantee (the issuer is

responsible to pay the merchant, even if the issuer cannot collect the money from the

cardholder),167 and the ability for merchants, who accepted credit cards, to expand sales at the

expense of their competitors. The reason was twofold: first, customers who bought assets from

a certain merchant did not need to purchase similar assets from competitors. Second, accepting

cards allowed merchants to make sales to illiquid customers, who but for the card, would not

have made those purchases, at least not at that time period.168

77. Cards reduced the risk of merchants from providing unsecured store-credit to customers.

Moreover, with the growth in trade and mobility, the number of occasional customers, who

sought to purchase with credit, increased. Merchants feared to grant credit to customers whom

they did not know. Guaranteed payment cards solved this problem for them. Cards acceptance

increased the proceeds of merchants who accepted them, at the expense of those who did not.

163Id. at 59. 164 Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper, supra note 156, at 572. 165 David S. Evans & Richard Schmalensee, The Economics of Interchange Fees and their Regulation: An Overview,

Payments System Research Conferences 73, 80 (2005): "Then, as now, cardholders who paid their bills within a

specified amount of time (usually a bit less than a month) did not pay any fee for charging and in fact benefited from the

float. Those who financed their store card charges paid interest, of course". 166 Fumiko Hayashi, Payment Card Interchange Fees and Merchant Service Charges - an International Comparison, 1

LYDIAN PAYMENT J. 6 (2010), at 15-16; for expansion see infra ch. 6.7. 167 Infra ¶¶ 87-88, 489. 168 Sujit Chakravorti & Ted To, A Theory of Credit Cards, 25 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 583, 584 (2007): "Merchants benefit

from sales to illiquid consumers who would otherwise not be able to make purchases".

Page 41: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

41

78. The MSF in the early days of the payment card networks stood at 5% to 10%.169 On the other

side, cardholders enjoyed a convenient means of payment, which saved them the need to carry

cash. Cards also released cardholders of liquidity constraints, so that they could pay with funds

that they did not yet possess at the time of the transaction.170

4.1. Historical Development of Open Networks

79. In my view, the development of open networks is not trivial. Theoretically antitrust authorities

could object to their creation. Open networks are actually cooperation between competitors that

includes an element of price fixing. Open networks involve cooperation between banks, which

generally ought to compete against each other. Instead, they agree to cooperate and acquire

cards issued by their rivals, or issue cards that are acquired by their rivals in consideration for

coordinated fees. This is not trivial.

80. Ironically, the main reason for this cooperation, which developed into contemporary open

systems such as Visa and MasterCard, was banking regulations. In the 1960s, U.S. banking

laws prohibited banks from acting outside their state of registry. Banks that desired to increase

the circulation of their cards beyond the borders of their state of registration, had to cooperate

with other banks, and grant issuing and acquiring franchises to rival banks. Franchisee banks

were entitled to acquire cards issued by their competitors, and issue cards that could be acquired

by competitors.171

81. Initially, bilateral franchise agreements stated that if the acquirer and the issuer were different

entities, then the acquirer had to remit the entire MSF to the issuer. This means that the

interchange fee was in fact equal to the MSF.172 The acquirer had no income, let alone profit.

However, in On-Us transaction (in which the acquirer and the issuer were the same

institution);173 the issuer/acquirer was entitled to bill and keep fees from both sides (the

169 Ahlborn et al., The Problem of Interchange Fee, supra note 97, at 192: “The original charge card systems in the

United States—American Express and Diners Club—charged merchant discounts in the range of 5-10 percent during

their first decade”. 170 For expansion of the costs and benefits of payment instruments see infra ch. 0. 171 Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper, supra note 156; EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC

THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND BORROWING, supra note 93, at 166. 172 Howard H. Chang, Interchange Fees in the Courts and Regulatory Authorities 1 PAYMENT CARD Rev. 13, 18 (2003):

"Under the franchise system, Bank of America did not set the fees charged to cardholders and merchants by its

licensees, so it, like the proprietary systems, needed an instrument to balance cardholder and merchant demand in its

system. It chose to require the acquirer to turn over the entire merchant discount to the issuer on a transaction where the

two banks were different. In other words, the implicit interchange fee under the Bank of America franchise system was

equal to the full amount of the merchant discount". 173 Supra ch. 2.4.1.

Page 42: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

42

merchant and the cardholder) at its own discretion.

The idea at the basis of this price structure, in which the issuer received the entire income, was

to encourage issuers to distribute cards. The entire revenue from cards was divided solely to

issuers, according to their market share on the issuing side, completely ignoring market shares

on the acquiring side. This indeed encouraged the issuance of cards. In the U.S., credit cards

were massively issued and distributed for approximately two decades. Until 1970, U.S. banks

used to mail their customers active payment cards, without customers even requesting them.174

This conduct increased the proliferation of cards among cardholders, but it had a significant

disadvantage on the other side. Acquirers did not find the business of acquiring, by itself,

attractive, and had no incentive to become acquirers. They became acquirers as an accompanied

activity to the issuing business, and because most of the acquiring in the early days of payment

cards was in “On-Us” transactions.175

82. When the volume of interchange transactions (i.e., transactions in which the issuer and the

acquirer were different institutions, and interchange fee was paid) increased, the incentive for

acquirers to operate with zero MSF decreased. Acquirers had no direct benefit from providing

free services. They had only indirect benefit, derived from their role as issuers. This price

structure also encouraged scams by acquirers, whereby they did not report all of their

transactions.176 In the terminology of this work (although this terminology was created years

later), no acquirer internalized the benefits of its free operations to the network, but each

acquirer fully well internalized the costs incurred thereby.

83. In 1970, Bank of America converted the franchise system to an open network, an association

of acquirers and issuers owned by its members. This association later changed its name to

Visa.177 In 1966 a group of other banks set up another open system, which is the forerunner of

174 ALBERT FOER, ELECTRONIC PAYMENT SYSTEMS AND INTERCHANGE FEES: BREAKING THE LOG JAM ON SOLUTIONS

TO MARKET POWER, Am. Antitrust Institute (2010): “In their early years, before MasterCard and Visa had a substantial

share of merchants, some of their big banks attempted to build a cardholder base by mass mailing live credit cards to

consumers who had not even requested them. Congress put an end to this abuse when it enacted the Unsolicited Credit

Card Act in 1970”. 175 Chang, Interchange Fees in the Courts and Regulatory Authorities, supra note 172, at 13: “However, given that most

transactions in those days were “on-us” (the issuer was also the acquirer), a bank still had significant incentives to sign

up merchants, as it would keep the entire merchant discount for “on-us” transactions”. 176 Timothy J. Muris, Payment Card Regulation and the (MIS)Application of the Economics of Two-Sided Markets, 3

COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 515 (2005); Chang, Interchange Fees in the Courts, supra note 172, at 18. 177 Chang, ibid; Evans & Schmalensee, The Economics of Interchange Fees and their Regulation, supra note 165, at 73:

“In 1970 the BankAmericard system was converted into a membership corporation, a multi-party system”.

Page 43: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

43

MasterCard.178 Those early open networks encountered a problem, which spurred the

development of the interchange fee. When the acquirer presented a transaction voucher to the

issuer of the card, the issuer had to remit the transaction sum to the merchant, via the acquirer.

The remittance process involved costs and risks for the issuer. The risks were mainly insolvency

of the cardholder or fraud, which could frustrate the ability of issuers to collect the money they

had paid to the acquirers.

84. Issuers and acquirers had to make contracts to allocate the risks of the transaction between

themselves. The contracts had to determine arrangements for allocating the risks of insolvency,

misuse and fraud against cardholders or merchants. Materialization of those risks often meant

that the party assuming them would bear their costs with no indemnification. The consideration

for the party assuming the risks had also to be determined. This was the initial motivation

underlying early interchange fee agreements.179

85. Early interchange agreements were made by banks in their double capacity as issuers and

acquirers. At first, the agreements were bilateral. Two banks regulated the terms of the contract

between them. Bilateral agreements were suitable for small networks with few issuers and

acquirers. As the networks grew, they required an ever-larger number of bilateral agreements.180

n*(n-1)/2 is the formula for the number of agreements required to cover a network, where n is

the number of participants. As numbers of members grew, too many bilateral agreements were

required.

86. In addition, two major disadvantages characterized bilateral agreements in big networks. First,

multiplicity of issuers and acquirers meant high transaction costs. Second, multiplicity of

participants caused a practical problem whenever a transaction between issuer and acquirer with

no previous arrangement occurred. Terms of such transactions, in which the issuer and the

acquirer did not have a former agreement, had to be settled. This problem intensified when

networks expanded. Bilateral agreements simply could not cover all possible transactions in the

network. Thus, it became necessary to make general default rules at the association level, to be

178 EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND BORROWING, supra note 93;

Avril McKean Dieser, Antitrust Implications of the Credit Card Interchange Fee and an International Survey, 17 LOY.

CONSUMER L. REV. 451 (2005). 179 David S. Evans, More than Money: The Development of a Competitive Electronic Payments Industry in the United

States, 2 PAYMENT CARD REV. 1 (2004). 180 Evans & Schmalensee, The Economics of Interchange Fees and their Regulation, supra note 165, at 84: “[B]ilateral

negotiations were not a practical solution in systems with many banks.”; Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of

Interchange Fees, supra note 64, at 641 n.41

Page 44: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

44

applied in instances where there was no existing agreement. For this purpose, open networks

instituted bylaws that obligated all of their members unless determined otherwise.

87. Early bylaws determined, inter alia, a default multilateral interchange fee. The default rate was

to prevail, unless otherwise provided in a bilateral agreement. Other default rules regarded risks

of fraud or insolvency.

The basic rules that were formed in these early bylaws, including the interchange fee, are still

used by credit card networks to this day. The interchange fee is paid by acquirers to issuers.

Issuers assume the risk of the payment guarantee. The payment guarantee is the liability of the

issuer to pay the merchant, through the acquirer, the transaction funds, even if the issuer is

unable to collect the money from the cardholder.181

88. The main provisions that merchants had to meet, in order to be eligible for the payment

guarantee, were passing the cards through a designated reader device, and verifying the identity

of the cardholder. Verification was initially done by comparing signatures. Merchants who

upheld these terms were entitled to receive the transaction funds, even if the money was not

collected from the cardholder due to insolvency or fraud.182

89. The bylaws were set through negotiations among members. Members were banks that

participated on both the acquiring side and the issuing side.183 At the beginning, the networks

were not biased in favor of either issuers or acquirers.184 Later, the market power of issuers in

Visa and MasterCard networks increased more than that of acquirers. The interchange fee began

181 Margaret Guerin-Calvert & Janusz a. Ordover, Merchant Benefits and Public Policy Towards Interchange: An

Economic Assessment, 4 Rev. NETWORK ECON. 384, 401 (2005): “When a payment is made with the credit card, so long

as the merchant has followed the prescribed procedures, the card issuer, not the merchant, assumes the customer credit

risk and provides a mechanism for billing and collecting payments from the merchant’s customers.";

Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 64, at 660: “The payment guarantee” refers

to the fact that a merchant receives payment even if the cardholder never pays an outstanding balance or in the event of

cardholder fraud when the issuer authorized the transaction after the merchant followed proper procedures”;

EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND BORROWING, supra note 93, at

153-54 (2nd ed. 2005). See also infra ¶ 489. 182 National Bancard Corp. (NaBanco) v. VISA 596 F. Supp. 1231, 1238 (1984): “[T]he issuer bank is ultimately

responsible for the sums due and owing from its cardholders, and thus, absent a breach of agreed procedure by the

merchant or merchant bank, the issuing bank bears the risk of default by the cardholder.”;

Evans & Schmalensee, The Economics of Interchange Fees and their Regulation, supra note 165, at 83: “As long as an

acquirer’s merchant met certain terms, such as properly authorizing transactions and checking card numbers against a

list of known fraudulent accounts, it was guaranteed payment. If a transaction turned out to be fraudulent or a consumer

failed to pay, the issuer was responsible”. 183 Semeraro, Credit Cards Interchange Fees: Three Decades of Antitrust Uncertainty, supra note 64, at 970: “In the

early days, most banks participated in both sides”. 184 Evans & Schmalensee, The Economics of Interchange Fees and their Regulation, supra note 165.

Page 45: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

45

to be determined according to the interest of issuers (even though they were also acquirers), or

directly by the networks (Visa and MasterCard) which favored the interest of issuers.185

90. It is interesting to note the excluding effect interchange fee had in extinction of competing

networks. Before Visa and MasterCard tilted in favor of issuers, some of the early networks,

which did not ultimately survive, had bylaws according to which, transactions were cleared by

issuers at par. Issuers remitted to acquirers all of the transactions' funds, meaning that the

interchange fee was zero.186 By contrast, Visa and MasterCard networks set positive and

relatively high rate of interchange fee. This caused issuing banks to cease issuing cards that did

not yield them an interchange fee, and to commence issuing cards of MasterCard and Visa that

did yield them an interchange fee. Thus, in evolutionary perspective, the interchange fee was a

mechanism that eradicated networks that operated without it. By contrast, in Europe, there are

local debit networks which were less exposed to competition from Visa and MasterCard, and

they continue to operate with zero interchange fees up to date.187

91. Initially the interchange fee was based on the estimated costs of the services that issuers

allegedly gave merchants. These included, apart from the payment guarantee, processing,

authorizing and clearing services. At that time, card transactions were executed using dedicated

"iron" POSs. The product of a transaction was a paper slip, a copy of which was given to the

cardholder. The paper slips that remained with the merchant eventually had to be converted to

money in the bank account of the merchant. Acquirers periodically collected the slips and

delivered them to the various issuers, whose cards they had acquired. Issuers would then

periodically remit to the acquirers the amounts of the slips, less the interchange fee, and charge

their customers, the cardholders, the due sums. In the networks’ early days, this process was

costly and included services that were labor-intensive and carried out mostly manually.

185 Infra note 1506. 186 EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND BORROWING, supra note 93,

at 66: “Some of the regional cooperatives had initially exchanged at par so that the cardholder’s bank reimbursed the

merchant’s bank for the entire transaction and the cardholder’s bank didn’t get any of the merchant fees”. 187 Stewart E. Weiner & Julian Wright, Interchange Fees in various Countries: Developments and Determinants, 4 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 290 (2005); Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 44, paras. 562-608;

and at para. 751: “[S]everal payment schemes in the European Economic Area have successfully been operating without

a MIF for a long time. These Schemes have been established between 1979 and 1992 and they are not merely viable but

indeed successful.";

Peter Jones, The Uncomfortable Consequences of a Universal Multi-Lateral Interchange Fee (MIF) for Europe,

PAYMENT SYS. EUROPE, at 3 (2005): "[M]any schemes were established without interchange and still operate this way

today.";

Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 67, at 11: “In 2006 there were at least four

national card schemes that operated without an MIF, namely those in Denmark, Finland, Luxemburg and the

Netherlands”. See also infra n. 1446.

Page 46: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

46

92. The consideration paid to the issuers for their services and risks they incurred was the

interchange fee. Early interchange fee rate was calculated according to the estimated costs of

issuers, their expenses, including the inherent risk of payment guarantee. The interchange fee

was essential, especially when direct channels of income, i.e., cardholder fees and interest on

credit, were low and yet undeveloped, so issuers did not have other significant sources of

revenue other than the interchange fee.

Historically, open credit card networks that did not have a positive interchange fee, did not

survive. They became extinct not because it was inherently unviable for an open network to

operate without an interchange fee, but because networks without interchange fees were less

attractive to issuers. Non-interchange-fee networks did not survive the Darwinian business

competition. Issuers preferred to issue cards that rewarded them interchange fee for every

usage, over cards that gave them nothing from usage, especially when cardholder fees and

interest on credit were degenerated revenue streams. The price structure in opened networks

that continued to operate, i.e., Visa and MasterCard, included interchange fee to the issuer.

93. The early Visa bylaws determined that, in any transaction in which the acquirer and the issuer

were not the same, the acquirer had to pay an interchange fee to the issuer at a rate of 1.95%.188

Determination of the MSF was left open to market forces, making it possible for acquirers to

earn profits from acquiring, by setting the MSF above the interchange fee.

A similar price structure also developed in closed systems (American Express and Diners Club)

that did not have an explicit interchange fee. Closed networks also revealed that it was best for

them to impose most of their costs on the merchant side.

Payment networks ultimately discovered that merchants had a greater willingness to pay for

cards than cardholders. Economically, merchants' elasticity of demand for cards is lower than

the demand elasticity of cardholders. Payment networks reacted by collecting most of their

revenue from merchants, the side with the more rigid demand. This is a basic and important

feature of two sided markets: the more-elastic side pays less and the less-elastic side with the

higher willingness to pay, bears most of the costs.189

188 EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND BORROWING, supra note 93,

at 154; Evans & Schmalensee, The Economics of Interchange Fees and their Regulation, supra note 165, at 74. 189 Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 67, at 12-13: “The imbalance in the way

card schemes allocate costs and obtain their income is caused by the lower price elasticity on the merchants’ side... As

the elasticity of demand for merchants in card payments is lower than that for cardholders, the prices for merchants are

higher than the prices for cardholders.”;

Page 47: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

47

The overall price level was lower in open systems than in closed systems.190 Both the MSF and

the cardholder fee charged by Visa and MasterCard were lower than that of American Express

and Diners Club. The lower fees gave the open networks a competitive advantage over closed

networks. The market share of Visa and MasterCard increased more than that of American

Express and Diners Club, due to higher penetration rates at the merchant side.191

94. As mentioned above, the interchange fee was initially based on an assessment of issuers’ costs.

However, growing dispersion increased market power of issuers. With it interchange fee began

to be determined based on demand factors.192 Due to their market power, payment networks

could charge interchange fees that were much higher than the issuers’ costs. The surplus of the

interchange fee above costs was used for two purposes. First, to rebate and reward cardholders,

and incentivize them to adopt and use cards even more. Second, as a source of profit for

issuers.193 The move from cost-based interchange fees to a demand-based interchange fees, is

in fact, a move from the realm of competition, where price is based on costs, to one of market

power of issuers.

95. Other contractual provisions in the early bylaws of open networks, helped to establish the

networks. The No Surcharge Rule ("NSR") prohibited merchants from charging more from

Nicole Jonker & Mirjam Plooij, Tourist Test Interchange Fees for Card Payments: Down Or Out? 1 J. FIN. MARKET

INFRASTRUCTURE 51, 54 (2013): “The assumption that merchants are relatively less price elastic compared with

consumers is commonly used as a rationale to justify that acquiring banks pay interchange fees to issuing banks, thus

raising merchant service fees for card payments and lowering consumer fees.”;

Ching & Hayashi, Payment Card Rewards, supra note 596, at 1775: “consumers are price sensitive”;

Steven Semeraro, The Antitrust Economics (and Law) of Surcharging Credit Card Transactions, 14 STAN. J. L. BUS. &

FIN. 343, 356 (2009): “Long standing practice in credit card markets appears to confirm that cardholder demand is

considerably more elastic than merchant demand.”;

Bolt & Schmiedel, SEPA, Efficiency, and Payment Card Competition , supra note 140, at 8: “Typically, merchants are

less price elastic than cardholders, and often bear the full burden of joint payment cost."

Steven Semeraro, The Economic Benefits of Credit Card Merchant Restraints: A Response to Adam Levitin, TJSL Legal

Studies Research Paper no. 1357840, at 26 (2009): “[M]erchant demand for credit cards is less elastic than consumer

demand”. 190 For expansion on price level, see supra ch. 2.4.2. 191 Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper, supra note 156, at 573; Ahlborn et al., The Problem of

Interchange Fee, supra note 97, at 192: “When the bank associations, Visa and MasterCard, entered the market and

introduced national credit card products in the mid-1960s in the United States, they wanted to expand well beyond the

traditional travel and entertainment sector. Not surprisingly, the merchant discounts for their products were much lower

than those of American Express and Diners Club. As a result, they were able to get many more merchants to sign up for

their cards.";

National Bancard Corp. (NaBanco) v. VISA 596 F. Supp. 1231, 1237 n. 8 (1984): “Annual fees [of American Express

and Diners Club – O.B] are normally much higher than those charged for the VISA or MasterCard”. 192 Chang, Interchange Fees in the Courts and Regulatory Authorities, supra note 172, at 18: “The fee was initially

based on costs but now depends significantly on demand factors as well”. 193 REPORT ON THE RETAIL BANKING SECTOR INQUIRY COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT ACCOMPANYING THE

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION - SECTOR INQUIRY UNDER ART 17 OF REGULATION 1/2003 ON RETAIL

BANKING (FINAL REPORT) [COM(2007) 33 Final] SEC(2007)106, at 100, 122 (Jan 31, 2007). See also infra ¶ 97 and

note 208.

Page 48: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

48

customers who paid with cards. The Honor All Cards Rule ("HAC") obligated merchants who

accepted cards of a particular brand (whether Visa or MasterCard), to accept all cards of this

brand, regardless the identity of the issuer.194 As a result, a MasterCard or a Visa card issued by

a small issuer is accepted with no discrimination by every merchant who accepts that card, all

over the world. These provisions helped the networks to increase proliferation worldwide.195

96. Until the 1980s cardholder fees were not common.196 In the U.S., the networks began to charge

cardholder fees as a result of the sharp increase in interest rates in the 1980s, which was

followed by legislation in several states that capped the interest rates banks could charge.

Capping the interest rates was approved by the U.S. Supreme Court in the Marquette

decision.197 The networks bypassed the interest-capping with the introduction of annual

cardholder fees.198 The Marquette decision also caused banks to move to states with fewer

interest-capping restrictions. This, in turn, led states to cancel interest-capping.199 Deregulation

during the 1990s eliminated these restrictions on interest. Again, issuers increased interest rates,

but this time, with their growing market power, they did so without giving up annual cardholder

fees.

97. The acquiring side is considered to be more competitive than the issuing side. The acquiring

business works on big volume but relatively small margins.200 Merchants are more sophisticated

customers (of acquirers) than cardholders (of issuers). This compels acquirers to act

competitively. Economies of scale exist on the acquiring side. Acquiring activities are

194 Supra ¶ 53. 195 Robert M. Hunt, An Introduction to the Economics of Payment Card Networks, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 80, 85

(2003): “The honor-all cards rule and the no-surcharge rule reduce the uncertainty consumers would otherwise face.

This was especially important in the late 1960s and 1970s, when the card associations were trying to build nationwide

acceptance of credit cards issued primarily by small banks”. 196 Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper, supra note 156, at 579. 197 Marquette Nat'l Bank v. First of Omaha Service Corp. 439 U.S. 299 (1978). 198 Carlton & Frankel, The Antitrust Economics of Credit Card Networks, supra note 97, at 648 n. 12: “Annual fees

were first introduced in the early 1980s when market interest rates moved to record highs but credit card interest rates

were constrained by usury laws”;

Christopher C. DeMuth, The Case Against Credit Card Interest Rate Regulation, 3 YALE J. ON REG. 201 (1986);

Timothy J. Muris, Payment Card Regulation, supra note 176, at 545. 199 Oren Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, 98 N.W. L. Rev. 1373, 1381-82 (2004). 200 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 64, at 633: “The U.S. acquiring market

is generally considered to be highly competitive”;

Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations,

33 RAND J. ECON. 549, 549 (2002): “The acquiring side involves little product differentiation as well as low search

costs and is widely viewed as highly competitive.”;

Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L. REV. 1321 (2008);

EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees for Card-Based Payment Transactions, COM (2013) 550, at 11

(July 24, 2013): “[A]cquiring markets tend to be more competitive than issuing markets”;

Ann Kjos, The Merchant-Acquiring Side of the Payment Card Industry: Structure, Operations, and Challenges, at 10

(F.R.B Phil' Discussion Paper 2007): "Unlike with competition for individual cardholders, acquirers have fewer ways to

differentiate their services to merchants; so price tends to be a dominant competitive factor".

Page 49: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

49

homogeneous by nature, so competition is mainly reflected in prices, i.e., the MSF.201 In

competitive markets, the pass-through rate of inputs into final prices is high. Changes in the

interchange fee are translated into parallel changes in the MSF, meaning a pass-through rate

close to 100%.202

In Israel, when the interchange fee decreased, the Israel Antitrust Authority ("IAA") initially

found that only about half of the decrease was passed-through to merchants.203 However, a later

study by Bank of Israel found that all the decrease in the interchange fee was passed through to

merchants, i.e., 100% pass through from the interchange fee to the MSF.204 Thus, pass through

takes a few years until completion. The bank noted that the full pass through indicates increased

competition.205

98. The issuing side is relatively heterogeneous with diverse customers, many kinds of cards and

often transfer barriers between firms. Issuers enjoy three major revenue streams: (1) interchange

fees; (2) interest on credit and loans; (3) cardholder fees. The issuing side is considered less

competitive and more profitable than the acquiring side.206 The pass through rate on the issuing

side, from the interchange fees to cardholders, is lower than the pass through-rate on the

acquiring side.207 Studies estimated the pass through rate on the issuing side to be less than

201 Levitin, Priceless? The Social Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 50, at 11: "Although the

acquiring market is dominated by only a few players, these players are highly competitive on price”;

Semeraro, Credit Cards Interchange Fees: Three Decades of Antitrust Uncertainty, supra note 64, at 972 ; EVANS &

SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND BORROWING, supra note 93; Howard H.

Chang, Payment Card Industry Primer, 2 PAYMENT CARD REV. 29 (2004). 202 Hayashi, A Puzzle of Card Payment Pricing, supra note 64, at 144: "In the United States, acquirers completely pass

through the interchange fee to merchants.”; Motion 34/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, para. 14 (Dec. 22,

2002); Marc Rysman & Julian Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, at 28 (2015): "Studies of the regulatory

experiment in Australia in 2003, in which interchange fees were reduced by 40 basis points in 2003, suggest a roughly

100% pass through into lower merchant fees, but that cardholder fees (net of rewards and interest-free benefits) have

increased by a more modest amount". 203 IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note

21, at 7. 204 BANK OF ISRAEL, THE BANKING SYSTEM IN ISRAEL, 2015 ANNUAL REVIEW, at 27, 30 (2016). 205 Id. at 30. 206 Infra notes 370, 1480. 207 Michael L. Katz, What do we Know about Interchange Fees and what does it Mean for Public Policy? Commentary

on Evans and Schmalensee, FRB Kansas Payments Sys. Res. Conference 121, 132 (2005): "Industry wisdom is that

most of the weight is put on issuer profits, at least in the United States, and that acquirers generally pass through a

higher percentage of fee changes to their customers than do issuers.";

EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees, supra note 200, at 10: “Consumers already pay through the

incorporation of Interchange Fees (via the MSC) in the retail prices, and banks are less likely to pass on the benefits of

the Interchange Fees to their account holders than merchants to their clients, given the lower level of competition in the

banking sector and the current lack of consumer mobility in the field of retail banking. Hence the pass through by

merchants should be greater in any case than the pass through by banks”.

Page 50: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

50

50%.208 This is in line with findings in the telephone industry, another two-sided-network

industry, in which the equivalent to the interchange fee is the "termination fee". Changes from

reducing the termination fee have been found not to be passed-through in full to calling

customers.209

4.2. History Of Debit Cards and ATMs

99. Historically, the first payment cards were credit cards, and the discussion above relates mainly

to them. Debit cards evolved in a different way. The historical development of debit cards is

important, especially since some debit card networks work with zero interchange fees.210 With

ATMs, the interchange fee is in the opposite direction, from acquirers to issuers.211

100. Debit cards are relatively new payment instruments. Debit expansion is related to its cost

effectiveness,212 but the beginning of debit is attached to the ATM networks. ATM networks

208 REPORT ON THE RETAIL BANKING SECTOR INQUIRY [COM(2007) 33 Final], supra note 193, at 101: "[A]n

econometric estimation controlling for other variables that may affect the fee per card level shows that if the

interchange fee increases by 1 Euro only 25 cents are passed on to consumers in lower fees.";

Levitin, Priceless? The Social Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 50, at 9: "Currently about 45% of

the interchange fee goes to fund rewards programs". AMY DAWSON AND CARL HUGENER, A NEW BUSINESS MODEL FOR

CARD PAYMENTS (WayToHigh.com: Diamond Management and Technology Consultants, Inc.,2008), http://waytoohigh.wordpress.com/2008/07/18/a-new-business-model-for-card-payments-via-diamond-management-technology-consultants/2006 : "Paying for issuer rewards programs consumes about 44% of interchange costs, but

merchants get nothing out of these programs; they are competitive tools for issuers.";

Scott Schuh et al., Who Gains and Who Loses from Credit Card Payments? Theory and Calibrations, at 29 (FRB of

Boston Public Policy Discussion Papers No. 10-03. 2010): "Thus, banks keep 65 percent of the revenues from

merchant fees, while consumers receive 35 percent in rewards". At 41 the writers argue that pass through rate out of

the interchange fee (as opposed to pass through rate out of the MSF), is 47%: “If we look at interchange fees instead of

merchant fees, subtracting 0.5 percent (acquiring banks' profit) from 2 percent we compute 35 percent times 4/3 ≈ 47

percent.”;

EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees, supra note 200, at 11: “[F]rom evidence in Australia, it seems that

retailers would benefit integrally (100%) from lower IFs – as acquiring markets tend to be more competitive than

issuing markets, whilst the potential increase in cardholder fees is limited to 30-40% of the amount of the interchange

fee decrease.”;

Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 64, 635 n. 28: “In the absence of perfect

competition and frictionless rebating, only a portion of interchange fee revenues are returned in this way to consumers.

Available evidence suggests that rebates, when offered, are lower than the associated interchange fee.”;

Fumiko Hayashi & Stuart E. Weiner, Interchange Fees in Australia the U.K and the United States: Matching Theory

and Practice, FRB KANSAS ECON. REV. 75, 95 (2006): “It does appear that pass through of interchange fees is 100

percent on the acquiring side, while on the issuing side it is less than 100 percent.”; see also infra note 590. 209 Wilko Bolt, Nicole Jonker & Mirjam Plooij, Tourist Test Or Tourist Trap? Unintended Consequences of Debit Card

Interchange Fee Regulation, DNB Working Paper 405, at 24 n.18 (2013): “Empirical evidence from another network

industry, i.e. the telephone industry, where termination rates were reduced as part of regulatory measures also point to

incomplete pass through of fee reductions to customers”. 210 Supra note 187. 211 David Balto, The Problem of Interchange Fees: Costs without Benefits? E.C.L.R 215, 218 (2000): “In the ATM

network environment, card-issuing banks pay ATM owners an interchange fee to compensate them for the costs of

deploying ATMs”; HAYASHI, A GUIDE TO THE ATM AND DEBIT CARD INDUSTRY, 2006 UPDATE, supra note 31. 212 Tim Mead, Renee Courtois Haltom & Margaretta Blackwell, The Role of Interchange Fees on Debit and Credit

Card Transactions in the Payments System, 11-05 FED. RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND (2011): “The economics of this

expanding network was based on cost reduction (primarily for labor associated with customer checking and savings

accounts) rather than on revenue generation as in the credit card model”.

Page 51: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

51

evolved as cheap and fast cash withdrawal systems, rather than payment networks. In the early

days of ATMs, a customer of bank A could not access her account and withdraw cash through

an ATM of bank B. In the late 1970s, banks began to connect their ATM networks, as a service

to their customers. This enabled a customer of a particular bank to withdraw cash from ATMs

of other banks in the network.213 ATM networks also allowed other banks to join. It was not

long until ATM networks integrated. This trend accelerated, and today most bank customers

can withdraw cash from any ATM worldwide. In Israel, the banks consolidated their own ATMs

through SHVA.214

101. The interchange fee in ATMs developed in the opposite direction of payment card interchange

fee. The ATM interchange fee is paid by the issuer (the bank where the account of the

withdrawing cardholder is managed) to the acquirer (the owner of the ATM). The history of

ATMs in the United States, which also applies to Israel, explains the reason for the reverse

interchange fee.

When ATM networks began to develop, ATM owners were not allowed to charge fees from

non-customers. This created a disincentive to install ATMs that served the general public.

Banks that enabled ATM withdrawals by non-customers, effectively gave a free service to

customers of other banks, and bore the associated costs and risks without any compensation.215

Interchange fee from issuer to the owner of the ATM served as consideration to ATM owners.

The interchange fee compensated ATM owners for the risks, especially fraud risks, from

providing cash to non-customers. The interchange fee thus enabled the growth of the ATM

network.216

102. In Israel, too, until the end of 2005, a price control order forbade ATM owners to charge fees

for withdrawals. As a result, the incentive to erect ATMs outside bank branches was low.217

213 FOER, ELECTRONIC PAYMENT SYSTEMS AND INTERCHANGE FEES, supra note 174: “In the late 1970s, banks began to

link their ATMs into networks that enabled each bank’s depositors to use not only his or her own bank’s ATMs to

withdraw cash but ATMs of all the banks linked in their bank’s network... and it wasn’t long before the banks in each

region figured out that it would be most convenient, and profitable, if they could offer their cardholders ATM access

anywhere in the country and then the world". 214 Infra ch. 8.1.7. 215 For expansion, James J. Mcandrews, Automated Teller Machine Network Pricing – A Review of the Literature, 2

REV. NETWORK ECON. 146 (2003). 216 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 64, at 12 n. 22: “Automated teller machine

(ATM) networks are another example where interchange fees flow in the opposite direction (i.e., card issuing banks pay

interchange fees to ATM operators for each transaction). Historically, this arrangement arose because ATM networks

prohibited ATM operators from charging transaction fees (i.e., surcharges) to ATM users whose cards were issued by

other banks. Under this restriction, interchange fees encouraged deployment of network-connected ATMs by providing

a means for ATM operators to recover their costs". 217 Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re: SHVA, at 4, Antitrust 5001307 (Nov. 5, 2008).

Page 52: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

52

Banks applied and received an exemption to a restrictive arrangement between them (as issuers

and ATM owners), whereby the bank that issued the card paid the owner of the ATM an

interchange fee of 20 cents (U.S.) per withdrawal.218

On December 13, 2005, Israel partially lifted its price controls on ATM withdrawal fees.

Owners of non-bank ATMs, and ATMs that are more than 500 meters from bank branches,

could charge fees for withdrawals.219 As a result, new players have entered the ATM market,

and a steep increase in the number of cash withdrawal points occurred, especially of non-banks

ATMs.220 This process also occurred in the U.S., when direct charges were permitted.

Incentives to install ATMs increased and the ATM market expanded.221

In my view, the deregulation should have been accompanied by a simultaneous reduction in the

ATM interchange fee, or even a complete cancellation of it. The interchange fee was originally

justified to encourage installment of ATMs, when withdrawal fees were forbidden, and ATM

owners could not recover costs. When the prohibition on direct withdrawal fee was canceled,

justification for ATM interchange fee was canceled with it. ATM owners can and do charge

direct fees for withdrawals. The anti-competitive effect of the unnecessary ATM interchange

fee is that issuers pass through the interchange fee they pay to their customers as foreign fees,

or in other ways that are not transparent. ATM interchange fee increases the price level of

banking services, but in a less transparent way than direct fees.

At the very least, the General Director should have examined the necessity of the interchange

fee for the viability of the ATM network, after the removal of the prohibition on withdrawal

fees, considering the flourishing channel of direct fees from withdrawers. This inspection

should have been a pre-condition to permit ATM interchange fee. Maintaining the interchange

218 Exemption to Five Banks - Interchange Fee in ATMs, Antitrust 3015632 (Oct. 8, 2002); Exemption with Conditions

to Five Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust 5000714 (June 17, 2004). 219 Price Ordinance (Removal of Supervision on ATMs Withdrawal Fees) 2006. See also Exemption with Conditions to

Five Banks in re: SHVA, at 4, Antitrust 5001307 (Nov. 5, 2008); Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re:

SHVA, at 7, Antitrust 5001953 (May 22, 2012). 220 Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re: SHVA, at 4, Antitrust 5001307 (Nov. 5, 2008). 221 Osborn v. Visa Inc., 797 F.3d 1057, 1060 (D.C. Cir. 2015): "Until the mid-1990s, consumers who wished to

withdraw cash from their bank accounts generally could do so only by visiting a bank branch or a bank-operated ATM.

But states began to abolish various laws that had prohibited ATM operators from charging access fees directly to

cardholders. This created a financial incentive for nonbanks to enter the ATM market, and independent ATMs took root

accordingly".

Page 53: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

53

fee should have been approved only if it was indispensable for ATM owners to operate without

interchange fees, despite charging direct fees, and to the minimal extent.222

103. In Australia, a pioneer country in regulating the interchange fee (as will be discussed below),223

since 2009 there has been no ATM interchange fee, but only direct charges for withdrawals.224

104. In the U.S, ATM interchange fee exist. A legal challenge against them failed, because of the

"indirect purchaser" doctrine.225 The Federal U.S. Supreme Court rule generally negates

indirect purchaser's standing.226 The interchange fee is interbank payment. Neither cardholders

nor merchants directly pay interchange fee in ATM transactions. Issuing banks pay it, and then

pass it to their customers, who are, in this sense "indirect purchasers". On this ground the action

was dismissed.227

In my opinion, this ruling is erroneous. The interchange fee is a restrictive arrangement of which

indirect payers (i.e., withdrawers) are injured. Unlike other inputs between buyer and seller, in

which the buyer bargains to pay less, and the seller bargains to charge more, ATM interchange

fee is a payment between banks that are payers and payees at the same time. They both have an

interest in increasing the interchange fee, and sharing the revenue according to their market

share as payees, i.e., as owners of ATMs. In their capacity as payees (ATM owners) they receive

interchange fee payments. In their role as payers (ATM card issuers), they pass the fee to their

customers, the withdrawers, e.g., as foreign fee. Antitrust injury is inflicted on withdrawers and

not issuers.

222 AT 491/98 Israel Electric Company v. Antitrust General Director, at 73 (March 22, 1999) (The Tribunal will not

approve a restrictive arrangement unless indispensable and proportional); AT 19545-04-10 Shovarei Bar v. Antitrust

General Director, at 8, 27 (Jan 24, 2012).

In Europe, indispensability is also one of the conditions for exemption, see Guidelines on the Applicability of Article

101 to Horizontal Co-Operation Agreements, O.J C 11/1, at 12 (Jan. 14, 2011): “[T]he restrictions must be

indispensable to the attainment of those objectives, that is to say, the efficiency gains”; Case T-111/08 MasterCard v.

Comm'n, para. 79 (May 24, 2012); C-382/12 P MasterCard v. European Commission, paras. 91, 107 (Sept. 11, 2014).

In the U.S. the requirement is that the restriction be reasonably necessary, see P. E. AREEDA & H. HOOVENKAMP, VII

ANTITRUST LAW 370 sec. 1505 (2d ed. 2003); FTC & DOJ, Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations among

Competitors, para. 3.36(b) (Apr. 2000); ABA 1 ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS 480 (7 ed. 2012). 223 Infra ch. 8.4. 224 Jocelyn Donze & Isabelle Dubec, ATM Direct Charging Reform: The Effect of Independent Deployers on Welfare,

10 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1 (2011): "Since March 2009, interchange fees and foreign fees have been removed and

replaced by a pricing scheme where ATM owners directly charge a fee to any cardholder who uses their ATMs.

Withdrawing money is free when the cardholder uses an ATM belonging to his or her own bank". Hugh Green,

Australia’s 2009 ATM Reforms: Transparency for Transparency’s Sake, 19 AGENDA 1 (2012). 225 In Re: ATM Fee Antitrust Litigation, 10-17354 LEXIS 14265 (C.A 9th Cir. 2012) 226 Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720 (1977). 227 Crayton v. Concord EFS, Inc. (In re ATM Fee Antitrust Litig.), 686 F.3d 741, 758 (9th Cir. Cal. 2012): "Plaintiffs

lack standing to seek damages for the alleged antitrust violations".

Page 54: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

54

Nevertheless, the Ninth circuit dismissed the claim because the plaintiffs were allegedly

"indirect purchasers", and unfortunately certiorari was denied.228 However, injured withdrawers

are forever "indirect" purchasers, whereas "direct" purchasers are never injured and would

never sue. In fact, the banks, which are purportedly direct purchasers, are part of the

"conspiracy" (in their capacity as ATM owners). Even under the "indirect purchaser doctrine",

its co-conspirator exception should have been applied. Not for vain the Illinois Brick rule has

drawn consistent criticism.229 To demonstrate the absurdity, the court's reasoning would apply

even if the interchange fee were $100 per ATM withdrawal... The narrow interpretation of the

Ninth Circuit to the exceptions of Illinois Brick was indeed criticized.230

The indirect purchaser doctrine does not apply in Europe.231 In Israel, too, the indirect purchaser

rule is not applicable. Indirect purchasers in Israel have a cause of action for damages that were

passed on to them.232

105. Getting back to the history of debit cards, when ATM networks combined, their bank members

understood that it would be possible to use the networks’ infrastructure for actual payments and

not only cash withdrawals. From there, it was a short step to the introduction of debit card

228 Brennan v. Concord Efs, 2013 U.S. LEXIS 6750 (U.S., Oct. 7, 2013) 229 ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMMISSION, REPORT AND RECOMMENDATIONS 267-274 (2007).

available at http://govinfo.library.unt.edu/amc/report_recommendation/amc_final_report.pdf ; 2A PHILLIP E. AREEDA &

HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 346d-k (3d ed. 2007); Herbert Hovenkamp, Quantification of Harm in

Private Antitrust Actions in the United States (at 209 OECD POLICY ROUNDTABLE QUANTIFICATION OF HARM TO

COMPETITION BY NATIONAL COURTS AND COMPETITION AGENCIES DAF/COMP(2011)25): "The Illinois Brick rule was

based on two premises, both of which today seem quite questionable.”;

Maarten Pieter Schinkel, Jan Tuinstra & Jacob Rüggeberg, Illinois Walls: How Barring Indirect Purchaser Suits

Facilitates Collusion, (Amsterdam Ctr. for Law & Econ. Working Paper No. 2005-02, 2008);

Edmund H. Mantell, Denial of a Forum to Indirect-Purchaser Victims of Price Fixing Conspiracies: A Legal and

Economic Analysis of Illinois Brick, 2 PACE L. REV. 153, 217 n.157 (1982); Colin Graham Fraser, An Illinois Brick

Wall without Foundation: The “Price Paid” Rule and the Roadmap to Antitrust Immunity: “[T]he “cost-plus”

exception, expressly recognized by Hanover Shoe and Illinois Brick, applies where an indirect purchaser enters into a

contract with a direct purchaser for a fixed quantity and a fixed markup." see also Paper Sys. Inc. v. Nippon Paper

Indus. Co., Ltd., 281 F.3d 629, 631 (7th Cir. 2002). 230 Marrero-Rolón v. Autoridad De Energía Eléctrica De P.R., 2015 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 134211, 36-37 (D.P.R. Sept. 28,

2015): "I disagree that this case presents an "exception" to Illinois Brick rather than a fundamentally different factual

scenario... neither In re ATM Fee or Dickson explain who, if anyone, could sue for the overcharges alleged in each

case. For these reasons, I would not follow either case to the extent it conflicts with my analysis. See Laumann v. Nat'l

Hockey League, 907 F. Supp. 2d 465, 480-83 (S.D.N.Y. 2012) (declining to follow In re ATM Fee and holding that

where the "middlemen are alleged to be co-conspirators," the first purchasers outside of the conspiracy have standing to

sue)". 231 DIRECTIVE 2014/104/EU, On Certain Rules Governing Actions For Damages Under National Law For

Infringements Of The Competition Law Provisions, article 12 O.J L 349/1 (Dec. 5, 2014): “[C]ompensation of harm can

be claimed by anyone who suffered it”. 232 CA 2616/03 Isracard v. Howard Reis, 59(5) 701, 718 (2005); Opinion of the legal advisor to the government in CA

10538-02-13 Hatzlacha v. El-Al et al. (Sept. 7, 2014); CA (Center) 46010-07-11 Ophir Naor v. Tnuva, Paras. 37-44

(April 5, 2016); CA (Center) 53990-11-13 Hazlacha v. AU, at 30 (March 6, 2016); CA 41838-09-14 Weinstein v Mifalei

Yam Hamelach (29.1.17).

Page 55: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

55

networks. A Debit transaction is routed through the ATM network. It is equivalent to a

withdrawal of the precise sum of the transaction from an ATM that is positioned at the cashier,

and immediately remitting the sum to the seller.

106. The proliferation of debit cards was rapid, due to the simple fact that all ATM cardholders are

automatically debit cardholders. Debit card networks therefore had to establish themselves only

on the merchant side. This was relatively easy to achieve. Debit networks could offer a lower

MSF because debit transactions are cheaper than credit transactions.233 In particular the cost of

the payment guarantee is lower in debit transactions compared to credit, because payment is

settled immediately. Risk of default by the cardholder is much smaller. With credit cards, the

payment guarantee is proportional, because the risk increases directly with the amount of the

transaction and the length of the credit period, which does not exist in debit.

Merchants that wanted to accept debit cards had to connect to the debit infrastructure which

was different than the credit infrastructure. Merchants also had to adjust their POSs for reading

and processing debit transactions. PIN debit POSs include smart terminals which identify the

cardholder by entering the PIN code, and not by signature.

To convince merchants to accept debit and make the required investment, early debit networks

offered a MSF low as 0% (i.e., acquiring at par value).234 Merchants had an incentive to invest

the initial lump sum and there-after enjoy a cheap payment instrument relative to credit cards.

107. After debit card circulation had grown to exceed critical mass and become viable, debit

networks began to charge a MSF of a few tens of cents per transaction (as opposed to the

proportional MSF applicable to credit card transactions). The MSF for debit reflects mainly the

processing and authorization costs. Those costs are not dependent on the sum of the transaction.

233 Infra ¶ 125. 234 David S. Evans, Robert E. Litan & Richard Schmalensee, Economic Analysis of the Effects of the Fed. Res. Board's

Proposed Debit Card Interchange Fee Regulations on Consumers and Small Businesses, (2011), available at

http://ssrn.com/abstract=1769887 : "The ATM networks were able to persuade merchants to install PIN pads at the

point-of-sale to route transactions through their systems by charging very low interchange fees in the 1990s.";

David S. Evans, The Antitrust Economics of Multi-Sided Markets, 20 YALE J. REG. 325 (2003); Ahlborn et al., The

Problem of Interchange Fee, supra note 97, at 192; Lloyd Constantine, Jeffrey I. Shinder & Kerin E. Coughlin, In Re

Visa Check/Mastermoney Antitrust Litigation: A Study of Market Failure in a Two-Sided Market, 2005 COLUM. BUS. L.

REV. 599, 609 (2005): “PIN debit also flourished because the regional networks priced it at par (i.e., merchants paid no

interchange fee), thus maximizing merchant incentives to install the PIN pads that they needed to accept PIN debit

transactions”.

Page 56: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

56

In debit, the proportional cost is negligible; hence debit acquirers could offer fixed and not

proportional MSF.235

Since the debit networks in the U.S. developed from ATM networks, Visa and MasterCard were

initially not part of them. However, when the volume of debit transactions began to rise, Visa

and MasterCard did not sit idle. Visa acquired a debit network named Interlink, and MasterCard

developed its own debit network, Maestro.

Currently, there are more than 10 debit networks in the United States. The 4 largest (Interlink,

Pulse, Star, and NYCE) possess 90% market share.236

108. In my view, the actions taken by Visa after it purchased Interlink are a text-book example of

anti-competitive conduct which unfortunately succeeded, because of a lack of regulatory and

judicial awareness. Visa used the interchange fee to attract banks to issue visa debit. As opposed

to other debit networks that charged very low MSF, if any, Visa charged a relatively high MSF,

from which Visa transferred a major part to the issuing banks as interchange fee.

The interchange fee on Visa’s debit cards was higher than the interchange fee in cheaper PIN

debit networks. Visa offered issuing banks a higher interchange fee for issuing its signature

(and inferior) debit, instead rivals' PIN debit. Other networks could not match Visa's offer.

Visa's conduct was a decisive factor. The high income from Visa's interchange fees was an offer

that issuers could not refuse. Banks reduced issuance of other networks’ cheaper debit cards,

which did not reward them such a high interchange fee, and switched to issue Visa’s more

expensive debit. As a result, networks with low interchange fees were excluded, even though

from social welfare perspective, they were cheaper and more efficient. The market share of

Visa's Interlink increased and with it the MSF jumped from 20 cents per $100 transaction in

2002 to 90 cents in 2008.237

235 NACS v. Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys., 746 F.3d 474, 479 (D.C. Cir. 2014): “In contrast to credit card

fees, which generally represent a set percentage of the value of a transaction, debit card fees change little as price

increases. Thus, a bookstore might pay the same fees to sell a $25 hardcover that Mercedes would pay to sell a $75,000

car”. 236 Zhu Wang, Demand Externalities and Price Cap Regulation: Learning from the U.S. Debit Card Market, at 6 (FRB

Richmond Working Paper No. 13-06R. 2014): “Interlink, Star, Pulse and NYCE are the top four networks, together

holding 90 percent of the PIN debit market share. The largest PIN network, Interlink, is operated by Visa”. See also Shy

& Wang, Why do Payment Card Networks Charge Proportional Fees, Supra note 31, at 2 n. 6. 237 FOER, ELECTRONIC PAYMENT SYSTEMS AND INTERCHANGE FEES, supra note 174, at 18; Andrew Martin, How Visa,

using Card Fees, Dominates a Market, N. Y. Times, Jan. 4, 2010; M. Pierce Sandwith, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street

Reform and Consumer Protection Act: Debit Card Interchange Fees and the Durbin Amendment's Small Bank

Exemption, 16 N. C. BANKING INST. 223, 230-31 (2012).

Page 57: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

57

Visa used signature debit and not PIN debit. Signature debit is not as fast as PIN debit, and is

more expensive. Signature debit is routed on the slower credit card network, as opposed to the

faster ATM network used by PIN debit.238 Signature debit is also less protected from fraud risks

than PIN debit.239

Visa thus paved the way for the market to move from the more efficient and cheap PIN debit

to the less efficient and more expensive signature debit.240 As I shall show, this is consistent

with the economic adage that bad money drives out good money.241

109. Later, a trend began in the United States whereby debit cards switched to proportional MSF,

probably for profit maximization.242 Debit interchange fee continued to increase gradually, and

apart from a temporary reduction in 2003, due to a class action settlement regarding the HAC

rule,243 debit card interchange fee was eventually reduced only after the U.S. Congress

intervened with a major reform, named the Durbin Amendment in the Dodd-Frank Law.244

110. Debit is a pure payment instrument. Debit cards are a substitute for cash.245 Debit card is also a

substitute for credit card, as long as the cardholder needs the card just as a payment instrument

(i.e., as a “transactor” and not as a “creditor”). Debit cards are not a substitute for deferred

payments or for those who need the inherent credit function in credit cards. Debit is also no

substitute for deferred checks. Therefore, debit is not an available option for consumers with

liquidity constraints. However, for customers who are pure transactors and need a payment

238 NACS v. Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys., 746 F.3d 474, 478 (D.C. Cir. 2014): “Signature networks

employ infrastructure used to process credit card payments, while PIN networks employ infrastructure used by ATMs...

PIN transactions are authorized and cleared simultaneously: because the cardholder generally enters her PIN

immediately after swiping her card, the authorization request doubles as the clearance message. Signature transactions

are first authorized and subsequently cleared: because the cardholder generally signs only after the issuer has approved

the transaction, the merchant must send a separate clearance message.”;

Shy & Wang, supra note 31, at 1576: “PIN debit cards are routed over the PIN debit networks, which used to charge

fixed per-transaction fees”. 239 Supra note 31. 240 Debit Card Interchange Fees and Routing, Final Rule, supra note 31, at 46262: “[T]he higher interchange revenue

for signature debit relative to PIN debit has encouraged issuers to promote the use of signature debit over PIN debit,

even though signature debit has substantially higher rates of fraud.”;

Balto, supra note 211, at 216: “[B]ecause of interchange fees the less efficient payment system prospered.”;

Borzekowski & Kiser, supra note 28, at 168; Sandwith, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform, supra note 237, at 230;

Constantine, Shinder & Coughlin, In Re Visa Check/Mastermoney Antitrust Litigation: A Study of Market Failure in a

Two-Sided Market, supra note 234, at 605-10. 241 Infra ch. 7.2.2 and ¶ 435. 242 Supra n. 68. 243 Wal-Mart Stores, Inc. v. Visa U.S.A. Inc., 396 F.3d 96, 103 (2d Cir. N.Y. 2005): "The district court described the

Settlement as providing for, among other things… Lowering, by roughly one third, of the interchange rates on debit

products for the period from August 1, 2003, through December 31, 2003". For expansion on this case see infra ch.

8.3.7. 244 Infra ch. 8.3.9. 245 Infra note 952

Page 58: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

58

instrument only to “pay” with, and of course for merchants, debit cards are cheaper, faster and

more efficient than credit cards.246

4.3. Interim Summary

111. The brief history description above shows how different payment networks evolved in diverse

ways, in terms of price structure and interchange fees, and as an answer to different supply and

demand pressures each payment system faced.

112. With Credit cards, networks were required to incentivize cardholders, the side with the higher

elasticity. Networks acted in creative ways to increase the distribution on the issuing side.

Merchants were willing to pay a high MSF, and needed fewer incentives for accepting cards.

Credit card networks developed by imposing most of the costs on the merchant side, and by

transferring interchange fees from acquirers to issuers in order to subsidize and incentivize

adoption and usage among cardholders.

With debit cards, the networks had to convince merchants to join, as the penetration at the

cardholders’ side was complete and automatic from the outset. Cardholders already had debit

cards - their ATM cards. Therefore, the price structure was tilted to attract merchants by

offering them a low MSF, and sometimes even an interchange fee of zero. Only when debit

networks matured and gained market power, did they raise the MSF for merchants.

With ATMs, the circumstances were the opposite and thus the interchange fee was reversed,

meaning from the issuer to the acquirer. The side that needed to be incentivized was the ATM

owners. Today, at least in countries that allow direct charges for withdrawals, interchange fees

in ATM transactions (not to mention interchange fees that are at the same level as that prior to

introduction of direct charges), is an anachronistic remnant of the period in which ATM owners

(acquirers) were not motivated to install ATMs, and had to be incentivized by collecting

interchange fees from issuers.

The historical evolution of interchange fees in payment networks demonstrates that interchange

fee is not an essential.247 Initially, credit card interchange fee was a tool to compensate issuers

246 For expansion on costs and benefits of payment cards see infra ch. 5.4. 247 Comp 29.373 Visa International — Multilateral Interchange Fee, O. J. L 318, 17, (July 24, 2002), http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:32002D0914:EN:HTML "The Visa MIF is, on the admission of

Visa itself, not indispensable for the existence of the Visa system";

Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 44, para. 608; see also id. Para. 648: "The

MasterCard MIF is not objectively necessary for the operation of an open payment card scheme such as MasterCard's.";

Page 59: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

59

for their costs. As networks gained market power, interchange fee was used for reducing

cardholder fee, and increasing rewards and profits, by exploiting the high willingness to pay on

the part of merchants. Also, in debit and ATMs interchange fee was used by the networks to

transfer money from the side that was more willing to pay to the side that needed inducement.

After networks gained market power they raised the interchange fee even more, and used its

proceeds as a source of profit.

Part II - Economic Analysis

5. Costs And Benefits Of Payment Instruments

113. There are several payment instruments in the market, of which the main ones are cash, checks

and payment cards. Payment cards include credit, deferred debit, prepaid and debit cards. New

payment instruments like Bitcoin and Pay-Pal have so far gained little market share, and are not

significant for this analysis.248 Pay-Pal is not an independent payment instrument, but rather an

add-on to the payment cards networks.

114. Interchange fees affect the level of payment card usage compared to other payment instruments.

In order to understand if it is indeed more efficient to increase the level of card usage, the

relative costs and benefits of payment instruments must be examined.

115. The costs and benefits of using a certain payment instrument are not limited to the payers and

payees. A positive correlation was found between usage of efficient payment instruments and

economic growth. For instance, electronic payment instruments, which are traceable, help to

suppress “black” or “shadow” economy, so their costs and benefits to society exceed those of

Case T-111/08 MasterCard v. Comm'n, para. 120 (May 24, 2012): “The Commission was legitimately able to conclude

that the MIF was not objectively necessary for the operation of the MasterCard system”. C-382/12 P MasterCard v.

European Commission, para. 113 (Sept. 11, 2014);

Semeraro, Credit Cards Interchange Fees: Three Decades of Antitrust Uncertainty, supra note 64, at 971: "Success

does not establish that interchange fees are essential to an efficient card system.";

EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees, supra note 200, at 11: “In terms of viability, a debit card scheme

without any interchange fee seems to be perfectly viable from a commercial perspective without raising the costs of

current accounts for consumers. Denmark for example has a zero-interchange fee on its domestic debit scheme while an

average account holder pays current account fees well below the EU average. Similarly, in Switzerland the main debit

card network is Maestro (part of MasterCard) which has no MIF”. 248 Carlos Arango, Kim P. Huynh & Leonard Sabetti, Consumer Payment Choice: Merchant Card Acceptance Versus

Pricing Incentives, 55 J. BANK. FIN. 130, 139 (2015): “However, currently none of the platform-based digital currencies

are widely accepted”.

Page 60: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

60

the parties to the transactions.249 This chapter will give a short summary of the costs and benefits

of payment instruments.

5.1. Costs of payment instruments

116. Like any other product or service, payment instruments also carry costs for their users.

Aggregate costs of payment instruments are substantial. Studies estimate that the total costs of

payment instruments amount to 1% (and, in some studies, even more) of the GDP.250

117. The main actors in the payment arena are the central bank, commercial banks, acquirers, issuers,

infrastructures owners, merchants (payees), customers (payers) and middle entities, such as

factoring firms. Every participant of a payment system incurs a private cost for using each

payment instrument (fees, time, labor, etc.). The costs can be summed up. The total of these

costs is the social cost of a payment instrument.251

249 Iftekhar Hasan, Emmi Martikainen & Tuomas Takalo, Promoting Efficient Retail Payments in Europe, 20 Bank of

Finland Research Discussion Papers, at 1: “[C]ash is an attractive method of paying in the shadow and underground

economies... Hence, the adoption of electronic payment methods might not only stimulate economic growth, but also

might provide a direct means to improve public finances for indebted European economies.”; Iftekhar Hasan, Tanya De

Renzis & Heiko Schmiedel, Retail Payments and the Real Economy, ECB Working Paper 1572 (Aug. 2013): “Using

data from across 27 European markets over the period 1995-2009, the results confirm that migration to efficient

electronic retail payments stimulates the overall economy, consumption and trade”. 250 David B. Humphrey, Retail Payments: New Contributions, Empirical Results, and Unanswered Questions, 34 J.

BANK. FIN. 1729, 1734 (2010): “In many of the most recent payment cost analyses, the full cost of a nation’s payment

system is somewhat less than 1% of GDP annually”.

Heiko Schmiedel, Gergana Kostova & Wiebe Ruttenberg, The Social and Private Costs of Retail Payment Instruments

A European Perspective, at 6, (137 ECB Occasional Paper Series, 2012): “The social costs of retail payment

instruments are substantial and amount to €45 billion, i.e. 0.96% of GDP for the sample of 13 participating EU

countries. When the sample results from the participating countries are extrapolated to 27 EU Member States, the social

costs of retail payment instruments are comparable to those of the sample countries, being close to 1% of GDP or €130

billion. These results are robust against the estimation method used”;

Wilko Bolt & Sujit Chakravorti, Digitization of Retail Payments, at 8 (DNB Working Paper 270. 2010): “Significant

real resources are required to provide payment services. Recent payment cost analyses have shown that the total cost of

a nation’s retail payment system may easily approach 1% of GDP annually (Humphrey, 2010). Even higher cost

estimates can be obtained depending on current payment composition and how much of bank branch and ATM network

costs are included as being essential for check deposit, cash withdrawal, and card issue and maintenance activity.”;

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT - ANNEX TO THE PROPOSAL FOR A DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN

PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL ON PAYMENT SERVICES IN THE INTERNAL MARKET - IMPACT ASSESSMENT,

SEC/2005/1535, at 2 (Dec. 1, 2005): "Studies estimate the cost impact of the payment system to society to as much as

2–3 % of GDP. Cash is the main cost driver and accounts for as much as 60–70 % of the total cost of the payment

system. Instead of efficient electronic payment services, for which the costs range between a few euro cents the cost per

transaction when paid for in cash ranges between EUR 0.30 to EUR 0.55.";

Soren Korsgaard, Paying for Payments Free Payments and Optimal Interchange Fees, 1682 ECB Working Paper, at 3

(2014): “Based on a joint microeconomic study conducted by central banks in 13 European countries, the European

Central Bank... estimates the real cost of producing payments to be almost 1.0 per cent of GDP on average.”;

Ewelina Sokołowska, Innovations in the Payment Card Market: The Case of Poland, ELECTRONIC COMMERCE

RESEARCH AND APPLICATIONS, at 2 (2015): “Printing, distribution, and cash controls were estimated to cost a developed

economy about 0.75% of annual gross domestic product (GDP), and an emerging economy 1–2%”. 251 Björn Segendorf & Thomas Jansson, The Cost of Consumer Payments in Sweden, at 8 (Sveriges Risbank Working

Paper 262. 2012): “When analysing the costs of an industry, one must make a distinction between private and social

Page 61: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

61

118. There is no single methodology to calculate total cost of a payment instrument. Some studies

consider only direct costs that are invested in the production of payment instruments. Other

studies also consider indirect costs, such as the cost of time.252 Some costs, like overhead,

should be counted only partially, because they are shared with costs of other payment

instruments or other activities which are not related to payments. This makes the cost

calculation even more complicated.253

119. Another distinction should be made between private costs and social costs.254 For example,

suppose a customer withdraws cash from an ATM. The withdrawal fee is a private cost to the

customer, and income to the bank.255 However this fee is not necessarily connected to the cost

of real resources involved in this transaction, as part of the cost may embody profit. The cost

of deploying and maintaining the ATM is a real cost. The cost of the customer's time at the

queue to the ATM is an indirect cost (of cash).256 From a social point of view, labor, time and

resources invested in cash transactions should be included in the calculation of the costs of cash.

From a social perspective, the costs of a payment instrument combine only real resources

invested in it, without including profit or transfer payments which offset each other.257 Thus,

costs. Private costs are the costs that individual participants incur, while the latter are the total costs to society reflecting

the real use of resources in the whole production process”. 252 Allan Shampine, An Evaluation of the Social Costs of Payment Methods Literature, at 8 (SSRN Elibrary 2012):

“Many studies, using both marginal and average estimates, include the time spent by a cashier on a transaction

multiplied by an average wage rate as a resource cost”. 253 Olaf Gresvik & Harald Haare, Costs in the Norwegian Payment System, 4 Norges Bank Staff Memo, at 10 (2009):

“There is no clear-cut answer to which costs should be relevant in a social cost analysis. In our opinion, all direct

production or user costs should be included. When it comes to the indirect production costs, questions might arise. For

instance, it is often not obvious how to allocate indirect costs in a bank between payment operations and other activities

in a bank. Likely, and perhaps even more difficult, is the question of allocating overhead costs between the different

payment instruments”. 254 Fumiko Hayashi & William R. Keeton, Measuring the Costs of Retail Payment Methods, at 17 (Fed. Bank of Kansas

City Paper. 2012): “While social costs are appropriate for assessing payments efficiency, private costs can be useful for

other policy questions. For example, data on private costs can help determine why consumers prefer a particular

payment method or whether consumers are paying higher fees for a payment service than it costs the provider to

produce it”. 255 Jakub Górka, Payment Behaviour in Poland – The Benefits and Costs of Cash, Cards and Other Non-Cash Payment

Instruments, at 15 (Jan. 2012): “Social costs are calculated by extracting payment participants’ payment revenues (from

fees, tariffs) from their total private costs. Alternatively, the social cost is the sum of all internal costs made by the

relevant parties in the payment chain in order to carry out transactions. Private costs include all costs, including the fees

paid, borne by payment participants... Net social costs are social costs corrected for social benefits. They are derived

from private costs and benefits which exclude transfer payments, that is double counting of some items.";

Chris Stewart et al., The Evolution of Payment Costs in Australia, RBA Research Discussion Paper 14, at 6 (2014): “[A]

transaction fee paid by a merchant to its bank represents a transfer and a private cost to the merchant, but not a cost for

society as a whole”. 256 Hayashi & Keeton, Measuring the Costs of Retail Payment Methods, supra note 254, at 7: “Although the consumer

may not incur a monetary cost, the time spent carrying out the transaction is still treated as a labor resource cost,

because in theory, the time could have been spent in other productive ways”. 257 Bolt & Chakravorti, Digitization of Retail Payments, supra note 250, at 9: “[S]ocial cost refers to the total cost for

society net any monetary transfers between participants, and reflects the real cost of resources used in the production

and usage of payment services”.

Page 62: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

62

the aggregate cost of a payment instrument differs from the sum of the individual costs for each

of its users. The former does not include transfer payments or profits, but only real resources.258

120. As with other products, costs of payment instruments can be divided into fixed and variable

costs.259 Payment cards are characterized by large fixed costs and relatively small variable

costs.260 Other payment instruments, like cash, are characterized oppositely, as variable costs

are more significant and the cost of payment increases with the size of the transaction.261 It costs

more to handle a large cash transaction than a small cash transaction, whereas for a debit

transaction, the amount has almost no influence on the cost, because the main costs are fixed

notwithstanding the size of the transaction.262 A credit transaction has a bigger variable cost,

because of the payment guarantee. A common baseline for comparison between costs must

therefore consider all costs of each payment instrument, both fixed and variable.263

258 Hayashi & Keeton, Measuring the Costs of Retail Payment Methods, supra note 254, at 7: “The social cost of a

payment instrument is the sum of the resource costs incurred by all parties in transactions using that instrument. This

cost is distinguished from the private cost of a payment instrument to an individual party. The latter cost includes not

only the resource costs incurred by an individual party to a payment transaction, but also the fees paid by that party to

other parties as part of the transaction. These fees are excluded from social costs because from society’s point of view,

the fees paid by one party to a transaction are offset by the fees received by another party.”;

Schmiedel, Kostova & Ruttenberg, The Social and Private Costs of Retail Payment Instruments, supra note 250, at 6:

“Private costs refer to all the costs incurred by the relevant individual parties in the payment chain. Social costs are the

costs to society, reflecting the use of resources in the production of payment services; that is, the total cost of production

excluding payments, e.g. fees, tariffs, etc., made to other participants in the payment chain. In this sense, social costs

measure the sum of the pure costs of producing payment instruments incurred by the different stakeholders in the

payments market". 259 Hayashi & Keeton, Measuring the Costs of Retail Payment Methods, supra note 254, at 8: “Fixed costs are those

incurred regardless of the number or value of payments, while variable costs are those that increase with the number or

value of payments. Fixed costs are generally associated with capital equipment, while variable costs are associated with

labor and raw materials.”;

EUROPEAN COMMISSION, SURVEY ON MERCHANTS' COSTS OF PROCESSING CASH AND CARD PAYMENTS FINAL RESULTS,

para. 6 (March 2015): “The total cost function of a given payment instrument is typically defined as the sum of fixed

costs, i.e. costs that do not vary with the number and value of payments with the payment instrument, and variable

costs. Variable costs can be of two types: costs that vary with the number of transactions (e.g. time of processing

payment at the cash counter) and costs that vary with the value of transactions (e.g. cost of delay in crediting the

incoming funds)”. 260 EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, THE INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION OF MARKETS WITH TWO-SIDED PLATFORMS, in ISSUES IN

COMPETITION LAW AND POLICY, at 679 (2008) available at

https://www.justice.gov/sites/default/files/atr/legacy/2006/12/13/219673_b.pdf : “[C]ard payment systems have to

maintain networks for authorizing and settling transactions for cardholders and merchants… The costs of developing,

establishing, and maintaining these networks are somewhat independent of volume”. 261 Dr Anikó Turján et al., Nothing is Free: A Survey of the Social Cost of the Main Payment Instruments in Hungary, at

6 (MNB Occasional Papers 93. 2011): “The share of variable costs is much higher in relation to cash and cash-based

payments... while the share of fixed costs is dominant for electronic payment instruments linked to payment accounts”.

Leo Van Hove, Central Banks and Payment Instruments: A Serious Case of Schizophrenia, 66 COMMUNICATIONS &

STRATEGIES 19, 25 (2007): “[O]ne additional cash payment would cost a minimum of EUR 0.11 - and this figure rises

considerably in accordance with the amount to be paid”. 262 Carl Schwartz et al., Payment Costs in Australia, at 124 (Conference Proceedings, Sydney, Nov. 29, 2007). 263 Hayashi, Measuring the Costs, supra note 258, at 8-9: “For questions involving the long-run efficiency of the

payments system, the appropriate measure of social costs is total cost, including both fixed and variable costs. For

example, electronic payment methods tend to require large investments in infrastructure, such as card-reading terminals

in stores and computer equipment in depository institutions and card networks. However, once that investment is in

Page 63: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

63

121. A common cost methodology, which considers all costs, is the Long Run Incremental Cost -

“LRIC”. This was the methodology that was used in Israel to implement the methodology

decision.264 The idea is that in the long run, even fixed costs can be viewed as variable, because

of the ability of the firm to avoid them. The LRIC methodology thus enables comparison of all

costs of payment instruments, fixed and variable.

122. The average cost of a single transaction can be calculated as the total costs of the payment

instrument divided by the number of transactions. A more economic approach is to look at the

cost of the marginal transaction. For instance, the tourist test is based on a marginal

methodology, because it considers the avoided costs of cash in the marginal transaction. Indeed,

the European Commission considers only variable costs, and disregards fixed costs in the tourist

test calculation. The Commission's stance is that fixed costs, such as annual fees, are considered

only at the adoption stage of a payment instrument, whereas usage decision is based on variable

costs.265

123. A marginal or incremental approach is appropriate to investigate whether a payment instrument

is used too much or too little, because, by definition, the underlying question concentrates on

the marginal transaction. An average approach is appropriate to determine broader market-wide

effects of payment instruments.266

124. There are two main methods of estimating net costs of a payment instrument. One approach

counts the costs and revenues for the different participants (central banks, banks, merchants,

customers, infrastructures).267 This can be viewed as a macro approach. The other way to

place, the additional costs of processing transactions tend to be low. Thus, electronic payments may have low variable

social costs but high total social costs because of their high fixed costs. Cash payments, on the other hand, require

relatively small investment in infrastructure but large inputs of labor and raw materials to print, process, and safeguard

cash. As a result, these payments may have high variable social costs but low total social costs”. 264 Supra ¶¶ 495, 641. 265 EUROPEAN COMMISSION, SURVEY ON MERCHANTS' COSTS OF PROCESSING CASH AND CARD PAYMENTS FINAL

RESULTS, para. 8 (March 2015): “In the MIT MIF calculation, fixed costs should be excluded. As proposed by Rochet

and Tirole (2007), the test consists of considering the merchant's willingness to accept a card payment when a tourist,

i.e. a non-repeat customer with enough cash in the pocket, stands at the till ready to make a purchase. Thus, the fixed

costs (which are linked to the acceptance of the payment instrument) do not appear relevant in determining the

merchant's transactional benefits from card usage, and the calculation of the merchant indifference MIF level should be

based on variable costs only”. 266 Shampine, An Evaluation of the Social Costs of Payment Methods Literature, supra note 252, at 8: “[S]hould costs

be measured on a marginal or average basis? Both measures can be useful, but for different purposes. If one is

interested in determining whether there are significant externalities such that customers are “over-using” relatively high

cost payment methods, then a marginal approach may be appropriate. If one is interested in determining the potential

effects of a significant increase in usage of a payment method within a country, then an average approach may be

appropriate". 267 Segendorf & Jansson, The Cost of Consumer Payments in Sweden, supra note 251, at 6: “The first group, to which

our study belongs, uses a cost and revenue model in which both costs and revenues for major stakeholders (central

banks, banks, retailers, infrastructure providers, and sometimes consumers) are collected. The focus of these studies is

Page 64: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

64

measure costs of payment instruments is called Activity Based Costing (“ABC”). This approach

disassembles all actions that are attributed to a payment transaction, and allocates the costs of

labor or real resource to each action.268 This is a micro approach. A caveat is that even within

the ABC method, there is wide amplitude of interpretations.269 For example, a cost analysis

which gives value to subjective criteria such as “time” is inconclusive by definition.

125. Payment cost studies have been conducted in various countries such as Netherlands,270

Sweden,271 Australia,272 Belgium,273 Norway,274 Hungary,275 and United States.276 There is also

literature that surveys these cost studies.277 There is only one emerging consensus: debit,

mainly on payments at the POS (point of sale); i.e. payments made by cash, debit- and credit card, checks and e-

money”. 268 Schmiedel, Kostova & Ruttenberg, The Social and Private Costs of Retail Payment Instruments, supra note 250, at

9: “ABC allocates the cost of the activities along the payment chain to the different payment products and services

within a bank”. 269 Shampine, An Evaluation of the Social Costs of Payment Methods Literature, supra note 252, at 6: “However, it

seems likely that ABC based point estimates are subject to significant uncertainty, and that differences in the precise

methodology used can lead to significantly different results”. 270 Hans Brits & Carlo Winder, Payments are no Free Lunch, 3 DNB Occasional Studies at 35, (2005): “Total social

costs involved with all POS payments in the Netherlands amount to 0.65% of GDP... the costs per pos

transaction average eur 0.35... . The credit card is the most expensive instrument, irrespective of the

transaction amount”. 271 Segendorf & Jansson, The Cost of Consumer Payments in Sweden, supra note 251, at 1: “The combined social cost

for these payments was 0.68 per cent of GDP. At the point of sale, cash is socially less costly than debit cards for

payments below EUR 1.88 (SEK 20) and credit cards below EUR 42.37 (SEK 450)”. 272 Stewart et al., The Evolution of Payment Costs in Australia, supra note 255, at 46: “[T]he costs involved in providing

payment services to households have fallen from 0.80 per cent of GDP in 2006 to 0.54 per cent of GDP in 2013.”; id. at

i: “The greater share of the overall cost is borne by merchants. The consumer undertaking a transaction typically pays a

small proportion of its cost; consumers face a similar cost for credit card payments as for debit card payments despite

the higher cost of credit cards to the economy”. 273 National Bank of Belgium, Costs, Advantages and Drawbacks of the various Means of Payment, NATIONAL BANK

OF BELGIUM ECON. REV. 41, 46 (2006): “The total macroeconomic costs associated with the use of the means of

payment are estimated at around 0.74 p.c. of Belgian GDP in 2003, which is a far from negligible figure”. 274 Gresvik & Haare, Costs in the Payment System, supra note 253 at 26: “The use of resources for payment and cash

services as a proportion of GDP is low (0.49 per cent). It is probably lower than ever before, and it is low in comparison

with other countries. The reasons for these low costs are low cash usage, high usage of the domestic debit card system

BankAxept, and widespread use of electronic payment services... The reason for the decrease in costs for the most

important payment services is a broad shift from manual to electronic services. The economies of scale associated with

producing electronic services have therefore been better realized”. 275 Turján et al., Nothing is Free: A Survey of the Social Cost of the Main Payment Instruments in Hungary, supra note

261, at 6: “[T]he social cost amounts to HUF 388 billion, i.e. 1.49% of GDP”. 276 Daniel D. Garcia Swartz, Robert W. Hahn & Anne Layne-Farrar, The Move Toward a Cashless Society: A Closer

Look at Payment Instrument Economics, 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 175, 196 (2006): “[W]hen all key parties to a

transaction are considered and benefits are added, cash and checks are not as desirable as many earlier studies suggest.

In general, the shift toward a cashless society appears to improve economic welfare”;

Daniel D. Garcia Swartz, Robert W. Hahn & Anne Layne-Farrar, The Move Toward a Cashless Society: Calculating the

Costs and Benefits, 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 199 (2006).

For criticism see of their work see Allan Shampine, Another Look at Payment Instrument Economics, 6 REV. NETWORK

ECON. 495 (2007).

For reply to the criticism see Daniel Garcia-Swarz, Robert W. Hahn & Anne Layne-Farrar, Further Thoughts on the

Cashless Society: A Reply to Dr. Shampine, 6 REV. NETWORK ECON. 509 (2007). 277 Shampine, An Evaluation of the Social Costs of Payment Methods Literature, supra note 252;

Turján et al., Nothing is Free: A Survey of the Social Cost of the Main Payment Instruments in Hungary, supra note

261, at 100; Górka, Payment Behaviour in Poland, supra note 255, at 15 ; Hayashi & Keeton, Measuring the Costs of

Retail Payment Methods, supra note 254, at 16.

Page 65: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

65

especially PIN debit, is cheaper than credit. No other conclusive results have been found.278

Most studies also support the conclusion that, except for coin-size transactions (for which cash

is the cheapest payment instrument), debit is the cheapest payment instrument for society.279

Thus, shifting payments from cash (except for very low value transactions) and checks to

payment cards may result in net benefits for society as a whole.280

126. Studies also reveal that costs of cash tend to stay stable over time, whereas costs of electronic

money, such as payment cards, decline over time due to economies of scale and technology

improvements.281

278 Shampine, id. at 6: “Again, the differences between studies are striking. Some studies find little difference between

the payment methods, while others find enormous differences. Also, there is no agreement as to which payment method

has the lowest social cost. Seven of the twenty-one results find cash to be the least costly, twelve find PIN debit to be

the least costly, one finds credit to be the least costly, and one ranks payment cards generally as the least costly... If

there is any consensus to be found, it is that PIN debit is less costly than credit.”;

Górka, id. at 15: “[D]ebit card is always cheaper than the credit card.”;

Hayashi & Keeton, Measuring the Costs of Retail Payment Methods, supra note 254, at 1: “[A] number of central banks

have recently conducted comprehensive studies of the costs of retail payment methods. These studies have reached

some common conclusions, such as that debit cards are less costly than credit cards.”;

EUROPEAN COMMISSION, COMPETITION INTERIM REPORT I: PAYMENT CARDS, SECTOR INQUIRY UNDER ARTICLE 17

REGULATION 1/2003 ON RETAIL BANKING, at 11 (Apr.12, 2006): “The credit card is less attractive than the debit card,

irrespective of the transaction amount, as the credit card’s variable costs both for the execution of the transfer itself and

in relation to the size of the purchase are larger.”;

Nicole Jonker, Card Acceptance and Surcharging: The Role of Costs and Competition, 10 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1, 2

(2011): “Credit card payments turn out to be very costly”. 279 Harry Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees Generally Lead to Cash-Promoting Cross-Subsidisation, at 8 BANK

OF FINLAND RESEARCH DISCUSSION PAPERS (2011): “According to payment cost studies done by central banks, cash is

generally efficient only for mini-size (coin-sized) purchases.”;

Górka, id. at 15: “cash is cheaper than debit cards in low value payments: up to EUR 11.63 in Netherlands, EUR 10.24

in Belgium, EUR 7.55 in Sweden, EUR 30.67 in Australia, about EUR 15 un Finland, about EUR 8 in Portugal; above

these thresholds a debit card is cheaper.”;

Segendorf & Jansson, The Cost of Consumer Payments in Sweden, supra note 251, at 5: “We found that for low-value

payments cash is more cost efficient than debit cards; the break-even point is estimated to be EUR 1.88 (SEK 20) and

for credit cards EUR 42.37 (SEK 450).”;

EC INTERIM REPORT, id. at 11: "Cash is more economical for purchases below a certain threshold.”;

Daniel Garcia-Swarz, Robert W. Hahn & Anne Layne-Farrar, Further Thoughts on the Cashless Society: A Reply to Dr.

Shampine, 6 REV. Network Econ. 509, 521 (2007): “[C]ash appears to be optimal at small transaction sizes. Fourth, as

the transaction size increases, a switching point is reached starting at which debit cards appear to become the socially

optimal payment instrument”. See also infra ¶143. 280 David Humphrey et al., What does it Cost to make a Payment? 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 159 (2003): “As a general

rule of thumb, an electronic payment costs only from one-third to one-half as much as a paper-based payment. If a

country moves from a wholly paper-based payment system to close to an all electronic system, it may save 1% or more

of its GDP annually once the transition costs are absorbed.”;

Humphrey, Retail Payments: New Contributions, Empirical Results, and Unanswered Questions, supra note 250, at

1734: "In many of the most recent payment cost analyses, the full cost of a nation’s payment system is somewhat less

than 1% of GDP annually. Higher cost estimates can be obtained depending on current payment composition (as

electronic payments are only 1/3–1/ 2 the cost of paper-based instruments).";

Schmiedel, Kostova & Ruttenberg, The Social and Private Costs of Retail Payment Instruments, supra note 250, at 6. 281 Segendorf & Jansson, The Cost of Consumer Payments in Sweden, supra note 251, sec. 6: “Economies of scale are a

decisive factor for the social cost. The higher the number of transactions with a certain payment instrument, the lower

the unit cost tends to be.”;

Nicole Jonker, Card Acceptance and Surcharging: The Role of Costs and Competition, 10 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1, 2

(2011): “ Several cost studies reveal that for society as a whole, the cost of a debit card payment is often lower than the

cost of a cash payment, and that the costs of debit card transactions decrease over time due to economies of scale,

Page 66: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

66

127. Most studies have also found that customers are not aware of the different costs of the payment

instruments they use. This is because customers often pay the same price for goods they buy,

irrespective of the payment instrument they use. Debit may generally be the cheapest payment

instrument, but many cardholders are not aware of that.282 Issuers benefit from this vagueness,

because they earn higher profits from the more expensive credit cards,283 but from an overall

welfare perspective, debit should be used more on account of (the more expensive) credit cards

and cash.284

128. Merchants derive benefits from switching to electronic money. Payment card networks

recognize this, and use their market power to extract these benefits from the merchant side, in

the form of higher fees, so that merchants end up paying a disproportionate share of the payment

costs.285 This distorts efficient decision making by merchants. The surplus they could derive

from card usage is extracted from them. All consumers bear the consequences because, as any

other cost, merchants' costs of payments instruments are passed through to consumers, in the

form of higher prices of products and services.

5.2. Benefits of payment instruments

129. Costs are only one side of the coin. To determine efficiency, benefits of payment instruments

should also be considered. A comparison between payment instruments must include benefits

and not only costs.286 Evans and Schmalensee give an example of cars with automatic

whereas the costs of cash payments are fairly stable. Credit card payments turn out to be very costly... In countries, such

as the Netherlands, where consumers mainly use cash and the debit card at the point-sale, a further substitution of cash

by debit card payments may bring considerable economic benefits for society as a whole”. 282 EC INTERIM REPORT, supra note 278, at 10: “[A]lmost no information about these relative costs is passed on to

consumers through price mechanisms. In the POS market, relative prices give no information to support a cost-efficient

choice between debit cards, credit cards and ATM withdrawals. Here, the debit card has a large cost advantage not

reflected in private variable fees”. 283 Górka, Payment Behaviour in Poland, supra note 255, at 16: “Credit cards are characterised by high resource costs,

but these cards also generate high profits for banks. This is the reason why they are promoted by credit institutions.

Direct debits, (electronically initiated) credit transfers and debit cards have the lowest social costs.”;

EC, INTERIM REPORT, id. at 11: “[A]ll means of payment except for cash distribution gives rise to net revenues for the

banks, where the most net revenue is generated by card payments (acquiring and issuing). Herefore, the non-transparent

price structure of payment instruments (with few exceptions consumers do not pay any variable fee and receive

insufficient price signals to make their choice) requires cross-subsidising between them”. 284 EC INTERIM REPORT, id. at 11: “From a welfare perspective, and given that user demand is price-elastic, a pricing

strategy based on variable costs would lead to greater use of debit cards, less use of credit cards and cash, and more use

of electronic credit transfers and direct debits”. 285 Wilko Bolt & Sujit Chakravorti, Economics of Payment Cards: A Status Report, 32 ECON. PERSPECTIVES 15, 18

(2008): “[S]hifting payments from cash and checks to payment cards results in net benefits for society as a whole, but

they also conclude that merchants may be paying a disproportionate share of the cost”. 286 Hayashi & Keeton, Measuring the Costs of Retail Payment Methods, supra note 254, at 5: “To determine whether

one retail payment method is more efficient than another, a central bank would need to know not only the costs to

society of using each payment method, but also the benefits”

Page 67: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

67

transmissions, which are more expensive than cars with manual transmissions, but probably

yield more benefit to their buyers.287 The cost of a credit transaction is more expensive than of

debit, but a credit transaction allows the cardholder, the benefit of free funding period and the

benefit of advancing consumption ahead of payment. Credit card users, especially heavy users,

also enjoy bigger rewards.

130. Adding benefits to the calculation of comparing payment instruments complicates the

equation.288 It is impossible to know how one should value a shift in levels of utility across

individuals without making arbitrary assumptions.289 Apart from the general difficulty involved

in measuring utility, benefits from a payment instrument vary from person to person, from

merchant to merchant, and, even for the same person or the same merchant, the utility varies

over time.

For example, recent studies confirm that when people receive a large sum of cash, they tend to

dispose of it. They do not want to hang around with large sum in their wallet. The relative utility

of using a payment card versus cash changes for the same person, in comparison to other days,

in which she/he does not have so much cash. An attempt to steer those customers (who are

eager to get read of the cash) to pay with cards, even by bestowing rewards, may be futile.290

For merchants, the benefits of the payment guarantee may differ between transactions and

287 Evans & Schmalensee, The Economics of Interchange Fees and their Regulation, supra note 1119, at 96: “There is

nothing unusual about a high-cost product driving out cheaper competition if the high-cost product is much better. U.S.

drivers generally prefer automatic to manual transmissions in their automobiles, for instance, even though automatic

transmissions cost more and are more expensive to maintain. Drivers seem to believe the difference in benefits

outweighs the difference in cost”. 288 Steven Semerraro, The Reverse Robin Hood Cross Subsidy Hypothesis: Do Credit Cards Systems Tax the Poor and

Reward the Rich?, 40 RUTGERS L.J. 419, 429 (2009). 289 KENNETH J. ARROW, SOCIAL CHOICE AND INDIVIDUAL VALUES, at 10-11 (2d ed. 1963): "Even if, for some reason,

we should admit the measurability of utility for an individual, there still remains the question of aggregating the

individual utilities. . . . In general there seems to be no method intrinsic to utility measurement which will make the

choices compatible. It requires a definite value judgment not derivable from individual sensations to make the utilities

of different individuals dimensionally compatible and still a further value judgment to aggregate them according to any

particular mathematical formula. If we look away from the mathematical aspects of the matter, it seems to make no

sense to add the utility of one individual, a psychic magnitude in his mind, with the utility of another individual”. 290 Fernando Alvarez & Francesco Lippi, Cash Burns: An Inventory Model with a Cash-Credit Choice, EIEF Working

Paper 02/15, at 1 (Feb. 2015): "[A]gents use cash for a purchase as long as they have any cash with them, but use credit

otherwise. Still, agents find it optimal to intermittently replenish their cash holdings, and so will use both cash and

credit... the agents in our model find that “cash burns” in their hands,"; id. at 25: "[T]he agent chooses whether to use

cash or credit purchase after purchase, a decision which turns out to depend on the amount of cash at hand. We find this

feature interesting because it makes contact with a body of recent evidence that the likelihood of using cash increases

with the level of cash holdings.";

Avner Bar-Ilan & Nancy Marion, Demand for Cash with Intra-Period Endogenous Consumption, 37 J. ECON.

DYNAMICS & CONTROL 2668, 2669 (2013): "[C]ash consumption depends positively on cash holdings. The rate of cash

consumption immediately after a cash withdrawal is greater than the consumption rate chosen at a lower cash level."; id.

at 2674: "[C]onsumption is positively correlated with the level of cash holdings"; id. at 2675: "[R]ecent empirical

studies support the positive correlation of cash position and the rate of cash consumption".

Page 68: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

68

between customers. In some transactions, or for some customers, the risk of default is greater,

and this influences the utility from the payment guarantee.291

131. Despite of these difficulties payment economics requires quantifying the costs and benefits of

payment instruments. Especially if merchants differentiate the prices of the goods they sell

based on the payment instrument used, an economic evaluation must consider both the costs

and the benefits they yield. When merchants accept different payment instruments without

surcharging, a usage externality occurs. The cheaper payment instrument subsidizes the

expensive one.292 Again an economic assessment is required to estimate the size of this

externality.

132. The benefits a payment instrument yields its users, are also a function of its acceptance rate.293

A payment instrument that is not widely accepted among merchants will yield fewer benefits

to customers. A payment instrument that is not common among customers will not be attractive

to merchants.294 When both card and cash acceptance is ubiquitous, the importance of this

feature fades.295

133. Payment instruments carry inherent benefits to their users.296 For example, cash, by its nature,

assures anonymity and adherence to the budget constraint of the payer. Cash payers are more

in control of their balance, and are less exposed to debt.297 For consumers who wish to keep

their anonymity and monitor liquidity the inherent features of cash constitute a crucial

advantage.

291 Margaret Guerin-Calvert & Janusz a. Ordover, Merchant Benefits and Public Policy Towards Interchange: An

Economic Assessment, 4 REV. NETWORK ECON. 384, 386 (2005): “By accepting the credit card, the merchant gets the

benefit of prompt payment, while the card issuer bears the cardholder credit and fraud risk. It is not at all clear that these

complex bundles of benefits can be neatly converted into a “per transaction” benefit with a well-calibrated cost easily

assignable to the transaction”. 292 Infra ch. 7.2.2. See also ¶654. 293 Hayashi & Keeton, Measuring the Costs of Retail Payment Methods, supra note 254, at 6: “One reason a retail

payment method could yield higher benefits to end users than another is that the method is more widely accepted”. 294 Carlos Arango, Kim P. Huynh & Leonard Sabetti, Consumer Payment Choice: Merchant Card Acceptance Versus

Pricing Incentives, 55 J. BANK. FIN. 130, 131 (2015): “Consumers would not adopt and use a payment instrument if

they anticipated low acceptance by merchants, and merchants would not accept such instruments if consumers seldom

adopted and used them”. 295 For expansion see infra ch. 7.4 (negation of network externality). 296 See infra note 614. 297 Ulf von Kalckreuth et al., Using Cash to Monitor Liquidity – Implications for Payments, Currency Demand and

Withdrawal Behavior, at 25 (Deutsche Bundesbank Discussion Paper No. 22/2011. 2011): “Cash has the distinctive

feature that it contains memory – the amount spent and the remaining budget can easily be gathered by a glance into

one’s pocket. For some consumers, notably consumers who wish to monitor liquidity and for whom information

processing is relatively expensive, this feature of cash constitutes a crucial advantage of cash – these consumers use

cash because it is the payment instrument which provides the least costly way of keeping control.“;

Carlos Arango, Dylan Hogg and Alyssa Lee, Why is Cash (Still) so Entrenched?, at 12 (Bank of Canada Discussion

Paper 2. 2012): “[O]ther cash attributes, such as anonymity, also matter at the POS”.

Page 69: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

69

Other consumers might value the inherent features of payment cards. Card transactions are

registered, and can be traceable. Development of online applications enables payers to pay

directly from their account and monitor the balance.298

134. Empirical studies found that liquidity constraint influences the payment choice. Illiquid

consumers resort to credit,299 but customers who have already used their credit line to the limit,

tend to use debit more often.300 Debit is used more than credit in small transactions. Debit is

more suited for repeating purchases in which the credit function is less important because of

the recurrence of the payment, e.g., gas stations or monthly utility bills. Credit is more often

used for large or irregular expenses.301

135. The direct users of a payment instrument are the merchant (payee) and the customer (payer).

Both of them are "consumers" of the payment instrument, and both of them are essential for the

transaction. Thus, the cost and benefits of a transaction must be considered from both sides of

the integrated customer i.e., the merchant and the customer.302 However, there is one major

asymmetry between merchants and consumers. In the ordinary case, the customer is the party

who chooses which payment instrument to pay with. Merchants can accept, refuse, surcharge

or try to steer the customer to another payment instrument, but eventually it is the customer

who is in charge of the payment method decision. The preferences of the customer are not

necessarily the same as the social preferences or the preferences of the merchant.

Studies that have investigated the choice of payment instruments of customers have revealed

different factors that influence the decision.

298 Hayashi & Keeton, Measuring the Costs of Retail Payment Methods, supra note 254, at 5: “[M]obile payment

methods may allow consumers to achieve much greater control over their finances and spending by allowing them to

check their account balances prior to making a payment”. 299 Ron Borzekowski & Elizabeth k. Kiser, Consumers’ use of Debit Cards: Patterns, Preferences, and Price Response,

40 J. MONEY, CREDIT & BANK. 149, 170 (2008): “[C]onsumers appear to have an underlying preference for spending

from liquidity, and may use credit to smooth consumption during periods of financial stress”. See also supra note 290. 300 Jonathan Zinman, Debit Or Credit?, 33 J. BANK. FIN. 358, 365 (2009). 301 John Simon, Kylie Smith & Tim West, Price Incentives and Consumer Payment Behaviour, 34 J. BANK. FIN. 1759,

1761 (2010): “ The share of payments made by debit cards is largest at petrol stations and supermarkets and credit

cards’ share of payments is largest for travel and insurance payments”. 302 OECD, POLICY ROUNDTABLES, COMPETITION AND EFFICIENT USAGE OF PAYMENT CARDS DAF/COMP 32, at 7

(2006): “In any transaction using a payment system both the purchaser (in this case, a cardholder) and the merchant are

consuming the services of the payment system; that is, both purchaser and merchant are consumers of payment systems.

When comparing costs and benefits of payment systems, the costs and benefits to the integrated purchaser-merchant

consumer should be considered”.

Page 70: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

70

136. The price of a transaction for the customer is a significant explanatory variable of the choice of

a payment instrument. Customers do not like to pay extra for their purchases, i.e., transaction

fees deter.303 This is why Bank of Israel prohibited imposing transaction fees on debit.304

Surcharging has also been found to have a significant effect on usage, as it steers customers to

the cheaper payment instrument.305 Price incentives, like rewards and free funding period, were

also found to influence the payment behavior of customers.306

137. Convenience of handling the transaction and security have also been found to be significant

explanatory variables for choice of payment instruments.307 Ease of setup and of record keeping

affect adoption of payment instruments.308

138. Applying the findings of the cost studies clarifies why card companies have no incentive to

facilitate the use of debit. Credit cards are more expensive than debit cards for the integrated

customer, but they generate higher profits for the payment card firms.309 Merchants not only

303 Borzekowski & Kiser, supra note 299, at 170: “The fee charged by banks for PIN-based debit transactions does

appear to steer consumers away from PIN debit and toward signature debit. In addition, this fee also appears to dissuade

consumers from using debit cards at all: a fee that comprises less than 2% of the average purchase amount is associated

with a 12% reduction in the likelihood of using the card”. 304 Supra ¶ 550 (prohibition on debit line-fee or action-fee). 305 Wilko Bolt, Nikole Jonker & Corry Van Renselaar, Incentives at the Counter: An Empirical Analysis of Surcharging

Card Payments and Payment Behaviour in the Netherlands, 34 J. BANK. FIN. 1738 (2010): “[S]urcharging steers

consumers away from using debit cards towards cash”. 306 Simon, Smith & West, Price Incentives and Consumer Payment Behaviour, supra note 301, at 1771: “[P]rice

incentives, and loyalty programs in particular, can be influential when it comes to consumer decisions about which

payment instrument to use.”;

Santiago Carbo-Valverde & Jose Linares-Zegarra, How Effective are Rewards Programs in Promoting Payment Card

Usage? Empirical Evidence, 35 J. BANK. FIN. 3275, 3287 (2011): “[R]ewards programs can also significantly affect the

choice for cards relative to cash payments.”; Andrew T. Ching & Fumiko Hayashi, Payment Card Rewards Programs

and Consumer Payment Choice, 34 J. BANK. FIN. 1773 (2010). 307 Scott Schuh and Joanna Stavins, How Consumers Pay: Adoption and Use of Payments, at 3 (FRB of Boston working

paper 2-2012): “[C]onvenience, cost, and security affect payment use.”;

Borzekowski & Kiser, supra note 299, at 170: “Convenience is cited overwhelmingly as a main reason for using debit

cards.”;

Scott Schuh & Joanna Stavins, Why are (some) Consumers (Finally) Writing Fewer Checks? the Role of Payment

Characteristics, 34 J. BANK. FIN. 1745, 1747 (2010): "[P]ayment characteristics— especially convenience and cost—

are the most important determinants of payment use.";

Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 1253, at 12 n.9: “Recent studies have shown

that consumers are price sensitive.”;

Humphrey, Retail Payments: New Contributions, Empirical Results, and Unanswered Questions, supra note 250, at

1732: “[N]on-price characteristics of different payment instruments – especially convenience – have a significant

influence on consumer choice.”;

Gabriele Camera, Marco Casari & Stefania Bortolotti, An Experiment on Retail Payments Systems, ESI Working

Paper, at 2 (July 2015): “Convenience and reliability are among the suggested reasons for the growing popularity of

electronic payments in retail transactions”. 308 Scott Schuh and Joanna Stavins, How Consumers Pay: Adoption and Use of Payments, at 3 (FRB of Boston working

paper 2-2012): “[S]etup and record keeping are especially important in explaining adoption”. 309 For example, see Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1121, 653-54:

“[S]tudies have concluded that credit cards currently cost merchants substantially more than cash, checks, and PIN debit

card transactions on either a per-transaction or a per-dollar basis... For example, the purchase of a $1,000 item would

Page 71: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

71

pay a higher MSF for credit card than for debit card, but are also being paid later. Debit is a

faster and cheaper payment instrument for customers, who do not need the credit function, but

only use the payment feature ("transactors"), but if merchants do not price differently

according to the cost of the payment instrument, debit cardholders are not aware of that. In

Israel, debit cards and credit cards are issued by the same three companies. For these three

firms, debit cards signify pure cannibalization of their credit card business.

139. From a nation’s efficiency point of view, the payment instrument to be used should be the one

that imposes the lowest cost on society for a given level of benefits.310 Transactors, who do not

need the credit function of the card and need the card only as a payment instrument for

transactions, should definitely use debit instead of credit. The additional benefit of the credit

function is redundant for transactors.311 When transactors pay with credit card, merchants

needlessly get paid later and in addition pay a higher MSF.

140. I will now highlight a few major costs and benefits of cash and cards.

5.3. Cash

141. The direct cost of producing cash lies entirely with the state. The state, through the central bank,

bears significant costs of printing, transporting, handling and securing cash, as well as costs of

labor and brick and mortar. On the other hand, the state earns seigniorage when it prints cash,

which is a cost to all users other than the state.312

142. Cash users may have to bear direct costs, such as withdrawal fees, to obtain cash. Fees create

income for banks, but are not real resources of production, and therefore are excluded from the

social costs of cash. Real resources devoted to cash, such as ATM deployment costs, safes,

cost a merchant $19.00 if paid with a credit card, but between $0.17 and $1.00 if paid by PIN-debit card (depending on

the size of the retailer), and $0.12 if paid by cash”. 310 Hayashi & Keeton, Measuring the Costs of Retail Payment Methods, supra note 254, at 3: "For a nation’s retail

payment system to be efficient, the payment methods used by consumers, businesses, and government entities should be

those that impose the lowest cost on society for a given level of benefits". 311 Simon, Smith & West, Price Incentives and Consumer Payment Behaviour, supra note 301, at 1763. 312 Tom Fish & Roy Whymark, How has Cash Usage Evolved in Recent Decades? What Might Drive Demand In The

Future?, 3 BANK OF ENGLAND Q. BULL., at 2-3 (2015): "As discussed above, a banknote that is sold by the Bank to the

commercial sector is paid for via an electronic funds transfer to the Bank. The Bank invests the funds received into an

interest-bearing asset, such as a government bond. The Bank therefore receives interest income from the assets, yet pays

no interest on the corresponding liability (the banknote). Once the costs of banknote production and issuance have been

deducted from this income, the net income earned — referred to as ‘seigniorage’ — is passed on to HM Treasury. This

amounted to £506 million in 2014–15.";

Górka, Payment Behaviour in Poland, supra note 255, at 19: “By issuing cash the central bank earns revenues called

seigniorage. Cash is the direct source of finance and non-interest bearing liability of the central bank... From the

perspective of all entities other than the central bank, seigniorage can be perceived as a quasi tax”.

Page 72: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

72

alarms, armored vehicles, security guards, vaults, counterfeit-detection means and other

security devices (including the associated labor), are part of the social costs of cash. Cash users

also incur indirect costs to obtain cash, such as time at the bank or at the ATM. These are costs

of cash which are hard to quantify.313

143. Customers often find cash handy for use, simple and fast. Cash also enables the payer to "feel

the money" that is spent, and thus helps monitoring expenditures.314 Especially for small value

transactions, cash is perceived as a faster, cheaper, safer and more favorable payment

instrument.315 However, as technology improves, the costs of electronic money, such as

payment cards, decrease. At the same time the costs of labor and physical inputs associated

with cash increase. The transaction size below which cash is cheaper than cards constantly

declines. Recent studies in Europe have found that cash is cheapest only for coin-sized

transactions.316 Above that amount debit is more efficient.317

144. Cash is less dependent on technology, computers or electricity. Its survivability is higher. Cash

is a legal tender. Its acceptance is assured by law. Cash is used more often when customers'

313 Górka, id. at 17-18. 314 Arango, Hogg & Lee, Why Is Cash (Still) So Entrenched?supra note 297; Ulf von Kalckreuth et al., Using Cash to

Monitor Liquidity – Implications for Payments, Currency Demand and Withdrawal Behavior (Deutsche Bundesbank

Discussion Paper No. 22, 2011). 315 Carlos Arango, Kim P. Huynh & Leonard Sabetti, Consumer Payment Choice: Merchant Card Acceptance Versus

Pricing Incentives, 55 J. BANK. FIN. 130, 130 (2015): “Small value transactions, which typically form a substantial

share of payments in an economy, are overwhelmingly settled in cash”; id. at 139: “We find that consumers use cash

because it is easy to use and widely accepted.”;

Naoki Wakamori & Angelika Welte, Why do Shoppers use Cash? Evidence from Shopping Diary Data, at 33 (Bank of

Canada WP 2012-24. 2012): “[C]urrent cash usage is driven by demand-side factors – consumers prefer using cash, in

particular, for small-value transactions”. 316 Nicole Jonker, Social Costs of POS Payments in the Netherlands 2002–2012: Efficiency Gains from Increased Debit

Card Usage, 2 DNB Occasional Studies, at 32 (2013): “[T]he average variable social costs for cash payments increased

from EUR 0.18 to EUR 0.26 between 2002 and 2009, whereas the average variable social costs for a debit card payment

fell slightly from EUR 0.20 to EUR 0.17. Moreover, the results reveal that in 2009 the variable social costs for an

additional cash payment exceeded the variable social costs for an additional debit card payment for transaction sizes

above EUR 3.06. In 2002 the break-even point below which cash was more economical than the debit card was much

higher, i.e. EUR 11.63 (Brits and Winder, 2005). The downward shift of the break-even point is the result of both the

increase in the variable social costs per cash payment and the decrease in the variable social costs per debit card

payment. It seems likely that the actual break-even point was even lower than EUR 3.06.The variable social costs for

banks and retailers include fees paid to other companies, such as to the ACH, telecom companies, terminal providers for

debit card payments and cash-in-transit companies for cash payments. These companies fees are intended to cover both

their fixed and variable costs. Furthermore, these fees probably also included a profit margin. Therefore, in reality, the

variable costs of the services incurred by these companies were probably lower than the sum of their fees. Especially for

debit card payments, because fees make up a larger share of the variable costs for debit card than for cash payments. In

addition, it is likely that the break-even point has continued its decline since 2009, as IT developments have made

debit card payment processing even more efficient. Our findings for the Netherlands correspond very well with recent findings for Denmark and Sweden. Kaas Jacobsen and Molgaard Pedersen (2012) report EUR 3.90 in Denmark in 2009 as the break-even point between payments in cash and by domestic Dankort debit card, which closely matches our EUR 3.06. And also Sweden shows a considerable decline of the break-even point between cash and debit card payments between 2002 and 2009, from SEK 72/EUR 7.80 in 2002 (Bergman et al, 2007) to SEK 20/EUR 1.88 in 2009 (Segendorf and Jansson, 2012)”. 317 Supra note 279.

Page 73: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

73

perceptions are that merchants do not accept cards. Cash is also a final and immediate payment

instrument.318

145. Private costs of cash include deposit and withdrawal fees. Cash exposes its users to risks such

as theft, robbery and counterfeiting, and requires security measures. Human error is also a risk

of handling cash exchanges.319 Cash involves risks of embezzlement and demands constant

counting, registration and monitoring. Other costs for cash users include foregone interest on

cash held.320

146. Indirect costs of cash to customers and merchants include, inter alia, time required to obtain

cash and extra time required for cash transactions at the counter. For merchants, this time is

translated into labor costs of employees and is somewhat easier to quantify than the value of

customers' time.

147. Cash has the advantage of anonymity that does not exist in electronic money.321 This advantage,

however, has a downside, as it facilitates the black economy.322 According to Visa, 21% of the

318 Arango, Hogg & Lee, Why Is Cash (Still) So Entrenched?supra note 297, at 2: “1. Cards are perceived by consumers

as not being widely accepted. Indeed, where cash, debit and credit are all accepted, consumers are 30 per cent less likely

to use cash. Cash use is especially high for transactions below $25, where perceived card acceptance is substantially

lower. 2. Cash has several characteristics that make it more appealing to consumers than other payment methods. In

particular, consumers prefer to use cash because they find it fast, cheap, safe against fraud and convenient for budget-

control purposes. Ease of use or speed, in particular, accounts for at least a third of the share of cash payments for

transactions below $25”; see also HAVAADA LEBHINAT TZIMZUM HASHIMUSH BEMEZUMAN BAMESHEK HAISRAELI

[THE COMMITTEE FOR EXAMINING REDUCTION OF CASH USAGE IN THE ISRAELI MARKET] (THE LOCKER COMMITTEE),

FINAL REPORT, at 38 (July 17, 2014). 319 Carlos Arango & Varya Taylor, Merchants’ Costs of Accepting Means of Payment: Is Cash the Least Costly? 2008

BANK OF CANADA REV. 15, 16 (2008): “However, cash exposes the merchant to the risk of theft, robbery, and

counterfeiting, as well as the risk of human error during the exchange. Security measures (e.g., surveillance cameras

and security guards), secure storage (vaults and cash registers), and investment in counterfeit-detection training are

necessary fixed costs associated with cash.”;

Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: What is the Optimal Balance between Merchant Fee

and Payment Card Rewards?, at 6 (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No. 08-06. 2008); Timothy J. Muris, Payment

Card Regulation, supra note 176, at 538: “[C]ash, for instance, imposes costs on retailers and consumers that electronic

payment systems do not. One example is the labor cost associated with counting cash and reconciling the cash register

drawer. As labor costs increase, the cost of cash payments to retailers becomes more expensive relative to electronic

payments. In addition, cash has a higher risk of theft and loss for both consumers and merchants (from employee

malfeasance). The costs associated with collecting and transporting cash safely, most notably armored cars, do not exist

for payment cards". 320 Steven Semeraro, Assessing the Costs & Benefits of Credit Card Rewards: A Response to Who Gains and Who Loses

from Credit Card Payments? Theory and Calibrations, at 27 (2012) 321 Supra note 297. 322 Van Hove, Central Banks and Payment Instruments: A Serious Case of Schizophrenia, supra note 261, at 35: “One

of the great benefits of cash is its anonymity and untraceability. However, the downside is that it is precisely these

features that make cash so popular in the underground and criminal economy.”; Górka, Payment Behaviour in Poland,

supra note 255, at 14: “It turns out that almost 2/3 of Poles want to be anonymous at Points-Of-Sale… For others

anonymity is important because they work in a shadow economy.”; see also Hasan, Martikainen & Takalo, Promoting

Efficient Retail Payments in Europe, supra note 248; COMMITTEE FOR REDUCING THE USE OF CASH (LOCKER

COMMITTEE), FINAL REPORT, supra note 318.

Page 74: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

74

GDP in Israel is not reported.323 This is an estimated black market of almost NIS 200 billion

annually. Card transactions combat black economy. Every card transaction is passed through

the network and is registered and traceable.324 In Israel a special committee was nominated for

this exact issue.325

148. The implication to our context is that cardholders who value anonymity, need to dispose of cash

or belong to the "cash economy", have strong cash preference at the time of the transaction.

Those customers might not be affected by steering attempts to other payment instruments, no

matter the level of rewards bestowed on them. Trying to steer those cash-lovers to card usage

would be futile, and expenditures on steering efforts would be spent for vain. Recent empirical

studies strengthen this conclusion with the finding that cash possessors tend to deplete the cash

they possess, and not use cards, until the cash is consumed.326

5.4. Payment Cards

Costs

149. Costs of producing payment cards are carried by the card networks. The networks cover their

costs with income from their customers, merchants and cardholders. The marginal cost of a

debit card transaction is relatively small. In Netherlands, merchants pay an average debit MSF

of 4.5 Eurocent on average.327 Even if the Netherlands is more competitive than other countries,

it is reasonable to assume that Dutch acquirers do not operate at a loss, so the Dutch costs of

acquiring must be lower than 4.5 Eurocent. Naturally, networks in other countries have different

cost, but nevertheless the Netherlands can serve as a benchmark for estimating the marginal

cost of a debit card transaction.

150. The main variable cost of a payment card transaction for merchants is the MSF. Other costs for

merchants are terminals and POS's equipment, hardware and software to read cards (fixed cost),

323 Dror Reich, Summary of Conference on Payment Cards, THEMARKER (Sept. 22. 2011). 324 Virag Ilona Blazsek, The 2009 Interchange Fee Decision of the Hungarian Competition Authority: A Comparative

Case Study, Central European University, at 10 (2010): “[P]ayment card industry can contribute to the fight against

hidden economy.”;

Hasan, Martikainen & Takalo, Promoting Efficient Retail Payments in Europe, supra note 248, at 14: "Furthermore,

there should be direct interventions that discourage cash use. For example, large value cash transactions should be made

void in the EU, and the European Central Bank should reassess the need to have 200 and 500 euro banknotes". 325 COMMITTEE FOR REDUCING THE USE OF CASH (LOCKER COMMITTEE), FINAL REPORT, supra note 318, see also supra

¶ 549. 326 Supra note 290. 327 Nicole Jonker, Card Acceptance and Surcharging: The Role of Costs and Competition, 10 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1,

20 (2011): “[T]he merchant service fee for debit card payments in the Netherlands averages about 4.5 eurocent, which

is low compared internationally”.

Page 75: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

75

and chargebacks, costs of disputes, and costs of fraud not covered by the networks (variable

cost). The cost of cards for cardholders is the cardholder fee minus the rewards.

151. Cardholders and merchants also carry indirect costs of payment cards such as time in the bank

for filling forms and other paperwork. For the merchant time can be translated to labor costs.

Variable time costs of card may be low, especially if payments with cards are faster than

payment with cash. For example, card payers in gas stations do not have to go to the cashier.328

On the other hand, in very small transactions, leaving a coin on the counter is sometimes faster.

Benefits

152. Cards leave identity tracks and records of payment patterns. This allows merchants to

communicate with their card customers and offer them tailored offers.329 Similar to other

marketing activities, merchants incur costs providing such offers, and the benefit is shared by

both cardholders and merchants.330 Customers value payment card acceptance as an element of

quality service.

153. Debit resembles cash in that it limits consumers from overspending.331 This might be an

advantage for some consumers and a disadvantage for others. Credit cards (and deferred debit,

to a lesser degree); carry the benefit of expanding the budget constraint. Deferred debit is a

short-term credit with a grace period of zero interest. Deferred debit allows the cardholder to

concentrate monthly expenditures to a single payment day. Cardholders who pay their balance

in full every month enjoy an interest free period averaging half a month.332 However, deferred

debit might create an expenditure shock if purchases with the card are not monitored properly,

especially if the cardholder suffers a parallel income shock.

328 GAO-10-45, supra note 28, at 31: “[C]ustomers at gas stations and other retail stores often can pay for purchases

without necessarily interacting with an employee”. 329 id. at 30: “For example, if cardholders purchased particular items, their next billing statement would include offers

for additional discounts on future purchases at specific merchants that accept their card that also sell such items. The

networks reported that through their respective databases, they help merchants identify and better understand their

prospective, current, and lapsed customers and employ a variety of niche marketing approaches that ultimately serve to

increase sales”. 330 Shampine, An Evaluation of the Social Costs of Payment Methods Literature, supra note 252, at 8: “[E]lectronic

payment methods may allow merchants to more precisely track their customers’ identities and purchase patterns, and

potentially to obtain other data on the customer that might allow, say, targeted marketing. It seems as plausible to

include such a “benefit” as to include the “benefit” to cardholders of assistance with budgeting”. 331 M. Anthony Fusaro, Why do People use Debit Cards: Evidence from Checking Accounts, 51 Econ. Inquiry (2013). 332 GAO-10-45, supra note 28, at 4; IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD

SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note 21, at 13.

Page 76: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

76

154. Illiquid cardholders, who have preferences for purchases in the present, derive unique benefits

from credit cards. Credit cards offer purchase opportunities that do not exist neither with debit

nor cash nor deferred debit. Credit cards help to smooth consumption over time, and advance

consumption ahead of income.

155. For merchants, credit cards are a superior substitute to the more expensive, ancient and

unsecured "store credit". Credit cards enable merchants to extend credit to their customers,

without risk.333 Accepting credit cards may also expand revenue at the expense of rival

merchants who do not accept cards.

156. Payment cards yield another benefit for merchants. Studies have found that customers are

willing to pay more for the same product, when they pay with cards. The main reasons proffered

for this behavior are the lack of self-control and the vague feeling of the expenditure when made

by card. In addition, credit buyers were found to underestimate the true cost of interest on credit

purchases. The payment with a plastic card, and not with real notes, blunts the payment feeling,

and increases willingness to pay.334

157. Credit card acceptance might increase present sales not only at the expense of competing

merchants, but also at the expense of future acquisitions, both within other merchants and in

the same storehouse as well. However, the conventional wisdom is that accepting credit cards

does not increase the overall revenue of merchants, because credit cards do not increase

consumption on aggregate level.335

333 GAO-10-45, supra note 28, at 30: "Accepting credit cards also allows merchants to make sales on credit at a

generally lower cost than operating their own credit program". 334 Adam J. Levitin, The Antitrust Super Bowl: America's Payment Systems, No-Surcharges Rules And The Hidden

Costs Of Credit, 3 BERKELEY BUS. L.J. 265, 288 (2005): “Not only will consumers shift more of their purchases to

credit, but they will also make more purchases because they feel less constrained in credit spending than they do when

spending cash on hand. An MIT study found that when Sloan School of Management MBA students, a financially

savvy subject group, bid on sporting events tickets using either cash or credit, they were willing to place bids up to 64%

higher when bidding with credit than with cash... Credit cards distort consumers' cost benefit analysis and increase

consumers' willingness to pay for goods and to make purchases they otherwise would not. When purchasing with credit

cards, consumers will pay more to get the same goods and services or pay more to acquire goods and services of

marginal value to them.”;

Santiago Carbo-Valverde & Jose Linares-Zegarra, How Effective are Rewards Programs in Promoting Payment Card

Usage? Empirical Evidence, supra note 306, at 3275: “Most of these behavioral studies show significantly large and

positive effects of incentive programs for general purchases… studies with data on consumer transactions to compare

the spending of consumers who paid with credit cards with those who used cash or checks, and they find that the former

spend more”. 335 Sujit Chakravorti, Externalities in Payment Card Networks: Theory and Evidence, 9 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1, 9

(2010): “In the long run, aggregate consumption over consumers’ lives may not differ because of access to credit, but

such access may increase consumers’ utility.";

Katz, What do we Know about Interchange Fees, supra note 207, at 128: “[B]y accepting particular payment cards, a

merchant may increase its sales but do so at the expense of rival merchants. Thus, the collective benefits of a

Page 77: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

77

158. Other strands in the literature opine that credit cards can have an effect on aggregate

consumption. One strand takes the position that card acceptance might increase total

consumption. The second strand takes the opposite position: that card acceptance might

decrease total consumption.

159. According to the first strand, if the merchant’s net benefit from cards is higher than the MSF,

then card acceptance leads to cost savings for merchants. Cards save costs of cash. Credit

transactions save the avoided costs of expanding store credit. In addition, if merchants manage

to attract customers from their rivals because they accept cards, then fixed costs are allocated

between more sales, and this might decrease average costs and as a consequence, decrease retail

prices. This is likely to increase aggregate consumption.336 By the same logic, if payment cards

are more expensive than the alternative payment instrument, than prices tend to increase

because of card acceptance, and aggregate consumption decreases.337

160. The other strand does not concentrate on the effect of cards on merchants, but on the effect on

cardholders. Scholars of this strand argue that notwithstanding the price of cards to merchants,

credit cards seduce cardholders to purchase with what seems to be cheap credit, but is actually

expensive. The intrinsic “seduction by plastic”, unique to credit cards, increases the risk of

default.338 Especially when the debt is rolled into the following months, a larger share of income

merchant’s accepting payment cards may be much lower than the merchant’s individual benefits.”; see also infra note

404. 336 Steven Semeraro, Assessing the Costs & Benefits of Credit Card Rewards: A Response to Who Gains and Who Loses

from Credit Card Payments? Theory and Calibrations, at 33 (2012): “If credit card use and rewards increase consumer

spending, it could effectively lower retail prices. Higher sales levels would enable retailers to spread their fixed costs

over greater sales volume. This cost spreading and savings would tend to reduce retail prices.”;

Jean-Charles Rochet & Julian Wright, Credit Card Interchange Fees, 34 J. BANKING FIN. 1788 (2010): ”Interestingly,

the equilibrium retail price may decrease in the interchange fee. A higher interchange fee shifts more transactions to

credit cards from store credit which could potentially outweigh the effect of a higher cost of accepting credit cards if

store credit is particularly costly to accept.”; Fumiko Hayashi, Do U.S Consumers really Benefit from Payment Card

Rewards? FRB KANSAS ECON. REV. 37, 61 n.25 (2009); Semerraro, The Reverse Robin Hood Cross Subsidy

Hypothesis: Do Credit Cards Systems Tax the Poor and Reward the Rich? Supra note 288. 337 Kahn & Roberds, Why Pay? Introduction to Payment Economics, supra note 2, at 16: “While there seems to be

widespread agreement that electronic forms of payment offer the potential for greater efficiency, card-based payments

in particular have in many cases remained more expensive (for merchants) than paper alternatives.”;

Scott Schuh et al., Who Gains and Who Loses from Credit Card Payments? Theory and Calibrations, at 14 (FRB of

Boston Public Policy Discussion Papers No. 10-03. 2010): “The limited available data suggest that a reasonable, but

very rough, estimate of the per-dollar merchant effort of handling cash is ɛ=0.5 percent. Available data suggest that a

reasonable estimate of the merchant fee across all types of cards, weighted by card use, is µ = 2 percent.”; see also

Schmiedel, Kostova & Ruttenberg, The Social and Private Costs of Retail Payment Instruments, supra note 250, at 28;

Carl Schwartz et al., Payment Costs in Australia, table 11 at 117 (RBA and ACCC Publication for a Conference Held in

Sydney on Nov. 29, 2007). 338 John Vickers, Public Policy and the Invisible Price: Competition Law, Regulation and the Interchange Fee,

Payments Sys. Research Conference 231, 235-36 (2005): “Credit card spending, unlike most other forms of payment,

leads directly to debt, which is typically relatively expensive for the many who do not clear their balances in full within

the interest-free period. Of course, irrespective of the means of payment it uses, the change in a household’s net

indebtedness in any period is equal to its expenditure (including interest payments) less its income (including interest

Page 78: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

78

is used for debt repayment. The temptation to consume at the expense of incurring future debt

often has a social and economic long-term negative impact.339 As a result the economy

experiences fewer savings and less purchasing power.340 Inter-temporal buying power of

consumers is reduced and aggregate consumption and consumer-welfare declines.341

6. The Economic Models

6.1. Introduction

161. This chapter discusses the economic theories and models with regard to interchange fees and

related issues. I do not expand on all aspects of the various models, but focus on issues

concerning the interchange fee.

162. The validity and usefulness of economic models depends highly on their underlying

assumptions.342 Changes in the assumptions may lead to different results.343 The main

differences between the models discussed here, due to the differing underlying assumptions,

are: (a) heterogeneity/homogeneity of merchants and cardholders; (b) strategic considerations

of merchants; (c) allowing surcharging compared to NSR; (d) type of cardholder fee

(fixed/proportional); (e) conditions of competition.344

income). But means of payment can nevertheless influence the evolution of the mix of the household’s net liability

position. In particular, it is natural to expect that encouragement (for example, via the interchange fee) of means of

payment that are conducive to particular kinds of debt (in other words, credit card debt) will tend to increase such debt”. 339 Oren Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, 98 N.W. L. REV. 1373, 1403 (2004): “[M]ost consumers are not pure

transactors. As noted above, approximately three-quarters of credit-card holders borrow on their credit cards, and credit

card issuers make the bulk of their revenues from finance charges paid by these borrowers”. 340Id. at 1373; Levitin, Priceless? The Social Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 50, at 52; Oren Bar-

Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. PA. L. REV. 1, 46 (2008). 341 Hoze Linares-Zegarra & John O. S. Wilson, Risk Based Pricing in the Credit Card Industry: Evidence from US

Survey Data, at 2 (2012) http://ssrn.com/abstract=2141360: “[R]eliance on credit cards has led to an increase in

consumer indebtedness and a rise in personal bankruptcy.”; see also Levitin, Social Costs, ibid at 52; Vickers, supra

note 338, at 235-36; Fennee Chong, Credit Card Dues, Annual Summit on Business and Entrepreneurial Studies, 196,

201 (2011); Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 1135; Bar-Gill,

Seduction by Plastic, supra note 339; Tim Westrich & Malcolm Bush, Blindfolded into Debt: A Comparison of Credit

Card Costs and Conditions at Banks and Credit Unions, Woodstock Inst. (2005); Oren Bar-Gill & Ryan Bubb, Credit

Card Pricing: The Card Act and Beyond, 97 CORNELL L. REV. 967 (2012); IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY &

COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note 21, at 26.

For criticism of this approach see Daniel Garcia-Swarz, Robert W. Hahn & Anne Layne-Farrar, Further Thoughts on

the Cashless Society: A Reply to Dr. Shampine, 6 REV. NETWORK ECON. 509, 516-18 (2007). 342 Robin A. Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks: Economics, Industry Developments, and

Policy Issues, at 21 (F.R.B. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 23-09, 2009): “The conclusions of the theoretical

literature vary substantially depending on the assumptions underlying the models”. 343 Fumiko Hayashi & Stuart E. Weiner, Interchange Fees in Australia the U.K and the United States: Matching Theory

and Practice, FRB KANSAS ECON. REV. 75, 80-86 (2006) (comparison table between results of models according to

their underlying assumptions). 344 Marc Rysman & Julian Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, at 10 (2015): “Key differences across these

models are whether (i) they allow for merchants to be heterogenous, (ii) whether they allow for merchant

Page 79: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

79

163. When assuming homogeneous merchants or cardholders, there will be always full acceptance

or full rejection – as all merchants or cardholders respond identically. Relaxing this assumption

and allowing heterogeneity enables partial acceptance or denial, and thus allows for over-usage

or under-usage of card transactions.345 Models also differ in the structure of fees and profits

(fixed or proportional fees/profits), the degree of network competition and competition between

payment instruments.346

164. I will concentrate on the models, where the underlying assumptions fit reality, i.e., models

assuming fixed annual cardholder fees, no per-transaction cardholder fees, rewards for card

usage (especially for heavy users), no surcharging and multihoming merchants. For the most

part I will assume ad-valorem MSF and interchange fees, although, in some countries, those

fees for debit are fixed per transaction, irrespective the size of the transaction.

165. The first model that explained the role of the interchange fee was created in 1983 by Professor

Baxter.347 It was an unrealistic but simple model, based on assumptions of perfect competition.

Despite its simplicity, the basic insights of the model remain useful until today. The

methodology that MasterCard presented to the European Commission to justify its interchange

fee was based on this model of Baxter.348 The methodology that was presented by the Visa

companies in Israel, i.e., the interchange fee as a tool to balance the alleged deficit of issuers,

was also largely based Baxter's model.349

internalization, (iii) whether cardholder pricing is restricted to usage pricing, fixed (or annual) fees or two-part tariffs

that combine both, and (iv) whether they allow for competing platforms”. 345 Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 1253, at 18: “When heterogeneity is

considered, there can be an underuse or overuse of card payments from the point of view of the social planner. If that is

taken as given, the volume-maximising, the profit-maximising and the welfare-maximising interchange fees are not

equal.”;

Santiago Carbo Valverde et al., Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation, at 10 (Federal Reserve

Bank of Chicago Working Paper No. 09-11. 2009): “In reality, there is heterogeneity among consumers and merchants

regarding the level of benefits they derive from payment cards”; Luis Cabral, Market Power and Efficiency in Card

Payment Systems: A Comment, 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 15, 19-21 (2005). 346 Sujit Chakravorti & Roberto Roson, Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Case of Payment Networks, 5

REV. NETWORK ECON. 118, 119-20, 128, 138 (2006). 347 Infra ch. 6.2. 348 Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 1027, para. 703: “The Baxter framework, on

which MasterCard relies...”. 349 AT 4630/01 Leumi v. General Director, at 6-11 (Aug. 31, 2006) ("The Methodology Decision"). See also supra ¶

488.

Page 80: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

80

166. It took nearly two decades, until the early 2000s, before Baxter’s model was further developed

by Professor Schmalensee.350 Schmalensee explained the role of the interchange fee as a

balancing device between the demands of merchants and those of cardholders.351

167. Rochet & Tirole were the first to explain that even though a balancing device, the interchange

fee nevertheless raises competitive concerns.352 They were first to model the strategic

considerations of merchants, i.e., merchants' fear of losing customers, if merchants surcharge

or do not accept cards. Strategic considerations reduce the resistance of merchants to increases

in the interchange fee. Rochet & Tirole argued that because of these strategic considerations,

merchants are often willing to accept cards, even when high interchange fees cause the MSF to

be above the benefits merchants gain from cards. Nevertheless, they argued that interchange

fees may still be pro-competitive. This is because the interchange fee serves as a mechanism

that restrains market power of issuers, and solves a problem of under-usage of cards.353

168. Later models revised certain assumptions that characterized earlier models. I will review

models that discuss the neutrality of the interchange fee and implications of releasing the

NSR;354 models that discuss implications of network competition on interchange fees;355

models that discuss rewards (financed by interchange fees), which are bestowed on cardholders,

and the relations between rewards and cardholders fees;356 models that discuss the credit

function latent in credit cards but not in debit cards, and its implications on the interchange

fee,357 and models that tried to locate the optimal interchange fee.358 There is also literature

surveying the models.359

350 Evans & Schmalensee, The Economics of Interchange Fees and their Regulation, supra note 1119, at 75: "In 1983,

William Baxter... published an important paper on the economic rationale for interchange fees. But after the NaBanco

decision, interchange fees faded from view in academic and policy circles and was a topic of interest mainly to industry

insiders. A few academic papers in the 1990s mentioned interchange fees, but for the most part, this topic languished in

obscurity until around the turn of this century”. 351 Richard Schmalensee, Payment Systems and Interchange Fees, 50 J. INDUS. ECON. 103 (2002); see also infra ch. 6.3. 352 Infra ch. 6.4. 353Id. 354 Infra ch.6.5. 355 Infra ch. 6.6. 356 Infra ch. 6.7. 357 Infra ch. 6.8. 358 Infra ch. 6.9 359 Sujit Chakravorti, Theory of Credit Card Networks: A Survey of the Literature, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 50 (2003);

Wilko Bolt & Sujit Chakravorti, Economics of Payment Cards: A Status Report, 32 ECON. PERSPECTIVES 15 (2008);

Jean Charles Rochet, The Theory of Interchange Fees: A Synthesis of Recent Contributions, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 97

(2003); Jean Charles Rochet, Competing Payment Systems: Key Insights from the Academic Literature (Paper Prepared

for the Payments System Review Conference, 2007); Chakravorti, Externalities in Payment Card Networks: Theory and

Evidence, supra note 335, at 9; Marianne Verdier, Interchange Fees in Payment Card Systems: A Survey of the

Literature, 25 J. ECON. SURVEYS 273 (2011) ; Richard Schmalensee, Interchange Fees: A Review of the Literature, 1

PAYMENT CARD ECON. REV. 25 (2003).

Page 81: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

81

169. All models are based on the costs and benefits of the different payment instruments which I

explained above.

6.2. The model of Baxter - balancing costs

170. In 1983, in a pioneering article, Prof. William Baxter was the first to analyze an open system

of payment cards.360 He was the first to recognize that a payment card transaction is a two-sided

transaction that involves simultaneously two customers from two different groups – a

cardholder and a merchant: "A transaction is a two-sided arrangement".361 Baxter explained

that payment card networks must cover their costs through the fees they collect from both of

these groups. However, there is no requirement that cardholders pay the exact cost of issuance

and merchants pay the exact cost of acquiring. One side, in which the benefits exceed the cost,

can transfer an (interchange) fee to cover any uncovered costs, i.e., a “deficit”, of the other

side.362

171. Competitive equilibrium in “regular” products occurs when price equals marginal cost

(P=MC).363 In Baxter's model, the sum of the marginal costs of acquirers and issuers equals the

sum of cardholder fees and the MSF, i.e., the price level.364 Therefore:

Pm+Pc=Ci+Ca

Pc - price for customer, i.e., Cardholder fee,

Pm – price for the merchant, i.e. the MSF,

Ci – cost for the issuer,

Ca – cost for the acquirer.

Bc – net benefit to the customer from card transaction

Bm – net benefit to the merchant from card transaction

360 Rysman & Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, supra note 344, at 22: “In an article that was well ahead of its

time, Baxter (1983) provided the first formal modeling of interchange fees”. 361 William F. Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper: Legal and Economic Perspectives 26 J.L. ECON. 541,

548 (1983). 362Id. at 552. 363 DENNIS W. CARLTON & JEFFREY M. PERLOFF, MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION (4th ed. 2005): “[T]he optimal

(profit maximizing) production rule for a competitive firm is to expand its output until its marginal output, MC, equals

price, p.”;

Katz, What do we Know about Interchange Fees, supra note 207, at 127: "In a non-two-sided market, a rule that sets

price equal to marginal cost does define the unique efficient price.";

Semeraro, Assessing the Costs & Benefits of Credit Card Rewards: A Response to Who Gains, supra note 336, at 64:

“In a typical one-sided market, an efficient price – one that will lead to an optimal consumption level – will generally

approximate the marginal cost of production plus the profit necessary to attract investment to the industry. This pricing

model is efficient because it maximizes short-run output consistently with the producer earning sufficient revenue to

continue providing the product or service”. 364 Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper, supra note 361, at 553: “The sum of the two revenue streams

equals the sum of the two marginal cost streams”.

Page 82: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

82

172. Baxter’s model can be illustrated with an example. The numbers in the example are taken from

the article of Schmalensee.365 The numbers are just an example, and could be replaced by any

other numbers that will bring different and even opposite results.

173. Suppose the cost of issuance is 2 (Ci=2), and the cost of acquiring is also 2 (Ca=2). Suppose

the benefit to a customer from a payment card is 1 (Bc=1), so 1 is the maximum cardholder fee

she/he is willing to pay (Pc=1). Lastly, let the benefit to the merchant (Bm), which is the

maximum MSF the merchant is willing to pay for card acceptance, be 5 (Bm=5).

The merchant’s willingness to pay reflects the net benefit to the merchant gained because the

transaction is not carried out with a different payment instrument. i.e., the total net benefit card

payment generates (for the merchant) in comparison to alternative payment instruments, as

discussed in the previous chapter. Thus, Bm=5 is the merchant’s net transaction benefit

reflecting the benefit from avoiding costs of alternative payment instruments (e.g., avoided

costs of cash), plus any additional benefit the merchant gains from card usage (e.g., expanding

sales to illiquid customers). In other words, if the transaction were paid for with another

payment instrument and not a payment card, the merchant would incur an additional cost of

Bm. Baxter referred to the real transaction benefit of the merchant (Bm), as an upper bound to

the MSF. Baxter did not recognize any strategic benefits of cards.

174. In this example, even though the card transaction generates a social aggregate surplus of 2

(Bm+Bc-Ci-Ca=5+1-2-2=6-4), the transaction will never take place. The cardholder is only

willing to pay the issuer a maximum cardholder fee of 1 (Pcmax=1 because Bc=1), which is less

than the minimal cardholder fee by which the issuer covers its costs (Ci=2).

175. An interchange fee of 1 (IF=1), from the acquirer to the issuer, changes the picture and enables

the transaction. There is no rule that the issuer’s costs be covered only by cardholders, e.g., in

the form of direct cardholder fee. If the acquirer would charge the merchant MSF=3 (or Pm=3),

of which the acquirer would remit 1 to the issuer as interchange fee (IF=1), and in addition the

issuer would charge a cardholder fee of 1 (Pc=1) which the cardholder is willing to pay, as

Bm=1, all costs would be covered. The merchant would pay the acquirer a MSF=3, of which 2

covers the acquirer’s cost, and the acquirer would transfer 1 to the issuer as an interchange fee

(IF=1). We get:

365 Schmalensee, Interchange Fees: A Review of the Literature, supra note 359.

Page 83: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

83

Ca(2)= Pm(3)- IF(1)

And

Ci(2)=Pc(1)+IF (1)

176. If we add those equations, the interchange fee falls, and we get:

Ca+Ci=Pm+Pc=4

which means price level equals costs (P=MC), adjusted to a two-sided market. This is

equivalent to the competitive "one side" product equilibrium. The transaction, in this example,

generates a surplus of 2 for the merchant (Bm-Pm=5-3=2). The surplus is the result of efficient

card usage, i.e., the fact the transaction was performed with card and not with a more

expensive payment instrument.

177. Without an interchange fee, only if the benefit of the cardholder is 2 or more (Bc≥Ci) would

the transaction take place. This highlights the importance of the assumption of heterogeneity

among cardholders. When customers are homogeneous (and with no interchange fee), they will

either be cardholders, if their benefit is at least equal to the issuer’s costs (Bc≥2), or none of

them will be a cardholder if their homogeneous benefit from cards is less than the issuer’s costs

(Bc<2). But when customers are heterogeneous, even if their average benefit from cards is 1

(Bcavg=1), some customers will still become cardholders (those for whom Bc≥Ci=2 so they

agree to pay Pc≥2) without the need for an interchange fee.

178. Baxter enabled heterogeneity of both customers and merchants in his model. However, even

assuming heterogeneity, absent any subsidy from the merchant side, the price of payment cards

might be too expensive for enough customers (for whom Bc<Ci), so as to hold the network

atrophied. Indeed, customers for whom Bc≥2 would become cardholders, but if their number is

not big enough, the payment card network might not reach the critical mass necessary for it to

exist, or might operate in a degraded form with a too small a number of cardholders and

suboptimal card usage.

179. The above example is very simple, but it explains the role of the interchange fee as a balancing

device to cover costs of one side, using the surplus of the other side.

180. Baxter’s article was a breakthrough, but following its publication, with only few exceptions,366

interchange fee was ignored in literature for a long period. At the beginning of this century, a

366 Few worth noting exceptions are: Alan S. Frankel, Monopoly and Competition in the Supply and Exchange of Money

66 ANTITRUST L.J. 313 (1998); Carlton & Frankel, The Antitrust Economics of Credit Card Networks, supra note 97;

Page 84: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

84

new wave of writing on the topic emerged, accompanied by an increase in worldwide regulatory

involvement.367 The new concern was the result of three main factors: (1) Payment card usage

increased sharply, and cards became common means of payment. (2) The interchange fee

became a significant expense for merchants. In the U.S., merchants’ representative argued

before a Congressional committee that the interchange fee was their second largest expense,

after wages,368 and that credit cards cost merchants much more than cash.369 Merchants in other

parts of the world also resented the fees they paid. (3) The payment card industry has abnormal

high profits with respect to the rest of the financial sector.370 In Europe, payment cards were

found responsible for approximately a quarter of the profits of the retail banking sector.371 These

factors renewed the focus on interchange fees.

6.3. Interchange Fee To Balance Demands

181. Baxter’s model assumed that issuers and acquirers operated under conditions of perfect

competition. In Baxter’s model, the interchange fee does not produce profits to issuers, but only

serves to cover costs, because there is no profit in perfect competition.

182. The assumptions of Baxter did not match real world conditions. Both the acquiring side and

even more so the issuing side, are extremely profitable.372 Payment cards networks definitely

David S. Evans & Richard Schmalensee, Economic Aspects of Payment Card Systems and Antitrust Policy Toward

Joint Ventures, 2 ANTITRUST L.J. 861 (1995). 367 See supra ch. 0 (worldwide regulation survey). 368 Credit Card Fair Fee Act of 2009: Hearing before the Committee on the Judiciary House of Representatives 111th

Cong. on H.R. 2695, Serial No. 111–101 at 33 (2010): "[I]t can clearly be seen that credit card fees are our second-

largest expense. Only labor costs us more";

Ozlem Bedre-Defolie & Emilio Calvano, Pricing Payment Cards, 5 AM. ECON. J. MICROECONOMICS, at 206 (2013):

“Such fees are the second-highest expense for many businesses after labor costs, exceeding the price of health care

insurance for employees”. 369 GAO-10-45, supra note 28, at 31-32: “Credit card interchange fees result in credit card payments being more

expensive for them overall. For example, staff from one large retail chain told us that for a $100 transaction, a credit

card payment generally cost the company about 14 times as much to accept as cash. Other merchants reported that

transaction costs for credit cards were two to four times more than their transaction costs for cash”. 370 NICHOLAS ECONOMIDES, COMPETITION POLICY ISSUES IN THE CONSUMER PAYMENTS INDUSTRY, in MOVING

MONEY: THE FUTURE OF CONSUMER PAYMENT 113, 113 ( R. Litan & M. Baily eds., 2009): “Credit card networks have

high price-to-cost markups despite non dominant market shares. There is evidence of very significant markups of price

above cost, with total costs representing only 15 percent of revenue. It is highly unlikely that consumers receive from

card networks anything approaching the fee level charged to merchants. The implied profit rates are comparable to

those of Microsoft and Intel, which each have a dominant and almost monopoly market share”;

Westrich & Bush, Blindfolded into Debt: A Comparison of Credit Card Costs and Conditions at Banks and Credit

Unions, , supra note 341, at 4: “Credit card lending is one of the most profitable sectors in the financial services

industry, and many credit card banks have profits higher than such profitable companies as Microsoft and Wal-Mart”. 371 EC, INTERIM REPORT, supra note 278, at ii: “It is estimated that cards alone account for up to 25% of retail banking

profits”. 372 Ibid, see also supra ¶¶ 60, 96, 574.

Page 85: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

85

possess market power.373 The next step that was made in order to adapt models to reality was

carried out by Professor Schmalensee.374

183. Schmalensee allowed for imperfect competition between both acquirers and issuers. Formally,

while the price level in Baxter equaled costs (Pm+Pc=Ci+Ca), in Schmalensee’s model issuers

and/or acquirers had a fixed profit margin (m=margin). This profit increased the price level:

Pm+Pc=Ci+Ca+m.

184. In Schmalensee’s model the interchange fee affects the price structure.375 There is an inverse

relationship (trade-off) between the MSF and the cardholder fee. The interchange fee is

responsible for this trade-off:

184.1 The higher the interchange fee, the higher the MSF and the lower the number of

merchants who accept cards. However, concurrently, the higher interchange fee

generates more cardholders, because the cardholder fee is lower due to the subsidy

from the interchange fee. The changes on each side depend on the price elasticity of

that side.

184.2 Conversely, the lower the interchange fee, the lower the MSF. Merchants' demand is

higher (low MSF) but cardholders’ demand decreases, because they have to pay a

higher cardholder fee.376

185. The interchange fee in Schmalensee’s model is a tool designed to balance the different demands

of each side, given the costs and margins of the network, in order to maximize the value of the

payment card network. The idea is to optimize through the interchange fee the attractiveness of

the network to both cardholders and merchants.377 In the model of Schmalensee, the fees on

each side (MSF or Pc) can rise as high as the merchant’s or the cardholder’s benefits (Bm or

Bc).

186. I will illustrate the difference between Schmalensee and Baxter in a simple example. Suppose

again that Ci=Ca=2; Bc=1, Bm=5. Baxter’s interchange fee is 1. With an interchange fee of 1,

issuers cover their deficit from the low willingness of cardholders to pay for cards (the deficit

373 Supra ch. 8.3.1. 374 Richard Schmalensee, Payment Systems and Interchange Fees, supra note 351. 375 Supra ch. 2.4.2 (price level and price structure). 376 Richard Schmalensee, Payment Systems and Interchange Fees, supra note 351, at 107. 377Id. at 118: “The interchange fee is not an ordinary market price; it is a balancing device for increasing the value of a

payment system by shifting costs between issuers and acquirers and thus shifting charges between consumers and

merchants."

Page 86: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

86

is Ci-Pc=2-1=1). By contrast, Schmalensee’s interchange fee can be anywhere from 1 to 3

depending on the demand elasticities of cardholders and merchants, and on the degree of market

power of acquirers and issuers. As a result, the network could grow larger than in the model of

Baxter. For instance, if effect of an increase in the interchange fee above 1 is minimal on the

merchant side (i.e., only few merchants stop accepting cards), but the growth on the

cardholders’ side is significant when Pc<1, then a higher interchange fee than 1, which would

be used to induce usage (lower cardholder fee) would expand the network. Increase in the

interchange fee "sacrifices" some marginal merchants that would cease to accept cards, but on

the other side, there would be more cardholders who adopt and use their cards more often. When

the expansion on the cardholder side is bigger than the decline in the merchant side, the network

would increase with the interchange fee, until the expansion on the cardholder side (because of

the decrease in cardholder fees) would be offset in full by the loss from the merchant side

(because of the increase in the MSF).378

187. In the model of Schmalensee, the interchange fee can rise until the corresponding MSF equals

the merchant’s benefit (i.e. until Pm=Bm). Above that fee the merchant would stop accepting

cards and would accept other payment instruments (because they become cheaper than the net

benefit of cards). Using the numbers of the example above, the maximum interchange fee would

be 3, because then the MSF is 5 (2 is the cost of the acquirer, so the MSF is IF(3)+Ca(2)=5).

For any number above Pm= 5, the merchant would not accept cards.

188. Schmalensee acknowledged that the interchange fee that maximizes the profit of the network

is not necessarily the same interchange fee that maximizes social welfare.379 Schmalensee also

recognized that the interchange fee is a horizontal price-fixing agreement between competitors.

As such, it is a restrictive arrangement. Nevertheless, Schmalensee claimed that contrary to

price fixing that is intended to reduce output, the purpose of the interchange fee is to increase

output and welfare (including the welfare of issuers and acquirers).380 Therefore, according to

378 Jean Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Tying in Two-Sided Markets and the Honor all Cards Rule, 26 INT'L J. INDUS.

ORG. 1333, 1334 (2008): “The interchange fee must be high enough so as to induce consumers to use the card, but low

enough so as not to meet with merchant resistance”. 379 Richard Schmalensee, Payment Systems and Interchange Fees, supra note 351, at 106: “The privately optimal fee

may be above or below the socially optimal fee, and the difference does not turn on the level of market power”. For

expansion on the optimal interchange fee, see infra ch. 6.9. 380Id. at 118-19: “The first-order effect of fixing an ordinary price is to harm consumers by reducing output, while in a

non-extreme case, collective interchange fee determination maximizes output and Marshallian welfare in order to

maximize the system's private value to its owners”.

Page 87: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

87

Schmalensee, a positive interchange fee is pro-competitive and desirable. As a result,

Schmalensee questioned the effectiveness of regulatory intervention in the interchange fees.381

189. As already noted, conclusions of models highly depend upon the underlying assumptions. In

the model of Schmalensee, issuers could not raise the MSF to a level higher than the merchant’s

benefit, because merchants would simply cease to honor cards. According to Schmalensee, that

resistance by merchants is a natural barrier against setting the interchange fee too high.

190. A decisive majority of merchants do accept payment cards. We might therefore conclude that,

according to revealed preferences and the model of Schmalensee, the MSF paid by merchants

does not exceed their net benefit from accepting cards, because otherwise merchants would not

agree to accept cards. However, revealed preferences do not show the entire picture and cannot

establish this conclusion. This was demonstrated by professors Rochet & Tirole.

6.4. Rochet & Tirole – Strategic Considerations

191. Schmalensee ignored a critical point, which was developed by Professors Rochet and 2014

Nobel Prize winner Jean Tirole,382 in a pioneering article.383 Most merchants cannot afford to

not accept payment cards.

192. Earlier models, before Rochet & Tirole, considered the net benefit of merchants (Bm) from

accepting cards as an upper bound for the MSF. The common assumption was that if the MSF

(Pm) exceeds the merchant’s benefit from a payment card (that is if Pm>Bm), then the merchant

will simply refuse to accept cards. This assumption overestimates the power of merchants.

Merchants weigh further considerations, beside the price they pay for cards. Those

considerations weaken their ability to oppose an increase in the MSF, even to a level above

Bm.384

193. These considerations were initially called by Rochet & Tirole "strategic" considerations.385

Strategic considerations force merchants to accept cards for fear that refusing to accept cards

will result in severe desertion of customers and significant loss of income.386 When customers

381Id. at 119 382 Mika Kato, Jean Tirole, Nobel Prize Winner, (Aug. 28, 2015). 383Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card

Associations, 33 RAND J. ECON. 549, 549 (2002). 384Id. at 551. 385Id. at 558 (proposition 2): “The merchants' card acceptance policies exhibit strategic complementarity”. 386 Robert J. Shapiro & Jiwon Vellucci, The Costs of “Charging it” in America: Assessing the Economic Impact of

Interchange Fees for Credit Card and Debit Card Transactions, at 16 (2010): “[C]redit cards are so ubiquitous that

Page 88: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

88

want to pay with cards but the merchant does not accept cards, the harm to the merchant is

expressed not only in the disappointment of the customer that must pay with a different payment

instrument. The disappointed customer might be upset enough to leave the merchant, if not at

that same purchase then at the next one, and transfer purchases to other merchants that do accept

cards. This concern compels merchants to pay a higher MSF than their transaction benefit

(Pm>Bm).

194. The loss to merchants from losing the entire transaction is generally much bigger than the

damage from a high MSF. Profits of transactions often reach tens of percent, while the MSF is

a few percent at most. Klein gives an example that when the profit from a transaction is 25%

and the MSF is 2%, compared to 1.5% cost of the alternative payment method, it is enough that

2% of customers abandon the refusing merchant, to render card refusal unprofitable.387

195. Rochet & Tirole quantified the size of the strategic considerations. They argued that it is equal

to the benefit of the average cardholder from payment with cards. Merchants internalize the

average benefit of cards to their customers who are cardholders.388 Merchants are willing to add

this average benefit to the MSF. In the example above where Bm=5; Bcavg=1, merchants are

willing to pay MSF=Pm=6, although their net benefit is only 5. They internalize the benefit of

the average cardholder.

196. In later articles, the strategic considerations were considered by Rochet & Tirole as a "quality

of service" feature.389 Merchants internalize the benefits of cards to cardholders, and are willing

merchants cannot apply market pressures to bring down their fees by withdrawing from the major networks, at least not

without jeopardizing their sales”. 387 Benjamin Klein et al., Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Antitrust Economics of Payment Card Interchange

Fees, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 571, 586 (2006): “[T]he average potential transaction fee savings from dropping the Visa

credit card would be about 50 basis points (the difference between the 2 percent cost of Visa credit and the average of

non-Visa payment methods of 1.5 percent). Assuming this potential cost savings and an average merchant gross margin

of approximately 25 percent, a merchant need only experience a 2 percent decrease in the sales that would have been

made with Visa credit cards (or 1 in 50 sales) for it not to be profitable for the merchant to drop acceptance of Visa

credit”; Alan S. Frankel, Towards a Competitive Card Payments Marketplace, RBA 29 (2007). 388 Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among competitors, supra note 383, at 556: “In words a*, a is the level of the

interchange fee at which the net cost to the merchants is equal to the average cardholder benefit”; see also id. at 565: “In

the absence of unobserved heterogeneity among merchants, an increase in the interchange fee increases the usage of

payment cards, as long as the interchange fee does not exceed a threshold level at which merchants no longer accept

payment cards. At this threshold level, the net cost for merchants of accepting the card is equal to the average

cardholder benefit.”;

Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Must-Take Cards: Merchant Discounts and Avoided Costs, 9 J. EUR. ECON. ASS'N

462, 466 (2011); Fumiko Hayashi, A Puzzle of Card Payment Pricing: Why are Merchants Still Accepting Card

Payments?, 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 144, 147-48 (2006): “Rochet and Tirole (2002), Guthrie and Wright (2003, 2006),

and Wright (2003b, 2004) have found that if merchants compete against each other, they accept cards as long as the

merchant fees do not exceed the sum of the merchant’s transactional benefits and the cardholder’s average net

transactional benefits from cards”. 389 Marc Rysman & Julian Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, at 10 (2015): “Subsequent research (Farrell,

2006; Wright, 2010, 2012; Rochet and Tirole, 2011) has shown that merchant internalization is a much more general

Page 89: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

89

to pay in order to improve their customers’ experience, as part of their services to attract clients,

even if the service itself is a ‘money-losing proposition’:

It might seem at first sight that, because of the merchants’ individual ability to turn

down the card, there could never be too many card payments by cardholders. This

reasoning however is incorrect as it misses the point that merchants accept cards

not solely for the convenience benefits (fraud protection, accounting facilities, time

savings at the counter relative to check payments, transaction enablement through

credit and float) that they derive from card usage, but also because card acceptance

makes their store more attractive to consumers. That is, merchants realize that card

acceptance is part of their quality of service (QoS) package and accordingly

internalize, at least in part, the cardholders’ net benefit from being able to use their

card. Put differently, merchants may be willing to accept cards even if doing

so is a money-losing proposition from a narrow accounting viewpoint that is

when the merchant discount exceeds the convenience benefit they themselves

derive from card usage.390

197. In another article, Rochet & Tirole further emphasized this aspect of accepting cards, even

though the MSF is higher than the transactional benefit. They argued that their conclusion holds

regardless of the degree of competition between merchants, i.e. whether merchants are

competitive or monopolistic.391 In a more recent article to which Tirole contributed, the

emphasis of the strategic considerations was on the “missed sales” that would occur if

merchants surcharge or do not accept cards.392

198. It is interesting to note that the approach of Rochet & Tirole negates the low category of

interchange fee in Israel, applied to transactions with the state, its agencies and the electric

company. Those merchants enjoy a lower category of interchange fee (0.5%).393 According to

Rochet & Tirole, those merchants, regardless of their market power, enjoy the higher quality of

phenomenon, holding in some cases even when merchants are monopolistic, Cournot competitors or perfectly

competitive. Simply put, when a merchant accepts cards it is improving the quality of the service it offers consumers,

the option of using cards for payment, and it is only natural this allows it to charge a higher price. The more surplus it

can offer consumers the more it is willing to incur a cost to do so”. 390 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems 5 REV. NETWORK ECON.

1, 3 (2006). 391 Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards, supra note 388, at 463: “[R]etailers may be willing to accept cards even if the

fee they have to pay exceeds their convenience benefit for card payments. Accepting cards increases the retailer’s

quality of service by offering to his customers an additional payment option. This property holds whether retailers are

perfect competitors, Hotelling–Lerner–Salop competitors or even local monopolists. Thus it is not due to a hypothetical

prisoner's dilemma situation where retailers would accept cards only to steal business from each other”. 392 Hélène Bourguignon, Renato Gomes & Jean Tirole, Shrouded Transaction Costs, CEPR Discussion Paper no.

DP10171, at 3-4 (Sept. 2014): “[C]oncerns about missed sales induce merchants to perceive that they must take the

card... card refusal or a high surcharge may cause the merchant to lose business at the point of sale, a widespread

concern... A missed sale occurs when the customer is in the shop and eager to buy, but has a high inconvenience cost of

paying by cash, and is discouraged by either a high card surcharge or an outright rejection of the card.”; id. at 17: “As

our analysis reveals, concerns about missed sales are an important new rationale for the “must-take-card” argument. In

particular, the possibility of missed sales has been ignored in the card payment literature”. 393 Supra ch. 8.1.3.2 (merchants' categories).

Page 90: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

90

service to their customers, as any other merchant. This is another reason to cast doubt on the

justification of a lower interchange fee to those merchants.394

199. Hayashi refines this point. She claims that monopolistic merchants, who enjoy inelastic

demand, are not exposed to strategic considerations. Only these merchants will not accept cards

bearing a MSF that exceeds their net transaction benefit from cards (Bm).395

200. According to Rochet & Tirole, cardholders recognize the improvement in quality of service

latent in card acceptance. Cardholders increase their purchases at merchants that provide this

enhanced service. Rochet & Tirole compare card acceptance to other services that merchants

grant their customers to improve their quality of service and to increase sales, such as free

parking, more cashiers or free packing services.396

201. Strategic considerations may not only cause merchants to accept cards. They compel merchants

to keep accepting cards after initial adoption. If after penetration of payment cards to a sector

which was historically reluctant to accept cards, merchants in that sector realize that the fee

they pay is higher than the net benefit they derive from cards, they might find it impossible to

go back to square one and cease to accept cards without suffering heavy loses. The risk is that

their competitors will not cease to accept cards, and thereby attract their angry cardholders.

An empirical example is found in the Israeli market. Gasoline stations in Israel have low

margins because their retail prices (selling prices to customers) and wholesale prices (buying

prices from refineries) are both regulated. For gas stations, every percent of profit is significant.

This sector was late to adopt cards. When finally it did, it was mainly because the low

interchange fee that was offered to gas stations (0.5% - lowest category). Gas stations accepted

the low fees and practically all gas stations turned to be card accepting. However, in 2010, when

the categories of interchange fees in Israel were unified, the interchange fee that gas stations

394 Supra ¶¶ 533 - 546 (criticism of categories). 395 Hayashi, A Puzzle of Card Payment Pricing, supra note 388, at 149: ”[O]nly monopoly merchants who are facing an

inelastic consumer demand may not accept cards if the fees exceed the merchant’s transactional benefits. In the other

three markets, merchants accept cards even when the fees exceed their transactional benefits. As previous studies found,

competing merchants accept cards for strategic reasons. Merchants initially hope that their card acceptance can lure

customers away from their rivals, but later on they accept cards to keep their current customers. Even monopoly

merchants accept cards when their transactional benefits are lower than the fees they pay if they face an elastic

consumer demand. They do so not because they have a strategic reason but because card acceptance shifts their

cardholder customers’ demand upward and thus brings in incremental sales." 396 Rochet & Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems, supra note 390, at 6: “From the merchant’s

viewpoint, card acceptance is one of many decisions that affect the store’s attractiveness. For example, hiring more

cashiers or offering convenient parking imply a direct loss for the merchant, but increase the quality of service

(especially to time-conscious consumers) and attracts more shoppers to the store”.

Page 91: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

91

paid doubled from 0.5% to 1%.397 This caused a significant bite in their margins. The gas

stations filed suit against this increase, litigating all the way to the Supreme Court, without

success.398

The option of gas stations to cease acceptance of cards was not even considered. No single gas

station alone could stop accepting cards, although all found the new interchange fee excessive.

Of course, gas stations could not gather together and collectively decide to not accept cards, as

this would be a blatant restrictive arrangement. The result was that each gas station continued

to accept cards, although together they thought they were better off without them. This is a

classic example of the strategic considerations.

202. In my view strategic considerations is the correct definition to describe the pressure cards exert

on merchants. In competitive markets, services and products are sold at prices that are related

to costs of production. If merchants give their customers free parking or packing services, which

merchants buy at competitive prices, these can be viewed as improvements in the quality of

service by merchants to their customers. However, if merchants face cartelistic parking or

packing prices, they would probably not offer them to their customers for free, unless they are

forced to. These are exactly strategic considerations. If merchants are forced to purchase

services for their customers at cartel prices, then the purchase becomes strategic. It is not only

the improvement of service that merchants seek, but something else. As long as merchants must

take cards even though cards are a "money-losing proposition", as Rochet & Tirole suggest, the

correct comparison cannot be to quality improving services sold at competitive prices, which

merchants may (or may not) freely and unilaterally decide to grant. Merchants might find it

necessary to purchase free parking for their clients, but this in no way gives owners of parking

lots any legitimacy to coordinate prices, knowing merchants would still be forced to pay for

them.

203. Strategic considerations lead merchants to accept cards, despite a MSF that exceeds the net

benefit of the transaction (Pm> Bm). In the words of Vickers that were adopted by Rochet &

Tirole, cards are a "Must Take”.399

397 See ¶¶ 524.2, 155. 398 AT 601/06 Gas Companies Association v. Antitrust General Director (7.7.10); appeal denied in CivA 5529/10 Gas

Companies Association v. Antitrust General Director (12.8.10). 399 Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards, supra note 388, at 462; Vickers, Public Policy and the Invisible Price:

Competition Law, Regulation and the Interchange Fee, supra note 338 at 234 : “Especially in a number of lines of

retail, it would be substantially detrimental to a retailer’s business not to accept at least the cards of the two main

schemes, above all because the retailer would otherwise risk losing profitable business to rival retailers. In short, there

is an element of must-take”.

Page 92: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

92

When strategic considerations take place, the interchange fee is higher than without strategic

considerations.400 Strategic considerations force merchants to internalize the interests and

benefits of cardholders, in addition to the cardholders' own internalization of the benefits from

cards to themselves. This is a major asymmetry between merchants and cardholders.

Cardholders do not internalize the benefits merchants derive from cards. The result is that

strategic considerations of merchants actually reflect a double-representation of cardholders’

interests.401

204. In the model of Rochet & Tirole, accepting cards increases revenues of accepting merchants, at

the expense of competing merchants.402 However, in their model card acceptance does not

increase the total number of purchases. In their model, the number of transactions and their

volume is constant (and is equal to the product of the number of cardholders and the number

of merchants, because they assume each cardholder buys once at each merchant).403 This

assumption is consistent with the conventional wisdom that card acceptance does not increase

aggregate consumption, which is limited by budget constraint.404

400 Stewart E. Weiner & Julian Wright, Interchange Fees in various Countries: Developments and Determinants, 4 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 290, 313 (2005): “When merchants accept cards for strategic reasons, the interchange fee that

balances demands across cardholders and merchants so as to maximize card volume and profits for the members, will

be higher”. 401 Chakravorti, Externalities in Payment Card Networks: Theory and Evidence, supra note 335, at 5: “A key

asymmetry is that merchants accept cards to attract business, in addition to any convenience or transactional benefits

they obtain. Even if cardholders and merchants play an otherwise symmetric role, this asymmetry causes a network

operator to over-represent the interests of cardholders — once in attracting additional card users and once in attracting

additional merchants who internalize their customers’ card benefits. This can result in merchants being charged more

(and cardholders less) than is efficient reflecting the over-representation of cardholders’ interests when merchants

accept cards to get more business.”;

Julian Wright, Why Payment Card Fees are Biased Against Retailers, 43 RAND J. ECON. 761, 773 (2012): “The bias

given in Proposition 5 reflects that buyers’ surplus from using cards gets counted twice in the determination of the

monopoly interchange fee -once from the platform extracting buyers’ surplus from using cards and once from the

platform extracting sellers’ surplus from accepting cards, given individual sellers already internalize the buyers’ surplus

from using cards when deciding how much to pay to accept cards”. 402 Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations, supra note 383,

at 552: “A merchant's total benefit, and thus his decision whether to accept a card, then depends not only on his

technological benefit (fraud control, theft protection, speed of transaction, customer information collection, etc.), but

also on the product of the increase in demand due to system membership and its retail markup”. 403 Id. at 552. 404 Supra ¶ 157; Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 1027, para. 705; Andrea Amelio,

Antitrust Assessment of MIF and the Tourist Test, at 8 (Conference Proceeding, June 15, 2011): "[T]he benefits of

business stealing evaporate at an aggregate level"; MICHAEL L. KATZ, REFORM OF CREDIT CARDS SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA

II COMMISSIONED REPORT, at 19 Reserve Bank of Australia (2001): "First, an individual merchant’s benefits of card

acceptance arise only from sales transactions that would not have been made if the merchant did not accept cards.

Second, the merchants’ collective benefits may be zero because one merchant’s increased sales can come at the expense

of other merchants’ sales.";

Sujit Chakravorti & Roberto Roson, Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Case of Payment Networks,

supra note 346, at 139: "However, the aggregate welfare of merchants does not improve with business stealing because

net sales presumably remain constant.";

Page 93: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

93

In the model of Rochet & Tirole, card acceptance increases the demand for products of

merchants that accept cards at the expense of their competitors who do not, but card acceptance

does not the affect total consumption. Card acceptance inflicts private benefits to card accepting

merchants without any raise in total revenue for merchants as a whole.

205. Rochet & Tirole quantified the size of the strategic considerations, i.e. the size in which Pm can

be larger than Bm, but merchants will still accept cards. They claimed that the size reflects what

merchants perceive as the benefit of the average cardholder from paying with a card and not

another payment instrument (Bcavg).405 For example, if there are three customers, and the net

benefit for them from card usage over other payment instruments is 1, 2, 3, respectively

(Bcavg=2), then the merchant will consent to pay a MSF as high as Bm+2, to ensure its average

customer will not be disappointed enough to leave to another merchant.

206. Wright notes that if the cardholder already paid the cardholder fee that corresponds to her/his

utility (Pc=Bc), then the strategic considerations actually double the ability of the network to

extract the cardholder’s surplus from cards – one time it is extracted from the cardholder as

cardholder fees; the second time from the merchant in the form of strategic considerations that

force the merchant to internalize the cardholder’s benefit, in addition to the merchant’s own

benefit.406

207. Rochet & Tirole were the first to model the phenomenon of interchange fees that are affected

by strategic considerations. Since then, courts and authorities have recognized the phenomenon

of honoring cards because of strategic considerations.407 The exact role of the interchange fee

Harry Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees Generally Lead to Cash-Promoting Cross-Subsidisation, at 7 BANK OF

FINLAND RESEARCH DISCUSSION PAPERS (2011): "The instrument selection and palette will not affect the total volume

of payments made, which is determined by the budget constraints for consumption.”;

Vickers, Public Policy and the Invisible Price: Competition Law, Regulation and the Interchange Fee, supra note 338,

at 235: “The interchange fee could conceivably affect the mix of demand, but aggregate demand remains constrained by

supply capacity”. 405 Supra ¶ 195. 406 Supra ¶ 203. 407 United States v. Visa, 163 F. Supp. 2d 322, 337 (S.D.N.Y 2001): “Some merchants, including large, prominent,

national retail chain stores, such as Target and Saks Fifth Avenue, believe that if they were to stop accepting Visa and

MasterCard general purpose cards they would lose significant sales. Consequently, these merchants believe they must

accept Visa and MasterCard, even in the face of very large price increases.”; see also id. at 341: “The reality is that Visa

and MasterCard are able to charge substantially different prices for those hundreds of thousands of merchants who must

take credit cards at any price because their customers insist on using those cards.”;

Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 1027, paras. 506, 705;

Julian Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees in Payment Systems, 52 J. INDUS. ECON. 1, 17 (2004):

“"Where merchants accept cards for strategic reasons (that is, to attract additional business), there will be some

merchants who accept cards even though the transactional benefits they obtain are less than the merchant fees they

pay.”;

Page 94: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

94

in the presence of strategic considerations, in the basic model of Rochet & Tirole, with further

clarifications and developments made by them in later articles,408 would now be explained.

208. As in any model, also Rochet & Tirole have a number of simplifying assumptions. Their basic

model assumes a monopolistic card network, with numerous acquirers and issuers. They

assume that the volume of transactions is constant and merchants are homogeneous (in most of

the article). The acquirers are assumed to be competitive (no profits and full pass through rate

of the interchange fee to the MSF), but issuers do have a profit margin - m. The cardholder fee

is fixed per transaction. NSR rule applies (for most of the article). Cardholders are

heterogeneous in their net benefit from cards, compared to cash (because of differences in

accessibility of cardholders to cash).409 If the customer adopts a card and becomes a cardholder,

she always uses the card and not cash, unless the merchant refuses to accept cards.410

209. The condition for card adoption (and therefore, in the model of Rochet and Tirole, for usage

also) is Bc>Pc which means that net benefit from the card (Bc) should be bigger than the

cardholder fee (Pc). By definition the benefit of the marginal cardholder from her card

(Bcmarginal) is lower than the benefit of the average cardholder (Bc

avg). The marginal cardholder

might be thought of as the cardholder that has cash in her wallet, and is indifferent between

using cash or card.

210. Merchants internalize the benefit of the average cardholder.411 Merchants are willing to pay

MSF that is bigger than their net benefit (Bm) from cards, in the size of the strategic component

(Bcavg). The meaning of merchants' internalization is that merchants are compelled to pay

GAO-10-45, supra note 28, at 36: "[S]everal merchants told us that if they did not accept credit cards from Visa or

MasterCard, their sales would decrease and they would lose business to competitors that did accept those cards.”;

Credit Card Interchange Fees: Antitrust Concerns? Congress Senate Committee on Judiaciary, at 112 (Bill Douglass on

behalf of the National Association of Convenience Stores Before the U.S. Senate Committee on Judiaciary, July 19,

2006), at 112 (U.S. Government Printing Office, 2006): "I have to take these cards or I will go out of business. I have

no option. The comparison that fits is with the old AT&T – before the breakup. Visa and MasterCard's dominance is

very similar to the dominance of Ma Bell before the breakup of AT&T, and protestations by Visa and MasterCard that

merchants do not need to accept cards rings just as hollow as someone saying we could just choose not to have

telephone service. It simply ignores how business is done in this country. Accepting cards is necessary." 408 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets, 1 J. EUR. ECON. ASS'N 990 (2003);

Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, An Economic Analysis of the Determination of Interchange Fees in Payment Card

Systems, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 69 (2003); Rochet & Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems,

supra note 390; Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards, supra note 388; Jean Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Tying in Two-

Sided Markets and the Honor all Cards Rule, 26 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 1333 (2008); Jean Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole,

Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report, 37 RAND J. ECON. 645 (2006) . 409 Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations, supra note 383,

at 553: “[S]ome customers have easy access to cash or a low value of time for going to get cash before shopping." 410Id. at 552-53. 411 Supra ¶¶ 195, 205.

Page 95: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

95

interchange fee higher than their net benefit (IF>Bm).412 When issuers have market power part

of the interchange fee (depends on the pass-through rate) is used to reward cardholders and

induce card usage, whereas the other part is used for issuers’ profits.

211. Formally, all merchants (because they are assumed to be homogeneous) agree to accept cards

as long as their transaction benefit, which is the sum of their net benefit plus the strategic benefit

(which is itself an estimation of the cardholder’s average benefit), is larger than the MSF. Thus

the merchants’ acceptance condition is:

1) Bm+Bcavg>Pm

212. From a social point of view, the condition of efficiency in a card transaction is that the

transaction generates benefits (to the merchant and the cardholder together, without strategic

considerations) that exceeds its costs to issuers (Ci) and acquirers (Ca).413 Thus the social

welfare condition dictates that net benefits (after deduction of the fees) should be bigger than

costs:

2) Bm+Bc≥Ci+Ca

or

Bc≥Ci+Ca-Bm

213. Cardholders use their cards as long as their benefit from paying with the card (Bc) is not lower

than the cardholder fee (Pc). Thus the condition for cardholders’ adoption (and in the model of

Rochet & Tirole also usage) is:

3) Bc ≥Pc

214. By definition of Bm, a merchant would prefer to pay a MSF sized Bm (Pm=Bm) and not a

smaller one, to avoid acceptance of cash. Merchants would prefer to finance all costs and

rewards up to Bm, as long as the cardholder indeed pays with the card, which is cheaper by

412 Julian Wright, Why Payment Card Fees are Biased Against Retailers, supra note 401, at 862: “Merchant

internalization is the property that when deciding whether to join a platform (e.g., whether to accept cards), sellers on

one side (known as merchants in the cards literature) take into account the benefits buyers on the other side get from

being able to interact with them on the platform (i.e., the benefits cardholders get from using cards including,

potentially, rewards and interest-free benefits that cardholders receive) given this allows sellers to charge a higher price

to buyers or to attract more business at the same price”. 413 Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations, supra note 383,

at 551: “At the social optimum, the total benefit of the marginal transaction… is equal to its total cost”.

Page 96: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

96

definition than cash, by the size of Bm. Otherwise the merchant “loses” Bm in each transaction

in which the customer pays with cash and not card. Merchants prefer to pay up to Pm=Bm,

provided this payment is required to steer cardholders to pay with cards, i.e., merchants are

willing to pay cardholder fee for cardholders, so the optimal cardholder fee would be:

4) Pc=Ci+Ca-Bm414

215. However, the sum of the fees in the model of Rochet & Tirole (Pm+Pc) is not equal to the costs

(Ci+Ca), as in Baxter's model, because in the model of Rochet & Tirole, issuers have markup

profit (m). Acquirers are assumed competitive in the model; thus their profit is zero. The

revenue from both sides equals the cost and the markup of issuers:

5) Pm+Pc=Ca+Ci+m

or

Pc=Ca+Ci+m-Pm

216. Now, substitute Pc from equation 4 in equation 5. We get:

6) Pm=Bm+m

217. In the model of Rochet & Tirole, merchants finance the profits of the issuers. This burden is

added to their transaction benefit, which is also extracted from them. Merchants would pay for

issuers' profit as long as the profit should not be bigger than the component of the strategic

considerations (Bcavg) (equation 1).415 Otherwise, if the profit is too big, even the strategic

considerations would not suffice, and merchant would give up cards (all merchants, as they are

homogeneous, so they either all accept or reject cards). The way merchants finance the profit

of issuers involves the interchange fee.

The Restraining Role Of The Interchange Fee

218. The interchange fee is the vehicle to shift money from merchants to issuers. However, when

issuers have market power, the pass through from merchants to issuers is not full. As issuers'

profits increase (i.e., as smaller is the pass-through rate from interchange fee to cardholders),

the amount of proceeds from merchants, delivered in the form of interchange fee to issuers,

414 See ¶ 340. See also Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Cards Fee Structure: What Drives Payment Card

Rewards?, at 2 (FRB Of Kansas City Working paper 08-07. 2009): “According to the theoretical literature on payment

card fee structure, in most cases the most efficient cardholder fees would be the difference between the card network’s

costs for a card transaction and the merchant’s transactional benefit from the card transaction". 415 Infra, equation 7.

Page 97: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

97

might not suffice to finance the costs and profit of issuers. Cardholder fees might also be

required to increase, in order to finance issuers' profits. If that were to happen, cardholder fees

would increase to the annoyance not only of cardholders, but of merchants also. This is because

demand of cardholders to cards would fall, and with it the number of card transactions. The

network would be impeded. There would be more cash transactions in which merchants suffer

"loss" of Bm.

In this respect the interchange fee restrains or offsets the market power of the issuers. The

interchange fee can be increased to lower cardholder fees and offset the market power of issuers.

219. In the model of Rochet & Tirole merchants agree to finance issuers’ profit, as long as issuers

do not exaggerate. Issuers' maximum profit must be smaller than the cardholders' average

benefit. Formally we see this if we substitute equation 6 in equation 1:

7) Bcavg>m

220. In the model of Rochet & Tirole, when equation 7 holds, the outcome is generally socially

efficient. Despite the fact that strategic considerations cause merchants to pay a fee that is in

excess of their benefit (equation 6: Pm=Bm+m=5+1=6), merchants receive compensation. Part

of the fee they pay is used to satiate issuers’ hunger for profits, but part is used for the merchants'

benefit – to induce card usage among cardholders. If it were not for the interchange fee, the

network was sub-optimal. Not enough customers would have paid with cards. Merchants would

have lost efficient card transactions to cash and suffer a cost of Bm in each cash transaction.

When part of the interchange fee induces card usage, marginal transactions are "saved" by the

interchange fee from being paid by cash.

221. Note that when equation 7 holds, even though merchants pay a fee that exceeds their net benefit

(Pm=Bm+Bcavg), the transaction as a whole is still efficient if its total net benefits are not smaller

than its total costs (Bm+Bc≥Ci+Ca, Equation 2).

222. In the model of Rochet & Tirole, the acquiring side has no gains, so the acquiring fee equals

acquirers’ costs. The MSF is the sum of the acquirer fee and the interchange fee (Pm=Ca+IF).

We can write equation 6 as a function of the interchange fee

8) Pm=Bm+m = Ca+IF

223. Substitute equation 4 in equation 8 and we get:

Page 98: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

98

9) IF=Pm-Ca=Ci-Pc+m

224. For merchants the interchange fee is a “tax” added to acquirers’ costs (Pm=Ca+IF). For

cardholders the interchange fee is a subsidy deducted from issuers’ costs and profits (Pc=Ci+m-

IF).

225. From Equation 9, it is easy to notice that for any given costs (Ci, Ca) and profit (m), as the

interchange fee increases the cardholder fee (Pc) decreases and the MSF (Pm) increases. The

interchange fee balances the "issuers’ deficit" from Baxter’s model (Ci-Pc), if any, plus it

finances the profit of issuers (m). As issuers’ profit increase, a larger interchange fee is required

to satiate their hunger.

226. According to Rochet & Tirole, if it were not for the interchange fee, the burden of funding

issuers’ profit would fall on cardholders, and this would be an inferior situation because of sub-

optimal card usage.), vgacBexceed the m does not (profit is not too big ’As long as the issuers 416

increasing the interchange fee that is financed by merchants, in order to restrain the market

power of the issuers, is generally efficient.

227. In the model of Rochet & Tirole, an interchange fee higher than the merchant’s benefit, has two

positive functions: a. On the merchants’ side, it causes merchants to internalize the benefits that

cardholders derive from payment cards; b. and on the cardholders’ side, it avoids undersupply

of payment cards, which could result from issuers’ market power.417

Concern of Oversupply

228. Rochet & Tirole recognize that according to their model, the interchange fee may lead to the

opposite result, an over-supply rather than an undersupply. In their model, oversupply may exist

if the cardholder fee is reduced "too much" due to a large interchange fee. By definition, the

marginal cardholder has a lower benefit from cards than the average cardholder. The marginal

cardholder may be seen as the one who has cash in the wallet. Were it not for the interchange

fee, this marginal cardholder would have used cash (without being disappointed if the merchant

did not accept cards). Nevertheless, an interchange fee that weighs the interest of the average

cardholder, when applied to the marginal cardholder, causes the execution of transactions, in

416 Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations, supra note 383,

at 559. 417Id. at 566: “The exploitation of the merchants' search for a competitive edge has two benefits from a social

viewpoint: on the merchant side, it forces merchants to internalize cardholders' convenience benefit, and on the

customer side, it offsets the underprovision of cards by issuers with market power”.

Page 99: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

99

which the aggregate benefits to the merchant and the marginal cardholder is lower than the

aggregate fees. For example, when Bm=5 and Bcavg=1, it is still efficient if the merchant pays

6 and the cardholder pays 0 (Bm+Bc=6≥Pm+Pc=6). But in the case of a marginal cardholder,

for which Bc=0, then the transaction is not efficient (Pm+pc=6+0>Bm+Bc=5+0). It would have

been more efficient not to steer the marginal cardholder with high interchange fee, and let the

transaction be paid for with cash.

229. When the interchange fee is used to finance card usage of marginal customers, the result might

be oversupply and over usage of cards. Oversupply, in this sense, is the normal result that occurs

in every product that is priced too cheaply. If cards are priced too low, marginal cardholders

adopt and use cards that are financed by merchants.418 Rochet & Tirole also recognize that when

merchants over-internalize cardholders’ benefits, (i.e. attribute a bigger value to Bcavg than in

practice), the interchange fee is too high and inefficient from a social point of view.419

Additional Developments And Criticism

230. In the model of Rochet & Tirole cardholders pay only fixed transaction fees (which can be

negative because of rewards), and not annual fees. More recent models released this

assumption, and allowed two-part tariff of cardholder fees. The two-part tariff consists of

adoption (annual) fees and per transaction fees, which are for the most proportional and

negative, as a result of the free funding period and ad-valorem rewards.420

231. When cardholder fee is divided into annual fixed fee and small negative transaction fee, the

strategic considerations are even larger. They tilt the price structure even more to the detriment

of merchants and to the benefit of cardholders.421

The reason for this tilt is that when a customer decides to become a cardholder, the annual fixed

fee is a lump sum. Rewards that are partly financed by the interchange fee have a double effect:

first, the rewards increase usage among existing cardholders; and second, the rewards provide

418 Id. at 556: “[T]he higher the interchange fee, the lower the customer fee; and so customers with lower willingnesses

to pay for a card are induced to take a card when the interchange fee increases.” See also infra ¶ 723. 419Id. at 558. 420 Ozlem Bedre-Defolie & Emilio Calvano, Pricing Payment Cards, supra note 368; Sungbok Lee, The Effects of

Issuer Competition on the Credit Card Industry: A Case Study of the Two-Sided Market, (2010) available at

http://www.javanfish.com/file/The%20Effects%20of%20Issuer%20Competition%20On%20the%20Credit%20Card%2

0Industry_October2010.pdf 421 Rysman & Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, supra note 389, at 3: “Merchant internalization can affect the

balancing act played by interchange fees, leading to more favorable terms to consumers and less favorable terms to

merchants than would be socially efficient.”

Page 100: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

100

an incentive for adoption of cards by new joiners.422 Both existing and new cardholders are

therefore more eager to pay with cards. Thus, the two-part tariff of cardholder fees increases

the eagerness of cardholders to pay with cards for which they have already paid, and worsens

the internalization effect of merchants, i.e., their strategic considerations.

Formally, under fixed annual cardholder fees and per transaction (negative) fees, merchants are

exploited even more to (over) internalize the benefits of cardholders from card usage (Bcavg

increases).423

232. Suppose again that the net benefits of the merchant from cards is 5 (Bm=5), and that the average

benefit of the cardholder is 1 (Bcavg=1). Suppose again Ci=2; Ca=2. According to Equation 4,

the cardholder fees should be -1 (Ci+Ca-Bm). Thus the model yields negative cardholder fees

of -1 (rewards).

233. The profit condition from Equation 7 implies efficient merchant internalization if the profit is

no higher than 1 (Bcavg≥m). Suppose indeed m=1. From Equation 6 the MSF is 6

(Pm=Ci+Ca+m+Bca=6). Merchants have a benefit of 5, but they also internalize the average

cardholder benefit of 1 and are thus forced to pay 6. Rochet & Tirole justify this internalization

because the transaction is still socially beneficial. It adheres to Equation 2, as long as the

interchange fee lowers cardholder fees so that Pm+Pc is not bigger than Bm+Bc. When the

average cardholder is considered, the aggregate benefits are indeed 6 (Bm=5, Bca=1) whereas

Pm+Pc=6+(-1)=5.

234. However negative cardholder fee of -1 causes all cardholders for whom Bc>-1 to pay with

cards. Some of those cardholders (for whom Bc>0) would have paid with card even if the

interchange fee was lower. Merchants were exploited to over-internalize the benefit of their

marginal cardholders, and as a byproduct gave a windfall to the infra-marginal cardholders.

The negative cardholder fee is financed by an interchange fee of 4 (Pm=6=Ca+IF=2+4). The

422 Ozlem Bedre-Defolie et al., Pricing Payment Cards, supra note 368: “Financing card usage perks through higher

charges on merchants not only increases issuance of new cards but also fosters usage of existing cards." 423Id. at 27: “[M]erchants pay excessive transaction prices and cardholders pay inefficiently low card usage prices. We

demonstrate that the price structure distortion originates from an asymmetry between consumers and merchants:

consumers make two distinct decisions, card membership and card usage, at different information sets, whereas

merchants decide only on membership, i.e., whether to accept the scheme's cards or not.”

Page 101: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

101

interchange fee is used to cover issuers’ costs (Ci=2); to finance rewards that lower cardholder

fees (rewards of 1); and to finance issuer’s profit (m=1).

235. On the merchants’ side - not only merchants are no longer indifferent to the means of payment,

but they strictly disfavor cards (Pm=6>Bm=5). Merchants, in this example, prefer other

payment instruments to a card. Their strategic considerations are used to exploit them.

236. On the cardholders' side, the part of the interchange fee that was used to lower cardholder fees

to minus 1 in the example, is redundant for all cardholders with positive benefit from cards

(Bc>0). They would have used cards anyway as they derive inherent benefit from cards. The

interchange fee indeed steers cardholders who “slightly” disfavor cards (their benefit from cards

is between -1 and zero, i.e. -1<Bc<0), but the price of steering them is too high. The price level

is 5 (6+(-1)=5) and the aggregate benefits, when marginal cardholders are considered, are less

than 5. Equation 2, therefore, does not hold.

237. In addition, because issuers have market power, the pass through to rewards is less than full.424

In the example above, issuers keep 1 as profit and pass through only 1 as rewards to cardholders,

whereas the price of goods would increase up to 2 in competitive markets. All customers suffer

from the price increase. Only some cardholders enjoy partial redeeming value:

Cardholders who strongly disfavor cards (Bc<-1) would not be steered to cards, even after the

high interchange fee turned their cardholder fee to be minus 1. They can be considered as "cash-

lovers".425 They suffer, with all other non-card customers, from the full price increase.

Cardholders with positive benefit from cards get redundant rewards (because they would have

paid with cards anyway) which do not fully compensate them for the price increase of goods.

As for merchants, were it not for strategic considerations, they would rather not accept cards at

all.

238. In a more recent article, Rochet & Tirole were more conservative about their original claim that

under certain conditions, interchange fee that is higher than Bm might be desired. They argued

that, at least under certain circumstances of maximizing short term consumer surplus (the

424 Rysman & Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, supra note 389, at 17: “The possibility of less than 100% pass

through of interchange fees to cardholders is allowed in most existing models.” 425 Carlos Arango, Kim P. Huynh & Leonard Sabetti, Consumer Payment Choice: Merchant Card Acceptance Versus

Pricing Incentives, 55 J. BANK. FIN. 130, 131 (2015): “Our findings suggest that in a world with full merchant card

acceptance cash would still be used because of its non-pecuniary benefits such as ease of use, speed of transacting, and

anonymity”. See also supra ¶ 148.

Page 102: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

102

“consumer” is the combination of merchant and cardholder), Bm should be an upper bound to

the interchange fee.426

239. In 2012, Julian Wright published an article in which he formalized my criticism above, that

contrary to Rochet & Tirole and to previous works of his own, the over-internalization effect

imposed on merchants is the reason for the biased price structure against merchants.427

240. Hayashi claims that the strategic considerations in practice may be much bigger than the benefit

to the average cardholder (Bcavg). Her claim is that the strategic considerations are not exhausted

in Bcavg. The strategic considerations may rise to a level almost as high as the merchant’s profit

from the transaction. As long as the merchant does not lose from the transaction, he is forced

to accept cards so as not to discourage customers.428 Merchants who fear that rejecting cards

may cause them to lose the transaction completely, are effectively extorted. Networks can

exploit their market power over merchants, to extract the surplus of merchants not only from

the payment instrument, but from the transaction itself.

241. Another criticism, which is more morally based, is that if issuers exploit their market power,

the response should be to fight this market power. The response should not be to accept high

interchange fee as inevitable so as to offset such market power. Interchange fee should not be

regarded as inevitable. Interchange fee is a horizontal minimum price fixing agreement between

competitors,429 which increases the prices of final goods in the market,430 and must operate

under a regulatory approval. Such approval can be conditioned.431 Recognizing as legitimate

426 Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards, supra note 388, at 486: “A key result of this paper is thus that, with constant

issuer margins and homogenous merchants, a regulatory cap based on merchants’ avoided cost is legitimate when

competition authorities aim at maximizing short-term total user surplus”. 427 Julian Wright, Why Payment Card Fees are Biased Against Retailers, supra note 401, at 762: “I take a standard

model of a card platform facing elastic demand for cards on each side of the market (i.e., the same model considered by

Rochet and Tirole, 2011, in reaching their conclusion above) and show it actually implies an unambiguous bias against

retailers… Specifically, the interchange fee determined by the platform will be excessive. Reducing the amount

retailers pay and making cardholders pay more will, up to some point, raise welfare... Contrary to claims in

previous work on the topic (including some of my own), these strong results do not depend on the relative level of

cardholder and retailer benefits from different payment instruments. Nor do they rely on there being any revenue-

shifting role for interchange fees, in which it is argued the interchange fee shifts revenues to the cardholder side of the

business, as this is the side where the revenues are competed away less (although the bias continues to hold when

revenue shifting also arises). Rather, the results arise by exploiting the full implications of a phenomenon known

in the literature as merchant internalization.”. See also Rong Ding & Julian Wright, Payment Card Interchange Fees

and Price Discrimination (2015). 428 Hayashi, A Puzzle of Card Payment Pricing, supra note 388, at 172: “As long as the merchant fee does not exceed

the level that gives merchants negative profits, merchants may have no choice but to continue accepting cards”. 429 Infra ch. 0. 430 Infra ch. 10.1. 431 For the condition I propose see infra ch. 14 (profit limitation).

Page 103: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

103

the “restraining” role of the interchange fee is analogous to subsidizing cartels as a counter

force to the harm they cause.432

242. An important condition for the basic model of Rochet & Tirole is that the NSR rule applies.

The NSR must apply in order to force merchants to internalize the benefits of cards to

cardholders. Application of NSR means that merchants cannot surcharge cardholders, even if

cards are expensive payment instruments. Other models, including those of Rochet & Tirole,

released the assumption of the NSR.

6.5. Neutrality, surcharge and merchant restraints

243. Carlton and Frankel were first to indicate the "neutrality" of the interchange fee.433 They argued

that if acquiring and issuing markets, as well as competition between merchants, satisfy the

conditions of a contestable market, the interchange fee has no real impact.

244. For example, if the interchange fee increases by 1, then the MSF increases by 1, and this spurs

the merchant to impose a surcharge of 1 on cardholders. However, at the same time the

cardholder fee decreases by 1, due to a reward received by the cardholder, which was financed

by the increase of 1 in the interchange fee (under assumption of full pass-through). The product

price for cardholders does not change. It is 1 higher but the cardholder received a reward of 1.

There is no real effect from the increase (or decrease) in the interchange fee. Despite the change

in the price structure, price level did not change. Product prices remain the same, as do the level

of card usage, the quantities sold and all other real economic variables. The interchange fee

would not affect the consumption or welfare of any party neither cardholders, nor issuers, nor

merchants nor acquirers.434

432 John Vickers, Public Policy and the Invisible Price: Competition Law, Regulation and the Interchange Fee,

Payments Sys. Research Conference 231, 237 (2005): “[T]he argument that the interchange fee should be raised in

order to subsidize imperfectly competitive issuers is unappealing. First, in so far as there is imperfect competition, it

should be addressed by pro-competitive measures, not rewarded by subsidy. (Pushed to an extreme, the

argument would favor subsidizing cartels.) Second, any subsidy has to be financed by, effectively, a tax on retail

purchases. It may be that some of the tax implied by a high interchange fee is recycled to card-paying consumers (for

instance, via the interest-free period and rewards for card use), but the recycling may well be imperfect and inefficient.

Moreover, there is usually no interest-free period for the many payers by credit card who do not routinely clear their

balances in full, and in the absence of frictionless surcharging, those paying other than by credit card get no tax

rebate at all. So besides the general unattractiveness of subsidizing imperfectly competitive firms, the effective tax to

finance the subsidy would seem likely itself to be inefficient and distorting.”; Alan S. Frankel, Towards a Competitive

Card Payments Marketplace, at 46 (RBA, 2007); Alan Frankel, Interchange in various Countries: Commentary on

Weiner and Wright, FRB Kansas 51, 54 (2005). 433 Dennis W. Carlton & Alan S. Frankel, The Antitrust Economics of Credit Card Networks, 63 ANTITRUST L.J. 643,

656-59 (1995). 434 Gans and King, The Neutrality of Interchange Fees in Payment Systems, 3 TOPICS IN ECON. ANALYSIS & POL'Y 1, at

5 (2003): "Neutrality requires that, while prices may change, real variables and payoffs do not"; id. at 9-10: "Note that

Page 104: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

104

Under neutrality conditions, the interchange fee would also not be a source of profit for issuers.

All economic variables will remain the same no matter what interchange fees prevails:435

If issuers and merchants were perfectly competitive and there were no costs

associated with pricing differently according to payment method, then it is

possible that an interchange fee would have no economic effects. To explain,

suppose an interchange fee for credit card transactions is set at 5 percent of

the sale amount and neither merchants nor issuers incur any other payment

costs. Because pricing is assumed frictionless in this scenario, merchants

charge credit card customers 5 percent more than cash customers, and issuers

rebate 5 percent to those same credit customers. The interchange fee merely

circulates revenue from cardholders to merchants and back again in full to

cardholders—a result known as neutrality. Interchange fees have no

economic effects in this scenario, creating neither harm nor benefit; the net

position of merchants, cash customers, and credit card customers would not

vary with changes in interchange fees.436

245. When there are several means of payment, such as cash, checks and payment cards, neutrality

is maintained, despite the increase (or decrease) in interchange fees, if merchants are pricing

their products differentially, according to the cost of the payment instruments to them, i.e.,

conduct perfect surcharging policy. If merchants freely pass costs to customers, without any

transaction costs, and if merchants exactly reflect changes in the costs of the different payment

instruments in the final prices of goods, the interchange fee remains neutral.437 For non-card

payers the price would not change.

nominal variables, such as merchant prices and credit card fees, may alter as the interchange fee alters. Neutrality of the

fee only applies to real economic variables." 435 Wilko Bolt & Sujit Chakravorti, Economics of Payment Cards: A Status Report, 32 ECON. PERSPECTIVES 15, 20

(2008): “The interchange fee is said to be neutral if a change in the interchange fee does not change the quantity of

consumer purchases and the profit level of merchants and banks”;

Joshua S. Gans & Stephen P. King, Approaches to Regulating Interchange Fees in Payment Systems, 2 REV. NETWORK

ECON. 125, 134 (2003): “[W]hen there is frictionless surcharging, interchange fees may change the nominal prices and

fees in payment systems but not relative prices or real decisions being made”;

Gans & King, The Neutrality, id. at 9: “The interchange fee is neutral if for any other interchange fee, a′, there is an

equilibrium E′, such that all customers’ purchases, all banks’ profits and all merchants’ profits are the same under E and

E'.” 436 Alan S. Frankel & Allan L. Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 627, 633

(2006); Dennis W. Carlton & Ralph A. Winter, Competition Policy and Regulation in Credit Card Markets: Insights

from Single-Sided Market Analysis, at 12 (2014): “Under these assumptions, the level of the interchange fee is

completely irrelevant”. 437 Rysman & Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, supra note 389, at 14: “The main result in the literature with

regard to surcharging is known as neutrality. This says that the level of the interchange fee will be irrelevant for the

decisions of cardholders and merchants when merchants can set a surcharge for consumers who pay by card”.

Page 105: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

105

246. When there are no transaction costs, surcharging under competitive conditions effectively turns

the two-sided market into standard "one-sided" market.438 Cardholders see one product price.

Interchange fee does not affect real economic variables, and neutrality is maintained.

247. In order to preserve neutrality, the cardholder fees should be imposed in the same way the MSF

is imposed. If the MSF is proportional, cardholder fees should be proportional or, alternatively,

both should be a fixed amount per transaction. Otherwise, the change in the price for merchants

will not be the same as the change in the price for cardholders.439

248. A development of the neutrality proposition was made by Professors Gans and King.440 They

showed that there is no need for the market to be contestable in order to preserve neutrality. It

is sufficient that merchants surcharge without transaction costs, and that in equilibrium, the

pass-through rate from the interchange fee to the prices of goods on the acquiring side, would

be identical to the pass-through rate on the issuing side, from the interchange fee to rewards.

This is enough for the price level to remain unchanged although price structure changes.441

For example, if the interchange fee increases by 1, and as a consequence the product price

increases by 0.6 (the acquirer absorbs 0.4, pass through rate of 60%), but the cardholder receives

a reward of 0.6 (the issuer keeps 0.4 as profit, pass through rate of 60%), then the product price

decreases for the cardholder due to the reward exactly in the same amount of the price increase

(0.6). Neutrality is maintained. The consumed quantities remain unchanged. This was explained

by Professor Katz more formally:

Rational consumers base their purchase and payment mechanism decisions

on p − r (p=price, r=rewards – O.B), the net cost to a consumer from making a card-

based purchase. Suppose a change in the interchange fee of da leads to

changes in p and r equal to dp and dr, respectively. Then the change in a

consumer’s net costs of a card-based transaction is dp − dr. Hence, if the rates

438 Hans Zenger, Perfect Surcharging and the Tourist Test Interchange Fee, 35 J. BANK. FIN. 2544, 2544 (2011):

"[P]erfect surcharging makes payment card markets one-sided."

Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: Policy Considerations of Payment Card Rewards, at

11 (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No. 08-08., 2008): “When per transaction costs and fees are fixed, the

merchants’ setting of different prices across payment methods changes the payment card market from two-sided to one-

sided. That is, the fee structure does not affect the number of card transactions any more”.

Rochet & Tirole, Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report, supra note 408, at 665. 439 Julian Wright, Optimal Card Payment Systems, 47 EUR. ECON. REV. 587, 590 (2003). 440 Gans & King, The Neutrality of Interchange Fees, supra note 434. 441Id. at 11: “The interchange fee does not alter the degree of bank competition, and so bank fees will move to offset the

changes in the interchange fees… The changes in bank fees can and will completely offset the change in the interchange

fee… In this sense, the interchange fee is a redundant price. A credit card payment involves transfers from the customer

to three parties – the merchant, the issuer and the acquirer. But there are four prices [payments to merchants, payments

to issuers, payments to acquirers and the interchange fee]. If one of these prices is altered then the equilibrium values of

the other prices will change so there is no change in any real variable."

Page 106: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

106

of change are equal (i.e., dp/da = dr/da), then changes in the interchange

fee have no effect on the net prices paid by consumers to make card-based

purchases442.

249. In equilibrium under neutrality conditions, when the interchange fee changes, prices adjust

themselves to the change, like the waterbed effect. The change in the price of the product is in

the same amount, but in the opposite direction of the cardholder fee. The total price of the

product for the cardholder is unchanged.443

250. The neutrality is based on the ability of merchants to signal their customers, or in economic

terms: to externalize on their customers, the real cost for the merchant, of each payment

instrument used by the customer.444 Customers may still prefer to pay with an expensive

payment instrument, if it yields benefit that justifies its higher price.445

251. Neutrality conditions bring customers to fully internalize all benefits and costs of each payment

instrument they use, not only for themselves but for the merchant also. Neutrality prevents a

customer from externalizing on merchants high costs of payment instrument, costly to the

merchant but cheap to the customer. Neutrality forces customers to acknowledge the full price

of payment cards for the integrated customer of payment card networks - customer and

merchant together.

252. According to the Coase Theorem, in the absence of transaction costs, surcharging should bring

efficient results.446 Customers internalize the aggregate cost of each payment instrument in their

wallet, not only for themselves, but for merchants also. Transactions between customers and

merchants will be efficient,447 even if customers choose to pay the surcharge. There is nothing

wrong with customers paying with an expensive payment instrument, if it produces benefits

442 MICHAEL L. KATZ, REFORM OF CREDIT CARDS SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA COMMISSIONED REPORT (Reserve Bank of

Australia, 2001); see also Amelio, supra note 404: “[I]f cost pass through of issuing and acquiring is not identical, MIF

influences the total fee level (issuing plus acquiring fee)";

Rochet & Tirole, Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report, supra note 408, at 648: “Neutrality in payment systems. The

choice of an interchange fee paid by the merchant's bank, the acquirer, to the cardholder's bank, the issuer, is irrelevant

if the following conditions are jointly satisfied: First, issuers and acquirers pass through the corresponding charge (or

benefit) to the cardholder and the merchant. Second, the merchant can charge two different prices for goods or services

depending on whether the consumer pays by cash or by card; in other words, the payment system does not impose a no-

surcharge rule as a condition for the merchant to be affiliated with the system. Third, the merchant and the consumer

incur no transaction cost associated with a dual-price system”. 443 For expansion on the waterbed effect see Aaron Schiff, The "Waterbed" Effect and Price Regulation, 7 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 392 (2008). 444 Fumiko Hayashi, Discounts and Surcharges: Implications for Consumer Payment Choice, Payments Sys. Res.

Briefing FRB Kansas City, at 3 (2012): “Merchant surcharging enhances efficiency in the retail payments system by

improving price signals consumers face when making payments”. 445 Supra ¶ 129. 446 See Ronald Coase, The Problem of Social Costs, 3 J. L. & ECON. 1 (1960). 447 Rochet & Tirole, Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report, supra note 408, at 665.

Page 107: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

107

which are greater than the surcharge.448 Surcharging leads to informed choice of consumers

between different means of payment. Consumers pay with the payment instrument that is the

most cost effective to the customer and the merchant alike.449

253. Freedom to surcharge means that is does not pay for merchants to reject expensive payment

cards. The merchant would be better off surcharging than rejecting. After all, if cards are

expensive but merchants reflect this in prices, they do not need to reject cards. The demand for

cards and the level of usage would be determined by fully aware cardholders, who would

consider the full cost of their payment instrument.450

The Literature In Favor Of NSR

254. Although surcharging leads to neutrality, top economic scholars have defended the NSR and

argued in favor of this rule.

The main justification to the NSR is the argument that merchants are not able to recognize the

full benefits of payment instruments. Every merchant sees only its own costs and benefits. A

single merchant cannot internalize the benefits of payment card networks as a whole. Allowing

merchants to surcharge neutralizes the positive effects of the interchange fees that encourage

adoption and usage of efficient payment instruments such as cards. Allowing surcharges

reduces the network attractiveness. NSR is therefore required to keep the wholeness of payment

card networks.451

448 Supra ¶ 129. 449 Rochet & Tirole, Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report, supra note 408, at 665: “The Coase theorem states that if

property rights are clearly established and tradeable, and if there are no transaction costs nor asymmetric information,

the outcome of the negotiation between two (or several) parties will be Pareto efficient, even in the presence of

externalities. Coase's (1960) view is that if outcomes are inefficient and nothing hinders bargaining, people will

negotiate their way to efficiency. Because, in the context of a buyer-seller interaction mediated by a platform, the gains

from trade between the two end-users depend on the price level but not its allocation, the latter has no impact on the

volume of transactions, the platform's profit, and social welfare in a Coasian world: markets are one-sided. The business

and public policy attention to price structure issues is then misguided”. 450Jean Charles Rochet, The Theory of Interchange Fees: A Synthesis of Recent Contributions, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON.

97, 106 (2003): “When sellers can costlessly surcharge, they never benefit from refusing card payments. The total

volume of card payments is then only determined by buyers’ demand… With perfect surcharging and in the absence of

transaction costs, volume only depends on the total price (pB + pS) for card services and not anymore on the price

structure. Similarly, the net margin of issuers… only depends on total price and total cost… The level of the interchange

fee ceases to play any role (neutrality)". 451 Rysman & Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, supra note 389, at 15: “By extracting the usage value of cards

through surcharges, merchants make fewer consumers willing to hold cards in the first place. However, this externality

is not internalized by merchants when deciding whether to surcharge since they take the number of cardholders as given

(as each merchant is just one of the very many merchants that consumers have a chance of dealing with)”.

Page 108: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

108

255. Proponents of NSR claim that this rule is the linchpin of payment card networks. Card networks

established even though the demand on one side (merchants) is less elastic than the other

(cardholders), because merchants’ higher willingness to pay for cards was reflected in uniform

prices. NSR guarantees a pricing structure, in which merchants pay more and cardholders pay

less, whereas surcharging destroys this essence.452 Surcharging causes under-provision of cards

and inefficiently too-low card level usage. Surcharging trims the optimal size of networks,

because surcharging – according to this line of argument –inefficiently reduces the number of

cardholders and their usage.453

256. Surcharging destroys the incentives of cardholders to join networks and use cards.454 In the

event of surcharging, marginal cardholders would not pay with cards. They might either choose

not to adopt a card from the outset, or even if they do adopt a card, they would use it less often.

Only cardholders with relatively high demand for cards would adopt and use cards in the

presence of surcharging.455

257. To the extent that cards are expensive payment instruments for merchants, relative to other

means of payment, surcharging indeed signals that costliness to cardholders, but at the same

time weakens the whole payment card network. NSR indeed intensifies negative usage

externality (the externality that is caused when a cardholder chooses to pay with a cheap

payment instrument for her, and externalizes on the merchant its expensive cost), but results in

a positive expansion of the payment card network (positive network externality).

452 Steven Semeraro, The Antitrust Economics (and Law) of Surcharging Credit Card Transactions, 14 STAN. J. L. BUS.

& FIN. 343, 353 (2009): “Card systems must deal with two distinct customer bases, cardholders and merchants. Within

such a two-sided market, efficient fee-setting is likely to require charges above marginal cost to the customer set that is

less sensitive to price, i.e. has lower demand elasticity, and prices below marginal cost to the customers on the other

side. Assuming reasonably that merchant demand is less elastic than cardholder demand, a rule prohibiting

surcharges may enable the card systems to ensure an efficient pricing structure in which merchants pay more

than their marginal cost of service and cardholders pay less”. 453 Steven Semeraro, The Economic Benefits of Credit Card Merchant Restraints: A Response to Adam Levitin, TJSL

Legal Studies Research Paper no. 1357840, at 26 (2009): “Economists have long cautioned that eliminating these rules

could inefficiently reduce credit card use”. 454 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, An Economic Analysis of the Determination of Interchange Fees in Payment

Card Systems, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 69 (2003), at 76: “…when issuers have market power, banning the NDR would

result in a systematic underprovision of card services, while with the NDR in place, the interchange fee chosen by an

association can result in an efficient card usage. Similarly, Wright (2000) shows that when merchants have market

power and cardholders’ payments to issuers are not perfectly proportional to transactions, merchants are able to extract

consumer surplus from card usage, destroying incentives for holding payment cards”. 455 Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations, supra note 383,

at 562: “Merchant price discrimination reduces the demand for payment cards. Issuers focus on the high end of the

market and no longer attract consumers who are not willing to pay much in the first place and who know that they will

face a second markup when paying with the card in the store. Put differently, the card surcharge in stores raises the

issuers' cost of providing cardholders with a given surplus of using the card and thus inhibits the diffusion of cards".

Page 109: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

109

258. The support or opposition to the NSR in the literature is, therefore, dependent on the writer's

approach to the question of which is the more important externalization, network or usage (for

expansion on these externalities see infra chapter 7.2). For those who seek to solve usage

externalities, i.e. those seeking to prevent customers from externalizing on merchants high costs

of expensive payment instruments, surcharging should be allowed. This approach, at its

extreme, argues that giving a free hand to merchants to surcharge obviates the need for any

further regulatory intervention.456

For those who are primarily concerned with the size of networks, surcharging should be

prohibited, and NSR should be mandatory. This approach, at its extreme opines that surcharging

could destroy payment card networks. Cardholders would not want to pay any cardholder fees

if “in reward,” they receive cards that raise prices of goods for them. No rational customer

would want to pay for the honor of being a holder of a card that has no usage benefits but usage

costs. Consumers would waive being cardholders from the outset.457

This argument has been illustrated by example of a club that allows free entry for women, but

then charges them extra for drinks. The entrance fee is analogous to the decision whether to

adopt a card. Payment for a drink is analogous to card usage. The surcharge on drinks dissuades

from entering the club, even for free.458

However, this argument is based on a flawed assumption of a single network. If there are

competing card networks, of which only some bear high MSF, consumers might react to

surcharge by waiving expensive cards that are rightly surcharged. Indeed, the surcharged

network might incur losses, but those losses are not necessarily lost sales for the entire

card network, but rather sales that would happen with a cheaper card. Thus, network

competition mitigates the negative network externality of surcharging. Any negative

externality to one network can be offset by positive externality to the competing

network. This insight is especially important in restraining large networks such as

456 Gans & King, The Neutrality of Interchange Fees in Payment Systems, supra note 434, at 12: "[R]emoval of

restrictions is a sufficient condition to avoid any regulatory concerns about the setting of interchange fees”. 457 Julian Wright, Optimal Card Payment Systems, supra note 439, at 599: “Under surcharging, merchants will set a

price for using cards that at least extracts all the payment benefits that the marginal cardholder receives... Knowing this,

the cardholder… will never join the network in the first place, since joining entails a fixed fee F but provides no

usage benefits”. See also Rochet & Tirole, An Economic Analysis of the Determination of Interchange Fees in Payment

Card Systems, supra note 454, at 76. 458 Semeraro, The Antitrust Economics (and Law) of Surcharging Credit Card Transactions, supra note 452, at 358.

Page 110: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

110

MasterCard or Visa from arguing against surcharging in the presence of competing

smaller networks. Network externality tends to be larger for smaller networks as their

growth is exponential, so surcharging by large networks might spur smaller networks’

growth, and gains to the card network would likely offset private losses of mature

networks.459

Other Models

259. Under different assumptions than Wright, especially under the assumption of flexible demand

for goods (in Wright’s model, as in the model of Rochet & Tirole, demand for final goods is

rigid. Changes in fees do not affect aggregate consumption), Schwartz & Vincent arrived at

different conclusions. In the model of Schwartz & Vincent, the NSR increases the profits of the

network (they refer to a closed network), and impedes the profitability and welfare of merchants

and cash users.460

In their model, when the MSF increases under NSR, merchants raise the prices they charge all

customers. As a result cash payers subsidize cardholders.461 The effect of this subsidy increases

as the MSF increases. Even if cardholders receive back as rewards the entire surcharge they

pay, cash payers are still harmed.462 Decline in cardholder fees (even to a negative amount)

further increases the demand and usage of cards. As demand in the model of Schwartz and

Vincent is flexible, the decrease in cardholder fees has a greater effect than in the model of

Rochet & Tirole. In the model of Rochet & Tirole the fees have no effect on aggregate

consumption, which is constant. In the model of Schwartz and Vincent, consumption of

cardholders increases with the MSF and at the same time - with prices of products. However

the increase in prices of goods is larger than the decrease in cardholder fees, because issuers

have markups. Cash payers suffer from higher prices with no offsetting benefit, and their

459 The author thanks an anonymous referee for this paragraph. 460 Marius Schwartz & Daniel R. Vincent, The no Surcharge Rule and Card User Rebates: Vertical Control by a

Payment Network, 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 72 (2006). 461Id. at 75: “NSR induces the merchant (in part) to raise its price to cash users. Holding other fees constant, this effect

induces a cross-subsidy from cash to cards”. 462Id. at 92: “If rebates are feasible the EPN grants them, benefiting itself and card users while harming cash users and

(weakly) the merchant”.

Page 111: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

111

consumption declines. Merchants also suffer from less consumption due to their higher prices.

Especially cash payers absorb the full price increase.463

260. Sujit Chakravorti and William Emmons found that surcharging may promote welfare.464 In their

model surcharging reduces the negative effects of cross-subsidization, not between cash and

cards but between credit and debit.465 Credit is a more expensive payment instrument than

debit.466 Credit is used by customers with liquidity constraints whereas debit is used by

customers that need the card only as a payment instrument (transactors). NSR causes the cheap

payment instrument to subsidize the expensive payment instrument. Specifically in their model,

NSR causes debit payers to subsidize credit payers. Abolishing NSR makes creditors internalize

the costs of credit.

261. Zenger argues that with free surcharging and no transaction costs, networks set interchange fees

that brings the MSF to be equal to the maximum fee that passes the tourist test (Bm), in order

to make merchants indifferent between payment instruments.467 When the MSF=Bm,

merchants will not surcharge, because at that level of MSF the merchant is indifferent between

payment instruments, and has no reason to surcharge.468 The ability to surcharge restrains

networks from exploiting merchants' strategic considerations.

262. Semeraro is a proponent of NSR, but not HAC. He claims that cancellation of the NSR is a

risky step. Some merchants could not afford to surcharge because of the competitive conditions

in the relevant market in which they operate. Merchants that possess market power may

surcharge too much. Semeraro proposes to abolish the HAC but not the NSR, and split the two

big open networks (Visa and MasterCard) to several closed networks. According to Semeraro,

merchants should be able to reject expensive cards, but if merchants choose to accept a card,

they should not be allowed to surcharge it. Semeraro opines that competition would force

463Id. at 76: “[T]he [network] grants rebates to card users so as to boost their demand and raises its fee to merchants

knowing that they will absorb part of the increase, because under the NSR any price increase must apply equally to cash

users”. 464 Sujit Chakravorti & William R. Emmons, Who Pays for Credit Cards? 37 J. CONSUMER AFF. 208 (2003). 465 For expansion on credit as opposed to debit, see infra ch. 6.8. 466Supra ¶ 125. 467 Hans Zenger, Perfect Surcharging and the Tourist Test Interchange Fee, supra note 438, at 2546: “There is price-

coherence, because the interchange fee is set such that merchants are indifferent among payment instruments”. 468Id. at 2546: “[T]he tourist test mimics as a second-best mechanism the market outcome in the absence of transaction

costs that inhibit merchants from differentiating retail prices by means of payment”.

Page 112: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

112

issuers that charge high MSF to lower their fees.469 As I will show in the next chapter,

competition does not necessarily bring to lower fees for merchants.

263. Economides finds that the degree of competition between merchants is a key factor to NSR

desirability. He suggests a market-by-market approach.470 When merchants have market power

they tend to absorb at least part of the increase in the MSF. Merchants with market power set

prices according to demand and not according to costs. Those merchants know that further

increase in the price of the products will impede their profit (otherwise they would have used

their market power and increase prices at the outset). So merchants with market power prefer

to absorb at least some of the price increase due to higher fees, and not fully surcharge. On the

other side cardholders enjoy decline in cardholder fees (due to rewards), and in addition suffer

less from price increase of goods, due to merchant’s partial absorption of MSF increase. Thus

when merchants have market power lifting the NSR is desirable, according to Economides.

In the model of Economides, when merchants are competitive or when their demand for cards

is elastic, free surcharging causes a full pass through from the interchange fee to final prices

and thus reduces welfare. Economides proposes to keep the NSR in competitive markets.471

264. In the model of Wright, under NSR, competitive merchants split between those who accept

cards and those who do not. The uniform prices of merchants that accept cards are higher than

of “cash only” merchants. The result is that card accepting merchants end up with cardholders

only as their customers.472 When merchants compete on prices (Bertrand competition) they end

469 Semeraro, The Antitrust Economics (and Law) of Surcharging Credit Card Transactions, supra note 452, at 346:

“Although surcharging potentially could combat this market power, it would be an uncertain and risky response … an

alternative, less risky response that would focus directly on card system market power by relaxing the rule that requires

merchants to accept cards from every issuer on the network (the “honor-all-cards rules”)." 470 Nicholas Economides & David Henriques, To Surcharge Or Not to Surcharge? A Two-Sided Market Perspective of

the no-Surcharge Rule, at 9 (ECB Working Paper No. 1338, Oct. 2011): “We consider the pros and cons of forbidding

the NSR versus no regulatory intervention emphasizing that one size policy does not fit all markets, since, in general,

there are significant market power differences across goods and geographic markets within the same country.

According to our welfare results, regulators should take into account the merchant’s market power in the goods and

geographic markets and the extent of network effect and decide on the NSR on a market-by-market basis instead of

imposing a rule common to all markets”. 471Id. at 27-28: “In order to assure social desirability, the NSR has to be applies in markets whose merchants have

sufficiently high market power… Hence, under the NSR, in a market whose merchants have sufficiently high market

power, cardholders do not pay much more for their purchases while benefit from a discount on the membership fee. In

these cases, the NSR… partially corrects the opposite price distortion in the goods market due to merchant market

power… On the other hand, if the market for goods is highly competitive… the NSR will introduce a distortion…

making society worse off". 472 Julian Wright, Optimal Card Payment Systems, supra note 439, at 590: “Under the no-surcharge rule, some

merchants will accept card payments and charge more (assuming card payments are more expensive for merchants to

handle than cash), while others will only accept cash and charge less. Any firm that accepts both card and cash

payments is vulnerable to a competitor that undercuts its price and just accepts the low-cost cash customers".

Page 113: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

113

up in the same situation whether NSR exists or not, i.e., in either case cash customers do not

purchase at card-accepting merchants.473

265. Hayashi sharpens the point that if allowed, merchants' decision whether to surcharge depends

on the competitive conditions in the relevant market. She claims that there are two kinds of

merchants with market power. Merchants who face elastic demand will be restrained from

surcharging, even if they have market power. Merchants with market power that face inelastic

demand, would not be restrained from surcharging.474

266. Bourguignon constructs a model in which the impact of surcharging depends on the level of the

MSF. If the MSF passes the tourist test or even lies just a little above Bm, allowing surcharging

reduces welfare, because then surcharging reduces the number of efficient card transactions. If

the MSF is higher than Bm, surcharging improves welfare as it restores proper payment

incentives and steers customers to cheaper payment instruments. When the MSF is very high

allowing merchants to surcharge improves welfare.475

267. Edelman & Wright claim that networks will always desire to impose NSR if they can do so, as

NSR increases the profits of the networks at the expense of consumer surplus.476 When NSR

applies, it is used to exploit merchants to pay a high MSF, of which part is used to subsidize

expensive cards that are over used.477

268. Korsgaard relaxes the assumption that surcharging neutralizes the interchange fee. He argues

that cardholders do not pay for transactions, with or without interchange fees.478 Surcharging

causes less card usage, which in turn makes the card network less attractive, so fewer merchants

473 Id. at 606: “Under Bertrand competition between merchants, both the card association and the regulator are

indifferent as to whether surcharges should be allowed or not. Bank profits and total surplus do not change when the no-

surcharge rule is lifted, regardless of the level of the interchange fee”. 474 Hayashi, A Puzzle of Card Payment Pricing, supra note 388; see also Wright, Optimal Card Payment Systems, supra

note 439, at 589: "In the case where merchants have local monopolies but are free to surcharge, we show they will do so

excessively, so as to extract surplus from inframarginal cardholders". 475 Bourguignon et al., Shrouded Transaction Costs, supra note 392, at 5: “[T]he welfare impact of card surcharges

depends on the level of the merchant fee; if the latter satisfies the tourist test or even lies reasonably above the

merchant’s convenience benefit, allowing card surcharge reduces welfare by excessively reducing card usage. For very

high merchant fees by contrast, allowing card surcharges improves welfare”. 476 Benjamin Edelman & Julian Wright, Price Coherence and Excessive Intermediation, at 31 (2014): “[A]n

intermediary always imposes price coherence if it has the ability to do so, as this increases its profit even though it also

lowers consumer surplus”. 477Id. at 32: "By offering benefits to buyers at no direct charge, intermediaries cause excessive usage of their services -

usage which then lets intermediaries extract significant fees from sellers, indeed beyond even the normal monopoly

fees". 478 Soren Korsgaard, Paying for Payments Free Payments and Optimal Interchange Fees, at 2 (1682 ECB Working

Paper, 2014): “payment services are often provided either for free or against periodical fees: Consumers’ marginal

cost is therefore zero, independent of interchange fees”;

Page 114: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

114

accept cards. In his model, when the MSF is not regulated, the optimal response of issuers to

surcharging merchants, is to choose a lower interchange fee in the first place. This has a positive

impact from a welfare perspective. On the other hand, surcharging causes some consumers to

pay with cash, despite their initial card preference.479 Surcharging is thus a sort of a whip, used

to restrain issuers’ market power, at the price of sacrificing marginal cardholders who quit using

cards.

269. Empirical studies reinforce the conclusion that merchants with market power surcharge

excessively.480 Merchants with market power that surcharge cause double distortion. Not only

their level of supply is sub-optimal at the initial phase (because of their market power), but after

an increase in the MSF, they surcharge excessively, and under-provision worsens.481

Proponents of NSR hold that when this is the case, the NSR has a restraining role, similar to

the one of the interchange fee in the model of Rochet & Tirole, described in the previous

chapter. NSR reduces the under-provision of cards, and offsets the market power of issuers.482

In my view, if issuers abuse their market power, regulators should combat the abuse, and not

mitigate its harsh effect by imposing a NSR, which is a further restriction in the abused

market.483

270. In sum, surcharging inflicts positive usage externality at the cost of negative network

externality, whereas NSR does the opposite. Intent to limit oversupply of cards and impose

internalization of costs, would favor surcharging, whereas ambition to cure undersupply,

increase the size of the network and induce cross subsidy between payment instruments

supports NSR.

479Id. at 4: "When fees are unregulated, permitting merchants to surcharge will lead banks to lower their fees, which is

positive from a welfare perspective. On the other hand, the surcharge itself causes some consumers to pay using cash,

even though they prefer card payments." 480 Nicole Jonker, Card Acceptance and Surcharging: The Role of Costs and Competition, 10 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1,

4 (2011): “[L]ocal monopolists ask a much higher surcharge fee than other surcharging merchants who face any

competition. This implies that monopolists more than other merchants employ the possibility to surcharge as a way to

extract any additional consumer surplus from card usage. These results are in line with the theoretical predictions by

Rochet and Tirole (2002), Wright (2003) and Hayashi (2006)”. 481 Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations, supra note 383,

at 562: “In case of initial underprovision of cards…, the card surcharge aggravates this underprovision and therefore

reduces welfare”;

Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees in Payment Systems, supra note 407, at 24: “Where merchants

compete imperfectly… since under surcharging consumers will face all the costs of the card network (including

covering the issuers’ and acquirers’ margins), but only some of the benefits, there will be too little card usage”. 482 Rochet & Tirole, An Economic Analysis of the Determination of Interchange Fees in Payment Card Systems, supra

note 877, at 76: "[W]e show in Rochet and Tirole (2002) that when issuers have market power, banning the NDR would

result in a systematic underprovision of card services." 483 Supra ¶ 241.

Page 115: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

115

All models agree that the relative costs of payment instruments determine the efficiency of

surcharging. Under NSR, cheap payment instruments subsidize expensive payment

instruments.484 If, for merchants, cards are more expensive than other payment instruments,

surcharging helps customers realize this. NSR, as a rule of thumb, disfavors those who pay with

cheap payment instruments.485

271. It is important to note that many of the scholars that support NSR have acted on behalf of Visa

or MasterCard, while many supporters of surcharging have been involved in proceedings

against Visa or MasterCard: Professor Rochet gave expert opinion for the Israeli Visa

companies in the Israeli proceedings (AT 4630/01), and together with Professor Tirole, advised

Visa. Professor Schmalensee was Visa's expert against the U.S. government. Wright advised

visa and also received research funds from Visa. Evans, too, received funds from Visa. In

contrast, Frankel is the expert for the merchants in proceedings against Visa. Carlton was the

expert on behalf of the U.S. Government in the case against Visa. Katz was the expert for the

Reserve Bank of Australia. Oz Shy, who supports surcharging, submitted an expert opinion

against the position of the Visa companies in the Israeli proceeding.486

272. In my view surcharging should be permitted for the following reasons.

273. First, nowadays payment card networks are mature. They have established themselves in the

market. They have high penetration rates among merchants and cardholders both in Israel and

abroad. Cards are ubiquitous. There is no concern for networks’ wholeness and size. The

practical concern is usage externality caused by excessive fees.

In this situation, NSR needlessly neutralizes competition between payment instruments.487

Surcharging, on the other hand, is a lynchpin of healthy competition between payment

instruments.488 Surcharging fosters efficient choice of payment instruments.489 Surcharging

484 Mark Armstrong, Competition in Two-Sided Markets, 37 RAND J. ECON. 668, 676 (2006): "[T]he consequence of a

ban on price discrimination is that one group is made better off (the group that has the higher price with discriminatory

pricing) while the other group is made worse off".

485 Sujit Chakravorti, Theory of Credit Card Networks: A Survey of the Literature, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 50, 58

(2003): “[T]here is consensus that one-price policies harm non-card users when cards are more ‘costly’ for merchants to

accept than other payment alternatives”. 486 Scott Schuh et al., Who Gains and Who Loses from Credit Card Payments? Theory and Calibrations, at 29 (FRB of

Boston Public Policy Discussion Papers No. 10-03. 2010). 487 Joseph Farrell, Efficiency and Competition between Payment Instruments, 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 26, 28 (2006). 488 United States v. Am. Express Co. 2015 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 20114 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015), at 187: “Steering is a

lynchpin to inter-network competition on the basis of price”. 489 Commission Staff Working Document - Annex to the Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the

Council on Payment Services in the Internal Market - Impact Assessment, sec. 48 (Dec. 1, 2005): “The overall social

cost of using payment services could be reduced if consumers and business selected the means of payments in a more

Page 116: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

116

signals customers about the real cost of the payment instrument they are using. Under NSR

customers are unaware of these costs.490

274. NSR serves as a barrier to entry, because it prevents cheap payment instruments from standing

out.491 Only when customers internalize the real costs of their payment instruments, they would

choose the most cost effective instrument for the “combined” customer – the cardholder and

the merchant.492

For example, PIN debit cards are cheaper than credit cards.493 For PIN debit to successfully

enter the Israeli market, PIN debit must overcome the chicken and egg problem and reach a

critical mass.494 In my view it is essential that merchants should be able to signal their customers

about PIN debit low prices, by differentiating debit and credit prices. Distinguished (lower)

MSF for debit is how debit cards were established in the United States.495

Whereas the concern for the size of mature networks is gratuitous, the concern over their fees

is very real. Because the network externality concern is the main basis on which the NSR is

built, then with this argument gone, the entire justification for NSR falls also (“Cessante ratione

legis cessat ipsa lex”).496

275. Second, surcharging is not costless. Merchants who surcharge risk negative reactions from

customers. In addition they have to invest resources in applying different prices to same

products, according to the payment instrument.497 The default preference of merchants is to

keep price coherence and not to surcharge. Merchants surcharge only as a last resort. Merchants

should be permitted to cry out and signal their customers if excessive prices are imposed on

them.

rational way. When prices paid by users reflect the real cost value of the service, they provide an incentive for users to

select services that meet their needs at the lowest possible private and social cost. This promotes the efficiency of the

payment system. It is well documented in studies that cost-based pricing of payment services triggers customer

behaviour and the right price signals can drive customers to select more efficient payment services rather than less

efficient ones”. 490 Sungbok Lee, The Effects of Issuer Competition on the Credit Card Industry, supra note 420, at 16: “Under the no-

surcharge rule, the higher interchange fee followed by the lower customer fee increases demand for card purchases,

because the effective cost of a card payment service is not informed to consumers”. 491 United States v. Am. Express Co., 2015 U.S. Dist. Lexis 20114, at 199-200 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015): “Notably,

Defendants do not strenuously dispute ... that such restrictions effectively raise a barrier to entry in the relevant market

for firms pursuing a low-price strategy”. 492 OECD, POLICY ROUNDTABLE, EXCESSIVE PRICES, at 7 DAF/COMP(2011)18. 493 Supra ¶ 125. 494 Infra ¶¶ 419 - 421. 495 Supra ¶¶ 105 - 106. 496 C.A 2299/99 Shfayer v. Diur Laole, 55(4) 213, 225 (2001). 497 Infra ch. 11.4.

Page 117: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

117

Merchants that weigh strategic considerations are even more reluctant to surcharge.498 Such

merchants surcharge only when they have no choice, but to signal to their customers, about the

high cost of the payment instrument.

276. Merchants may err and surcharge too high or too low, but the consequences fall on them, similar

to any other mistake in pricing. If a merchant is ready to take the risk involved in surcharging,

there is no reason to ban the merchant from doing so, let alone when this ban is a restrictive

arrangement.499 There is no reason to negate the autonomy of merchants to dispatch messages

to their clients about the costs of payment instruments. Surcharging should be a prerogative of

the merchant, and the merchant should not be deprived of it.

277. Third, the mere potential for merchants to surcharge is by itself, a credible threat that enhances

merchants’ bargaining power. Merchants can restrain networks from imposing high fees and

exert downward pressure on fees, just by having a possibility to surcharge. Surcharging should

be a deterrence mechanism to balance biased price structure against merchants.500

278. Fourth, surcharging increases transparency. Permitting surcharges induces merchants and

consumers to learn more about the different costs of payment instruments. Merchants will be

incentivized to better examine the price they pay for each payment instrument they accept.

Competition between payment instruments becomes more effective, as cheaper payment

instruments can be advertised and promoted.501 Consumers would also become aware to the

costs of the payment instruments they possess.

498 Infra ch. 11.3. 499 See infra ¶ 750. 500 COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT, SWD(2013)288 Final, at 135 (July 24, 2013):

“[A]t least some merchants saw surcharging as a 'threat' they could use in negotiations with their acquirers in order to

decrease their MSCs.”;

Robin A. Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks: Economics, Industry Developments, and Policy

Issues, at 44 (F.R.B. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 23-09, 2009): “[E]ven the threat of surcharging may

improve the bargaining position of merchants as a whole, which could induce the networks to lower interchange fees.”;

Chakravorti, Externalities in Payment Card Networks: Theory and Evidence, supra note 335, at 6: “Even if price

differentiation based on the payment instrument used is not common, the possibility to do so may enhance the

merchants’ bargaining power in negotiating their fees. Merchants can exert downward pressure on fees by having the

possibility to set instrument-contingent pricing.”;

Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L. REV. 1321, 1355

(2008): “Ultimately, though, whether merchants would actually surcharge is irrelevant. The ability to surcharge would

give merchants negotiating leverage to gain lower fees, and with lower fees, there would be no need to surcharge". 501 NICHOLAS ECONOMIDES, COMPETITION POLICY ISSUES IN THE CONSUMER PAYMENTS INDUSTRY, in MOVING

MONEY: THE FUTURE OF CONSUMER PAYMENT 113, 119 ( R. Litan & M. Baily eds., 2009). For a different view on

transparency see Bourguignon et al., Shrouded Transaction Costs, supra note 392, at 5-6.

Page 118: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

118

279. Fifth, nascent networks require interchange fees to lower cardholder fees and penetrate the

cardholder side. For them, NSR is a kind of infancy protection, which might be justified.

However, banning surcharges out of concern for the size of mature networks, when networks

are already in saturation, is ridiculous and unrelated to any legitimate fear.502

280. Sixth, the concern that some merchants will abuse their market power to surcharge excessively

ignores two points.

(a) If payment cards indeed yield net benefits to merchants, then excessive surcharging is

against their interest. If cards are more beneficial, surcharging steers customers to less attractive

payment instruments for the merchants, to the merchants’ detriment.

(b) According to Economides and Hayashi, most merchants with market power would tend not

to fully surcharge, because their prices are optimal for them at the outset.503

Nevertheless, if merchants (probably with market power and inelastic demand) abuse their

position and surcharge excessively, albeit taking the negative implications on themselves, a

specific ex-post rule to limit their surcharging opportunity might be considered. This is

preferable to an over-broad ex-ante NSR. In practice, regulators that are concerned about

excessive surcharges, avoid this situation by capping surcharges.504

281. Levitin suggested that in order to prevent excessive surcharges, merchants who surcharge

should be obligated to openly display the MSF they pay. Customers can then compare the

surcharge to the MSF. If networks know the MSF is to be openly displayed, this might also

restrain them from charging excessive fee from the outset. It would also neutralize negative

feelings of customers toward surcharges and refer them to blame the payment card firms.505

282. From all the above my conclusion is that unless abused, surcharging should be legitimate and

NSR should be prohibited.

502 Scott Schuh et al., An Economic Analysis of the 2011 Settlement between the Department of Justice and Credit Card

Networks, 8 J. COMPETITION L. ECON. 1, 25 (2012): "[T]he externality argument in favor of the no-surcharge rule is

most compelling in the case of an emerging payment network, where implicit subsidies may be needed to attract users

and establish the network. This argument may have little relevance in the case of a mature payment network, such as

credit cards in the United States”. 503 Supra ¶¶ 263, 265. 504 See, for example, the Australian experience, infra ¶ 663. 505 Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L. REV. 1321

(2008)

Page 119: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

119

Surcharging indeed restrains the market power of networks. However, the ability to surcharge

alone might not be sufficient to bring an efficient price level, let alone an efficient price

structure.506 In practice, most merchants do not surcharge, even when they are allowed to do

so. The reasons for that are discussed in chapter 11 below. The ability to surcharge is thus a

necessary but insufficient condition. The sufficiency of network competition to prevent

exploitation of the interchange fees will be explored now.

6.6. Payment Card Competition

283. In the 1990s, restaurants in Boston demanded that American Express reduce the MSF it charged

them, which was 3.25%. The conflict won the nickname “The Boston Fee Party”.507 Other

networks, such as Visa and MasterCard, took advantage of merchants' grievance. They offered

merchants cheaper MSF and gained market shares on account of American Express. Eventually

American Express had to reduce its MSF.508

The event led to the belief that competition between networks promotes efficient price level

and price structure, similar to the usual view that competition leads to an efficient equilibrium.

284. However, competition in two sided markets such as payment cards, differs from competition in

regular markets.509 There is an important asymmetry between cardholders and merchants that

heavily impacts payment card competition. The cardholder is the active side. The customer is

the one sitting on the driver’s sit and deciding with which payment instrument to pay.510

Merchants are passive in the sense they can accept or reject the payment instrument in which

the customer chooses to pay with, but they are not in a position to choose the payment

instrument themselves.

506 Edelman & Wright, Price Coherence and Excessive Intermediation, supra note 476, at 32: “In principle, this

neutrality need not hold. For example, menu costs or other frictions could inhibit pass through even if intermediaries are

not allowed to impose price coherence... and the benefits of banning price coherence may be overstated.” 507 The “Boston Tea Party” is one of the constitutive events in American independence history,

http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Boston_Tea_Party 508 DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND

BORROWING 185-88 (2d ed. 2005). 509 Julian Wright, One-Sided Logic in Two-Sided Markets 3 REV. NETWORK ECON. 44 (2004); Rochet & Tirole,

Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems, supra note 390, at 1: "It is now well-understood that the

implementation of competition policy must be amended in order to reflect two-sidedness". 510 Farrell, Efficiency and Competition between Payment Instruments, supra note 487, at 26: “[M]ost observers believe

that cardholders are 'in the driver’s seat'.”;

Julian Wright, Why Payment Card Fees are Biased Against Retailers, supra note 401, at 3: “[W]hile consumers ignore

the benefits retailers get from accepting cards, the reverse is not true."; see also supra ¶ 135.

Page 120: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

120

285. Two key terms in the terminology of payment card competition should be introduced:

“multihoming” and “singlehoming”.

Multihoming occurs when customers at one side of the market, choose to interact with more

than one platform. Cardholder's multihoming occurs if a cardholder belongs to more than one

payment card network (for example, American Express and Visa). Multihoming on the

merchant side occurs when merchants accept cards of more than one network.

Multihoming is a term drawn from the internet literature. The term was adopted by Rochet &

Tirole to the context of payment cards.511 Other examples of multihoming are buyers or sellers

contracting with a number of real estate agents; engagement of men or women with more than

one dating club; or interaction of readers or advertisers with several newspapers.

Singlehoming occurs when a person interacts only with one platform. Cardholders that have

only one card in their wallet are singlehoming, as are merchants that accept only one brand of

cards.512 Like multihoming, also singlehoming occurs in other multisided platforms. For

example, readers of newspapers often subscribe to only one newspaper; end-users usually

purchase only one game console. On the other side, game developers aspire to multihome, and

contract with many consoles, to disperse the games they develop.

Multihoming and singlehoming are important factors in determining the effects of competition

on both price level and price structure.513

286. Effect on price level - the conventional wisdom is that price level tends to be lower under

multihoming. This is the typical result of multiplicity of competitors, drawn from ordinary one-

511 Rochet & Tirole, Tying, supra note 408, at 1334: “The term “multi-homing” is borrowed from the Internet literature.

It refers to a situation where some users are members of several platforms. In the context of payment cards it means

either that consumers hold several cards (buyers' multi-homing) or that merchants accept several cards (sellers' multi-

homing);

Frederic Jenny, Competition Policy Issues in the Financial Services Sector: Regulation of the Interchange Fees in

Credit Card Systems, at 10 (Conference competition policy for regulated industries, Athens, Sept. 2008): "Multihoming

is a situation in which some agents, in one or both sides of a two sided market, adopt more than one platform, so that

interactions may occur through a series of alternative channels. A shop manager multihomes when several credit cards

are accepted for payment. A consumer multihomes when she owns several credit cards, among which to choose”.

Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets, 1 J. EUR. ECON. ASS'N 990, 992

(2003). 512 Mark Armstrong, Competition in Two-Sided Markets, supra note 484, at 669: “When an agent chooses to use only

one platform, it has become common to say the agent is “single-homing.” When an agent uses several platforms, she is

said to “multi-home".” 513Id.; see also David S. Evans, The Antitrust Economics of Multi-Sided Markets, 20 YALE J. ON REG. 325, 346 (2003):

“Multihoming affects both the price level and the pricing structure”.

Page 121: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

121

sided markets. Multihoming means that cardholders have several cards in their wallet and

merchants accept variety of cards. This increases the resistance of merchants to expensive

cards.514 Merchants' elasticity of demand is more elastic under multihoming. Customers can, at

least theoretically, switch to substitute networks, because they are already connected to them.

Refusal of a merchant to accept an expensive card, leads to less severe consequences when

cardholders are multihoming. The conventional wisdom opines that under multihoming,

networks must cut prices to merchants. Competition for merchants due to multihoming causes

prices to fall and lowers the price level.515

287. The conventional wisdom is based on symmetric pass through rates in the issuing and acquiring

sides, and concave demand curves.516 Under different (and, in my opinion, more realistic)

assumptions, especially when the pass through rate on the issuing side is lower than on the

acquiring side, due to market power of issuers, competition can raise price level, even when

cardholders are multihoming.517 As explained below, this occurs when A. Interchange fees rise

as a result of competition, in order to finance reduction in cardholder fees and rewards; B.

Demand of merchants is rigid, due to strategic considerations; C. Issuers keep some of the

revenue from the interchange fee to themselves as profit. The result is that cardholder fees

indeed decrease, but the increase in the MSF is larger than the decrease in cardholder fees.

Under such circumstances, competition can yield an increase in the price level (Pm+Pc).

Specifically, Pm might increase more than Pc decreases.

514 Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations, supra note 383,

at 561: ”System competition increases merchant resistance”. 515 Rochet & Tirole, Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets, supra note 511, at 1006: “The price level is lower for

associations with healthy competition among their members.”;

Chakravorti & Roson, Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Case of Payment Networks, supra note 346, at

129: “In our model, market competition reduces the total price, the sum of the consumer and merchant fees, and

increases merchant and consumer welfare.”;

David S. Evans, The Antitrust Economics of Multi-Sided Markets, 20 YALE J. ON REG. 325, 346 (2003): “[T]he price

level tends to be lower with multihoming because the availability of substitutes tends to put pressure on the multi-sided

firms to lower their prices.”;

Stewart E. Weiner & Julian Wright, Interchange Fees in various Countries: Developments and Determinants, 4 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 290, 313 (2005): “Greater inter-system competition should not increase the total fees charged across

both sides of the market.”;

Mark Armstrong & Julian Wright, Two-Sided Markets, Competitive Bottlenecks and Exclusive Contracts, 32 ECON.

THEORY 353, 359 (2007). 516 E. Glen Weyl, The Price Theory of Two-Sided Markets, at 7 (2009) available at http://ssrn.com/paper=1324317: “However when demand is log-convex on one side of the market… things can be entirely different... competition and

price controls may well raise the price level”. 517 Farrell, Efficiency and Competition between Payment Instruments, supra note 487 at 37: “[W]hereas one might

naturally think of interchange as primarily affecting fee structure, not fee level. Changes in the level of interchange will

affect only fee structure if pass through of those changes is symmetric on the acquiring and issuing sides”.

Page 122: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

122

288. Impact on the price structure - Competition significantly affects the price structure.

Competition leads to a drop in the price on one side, in which the competition is fierce, and to

a rise in the price on the other side, where the competition is weaker. The interchange fee is a

major key in this competition.

289. Generally, if one side is singlehoming and the other side is multihoming, the strong competition

would be on the side which is singlehoming.518 In the extreme, the multihoming side will pay

monopoly prices, because the network has monopoly on access to its customers on the

singlehoming side.519

This is similar to the way a telecom operator enjoys a monopoly over the termination of calls

made to its subscribers. When cardholders are singlehoming each issuer can charge interchange

fees that reflect its market power.520 In the literature this situation is called "competitive

bottlenecks".521 Merchants cannot afford to refuse the only card that the cardholder carries,

especially if it is a common card.522

290. When merchants do not surcharge, a cardholder who can choose between different payment

instruments, would pay with the most beneficial instrument for herself.523 The crucial element

becomes recruiting cardholders.524

518 Marc Rysman, An Empirical Analysis of Payment Card Usage, 55 J. INDUS. ECON. 1, 9 (2007): "[W]hen one side of

a market multi-homes and one side singlehomes, competition between intermediaries is fierce on the side that

singlehomes and much lighter or even non-existent on the side that multi-homes". 519Rochet & Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems, supra note 390, at 8: “Intuitively, under

single-homing, each system holds a monopoly of access to its own cardholders.”;

Armstrong, Competition in Two-Sided Markets, 668, supra note 484, at 669: “[P]latforms have monopoly power over

providing access to their singlehoming customers for the multi-homing side. This monopoly power naturally leads to

high prices being charged to the multi-homing side, and there will be too few agents on this side being served from a

social point of view”; 520 Rochet & Tirole, Externalities, id. at 8: “Intuitively, under single-homing, each system holds a monopoly of access

to its own cardholders (in the same way each telecom operator enjoys a monopoly over the termination of calls made to

its subscribers). Thanks to this competitive bottleneck, it can “charge” a monopoly merchant discount”. 521 Ozlem Bedre-Defolie & Emilio Calvano, Pricing Payment Cards, 5 AM. ECON. J. MICROECONOMICS 206, 221

(2013): “Assuming that consumers get only one card (single-home) and merchants multi-home, network competition

would fail to mitigate the distortion we describe… Intuitively, competition has a bias favoring the single-homing side,

since steering customers toward an exclusive relationship lets platforms extract monopoly rents from the multi-homing

side users (competitive bottleneck)”; Mark Armstrong & Julian Wright, Two-Sided Markets, Competitive Bottlenecks

and Exclusive Contracts, 32 ECON. THEORY 353 (2007). 522 Timothy J. Muris, Payment Card Regulation, supra note 176, at 522: ”Because most consumers do not carry all of

the major payment cards, refusing to accept a major card may cost the merchant substantial sales." 523 Wilko Bolt & Sujit Chakravorti, Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment Media (FRB of Chicago

Working Paper No. 2008-11. 2008): "However, when merchants are unable to price differentiate and post one price,

consumers do not face any price inducements in the store, and are assumed to opt for the instrument with the greatest

functionality”. 524 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 500, at 22: “[N]etwork competition has

varying effects on interchange fees, depending crucially on the cardholding behavior of consumers”.

Page 123: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

123

Multihoming Analysis

291. When merchants and cardholders multihome, merchants' resistance to expensive cards

increases, because cardholders carry more than one card in their wallet. Competition between

networks will be reflected in downward pressure on the MSF, which in turn will exert

downward pressure on the interchange fee.525

292. Reality reinforces theory in that there are merchants who do not accept American Express or

Diners cards, for which the MSF is more expensive than of Visa and MasterCard. These

merchants rely on customers' multihoming, i.e., cardholders would pay with another card, but

not abandon the merchant.526

293. When both sides are multihoming, even though the control is in the hands of the cardholder,

the merchant can steer the cardholder to the merchant's preferred payment instrument. The

merchant can use direct rewards or surcharge (if surcharging is permitted). Indeed, merchants

often provide discounts or other rebates for those who purchase with the preferable card for

them. 527

For example, Super-Pharm offers benefits to customers who purchase with Lifestyle cards that

are issued by Isracard in conjunction with Super-Pharm. Supersal offers similar discounts to its

525 Jean Tirole, Payment Card Regulation and the use of Economic Analysis in Antitrust, 4 TOULOUSE SCHOOL ECON.,

at 18 (2011): “System competition puts downward pressure on IFs only if individual cardholders hold cards on different

systems. Under full “multi-homing” merchants cannot be charged more than their net benefit.”;

Rochet & Tirole, Tying, supra note 408, at 1334: “[W]hen consumers hold multiple cards (multi-home), system

competition tilts the price structure toward lower merchant discounts and higher cardholder fees, because merchants

then have an incentive to turn down the card that is most expensive to them”.

Weiner & Wright, Interchange Fees in various Countries: Developments and Determinants, supra note 515. 526 Jenny, Competition Policy Issues, supra note 511, at 10: “When consumers hold several payment instruments,

platforms cannot charge merchants with excessive commissions, otherwise the merchants would not choose to be

affiliated with the platform. Merchants need not be affiliated with several platforms, because they know that consumers

can substitute one payment instrument for another. Best example is Visa which overtook American Express by charging

lower merchants fees”. 527 Sujit Chakravorti, Externalities in Payment Card Networks: Theory and Evidence, 9 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1, 10

(2010), at 10: “If consumers carry multiple types of payment instruments, merchants may be able to steer them away

from more costly payment instruments.”;

Rochet & Tirole, Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets, supra note 511, at 1001: “By undercutting the rival

platform, each platform thus induces some sellers (those with intermediate types) to stop multihoming, a strategy

known as steering.”;

Graeme Guthrie & Julian Wright, Competing Payment Schemes, 55 J. INDUS. ECON. 37, 38-39 (2007): “[I]f cardholders

always hold multiple cards, merchants can steer consumers to their preferred card network, meaning platform

competition will focus on attracting merchants to accept their cards exclusively. In this case, despite the additional

incentive merchants face to accept cards, platform competition can result in lower merchant fees and higher card fees

compared to those set by a single scheme.”; GAO-10-45, supra note 28, at 29-31.

Page 124: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

124

loyalty Supersal cardholders. There are many more affinity cards. Merchants are using club-

cards to steer customers to the merchant's preferable payment instrument.

294. In Israel, when a merchant steers customers to pay with the merchant's preferable card, the

merchant does not pay a lower interchange fee. The Trio Agreement stipulates that an acquirer

may not charge merchants different fees for cards of the same brand, based on the identity of

the issuer. In addition, issuers may not discriminate between acquirers.528

In practice, however, there is revenue sharing between issuers and merchants that operate

affinity or club cards. The justification for the revenue sharing, which in practice equals a

reduced MSF (allegedly contrary to the Trio Agreement), is that such merchants act as a

marketing arm of the issuer. The bottom line is that merchants pay less for affinity cards.

295. Affinity cards encourage shopping in affiliated merchants, but they pose a trade-off for

merchants. A purchase with a loyalty card generates higher revenue but also higher costs.

Merchants must weigh the possible increase in sales against the required rewards associated

with their affinity cards. Merchants must also consider the increase in advertising costs and

marketing efforts, including ad-hoc campaigns with unaffiliated cards. Merchants must also

balance the loss of revenue associated with giving discounts to buyers who would have paid

with the merchant’s most preferred payment instrument even in the absence of a discount.

Merchants choose whether to invest in steering through affinity cards on the basis of these

conflicting considerations.529

296. However, even under multihoming, steering is only a passive and partial remedy for merchants.

Merchants will not necessarily steer and certainly not hasten to refuse expensive cards. An

effort of a merchant to steer, might encounter abandonment and not the desired steering. After

all, the merchant does not know in advance if the customer is multihoming or singlehoming,

528 AT 610/06 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, (§ 5 of Annex B to the Motion to Approve a Restrictive

Arrangement), Antitrust 6652 (Oct. 30, 2006). 529 Worthington, supra note 45; Steven Semeraro, Assessing the Costs & Benefits of Credit Card Rewards: A Response

to Who Gains and Who Loses from Credit Card Payments? Theory and Calibrations, at 32-33 (2012): “In short, if

merchants recognize that rewarding their customers helps expand their own businesses, similar programs should also be

a good way to expand the credit card business”;

Tamás Briglevics & Oz Shy, Why Don’t most Merchants use Price Discounts to Steer Consumer Payment Choice? 12-9

FRB BOSTON, at 21 (2012): “[T]he degree to which profit increases or decreases as a result of steering with price

discounts depends on both consumers’ responsiveness to price incentives and on the tradeoff between reductions in

payment processing costs and the loss of revenue associated with giving discounts to all buyers, including buyers who

would have paid with the merchant’s most preferred payment instrument even in the absence of a discount.”;

Sumit Agarwal et al., Why do Banks Reward their Customers to use their Credit Cards? (Fed. Res. Bank of Chicago

Working Paper No. 2010-19. 2010); see also infra ¶ 335.

Page 125: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

125

and even if the customer is multihoming, she might be eager to pay with a specific card. To

avoid the risk, it is almost always profitable for the merchant to accept the less favorable

payment instrument. Profit from the transaction usually exceeds the cost difference of the

different payment instruments.530 Merchants are also aware that accepting cards, even

expensive cards, increases their own revenue at the expense of their competitors. For these and

for more reasons, explored more deeply in chapter 11 below, merchants do not tend to

surcharge, let alone refuse expensive cards, even under cardholders' multihoming.

297. Cardholders who multihome often have a preferred card. The fact that they are multihoming in

adoption does not mean they are multihoming in usage. In fact, most cardholders are

singlehoming in usage.531

Multihoming Merchants And Singlehoming Customers

298. When customers singlehome and merchants multihome, competition is focused on cardholders.

Conquering the cardholder means having monopoly access to her wallet.532 Demand elasticity

of merchants to cards becomes rigid. Competition for cardholders compels networks to offer

cardholders low fees, free funding period, and rewards. Cardholder fees decrease as competition

increases.533 A higher interchange fee is required to finance rewards.534 This exerts an upward

pressure on the MSF (and on final prices).535

530 Supra ¶ 194. 531 Infra notes 547-549. 532 Ozlem Bedre-Defolie & Emilio Calvano, Pricing Payment Cards, 5 AM. ECON. J. MICROECONOMICS 206, 210

(2013): "If merchants accept the cards of multiple card networks (multi-home), competition increases the distortion

even further as networks try to woo cardholders back from their rivals by lowering their prices."

Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Cards Fee Structure: What Drives Payment Card Rewards? at 7 (FRB Of

Kansas City Working paper 08-07, 2009): “When a cardholder holds only a single-branded card or has a strong

preference among cards (singlehoming), then each card network can set monopolistic merchant fees”. 533 Jean Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report, 37 RAND J. ECON. 645, 660 (2006). 534 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 500, at 4: “In general, competition among

payment networks is unlikely to exert downward pressure on interchange fees because the networks tend to focus their

competitive efforts on getting their card to be the favored card of a consumer. This objective is facilitated by having a

higher interchange fee that can be used to fund more attractive terms (e.g., lower fees and higher rewards) for the

consumer.”;

Guthrie & Wright, Competing Payment Schemes, supra note 527, at 59: “[C]ompetition between schemes can be the

cause of high interchange fees.” 535 Fumiko Hayashi, Network Competition and Merchant Discount Fees, at 32 (FRB of Kansas City, Payments System

Research Department, Working Paper 05-04. 2006): “Network can increase its net revenue by setting the cardholder fee

lower than its rival’s cardholder fee. Since lower cardholder fees likely make equilibrium merchant fees higher, the

results may emphasize that network competition does not necessarily lower merchant fees.”;

Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 436, at 650-51: “[N]etwork competition

may not reduce merchant fees.”;

ALBERT FOER, ELECTRONIC PAYMENT SYSTEMS AND INTERCHANGE FEES: BREAKING THE LOG JAM ON SOLUTIONS TO

MARKET POWER, Am. Antitrust Institute, at 6 (2010): “Ironically, the competition this creates between Visa and

MasterCard is not toward lower prices, but higher ones.”

Page 126: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

126

299. The effect of competition versus monopoly is particularly evident on the cardholders’ side. If

there were just one monopoly network with many issuers and acquirers, it would set a monopoly

price on the cardholder side, in order to extract maximum consumer surplus. The monopoly

network would do the same on the merchant side, taking into consideration the interdependency

of the two sides.

Competition yields lower cardholder fees and higher MSF than a monopoly.536 Competition

forces networks to reduce cardholder fee from monopoly level. Competition is reflected in

lower cardholder fees and abundance of rewards bestowed on cardholders.537 Those rewards

are fueled and financed by higher interchange fees.538 Frankel cites publications and notices of

Visa and MasterCard officials, who explained recurring increases in the MSF by the need to

increase interchange fee in pursuit of cardholders.539

300. Nevertheless, the reduction of cardholder fees does not offset the increase in the price level,

due to issuers' higher costs under competition. Total issuers' costs are higher in competition

than in a monopoly. Issuers spend more in competition (than a monopolist), on advertising and

marketing efforts including rewards. The effect of such expenditures is only an internal shifting

between cards, with no effect on aggregate consumption or volume of transactions.540 Thus, the

price level is higher in competition than under a monopoly, even if pass through on the issuing

side is full (a far-fetched assumption), let alone when pass through to rewards is partial. From

a social perspective, this kind of competition on cardholders, fueled by the interchange fee (and

a corresponding MSF and price increase), is futile.

301. Cardholders' tendency to singlehome leads competition to inefficient price structure, biased in

favor of cardholders against merchants.541 Strong competition might reduce welfare more than

536 Ozlem Bedre-Defolie & Emilio Calvano, Pricing Payment Cards, 5 AM. ECON. J. MICROECONOMICS 206, 222

(2013): “Hence, in equilibrium, cardholders pay too little and merchants pay too much.”; Hayashi, Network Competition

and Merchant Discount Fees, ibid. 537 Chakravorti, Externalities in Payment Card Networks: Theory and Evidence, supra note 527, at 8: “As a general

finding, competing networks try to attract end-users who tend to singlehome, since attracting them determines which

network has the greater volume of business. Accordingly, the price structure is tilted in favor of end-users who

singlehome”. 538 Guthrie & Wright, Competing Payment Schemes, supra note 527, at 59: “[T]o the extent competing (heterogeneous)

merchants internalize their customers’ benefits from using cards and to the extent cardholders are at least as important

as merchants in determining which card will be adopted by both sides, system competition will generally drive

interchange fees higher.";

Carlos Arango, Kim P. Huynh & Leonard Sabetti, Consumer Payment Choice: Merchant Card Acceptance Versus

Pricing Incentives, 55 J. BANK. FIN. 130, 131 (2015): “Rewards in turn are funded through an interchange fee”. 539 Alan S. Frankel, Towards a Competitive Card Payments Marketplace, at 33-34 (RBA, 2007). 540 Infra ¶336; see also supra note 404 541 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Two-Sided Markets: An Overview, at 35 (2004): "Platform competition does not

necessarily lead to an efficient price structure."; see also note 427 and accompanying text.

Page 127: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

127

under monopolistic network.542 Hayashi and others go further and claim that when competition

causes issuers’ costs to rise, in order to finance rewards, then even if cardholders are

multihoming, the bleak result is an economy inferior to that without cards at all(!).543 This

542 Santiago Carbo Valverde et al., Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation, at 11 (Federal Reserve

Bank of Chicago Working Paper No. 09-11. 2009): “[N]etwork competition may yield a price structure that has a lower

social welfare than when there is only one network. If competition is too strong on the consumer side, the network may

extract too much from merchants resulting in higher than socially optimal interchange fees.”;

Fumiko Hayashi, Pricing and Welfare Implications of Payment Card Network Competition, at 6 (FRB of Kansas City,

Working Paper 06-03. 2006): “It is possible that equilibrium merchant fees under network competition are higher than

the merchant fee set by a monopoly network."; id. at 21: “[T]he social welfare is always lower under network

competition than under monopoly because providing rewards is costly.”;

Rochet, Competing Payment Systems: Key Insights from the Academic Literature, at 8 “[I]ntersystem competition is

completely ineffective when consumers hold a single card.”;

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT ACCOMPANYING THE PROPOSAL FOR A DIRECTIVE ON

PAYMENT SERVICES, at 104, SWD(2013) 288 Final, (24.7.2013): “[C]ompetition between payment schemes may lead to

merchants being charged more and consumers less, which means higher interchange fee relative to what a single

scheme would set... competition between schemes is not necessarily more likely to yield a socially optimal interchange

fee than when card services are provided by a single network”. 543 Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: Policy Considerations of Payment Card Rewards,

at 7-8 (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No. 08-08. 2008): “[W]hen per transaction costs and fees are proportional to

the transaction value, even if all cardholders are multihoming, the equilibrium cardholder fee set by competing card

networks would unlikely be the most efficient; rather it would be less efficient than the cardholder fee set by a

monopoly network. This implies that competition among card networks potentially deteriorates social welfare. In fact,

the results suggest that when per transaction costs and fees are proportional to the transaction value, the equilibrium

social welfare would not just be lower than the maximum social welfare, but would also potentially be lower than the

social welfare without cards at all. Consumers as a whole and merchants would be worse off, compared with the

economy without cards. This may warrant public policy interventions”.

Fumiko Hayashi, Do U.S Consumers Really Benefit from Payment Card Rewards?, FRB Kansas Econ. REV. 37, 52

(2009): “If the current level of rewards is too high, then that level may not only offer less social welfare than zero

rewards, but it may also potentially offer less social welfare than making transactions without payment cards at all.

Rewards that exceed a certain level unlikely play a role of reducing the total costs to society... Further, additional

rewards may potentially increase total costs of transactions... A higher level of rewards may raise the merchant fees and

ultimately raise retail prices, which may increase the value of the transaction. Thus, a higher level of rewards may

require more real resources to society. If this additional resource cost is substantial, then social welfare with very

generous rewards may potentially be lower than social welfare without cards at all”.

Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Cards Fee Structure: What Drives Payment Card Rewards?, at 13 (FRB

Of Kansas City Working paper 08-07. 2009): “[T]he theoretical models suggest that when per transaction costs and fees

are proportional to the transaction value, the equilibrium social welfare would potentially be lower than the social

welfare without cards at all. Consumers as a whole and merchants would be worse off, compared with the economy

without cards at all”.

Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: What is the Optimal Balance between Merchant Fee

and Payment Card Rewards?, At 19-20 (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No. 08-06. 2008): “When the merchant

fee is higher than the merchant transactional benefit from a card, then the product price set by the merchants is likely to

be higher, compared with the level of the product price in the economy where no card products are available. As a

result, consumers who use the alternative payment method would likely be worse off, compared with the economy

without cards. Some card using consumers, whose transactional benefit from a card is relatively low, would also likely

be worse off, due to the higher product price”.

Rong Ding & Julian Wright, Payment Card Interchange Fees and Price Discrimination, at 5 (2015): "Our paper also

relates to the recent work of Edelman and Wright (2015), who provide a setting in which a platform that imposes price

coherence ends up setting such high fees to merchants that the platform actually destroys consumer surplus; that is,

consumers would be better of without the platform. We show a similar result exists in our setting… card platform

contributes nothing to overall welfare despite being profitable… consumer surplus is reduced by the existence of the

card platform, reflecting that the platform raises retail prices… the extent of consumer surplus loss and harm to welfare

from leaving interchange fees unregulated may be so significant that they offset all the positive benefits that payment

cards provide.";

Wang Zhu, Market Structure and Payment Card Pricing: What Drives the Interchange? 28 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 86, 96

(2010): “At equilibrium, consumer rewards and total card transaction values increase with interchange fees, but

consumer surplus and merchant profits may not improve”.

Page 128: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

128

conclusion is extreme but even most conservative scholars admit that payment card competition

expressed in excessive rewards might yield an inferior economy, a phenomenon that Rochet &

Tirole (and others) call "wasteful competition".544

302. Thus, in the payment cards sector, the conventional approach from ordinary markets, according

to which the ‘invisible hand’ of competition lowers prices and increases welfare, is reversed.

Contrary to the conventional wisdom, competition expressed in "reward wars", may actually

increase price level and worsen welfare.545

303. The situation of multihoming merchants and singlehoming customers is common. Merchants

are most often multihoming.546 In Israel, merchants generally accept a variety of payment cards.

Even merchants who do not accept American Express or Diners usually do accept Visa,

MasterCard and Isracard.

304. Regarding cardholders, the IAA found in 2005 that cardholders tend to singlehome.547 An

empirical research in Spain came to the same conclusion.548 Other studies found that even when

cardholders possess several cards, they tend to use only the card which gives them the maximum

benefits and rewards.549 Thus the empirical evidence supports singlehoming in usage, at least

544 Rochet & Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems, supra note 390, at 11: "wasteful

competition Suppose that issuers do not tacitly collude, but compete in ways that bring limited benefits to

consumers.28"; and in n. 28 which they refer to: "The large advertising expenditures mentioned by Farrell in the above

citation sometimes fall into this category.";

Steven Semeraro, The Antitrust Economics (and Law) of Surcharging Credit Card Transactions, 14 STAN. J. L. BUS.

FIN. 343, 345-46 (2009): “Card issuers may then retain some revenue as supracompetitive profit and wastefully

compete some away in pursuit of highly profitable cardholders.”;

Jean Tirole, Payment Card Regulation and the use of Economic Analysis in Antitrust, supra note 525, at17: “If the

profits associated with cardholders’ installed base are dissipated through wasteful advertising expenditures to “acquire”

cardholders, profits should not enter social welfare calculations.”. 545Chakravorti, Externalities in Payment Card Networks: Theory and Evidence, supra note 527, at 7-8: “Economic

theory suggests that competition generally reduces prices, increases output, and improves welfare. However, with two-

sided markets, network competition may yield an inefficient price structure… Unlike one-sided markets, competition

does not necessarily improve the balance of prices for two-sided markets.";

Santiago Carbo Valverde et al., Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation, at 11 (Federal Reserve

Bank of Chicago Working Paper No. 09-11. 2009): “"Standard economic theory suggests that competition would

increase consumer and merchant surplus. Some theoretical models predict that competition in a two-sided market

environment may worsen social welfare.”;

Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Cards Fee Structure: What Drives Payment Card Rewards? 13 (FRB Of

Kansas City Working paper 08-07. 2009): “Thus, competition among card networks would likely increase the

equilibrium merchant fee and the level of payment card rewards”. 546 Valverde, id. at 11: “Merchants generally accept cards from multiple networks”. 547 Declaration on Isracard as Monopoly in Acquiring Isracart and MasterCard, at 13, Antitrust 5000034 (May 22,

2005) (finding that in only 3% of checking accounts in big banks who own a payment card firm, there are standing

orders to another payment card). 548 Santiago Carbo Valverde et al., Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation, at 11 (Federal Reserve

Bank of Chicago Working Paper No. 09-11. 2009): “Merchants generally accept cards from multiple networks and

consumers choose their preferred issuer and network”. 549 Marc Rysman, an Empirical Analysis of Payment Card Usage, 55 J. INDUS. ECON. L (2007) “[C]onsumers maintain

cards in multiple networks but tend to use only one network. That suggests that they have a preference for single-

Page 129: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

129

for large part of purchases.

In this context there is a major difference between late and early models. In early models, there

was no distinction between possession and usage. Possession dictated usage.550 In practice,

however, singlehoming in usage might occur even if the cardholder is multihoming in adoption.

An unused card might be kept in the wallet for security reasons or only for certain specific

purchases.551

305. Hayashi found that if the share of multihoming cardholders is less than 20 percent, a network

can act towards merchants, as if the network is monopoly in supplying access to its

singlehoming cardholders.552

306. Competition for cardholders leads even small networks to exert market power over

merchants.553 Rochet & Tirole note that sometimes cardholders of a certain brand are perceived

as being more lucrative. Rochet & Tirole call them "Marquee Buyers".554 Where merchants

attach special importance to cardholders of a minor network, its small market share does not

lessen the market power that it can exert on merchants. This effect is even stronger in specific

sectors, like travel and entertainment, in which merchants are more dependent on those more

lucrative cardholders.555

homing but recognize that some purchases are valuable enough to warrant using a less-preferred network."; id. at 34:

"[V]ery few consumers multi-home in the sense that they place almost all of their spending on a single payment

network. However, about two-thirds of consumers maintain cards from different networks so they may switch to multi-

homing for relatively small benefits.”;

Arango et al., Consumer Payment Choice: Merchant Card Acceptance Versus Pricing Incentives, supra note 538, at

138: “Our results empirically confirm the role that rewards play as a coordination device, shifting the ranking of top-of-

the-wallet payment instruments and increasing the likelihood of single-homing in payments”. 550 Rochet & Tirole, Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets, supra note 511; Fabio M. Manenti & Ernesto

Somma, Plastic Clashes: Competition among Closed and Open Systems in the Credit Card Industry, WPA Industrial

Organization, at 9 (2002): “[A]doption and usage decisions are equivalent and depends on the per transaction cost of

card usage”. In a later version from 2010, (Fabio M. Manenti and Ernesto Somma, Plastic Clashes: Competition Among

Closed and Open Payment Systems, at 9 (March 2010)), Manenti relaxed this assumption, and enabled adoption

decision to be independent of usage which is decided per transaction: “when individuals endorse a platform, they do not

know in advance how many transactions they will perform, and they take the adoption decision on a per transaction

basis”. 551 Rysman, supra note 549. 552 Hayashi, Network Competition and Merchant Discount Fees, supra note 535 at 31: "For most parameter values, if

the share of multihoming cardholders is less than 20 percent, networks can act as if they are monopolies". 553 Rysman & Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, supra note 389, at 21: "Card networks have monopoly power

over access to those consumers to the extent that the consumers only want to use that form of payment (e.g. if

consumers single home). In that case, card platforms can theoretically have a type of “market power” with regard to

merchants even if the card platforms have relatively small market shares among consumers". 554 Rochet & Tirole, Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets, supra note 511, at 1008: “[M]arquee buyers make the

platform more attractive for the sellers”. 555 The following facts findings from United States v. Am. Express Co., 2015 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 20114, at 130-32

(E.D.N.Y. Feb. 19, 2015), are worth noting, although the decision was reversed: “Similar "single-homing" behavior is

Page 130: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

130

307. The degree of multihoming / singlehoming is indeed important to determine the effects of

competition. However, it is not conclusive. Several other factors are also influential.

308. The degree of competition between merchants affects the results of competition between

networks. Competitive merchants, who are driven by strategic considerations, are less resistant

to increases in the MSF than merchants with market power.556 Networks with categories of

interchange fees can bypass the resistance of merchants with market power, by offering them

lower category of fees. However, if there is only one level of interchange fee, then merchants

with market power serve as a barrier to attempts of networks to increase the interchange fee. In

this sense, ascribing the State its agencies and the Israeli Electric Company (the “marginal

consumer” of cards) to a low category of interchange fee in Israel, prevented a possible decrease

(that could occur without categories) for all other merchants.

309. Heterogeneity between merchants enables the networks to sacrifice marginal merchants,

when the price structure is tilted against them as a consequence of networks competition.

According to Guthrie & Wright, competition will have no effect on homogeneous merchants,

because when merchants are homogeneous, the worst result for them, monopolistic pricing, is

achieved anyway.557 Monopolistic network determines the interchange fee and the resulting

MSF at the maximum rate that merchants (all of them, because they are homogeneous) will still

accept cards. Higher costs to issuers, because of competition, cannot be subsidized by any

further increase of the MSF.

also observed among the approximately 10-20% of Amex cardholders who own or regularly carry only their Amex

cards... Amex's industry-leading corporate card program, for instance, drives a significant degree of insistent spending,

particularly at those T&E merchants that cater to the needs of business travelers... approximately 70% of Corporate

Card consumers are subject to some form of "mandation" policy, by which employers require the employee-cardholders

to use Amex cards for business expenses”;

Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 500, at 51 n. 113 (FRB Finance and Economics

Discussion Series 23-09. 2009): “A merchant’s tradeoff between costs and benefits of card acceptance implies that a

merchant will not necessarily choose to accept cards from the network with the lowest interchange fee. The benefits that

a merchant derives from card acceptance include both the transactional benefits (e.g., reduced handling costs or

increased certainty of payment, relative to other payment methods) and increased demand for its products. The

magnitude of the latter effect depends, in part, on the surplus that consumers derive from the use of a given network’s

card – the greater the consumer’s surplus from a card, the more likely he or she will be to choose a merchant based on

whether the merchant accepts that card. In general, consumer surplus from using a network’s card will be higher (e.g.,

rewards will be greater or fees will be lower) when the interchange fee is higher. Thus, when making its card

acceptance decision, a merchant will weigh the cost of the interchange fee (or, more precisely, the merchant discount)

against the benefit of increased final product demand generated by card acceptance”. 556 Hayashi, A Puzzle of Card Payment Pricing, supra note 388, at 171: “Merchant competition allows the network to

set higher merchant fees." 557 Guthrie & Wright, Competing Payment Schemes, supra note 527, at 51: “Whichever equilibrium is selected in

practice, competition between payment schemes can never increase the equilibrium interchange fee (when sellers obtain

identical benefits from accepting cards), reflecting that a single card scheme already sets interchange fees to the highest

possible level consistent with sellers’ accepting cards”.

Page 131: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

131

However, when merchants are heterogeneous, competition drives up the costs of issuers. Issuers

cover their increased costs by further increases in the interchange fee. The MSF also increases

and the bias in the price structure against merchants intensifies. Heterogeneity means that

marginal merchants will drop out of the card network whenever the MSF increases. When

demand elasticity of merchants to cards is sufficiently rigid, network competition worsens their

position in comparison to a monopoly network.558

310. A fixed or ad valorem cardholder fee is relevant only when competition exists. Under a

monopoly network, there is no difference whether the cardholder fee is fixed or variable,

because a monopoly network can compute how to extract the same fees, anyway.559

Fixed cardholder fees primarily affect the degree of card adoption. Competition on cardholders,

when cardholder fee is fixed, may result in multihoming cardholders. Competition to encourage

cardholders to adopt cards causes lower (fixed) cardholder fees, and higher multihoming among

cardholders. Multihoming cardholders and fixed cardholder fees increase merchant resistance

and can correct the biased price structure against them.560

Ad valorem fees primarily influence the degree of usage.561 When cardholder fees include a

fixed positive component (such as a monthly or annual fee), and a variable negative price

(rewards), the cardholder is even more eager to use the card that gives the maximum benefits,

especially after paying the subscription fees.562 When benefits of cardholders from card usage

increase, strategic considerations of merchants intensify. Merchants' resistance weakens. Thus,

contrary to the initial model of Rochet & Tirole, in which cardholder fees were constant and

not correlated to usage, ad valorem (negative) variable fees are positively correlated to the level

558Id. at 58: “[W]ith seller heterogeneity, …competition between card schemes can increase interchange fees above the

level set by a single monopoly scheme. Competition can lead card schemes to set interchange fees too high for their

own good. In effect, each card scheme sets its interchange fee too high in an attempt to get buyers to switch to holding

its card exclusively, an effect which ends up reducing the total number of card transactions as fewer sellers accept

cards". See also ¶ 301. 559 Armstrong, Competition in Two-Sided Markets, 668, supra note 484, at 669: “The distinction between the two forms

of tariff only matters when there are competing platforms. When there is a monopoly platform… it makes no difference

if tariffs are levied on a lump-sum or per-transaction basis”. 560 Hayashi, What Drives Payment Card Rewards, supra note 545, at 12: “When all cardholders are multihoming (i.e.,

they are indifferent among cards as long as the cardholder fees are the same), the equilibrium cardholder fee depends on

whether per transaction costs and fees are fixed (Scenario I) or proportional to the transaction value (Scenario II). If the

former is the case, the competing card networks would set their cardholder fee at the most efficient level and their

merchant fee at the merchant’s transactional benefit. This is because oligopolistically competing merchants would only

accept the cards with the lower merchant fee”. 561 Joanna Stavins, Potential Effects of an Increase in Debit Card Fees (FRB of Boston Public Policy Briefs No. 11-03.

2011) "Fixed one-time fees are more likely to affect the adoption of a payment method, while per-transaction fees are

more likely to affect the use of payment methods". 562 Supra ¶ 230.

Page 132: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

132

of usage.563 Competition on cardholders negatively exploits this correlation through anti-

competitive "reward wars" which likely result in "wasteful competition".

Competition on Issuers

311. Another ground for competition between networks is for issuers. In Israel this kind of

competition is degenerated, because banks own issuers. Leumi Bank would not issue cards

other than of Leumicard. It is unlikely that Hapoalim Bank would issue cards other than in

conjunction with Isracard. However this competition exists in a degenerated form, on

"independent” banks such as Mizrachi-Tfachot, Igud and Jerusalem bank.564 In other countries,

this competition is much more significant.

312. Interchange fees are the primary tool for a network that wishes to persuade a financial institution

to issue its cards. For the issuer bank, the interchange fee generates per transaction income.

Issuers have incentives to issue the card that gives them the highest income, i.e. the highest

interchange fee.565 Thus, competition between networks for issuers tends to increase the

interchange fee.566 A number of empirical studies from around the world have confirmed this

result:

563 Supra ¶ 204; see also Lee, The Effects of Issuer Competition on the Credit Card Industry: A Case Study of the Two-

Sided Market, supra note 420, at 16: “By assuming that the customer fee is a price per transaction, the model in this

paper derives that the interchange fee increases with competition, which is one of significantly different results from

those in Rochet and Tirole (2002)”. 564 See supra ¶¶ 560-562 for arrangement of issuers with independent banks in Israel. 565 Ann Borestam & Heiko Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, ECB Occasional Paper Series 131, at 13

(2011): “Issuers’ decisions on which card to issue depend on the level of the interchange fee”. 566 EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees, supra note 1042, at 2: “Competition between card schemes

appears in practice to be largely aimed at convincing as many issuing payment service providers as possible to issue

their cards, which usually leads to higher rather than lower fees, in contrast with the usual price disciplining effect of

competition in a market economy”;

Frankel, Interchange in various Countries: Commentary on Weiner and Wright, supra note 432, at 56; “[T]he issuer has

an incentive to choose the network with the higher fee";

Benjamin Klein et al., Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Antitrust Economics of Payment Card Interchange Fees,

73 ANTITRUST L.J. 571, 604 (2006): “[I]ncrease in interchange fees can be explained by the increased competition

between Visa and MasterCard for issuers.”;

Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 436, at 651: “Competition between card

brands is ineffective at constraining interchange fees because a network with lower fees gets fewer sales. If one network

were to set its interchange exactly at a theoretically efficient level while its rival offered a slightly higher interchange

fee, issuers would prefer the network with the higher fee unless the fee was so much higher that merchants refused that

brand.”;

Albert A. Foer, Our $48 Billion Credit Card Bill, N. Y TIMES, Apr. 20, 2010: “The result is that Visa and MasterCard

compete to deliver the highest returns to the banks rather than offer the lowest prices to consumers”;

Alberto Heimler, Payment Cards Pricing Patterns: The Role of Antitrust and Regulatory Authorities, SSRN (2010): “In

Europe most cardholders receive their cards from the financial institution where they have a checking account. The

bank is certainly not chosen with respect of the credit card it offers, so competition can hardly discipline banks with

respect to the pricing of payment systems. Furthermore, financial institutions often carry a number of cards (for

example Visa, MasterCard, or even American Express). Banks, however, tend to suggest one card to depositors. It is

true that consumers may ask for a different one, but they seldom do. The incentive of the issuing bank is to offer the

Page 133: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

133

313. In the proceedings of the U.S government against MasterCard and Visa, the court ruled in 2003

that Visa and MasterCard could not prevent their member banks from issuing American Express

cards.567 After that ruling American Express began to grant issuing licenses to banks. American

Express offered higher (notional, because it is a closed network) interchange fee than Visa or

MasterCard. As a result, both MasterCard and Visa had to raise their interchange fees in order

to persuade banks to keep issuing their cards and not those of American Express.568 Also, as

described in the historical review (chapter 4), competition for debit issuers caused interchange

fees to rise.569 In the MasterCard Decision, the European Commission also determined that

competition between networks for issuers increases the interchange fee.570 Merchants bear the

direct consequences of such competition in the form of the higher MSF they must pay.

Merchants pass through to their consumers the price increase they suffer.571

314. An empirical study conducted by Weiner & Wright on interchange fees in various countries,

did not find significant correlation between issuers’ concentration and interchange fees.572 In

2015 Wright, this time with Rysman, was more decisive about this point and concluded that

competition between networks for issuers increases the interchange fee.573

315. In Israel, the Trio Agreement disabled competition between Visa and MasterCard for issuers.

The card companies - Isracard, LeumiCard or CAL - cannot offer individual issuers higher

interchange fees. The card firms bypass this limitation by offering issuing banks higher share

card with the highest interchange fee, not the lowest. So, since cardholders usually do not pay for their card, nor for the

use of it, competition can hardly discipline the behaviour of issuing banks. On the contrary, the high interchange fee

will drive out the low interchange fee card, and therefore interchange fees between competing networks will tend

to converge at the highest, not the lowest level. A further perverse result.";

Jean-Charles Rochet & Zhu Wang, Issuer Competition and the Credit Card Interchange Fee Puzzle, at 2 (2010): “We

show that the increasing concentration of large card issuers is indeed a main driving force of rising interchange fees and

consumer card rewards. As a result, large issuers’ profits increase whereas merchant profits and consumer welfare are

reduced”.

567 See supra ch. 8.3.6. 568 GAO-10-45, supra note 28, at 20-21; Robert J. Shapiro & Jiwon Vellucci, The Costs of “Charging it” in America:

Assessing the Economic Impact of Interchange Fees for Credit Card and Debit Card Transactions, (2010): “Following

a 2003 court ruling allowing banks that are members of VISA or MasterCard to also issue other credit cards, Visa and

MasterCard both moved to retain banks by introducing new cards with higher interchange fees”. 569 See ¶ 108. 570 Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, at 131-37 (Dec. 19, 2007), available at

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/dec_docs/34579/34579_1889_2.pdf. 571 Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 505, at 1341. 572 Weiner & Wright, Interchange Fees in various Countries: Developments and Determinants, supra note 515, at 315:

“[T]here is no obvious relationship between issuer market concentration and interchange fees across the sample of

countries considered”. 573 Rysman & Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, supra note 389, at 13: “[I]ndividual issuers prefer a card

system that offers them a higher interchange fee... interchange fees increased due to the increasing ability of large

issuers to play one platform off against another in the U.S., which was the result of a shift towards a more equal

distribution of market shares among the top 5 issuers over the period and strong inter-system competition. Each of the

episodes in which interchange fees jumped up was associated with a battle to keep issuers”.

Page 134: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

134

of the MSF, or even a few percent ownership in the card firm, in return for issuing minimum

quantities of cards.574

316. The Trio Agreement did enable competition between Isracard, Leumicard and CAL for

merchants. As a consequence both the interchange fee and the MSF decreased significantly.575

However, Israel is not an exception to the rule according to which payment card competition

increases interchange fees. Israel falls under the rule that regulation lowers interchange fees,

and as a consequence, also lowers the corresponding MSF. Without regulation, the interchange

fee in Israel would have probably remained on its initial level (almost 2%).

Competition Between Open And Closed Networks

317. Another notable field of competition which is affected by the interchange fee is competition

between open and closed networks.

318. Scholars have argued that regulating the interchange fee is a discrimination against open

networks as opposed to closed networks.576 The interchange fee in closed networks is virtual.

Closed networks determine only the cardholder fees and the MSF. American Express, for

instance, is effectively the sole acquirer and sole issuer of its own cards. It contracts with

merchants and unilaterally sets the MSF for them, and it also contracts with cardholders and

unilaterally sets the fees for them.577 There is no coordination between competitors in a closed

network, and the fees are not treated as restrictive arrangement.

319. The discrimination argument is that regulating interchange fee puts open networks in a

competitive disadvantage in comparison with closed networks. Closed networks can set the

MSF as high as they desire, and transfer part of the revenues to their cardholders as rewards,

with no regulatory scrutiny. On the other hand, open networks whose interchange fees are

monitored, are limited in the rewards they can offer cardholders, and payments they can offer

issuing banks. Cardholders of closed networks can receive greater rewards and pay lower

cardholder fees. If a closed network wishes to expand, it will be able to offer higher notional

574 Supra ch. 8.1.6. 575 Supra ¶ 97; see also Motion 34/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, para. 4 (Dec. 22, 2002) (indicating that the

cross acquiring agreement caused a decrease of 20-35% in the MSF). 576 Jean Tirole, Payment Card Regulation and the use of Economic Analysis in Antitrust, 4 TOULOUSE SCHOOL ECON.

18 (2011): “Regulation has hitherto been misguided in that it favors closed, three-party systems over open, four-party

ones. There is absolutely no economic reason for treating the two asymmetrically”. 577 United States v. Am. Express Co., 2015 U.S. Dist. Lexis 20114, at 31 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015): “American Express

operates a partially integrated "3-party" or "closed-loop" payment card system. In addition to operating its credit and

charge card network, American Express also acts as the card issuer and merchant acquirer for the vast majority of

transactions involving its cards”.

Page 135: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

135

interchange fees (i.e., higher part of the MSF) to issuing banks and steer them to cooperate with

the closed network. The argument finishes at that cardholders will prefer higher rewarding cards

of closed networks that will supplant open networks.578

320. The MSF in closed networks is indeed higher than it is in open networks. Nevertheless, closed

networks not only do not dominate open networks, but their market share remains relatively

small. One reason for that is the regulation of the interchange fees. This lowers the MSF of

open network cards, and enables merchants to accept Visa and MasterCard, but reject (or

surcharge) closed networks, especially if cardholders are multihoming. As a consequence, cards

of closed networks are less accepted and less popular.

321. In my view, even if closed networks would supplant open networks, by charging high MSF,

this should not lead to deregulation of interchange fee, but rather to regulation of closed

networks. The law should not disregard high interchange fees in open networks, because of the

existence of a high MSF in closed networks. There should be no correction of evil by another

evil.579 If high prices supplant low prices, this is a market failure, and the cause for high prices

should be regulated.

322. Several options of regulating closed networks, in the event they abuse their position and charge

excessive MSF, are possible:

The first option is to obligate closed networks that gain large market share (by charging high

MSF), to "open" i.e., to let others to acquire their cards.580 In Israel, this authority is vested in

578 VISA'S RESPONSE TO THE RESERVE BANK OF AUSTRALIA AND AUSTRALIA COMPETITION AND CONSUMER

COMMISSION JOINT STUDY, at 1 (Visa International Service association,2001): “Any moves to regulate interchange for

open card systems such as VISA would provide a significant competitive advantage for closed credit card networks

such as American Express.”; see also id. at 22-23 (“Comparison with 3-party credit card systems”);

Benjamin Klein et al., Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Antitrust Economics of Payment Card Interchange Fees,

73 ANTITRUST L.J. 571, 610 (2006): “[I]f an open-loop payment card system's default interchange fees are reduced by

regulation, these systems are placed at a competitive disadvantage relative to closed-loop systems.";

Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: Policy Considerations of Payment Card Rewards, at

13 (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No. 08-08. 2008): "[R]egulating the four-party schemes interchange fees gives

a competitive advantage to the three-party scheme networks and card issuing financial institutions would likely switch

their card brands from the four-party to the three-party schemes.”;

Richard Schmalensee, Payment Systems and Interchange Fees, 50 J. JNDUS. ECON. 103, 119 (2002): "[A]ny serious

restriction on collective interchange fee determination would have one clear effect: it would make it harder for the bank

card systems to compete effectively with American Express and other proprietary payment systems". 579 CA 189/66 Aziz Sasson v. Kedma, 20(3) 477 (1966) ; HCJ 637/89 Huka LeIsrael v. Minister of Finance, 46(1) 191,

203 (1991). 580 Frankel, Towards a Competitive Card Payments Marketplace, supra note 539, at 57: “If three-party card networks

did begin to take over the market and cause harm to the public, as MasterCard and Visa warn (or if MasterCard or Visa

themselves attempt to transform their structures by integrating directly into acquiring like American Express), then one

possible remedy is to simply prohibit the monopolisation of their respective acquiring markets through such vertical

control”.

Page 136: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

136

the hands of the Banks’ Supervisor, after consultation with the Antirust General Director.581

The Banks’ Supervisor has used this authority to declare Isracard as a major acquirer, thus

obligating Isracard to allow CAL and Leumicard to acquire its cards. Isracard was compelled

to open its closed network and receive interchange fee that is effectively the same as the

interchange fee in the open networks of Visa and MasterCard.582

323. The second option to deal with a high MSF of closed networks is to monitor the MSF.583 The

MSF is not a restrictive arrangement. It is determined in bilateral negotiation between the

merchant and the acquirer. Nevertheless the MSF is a banking fee and banking fees are

regulated by central banks.584 In my view it is enough (and better) to prohibit price

discrimination in the MSF than to regulate its level. Regulators rightly avoid price control, and

use it as last resort.585 Prohibiting price discrimination would tie the bargaining power of large

merchants (such as the state and the Israel Electric Company for example), which enables them

to get low MSF, to the MSF of marginal merchants. The outcome would probably be one low

MSF.586 My proposal is subject to general principles of price discrimination. If different MSFs

reflect different costs or different risks, due, for example to distinctive characteristics of

merchants, then the MSF might and should reflect these differences.

324. The third way to regulate the MSF of closed networks is by declaring closed networks with

market power as monopolies in acquiring their cards. Section 30 of the Antitrust Law authorizes

the General Director to give instructions to a monopolist that poses a risk of substantial harm

to competition or to the public, regarding the measures it must take to prevent such harm. Thus,

the General Director may give a monopolist closed network instructions to lower the MSF, as

it intended to do with Isracard.587

325. Even with no regulation of the MSF in closed networks, the mere fact that the interchange fee

in open networks is reduced due to regulation, puts downward pressure on the MSF in closed

581 Banking Law (Licensing) 1981, sec. 36(13). 582 For expansion, see ch. 8.1.2. 583 Julian Wright, Why Payment Card Fees are Biased Against Retailers, 43 RAND J. ECON. 761, 775 (2012):

[R]egulating interchange fees... only deals with the bias in fee structure arising from four-party payment networks,

leaving three-party networks that avoid interchange fees to continue to set high merchant fees and high rewards to

cardholders if doing so gives them a competitive advantage... An alternative approach of directly imposing caps on

each network’s average merchant fees would avoid this problem, as it would apply across the board regardless of

whether card networks make use of competing acquirers or deal with retailers directly”. 584 Amendment 12 to the Banking Law (Service to Customer), 1981. 585 IAA, Opinion 1/17 Considerations of the General Director in Enforcing Excessive Pricing, Antitrust 501194 (Feb.

28, 2017). 586 See ¶¶ 541, 308. 587 See ¶ 514.

Page 137: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

137

networks, in a way that might restrain the ability of closed networks to charge higher MSF.588

In Israel and in Australia, interchange fee regulation that caused the MSF in open networks to

decrease, caused a parallel reduction in the MSF of closed networks. Closed networks likely

lowered their MSF out of fear that merchants would stop accepting them. Especially

multihoming cardholders place merchants in a position of credible threat to do that.

6.7. Cardholder Fees and Rewards

326. The direct effect of the interchange fee is on price structure. The effect of the interchange fee

on price level is indirect and depends on the pass-through rates, both from acquirers to

merchants and from issuers to cardholders.589 This chapter explores the literature regarding the

effects of the interchange fee on cardholder fees and rewards.

327. The bigger the interchange fee, the more merchants pay and the less cardholders pay. The

interchange fee is a main source for financing rewards, bestowed by issuers upon

cardholders.590 Rewards decrease cardholder fee and generous reward plans may even cause

cardholder fee to be negative.

328. Cardholder fee is usually a combination of a fixed amount for a set period and zero or even

small negative variable fee. Rewards can be given with respect to either part of the cardholder

fee. Rewards can be given as a full or partial discount of annual fee, especially in the first period

588 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 436, at 664: “In fact, American Express

acknowledges that low interchange fees put downward pressure on its own merchant fees”. 589 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 500, at 49: “Regulation of interchange fees

is also problematic because the key issue is the overall structure of fees across parties to a transaction, not the

interchange fee itself.”;

Julian Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees in Payment Systems, 52 J. INDUS. ECON. 1, 8 (2004):

“When an interchange fee is used to try to optimize the size of the network, it can have at best only a limited effect…

the main effect of a single interchange fee will be to get the right structure of fees between consumers and merchants,

while the overall level of fees (card fee plus merchant fee) will be pinned down by competition between members of the

card association, and between different payment systems.”;

Ozlem Bedre-Defolie & Emilio Calvano, Pricing Payment Cards, ESMT Working Paper 10-005 , at 6 (Aug. 11, 2010)

(draft - these sentences were omitted from the final version): “The interchange fee affects only the allocation of the total

user price between consumers and merchants whereas the first-best efficiency requires also a lower total price level due

to positive externalities between the two sides.”; id. at 31: “[R]egulating the interchange fee corrects only the distortion

in the price structure, but this is not enough to achieve full efficiency in the payment card industry, since efficiency

requires each user fee be discounted by the positive externality of that user on the rest of the industry, and one tool

(interchange fee) is not enough to achieve efficient usage on both sides”. 590 United States v. Am. Express Co., 2015 U.S. Dist. Lexis 20114, at 39 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015): “[R]ewards are

generally funded through the interchange fee paid by the merchant that is passed through to the issuing bank.”;

Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: What is the Optimal Balance between Merchant Fee

and Payment Card Rewards?, (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No. 08-06. 2008): "Typically rewards are most

financed by the issuer's interchange fee revenue.";

Douglas Akers et al., Overview of Recent Developments in the Credit Card Industry, 17 FDIC Banking REV. 23, 29

(2005): “Card issuers are funding these increasingly popular reward programs through interchange fees”; See also supra

notes 208, 534; Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 505, at 1332.

Page 138: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

138

after the issuance of the card. Varying rewards are expressed in discounts, points, gifts or cash-

back in a certain percentage of a given transaction or of the volume of transactions for a

period.591

329. Rewards have a particularly important role when networks are in their infancy. Rewards

encourage adoption and usage among cardholders.592 However, historically, networks did not

establish themselves as a result of rewards. What drove cards' growth were their inherent

benefits to merchants and cardholders, such as security, convenience and expansion of liquidity

constraint.593 Only years later, networks decided to do something more in order to stimulate

usage among cardholders, and began to provide rewards.594

330. In 1984, Diners was the first network to offer rewards, including accumulating airline miles.595

Since then credit card rewards have flourished, as have debit card rewards though to a lesser

degree.596 Especially in the U.S., card schemes are characterized by generous reward plans.597

U.S. credit card rewards are on average 1 percent of total purchases. Rewards in debit cards

591 Andrew T. Ching & Fumiko Hayashi, Payment Card Rewards Programs and Consumer Payment Choice, 34 J.

BANK. FIN. 1773, 1774 (2010): “[V]arious types of rewards are offered: airline miles, cash-back, discounts, gifts, etc.”;

Oren Bar-Gill & Ryan Bubb, Credit Card Pricing: The Card Act and Beyond, 97 Cornell L. REV. 967, 969 (2012):

“[C]redit card contracts commonly lure consumers with low short-term prices (e.g., no annual fees and zero-percent

introductory or teaser rates) and then impose high long-term prices (e.g., default interest rates and penalty fees)”. See

also supra ¶ 27. 592 Fumiko Hayashi, Do U.S Consumers really Benefit from Payment Card Rewards? FRB KANSAS ECON. REV. 37

(2009); Santiago Carbo-Valverde & Jose Linares-Zegarra, How Effective are Rewards Programs in Promoting Payment

Card Usage? Empirical Evidence, supra note 306. 593 For expansion on cards' benefits see supra ch. 5.4.2. 594 Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 505, at 1346: “When credit

cards first became widely available a quarter century ago, they provided merchants a significant boon by enabling

greater spending by masses of credit-constrained consumers. Now, however, growth in credit card usage is fueled by

affluent, non-credit-constrained consumers, seeking rewards points and frequent flier miles, rather than by credit-

constrained consumers, seeking the benefits of paying later for goods and services received now.”;

Hayashi, Do U.S Consumers really Benefit from Payment Card Rewards?, supra note 592, at 38-40. 595 GAO-10-45, supra note 28, at 26. 596 Andrew T. Ching & Fumiko Hayashi, Payment Card Rewards Programs and Consumer Payment Choice, 34 J.

BANK. FIN. 1773, 1774 (2010): “In the United States, credit card rewards have more than 25 years of history, while

debit card rewards are relatively new. All top 10 credit card issuers (whose aggregate market share is more than 80%)

provide rewards, according to their websites; while about one-third of depository institutions provide debit card

rewards”.

597 United States v. Am. Express Co., 2015 U.S. Dist. Lexis 20114, at 130-31 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015): “Cardholder

insistence is derived from a variety of sources. First, and perhaps most importantly, cardholders are incentivized to use

their Amex cards by the robust rewards programs offered by the network. Enrollees in American Express's Membership

Rewards program, for example, receive points for purchases made with their Amex cards, and may then redeem those

points with Amex or one of its redemption partners for merchandise, gift cards, frequent flyer miles, statement credits,

or other goods and services... Cardholders who value the ability to earn points, miles, or cash rebates often centralize

their spending on their Amex cards to maximize these benefits”.

See also an internet site that compares rewards on card schemes: http://www.moneysavingexpert.com/credit-

cards/cashback-credit-cards

Page 139: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

139

were, until recently, 0.25 percent on average.598 However, the Durbin reform, which reduced

interchange fees in debit cards, trimmed rewards on debit card programs.599

331. Studies found that rewards have a significant positive effect on the use of the card that carries

them, as long as the reward program exists.600 Credit card rewards encourage usage not only on

account of other non-rewarding credit cards but also with respect to cash and debit.601

332. Merchants bear the costs of rewards that are funded by the interchange fee, as an integral (and

invisible) part of the interchange fee, which itself is an integral (and invisible) part of the MSF.

As with all other costs, the cost of rewards is passed through to final prices, depending on the

pass-through rate, which itself depends on the degree of competition in the relevant market in

which the merchant operates.

333. Studies have found that rewards have psychological effects. Rewards cause cardholders to

spend more. This finding integrates with the conclusion of other behavioral studies, according

598 Hayashi, Do U.S Consumers really Benefit from Payment Card Rewards?, supra note 592, at 39. 599 Benjamin Kay, Mark D. Manuszak & Cindy M. Vojtech, Bank Profitability and Debit Card Interchange Regulation:

Bank Responses to the Durbin Amendment, at 16 (2014): “Following the enactment of Reg II, many banks ended debit

card rewards programs”; Wells Fargo Ends Debit Rewards Program Entirely, (Aug. 22, 2011); Stavins, Potential

Effects of an Increase in Debit Card Fees, supra note 561. 600 Liyuan Wei, Consumer Choice of Credit Cards, Usage and Retention (2015): “Once the card is chosen, the effects of

annual fee waiving policies on cardholder behavior are twofold: they encourage more usage thus retain customer longer

and at the same time make them terminate the service relationship when the fee is not waived.” 601 Carlos Arango, Kim P. Huynh & Leonard Sabetti, Consumer Payment Choice: Merchant Card Acceptance Versus

Pricing Incentives, 55 J. BANK. FIN. 130, 131 (2015): “Having a reward feature raises the likelihood of paying with

credit cards by a range of 3.6–12.8 percentage points for transactions of $25 and above at the expense of both debit card

and cash payments. We find that the intensive margin of rewards is inelastic; a 10 percent increase in rewards raises the

likelihood of paying with a credit card between 1.8 and 2.7 percent, depending on the transaction value and the type of

reward plan.”; id. at 138: “In our scenario analysis of universal acceptance of cards, consumers shift towards credit

cards rather than debit cards even at low transaction values, which is driven by the extensive margin of rewards... Our

analysis shows instead, that the presence of credit card rewards leads to substitution not only away from debit cards but

also cash, to varying degrees across the transaction value spectrum.”; id. at 139: “[T]he effects of credit card rewards

plans induce substitution away from not only cash but debit cards”.

Jens Uhlenbrock, Pricing and Regulation in Multi-Sided Markets - Implications for Payment Card Networks and Smart

Metering, at 53 (2012): “[R]eward programs seem to play an influential role when consumers make a choice for a

specific payment instrument… card networks offer reward programs to change overall perception and usage pattern”;

Santiago Carbo-Valverde & Jose Linares-Zegarra M., How Effective are Rewards Programs in Promoting Payment

Card Usage? Empirical Evidence, 35 J. BANK. FIN. 3275, 3287 (2011): “[W]e show that rewards programs can also

significantly affect the choice for cards relative to cash”;

John Simon, Kylie Smith & Tim West, Price Incentives and Consumer Payment Behaviour, 34 J. BANK. FIN. 1759,

1768 (2010): “Our model shows a strong relationship between participation in a loyalty program and the probability of

credit card use. The results indicate that the probability of a credit card holder using a credit card to make a payment is

23 percentage points lower for a base case cardholder that does not participate in a loyalty program, than a cardholder

that does have a loyalty program. The effect is reasonably large given that the predicted probability of our base case

person using a credit card is 45%. In other words, there is a 45% chance that a credit card holder with a loyalty program

(who is female, is a transactor and does not have a scheme debit card), spending $51–$60 at a retail store will use a

credit card to make the payment. This falls to a 22% chance if the same cardholder does not have a loyalty program.”;

Ching & Hayashi, Payment Card Rewards, supra note 596, at 1779: “[C]redit card reward dummy remains statistically

significant for all types of retail stores and the signature-debit reward dummy remains significant for all retail types but

fast food restaurants”.

Page 140: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

140

to which, cardholders tend to spend more when they purchase with cards than when they

purchase with cash.602 However, this effect vanishes on aggregate level. Rewards do not expand

the budget constraint.603

334. Rewards increase the pressure on merchants to accept cards, even if the MSF is higher than the

net benefits cards yield.604 Merchants are aware that the cardholder is eager to use the card, in

order to gain fee reduction, airline points or a discounted toaster. Thus, the merchant finds it

difficult refusing a reward card, even if it bears a high MSF.605

335. Rewards are often given with the cooperation of merchants. A merchant that contracts with a

payment card firm, for provision of rewards to customers who pay with cards of that firm, gets

a private benefit such as exposure and advertisement that may result in more sales. However,

rewards carry a trade-off for the merchant. Providing the reward makes the card bearing it to

be the most expensive payment instrument for the merchant. At least some of the customers

would have purchased the goods with no need for rewards.606 On the other hand, some of these

buyers would not have bought at this merchant at the outset if it were not for the rewards.607

336. Rewards can be efficient if they induce a shift from costly payment instruments to more

efficient payment instruments.608 Unfortunately this is not the situation. The main impact of

rewards was found to be an inner transition between non rewarding cards to rewarding cards,

especially at more affluent levels of society.609 Elimination of rewards would thus have no

602 Supra ¶ 155. 603 Supra ¶ 157. 604 Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations, supra note 383,

at 560: “When the interchange fee exceeds the issuer cost, variable pricing rewards the cardholder for using the card;

the cardholder is then even more upset when a shop turns down the card, as she loses the reward on top of the

convenience benefit. This of course is more than a theoretical possibility. Many Visa and MasterCard banks as well as

proprietary cards have introduced inducements for customers to use their card: cash-back bonuses (Discover), discounts

on products sold by affiliates, travel insurance, frequent-flyer mileage, and so forth.”;

John Vickers, Public Policy and the Invisible Price: Competition Law, Regulation and the Interchange Fee, Payments

Sys. Research Conference 231, 234 (2005): “If the interchange fee is so high that competition among issuers leads to

users getting rewards for card usage (for example, air miles or cash back), the cardholder is then even more upset when

a shop turns down a card, as she loses the reward on top of the convenience benefit… This reinforces the key point that

individual retailers' willingness to accept cards is not a good measure of overall retailer (or social) benefit from card

acceptance. The sum of the willingness of each retailer to accept can greatly exceed the aggregate benefit to retailers or

to economic welfare generally". 605 For expansion, see the strategic considerations of merchants – (chapter 7.4 above). See also ¶ 203 for why cards are

"must take". 606 Simon, Smith & West, Price Incentives and Consumer Payment Behaviour, supra note 601; Sumit Agarwal et al.,

Regulating Consumer Financial Products: Evidence from Credit Cards, at 5, SSRN (Aug. 2014). 607 Supra ¶¶ 293-295. 608 Ching & Hayashi, Payment Card Rewards, supra note 596, at 1773: "[R]ewards can reduce total costs to the

economy by inducing consumers to switch from a more costly payment method, such as checks, to a less costly

payment method, such as credit and debit cards". 609 GAO-10-45, supra note 28, at 33: “[R]ewards cards generally have been offered to higher-income cardholders. Such

cardholders might spend more than the average cardholder generally. Thus higher total spending on rewards cards by

Page 141: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

141

impact, or only a slight impact on aggregate card usage (but price level would be lower).610

More perversive, rewards often steer debit cardholders who intend to pay with cheap debit cards

to expensive credit cards.611 When this effect materializes, rewards strictly worsen social

welfare.612

337. Apparently, most cardholders enjoy inherent benefits from using cards, which are not connected

to rewards, such as ease of use, security, monitoring and registration of costs and

convenience.613 Thus, most cardholders would not give up their card usage if cards carried no

rewards. Empirical studies confirmed that cardholders have inherent benefit from payment

cards. They will not give up using cards even if rewards were abolished.614

individual cardholders or increased ticket sizes for such cards may reflect only that those cardholders spend more in

general, and not represent additional sales that a merchant otherwise would not have received. Similarly, higher total

spending on rewards cards compared with spending on nonrewards cards could reflect that rewards cardholders tend to

consolidate their spending on fewer cards—sometimes onto a single card—in order to maximize their ability to earn

rewards. As a result, such cardholders may not be spending more overall but just limiting their payment methods.”;

Arango et al., Consumer Payment Choice: Merchant Card Acceptance Versus Pricing Incentives, supra note 601, at

130: “Ching and Hayashi (2010), Simon et al. (2010) and Carbó-Valverde and Linares-Zegarra (2011) find that the

introduction of credit card rewards has only a small impact on the use of cash”. 610 Ching & Hayashi, Payment Card Rewards, supra note 596, at 1774: “The results from the policy experiments of

removing rewards suggest that the majority of consumers who currently receive rewards on credit and/or debit

cards would continue to use those payment methods even if rewards were no longer offered.”;

Humphrey, Retail Payments: New Contributions, Empirical Results, and Unanswered Questions, supra note 250, at

1732: “[C]redit card reward programs make consumers much more likely to use their card than if there are no rewards.

However, if rewards were reduced or eliminated the effect on credit card market share would seem to be small.";

Levitin, Priceless? The Social Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 50, at 18: “[T]he higher purchase

volume on rewards cards may be merely a reflection of the greater purchasing power of rewards card consumers

relative to regular card consumers and may have little or nothing to do with the rewards themselves”. 611 Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 505, at 1347: “It appears,

however, that rather than inducing consumers to make more and larger purchases, rewards merely induce

consumers to shift their consumption from non-credit-card payment systems and nonrewards credit cards to

rewards cards. In other words, rewards induce consumers to shift from low-cost to high-cost payment systems.”;

Alberto Heimler, Payment Cards Pricing Patterns: The Role of Antitrust and Regulatory Authorities, at 2 (SSRN,

2010): “[C]ard holders are not aware of the costs associated with using them and do not choose between alternatives

considering their total cost. They simply consider their private benefit, for example, the reward they receive at the end

of the year for using a certain type of card. As a result, the highest-reward /highest-cost, not the lowest-cost payment

instrument is chosen. Consequently, free market competition may result in the high-cost payment system being

preferred to its low-cost rivals”; Ching & Hayashi, Payment Card Rewards, supra note 596. 612 Wang Zhu, Market Structure and Payment Card Pricing: What Drives the Interchange?, 28 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 86,

96 (2010): “At equilibrium, consumer rewards and total card transaction values increase with interchange fees, but

consumer surplus and merchant profits may not improve.”; see also supra note 543. 613 Supra ch. 5.4.2 (cards' benefits). 614 Arango et al., Consumer Payment Choice: Merchant Card Acceptance Versus Pricing Incentives, supra note 601, at

139: “Our results suggest that in mature card payment markets like Canada, card users are quite inelastic to variations in

incentives. This result suggests that reductions in rewards may broaden merchant acceptance of electronic

payments while having minimal impact on market outcomes.”; see also supra note 610;

Humphrey, Retail Payments: New Contributions, Empirical Results, and Unanswered Questions, supra note 250, at

1732: "[I]f rewards were reduced or eliminated the effect on credit card market share would seem to be small.";

Ching & Hayashi, Payment Card Rewards, supra note 596, at 1783: “Some consumers may have improved their

perceptions toward payment cards after joining a rewards program, which induces them to use payment cards more

frequently. However, once they learned the cards’ features, their perception about payment cards, such as how fast the

card transactions are, whether the payment cards are easy to use, and whether the payment cards keep money and

accounts safe, would likely remain unchanged even if consumers no longer receive rewards".

Page 142: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

142

338. Rewards lure present consumption on account of future debt. A study by Agarwal et al. found

that rewards increase the expense in the card that carries the rewards, by an average of $68, and

increase debt in that card by average of $115. Total spending and debt of those people did not

change. Thus, cardholders shift expenses to rewarding cards with no aggregate effect. They

conclude that rewards are a primary tool in competition between issuers, and not a tool to

increase usage in more efficient payment instruments.615

339. Baxter's original argument was that interchange fees should be transferred from one side to

finance uncovered costs of the other side. Today, interchange fee proceeds exceed uncovered

costs. When the interchange fee proceeds are used to finance rewards, the "covering costs"

argument falls.616

However, if cards yield positive benefit to merchants compared to other payment instruments,

then merchants would rather pay an MSF above costs and up to their benefit (Pm=Bm), in order

to steer customers to pay with card and not with another, more expensive, payment instrument.

Whenever the net benefit of the merchant from cards (Bm) is bigger than the total costs of the

transaction (Ci+Ca), then it is profitable for the merchant to pay an MSF up to Bm. In fact, even

if the merchant is paying all costs and an additional sum as rewards (the difference between its

benefit to costs, i.e., Bm-Ci-Ca), it is still profitable for the merchant to do so, as long as rewards

cause the receiving cardholder to shift and pay with the efficient payment instrument that saves

the merchant Bm.

340. Indeed, Rochet & Tirole,617 and other scholars after them,618 concluded that if the benefit of the

merchant is bigger than transaction costs, than optimal cardholder fee should be negative

(rewards), in an amount of the difference represented by (Pc=Ci+Ca-Bm),619 as stated in

615 Agarwal et al., Regulating Consumer Financial Products, supra note 606, at 18. 616 Avril McKean Dieser, Antitrust Implications of the Credit Card Interchange Fee and an International Survey, 17

LOY. CONSUMER L. REV. 451, 492 (2005): “If indeed Visa and MasterCard based their interchange fees on costs,

issuing banks could not likely afford to offer substantial rebates, frequent flyer miles, or attractive financing”. 617 Supra ¶ 214. 618 Wilko Bolt & Heiko Schmiedel, SEPA, Efficiency, and Payment Card Competition, at 20 (DNB Working Paper

239/2009); Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: What is the Optimal Balance between

Merchant Fee and Payment Card Rewards?, at 12 (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No. 08-06. 2008); Hayashi, Do

U.S Consumers really Benefit from Payment Card Rewards?, supra note 592, at 49: “When the Payment Service

providers' net joint cost is less than the merchant's transaction benefit, the most efficient cardholder fee is negative – in

other words, a reward”. 619 Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: What is the Optimal Balance between Merchant

Fee and Payment Card Rewards?, at 21-22 (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No. 08-06. 2008): “[I]n most cases the

most efficient cardholder fee is the difference between the card network’s costs of processing a card transaction and the

merchant transactional benefit from a card transaction. Therefore, in most cases, providing rewards to card-using

consumers is the most efficient only when the merchant transactional benefit from a card transaction exceeds the card

network’s costs”.

Page 143: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

143

Equation 4 above.620 When this difference is positive (Ci+Ca-Bm>0), cardholder fees should

be positive, to cover a real "issuers' deficit". Hayashi claims, based on cost surveys, that the

benefit to merchants from payment cards does not exceed the costs. Therefore cardholder fees

should be positive, and merchants should not fund rewards.621

341. Let us turn back to the situation where the benefit of merchants is large enough to cover costs

and rewards (Bm>Ci+Ca). This can be the case if, for example, due to technological

improvements and scale economies, the cost of cards declines, and the benefit to merchants

from cards relative to other payment instruments is very high.622 For example assume that the

total costs of the transaction are 2 (Ci+Ca=2) and Bm=10. According to Rochet & Tirole and

others, the optimal cardholder fees should be negative, i.e. cardholders should receive (huge)

rewards. I will now illustrate, and with all due respect to those researchers, criticize this

position.

342. If the cardholder not only do not pay any cardholder fee, but in addition receives a reward of 6

(Pc=Ci+Ca-Bm=2+2-10=-6), the result, apart from a negative cardholder fee of -6, would be

an increase of 10 in the final prices of goods.623

Models that predict such result (that Pc should be Ci+Ca-Bm) ignore that most cardholders do

have positive benefit from cards, and therefore do not need rewards to encourage them to use

cards. Networks actually know this, and consequently extract positive cardholder fees from

most cardholders. In this situation the rewards paid by merchants are: (1) double extraction of

the cardholders’ surplus after it was already extracted from them in the form of cardholder

620 Supra ¶ 214. 621 Ching & Hayashi, supra note 596, at 1785: “[P]olicy implications of our results are rather straightforward for the

policy of disallowing card issuers to offer rewards.”;

Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Cards Fee Structure: What Drives Payment Card Rewards?, (FRB Of

Kansas City Working paper 08-07. 2009): “Available empirical evidence suggests that in the United States the

merchant’s transactional benefit from a card transaction may not exceed the card network’s cost. This implies providing

rewards would unlikely be the most efficient.”; id. at 8: “[U]nless the merchant transactional benefit from a card

exceeds the card network’s costs of processing a card transaction, providing payment card rewards to consumers is less

efficient.”;

Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: Policy Considerations of Payment Card Rewards, supra note

578, at 8. 622 Supra ¶ 125. 623 Edelman & Wright, Price Coherence and Excessive Intermediation, supra note 476, at 31 (2014): “Indeed, many

readers of this paper probably enjoy credit card rebates and other benefits resulting from price coherence. Of course

consumers ultimately do pay the associated costs: In equilibrium, prices increase to cover sellers' costs of offering ‘free’

benefits.”;

Ching & Hayashi, Payment Card Rewards, supra note 596, at 1773: “[R]ewards may lead to higher card transaction

fees to merchants, which may cause higher prices for their goods and services. As a result, consumers, especially those

who do not use rewards cards, could be hurt by the higher retail prices.”; See also infra ch. 10.1 (the concern of price

increase due to high interchange fee).

Page 144: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

144

fees;624 and (2) not required to steer cardholders, because most cardholders (except the

marginal) will pay with cards anyway.

Even in the unlikely event that the pass-through rate is full, then the high MSF merchants pay

causes final price of goods to increase, especially for those who do not enjoy card rewards. If

pass through is not full, then my criticism is even stronger. Merchants effectively fund issuers’

profit which is extracted from merchants under the pretext of rewards to cardholders. Indeed,

Schwartz and Vincent argue that rewards are a tool in the hands of networks to extract more

profit from the NSR.625

343. The distortion is even graver, as rewards are given to all cardholders, not only to the marginal

cardholders. Assuming cardholders do not pay per-transaction fees, and most of them derive

positive benefits from card usage, then most cardholders would pay with a card anyway.

Rewards for them are redundant.

Marginal cardholders who strictly prefer cash (or any payment instrument other than card),

might not suffice with the reward offered. We can formalize these anti-card customers as "cash

lovers", whose preference for the other payment instrument is bigger than the offered reward.626

Those cardholders would continue to pay with another payment instrument despite the reward.

Note that it is efficient that these cardholders will not be steered to pay with a payment card,

when their benefit from paying with a card is highly negative. (Formally, when Bc<Ci+Ca-Bm,

equation 2 in para 212 above does not hold).

In addition, every time merchants pay MSF=Bm (and even more, if the merchants weigh

strategic considerations), the attempt to steer is futile for "card lovers" who derive inherent

benefit from cards. Those cardholders would have used their card anyway. Thus, for both "card

lovers" and "cash lovers" (whose anti-card preference is bigger than the reward), rewards are

redundant.

Only cardholders with relatively small (but negative) benefit from cards, who intended to pay

with another payment instruments, but were steered to cards because of the rewards, are "true"

targets for rewards (if a cardholder has even slight positive card benefit, she/he pays by card

624 Supra ¶¶ 507,681, 203, 206. 625Id. at 81: “[R]ebates can be a pricing tactic designed to better exploit the power of the NSR”. 626 Supra ¶¶ 148, 237.

Page 145: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

145

even with no rewards at all). This group of "small anti-card payers" is the only group which

might switch to cards because of the rewards. But if the number of consumers in this group is

small, then the price of steering them is way too high. The costs of steering are higher MSF for

all transactions, which inevitably cause higher prices of goods. It is more efficient to lower the

MSF, so it will not include rewards, and to let those customers pay with other payment

instruments.627

344. Under the assumption that most cardholders have positive benefit from cards (Bc>0), they

would use cards anyway. Those who have a strong preference for cash would not use cards

anyway (despite the rewards). Therefore rewards are an ineffective tool that costs too much and

drives up the prices of goods, with a very small redeeming value compared to the harm they

cause.

345. The aggregate effect of rewards is dependent on the number of cardholders in each group.

Without formalization we can say that the general effect of rewards on each group involved are:

346. "Heavy" card users – may derive private benefit from rewards but together as a group, they

also suffer from price increase, more than they benefit from rewards. Rewards offset the rise in

prices, which in itself is a result of the high interchange fee that funds the rewards. However,

unless pass through is full on the issuing side, the offset in rewards is not full, and rewards are

smaller than the "tax" they impose on merchants. In practice the pass-through rate of

interchange fees to rewards has been found to be less than half.628

It is indeed possible that in a certain month, a specific cardholder enjoys rewards that offset the

price increase for her. Individual cardholders enjoy 100% of any reward they receive, whereas

the rise in final prices is spread across the entire market. However, in the aggregate, rewards do

not compensate for the price increase they cause.629

All other parties strictly suffer from rewards:

347. For customers who do not enjoy rewards (or do not use cards), rewards raise the MSF and

as a result raise the final prices of goods, without any redeeming value. Cardholders, at least,

receive some redeeming value, even partial, in the form of rewards. This argument has a social

627 For a numerical example, see infra ¶ 477. 628 Supra note 208, and infra note 590. 629 Fumiko Hayashi, Do U.S Consumers really Benefit from Payment Card Rewards? FRB KANSAS ECON. REV. 37, 55

(2009).

Page 146: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

146

touch, because most often customers who do not enjoy rewards belong to the weak class of

population.630

348. Marginal cardholders that were steered to pay by card only because of the rewards, and

otherwise would have paid with another payment instrument, would prefer that instead of

rewards, prices would be a little lower. These marginal cardholders can be seen as those who

have cash in their wallet, and intended to pay with cash anyway (a lower price), if not for the

rewards. This is why their benefit from cards is, by definition, marginal.

349. Merchants bear the costs of rewards that issuers bestow upon cardholders. Rewards exacerbate

the strategic considerations exerted on them. Rewards cause the interchange fee and the MSF

to rise. Merchants have no other choice but to pay the higher MSF, even (a) when it exceeds its

net benefit from cards; (b) when it finances rewards given to cardholders who would have paid

the merchant with card anyway; and (c) when rewards are offered in a futile attempt to steer

cardholders who pay with other payment instruments.

Merchants have no control over the pass-through rate. The merchant is not aware what part of

the high MSF issuers keep as profit. The merchant would have preferred that the MSF would

be lower, and the reward would be given directly to the customer (direct steering). Thus, instead

of recognizing to merchants the efficiency of cards, rewards turn merchants against cards.

350. Another distortion caused by rewards is that they cause the absurd result that merchants finance

their rivals. Take, for instance, the following example: Isracard gives its customers a reward –

a free meal at McDonald’s. The reward is inevitably funded by all merchants that accept

Isracard, including the competitors of McDonald's. Thus when Burger Ranch accepts cards

issued by Isracard, Burger Ranch pays for rewards offered at McDonald's. In the U.S. the

authorities recognized this absurdity, and determined that rewards that are funded by

interchange fee cause a subsidy of selected merchants by all other merchants, including their

competitors.631 Indeed, rewards are not to be included as eligible costs in the calculation of the

interchange fee both in Israel and in the U.S., but unfortunately, in practice, rewards do exist.

Interchange fee that is transferred to the issuing side, inevitably supports rewards.

630 Infra ch. 10.2 (cross subsidy effect of interchange fees). 631 Final Rule on Debit Card Interchange Fees, supra note 1155, at 128: “Including these costs in interchange fees that

are charged to all merchants would amount to a subsidization of selected merchants by all other merchants that do not

benefit from the rewards program (including competitor merchants)”.

Page 147: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

147

351. In my view, rewards funded by the interchange fee, should be prohibited:

First, payment card networks reached maturity, and they do not need incentives. As explained

above, rewards are reflected in internal shifting between cards (sometimes from more efficient

payment instruments to more expensive reward cards), but the aggregate size of networks would

not be influenced from elimination of rewards.

352. Second, attempts to steer marginal customers to pay with cards, are socially too expensive.

Moreover, the social perversive results, in which affluent customers are funded by the weak,

should not be a product of rewards.

353. Third, apart from a small group of cardholders, most people would either use cards anyway or

not use them at all. It is preferable to waive attempts to steer them to cards through rewards.

354. Fourth, rewards are actually a sort of "bribe" given to cardholders for using their cards.632

Rewards are "prize" for shopping. They create cross subsidy for the rich (who consume a lot,

and thus earn many rewards) by the poor (who consume less, and are entitled to few rewards).633

Cards are first and foremost a means of payment. Just as the state does not give rewards to cash

users, payment card networks should not reward excessive consumption with cards.

355. Fifth, cardholders are more sensitive to their fixed cardholder fees, which cost them out of

pocket money, than to elimination of points, discounts, cash-back, presents and other kinds of

rewards, which do not cost them directly.634 If the interchange fee decreases, then issuers will

first tend to cancel wasteful rewards. An increase in cardholder fees is a step that is much more

prone to irritate cardholders. As long as their costs are covered, issuers, especially in

competition, would probably not raise cardholder fees.635 However, as the European

632 Joseph Farrell, Efficiency and Competition between Payment Instruments, 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 26 (2006);

Frankel, Towards a Competitive Card Payments Marketplace, supra note 539, at 30: “The rebates and rewards funded

by interchange fees and offered to card users act like a systematic form of commercial bribery”. 633 Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Social Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, at 68, SSRN (2008), available at

http://ssrn.com/paper=973970: “Ending rewards programs would end a highly regressive cross-subsidy among

consumers and an unfair externality imposed on merchants.”;

Simon, Smith & West, Price Incentives and Consumer Payment Behaviour, supra note 601, at 1766: [H]igher income

consumers may be more likely to hold a credit card with a loyalty program”;

Robert J. Shapiro & Jiwon Vellucci, The Costs of “Charging it” in America: Assessing the Economic Impact of

Interchange Fees for Credit Card and Debit Card Transactions, at 11 (2010): “[T]he interchange fee system creates

cross-subsidies in which consumers who don’t use credit cards or who cannot qualify for high-reward cards pay higher

prices to support not only the banks issuing the cards but also the rewards offered to other consumers”. For further

expansion see infra ch.10.2. 634 Infra ch. 11.5. 635 See infra ¶¶ 659 & 462- 468.

Page 148: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

148

Commission stated, theoretical threat of increase in cardholder fee, should not thwart lowering

the interchange fee and prices of goods:

Even if cardholder fees increase – which is not a given…consumers are still

likely to benefit from lower interchange fees through lower retail prices, even

if retailers do not pass through 100% of the savings, and from new entry in

the payment market.636

356. Sixth, merchants that want to offer rewards to those who pay with preferable payment

instruments can do this directly, by negative surcharge (discounts) to those who pay with

preferred payment instruments. Inducing shopping by rewards can be done in ways other than

the payment instrument. Indeed, recent years have seen flourish of rewards that are not

connected to payment instruments, such as Groupon and its followers.

357. Seventh, the pretext of rewards is to induce adoption and usage of allegedly efficient payment

instruments. This pretext does not provide a basis for enriching issuers. In chapter 14, I expand

on my proposal with respect to this idea.

6.8. Debit v. Credit

358. Most of the discussion until now has been focused on the payment function of payment cards.

Some payment cards also fulfill another function – the provision of credit to cardholders for

purchases of goods. This function exists in credit and deferred debit cards, where payment is

deferred.637 Debit and prepaid cards are payment instruments only.

359. Credit cards provide additional benefits for merchants and cardholders, beyond being just a

payment instrument: (a) Credit enables merchants to make present sales that would not have

been done without credit, because of liquidity constraints of the cardholder; (b) Credit enables

merchants to make present sales that otherwise might not have occurred in the future in their

stores.638 (c) Credit card enables consumption prior to income; (d) Credit enables cardholders

not only to precede consumption but also to expand consumption, by using future money they

636 EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees, supra note 1042, at 12; David Balto, The Problem of

Interchange Fees: Costs without Benefits?, E.C.L.R 215, 223 (2000). 637 Chakravorti, Externalities in Payment Card Networks: Theory and Evidence, supra note 527, at 2: “Credit cards

allow consumers to access lines of credit at their banks when making payments and can be thought of as “pay later”

cards because consumers pay the balance at a future date”. 638 Sujit Chakravorti & Ted To, A Theory of Credit Cards, 25 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 583, 584 (2007): “Merchants also

benefit from accepting credit cards. Merchants benefit from sales to illiquid consumers who would otherwise not be

able to make purchases”.

Page 149: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

149

do not yet have at the date of acquisition;639 and (e) Credit increases the turnover of merchants

in the present at the expense of future sales at other merchants or even at the same merchant.

360. The benefits of merchants from credit are not reflected in aggregate increase in turnover over

time. The inter-temporal budget constraint of cardholders does not expand because they use

credit and not debit. On the contrary, the budget constraint for material goods decreases due to

pledging part of the future income for repayment of credit debt.640

361. Merchants are heterogeneous in the benefit they derive from making credit sales. The benefit

depends on the present preferences of merchants (i.e., the discount factor) and the intensity of

the strategic considerations of drawing customers away from competing merchants (as well as

from the merchant's own future sales).

362. Merchants who accept credit cards, and thus enjoy the benefit of expanding sales to illiquid

customers, find that this benefit does not come for free. Credit cards are more expensive

payment instrument than debit cards.641 The real costs of the transaction are larger. Especially

the risk of default, which is part of the payment guarantee, is larger. The longer the credit period,

the higher is the cost of the payment guarantee.642 This risk is usually reflected in a higher

interchange fee in credit cards.

363. When merchants charge one price for goods irrespective of the payment instrument used, then

cardholders who pay with debit subsidize the higher credit costs incurred by those who pay

with credit cards.643

In Israel, the Antitrust Tribunal specifically ordered in the Methodology Decision that

transactions, whose payment guarantee is significantly different, shall bear different

interchange fees.644 The payment card firms did not enact such fee differences, and continued

639 Ian Lee et al., Credit Where It’s due: How Payment Cards Benefit Canadian Merchants and Consumers, and how

Regulation can Harm Them, at 2 (Geo. Mason U. L. Econ. Res. Paper Series 13-58, Oct. 2013): “Debit cards offer

security, convenience, and a ready access to funds that benefits consumers and merchants alike. Credit cards provide all

these benefits and more, enabling consumers to spend money they don’t currently have in their bank accounts”. 640 Supra ¶ 159. 641 Supra ¶ 125. 642 Bolt & Schmiedel, SEPA, Efficiency, and Payment Card Competition , supra note 618, at 11. 643 Supra ¶ 270. See also Harry Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees Generally Lead to Cash-Promoting Cross-

Subsidisation, at 32 BANK OF FINLAND RESEARCH DISCUSSION PAPERS (2011): “In a non-surcharging setup, debit cards

always cross-subsidise credit cards with delayed debit, because the payment function and payment costs are identical,

so some of the credit costs will be transferred to debit card users”. 644 AT 4630/01 Leumi v. General Director, para. 53 (Aug. 31, 2006) ("The Methodology Decision").

Page 150: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

150

(until April 2016) to charge the same interchange fee for debit transactions.645 A class action is

pending on this issue (see ¶529).

364. Early scholars, who modeled payment cards, ignored the implications of the credit function on

the interchange fee. Their models related to interchange fees in all payment cards without

distinction. The interchange fee was assumed to be uniform for all payment cards. Later

scholars investigated both empirically and theoretically the inherent credit function that exists

only in credit cards and deferred debit transactions.646

365. Chakravorti and Emmons were the first to model the inherent credit function of credit cards,

without referring explicitly to interchange fees.647 In their model, credit cards are more

expensive than debit cards, but if the cardholder has a strong present value preference, then

cardholders with liquidity constraints, are willing to pay the extra cost involved in credit cards.

Credit card networks lure customers through initially low (even negative) fixed cardholder fees,

and earn profits by interest on the credit they provide to cardholders who wish to consume with

credit. Merchants also finance the expensive cost of credit cards in the MSF they pay.

In their model, merchants can surcharge to prevent cross-subsidization. When merchants

surcharge, only customers with liquidity constraints will use credit, and finance the higher costs

of credit card networks. Those who need cards just as a payment instrument (transactors) will

use cheaper payment instruments. If NSR applies, merchants that accept credit raise their

uniform prices. Customers that are liquid and do not need credit, are not shopping at those

expensive merchants, unless they are subsidized by rewards. This model distinguishes between

setup in which there are rewards and setup with no rewards. If there are no rewards, merchants

that accept credit cards attract only cardholders with liquidity constraint that are willing to pay

the higher prices of credit. If rewards exist, they are given both to liquidity constrained

cardholders, as well as to transactors that do not need them. Rewards make merchants who

accept credit cards, serve both transactors and creditors.

645 Supra ¶ 553. 646 Sujit Chakravorti & William R. Emmons, Who Pays for Credit Cards? 37 J. CONSUMER AFF. 208 (2003); Wilko

Bolt & Sujit Chakravorti, Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment Media (FRB of Chicago Working

Paper No. 2008-11. 2008); Chakravorti & To, A Theory of Credit Cards, supra note 638; Jean-Charles Rochet & Julian

Wright, Credit Card Interchange Fees, 34 J. BANK. FIN. 1788 (2010); Bolt & Schmiedel, SEPA, Efficiency, and

Payment Card Competition , supra note 618. 647 Chakravorti & Emmons, ibid.

Page 151: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

151

366. Another model is of Chakravorti and To.648 They opine that if merchants have sufficiently high

margins from the goods they sell with respect to the MSF, then, as more cardholders with

liquidity constraints exist, the MSF that merchants are willing to pay increases. Merchants want

customers to purchase in the present, because a customer that purchases a non-consumable asset

will not acquire this asset again in the next period. A major development of their model points

to an intertemporal prisoner's dilemma:

367. From the perspective of merchants, greater dispersion of credit cards increases strategic

considerations. Merchants that do not accept credit cards are "punished", not only by customers

that abandon them in favor of other merchants, but also by current customers who will not come

back in future periods. In this respect, credit cards allow not only a business to draw customers

away from other merchants, but also drawing purchases from the next period to the present.649

368. Strategic considerations place each merchant in a prisoner's dilemma. If no other merchant

would accept credit cards, merchants on the whole will pay less and be better off. However, no

single merchant can afford to refuse cards, for fear of jeopardizing its income, if its competitors

will behave differently and accept credit cards. The greater the present value of sales to the

merchant, the greater is its dilemma. The result is that merchants end up accepting credit cards.

Their aggregate profit is lower than if they all would have refused credit cards. Issuers extract

a greater proportion of merchants’ surplus through higher MSF.650

369. Bolt and Chakravorti construct a model including cash, debit and credit. Merchants who accept

cards benefit from greater sales compared to a cash-only economy.651 They consider the case

when issuers can issue credit, debit or both. They assume that consumers participate in credit

card networks to insure themselves against inter alia, liquidity constraints. The network

determines the rate of the cardholder fees at the maximum price cardholders are willing to pay.

Merchants trade off increased sales when accepting cards, against higher fees. The MSF in

credit cards is always higher than the MSF in debit. They conclude that when the costs of credit

648 Chakravorti & To, A Theory of Credit Cards, supra note 638. 649Id. at 592: “[T]he acceptance of credit cards allows individual merchants to capture sales which might otherwise be

made by another merchant in the second period. Business stealing in our model occurs across industries and across

time”. 650Id. at 591-92: “This effect comes about because merchants face an externality much like that in the Prisoner's

Dilemma. As a group, merchants realize group acceptance of credit cards reduces second period profits… merchants

accept credit cards despite the fact that they are made worse off. One can also think of this externality as an

intertemporal business stealing effect”. 651 Bolt & Chakravorti, Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment Media, supra note 646.

Page 152: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

152

cards are relatively low, issuers refrain from supplying debit cards and offer only credit cards.652

This conclusion is consistent with the situation in Israel, where the payment card firms offer

almost no debit cards. In their mode merchants prefer to surcharge, because by surcharging,

merchants can steer consumers to the low-cost payment instrument, i.e., debit (there are no

rewards in their model).653 The profit of the card network is bigger under NSR because when

merchants surcharge, consumers pay with debit which is less profitable, unless the consumers

are liquidity-constrained.654

370. Another model of Bolt et al. considers competition between debit and credit.655 The authors

assume that merchants accept either debit or credit, but not both. In equilibrium, only merchants

with high profit margins accept credit cards, since credit cards are more expensive.656 Debit

cards are linked to bank accounts, whereas credit cards have a prearranged grace period,

followed by an interest-carrying credit line on unpaid balances.657 They find that merchants tend

to accept more debit when default risk increases, despite an increase in the MSF of debit

(because the corresponding MSF of credit increases even more sharply), causing some

merchants to switch from credit to debit.658 In addition, if the interest rate is high, banks (which

are debit issuers) enjoy when their customers use credit cards. Banks benefit from the ‘free

funding’ period offered to credit cardholders, as the bank can earn interest on the balance that

remains in their account during this period.659

371. Rochet & Wright were the first to provide a model that relates specifically to the interchange

fees in credit cards.660 Models before them that examined the credit function of payment cards,

related to the MSF and not to the interchange fee. Rochet & Wright referred to the inherent

credit function in credit cards, as a cheaper and more efficient substitute to store credit. In their

model, credit cards are used for two types of transactions. The first type is convenient

652Id. at 2: “For relatively low credit card costs, the bank would refrain from supplying debit cards and only offer credit

card services”. 653Id. at 25. 654Id. at 26: “[C]onsumers pay a lower price when using their debit cards (pdc < pcc), they will use credit cards only

when they have not yet received their income”. 655 Bolt, Foote & Schmiedel, Consumer Credit and Payment Cards, (ECB Working Paper 1387, 2011). 656Id. at 32: “We assume that merchants singlehome; if they accept a card at all, it is either a debit or a credit card. In

equilibrium, only merchants with high profit margins accept credit cards, since these are more costly”. 657Id. at 12-13. 658Id. at 8: “[W]e find that debit merchant acceptance actually increases with the probability of default, despite an

increase in the merchant fee. This is because the credit card merchant fee responds more to the higher default risk,

causing some merchants to switch from credit cards to debit cards”. 659 Id. at 41-42: "The bank providing the debit card and current account actually benefits from consumers using credit

cards, if they have positive initial income. In effect the bank benefits from the ‘free credit’ period offered to the

consumer by the credit card network, as the bank can earn interest on the balance that remains in the current account

during this period”. 660 Rochet & Wright, Credit Card Interchange Fees, supra note 646.

Page 153: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

153

transactions. Those are transactions performed by customers who use credit cards instead of

cash or debit cards ("Transactors"). The second type is credit transactions. In these transactions

the customer is illiquid, so if not for the credit function, the transaction would not be executed,

unless the merchant provided store credit of its own.

Store credit is more expensive, meaning that merchants can supply store credit themselves, but

at a higher cost than the cost of credit for credit cards schemes. Credit has no effect on aggregate

consumption.661 The use of credit may be required for big or impulsive purchases, or when the

credit function facilitates the execution of the transaction.662

372. In the model of Rochet and Wright, credit cards are a more expensive payment instrument than

debit cards. For that reason credit cards are less efficient for "ordinary" transactions.663

However, because credit card fees are higher, credit networks that maximize profit provide

rewards to entice cardholders to use credit cards. The result is that transactors (convenience

cardholders who do not need the credit function), use credit cards for ordinary purchases, even

though it is more efficient to use debit in these transactions. Credit networks set high

interchange fees, to fund rewards that fuel this excess usage. The more such cardholders there

are, who do not need the credit function but still use credit cards for ordinary transactions, the

worse is the effect of the (too-high) interchange fee on final prices.

On the other hand, the alternative to credit cards in the model is store credit. Store credit is even

less efficient, riskier and more expensive for the merchant than credit cards. High interchange

fees induce credit usage, by cardholders who do not internalize the high cost of credit cards to

merchants, but at the same time high interchange fees enable merchants to avoid store credit.

Customers who need the credit function, indeed use credit cards and not store credit. However,

this comes with a price. Transactors who do not need credit cards are lured to use them also.664

661 Id. at 1789: “The existence of store credit in our framework means credit cards will not have any effect on aggregate

consumption”. 662 Id. at 1788-89: “Credit purchases could capture a range of different types of purchases (such as unplanned purchases,

impulse purchases and large purchases) for which the consumer does not have the cash or funds immediately available

to complete the purchase or for purchases for which the deferment of payment facilitates the transaction. Thus, offering

credit allows an individual merchants to make sales that they otherwise would not make”. 663 Id. at 1789: “For ordinary purchases, we assume credit cards are inefficient compared to pure payment technologies

given we assume there are additional costs of transacting with credit cards”. 664 Ibid: “Since consumers do not internalize retailers’ cost savings from avoiding direct provision of credit and since

merchants cannot distinguish the type of consumer they face, there is also a case for setting a relatively high interchange

fee so that consumers who wish to rely on credit are induced to use credit cards when it is efficient for them to do so.

Page 154: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

154

373. According to Rochet & Wright, in order to maximize consumer surplus (including cash buyers),

the required interchange fee must encourage credit card usage, at the price of over usage for

ordinary purchases. Rochet & Wright recognize that without regulation, interchange fee which

is determined by the network would be too high. They claim that capping privately determined

interchange fee will decrease it, and increase consumer surplus.665 They offer caps for the

interchange fee which brings it to a more efficient level than a privately determined interchange

fee. The lower bound is a cost-based interchange fee. The upper bound is an interchange fee

that passes a "mutatis mutandis" tourist test, i.e., an interchange fee that would cause the

merchant to be indifferent between accepting a card or providing store credit.666

Rochet & Wright claim that the higher benefits merchants derive from credit cards, justify the

adverse effect (customers using credit even when they do not need it).667 They also claim that

extraction of surplus from merchants, in order to induce more credit card usage, and to save

merchants from the need to provide inefficient store credit, is inevitable.

374. The stance of Rochet & Wright is that interchange fees should be higher than cost-based. This

is because the fee must be high enough to fund rewards that in turn, will increase card usage

and prevent store credit. They acknowledge that some customers do not need rewards, but as

merchants cannot distinguish them, there is no choice but to reward all cardholders. Given the

high benefits to merchants from cards, they opine that the outcome is still beneficial. The

alternative to store credit is inferior, and would decrease social welfare. They maintain that a

degree of overuse of credit cards is inevitable.668

In my opinion, if store credit is inferior to credit cards, the interchange fee does not have to be

high in order to persuade consumers to shift credit purchases to credit cards and not store credit.

The inherent benefits of cards and their superiority over store credit, are recognized by

cardholders without any need for interchange fee. Merchants can also easily and directly steer

credit consumers to cards, without resorting to high interchange fee for that.

For this reason, to maximize consumer surplus (including the surplus of cash customers) may require setting an

interchange fee which induces excessive usage of credit cards for ordinary purchases”. 665 Id. at 1793: “[L]owering interchange fees from the private maximum to at unambiguously raises consumer surplus”. 666 Id. at 1789: “[T]he cap should either be based on the issuers’ costs (to avoid excessive usage of cards for ordinary

purchases) or on merchants’ net avoided costs from not having to provide credit directly” 667 Id. 668 Id. at 1796: “Some excessive use of credit cards may be unavoidable given merchants cannot easily observe if credit

is needed or not by their customers”.

Page 155: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

155

375. Other scholars also opine that merchants recognize the benefits of credit cards to customers

with liquidity constraints, and are willing to pay a higher price for them. Merchants indeed pay

more, but they also gain more.669 Credit might have benefits for some cardholders and

merchants that outweigh the extra costs.

376. I shall use the example of Evans & Schmalensee for my modest criticism. Competitive prices

are based on costs, whereas prices that reflect market power are based on demand. In my

opinion, in a competitive market, when better products, e.g. cars with automatic transmissions,

displace inferior products, the price of the former will still be based on the marginal cost of

production, and not on demand. “Better product” is not a magic word to move from the realm

of competition to the realm of market power, and extract all of the consumer surplus, let alone

in a restrictive arrangement. In addition, (poor) customers who prefer cheap manual

transmission cars should be able to purchase one without having to subsidize (rich) buyers of

automatic cars.

377. Further, in competitive markets, a more beneficial product will cost more than an inferior

product only if it is costlier to produce. Many new products replaced inferior products because

they were both more beneficial and cheaper. However, even if a better product costs more to

produce than an inferior product, in a competitive market the price difference should reflect the

difference in costs of production, and not the difference in the benefits they yield. The fact that

merchants derive benefits from credit cards is not a reason to extract that entire benefit from

them, and certainly not through a cartel that causes final prices to rise.

6.9. Determination of the Optimal Interchange Fee

378. One of the main goals of models that formalize the interchange fee is to determine what that

optimal interchange fee is. The optimal interchange fee should, in theory maximize the welfare

of all relevant participants.

Participants in card payments include in the demand side both cardholders and merchants. The

supply side includes issuers, acquirers and the network. Those are the direct participants, but

669 Julian Wright, Why do Merchants Accept Payment Cards? 9 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1, 2 (2010): "[P]ayment cards

such as credit cards increase consumers’ willingness to pay. As a result, merchants that accept payment cards also sell

more than otherwise identical merchants, and earn more profit."

Chakravorti, Externalities in Payment Card Networks: Theory and Evidence, supra note 527, at 20: “[B]oth consumers

and merchants value credit extended by credit card issuers (along with other benefits such as security), and consumers

and merchants are willing to pay for it"; Bolt & Chakravorti, Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment

Media, supra note 646, at 4.

Page 156: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

156

they are not the only parties whose welfare should be considered. Consumers who pay with

other payment instruments are also affected by the interchange fee. The state also participates

in the payment system arena.

379. The first problem is that “optimal” interchange fee in the eyes of one party can be the worst for

the other. The interchange fee has contradicting effects, on the welfare of each party:

380. Issuers – For issuers, interchange fee is a source of profit. Issuers would like the interchange

fee to be as high as possible. If issuers could push the fee above the merchant transactional

benefit, because of strategic considerations, they would gladly do so, until the point of merchant

refusal. If issuers could price-discriminate between merchants and charge different interchange

fees, according to each merchant's willingness to pay, they would also do that. Issuers would

also keep as large share of the interchange revenue as they can, and transfer to cardholders only

the necessary minimum to keep the volume of transactions from falling.670

381. Acquirers – For acquirers, the interchange fee is a cost. Acquirers presumably would like to

lower this cost as much as possible, but this does not happen in practice. The reason is that

acquirers are also issuers, or connected to issuers.671 This double function creates conflict of

interest for acquirers. Wearing their acquiring hat, they would like to reduce the interchange

fee in order to offer an attractive MSF to merchants. On the other hand, wearing their issuer

hat, they enjoy high interchange fees. Acquirers enjoy the proceeds from the interchange fees

according to each acquirer’s market share in its capacity as an issuer.

When the acquiring side is more competitive than the issuing side, the pass-through rate is

higher on the acquiring side. That solves the conflict of interests faced by acquirers (that are

also issuers), in favor of the issuing side. Acquirers will prefer a higher interchange fee that is

transferred to themselves, in their role as issuers, where it will be less competed away.672

670 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 436, at 634. 671 Supra ¶ 89 (interchange fee is determined by issuers). 672 Alan S. Frankel, Towards a Competitive Card Payments Marketplace, RBA 27, 37 (2007): “Whether or not banks

are primarily acquirers, primarily issuers, or have a more balanced credit card operation, they prefer high interchange

fees. The reason is that in their function as issuers, they will each receive those fees and pass only a portion of them

along to cardholders as rewards; as acquirers, they pass the full amount of the cost increase to their merchant

customers.”;

EC, INTERIM REPORT, supra note 278, at 70-71: “[H]igh interchange fees are a way to transfer profits to the side of the

scheme where they are least likely to be competed away.”;

Julian Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees in Payment Systems, 52 J. INDUS. ECON. 1, 12 (2004);

Rysman & Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, supra note 389, at 27: "Schmalensee (2002) first pointed out that

if the interests of issuers and acquirers are not weighted equally in the determination of interchange fees, the

privately determined interchange fee will be affected by the desire to shift profit from one side of the system to

Page 157: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

157

382. In On-Us transactions acquirers pay the interchange fee to themselves. This means that in On-

Us transactions, income for acquirers (i.e., the income from their role as issuers) directly

increases with the interchange fee. In countries where there are only few issuers and acquirers,

such as Israel, the market share of On-Us transactions is large. This further incentivizes a high

interchange fee for acquirers that are also issuers.

In addition, every acquirer knows that even if the merchant replaces it by another acquirer, it

will still earn the interchange fee from transactions, in its capacity as an issuer. Thus, high

interchange fee reduces the attractiveness of acquiring, and serves as an entry barrier. The result

is that especially in On-Us transactions, the considerations of acquirers are tilted to the issuing

side, meaning they favor high interchange fees.

383. Merchants – For merchants, the interchange fee is similar to a tax on payment cards. The

interchange fee is passed through the MSF to final prices of goods, thus causing a small increase

in final prices.673 Allegedly, the interchange fee also has a positive effect, because it increases

demand and usage of cards on account of less efficient payment instruments. But if the

interchange fee causes the MSF to be as high as the merchant’s benefit from cards (Bm), or

even higher because of strategic considerations, this positive effect is diminished and merchants

capture none of the benefits from cards.

384. Cardholders – Cardholders presumably benefit from the interchange fee. It lowers cardholder

fees and is a source for rewards. The size of the reduction is dependent on the pass-through rate

from the interchange fee to cardholder fee. What cardholders do not see is that at the same time

it benefits them, the interchange fee causes a small but wide price increase of final goods. In

the aggregate, pass through is full only on the acquiring side,674 so prices increase more than

cardholder fee decreases.675

385. Non-card payers – For non-card payers there are two options. When merchants do not

surcharge, an increase in the interchange fee causes a small but wide price increase for them,

the other. He focuses on the case of a monopoly issuer and monopoly acquirer, but the issuer's profit is given more

weight in determining the platform's interchange fee, thereby leading the platform to prefer a higher interchange fee

than otherwise would be the case. All else equal, this profit-shifting motive leads to a bias towards excessive

interchange fees compared to the socially optimal interchange fee”. 673 Infra ¶ 695 and note 1281. 674 Supra ¶ 97. 675 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 436, at 634: "As interchange fees

increase, merchants are likely to pass the additional costs on to all of their customers. Issuers, on the other hand,

generally do not fully rebate each increment in interchange fee revenue back to their cardholders". See also supra ¶¶

346-348, 714 and infra notes 684, 1311.

Page 158: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

158

without any offsetting benefit, as only cardholders get the rewards. When merchants surcharge,

the interchange fee is neutral for non-cardholders.676

386. The state –The state has several roles. First, the state is also a major merchant.677 Second, as a

benevolent social planner, the state desires to induce the usage of efficient payment instruments.

Thus, the role of the interchange fee in inducing card usage integrates with the state's goals, as

long as card usage is indeed efficient.678 From this social point of view, when increasing the

interchange fee induces efficient card usage the state would support this increase. When

increase in the interchange fee makes card usage inferior to another payment instrument, the

state should oppose this increase. Third, the state is major player in the payment arena. The

state is a supplier of cash and bears the cost of production of cash. States usually encourage the

transfer to electronic money, which saves the cost of producing cash and support the fight

against black economy. The downside for the state is the loss of seigniorage.679

Defining The Standard For Optimal Interchange Fees

387. When talking about optimality, it is important to define the chosen standard which is to be

optimized by the interchange fee.

388. Economic models formalize definitions to the optimal interchange fee, that maximizes the

chosen standard. For payment card networks, issuers and acquirers, the chosen standard is

maximum profit. From a welfare perspective, the chosen standard which is to be maximized is

social welfare.680 For consumers, i.e., merchants and payers, the standard is consumer surplus

or consumer welfare. In order to find the interchange fee that maximizes the chosen standard,

the standard is defined in complicated formulas as a function of the interchange fee, and then

differentiated and equated to zero, to find the fee that maximizes first order conditions for

optimality.

676 For neutrality of the interchange fee see supra ch. 6.5. 677 See supra ¶ 24. See also U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., GAO-08-558, FED. ENTITIES ARE TAKING ACTIONS TO

LIMIT THEIR INTERCHANGE FEES, BUT ADDITIONAL REVENUE COLLECTION COST SAVINGS MAY EXIST (2008). 678 For the condition to efficiency see supra ¶ 212, infra ¶ 399. 679 See supra ch. 5.3. 680 Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: What is the Optimal Balance between Merchant Fee and

Payment Card Rewards?, at 3 (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No. 08-06. 2008): “Efficiency is often measured by

social welfare, which consists of welfares of all parties involved in the market. The most efficient card fee structure,

therefore, can be defined as the fee structure that maximizes social welfare of all parties involved in the payment card

market”.

Page 159: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

159

389. I will explain the notion of the privately (profit maximizing) optimal interchange fee, then the

notion of the socially optimal interchange fee, and lastly the notion of consumer welfare

optimizing interchange fee.

Privately Optimal Interchange fee

390. Privately set interchange fee is the fee that an open network would choose in order to maximize

its profits.

When open networks determine the interchange fee, they must consider a trade-off. Increasing

the interchange fee enlarges cardholders demand and volume of transactions. At the same time

it reduces merchants demand for cards. As long as the positive effect on cardholders is stronger

than the negative effect on merchants, an increase in the interchange fee is profitable for the

network.

In other words, networks increase interchange fee until the point where a further marginal

increase in the volume of transactions (due to the larger cardholder demand although with fewer

merchants) that occurs when the interchange fee increases, is outweighed by the effect of

reduction in the volume of transactions due to desertion of merchants. At the optimum, any

increase in the profit per transaction (due to the higher interchange fee), is outweighed by the

reduction in the volume of transactions (due to desertion of merchants).

Increase in the interchange fee causes an increase in profit, for the network, from each

transaction with the remaining merchants. This effect is balanced at the optimum by the

reduction in the volume of transactions. When the effect of deserting merchants on volume of

transactions is stronger than the effect of a larger profit per transaction, an increase in the

interchange fee will no longer be profitable. As long as the positive “cardholder effect” is

stronger than the negative “merchant effect”, an increase in the interchange fee will be desired

by the network.681

681 Benjamin Klein et al., Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Antitrust Economics of Payment Card Interchange

Fees 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 571, 582 (2006): “Profit-maximizing prices are determined such that the percentage change in

merchant acceptance from a small increase (or decrease) in P[M] is equal to the percentage change in cardholder use

from an equal decrease (or increase) in P[c]. The intuition behind this equation is simple: If these terms are not equal,

then the payment network can increase transaction volume and profits by changing relative prices between cardholders

and merchants while keeping the total transaction price the same.";

Julian Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees in Payment Systems, supra note 672, at 10: “[T]he output

maximizing interchange fee balances the increase in consumer demand for cards resulting from lower card fees (this has

to be multiplied by the proportion of merchants that accept cards to obtain the impact on total demand) with the

Page 160: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

160

The profit maximizing interchange fee for the networks is achieved, when the profit per

transaction multiplied by the number of transactions is at its peak.682

391. A further fine tuning of the privately optimal interchange fee considers the distinction between

the output maximizing interchange fee and the profit maximizing interchange fee. This

distinction does not always occur. It depends on the pass-through rates of issuers and acquirers.

If pass through rates are identical then profit and volume maximum coincide.683

To see the effect of the pass-through rate, imagine a small increase in the interchange fee from

the output maximizing interchange fee. This increase leads, by definition, to fewer transactions.

But the increase in the interchange fee implies a higher profit per transaction. Specifically this

is the case if part of the revenue from the increased interchange fee is kept by issuers as profit

and the part which is passed-through to cardholders is less than the increase in revenue from

merchants on the acquiring side. In this situation, the network enjoys a bigger increase in profit

per transaction on the issuing side, than the decrease of profit in the acquiring side. The profit

maximizing interchange fee would be higher than the output maximizing interchange fee.

If the profit per transaction increases so that its aggregate effect outweighs the effect of the

reduction in the number of transactions, networks would prefer to sacrifice some transactions,

but earn higher profits for each remaining transaction. This implies that when the issuers' side

is less competitive than the acquirers' side, it is profitable for the network to increase the

interchange fee with fewer transactions. Proceeds are transferred to the issuers' side, where they

are less competed away.684

decrease in merchant demand for accepting cards resulting from higher merchant fees (this has to be multiplied by the

proportion of consumers that use cards to obtain the impact on total demand)”. 682 Julian Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees, id. at 11: “The joint profit maximizing interchange

fee involves a trade-off between maximizing the total number of card transactions and maximizing profit per

transaction”. 683 E. Glen Weyl, The Price Theory of Two-Sided Markets, at 2 (SSRN 2009): “This makes the rate at which the firm

passes these cross-subsidies on to consumers on the other side of the market crucial.”;

Rysman & Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, supra note 389, at 9: “[T]hese two approaches (profit

maximization and volume maximization) become equivalent if issuers and acquirers pass through interchange fees

into their respective prices equally. In this case, when the interchange fee is changed, issuers' and acquirers'

aggregated profit will only change to the extent that the value or volume of card transactions will change. Therefore,

maximizing the value or volume of card transactions will be equivalent to maximizing the profit of issuers and

acquirers, thereby providing equivalence between these two approaches.”; id. at 27: "Without this asymmetry in pass

through rates, the card platform would maximize the profit of issuers and acquirers by setting an interchange fee to

maximize the volume of card transactions". 684 Ann Borestam & Heiko Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, ECB Occasional Paper Series 131, at 15

(2011): “It has often been argued that the pass through of interchange fee income from issuers to cardholders takes

Page 161: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

161

392. Early models did not find a systematic bias in the privately optimal interchange fee compared

to the socially optimum interchange fee.685 Later models sharply deviated from that conclusion.

When merchants have rigid demand for cards, and the interchange fee is privately set, there is

a bright line that directs the setting of the privately optimal interchange fee. The chosen

interchange fee is the one which makes the corresponding MSF to be on the maximum level in

which merchants still accept cards.686 If merchants weigh strategic considerations, the network

will exploit them to increase the interchange fee and the resulting MSF even more.687 The

network will than transfer to cardholders (as rewards or discounts from cardholder fees), the

minimal sum which is required to keep the volume of transactions from falling.688

393. Formally, when acquirers are competitive (their markup is zero), merchants fund all costs

(Ci+Ca) and profits of issuers (m). The interchange fee (IF) is transferred to the issuing side to

fund any difference between issuers' costs and cardholder fees (Ci-Pc) i.e., the so called "issuing

deficit" plus issuers’ profit.689 Formally:

place at a lower rate than the pass through of interchange fee costs from acquirers to merchants. With such an

asymmetric pass through, schemes have an incentive to use the interchange fee to affect the price structure of payment

card markets so as to maximise output. In addition, it would be commercially profitable for them to raise the

interchange fee to a higher level in order to shift revenues to the side of the market where the pass through is low

(issuing), while costs are shifted to the side of the market where the pass through is high (acquiring). In this way, they

can increase banks’ joint profit margins across issuing and acquiring, which allows rents to be extracted from

consumers. With such an asymmetric pass through, a reduction of the interchange fee must decrease the price level

across issuing and acquiring, because the original interchange fee set by the scheme could otherwise not have been

profit-maximising.”;

Julian Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees, supra note 681, at 12: “Whenever higher interchange

fees increase per-transaction profits to issuers more than they decrease per-transaction profits to acquirers... the profit

maximizing interchange fee will be higher than the interchange fee which maximizes output, with some transactions

being sacrificed in order to transfer per transaction profits to the side of the market where they will be competed away

less. Alternatively, if costs are passed through by the same amount on both sides of the market, then the output and

profit maximizing interchange fee will coincide". 685 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, An Economic Analysis of the Determination of Interchange Fees in Payment

Card Systems, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 69, 71 (2003): “[T]here is no reason to think that privately optimal IFs are

higher or lower than socially optimal ones.”; id. at 75: “although socially optimal and privately optimal IFs may

sometimes differ, there is no systematic bias between them. In specific environments, (linear demands, constant

margins) they actually coincide.”; Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment

Card Associations, supra note 383; Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees, ibid. 686 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Must-Take Cards: Merchant Discounts and Avoided Costs, 9 J. EUR. ECON.

ASS'N 462, 473 (2011): “[W]hen there is a single association, when acquiring is perfectly competitive and when there is

no unobservable heterogeneity among retailers, the association sets the highest possible IF am that retailers accept.

am is always larger than the level aTUS that maximizes total user surplus (and thus consumer surplus)”. 687 Julian Wright, Why Payment Card Fees are Biased Against Retailers, 43 RAND J. ECON. 761 (2012). 688 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 436, at 672. 689 Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards, supra note 686, at 472 (equation 15).

Page 162: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

162

10) Pm=MSF=Ca+IF=Ci+Ca+m-Pc →

11) IF=Ci+m-Pc

394. When the interchange fee is privately set, the MSF can be higher than the merchant's benefit

(Pm>Bm) due to strategic considerations. Prices are high but networks are not sensitive to the

prices of goods, but only to their own profits. Welfare considerations of non-card payers are

also ignored by networks.690

395. Indeed, there is a consensus in literature that privately set interchange fee is too high from a

social point of view. Under realistic assumptions, the optimal interchange fee that would be set

by a benevolent social planner to maximize total welfare, is always lower than the privately set

interchange fee that networks would like to set in order to maximize their profit. Privately set

interchange fee is thus always above the socially optimal level.691

690 James J. Mcandrews & Zhu Wang, The Economics of Two-Sided Payment Card Markets: Pricing, Adoption and

Usage, at 23 (Fed. Res. Bank of Kansas City Research Working Paper 08-12. 2008): “What cause the fundamental

differences between the monopoly outcome and social optimum? The answer lies on their different objectives. The card

network makes its profit from providing card services, so it only cares about card users but not cash users. Moreover,

lowering card fees to consumers help inflate the value of card transactions, so the card network prefers high interchange

fees. As card service costs decline over time, the card network is able to further raise interchange fees to extract more

profits out of the system. In contrast, the social planner maximizes the consumer surplus, so it cares about both card

users and cash users”. 691 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 436, 672: “The mere ability to construct

a theoretical model in which it might be possible [emphasis in the original – O.B] for an omniscient and benevolent

social planner to fix an interchange fee in a way that improves upon a decentralized, competitive market, does not mean

that this is what banks do if given the unrestricted right to fix these prices—particularly when there is a clear and

plausible mechanism by which such price fixing, in fact, harms the public.”;

Julian Wright, Why Payment Card Fees are Biased Against Retailers, supra note 687, at 762: “I take a standard model

of a card platform facing elastic demand for cards on each side of the market (i.e., the same model considered by

Rochet and Tirole, 2011, in reaching their conclusion above) and show it actually implies an unambiguous bias

against retailers, even when there is no possibility of price discrimination on either side of the market. Specifically, the

interchange fee determined by the platform will be excessive. Reducing the amount retailers pay and making

cardholders pay more will, up to some point, raise welfare.”; id. at 768-69: "[T]he privately set interchange fee

strictly exceeds the interchange fees maximizing consumer surplus, total user surplus and welfare... Lowering

interchange fees from the privately set level unambiguously raises consumer surplus and total welfare.";

John Vickers, Public Policy and the Invisible Price: Competition Law, Regulation and the Interchange Fee, Payments

Sys. Research Conference 231, 238 (2005): “It follows from the points discussed above that the level of the interchange

fee that is best for the major credit card associations, and their members, could well be significantly in excess of the

level that best serves economic efficiency and overall consumer welfare.”;

Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 500, at 21-22: “In theory, privately-set

interchange fees can be too high or too low relative to the efficient interchange fee, depending on a number of factors.

However, the incentives underlying merchants’ card acceptance decisions in the theoretical models tend, all else

equal, to support interchange fees that are higher than the social optimum. In such a situation, merchant fees will

be inefficiently high and card use fees will be inefficiently low (or card rewards will be inefficiently high), leading to

excessive card use”;

Rong Ding & Julian Wright, Payment Card Interchange Fees and Price Discrimination, at 2, 3 (2015): “The two most

recent papers in this line of research (Bedre-Defolie and Calvano, 2013, and Wright, 2012) have both been able to

establish that a systematic upward bias in interchange fee arises under price coherence… we show that with some

degree of merchant internalization, a card platform will always set the weighted average interchange fee too high

compared to the socially optimal level of interchange fees.”;

Page 163: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

163

396. The privately set interchange fee is higher than the socially optimal interchange fee for several

reasons. When pass through rate is not full on the issuing side, and assuming rigid demand of

merchants, increase in the interchange fee above social optimum would not reflect in significant

loss on the merchant side but would reflect is a significant higher profit from the issuing side.

Networks enjoy profits from a greater number of transactions within merchants that accept

cards.692 Cardholder fees are reduced and more cardholders join and use cards. Existing

cardholders also enjoy greater benefits, and increase their card expenditures. The networks

enjoy higher revenues from more transactions.693

397. A question may be posed, as to why networks determine the interchange fee but not the MSF.

First, interests of issuers are weighted more in networks. The interchange fee is issuers’ income,

whereas the MSF is acquirers’ income. Second, the issuing side is considered less

competitive,694 so revenues of the interchange fee that are shifted to the less competitive issuers’

side are less competed away.695 Third, the interchange fee is a latent fee, and thus it is easier to

hide profit through it, than an overt fee such as the MSF, which is more exposed to competition.

Fourth, contrary to the tolerant approach towards the interchange fee, MSF price fixing by

competitors would be considered a blatant hard-core price fixing cartel.

Socially Optimal Interchange fee

398. Most models recognize the tension between privately interchange fee that maximizes profits,

and the optimal interchange fee that maximizes social welfare.

James J. Mcandrews & Zhu Wang, The Economics of Two-Sided Payment Card Markets: Pricing, Adoption and Usage,

at 22 (Fed. Res. Bank of Kansas City Research Working Paper 08-12. 2008): “[U]nder the same parameterization, the

monopoly network charges a much higher interchange fee than the social planner”; id. at 25: “Lowering card fees

to consumers but raising them to merchants help inflate the card transaction value, so the card network prefers high

interchange fees... imposing a ceiling on interchange fees may improve consumer welfare”;

EC, INTERIM REPORT, supra note 278, at 70-71: “Our findings seem to confirm some recent theoretical predictions of

the two sided market literature, which suggest that privately optimal interchange fees may be too high, notably if

merchant fees increase with interchange fees but issuers do not pass the additional interchange fee revenue back to

cardholders. In this case, high interchange fees are a way to transfer profits to the side of the scheme where they are

least likely to be competed away.”;

Ozlem Bedre-Defolie & Emilio Calvano, Pricing Payment Cards, 5 AM. ECON. J. MICROECONOMICS 206, 218 (2013):

“The privately optimal IF is higher than the socially optimal IF. Hence, in equilibrium, cardholders pay too little

and merchants pay too much per transaction.”;

Soren Korsgaard, Paying for Payments Free Payments and Optimal Interchange Fees, at 11 (1682 ECB Working Paper

2014): “Privately set fees exceed those set by the social planner, except in special cases”. 692 Dennis W. Carlton & Ralph A. Winter, Competition Policy and Regulation in Credit Card Markets: Insights from

Single-Sided Market Analysis, at 13 (2014). 693 Ozlem Bedre-Defolie & Emilio Calvano, Pricing Payment Cards, 5 AM. ECON. J. MICROECONOMICS 206, 218

(2013): “Increasing the interchange fee above the socially optimal level attracts new cardholders because cardholders

fees are reduced; (2) Existing cardholders also enjoy greater rewards and increase their card expenditure; (3) Networks

can extract the higher utility of cards to cardholders through higher membership fee”. 694 Supra ¶ 98. 695 Supra ¶ 381.

Page 164: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

164

However, social welfare of all parties cannot be achieved with one interchange fee, due to the

conflicting effects on merchants, cardholders and issuers.696 A higher interchange fee makes

cardholders and issuers better off, but merchants are worse off.697 Optimizing the utility of both

cardholders and merchants with one interchange fee is not possible.698

399. Thus, models look after a second-best solution, in which the interchange fee sets a fee structure

that induces as many efficient card transactions, in which the joint benefits from cards (Bm+Bc)

exceed costs (Ci+Ca). At the same time, the welfare maximizing fee should aim to be such that

whenever this condition is not met (i.e. when Bm+Bb<Ci+Ca), the transaction will be executed

with another payment instrument.699

Under the assumption that cost of supplying card transactions (the supply curve) is not

decreasing, and that demand curve for card transactions (aggregate utilities of cardholders and

696 Supra ¶¶ 380-386. 697 Ozlem Bedre-Defolie & Emilio Calvano, Pricing Payment Cards, 5 AM. ECON. J. MICROECONOMICS 206, 222

(2013): “Merchants and cardholders have conflicting interests over the level of the interchange fee.”;

Marc Rysman & Julian Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, at 24 (2015): “[W]elfare maximization requires a

trade-off between getting the price right on each side. Thus, for instance, in the presence of positive issuing and

acquiring markups, the welfare maximizing interchange fee will be complicated by the need to try to offset these

markups. Since the interchange fee acts as a transfer between the two sides, obviously reducing one markup will

exacerbate the other”. 698 Julian Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees, supra note 681, at 13: “In general, both conditions

cannot simultaneously be satisfied”.

Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: What is the Optimal Balance between Merchant Fee

and Payment Card Rewards?, at 17-18 (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No. 08-06. 2008): “The first best solution

violates merchant and/or card network’s incentive compatibility constraints: That means either merchants or card

networks or both make losses at the first best solution. The second best solution is, therefore, to maximize consumer

surplus subject to the incentive compatibility constraints of merchants and card networks”. 699 Julian Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees, id. at 13: “Welfare is maximized by setting a fee

structure so that as many transactions where joint transactional benefits (bB + bS) exceed joint costs (cI + cA) take place

using cards, and as many transactions where bB + bS < cI + cA take place using cash.”;

Rysman & Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, supra note 697, at 23-24: "The welfare-maximizing interchange

fee involves a trade-off between getting the right price signal for consumers and getting the right price signal for

merchants. The right price for consumers is such that they use cards whenever the sum of their convenience benefits

from using cards and the average convenience benefits from merchants they purchase from with cards exceeds joint

costs. The right price for merchants is such that they accept cards whenever the sum of their convenience benefits from

accepting cards and the average convenience benefits of their card-paying customers exceeds joint costs. Except for

very special cases, these goals are conflicting and a single instrument (the interchange fee) cannot achieve both

conditions";

Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 684, at 17: "What is of key interest both in

terms of economic modelling and from a regulatory perspective is to determine whether the current interchange fee

patterns are socially optimal, i.e. whether the various payment instruments will be overused or underused relative to a

socially optimum outcome”.

Page 165: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

165

merchants) is strictly declining, an equilibrium interchange fee should allegedly exist, in which

the benefits of the marginal card transaction equals its costs.700

400. The difference between the socially optimal interchange fee and the privately set interchange

fee is that social optimum cares about final prices of goods. From a social perspective the

presence of interchange fees does not alter the general rule that welfare is maximized when

prices of goods are set by their marginal costs of production (P=MC).701

Thus, the interchange fee that maximizes social welfare, considers, from the demand side, the

welfare of cardholders, merchants and non-card payers. From the supply side it considers the

welfare of issuers and acquirers. Under this standard, increasing the supplier’s surplus (issuers

and acquirers) at the expense of consumer surplus (merchants and customers) is not in itself an

inherent loss of welfare. What matters is the total surplus.

401. Social welfare generally dictates that networks should charge merchants no more than their

transaction benefit (Bm), with no exploitation of strategic considerations. According to the

conventional models, cardholders should pay the difference between Bm and costs (Pc=Ci+Ca-

Bm).702 Thus, the framework of Equations 10 & 11 (supra ¶ 393 מעלremain, but the different

standard which is to be optimized yields different results. Specifically the social welfare

interchange fee is lower than the privately set interchange fee, in order to prevent the price

increases of final goods. The socially optimal interchange fee (IFw) is lower than the privately

set interchange fee (IFp>IFw). The cardholder fee (Pc) that is negatively correlated to the

interchange fee, is bigger when social welfare is the standard, i.e. cardholders pay more or

issuers earn less, and merchants pay less. Prices of goods are lower under social welfare

optimum interchange fee.

402. Socially optimal interchange fee tolerates profits. As long as the condition for efficiency is kept,

i.e., the benefits of the transaction are higher than its costs plus the profit (i.e., as long as:

700 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 500, at 18: “An efficient interchange fee

would lead to a socially optimal number of payment card transactions. That is, with an efficient interchange fee, a

payment card would be used in a transaction if and only if using the card would result in a non-negative change in total

surplus. Technically, the number of card transactions would be such that the marginal social benefit of the last card

transaction would be equal to its marginal social cost”. 701 DAVID GILO, CONTRACTS THAT RESTRICT COMPETITION, in 3 CONTRACTS 638 (Nili Cohen & Daniel Fridman eds.)

(increase or decrease in price above or under marginal cost leads to distortion that reflects in inefficient allocations of

resources). 702 Supra equation 4) in ¶ 214; Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards: Merchant Discounts and Avoided Costs, supra note

686, at 469: “Social welfare is a single-peaked function of pB, and reaches its maximum at (7) pWB≡ c − bS. The first-

best price pWB makes the consumer perfectly internalize the externality associated with the decision of paying by card”.

Page 166: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

166

Bm+Bc>Pc+Pm=Ci+Ca+m), there is nothing wrong, from a social point of view, with

networks' profit generated from interchange fees

403. Factors that must be quantified in order to calculate the optimal interchange fee include, inter

alia, demand elasticities, the split of costs between issuers and acquirers, the degree of

competition in the relevant markets, and other parameters required to delineate the demand and

supply curves.703 The calculation requires estimation of all costs and benefits of card services,

which are very difficult to define, let alone quantify.

For these reasons, although the principle for finding the optimal interchange fee may sound

simple, determination of a specific result is very difficult, and the formulas that delineate the

optimal interchange fees are complicated and dependent on many variables.704

404. To understand the notion of a socially optimal interchange fee, consider a small increase in the

interchange fee. As a result of the lower cardholder fee, there will be some additional card

demand. The surplus of new and existing cardholders will increase. The additional benefits of

cardholders from the increase in the interchange fee have to be weighed against the increase in

the MSF, which lowers merchants’ demand for cards, and causes an increase in final prices.

The additional benefits to the newly joining cardholders are relatively lower, as they are, by

definition, marginal cardholders, who did not want to use cards until the last increase in the

interchange fee. Thus, due to the fact that the additional benefit of marginal cardholders from

cards is strictly declining, at a certain point, which depends on the merchants' and cardholders'

elasticities of demand, the negative effects of increase in the MSF will outweigh the positive

benefits from the lower cardholder fees.705

703 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, An Economic Analysis of the Determination of Interchange Fees in Payment

Card Systems, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 69, 75 (2003): “Both socially optimal and privately optimal IFs have to take

several factors into account: the split of total costs between issuer and acquirer, the demand elasticities for both types of

users, and the intensity of competition in both the issuing and the acquiring markets”. 704 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 500, at 18: “Even in the simplest case, the

efficient interchange fee can be difficult to determine. At a minimum, calculation of the efficient interchange fee

requires estimation of the demand curves for card services for heterogeneous consumers and merchants, in addition to

precise cost data for acquirers, issuers, merchants, and consumers.”; id. at 47: “Ideally, the regulator would want to set

the interchange fee equal to the efficient level (i.e., the level that internalizes externalities between the parties to a

transaction)... calculation of that fee requires knowledge of social costs and benefits that are difficult, if not impossible,

to measure accurately”. 705 Julian Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees, supra note 681, at 12-13: “To interpret the welfare

maximizing interchange fee, consider a small increase in the interchange fee. As a result of lower card fees there will be

some additional consumers who will now want to use cards for transactions whereas previously they did not... The

increase in surplus arising from the additional consumers who now want to use cards depends on the number of

merchants that accept cards (S) multiplied by the social benefits averaged over these additional transactions... On the

other hand, as a result of higher merchant fees, there will be some industries where merchants no longer want to accept

Page 167: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

167

The socially optimal fee is reached when the additional marginal surplus from increasing the

interchange fee (all the new efficient transactions that now occur, in which joint benefits exceed

joint costs), is outweighed by the marginal loss from this same increase (efficient transactions

that do not occur with cards anymore, because of fewer participating merchants). Until this

point, total welfare (that includes issuers' profit) increases along with increases in the

interchange fee.

405. When considering total welfare, if pass through rate from the interchange fee to cardholders is

not full, then part of the revenue is extracted as issuers’ profits. This profit is added to the total

welfare calculation.706 If it were but for the profit of issuers, the MSF and final prices of goods

could be lower, and closer to cost (P=MC). This is the basis for the distinction between socially

optimal and the consumer welfare optimal interchange fee.

Consumer Welfare Optimal Interchange Fee

406. The socially optimal interchange fee maximizes efficient card transactions. Even if part of the

surplus from efficient card transactions finds its way as profit of issuers or acquirers, there is

nothing wrong with that, as long as the profit is a result of efficient transactions.

407. The social welfare standard is somewhat in contrast to the current standard of antitrust law,

which aims not to maximize social welfare, but to maximize consumer welfare.707 Under the

consumer welfare standard, the optimal interchange fee excludes the welfare of issuers and

acquirers.708 I can think of two main reasons to justify this exclusion in our context.

First, antitrust laws most often come into play, when competition is impeded at the outset

because of suppliers' market power. The general situation antitrust laws deal with is suppliers’

market power. Although not directly in the payment market, it is worth noting that in Israel the

initial market power of banks over households and small merchants, is undisputed and

supported by numerous studies.709

cards even though previously they did... The decrease in surplus arising from this fall in merchant acceptance depends

on the proportion of consumers that would have wanted to use cards at these merchants (D) multiplied by the social

benefits that would have arisen when averaged over these transactions”. 706 Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards, supra note 686, at 470. 707 See supra note 943. 708 Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards, supra note 686, at 486: “TUS {defined by them as total user surplus – O.B},

equal to cardholders’ plus merchants’ surplus, that is not including issuer markups”. 709 Determination According to Section 43(a)(1) of the Antitrust Law to Information Exchange between Banks, at 4-7

Antitrust 501411, (Apr. 26, 2009); BANK OF ISRAEL, ECONOMIC SURVEY, Chapter 2, 48 (March 18, 2013) available at

Page 168: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

168

The second reason for emphasizing the consumer side in our context is suggested by Rochet &

Tirole. Consumers of the payment card networks, i.e., merchants and customers, have greater

utility from money than ultimate beneficiaries of the supply side i.e., the shareholders of the

issuers and the acquirers.710 Thus, expanding consumer surplus contributes greater value to

social welfare, even if it is at the expense of producer surplus. Indeed, some scholars recognized

that consumer welfare, and not total welfare, should be the standard which the interchange fee

should maximize.711

408. The distinction between an interchange fee that maximizes total welfare and an interchange fee

that maximizes consumer welfare, is that the latter includes only the welfare of merchants and

customers. Profit of issuers is not included under the consumer welfare standard. In fact, the

difference between the consumer welfare optimal interchange fee and the total welfare optimal

interchange fee, is the profit of issuers.712

409. The outcomes of models that subject the interchange fee to the consumer welfare standard are:

(1) final prices of goods should be equal to the marginal cost of production (including the cost

of the payment instrument) (P=MC); (2) the interchange fee cannot be used as a source of profit

https://www.boi.org.il/he/BankingSupervision/Survey/DocLib/chap2.pdf ; COMMITTEE FOR ENHANCEMENT OF

COMPETITION IN COMMON BANKING & FINANCIAL SERVICES (SHTRUM COMMITTEE) FINAL REPORT, at 10-9 , 34-30 (Sep

1, 2016). 710 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems, 5 REV. NETWORK ECON.

1, 11 (2006): "Should markups be part of social welfare?... the resulting supra-normal profits are either dissipated

through an “easy life” and inefficient production of card services, or go to wealthy shareholders whose marginal utility

of income is much lower than that of the average consumer. Then issuers’ markup should not be counted as part of

social welfare.”;

Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards, supra note 686, at 477: “Focusing on the narrow notion of consumer surplus is

legitimate for a shortterm analysis as long as the welfare of shareholders is weighted much less heavily than that of

consumers.”; See also Ofer Groskoph, Paternalizm, Public Policy and Government Monopoly in the Gambling Market

(Paternalizm, Takanat Hatzibur Vehamonopol Hamemshalti Beshuk Hahimurim), 7 HAMISHPAT 9, 18 (2007) 711 Jean-Charles Rochet & Julian Wright, Credit Card Interchange Fees, 34 J. BANKING FIN. 1788, 1793 (2010): “[I]f

competition authorities aim at maximizing (short-run) consumer surplus... they will always find the privately optimal

interchange fee excessive.”;

Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards, ibid at 486: “A key result of this paper is thus that, with constant issuer margins and

homogenous merchants, a regulatory cap based on merchants’ avoided cost is legitimate when competition authorities

aim at maximizing short-term total user surplus”;

Joseph Farrell, Efficiency and Competition between Payment Instruments, 5 REV. Network Econ. 26, 34 (2006): “While

this is in part a matter of judgment, it seems to me that if a payment instrument with a large market share avoids the

demand penalty of relatively high overall fees by loading its fees heavily on the merchant side, making usage attractive

to consumers in a way that it may well not be to the two-sided customer, and inflicting real negative externalities on

non-participating consumers and on rival payment instruments, then policy intervention to make it more likely that the

two-sided customer generally chooses the best available offer (as is usually automatic in a one-sided market) is well

worth exploring”. 712 Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards, id. at 471: “[T]he wedge between the welfare-optimal IF, which remains equal to

aW = bS − cS + mB, and the TUS-maximizing IF, aTUS = bS − (cS + mS)”. m is the profit margin, which is added to the

total welfare interchange fee (aW) but deduced from the “total user surplus” interchange fee - aTUS".

Page 169: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

169

for acquirers or issuers (m=0), and (3) the sum of the cardholder fee and the MSF (Pm+Pc)

should equal the network’s cost (Ci+Ca).713

410. Formally, the consumer optimum interchange fee (IFcw) is lower than the privately set

interchange fee (IFp) and the social welfare interchange fee, because instead of

11) IFtotal welfare=Ci+m-Pc

comes

12) IFconsumer welfare=Ci-Pc714

411. Note that if merchants surcharge and pass-through rate is full, the consumer welfare standard,

if applied only on cardholders (and not on cash payers), allows for rewards. However, under

NSR and whenever pass-through is not full - rewards inflate the price of goods, especially for

non-cardholders.715 This is why using consumer welfare as the standard, by itself, is not

sufficient to halt redundant rewards, unless the interest of non-card payers is also considered

and pass-through is full. i.e., no profit for issuers. In chapter 14 I expand this insight in my

innovation to limit profits of issuers.

412. The consumer welfare optimal interchange fee considers both final prices of goods and efficient

card usage.

Card payments are optimal if they are more cost effective than other payment instruments.

Under the consumer welfare standard, the net benefit from card payments, should be passed-

through to customers, so prices of goods would sustain the basic principle of P=MC.

If cardholders are heterogeneous, marginal cardholders might not pay with cards, even if cards

are the most efficient payment instrument. In this situation a higher interchange fee than a cost-

based fee is required, to induce efficient card usage. Thus, the heterogeneity of cardholders is

a crucial factor in the determination of the social welfare optimal interchange fee.

713 Fumiko Hayashi, Do U.S. Consumers really benefit from Payment Card Rewards, FED. RES. BANK KAN., ECON.

REV. 37, 50 (2009); Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: What is the Optimal Balance between

Merchant Fee and Payment Card Rewards, supra note 698, at 18: “The maximum social welfare is more likely to be

achieved when the product prices for card-using consumers and for non-card-using consumers, respectively, are set at

the merchant’s marginal costs, and the sum of a cardholder fee and a merchant fee equals the card network’s cost.” 714 Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards, supra note 686, at 470. 715 Supra ch. 6.7.

Page 170: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

170

An interchange fee which is above costs is efficient only when it effectively steers cardholders

to pay with efficient cards, so merchants actually save costs of the alternative and more

expensive payment instrument, when steering succeeds. The trade-off is that rewarding

marginal cardholders comes along with rewarding all other cardholders who do not need

rewards. The interchange fee which funds those rewards is a cost to merchants. It lowers their

surplus from cards and is passed through to final prices. Non-card customers suffer from the

price increase, as well as cardholders who do not get rewards. Thus, in order for a steering

interchange fee to be efficient, the steering effect must outweigh all the negative effects it

simultaneously generates.

Optimal interchange fee should balance between price increase and efficient steering. As long

as merchants actually save costs when the interchange fee increases to shift the marginal

cardholders to pay with card, it is efficient to increase the interchange fee.

When the “price” to steer the marginal cardholder, i.e. when the rise in the MSF for all infra-

marginal cardholders has a stronger effect, the interchange fee should be lowered, until the point

where the "price increase" effect and the "steering" effect equalize.

413. Wright formalized a similar argument in an article which, in fact, conflicted with his own

previous works, and those of Rochet & Tirole.716 He claimed that it is sufficient for merchants

to internalize the utility of their marginal cardholders, to conclude that the privately set

interchange fee is biased against merchants, and too high compared to social optimum.717

414. The conclusion from the above is twofold. The exact numerical calculation of the optimal

interchange fee is probably not achievable with existing market data. However, few milestones

can be placed. On the 'number line'. The privately set interchange fee is the highest. The socially

optimal interchange fee is in the middle, and the consumer welfare optimal interchange fee is

the lowest (IFp>IFw>IFcw).

716 Julian Wright, Why Payment Card Fees are Biased Against Retailers, supra note 687, at 762. 717 Id. at 765: “The difference between the average and marginal user’s interaction benefit, which I call i’s inframarginal

surplus per interaction, is defined as vi(bi) = E(bi|bi ≥ bi) −bi . It plays a critical

role in the analysis that follows.”; id. at 769: “Therefore, it is only the difference between the average and marginal

seller surplus that drives a wedge between the profit-maximizing and welfare-maximizing interchange fee. This is the

key insight I exploit”.

Page 171: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

171

7. The Special Features Of The Interchange Fee

415. Payment cards have unique characteristics that should allow for a different rule to be applied to

the interchange fee arrangement, as opposed to the prohibition which applies to other

arrangements of minimum price fixing between competitors. Payment cards are a two-sided

network product. The interchange fee enables internalization of externalities that exist in two-

sided network markets.

7.1. Two-Sided Network Products

Network Products

416. Payment cards are a network product. A network product is a product whose marginal benefit

for the user is influenced by the number of other users. The fax machine is a good example

of a network product. If there were only one user of fax machine, the device would be useless.

The costs of producing the first fax machines were much greater than the benefits they yielded.

As more people are able to receive and send faxes, the benefits from fax to the new (marginal)

users increase and the marginal cost decreases, due to the division of the initial high fixed costs

among many products.

417. Facebook is another example. The value to users increases as more people are connected to this

platform. The same logic applies to payment cards. If there were only a few people who used

cards, they would not be attractive. As the network increases and more cardholders and

merchants join, the value for the marginal user – be it a cardholder or a merchant – increases.718

418. However, it should be noted that even a network product may have a maximum size beyond

which the value falls. Generally, there is a no need for more than one fax machine per person.

Additional fax machines may even cause confusion. Number of individuals more or less limits

the optimal size of the fax network. Therefore, for accuracy, a network product is a product

718 David S. Evans, The Antitrust Economics of Two-Sided Markets, at 4-5, SSRN (2002): “A network effect arises

when the value that one user receives from a product increases with the number of other users of that product. A

modern, but already almost quaint example, is the fax machine”;

Howard H. Chang & David S. Evans, The Competitive Effects of the Collective Setting of Interchange Fees by Payment

Card Systems, 45 ANTITRUST BULL. 641 (2000); Dennis Carlton & S. Alan Frankel, Transaction Costs, Externalities,

and "Two Sided" Payment Markets, 2005 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 617 (2005); AT 46791-03-14 El Rov v. General

Director, para. 30 (Dec. 4, 2014); Objection of the General Director to a Merger between Seebus and Millpas, Antitrust

5001982, at 6-8 (June 14, 2012).

Page 172: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

172

whose value is rising, in a relevant range.719

In the relevant range, the network feature is characterized by an increase in demand as a function

of increase in quantity. This is a special feature of network product that does not exist with

ordinary products. Demand increases due to a double effect: 1. the joinder of new customers,

for whom the large network is more attractive, and 2. veteran customers get more benefits from

the network when it grows, so they are willing to pay more.720

419. High fixed costs are required to establish a network. A network product requires a critical mass

of users to survive. Only entities that manage to establish the network and overcome the

problem of critical mass can succeed. This is sometimes regarded as a “chicken and egg”

problem, i.e., choosing which side to develop first and reach a critical mass, in order to leverage

the attractiveness of the product to the other side.721

420. Typically there are not many competitors in network product markets. The feature of scale

economy enables only big players to enter and survive in network markets. The market structure

creates high barriers to entry. Indeed markets that are characterized as network-product markets

are often oligopolies by nature.722 In the extreme, the phenomenon of “the winner takes it all”

719 George L. Priest, Rethinking Antitrust Law in an Age of Network Industries, at 2 (John M. Olin Center for Studies in

Law, Economics, and Public Policy Research Paper No. 352, 2007): “The term “network effect” describes the

phenomenon according to which the value of participation in a network increases over some range as the number of

members of the network increases”. 720 GEORGE L. PRIEST, NETWORKS AND ANTITRUST ANALYSIS, in 1 ISSUES IN COMPETITION LAW AND POLICY 641

(ABA section of Antitrust Law, 2008): "As the scale of the network increases, demand increases, either by those

consumers considering joining the network—the aggregate network becomes more valuable—or by those consumers

who have already joined the network—the network they have joined becomes more valuable to them as more

consumers join". 721 Wilko Bolt, Retail Payments in the Netherlands: Facts and Theory,154 DE ECONOMIST 345, 353-54 (2006): "It is a

well-known phenomenon that new payment instruments first have to build some “critical mass” before end-users get

convinced of their use and convenience."; id. 354 n.9: "This is sometimes called the “chicken-and-egg” problem of

payment instruments.";

MICHAEL L. KATZ, REFORM OF CREDIT CARDS SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA II COMMISSIONED REPORT, at 14 (Reserve Bank of

Australia, 2001): “The chicken-and-egg problem arises when no consumer wants to join a network because too few

merchants accept the card, but additional merchants don’t want to join the network because too few consumers carry the

card”. 722 Robert M. Hunt, An Introduction to the Economics of Payment Card Networks, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 80, 84

(2003); David S. Evans, The Antitrust Economics of Multi-Sided Markets, 20 YALE J. ON REG. 325, 354 (2003): “In

practice, a relatively small number of firms tend to compete in multi-sided platform markets because of indirect

network effects on the demand side and fixed costs of establishing platforms”.

Page 173: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

173

occurs in network markets.723 A well-known example of this is the struggle between the video

formats VHS and BETA which was finally won by the VHS format.724

421. Most often in network products, the marginal cost is larger than the marginal utility for the user

when the network is in its infancy. The opposite becomes the case as the network matures.

Marginal costs decline due to scale economies and marginal utility increases. In mature

networks, the marginal price that users pay and the marginal cost of production are relatively

law.725 The benefit users derive from a fully developed and powerful network is higher. For

example, imagine that only few people had to pay for the costs of a telephone network. The

costs for them would be enormous, and certainly greater than their benefits from the network.

When the network is in its infancy, the marginal cost is larger than the marginal utility, and this

is why networks find it difficult to establish. When a network already has millions of users, the

marginal cost of supplying the service to the additional customer is minimal, relative to the

utility derived from the network. The marginal customer enjoys a mature and powerful network,

with all of its benefits, immediately from the moment of accession.

422. It should be emphasized that the marginal cost of a network product does not necessarily

decline, even though it is possible that due to economies of scale, the costs of the marginal (e.g.,

card) transaction (e.g., for issuers and acquirers) actually decrease.726 In mature networks, even

if the marginal cost of production increases, the important thing is that the marginal utility is

greater and increasing faster, sometimes even in exponential growth, such as the exponential

growth of Facebook. The fact that the utility of the marginal customer is bigger than the costs

enables mature networks to create positive surplus through transactions.

723 David S. Evans, The Antitrust Economics of Two-Sided Markets, SSRN (2002); David S. Evans & Richard

Schmalansee, Failure to Launch: Critical Mass in Platform Businesses, 9 REV. NETWORK ECON. (2010): “With strong

network effects, new networks tend either to capture the entire market (e.g., Blu-Ray) or to fail completely (e.g., HD-

DVD)”. 724 WILLIAM H. PAGE & JOHN E. LOPATKA, NETWORK EXTERNALITIES, in 1 ENCYCLOPEDIA OF LAW AND ECONOMICS

952, 960 (1999). 725 Leo Van Hove, Central Banks and Payment Instruments: A Serious Case of Schizophrenia, 66 COMMUNICATIONS &

STRATEGIES 19, 21 (2007): “[W]hereas significant investment in infrastructure is needed to start a payments scheme,

the marginal cost of services produced over the existing infrastructure is typically relatively small”. 726 Wilko Bolt & Sujit Chakravorti, Digitization of Retail Payments, at 10 (DNB Working Paper 270. 2010): “As more

consumers and merchants adopt payment cards, providers of these products may benefit from economies of scale and

scope. Size and scalability are important in retail payment systems due to their relatively high capital intensity. In

general, electronic payment systems require considerable up-front investments in processing infrastructures, highly

secure telecommunication facilities and data storage, and apply complex operational standards and protocols. As a

consequence, unit cost should fall as payment volume increases (when appropriately corrected for changes in labor

and capital costs)”; Heiko Schmiedel, Gergana Kostova & Wiebe Ruttenberg, The Social and Private Costs of Retail

Payment Instruments A European Perspective, at 28-29 (137 ECB Occasional Paper Series, 2012).

Page 174: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

174

Two-Sided Products

423. A second characteristic of payment cards (in addition to being a network product) is that they

are a two-sided product.727 A two-sided product is a product (or service) that is consumed by

two different groups of customers that engage in reciprocal interactions.728 The reciprocity is

expressed in that changing the price structure for each group, without changing the price level,

can affect the volume of transactions.729 Lowering the price on one side and increasing the price

on the other side, affects the volume of transactions. A two-sided product is a private case of a

multi-sided product, which is defined as a platform that enables the creation of value between

distinct groups of customers that are engaged in reciprocal interactions.730

424. The customers of payment card networks are simultaneously both merchants and cardholders.

To create a payment card transaction, the simultaneous cooperation of both a merchant that

accepts the card and a cardholder that uses the card is required.731 The reciprocity is based on

the network feature, which means that the value of the product for one consumer group

increases with the number of consumers in the other group. More cardholders make the network

727 For expansion, Armstrong, Competition in Two-Sided Markets, supra note 484, at 668; Evans, The Antitrust

Economics of Multi-Sided Markets, supra note 722; Julian Wright, One-Sided Logic in Two-Sided Markets 3 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 44 (2004); Marc Rysman, The Economics of Two-Sided Markets, 23 J. ECON. PERSPECTIVES 125

(2009); Massimo Motta & Helder Vasconcelos, Exclusionary Pricing in a Two-Sided Market, CEPR Discussion Paper

no. 9164 (Oct. 2012). 728 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 500, at 14-15: “A two-sided market is a

market for the provision of a product whose value is realized only if a member of each of two distinct and

complementary sets of users simultaneously agrees to its use…. A payment card has value only if a merchant and the

merchant’s customer agree on its use to carry out a transaction”. 729 Jean Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report, 37 RAND J. ECON. 645, 664-65 (2006):

“A market is two-sided if the platform can affect the volume of transactions by charging more to one side of the market

and reducing the price paid by the other side by an equal amount; in other words, the price structure matters, and

platforms must design it so as to bring both sides on board”;

Gonenc Gurkaynak et al., Multisided Markets and the Challenge of Incorporating Multisided Considerations into

Competition Law Analysis, J. ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 1, 4 (2016): "The pioneers of the multisided markets theory,

Rochet and Tirole, have provided a formal definition that focuses on the pricing structure. Based on their 2006 paper, ‘a

market is two-sided if the platform can affect the volume of transactions by charging more to one side of the market and

reducing the price paid by the other side by an equal amount. In other words, the price structure matters, and platforms

must design it so as to bring both sides on board’. Rochet and Tirole further narrow down the limits of two-sided

markets by providing a definition for one-sided markets. They suggest that ‘[t]he market is one-sided if the end-users

negotiate away the actual allocation of the burden (ie the Coase theorem applies)". 730 Andrei Hagiu & Julian Wright, Multi-Sided Platforms, at 7 (Harvard Business School Working Paper 12-024, 2011):

“Multi-sided platform (MSP): an organization that creates value primarily by enabling direct interactions between two

(or more) distinct types of affiliated customers”; Evans, The Antitrust Economics of Multi-Sided Markets, supra note

722. 731 Evans, The Antitrust Economics of Multi-Sided Markets, supra note 722, at 34: “Payment systems—cash, checks,

cards, and emerging e-pay systems—are viable only if both buyers and sellers use it.”;

Dennis W. Carlton & Ralph A. Winter, Competition Policy and Regulation in Credit Card Markets: Insights from

Single-Sided Market Analysis, section 3A (2014): “The credit card network is a two-sided market in the sense that both

cardholders/consumers and merchants must be attracted to the network. Neither side will join without sufficient

numbers of agents on the other side of the market”.

Page 175: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

175

more attractive to merchants. More merchants accepting cards signify the attractiveness of the

network to cardholders. Therefore, most network products are also two-sided products.732

425. Other two-sided products include, inter alia, newspapers that require both advertisers and

readers; operating systems that face end-users on one side and developers of applications on

the other side; shopping malls that apply to businesses on one hand and to consumers on the

other; video game consoles targeting developers on one side and buyers of video games on the

other; brokers, auction houses and real estate agents, which serve as platforms for interactions

between one group of sellers and another group of buyers; dating clubs which turn to men and

women; and stock exchanges which interact with both buyers and sellers of securities.

Thus, payment cards are two-sided network products. In addition, payment cards have another

feature that affects the approval of the interchange fee.

7.2. Externalities

426. The main reason that the interchange fee deserves sanctioning, in spite of it being horizontal

minimum price fixing, is because the interchange fee is a mechanism for internalizing

externalities.733

427. Externality is a phenomenon which occurs when the cost of an agent’s action for herself is

significantly different from the social costs of that action.734 Actions of agent do not depend on

the full social costs of the action, but on the cost of the action to the agent. Therefore an agent

may act inefficiently, from a social point of view, in the presence of externalities. The classic

example is of a polluting factory which derives for its owner utility of 10, but inflicts

environmental damage of 100 on its neighborhood. The damage is dissipated equally among a

732 David S. Evans, The Antitrust Economics of Two-Sided Markets, supra note 723 at 4: “It turns out that most, if not

all, industries characterized by network effects—a subject of considerable economic theorizing since the mid 1980s—

are two-sided markets”. 733 For expansion on externalities see STEVEN SHAVELL, FOUNDATIONS OF ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW (2004);

DENNIS W. CARLTON & JEFFREY M. PERLOFF, MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION (3d ed. 2000); Rochet & Tirole,

Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems, supra note 710; ANDREU MAS-COLELL ET AL., MICROECONOMIC

THEORY, Chapter 11 ( Oxford University Press, 1995); James M. Buchanan & William Craig Stubblebine, Externality,

29 ECONOMICA 371, 372 (1962). 734 Hayashi, Do U.S consumers, supra note 629, at 48: “An externality is the effect of one agent’s action on the benefits

or costs of another agent whose benefits or costs are not taken into account when an economic decision is made.”;

Carlton & Frankel, Transaction Costs, Externalities, and "Two Sided" Payment Markets, supra note 718, at 622:

“Externalities arise when the private cost facing a buyer or a seller differ significantly from the social cost.”;

Harrison J. McAvoy, Regulation Or Competition?: The Durbin Amendment, the Sherman Act, and Intervention in the

Card Payment Industry, 37 SETON HALL LEGISLATIVE J. (2013): “Externalities are defined as “indirect effects of

consumption or production activity”.

Page 176: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

176

population of 1000 people.735 If there is no rule governing the situation and allocating

entitlements,736 the existence of transaction costs might frustrate enjoining the factory owner

from continuing to self-internalize the profit of 10 while externalizing the damage of 100 on

the local population. Payment cards exhibit two types of externalities: network and usage.737

Network Externality

428. Network externality – is the externality that is caused when cardholders or merchants take into

account only their private considerations, and as a result, do not join the network, even though

the aggregate benefit from their joinder would be larger than the costs.738 For example, without

interchange fees, when the cost of the issuer is 2 (Ci=2), but the utility the customer derives

from cards is 1 (Bc=1), the customer will not adopt a card. This presents a network externality

if the aggregate utility is in fact, big enough to make card adoption beneficial from a social

point of view (e.g., when Bm=5, Ci+Ca=4 so Bm+Bc=6>4=Ci+Ca). The fact that the

cardholder considers only her private considerations frustrates the efficient outcome.739

429. The focus of the network externality is the “to be or not to be” question, whether to be a

cardholder or a card accepting merchant, or not. The focus is on the initial joinder to the network

and adoption of cards. The concern of the network externality is on the critical mass of

cardholders and merchants, needed for the network to be viable on both sides and beyond that

- on the optimal size of the network.

430. Network externality is sometimes called membership externality.740 The effect of this

externality is on the initial decision whether (or not) to become a cardholder or a card-accepting

merchant.

735 For a similar example, KATZ, REFORM OF CREDIT CARDS SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA COMMISSIONED REPORT, supra note

721, at 15 . 736 For expansion, Guido Calabresi & Douglas Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules and Inalienability: One View

of the Cathedral, 85 HARV. L. REV. 1089 (1972). 737 Rochet & Tirole, Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report, supra note729, at 647; Wilko Bolt, Retail Payments, supra

note 721, at 346: “[P]ayment networks give rise to strong usage and network externalities”. 738 Nicholas Economides & David Henriques, To Surcharge Or Not to Surcharge? A Two-Sided Market Perspective of

the no-Surcharge Rule (ECB Working Paper No. 1338. Oct. 2011). 739 PAGE & LOPATKA, NETWORK EXTERNALITIES, supra note 724, at 957: “In deciding whether to buy a network good,

the individual compares the price only with his private benefit, not the benefit that his purchase confers on other users.

Consequently, the equilibrium size of a physical network under perfect competition, with direct network externalities,

may be smaller than the social optimum”. 740 Rochet & Tirole, Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report, supra note729, at 650; Hayashi, Do U.S Consumers, supra

note 629, at 48: “[M]embership externality, which is equivalent to the chicken and-egg problem”.

Page 177: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

177

431. As shown by Baxter,741 without interchange fees, if the issuer's cost is bigger than the benefit

to the cardholder (Ci>Bc), even the minimal fee the issuer must offer (Pc=Ci) will not convince

the potential cardholder to join the network. The network will have a problem achieving critical

mass. If consumers are homogeneous, then it is possible that their utility from cards, exceeds

Ci and all of them (because they are homogeneous) will become cardholders. However it is also

possible that none of them will become a cardholder. Heterogeneity in demand for cards among

consumers means that there will be some who become cardholders (for whom Bc>Ci), but if

not, enough cardholders are willing to pay at least Pc=Ci, the network will operate in a degraded

form. Only consumers who are at the upper left of the demand curve might become cardholders.

432. The network externality arises because consumers consider only their private cost / benefit

calculations. Consumers have no reason to take into account the benefits to merchants or to

society when they consider whether or not to become cardholders. Whenever the private cost

exceeds the private benefit (Pc>Bc), the customer will not join the network. When private costs

exceed private benefits, a subsidy is required to persuade customers to join. Without this

subsidy, the size of the network is limited by the side with the smaller demand.

Usage Externality

433. The second externality in payment cards does not occur at the adoption stage but rather when

the cardholder uses the card. The usage externality - is not related to the size of the network,

but to the existence of other means of payment, and the various costs and benefits of each

payment instrument.

434. When a customer approaches the cashier with several payment instruments in her/his wallet

(check, cash, debit and credit), the customer will choose to pay with the instrument that is most

beneficial to her/him. The usage externality occurs when the chosen payment instrument is in

fact more expensive, especially for the merchant, but nevertheless, the cardholder chooses to

use it anyway. The cardholder externalizes on the merchants the expensive cost, and enjoys

(internalizes) the cheap cost or the other benefits the chosen payment instrument inflicted on

her/him.742

741 See supra ch. 6.2. 742 Hayashi, Optimal Balance, supra note 619, at 5: “Usage externality arises from usage decision. In a payment market,

consumers choose a payment method from a set of payment methods the merchant accepts. The consumer’s choice of

payment methods affects the merchant benefits/costs. However, the consumer’s private incentive typically does not

reflect the merchant benefits/costs”; Joseph Farrell, Efficiency and Competition between Payment Instruments, 5 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 26, 28 (2006).

Page 178: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

178

435. Usage externality on a large scale creates a problem of adverse selection. The concern is that a

cheap payment instrument will not be able to provide usage incentives for its users

(cardholders), as the expensive payment instrument provides. The outcome might be that the

expensive payment instrument would exclude the cheap one, due to lack of attractiveness of the

latter among payers, and only expensive payment instruments will survive. Another name for

this phenomenon is “Gresham's Law of Payments”, which states that “bad money drives out

good money”.743

For example, if there are two bills in your wallet, one worn and the other brand new, you would

probably prefer to use the worn bill, before it will be torn apart while in your possession. The

merchant would also like to dispose of the bad bill first, and so the bad money drives out the

good money from circulation. Every user externalizes the risk of the torn bill on the next user.

This is a classic usage externality.

436. The difference between the two externalities is very important. The network externality affects

the adoption decision in the first place. It therefore affects the size of the network. The usage

externality affects the usage decision, and therefore affects the volume of transactions.

437. The interchange fee is a mechanism which internalizes both of these externalities. This is the

justification for sanctioning the interchange fee, despite its being a minimum price-fixing

arrangement between competitors. I shall explain now the role of the interchange fee in

internalizing the two externalities in payment cards, both network and usage.

7.3. Interchange Fee As a Mechanism To Internalize Network

Externality

438. In general, the surplus a consumer derives from consumption of a product, is the difference

between its price and the value to the consumer. The utility consumers derive from apparel or

743 Christian Von Wizsacker, Comments regarding "Reform of Credit Card Schemes in Australia II" Commissioned

Report, RBA (2002): “Gresham’s Law: bad coins drive out good coins. Traditionally, coins had a certain metallic value.

If the metallic value of different exemplars of the same denomination differed, the buyer preferred to pay with a bad

coin.”;

John Vickers, Public Policy and the Invisible Price: Competition Law, Regulation and the Interchange Fee, Payments

Sys. Research Conference 231, 235 (2005): “Just as our 16th century forbears would rather pay with a coin that had lost

1 per cent of its gold than a full one, so in the 21st century some of us may be tempted to pay by means that yield 1 per

cent rewards at the expense of the retailer than by ways that do not.”; Alan S. Frankel, Monopoly and Competition in

the Supply and Exchange of Money 66 ANTITRUST L.J. 313, 317 (1998); I. J. Macfarlane, Greshams Law of Payments,

RBA (Address to Australasian Institute of Banking and Finance Industry Forum), Sydney, 23 March 13 (2005). See

also infra note 1646.

Page 179: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

179

a beverage or any other product or service - does not change, as a function of the number of

other people that use the product. On the contrary, sometimes consumers derive higher benefit

if fewer consumers buy the product. For example, apparel buyers might prefer to be unique.

439. In network products, customer's utility is positively correlated with the number of other

members in the network. As more merchants honor payment cards, and as more consumers

adopt cards, the individual cardholder or merchant derives higher utility from the bigger size of

the network.

440. The interchange fee is a tool which transfers surplus from the side with the higher demand to

the side with the lower demand. The interchange fee is a tool to expand the size of the network,

on the side that limits network’s growth, for the benefit of the two sides. Imagine for instance

two runners. The pace is determined by the slower runner. The interchange fee is similar to a

boost to this slower runner. The interchange fee induces the side with the less willingness to

pay. Wise utilization of the interchange fee can increase the size of the network not only to the

point of critical mass, where the network is viable, but above it, to its optimal size. On the other

hand, excessive interchange fees might cause market wide price increase together with

oversupply and excessive usage of cards.744

441. The history of credit cards reveals that cardholders' side was less willing to pay for cards (high

elasticity).745 Networks encouraged cardholders to join, through low cardholder fee (even

negative). The interchange fee was a major factor in encouraging cardholders to adopt cards.

The growth on the side of cardholders caused the network to be more attractive to merchants.

Growth on the merchants' side made the network more attractive to cardholders, and the cycle

continued.

442. History also provides an example of a payment instrument that did not manage to overcome

network externality. In the 1990s a revolutionary payment instrument was developed: the finger

(print). The company which developed this payment instrument was called “Pay by Touch”.746

All one had to do in order to pay was to place a finger on a biometric reader at the cashier,

instead of swiping a card through a POS device. The finger was the payment card, read just like

a card is read in a card reader device.

744 See infra ch. 10 for a discussion on the competitive concerns raised by interchange fee. See also supra ¶ 374. 745 Supra note189. 746 https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Pay_By_Touch

Page 180: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

180

443. The finger print is probably more convenient and more secure than payment cards. It goes

without saying that this form of payment is safer, in terms of fraud and abuse. Nevertheless,

Pay By Touch never became viable. It failed to establish and reach a critical mass on the

merchant side. Had it been successful, it would have had automatic high penetration on

cardholders' side.747

444. The need to recruit critical mass on one side of the market, in order to attract critical mass on

the other side, is certainly not unique to payment cards. Dating clubs that do not have a critical

mass of subscribers from one gender, will not be attractive to the other gender, even if the entry

is free.748 Application developers will not develop applications for operating systems with few

end users, even if the source codes are provided free of charge, and vice versa, i.e., end users

will not find attractive operating systems with few applications. A newspaper that has no critical

mass of readers will not be attractive to advertisers, even if it distributed for free, and vice versa.

A mall without interesting shops will not attract customers, and vice versa. Real estate agents

with property for sale but with no buyers will not succeed, and vice versa.

445. The interchange fee has two effects on the payment card network, which are connected to the

network externality: a direct effect followed by an indirect effect.

Direct network effect is the ordinary effect that also exists in ordinary 'one-sided' products.

When the price of a (normal) product increases, its consumption decreases. The direct effect of

an increase in the interchange fee is an increase in the MSF and decrease in the cardholder fee.

This direct effect is expressed in fewer merchants and more cardholders in the network. But the

effects on each side are not of the same magnitude. The consensus is that merchants’ demand

is rigid and far less elastic than cardholders’ demand.749 Especially after merchants already

accept cards, they would find it almost impossible to cease accepting them.750 When this is the

case, an increase in the interchange fee will lead fewer merchants to abandon cards but many

cardholders to adopt them. As long as the effect on the cardholder side is stronger, the direct

effect of an increase in the interchange fee will therefore be expansion of the network.

747 DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND

BORROWING ch. 1 (2d ed. 2005). 748 Sebastian Voigt & Oliver Hinz, Network Effects in Two-Sided Markets: Why a 50/50 User Split is Not Necessarily

Revenue Optimal, at 29-30 (2015): “Users may derive positive cross-side network effects from the participation of the

other user group; for example, the more women are on a dating platform, the more attractive the service is for men”. 749 United States v. Am. Express Co., 2016 U.S. App. LEXIS 17502 (2d Cir. N.Y. Sept. 26, 2016): "Within the credit-

card industry, cardholders are generally less willing to pay to use a certain card than merchants are to accept that same

card, and thus a network may charge its cardholders a lower fee than it charges merchants."; For expansion see supra ¶¶

93, 441 and note 191. 750 Supra ¶ 201.

Page 181: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

181

446. The Indirect network effect is the effect of an increase in demand of a side (e.g., merchants),

despite an increase in price for them. This is the most special feature of two sided products.

The increase in demand despite higher price, results from the increase in demand of the other

side (e.g., cardholders), due to the direct network effect, which makes the product/service more

attractive. This is certainly different and distinct from an ordinary "one-sided" product, in

which, ceteris paribus, an increase in price leads to a drop in demand, with no countervailing

effect. The indirect network effect characterizes other two-sided products as well, and is not

unique to payment cards.

For example, the benefit to merchants in a mall rises when more customers visit the mall. All

else being equal, it is possible that a merchant would prefer to pay higher rent, if part of it is

intended for marketing, advertising and promotions designated to increase the number of

customers.751

Another example is the increase in the utility for a gender in a dating club, as the number of

members from the other gender increases, even if the price goes up. Men, for example, may

prefer to pay higher subscription fee, if in return price for women falls and their number

increases, and vice versa. An increase in the number of men despite the rise in price for men is

a classic example of the indirect network effect.752

447. Spain exhibited an empirical example of indirect network effects. Following a regulatory

reform, the interchange fee in Spain decreased. As a result: (a) the MSF fell, and more

merchants began to honor payment cards (direct effect); (b) despite an increase in cardholder

fees (direct effect), the adoption of payment cards among cardholders increased (indirect effect,

caused by the larger merchant acceptance); and (c) total revenue from card fees increased,

despite a decrease in the revenue per transaction, because the aggregate increase in the volume

of transactions, outweighed the effect of the drop in revenue per transaction.753

448. The direct and indirect effects of the interchange fee on demand and supply can be described

as follows: interchange fees increase the cost to merchants (direct effect - the movement of the

751 See AT 46791-03-14 El Rov v. General Director, at 15 (Dec. 4, 2014) 752 Voigt & Hinz, Network Effects in Two-Sided Markets, supra note 748: “[P]ositive cross-side and negative same-side

network effects have a significant impact on the revenue generated per user”. 753 Santiago Carbo Valverde et al., Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation, at 8-9 (Federal Reserve

Bank of Chicago Working Paper No. 09-11. 2009). For criticism, David S. Evans & Abel M. Mateus, How Changes in

Payment Card Interchange Fees Affect Consumers Fees and Merchant Prices: An Economic Analysis with Applications

to the European Union, at 29-31 (2011) available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1878735.

Page 182: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

182

supply curve of cards for merchants up and left), and lowers the cardholder fees (movement of

the supply curve of cards for cardholders down and right), so the number of cardholders

increases.

The indirect network effect is reflected by an increase in demand of cards by merchants

(movement up and right of the demand curve of merchants), as cards become more attractive

for them because of increased cardholder usage, despite the increase in the MSF. This, in turn,

increases even more the attractiveness of cards to cardholders (movement up and right of the

demand curve of cards for cardholders). The indirect effects continue until convergence.754

449. The interchange fee creates an asymmetric price structure. One side (merchants) pays more than

the other. However, asymmetric pricing is a fundamental characteristic of two-sided products.

The platform exploits the rigid demand of one side to allocate more costs on this side and

transfer revenue to the other side, which has more elastic demand. Other two-sided products

are also characterized by asymmetric price structure. One side funds most of the costs:

Shopping malls do not charge customers, although customers entail high costs on shopping

malls. Malls even offer benefits to customers (which are equivalent to negative fees), in the

form of free parking or other kinds of discounts. Malls earn almost all of their income from

merchants.

Operating systems charge little from application developers, and sometimes even allow free

access to components of their operating systems. They collect most of their revenue from end-

users.755

Real estate agents, stock markets and auction houses charge different prices to each side, buyers

and sellers. At the extreme, one side pays nothing and the other side everything. For example,

real estate agents might implement this pricing structure to increase the supply of assets (charge

nothing from sellers) or the demand to assets (charge nothing from buyers).

Adobe distributes for free its Acrobat reader for PDF files, and charges payment for the Adobe

754 Janusz a. Ordover, Comments on Evans & Schmalensee’s “The Industrial Organization of Markets with Two-Sided

Platforms”, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 181, 185 (2007): “An increase in price on one side above some initial level

reduces participation on that side and sets off a chain of adverse effects that bounce back and forth between the sides”. 755 EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC, supra note 747, at 145.

Page 183: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

183

writer.756

Newspaper readers generally do not fund all costs of content and production. Typically,

advertisers bear most of the costs.

450. As trivial as those examples may be for the reader up to this point, those who are not familiar

with two-sided network products, might mistakenly analyze the price structure of two-sided

products through the same lens used to analyze ordinary products, and arrive at different, even

absurd, conclusions (at least from the point of view of this work).757 I will give two examples:

451. In 2010, and again in 2014, two bills, which were aimed to restrict free distribution of

newspapers, made headlines in Israel.758 The 2014 bill even passed first reading (first stage of

legislation).759 In practice, this Bill is aimed to prevent further dissemination of the newspaper

“Israel Today”. This newspaper is distributed in the form of a radically asymmetrical price

structure: the paper is distributed for free to readers. It collects all of its revenues from

advertisers.

In my opinion, the bill demonstrated a fundamental lack of understanding for the need of a two-

sided product, such as a newspaper, to overcome the chicken and egg problem in order to reach

a critical mass of readers, and penetrate into a market with a dominant player (Yediot Ahronot).

In two-sided markets, it is common that charging even a small amount from one side (readers)

reduces the amount of readers dramatically.760 The price structure of 'Israel Today' is a

legitimate pricing of a two-sided product. Even a price of zero on one side (which is, of course,

below marginal cost), cannot be considered predatory.761 Predatory pricing in two-sided

products can be considered only if the price level (as opposed to the price structure),762 charged

from both sides together (readers and advertisers), is lower than the costs of the newspaper.

756 Id. at 8, 42, 139. 757 Julian Wright, One-Sided Logic in Two-Sided Markets 3 REV. NETWORK ECON. 44 (2004). 758 Proposal for a Law to Amend the Press Command (Restriction on Free Distribution of Newspaper with National

Circulation), (2010); Proposal, Law to Promote and Defend the Written Press in Israel, (2014)

www.knesset.gov.il/privatelaw/data/19/2464.rtf. 759 Divrei Haknesset 19, Sitting 177 at 46-62 (Nov. 12, 2014). 760 EVANS AND SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC, supra note 747, at 145. 761 Jenny, Competition Policy Issues, supra note 511, at 16: “In two sided markets, a price below marginal cost ( for

example a consumer fee equal to zero) does not necessarily indicates predation or cross subzidisation”. 762 Supra ch. 2.4.2 (price level and price structure).

Page 184: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

184

Only then, and with the existence of a dominant market position, can commencement of a

predation examination be considered.763

452. Second, in 2008, a motion for certification of a class action against a night-club that charged

different entrance prices from men and women, was submitted to court.764 The claim asserted

that the night club discriminated against men on basis of gender, contrary to the law.765

As explained above, asymmetric pricing of a night club is designed to balance different

demands of men and women. It is a rightful distinction and not discrimination. The claim argued

for a narrow, literal interpretation of the law, which stands against its purposive

interpretation.766 Men may even encourage club owners to price asymmetrically (even though

men would pay more), when the result is a women/men ratio that yields higher utility for them.767

A night club is a two-sided product. It is not to be analyzed in the same manner as ordinary

product, in which price discrimination based on gender is prohibited.

The court dismissed the motion to approve the class action, but determined that the different

pricing was discriminatory.768 Another court also ruled that charging different entrance prices

to night-clubs for men and women is prohibited discrimination.769

In my opinion, these judgments did not pay enough attention to the balancing requirement of

different demands between men and women. The need to balance demands leads in my view to

the conclusion that this is not discrimination, but a permitted price distinction. A night club is

a two-sided product. Actions of club owner to reduce demand on one side and increase demand

on the other has should not be considered inappropriate discrimination. Courts should not look

through one-sided glasses at two-sided products.

763 Amelia Fletcher, Predatory Pricing in Two-Sided Markets: A Brief Comment, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INTE'L 221, 223

(2007): “[P]redation can clearly occur where a platform prices its total service at a level that fails to cover its avoidable

costs of providing the total service, taking revenues from both sides of the market into account”; see also Ori BarAm &

Elad Man, The Other Side of the Newspaper, The 7th Eye (Dec. 15, 2012). 764 Ci.C Nadav Lahat v. Forum Production (Claim), (Nevo, Oct 30, 2008). 765 Prohibition of Discrimination in Products, Services and Entry to Places of Entertainment and Public Facilities Law,

2000. 766 For purposive interpretation see, for example, Civ. A. 105/92 Ram Engineering V. Nazereth Municipality, 47(5) 189,

(1993); HCJ 267/88 Reshet Kolel Haidra v. Court of Local Affairs, 43(3) 728, (1989); CA 2706/11 Sybil Germany v.

Harmatic, para. 45 (Sept. 4, 2015) (The meaning of legislation is determined by the purpose of it). For expansion see

AHRON BARAK, INTERPRETATION IN LAW - INTERPRETATION OF LEGISLATION (1993). 767 Voigt & Hinz, Network Effects in Two-Sided Markets, supra note 748. 768 Ci.C 5315/08 Nadav Lahat v. Forum Productions, (Dec. 26, 2011). 769 CiC 2786-06-12 Kobi Tzetzna v. Lord Bars Ltd, (July 16, 2014).

Page 185: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

185

Nothing in the above should be construed to legitimize other sorts of unlawful discrimination

in clubs (like racism), which are invidious, regardless of whether they could be economically

justified from the two-sided prospective.

453. In 2011, the Supreme Court held that discrimination between men and women in an entrance

to a night club, based on age, is unlawful.770 In my view, it is of no importance if balancing the

demands is done by different pricing or by age hurdles. Reducing demand for one side to

balance demands, in a two sided product, is for the benefit of that side, and cannot be regarded

as discrimination against it.771

454. However, a clear distinction should be made between the legitimacy of asymmetric pricing of

a newspaper or a night club and the interchange fee.

In all of the two-sided products above, the owner of the platform chooses independently and

unilaterally, without consulting competitors, how to divide the price level between the two

sides. Mall owners choose unilaterally whether to charge or not to charge for parking. If mall

owners would have met and coordinated parking fees at malls, this would be an explicit cartel.

A newspaper chooses whether to charge or not to charge readers, and if so, how much. If

newspaper owners met to coordinate prices for readers, they would probably find themselves

on the defendants’ bench. A night club owner solely decides on the price structure between men

and women. If this decision would be made among competing club owners, it would be a blatant

restrictive arrangement.772

Regularly in two-sided products, the price structure determination is made without coordination

between competitors. The platform owner communicates directly with the two sides of

customers. Indeed regulation of interchange fee is not applicable to close (three-party) card

networks, in which the network connects directly with the two sides. On the other hand, open

card networks cannot avoid coordination. By definition, except “On-Us” transactions every

other transaction involves two competitors - an issuer and acquirer that are not the same. Thus,

while most two-sided products act as closed systems, where the owner contracts directly with

770 CA 8821/09 Pavel Prozianski v. Laila Tov Productions, (Nov. 16, 2011). 771 Ori BarAm, Note on Ruling 8821/09 Pavel Prozianski v. Laila Tov Productions, (Nevo, 2011). 772 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1280, at 636 n. 30: “However, decisions

not to charge differentially in such cases are typically made by independent, competing firms, not by all providers of,

e.g., parking lots”.

Page 186: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

186

the two sides of customers and unilaterally sets the price structure, the interchange fee in open

card networks is a restrictive arrangement.773

455. A similar restrictive arrangement in two sided market is termination fees in

telecommunications. Communication networks are also a two-sided product. They have to

decide how much to charge the calling party and how much to charge the addressee side.

Termination fee is the payment that the calling network pays to the receiving network for

completion of a call (when the call is not "on-net" which is the parallel term for "On-Us" in

telecommunication networks).

Interchange fees and termination fees are both hidden from the payer. Both fees are set by

competitors wearing two different hats at the same time, when determining the termination fee.

The price (termination fee) they decide to pay, in their capacity as a calling network, is actually

paid to themselves, in their capacity as the addressee network. The negotiation to determine the

termination fee is thus a self-negotiation, which unsurprisingly yields high prices. The result is

increase in the price of calls.

Rochet & Tirole claim the need to compare the approach of the interchange fees and termination

fees ("Need for Consensus").774 Without regulation, there is a high possibility of market failure

that will result in termination fees being set on supra-competitive rates.775 Indeed, termination

fees, like interchange are under regulatory supervision.776

456. In Israel, one of the major consumer revolutions occurred, when termination fees dropped in

2011 due to a governmental reform. This enabled cellular operators to offer unlimited packages

for prices under NIS 50 per month, a fraction of the prices prior to the reform. Before the reform,

a mobile operator could not offer unlimited calls to its subscribers, because of the risk that they

would make lengthy calls to other networks, and expose it (the calling network) to enormous

termination (interchange) fees. The reform reduced termination fees (analogic to interchange

773 Harry Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees Generally Lead to Cash-Promoting Cross-Subsidisation, at 8 BANK

OF FINLAND RESEARCH DISCUSSION PAPERS (2011): “Multilateral interchange fees (MIFs) in particular are set jointly by

the issuers, which can be viewed as a system of cartel-type anti-competitive agreements”. 774 Rochet & Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems, supra note 710, at 12. 775 Jean-Jacques Laffont, Patrick Rey & Jean Tirole, Network Competition I Overview and Nondiscriminatory Pricing,

29 RAND J. ECON. 1 (1998); David Gilo & Yossi Spiegel, Network Interconnection with Competitive Transit, 16 INFO.

ECON. POL'Y 439 (2004). 776 Communication Regulations (Bezeq and Transmissions) (Payments for Termination Fee), (2000). For expansion,

OECD, DEVELOPMENTS IN MOBILE TERMINATION (OECD Digital Economy Papers, no. 193, 2012); Commission

Recommendation on the Regulatory Treatment of Fixed and Mobile Termination Rates in the EU, supra note 866.

Page 187: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

187

fees) to very low sums - few single agorot per minute. The risk (of the calling network) to pay

high termination fee became negligible, so networks could offer unlimited packages.

457. The conclusion is that from the network externality viewpoint, interchange fee is warranted to

balance demands and enlarge the size of networks, when networks are at their early stages, and

still must establish themselves in the market. This purpose does not apply to mature networks,

as will be explained now.

7.4. Negation Of The Network Externality Justification

458. The role of the interchange fee as a mechanism to internalize network effect is exhausted when

the network is mature and ubiquitous. When the network is universal, a higher interchange fee

does not contribute anymore to the size of the network.

The network effect might also be exhausted in other products. A club might be attractive only

up to a certain capacity. Too many fax machines will cause confusion and degrade the value of

fax machines for their users.

459. The justification of interchange fees, which is based on network externality, draws its vitality

from the need to expand the network. The need to solve the chicken and egg problem and reach

a critical mass and further, an optimal mass, is valid when absent the interchange fee (or with a

lower interchange fee), the network would act in a degraded form. The justification relies on

the assumption that without the required interchange fee, cardholder fees would exceed the

utility for enough cardholders, so as to render the network atrophied. The interchange fee,

according to the network rationalization, is required not only to keep the network from being

too small, but to bring it to optimal size. This argument applies well to nascent networks.

However, in mature networks this rationale is not valid.777

When cards are ubiquitous, scale and scope economies cause transaction's costs to decrease. At

the same time benefits to users from the large network are maximized on both sides. The

important thing is that in mature networks, the marginal benefit from the network, to users at

777 Dennis Carlton & S. Alan Frankel, Transaction Costs, Externalities, and "Two Sided" Payment Markets, supra note

718, at 639 : “Credit cards, however, have achieved widespread consumer adoption and almost universal acceptance

among major retailers. It therefore remains difficult to defend the present need for collective setting of interchange fees

on the grounds that the fees were necessary to launch the network decades earlier.”;

Vickers, supra note 743, at 236: “As to the desirability of using the interchange fee to tune the balance between card

acceptance and card holding/usage, it may well be that the case is stronger in nascent systems than in mature systems

with wide coverage”.

Page 188: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

188

both sides, should be big enough for them to bear the cost, with no need for subsidy. In the

literature there is a consensus that when payment card networks reach maturity the network

effect is exhausted.778

460. Contrary to its initial intent, any attempt to justify an interchange fee on the grounds of the need

to internalize network effects, when applied to mature networks, may undermine the

justification.779 Mature networks can even suffer from congestion.780 Just like a problem of too

many men and women in a dance club, or too much advertising in a newspaper (which lowers

the attractiveness to readers), too-high interchange fees can also cause congestion and over-

supply of payment cards.781

461. Against the argument that current size of networks is large enough, so the network externality

justification for interchange fee is inapposite (at least not at the former levels), the payment

card firms have repeatedly claimed, in Australia, United States, Israel, Spain, and probably

elsewhere that reducing the interchange fee will ignite a process of a “death spiral” that would

destroy the network. The argument goes as follows: (1) a decrease in the interchange fee would

require a raise in the cardholder fees; (2) this would result in fewer cardholders; (3) cards would

778 Howard H. Chang, David S. Evans & Richard Schmalensee, Some Economic Principles for Guiding Antitrust Policy

Towards Joint Ventures (1997): “[J]ust as economies of scale or scope can be exhausted at some level of firm size or

output diversity, so too can the magnitude of network externalities decrease as a network increases in size and reach

zero at some point.”;

Jean Charles Rochet, The Theory of Interchange Fees: A Synthesis of Recent Contributions, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON.

97, 98 (2003): “This network externality becomes less and less important as the network matures, when virtually all

potential users have joined.”;

Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1280, at 655: “By its nature, a network

externality is likely to become less important (and a less persuasive justification) as a network matures… Visa and

MasterCard now operate the largest card payment systems and enjoy almost ubiquitous penetration among major

merchants. Thus, they probably have little continued need to overcome chicken-and-egg entry barriers.”;

Wang Zhu, Market Structure and Payment Card Pricing: What Drives the Interchange?, 28 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 86, 96

(2010): “[W]e model a mature card market where the extensive margin of card usage is less important.”;

Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L. REV. 1321, 1388

(2008): “The network effects concern is simply inapplicable in the context of mature payment networks competing

against other mature payment networks.”;

Amelio, Antitrust Assessment of MIF and the Tourist Test, supra note 404, at 16: “If consumer adoption and usage of

payment instrument would be almost complete even without MIF, limited benefits can be achieved.”;

Hayashi, Optimal Balance, supra note 619, at 5: “Once the market matured, the positive feedback becomes almost

negligible. That means, additional cardholders do not influence merchant card acceptance and additional merchants do

not influence consumer cardholding”; KATZ, REFORM OF CREDIT CARDS SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA COMMISSIONED REPORT

supra note 735 at 14; Heimler, Payment Cards Pricing Patterns, supra note 611, at 8. 779 Dominique Forest & Vaigauskaite Dovile, EC Competition Policy in the Payments Area: New Developments in

MIFs for Cards and SEPA Direct Debit, 2 EC COMPETITION POL'Y NEWSL. 38, 40 (2009): “When a payment card

would reach universal usage in a market even without MIF, the need to promote the issuing of such a card in terms of

network effects would vanish”. 780 DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALANSEE, MARKETS WITH TWO-SIDED PLATFORMS, in 1 ISSUES IN COMPETITION

LAW AND POLICY 667 ( ABA Section of Antitrust Law ed., 2008): “At a given size, expanding the number of customers

on the platform can result in congestion that increases search and transaction costs”. 781 Infra ch. 10.3.

Page 189: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

189

then be less attractive to merchants (the indirect network effect); (4) at the margin, merchants

will stop honoring cards; (5) this will in turn lead to a further reduction in demand for cards on

the cardholder side, and so forth; (6) This snowball effect will keep on going until the

demolition of the network, or at least until it will exist only in a degraded form.782

The death spiral prophecy was refuted empirically in Australia, Spain and Israel.783 Courts

found that despite the decline in interchange fees and increase in cardholder fees, there has not

been a drop on the cardholder side. On the contrary, the volume of purchases and the number

of active cards is increasing every year.784

462. Beyond the empirical refutation, the “snowball” argument is also theoretically unfounded, and

has no merit.

First, a drop in the interchange fee does not necessarily cause an increase in cardholder fee to

any positive sum, let alone inevitable abandonment by cardholders. When cardholder fees are

negative at the outset, because of rewards, an increase in cardholder fees will not necessarily

exclude cardholders from the networks. Cardholder fees might increase but still remain negative

or near zero. Issuers have other channels of income than interchange fees, such as interest on

credit, which is a main and growing source of income.785 The direct income from cardholders

might well suffice to keep cardholder fees low enough, so that the cardholder side will not be

harmed in the event of a drop in the interchange fee.786 Indeed, in Australia, even after the

reform substantially trimmed the interchange fee, cardholder fees remained negative.787

782 Supra ¶ 659. 783 Supra ¶¶ 660, 672, 447. 784 AT 4630/01 Leumi v. General Director, at 20 (Aug. 31, 2006) ("The Methodology Decision") (Yet, despite the

decline in interchange fees and raise in cardholder fees, the huge drop in willingness to hold cards did not occur. On the

contrary, the volume of purchases by households is increasing every year). See also supra ch. 3, and supra ¶¶ 658-659. 785 Supra ¶ 28. 786 Vickers, supra note 743, at 242: “[C]redit card issuers have substantial revenue streams other than the interchange

fee to finance the cost of funding the interest-free period, especially interest payments from the many who do not

routinely pay off their credit card balances in full.”;

Soren Korsgaard, Paying for Payments Free Payments and Optimal Interchange Fees, 1682 ECB Working Paper, at 2

(2014): “payment services are often provided either for free or against periodical fees: Consumers’ marginal cost is

therefore zero, independent of interchange fees”; id. at 5: “The countries which have historically operated payment

card schemes without interchange fees also happen to be those in which card usage is greatest”. 787 Macfarlane, Greshams Law, supra note 743, at 13: “Despite the cut in interchange fees to an average around 0.55 per

cent, issuers are still able to offer interest-free credit and rewards whose value averages around 0.6-0.7 per cent. Issuers

are able to do this partly due to the revenue they earn from annual fees and the interest earnings from those credit card

users who do not pay their bill by the due date. For many people, credit cards remain one of the very few services that

they are actually paid to use!”.

Page 190: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

190

463. When direct income from cardholders is high enough, and given that the interchange fee is a

minimum price fixing agreement that cause an increase in final prices, there is no need for it to

further subsidize issuers. In Europe, it was found already in 2007 that most issuers do not need

the revenue from the interchange fee to be profitable:

It appears that 62% of all banks surveyed would still make profits with credit card

issuing even if they did not receive any interchange fee revenues at all. In 23 EU

Member States, at least one bank participating in the survey was able to make a

profit from issuing credit cards without interchange fees. This exercise seems to

partially invalidate explanations put forward by the industry that total system

output would suffer if issuing were not subsidised through the transfer of revenues

from acquirers. The aim of this analysis is not to argue in favour of a zero

interchange fee. However, in the light of the results, it is legitimate to question the

optimality of the current level of interchange fees in several countries.788

464. The conclusion of the European Commission from January 2007 that an interchange fee is

probably not required, when the pretext is the network size, is even more valid today. In recent

years, direct channels of income from cardholders to issuers (interest on credit, loans and

cardholder fees) only expanded, to well above their 2007 levels, accompanied by a parallel

reduction in transaction's costs.789

465. However, even if cardholder fees will rise to a low positive level, then, as explained above, in

mature networks, enough cardholders derive sufficient utility from cards so as not to abandon

the network. It is reasonable to assume that cardholders will cease carrying the second and third

cards in their wallet, but will keep at least one card. Giving up the extra card in the wallet cannot

be considered as a negative impact on the card network. If a cardholder gives up her Visa or

MasterCard or vice versa, there is indeed a negative effect on the abandoned network, but this

a zero sum game with no aggregate effect. This is not a matter for competition law that is

focusing on protecting competition, and not competitors.790

466. Another reason which renders the death-spiral argument inapplicable is that cardholder fee

cannot rise to unreasonable levels, because this is a regulated fee under the Banking rules.791 In

788 COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT ON RETAIL BANKING, at 157, SEC 2007 (0106) final (Jan. 31, 2007);

Pierre Bos, International Scrutiny of Payment Card Systems, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 739, 751 (2006): "On the issue of

profitability, the main findings of the Commission's inquiry are:1. Profitability in card issuing is high and has been

sustained over time. 2. Profitability is higher for credit cards than for debit cards. 3. Even without interchange fees,

card issuing remains profitable". 789 Supra ch. 3, see also ¶¶ 28, 502595, 609, 126, 143. 790 Appeal 9/99 Amana v. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 3013742, para. 17 (Feb. 21, 2002) (Antitrust laws

intended to avoid harm to competition, not competitors, and citing Brooke Group Ltd.v.Brown & Williamson Tobacco

Corp., 113 S.Ct. 2578, 2588 - 2589). 791 Supra ¶ 27.

Page 191: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

191

practice due to rewards, cardholder fee, especially for "heavy" users, is much lower than the

ceiling allowed by the banking rules.792 Most probably, even in the unlikely event that

cardholder fee would increase, this would reflect in curtailing rewards (which is pro-

competitive!),793 and not an increase in fixed cardholder fee. It is reasonable to assume that

networks' size would not be impeded.

467. Leinonen has another explanation why reduction in the interchange fee will not lead to an

increase in cardholder fees. The costs of cash for banks are higher than the costs of payment

cards.794 Banks would not want to enlarge their costs by enabling cardholders to shift their

expenditures from cards to (expensive) cash (for banks). Thus, issuers (which are all banking

auxiliary corporations),795 would refrain from increasing cardholder fees.796

468. The logical fallacy in the “death spiral” argument is that the spiral or the snowball would stop.

The cycle argument is flawed. Even if the effect of a reduction in the interchange fee would be

negative on cardholders, this would not be the effect on merchants. It is very unlikely that

reduction in the interchange fee will result in abandonment of the network by merchants. The

direct effect on merchants from lowering the interchange fee is positive (more merchants accept

cards). It is reasonable to assume that the negative indirect effect on merchants (which would

occur in the unlikely event that the cardholder side would decline), would only offset but not

outweigh the direct effect. Theoretically, it is possible that indirect effect would outweigh the

direct effect. However, it is hard to assume that this is the case here. It is not plausible that a

decline in the interchange fee that means a lower MSF for merchants will result in fewer

merchants in the card network.797

469. Reduction of the interchange fee transfers competition from hidden grounds to direct channels,

in which prices are visible and competition is transparent. Already in 2000, Balto proposed to

792 Supra ¶ 28. 793 see supra ¶¶ 351-357. 794 See supra ch. 5.3 (costs of cash). 795 Supra note 1264. 796 Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees, supra note 773, at 27: “Issuers often warn that cutting MIFs would result in

higher card fees and therefore in less use of cards and more use of cash. However, the outcome will probably be the

opposite, because if banks would promote the use of cash it would increase their overall costs due to more expensive

cash distribution”. 797 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1280, at 656: “Yet while a reduction in

interchange fees might well reduce the use of credit cards by some consumers in some transactions, it seems unlikely

that a reduction in merchant fees would be associated with a net decrease in the number of merchants accepting the

cards. This is particularly unlikely if, net of interchange fees, each card transaction costs merchants less on average than

alternative methods of payment—as suggested by the claimed usage externality justification.”; United States v. Am.

Express Co. LEXIS 20114, at 111 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015).

Page 192: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

192

reduce the interchange fee gradually, and monitor the effects, to ensure that the networks are

not harmed:

Card issuers and merchants will have to recover their costs internally. This may

mean higher direct costs for consumers for credit cards and debit cards. But again,

these prices will be transparent and in that fashion consumers can choose between

banks offering the lowest cost product and this will force banks to compete more

aggressively on these different cost factors. Ultimately it will force banks to

attempt to reduce the costs that are currently compensated by the interchange fee:

card issuance and risk of loss. This will provide even greater incentives for banks

to drive for efficiency.798

470. This proposal was revolutionary and ahead of its time. Today it seems logical as in mature card

networks, the argument that interchange fee is necessary to internalize network externalities is

flawed. I will examine now the second argument, which hinges the necessity of the interchange

fee on the usage externality.

7.5. Usage Externality Justification

471. Usage externality is caused due to the different costs and benefits of each payment

instrument.799 The usage externality is caused when the cardholder decides to pay with the most

beneficial payment instrument for her/him, even if it is an expensive payment instrument for

the merchant.

472. In Israel, merchants that accepted debit and prepaid cards were harmed, because the payment

card companies charged (contrary to the Methodology Decision), at least until April 2016,

unified MSF.800 Merchants could not enjoy the cheaper costs of debit and prepaid.

Credit card is a more expensive payment instrument than debit card, for merchants especially.801

PIN debit is an especially cheap payment instrument compared to credit cards.802 Efficiency

dictates that credit would be used only in transactions in which the credit function is needed.803

However, credit card firms grant cardholders a free funding period and bestow on cardholders

other rewards in order to steer them to pay with expensive credit cards and not cheap debit. The

result is that cardholders externalize high costs of their payment instrument on merchants, and

798 David Balto, The Problem of Interchange Fees: Costs without Benefits? E.C.L.R 215, 223 (2000). 799 For expansion see supra ch. 7.2.2 (Usage Externality). 800 Supra ch. 8.1.4. 801 Supra ¶ 125 802 Id. 803 Supra ch. 6.8 (Debit vs Credit).

Page 193: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

193

enjoy (internalize) benefits their choice bestows upon themselves. An OECD report emphasized

this point:

Systems that yield the lowest costs to the group of purchaser/merchants may not

be the ones that purchasers will choose to use. For example, if PIN-based debit

cards are the minimum cost electronic payment instrument to the integrated

consumer, but non-PIN cards offer purchasers a small financial incentive for each

marginal use of the card, purchasers may choose the non-PIN card despite it being

much more expensive for the merchant and less secure. That is, purchasers will not

take into account the full costs of card use to the integrated payment system

"consumer". As a result, modest rewards to purchasers for use of a much higher

total cost payment system can lead purchasers to use the higher cost system much

more frequently than they would if the costs of different payment systems were

always reflected in the retail prices of goods.804

473. When usage externality occurs, a merchant can take steps to prevent it by making his customers

internalize the costs of the payment instrument they use. The merchant does this by surcharging,

discounting, rewarding or steering customers in any other way, to pay with the preferred method

for the merchant. Price discrimination neutralizes the usage externality. For example if the

“cheap money” costs the merchant 1 and the “expensive money” costs the merchant 2, then by

surcharging 1, the merchant eliminates the usage externality. The cardholder internalizes the

full costs of the expensive payment instrument.

In practice, surcharging is not a widespread phenomenon, as explained in chapter 11.

474. Proponents of the interchange fee as a solution to the usage externality claim that interchange

fee is a better alternative to surcharging.805 The internalization of the usage externality is

exhausted at the point in which the MSF reaches the indifference criterion. When the merchant

pays a MSF that is equal to the net benefit (Bm), the merchant becomes indifferent to the

payment method the customer pays with.806 However, when the MSF sustains the indifference

criterion, the merchant no longer has any "profit" from the fact the customer pays with the cheap

instrument. The entire surplus is extracted from the merchant through the MSF.

When the MSF is different than Bm, the merchant is not indifferent between cards and other

payment instruments. When the MSF is lower than Bm the merchant would prefer to pay an

additional fee to marginal cardholders who intend to pay with another payment instrument, and

804 OECD, POLICY ROUNDTABLE, EXCESSIVE PRICES, at 7 DAF/COMP(2011)18. 805 Hans Zenger, Perfect Surcharging and the Tourist Test Interchange Fee, 35 J. BANK. FIN. 2544, 2544 (2011). 806 Supra ch. 8.2.1.

Page 194: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

194

steer them to pay with a card (the implied assumption is full pass through rate). When the MSF

exceeds Bm (Pm>Bm) e.g., because of exploitation of strategic considerations of merchants,

the usage externality is reversed ("Reverse Usage Externality"). The merchant prefers other

payment instrument, but is compelled to accept the card. Merchant pays for cards more than the

benefits cards yield. In this situation, when merchants do not surcharge, customers who pay

with other payment instruments (e.g., cash) are subsidizing the expensive payment instrument.

Farrell calls this: "negative externality".807

475. Theoretically an MSF=Bm could perfectly internalize usage externality. However, this requires

another condition – full pass through rate. When the pass through rate is not full, the usage

externality fails.808 The reason is that under the consumer welfare standard, interchange fee that

is not fully passed through, but is kept as profit, should not be eligible. Profits have nothing to

do with the need to internalize the usage externality or encouraging efficient usage of payment

instruments.809

476. But even under the unlikely assumption of full pass through, justification for interchange fee

which is under Bm is flawed, when most cardholders have enough utility from cards, or when

they suffice with a lower rate of interchange fee, for using their card. When this is the case,

interchange fee and the corresponding MSF should be lower than Bm.

For the majority of the infra-marginal cardholders, who derive inherent utility from cards, the

merchant does not need to pay a MSF which partly subsidizes them. Those cardholders would

pay with cards anyway, i.e., even with a lower interchange fee.

With regard to marginal cardholders, my argument is that merchants would rather pay a MSF

that is slightly lower, and give up the attempt to steer them (i.e., let them pay with a different

instrument). Merchants indeed "sacrifice" marginal cardholders, but in return save some of the

surplus from accepting cards in all transactions made with cards.

In this scenario, merchants are not indifferent but strictly prefer cards, because the MSF is

lower than Bm. The savings might be passed-through, depending on the pass through rate in

807 Farrell, supra note 742, at 38: “I think there is a good argument that the negative externality on non-card consumers

is more of a concern than the vertical externality between cardholder and merchant that the fee structure’s “balancing

role” resolves. Essentially this would be the view that participants in a complex venture should seek ways to solve their

internal problems without hurting outsiders". 808 Emilio Calvano, Note on the Economic Theory of Interchange, at 6 (Feb. 22, 2011). 809 For expansion, see my proposal, infra ch. 13.614.2.

Page 195: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

195

the industry to which the merchant belongs, and be reflected in a decrease in the final prices of

goods. In other words, there is no reason to bring the merchant to the point of indifference, if

we are guaranteed to get the merchant (and his customers) to a better point. I will illustrate with

an example:

477. Suppose that there are 1000 cardholders. Each performs one transaction (total of 1000

transactions). Now, as opposed to models that assume uniform distribution of utility among

cardholders, suppose now, what I find to be a more realistic assumption (which calls for

empirical confirmation that I leave for future research), that the utility of the cardholders from

cards is distributed unevenly between 2 to minus 2 (-2<Bc<2) so that:

900 cardholders have a greater utility than minus 0.5 (Bc>-0.5) from card usage compared to

other means of payment. Meaning, they either have an inherent positive benefit from card

usage, or they need only a “small push” of a reward up to 0.5 in order to steer them to pay with

a card.

50 cardholders have a negative utility from cards which is between minus 0.5 to minus 1 (-

0.5<Bc<-1). That is, they will pay with a different instrument, unless they receive a subsidy of

0.5 to 1 to steer them to cards. A cardholder in this group may be someone who has a large sum

of cash, and wants to get rid of it, but if paying with a card offers a large enough discount or

rebate, this cardholder will be steered and pay with card.

50 cardholders have a strong negative utility from cards (Bc<-1) meaning they strongly prefer

to pay with another payment instrument. A cardholder in this group may be someone who wants

to make a discreet purchase or one who has “black” cash money, or someone who wants and to

dispose of large sum of cash she carries. It is possible to steer at least some of these cardholders,

but only if the reward is substantial (bigger than 1).

Suppose again that Ci+Ca=4 and Bm=5. MSF that meets the indifference criterion is by

definition 5. Under full pass through rate the interchange fee is 3 and the cardholder fee is minus

1 (Pc=Ci+Ca-Bm=4-5=-1).810

However, even under a full pass through rate, and certainly if the pass through rate is not full,

810 Supra ¶ 214 (Equation 4) and 223 (equation 9).

Page 196: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

196

the merchant is better off if the MSF is less than the fee that meets the indifference criterion.

If the cardholder fee is not minus 1 but “only” minus 0.5, which is tantamount, under a full pass

through to MSF of Pm=4.5, interchange fee of IF=2.5, and Pc=-0.5 (instead of: MSF=5, IF=3,

Pc=-1 under the indifference criterion), then the merchant allegedly "loses" 250 from the 50

infra-marginal cardholders whose benefit is -0.5<Bc<-1, as they are not steered to pay with a

card (a loss of 5 in each transaction made with the alternative payment instrument that costs 5

more than a card).

The 50 marginal cardholders whose utility from cards is strongly negative (Bc<-1) continue to

pay with cash. They would do so anyway, even under a MSF=5 and Pc=-1, because their utility

from cards is smaller than -1. The shift from an interchange fee of 3 to an interchange fee of

2.5 does not affect them. It was futile with respect to them. They paid with cash before and

continue to do so.

The results of this example show that under a MSF=4.5 and not 5, merchants are better off.

Total consumer surplus of merchants and customers together is bigger than under the

indifference criterion. Indeed, the merchant “lost” 250 because 50 customers (who sustain -

0.5<Bc<-1) shifted to pay with the expensive payment instrument that costs the merchant 5

more than a card in each transaction. The loss would have been avoided, had those 50 paid by

card, and saved the merchant 250.

Nevertheless, merchants are better off. They saved 0.5 in the MSF (4.5 instead of 5) in the 900

other transactions that did take place with cards. Merchants payed Pm=4.5 and not Pm=5 in

900 transactions (total of 4,050), instead of paying Pm=5 in 950 transactions (total of 4,750).

Thus, the merchants saved 700. The sacrifice of 50 transactions cost the merchant 250. The

total surplus is therefore 450. Depending on the competitive conditions, some of the savings

will be transferred to a reduction in the final prices of goods in the market.

Another way to see this is when MSF=5, the merchant has zero surplus from accepting payment

instruments. The entire surplus from the 950 transactions that are made by cards (4750) is

extracted in the form of the MSF which is also 4750 (950x5=4,750). Under a MSF=4.5, the

merchant remains with surplus of 450 (surplus of 0.5 in 900 transactions=450).

Page 197: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

197

478. When the MSF is lower, prices are lower. The conclusion drawn is that when enough

cardholders do not need an interchange fee to encourage them, a fee lower than the fee that

sustains the indifference criterion might be preferable from the joint consumers' (merchants and

customers) standpoint. This holds even though the internalization of the usage externality is

lower, as social welfare is also higher when prices are lower, quantities increase and marginal

customers, especially those who pay with other payment instruments, enjoy lower prices and

purchase goods they did not purchase before.

The numbers above are just an example. Other numbers will yield different results. The example

is just intended to demonstrate a situation which I believe reflects reality, that when

cardholders have sufficient benefit from cards, the usage externality is not a good pretext

for existing levels of interchange fee. This is especially true where interchange fee is based

on the indifference criterion (Europe). Inherent incentives to pay with cards already exist for

most cardholders with no need for interchange fees to encourage them.

The existence of enough cardholders with sufficient benefit from cards, is what might make an

interchange fee that is intended to overcome the usage externality for the marginal customer,

too expensive from a social (and of course, consumers') point of view.

479. A critical point is that even if we acknowledge the usage externality as a pretext for interchange

fee, the condition must be full pass through.811 If issuers claim they need the revenue of the

interchange fee to incentivize usage, then they cannot use it for their own profits. Those are

conflicting and even contradictory goals. Rochet & Tirole call issuers' profits, which are derived

from interchange fees, “cozy cartel”.812 My proposal is to forbid profits achieved through cozy

cartel.813

480. A full pass through rate is a necessary but not a sufficient condition for the efficiency of the

interchange fee. Another concern is that in order to justify collection of high interchange fees,

issuers who know they must use interchange fee proceeds in order to justify their initial

collection, would abuse them. Rochet & Tirole call the phenomenon in which issuers artificially

inflate their costs to justify high interchange fee “wasteful competition”.814 This occurs when

811 Alan S. Frankel, Towards a Competitive Card Payments Marketplace, RBA 27, 43 (2007): "The interchange fee

proceeds are (in this theoretical framework) rebated entirely to the cardholder customer". 812 Rochet & Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems, supra note 710, at 10-11. 813 Infra ch. 13.6. 814 Rochet & Tirole, Externalities, supra note 710, at 11: "Perhaps more complex is the case of wasteful competition.

Suppose that issuers do not tacitly collude, but compete in ways that bring limited benefits to consumers.";

Page 198: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

198

issuers know that their revenues from the interchange fee hinges upon their costs (as, for

example, in Israel, where the fee is cost based). Issuers then make an effort to "waste" the

proceeds from the interchange fees.815

This concern might generally be attributed to inflating salaries, management and other costs,816

but in the payment cards sector the concern is more about futile marketing and advertising

expenses, which can be socially wasteful and a form of rent-seeking cost.817 This is true even

more definitely regarding issuers’ advertisements in a mature payment card markets.818

Abuse might take the form of futile expenditures such as wasteful marketing campaigns that do

not contribute to an increase in card usage. Frankel & Shampine give as an example, the vast

expenses of card firms on direct mail solicitation, where only a tiny percentage of customers

respond. They equate this to rent seeking costs spent in vain by a monopoly.819 Agarwal found

response rates to mail solicitation in mature payment card markets as negligible.820 Even worse,

those few who do respond to aggressive solicitations are significantly riskier customers. The

offers to which they respond to are inferior, i.e. they carry a higher interest rate on credit.821 Not

surprisingly, the risk of default among respondents to inferior mail solicitations is bigger.822

This, in turn, causes an adverse selection. Riskier cardholders respond to inferior solicitations

and default more. The interest on cards' credit increases for all cardholders. Customers with

high credit scores abandon the network. The network is compelled to increase interest rates,

because remaining cardholders are riskier. Again the customers with high credit scores

Alan Frankel, Interchange in various Countries: Commentary on Weiner and Wright, FRB Kansas 51, 52 (2005):

“[I]ssuer costs are endogenous to the level of the fees. In response to an increase in interchange fees, issuers will have

an incentive to spend more promoting their cards and enhancing their rebate programs”. 815 Supra note 544. 816 For expansion see infra ¶ 887. 817 ANTHONY J. DUKES, ADVERTISING AND COMPETITION, in ISSUES IN COMPETITION LAW AND POLICY 515 (ABA

Section of Antitrust Law, 2008). 818 DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND

BORROWING 123 (2d ed. 2005). 819 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1280, at 634: “Such competitive

responses (marketing efforts – O.B) may benefit consumers to some extent, but they can also reflect “rent-seeking”

costs symptomatic of excessive profits generated from interchange fees.”; Frankel, Interchange in various Countries:

Commentary on Weiner and Wright, supra note 814, at 56. 820 Sumit Agarwal et al., Regulating Consumer Financial Products: Evidence from Credit Cards, at 1, SSRN eLibrary

(Aug. 2014): “[I]n 2005, the response rate was 0.3%”. 821 Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet & Chunlin Liu, The Importance of Adverse Selection in the Credit Card

Market: Evidence from Randomized Trials of Credit Card Solicitations, 42 J. MONEY, CREDIT & BANK. 743, 753

(2010): “[C]onsumers who responded to the lender’s credit card solicitations exhibit significantly higher credit risk

characteristics than those who did not respond”; Lawrence M. Ausubel, Adverse Selection in the Credit Card Market

(University of Maryland Working Paper 1999). 822 Agarwal et al., id. at 753: “[C]ardholders who responded to the inferior credit card offers are significantly more

likely to default”.

Page 199: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

199

abandon, and so forth.823

In this setup there is no reason to allow the interchange fee to recruit and finance risky

cardholders (who from the outset derive low utility from cards), especially when the result is a

price increase for low-risk cardholders. In addition, switching from one card to the other due to

marketing efforts and rewards cannot be regarded as a legitimate purpose of the interchange

fee. It does not contribute to efficient card usage. On the contrary, it contributes to inefficient

card usage, as marketing efforts are funded by merchants’ money and cause price increase, from

which users of non-rewarding cards and cash payers suffer the most. Marketing efforts funded

by interchange fees cause an inversion of the usage internalization, or a “negative usage

externality”. Merchants are forced to take the expensive cards due to the eagerness of inflamed

cardholders.824

481. In addition, inflated interchange fee that is collected under the pretext of rewarding cardholders

causes a transfer of wealth from those who do not pay with rewarding cards (but nevertheless

still pay the higher prices of goods resulting from rewards) to those who enjoy the rewards.825

482. Therefore, a full pass through rate is a necessary but insufficient condition for approving the

interchange fee. Issuers should also bear the burden to show that the interchange fee was indeed

transferred to cardholders in order to encourage efficient usage of payment cards, and was not

abused in wasteful competition.826

823 Id;. see also Barry Scholnick et al., The Economics of Credit Cards, Debit Cards and ATMs: A Survey and some

New Evidence, 32 J. BANK. FIN. 1468, 1472 (2008). 824 Ann Borestam & Heiko Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, ECB Occasional Paper Series 131, at 15

(2011): “When a payment is made with a high interchange fee card, cardholders impose a negative externality on the

merchant and, hence, all other purchasers. Cardholders are tempted to use more expensive payment cards, because their

high interchange fee is often reimbursed via low cardholder fees and reward programmes. In doing so, they do not take

into account the genuine costs of the payment, which is to a large extent borne by the merchant and other shoppers.

Rather than internalising positive externalities for merchants, excessive interchange fees therefore create negative

externalities”. 825 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1280, at 658: “In the credit card market,

moreover, switching, rebating, and marketing costs may dissipate much of the fee proceeds and permit issuers to retain

profits, and significant wealth transfers to card customers from other consumers may be problematic as a matter of

public policy.";

Jean Tirole, Payment Card Regulation and the use of Economic Analysis in Antitrust, 4 TOULOUSE SCHOOL ECON., at

17 (2011): “If the profits associated with cardholders’ installed base are dissipated through wasteful advertising

expenditures to “acquire” cardholders, profits should not enter social welfare calculations.”; For expansion see supra ¶¶

351357. 826 ECJ C-382/12 P Mastercard v. European Commission, paras. 90-92 (Sept. 11, 2014); Neelie Kroes, Introductory

Remarks At Press Conference, SPEECH/07/832 (Dec. 19, 2007): “It is not sufficient that a MIF simply increases the

sales volumes of a [credit card network] scheme to the sole benefit of the member banks. Rather, a MIF should

contribute to objective efficiencies such as to promote more efficient payment means to the detriment of less efficient

ones. Also, the proceeds from a MIF should not just increase bank’s revenues—they should be clearly dedicated to the

achievement of efficiencies”. See also supra notes 222, 247.

Page 200: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

200

Part III – Regulation and Legal Analysis

8. Regulation Of Interchange Fees Around The World

483. The interchange fee is one of the restrictive arrangements with the largest financial impact in

the world.827 This has not gone unnoticed by various regulators, especially in light of complaints

from merchants, and the extremely high profit margins of the payment card industry. Thus, at

the same time payment systems have flourished, regulatory scrutiny also has increased. A

survey of the regulatory involvement in Israel and in some other countries is a useful

introduction to the next parts of this work.

8.1. Israel

484. Until 1998 there were no interchange fees in Israel for payment cards, simply because there

were no open payment card networks. Isracard was the only issuer and acquirer of MasterCard

and its proprietary brand, Isracart. Isracard is owned by Bank Hapoalim, which is one of the

two biggest banks in Israel. Leumi and Discount are the next two largest banks in Israel. CAL,

the only other payment card firm in Israel until 1998, was jointly controlled by Leumi and

Discount banks.828

Isracard and CAL issued cards, each to clients of their respective associated banks. Customers

of Leumi, Discount and their respective associated banks were issued Visa cards. Customers of

Hapoalim and its associates were issued either a local Isracart or the more lucrative global

MasterCard. Both Isracard and CAL operated as closed networks, meaning that each one was

the sole issuer (in cooperation with its associated banks) and acquirer of its cards.829

485. In 1998, AlphaCard entered the market, after receiving a license to issue and acquire Visa cards

from Visa Europe.830

In the same way described in the historical review of credit cards,831 so too happened when

Alpha entered the market. CAL and Alpha had to regularize the conditions of cross-acquiring

827 Adam J. Levitin, The Antitrust Super Bowl: America's Payment Systems, No-Surcharge Rules, and the Hidden Costs

of Credit, 3 BERKELEY BUS. L.J. 265 (2005). 828 David Gilo & Yossi Spiegel, The Credit Card Industry in Israel, 4 REV. NETWORK ECON. 266 (2005). 829Id. 830Id. 831 Supra ¶¶ 83, 84, 87.

Page 201: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

201

whenever a Visa transaction took place, in which one of them was the issuer and the other was

the acquirer. Isracard continued to operate as a closed network.

Alpha and CAL signed a mutual cross-acquiring agreement that enabled each of them to acquire

cards issued by its rival. The cross-acquiring agreement included three categories of interchange

fees. In July 1998, the General Director exempted the agreement, on condition that a

methodology for calculating the interchange fee would be presented to him.832 The parties failed

to submit such methodology despite several deadline extensions.833 Hence, in his decision of

March 8, 2001, the General Director agreed to exempt the mutual acquiring agreement, only if

the parties (by that time Alpha Card ceased operations. Its current incarnation is LeumiCard),

would seek approval of the interchange fee from the Antitrust Tribunal.834 The General Director

continued to grant exemptions to the existence of the mutual cross-acquiring arrangement

between the Visa firms, but not to the interchange fee.835

486. On September 6, 2001, LeumiCard, CAL and their controlling banks, submitted to the Antitrust

Tribunal a motion for approval of the interchange fee.836 The Antitrust Tribunal granted a

temporary ex-parte approval that was extended to an interim approval.837 Until final judgement

in 2012, the interchange fee was approved by interim permits that were extended from time to

time according to Article 13 of the Restrictive Trade Practices Law. As for the interchange fee

itself, the Tribunal ruled that the hearing would be bifurcated. First, the methodology for

calculating the interchange fee would be determined.

487. It is interesting to note that the Visa firms included in their main motion to approve the

interchange fee, a request to maintain as privileged the annex that detailed the exact rates of the

interchange fees. The Antitrust Tribunal rightly rejected the request to privilege the exact rates

of the interchange fees.838 The interchange fee is paid by merchants who are not a party to the

832Exemption with Conditions to a Restrictive Arrangement between Alpha Card and Others, Antitrust 3007229 (July 7,

1998). See also Annex B2 to AT 4630/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, (Publication 4630 in the Antitrust

Registry, Sept. 13, 2001). 833 Exemption with Conditions to Issuers and Acquirers in Visa Network, Antitrust 3009123 (May 18, 2000); Exemption

with Conditions to Issuers and Acquirers in Visa Network, Antitrust 3008373 (July 6, 2000). 834 Exemption with Conditions to a Restrictive Arrangement between Leumicard et al., Antitrust 3010373 (March 8,

2001). 835 Exemption with Conditions to a Restrictive Arrangement between CAL et. el., Antitrust 3014977 (July 22, 2002);

Exemption with Conditions to a Restrictive Arrangement between CAL et al., Antitrust 3015230 (Aug. 12, 2002);

Exemption with Conditions to a Restrictive Arrangement between CAL et al., Antitrust 3019786 (March 1, 2004);

Exemption with Conditions to a Restrictive Arrangement between CAL et al., Antitrust 5000444 (Feb. 19, 2006). 836 AT 4630/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 4630 (Sept. 13, 2001). 837 Motion 34/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director (Dec. 22, 2002). 838 Article 120 to the Motion To Approve Restrictive Arrangement in AT 4630/01 Leumi v. General Director (Registry

Publication 4630); AT 4630/01 Leumicard v. Antitrust General Director, (Removal of Privileges), Antitrust 3015470

Page 202: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

202

arrangement that determines it. Merchants cannot bargain and negotiate the rate of the

interchange fee. At the very least, this fee, which sets a floor to the MSF merchants must pay,

should be transparent to them. When the interchange fee is unknown, merchants cannot bargain

with the acquirers about the acquirer fee, which is the gap between the interchange fee and the

MSF.

There is no real justification to hide the particulars of the interchange fee, apart from the desire

of the payment card firms to hinder competition. Unfortunately in Europe, too, Visa’s

interchange fees were privileged until 2002.839 Also in the U.S., prior to 2009, merchants could

not see Visa and MasterCard rules, by which they were bound.840 However in recent years,

understanding the importance of transparency and full information to customers has caused a

change in the regulatory attitude. The interchange fee rates today are transparent and published

in Israel and around the world.841 Moreover, comparative studies are conducted on this topic.842

488. With respect to the interchange fee methodology, the position of the Visa firms was based on

what they called "the issuing deficit”. At the core of the Visa firms position was the idea that

the interchange fee should balance the deficit that is allegedly the result of subtracting the

(purportedly low) income issuers derive from cardholder fees and other issuers’ direct income

obtained from cardholders (Pc), from all of the issuing costs (Ci) – i.e., the interchange fee

should be based on Ci-Pc. The underlying assumption was that there is such a deficit (i.e.,

(Sept. 1, 2002); Antitrust, Press Release, Tribunal Refused to Privilege the Interchange Fee, Antitrust 3015423 (Sept. 3,

2002). 839 Press Release, Antitrust, Commission Exempts Multilateral Interchange Fees for Cross Border VISA Card

Payments, IP/02/1138 (July 24, 2002): "The levels of MIFs prior to these reductions cannot be revealed as they are

considered business secrets by Visa". 840 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 64, at 13 n. 25: “Merchant groups have

frequently expressed concern that merchants themselves were not permitted to view the network operating rules by

which they were bound because they were not network members... In response to these concerns, Visa and MasterCard

have recently [As of February 2009] begun to make their rules available to merchants”. 841 Interchange in Israel is published on the IAA internet site - Antitrust, Press Release, The Antitrust Tribunal Approved

the Settlement between the General Director and the Credit Card Firms, Antitrust 5001903 (March 8, 2012).

Visa interchange fees in U.S: https://usa.visa.com/content/dam/VCOM/download/merchants/visa-usa-interchange-

reimbursement-fees-2016-april.pdf . MasterCard interchange fees in U.S.: http://www.mastercard.com/us/company/en/whatwedo/interchange/Country.html Interchange fees of Visa in Europe: https://www.visaeurope.com/media/images/intra%20visa%20europe%20non-

eea_09122015-73-17767.pdf MasterCard interchange fees in Europe: http://www.mastercard.com/us/company/en/whatwedo/interchange/Intra-EEA.html

290; , at 187 note supra, Interchange Fees in various Countries: Developments and DeterminantsWright, Weiner & 842

Fumiko Hayashi, Payment Card Interchange Fees and Merchant Service Charges - an International Comparison,

supra note 166, at 6; Terri Bradford & Fumiko Hayashi, Developments in Interchange Fees in the United States and

Abroad, FRB KANSAS PAYMENTS SYS. RES. BRIEFING (2008). Jakub Górka, Payment Behaviour in Poland – The

Benefits and Costs of Cash, Cards and Other Non-Cash Payment Instruments, at 8 (table showing interchange fees in

various countries) (Jan. 2012). Fumiko Hayashi, Public Authority Involvement in Payment Card Markets: Various

Countries, August 2013 Update, PAYMENTS SYS. RESEARCH DEPARTMENT OF THE FED. RES. BANK OF KANSAS CITY.

Page 203: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

203

Ci>Pc), which the interchange fee is required to gap.843 The position of the Visa firms was that

1.8% interchange fee was required to cover that deficit. I will show below that this methodology

is, in fact, based on the model of Professor Baxter, though the firms themselves did not claim

that.844 In addition, I will claim in chapter 14, as one of my innovations, that permitting

interchange fee to cover any gap in issuers’ costs implies that if in fact there is no such gap, the

justification for interchange fee falls. But even if an “issuing deficit” does exist, under such

position interchange fee should cover it and not be used as a source of profit.

In support of their position, the Visa card firms initially attached an expert opinion by Professor

Rochet, who published, together with 2014 Nobel Prize winner, Professor Jean Tirole, some of

the most important articles in this field. Interestingly, in his academic articles (discussed

below)845 Professor Rochet has expressed a different opinion than that which he submitted to

the Antitrust Tribunal. Professor Rochet did not arrive in Israel to be cross examined, and his

expert opinion was withdrawn from the court file. The payment card firms submitted a

replacement expert opinion of Professor Fershtman.

Another interesting point was that the proposed methodology of the Visa firms in Israel ran

contrary to the consent of Visa Europe at the same time in proceedings before the European

Commission. In Israel the Visa firms opined that the interchange fee should be based on the

“issuing deficit”. In Europe Visa agreed to base the interchange fee on costs.846

489. The position of the General Director with respect to the methodology was that interchange fee

should be calculated according to three specific costs that reflect services issuers allegedly

provide to merchants (“Cost Methodology”).847 A number of retailers supported the General

Director’s position. At that time cost methodology was adopted in Australia and in Europe.848

Cost methodology is based on the premise that issuers provide specific services to merchants,

and the consideration for these services cannot be collected from cardholders. On the other

hand, merchants allegedly benefit from these services, and therefore should pay for them.849

Cost methodology excludes costs of acquirers from the interchange fee calculation. With

843 AT 4630/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, at 9, Antitrust 5000592 (Aug. 31, 2006). 844 Infra ch. 6.2. 845 Infra ch. 6.4. 846 Infra ¶ 572. 847 AT 4630/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, at 12, Antitrust 5000592 (Aug. 31, 2006). 848 Infra ¶ 572 (Europe) and Ch. 8.4 (Australia). 849 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 64, at 47: “cost-based” fees in which the

regulated value of or cap on interchange fees is computed so as to reimburse card issuers for costs that they cannot

recover from card users without a substantial increase in card user fees”.

Page 204: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

204

respect to issuers' costs, the cost-methodology includes as eligible only part of issuers’ costs

i.e., the part that is to be attributed to services issuers purportedly grant merchants.850

The position of the General Director was that the main cost of issuers, which is to be included

in the interchange fee, is the cost of Payment Guarantee. This is the cost related to issuer's

obligation to remit to the merchant, via the acquirer, transactions’ funds, even if the issuer

cannot collect the money from cardholders. The stance was that payment guarantee is the main

service issuers purportedly provide to merchants. Therefore merchants should pay for the cost

of this service.851

According to the opinion of the General Director, other services issuers purportedly provide

merchants, the costs thereof to be included in the interchange fee, were processing costs and

the cost of the free funding period.852

490. The cost of free funding is the cost associated with paying merchants before collecting from

cardholders.853 Regarding this cost, Frankel notes that its origin has an historic explanation,

which has nothing to do with services issuers purportedly provide to merchants. In the early

days of payment cards, the costs of processing transactions were relatively high and the interest

rate was relatively low. Acquirers adopted the custom of merchants, who preferred to save

themselves the trouble of calculating daily interest until the monthly payment was due. They

charged their customers once a month without interest. Interest was added only to unpaid

balance of customers who delayed payment over a month.854

850 Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 67, at 32: “Not every cost that can be linked

with an operation of a payment card should be included in the interchange fee, and should thus be borne by merchants.

There had to exist a convincing direct relationship between a given activity and the benefits that merchants receive from

it”. 851 See supra note 181. 852 AT 4630/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, at 12-15, Antitrust 5000592 (Aug. 31, 2006). 853 GAO-10-45, supra note 28, at 21: “Among the costs that issuers told us they incur in running their credit card

programs were costs related to preventing and address fraud and data breaches; write-offs for credit losses from

delinquent or defaulting cardholders; funding costs associated with paying the merchant before receiving payment

from the cardholder; paying for rewards and other cardholder benefits; and general operations, including the issuance

of cards and credit card bill statements”. 854 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 64, at 662: “The interest-free period

itself likely originated from the high costs of processing small credit transactions prior to the invention and general

adoption of computer technology. Merchants—particularly small merchants—offering credit to their customers would

have been faced with a difficult and expensive task if they sought routinely to charge interest during the period between

the purchase date and the statement date. At the same time, interest rates were usually relatively low, so it was more

sensible to wait until the statement date and then apply simple, easily computed interest (say, at 1 percent or 1.5 percent

per month) on the unpaid balance”.

Page 205: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

205

491. The OECD raised another criticism regarding the crux of the free funding cost, imposed on

merchants according to cost-based methodology. Cardholders, and not merchants, are the actual

beneficiaries of the free funding period.855 Merchants do not enjoy from the cardholders' free

funding period. On the contrary, merchants should not pay but be paid for the delay for them.

Merchants would have preferred to get paid immediately. Therefore, cardholders, and not

merchants, should pay for the cost of free funding period. This approach was adopted in the

U.S.856 and Poland.857

492. The trial in Israel was conducted for five years during which several expert testimonies were

heard. In August 2006, the Antitrust Tribunal gave its decision (“The Methodology

Decision”).858 The Antitrust Tribunal rejected the "Issuing Deficit" methodology that was

suggested by the Visa Firms, and accepted the cost-based methodology. The Tribunal

determined three costs as eligible costs, which should be included in the calculation of the

interchange fee: (a): the cost of the payment guarantee; (b) the cost of authorization of

transactions; (c) the cost of the free funding period.859

493. In September 2006, short after the delivery of the Methodology Decision, Isracard (which until

then had operated a closed system, and was not an applicant in the proceedings, which involved

only the Visa firms), and the two visa companies, signed a multilateral trio acquiring agreement,

according to which, each firm of the three could acquire any Visa or MasterCard any of them

issued (“The Trio Agreement”).860

The Trio Agreement stipulated that the interchange fee was to be decreased during its operative

period (until 2013) from 1.25% to 0.875%. The Trio Agreement also determined a gradual

reduction in each of the prevailing categories of interchange fees, until unification of the

855 OECD, POLICY ROUNDTABLE COMPETITION AND EFFICIENT USAGE OF PAYMENT CARDS, at 26 DAF/COMP 32

(2006): “The supply of credit to holders of credit cards including the first fifty or so days is fundamentally not a

payment service supplied to retailers. Rather, it is a credit service supplied by credit card issuers to credit card holders”. 856 Infra ¶ 642. 857 Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 67, at 33: “The funding of the interest-free

period was a service provided by the issuing bank to the credit card user. The TDC emphasised that there was no

evidence, neither theoretical nor empirical, that served to prove that this service led to a permanent increase in sales of

the merchant outlets, taken as a whole. The TDC also pointed out that the interest-free period, like the default

management, was closely linked to one of the most important sources of income for issuing banks, namely the high

interest rates charged for using credit cards outside the interest-free credit periods, and should therefore not be included

in the interchange fee”. 858 AT 4630/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 5000592 (Aug. 31, 2006). 859Id. para. 55 860 AT 610/06 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, (Motion to Approve a Restrictive Arrangement), Antitrust 6652

(Oct. 30, 2006)

Page 206: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

206

categories (subject to exceptions, discussed below).861 Also, as a part of the Trio Agreement,

the firms established a joint interface and routing system, operated by SHVA.

The Trio Agreement opened the market for competition on the MSF merchants paid to

MasterCard, which operated until then as a closed network, i.e., as the sole acquirer of

MasterCard. The Trio Agreement also increased the number of acquirers in the Visa network

from two to three firms. The Trio Agreement initiated competition between the three firms for

providing acquiring services to merchants, on any Visa or MasterCard each of them issued. The

Trio Agreement provided that 18 months before its expiration, an expert would be appointed to

determine the appropriate interchange fee in the post-agreement period, according to the

methodology that would prevail at that time.

494. In October 2006, Leumi Card, Isracard and CAL together submitted to the Antitrust Tribunal a

motion to approve the Trio Agreement and the interchange fee contained therein.862 The

Tribunal refused to wait with nomination of an expert until 18 months before expiration of the

Trio Agreement. In November 2007, the Tribunal held that the General Director would appoint

an expert to determine the appropriate interchange fee in accordance with the Methodology

Decision.863 In January 2008, an expert was appointed (Dr. Yossi Bachar). The expert submitted

his interim report on January 1, 2009.864

495. In implementing the Methodology Decision, the expert used the LRIC (Long Run Incremental

Cost) methodology.865 This methodology has been used already in determining termination fees

in the phone industry,866 and was used in other payment cost studies also.867 In a LRIC model,

all costs become variable, and since it is assumed that all assets are replaced in the long run,

setting charges based on LRIC allows efficient recovery of costs. According to the LRIC

methodology, the expert took account of all costs of the payment card firms, both fixed and

variable, including the cost of capital, which is a virtual cost, as long as they were fully or

861 Infra ch. 8.1.3. 862 AT 610/06 Leumi v. General Director, (Motion to Approve a Restrictive Arrangement), supra note 648. 863 AT 610/06 Leumi v. General Director (Decision to Appoint an Expert), Antitrust 5000840 (11.11.07) 864 AT 610/06 Leumi v. General Director (Interim Expert Report on Calculation of the Interchange Fee) (Jan. 1, 2009). 865Id. at 27-30. 866 Commission Recommendation on the Regulatory Treatment of Fixed and Mobile Termination Rates in the EU, O.J.

L 124/67, para. 13 (may 7, 2009): “Taking account of the particular characteristics of call termination markets, the costs

of termination services should be calculated on the basis of forward-looking long-run incremental costs (LRIC). In a

LRIC model, all costs become variable, and since it is assumed that all assets are replaced in the long run, setting

charges based on LRIC allows efficient recovery of costs. LRIC models include only those costs which are caused by

the provision of a defined increment. An incremental cost approach which allocates only efficiently incurred costs that

would not be sustained if the service included in the increment was no longer produced (i.e. avoidable costs)”. 867 European Commission, Survey on Merchants' Costs of Processing Cash and Card Payments Final Results, para. 7,

(March 2015): “[T]he longer the time horizon, the more costs become variable”. See also infra ¶ 121.

Page 207: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

207

partially qualifying costs, i.e., belonging to the cost of payment guarantee or the cost of

authorization.

With respect to the free-funding period cost, the expert determined that this cost does not exist

in Israel, as issuers in Israel do not remit transaction funds to merchants before issuers collect

those funds from cardholders.868

496. The absence of any free funding period in debit cards creates a further distortion in debit and

prepaid transactions in which issuers pay merchants 20 days (on average) after they collect the

sums due from cardholders.869 In deferred debit, assuming uniform distribution of card

purchases during the month, issuers collect transaction funds from cardholders 15 days after

the purchase (on average), so issuers pay merchants “only” 5 days (on average) after they

already collect the money. Thus, with debit and all the more so with prepaid cards, cardholders

actually grant free funding period to issuers. In Israel issuers enjoyed until April 2016 a free-

funding income from debit and prepaid cards.870 One way or the other, in Israel merchants are

certainly not funded by issuers but instead fund issuers and cardholders.

497. To determine what costs qualify for inclusion in the interchange fee, the expert divided the costs

of the payment card firms into three main groups:

497.1 Fully qualifying costs: those costs were entirely attributable to the payment

guarantee or the processing of transactions.

497.2 Fully unqualified costs: those costs were not attributable to payment guarantee or

to processing of transactions at all. Those costs include all acquiring costs and on the

issuing side, mainly marketing costs.

497.3 Partially qualifying costs: those costs are attributable in part to the payment

guarantee and processing of transactions, i.e., eligible costs, and in part to ineligible

costs. These costs were the problematic to attribute, because all three firms function

as issuers and acquirers, so some of their costs are bundled. Indeed, all countries in

which cost based methodology was adopted encountered this kind of difficulty in

separating and allocating the eligible issuing costs from the bundled joint costs of

868 AT 610/06 (Interim Expert Report), supra note 864, at 23-24. 869 IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note

21, at 25. 870 Supra ¶ 15.

Page 208: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

208

issuing and acquiring. Partially qualifying costs included overhead, staff costs,

wages, payment to banks, cost of capital, administrative expenses and more. The

expert determined coefficients to allocate those partially qualifying costs to the

interchange fee.

498. In May 2011 the expert (whose role has subsequently been filled by Dr. Shlomi Parizat, when

Dr. Yossi Bachar was nominated to be Chairman of Bank Discount) submitted a final report to

the Tribunal. The final report fully adopted and implemented the interim report of Dr. Bachar.

According to this final report, the appropriate rate of the interchange fee, as determined by the

Methodology Decision, was 0.638%. At that time, the interchange fee was 0.975% according

to the Trio Agreement. On July 2011 the Antitrust Tribunal ordered a decrease in the

interchange fee to 0.875%, effective no later than November 1, 2011.871 In September 2011, the

payment card firms filed counter-opinions according to which, the interchange fee should be

higher than 0.638%.

499. In December 2011, the Antitrust General Director reached a settlement with the three payment

card firms, according to which, the interchange fee would decrease gradually to 0.7%, effective

from July 1, 2014 until the end of 2018.872 On March 7, 2012, the Antitrust Tribunal approved

the settlement, ending more than a decade of litigation.873

Criticism Of The Cost-Based Methodology

500. The total volume of purchases with payment cards in Israel in 2015 was more than NIS 250

billion.874 The interchange fee amounts to income of more than NIS 1.75 billion for the three

payment card companies (0.7% of the volume of transactions). The total costs of the three

payment card firms for 2015 (issuing plus acquiring) amounted to NIS 3.3 billion.875 Total

issuing costs in 2015 amounted to NIS 2.576 billion.876 Deducting 15% of the three firms'

artificial payments to their controlling banks, implies that the true total issuing costs amounts

to NIS 2.1 billion, of which the interchange fee alone covered more than NIS 1.75 Billion.877

871 AT 610/06 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director (Aug. 7, 2011); Antitrust, Press Release, Credit Card Firms Will

Decrease tomorrow the Average Interchange Fee to no More than 0.875%, Antitrust 5001868 (Oct. 31, 2011). 872 Antitrust, Press Release, General Director and the Credit Card Firms Reached a Dramatic Decrease in the

Interchange Fee and Extension of the Cross Acquiring Agreement Until 2018, Antitrust 5001886 (Dec. 28, 2011). The

settlement is published at the IAA's internet site:

http://www.antitrust.gov.il/files/7925/11_12_27_הסדר_סליקה_צולבת_מתוקן.pdf 873 AT 610/06 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 500191 (March 7, 2012). 874 Supra ¶ 56. 875 Bank of Israel, Table J-11, Income Statements of the Payment Card Firms (last visited, Oct. 30, 2016). 876 Bank of Israel, Data on Payment Card Firms, Table J-13, Income Statements According to Activity Sectors for 2014. 877 MILRED, supra note 58, at 9. See also Table 5 supra ¶ 62.

Page 209: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

209

In other words, under the pretext of receiving back “only” the costs of authorization and

payment guarantee, the 0.7% interchange fee assures the payment card firms that almost all of

their total issuing costs, and more than half of their total costs (including acquiring costs), are

to be returned to them within the framework of a cartel, and without any need for competition.

Vickers warned of a scenario in which the interchange fee would be used as a pretext for

covering all costs:

More generally, having regard to the fact that credit card systems provide payment

services jointly to retailers and to cardholders, it might be thought that there is a

distortion of competition in the acquiring market arising from the interchange fee,

at least if it effectively requires acquirers to charge retailers more than their fair

share of the costs of providing the payment services. But it is not obvious what

constitutes a fair share. So a related, but perhaps rather modest, view would be that

there is certainly a distortion of competition in the acquiring market arising from

the interchange fee if it effectively requires acquirers to charge retailers more than

all the costs of providing the payment services that are provided jointly to retailers

and cardholders.878

501. Fortunately the interchange fee in Israel does not exceed all costs of payment card firms, but it

already covers a substantial part of them. The Antitrust Tribunal did not intend that interchange

fee would evade competition between payment card firms. However, when most expenses are

returned through a cartel such as the interchange fee, which originally was intended to cover

only two costs (payment guarantee and authorization), this raises doubts whether the

interchange fee is not a disguise for what Rochet & Tirole named "cozy cartel".879 Current level

of interchange fee certainly raises doubts about the legitimacy of the fee's underlying

methodology.880

502. In my view, the concern for the future is even more serious. The interchange fee is a fraction.

The eligible costs are the numerator. The total volume of transactions is the denominator. Due

to technological innovations and the continuous increase in card usage, the numerator is

expected to decrease and the denominator is expected to increase, thus, the fraction, i.e., the

interchange fee, should decrease.881 Cost-based interchange fees, which are not adjusted to the

878 John Vickers, Public Policy and the Invisible Price: Competition Law, Regulation and the Interchange Fee,

PAYMENTS SYS. RESEARCH CONFERENCE 231, 241 (2005). 879 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems 5 REV. NETWORK ECON.

1, at 10-11 (2006). For expansion see infra ¶ 871. 880 REPORT ON THE RETAIL BANKING SECTOR INQUIRY [COM(2007) 33 Final], supra note 193, at 127: "[I]t is legitimate

to question the optimality of the current level of interchange fees in several countries". 881 Infra note 316.

Page 210: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

210

decline of costs and the rise in volumes, are effectively a way to artificially inflate profits of

issuers. I hope this conclusion will be followed towards the end of the Trio Agreement in 2018.

503. Another way to look at this criticism is by examining other sources of issuers' income, i.e.,

interest and cardholder fees. A cost-based interchange fee ensures issuers a minimum income

floor, regardless of issuers' other incomes. When the "other" income is high enough, the

interchange fee automatically compels issuers to gain profit.

The implicit assumption underlying the cost-base methodology was that absent the interchange

fee, issuers would not be able to collect the eligible costs from cardholders.882 This assumption

is clearly refuted when in fact issuers are able to cover all of their costs with no need for

interchange fees, or with a need for only a fraction of the interchange fee. An empirical study

made by the European Commission in 2006 strengthens this criticism. The Commission found

that already in 2006, 62% of issuers did not need any interchange fee to cover all of their

costs.883 Since 2006 issuers' direct sources of income (especially interest) only expanded.

Interchange fee should not be used as a disguise for inflated profits under the pretext of covering

costs.884 In the last chapter of this work, I propose a development of this criticism. My proposal

is to impose profit limitations on issuers who collect interchange fees.

504. Besides criticizing the level of the interchange fee yielded by the cost methodology, there are

further practical and theoretical problems in the cost methodology, as adopted in Israel.

First, cost-based pricing has an inherent difficulty. It incentivizes issuers to inflate their

expenditures.885 Cost-based pricing that is calculated in accordance with accounting principles,

gives incentive for the controlled entity, to inflate the qualifying costs, loading them up with

overhead, and attributing costs to the qualifying components. It is not difficult to fool an outside

inspector, and make him assign to the interchange fee, artificially inflated costs that do not

honestly belong to the qualifying components. The main reason is asymmetric information. Full

information is available only to the regulated firm, which can manipulate its presentation to the

882 AT 4630/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, at 7, Antitrust 5000592 (Aug. 31, 2006). 883 Infra ¶ 463. 884 Harry Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees Generally Lead to Cash-Promoting Cross-Subsidisation, at 13 BANK

OF FINLAND RESEARCH DISCUSSION PAPERS (2011): “Issuers should not be able, according to the legislation principles

of competition, to cooperate in price setting so as to increase their profits”. 885 Alen Frankel, Interchange in various Countries: Commentary on Weiner and Wright, FRB KANSAS 51, 52 (2005):

“[I]ssuer costs are endogenous to the level of the fees. In response to an increase in interchange fees, issuers will have

an incentive to spend more promoting their cards and enhancing their rebate programs”.

Page 211: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

211

outer supervisor.886 Indeed, cost-based interchange fee has been criticized by scholars.887

Australia and the European Commission abandoned cost-based pricing.888 The Supreme Court

of Israel has also criticized, in another context, the drawbacks of cost-based pricing.889 This is

the reason why cost-based pricing is usually not acceptable, especially when offered by

collaborating competitors.890 Firms that suspect their prices are to be based on costs may

deliberately operate inefficiently or artificially inflate their costs, resulting in higher prices and

higher profits to the collaborators.891

505. Second, cost-based pricing creates a moral hazard. A similar example of moral hazard is the

"tendency for the insurance plans to encourage behavior that increases the risk of insured

loss”.892 The interchange fee, as calculated in Israel, encourages moral hazard. It compensates

issuers for, inter alia, the materialized risks arising from their payment guarantee. Issuers can

act more riskily, knowing that the interchange fee is going to compensate them anyway for the

greater risk assumed.893 This can be compared to abandoning an insured asset, and externalizing

the risk on the insurer. The "insurers" of payment cards, who pay the premium (as part of the

886 MARK ARMSTRONG & DAVID E. M. SAPPINGTON, RECENT DEVELOPMENTS IN THE THEORY OF REGULATION IN 3

HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION, 1560 (Ch. 27, Asymmetric Cost Information), at para. 2.3.1 (2007). 887Semeraro, Credit Cards Interchange Fees: Three Decades of Antitrust Uncertainty, supra note 64, at 958: “Systems

attempting to regulate price based on costs have historically been plagued with practical problems even in industries

where theory would predict that optimal prices can be set based on cost. In credit card markets, there is reason to

believe that these practical problems would be just as bad… costs are too manipulable to serve as an objective means to

regulate price. In short, a firm has little incentive to cut cost if its revenue is tied directly to cost.";

Balto, supra note 211, at 219: “Antitrust courts and enforcement agencies rarely, if ever, accept promises that price

setting will be "cost based" as a reason to permit collective price fixing…decades of unsuccessful government

regulation has demonstrated, setting price based on cost often creates the wrong incentives for the market. If price is

based on cost, there may be insufficient incentive for the venture or its members to attempt to reduce costs, because

they know at the end of the day, all the costs will be recovered.”;

Benjamin Edelman & Julian Wright, Price Coherence and Excessive Intermediation, at 33(2014): “Direct oversight of

fees presents clear problems, most notably a regulator's difficulty in determining the “right" fee, a price-setting function

that is viewed as unduly intrusive in most markets”;

Don Cruickshank, Competition in UK Banking: A Report to the Chancellor of the Exchequer U.K. Stationery Office,

sec. 3.114 (2000); AVINASH DIXIT & BARRY NALEBUFF, GAME THEORY, 380-81 (Ilan Michal trans., Aliyat Hagag

Books, Hebrew ed., 2010) (It is easy for a firm which operates under cost based pricing to inflate costs); Benjamin

Edelman & Julian Wright, Price Coherence and Excessive Intermediation, at 33(2014): “Direct oversight of fees

presents clear problems, most notably a regulator's difficulty in determining the “right" fee, a price-setting function that

is viewed as unduly intrusive in most markets”. 888 Infra ch. 8.2 (Europe) and Ch. 8.4 (Australia). 889 C.A 449/85 General Attorney v. Gad Building Company, 43(1) 183, 192 (1989) (criticizing cost plus agreements for

their incentive to inflate costs). See also the Methodology Decision, supra note 882, para. 35. 890 Balto, supra note 211, at 215: “Antitrust courts and enforcement agencies rarely, if ever, accept promises that price

setting will be "cost based" as a reason to permit collective price fixing”. 891 Alan S. Frankel, Monopoly and Competition in the Supply and Exchange of Money 66 ANTITRUST L.J. 313, 342

(1998); Carlton & Frankel, The Antitrust Economics of Credit Card Networks, supra note 97, at 652-53. 892 Allard E. Dembe & Leslie I. Boden, Moral Hazard: A Question of Morality? 3 NEW SOLUTIONS 257 (2000). 893 Duncan B. Douglass, An Examination of the Fraud Liability Shift in Consumer Card-Based Payment Systems, FRB

Chicago 43, 46 (2009): “As it currently stands, the major card networks’ zero liability policies (and even the very low

deductibles payable by cardholders under public law) leave in place a significant risk of moral hazard that almost

certainly, at least at the margins, contributes to overall systemwide fraud losses”.

Page 212: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

212

interchange fee), are the merchants, and ultimately the public. The insured parties are the

issuers, who can act recklessly in their credit offerings. Indeed issuers in Israel offer generous

credit lines. They know that proceeds from interchange fee would reimburse them for any loss.

Thus, merchants (and indirectly the public), compensate issuers for granting high credit to

cardholders.

The expert that was nominated to implement the Methodology Decision, acknowledged the

moral hazard, but argued that payment guarantee losses are fully qualifying costs, since the

payment card firms were not prepared in advance for his inspection of their costs, and therefore

did not deliberately inflate their credit lines in order to be repaid with a higher interchange

fee.894 In my view this reasoning is flawed. The interim report was based on 2007 costs. The

final report was based on 2009 costs. Thus the payment card firms had more than a year to

“prepare” their costs. The reasoning behind inclusion of actual losses in the interchange fee

does not hold. In Australia, while the cost based methodology was in force and in U.S today,

materialized fraud losses are excluded from the interchange fee.895 In my view, in Israel, credit

losses should likewise not be part of the interchange fee calculation, as issuers are already

reimbursed for this cost through the (high) interest they charge their cardholders on outstanding

credit.

506. In Israel moral hazard is a real concern. Issuers, especially non-bank issuers who have less

information than banks about the credit scoring of their cardholders, are very generous in the

unsecured credit lines they grant their cardholders, with no collateral. Banks, which are better

aware of the credit scoring of their customers, are reluctant to grant such generous credit lines

that non-bank issuers give out easily. The explanation for such risky credit is that issuers create

moral hazard and externalize the costs of default on merchants via the interchange fee.

507. Not only does the interchange fee reimburse issuers, but so does the interest from cardholders

earned on credit lines granted by issuers. Issuers get paid for the costs associated with this credit

two times: First through the interchange fee and second through the interest from cardholders.

It turns out that interchange fee double-compensates issuers. Indeed in U.S., the costs of

granting credit lines to cardholders are considered a service from issuers to their cardholders

894 AT 610/06 (Interim Expert Report), supra note 864, at 47. 895 REFORM OF CREDIT CARD SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA, FINAL REFORMS AND REGULATION IMPACT STATEMENT, at 37

(RBA, 2002): “[T]he Reserve Bank has not been persuaded that other costs of clear benefit to cardholders, such as…

the cost of credit losses, should be included in the cost-based benchmark.”; Debit Card Interchange Fees and Routing,

Final Rule, supra note 31, at 46264: “[F]raud losses, including ATM losses... are not costs incurred to prevent

fraudulent electronic debit transactions and are excluded”.

Page 213: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

213

and not to merchants. However, it should be noted that the costs which make up the core of the

payment guarantee, i.e., the actual default and fraud losses, are relatively small, and amount to

less than 0.1% (out of the 0.7% of the interchange fee in Israel).896

508. Unexpectedly, the biggest two components of the interchange fee in Israel are the cost of capital

and payments to the banks. These costs seem not to raise much attention in the literature. Quiet

as they are, they alone account for 0.4%, i.e., more than half of the interchange fee.897 In my

opinion these components should not have been included in the calculation of the interchange

fee.

The cost of capital is a virtual cost. It reflects the price of the capital that issuers must confine,

because of their open debt position to merchants. This cost imitates a virtual loss of interest (for

shareholders of issuers) on the confined capital. First, the cost of capital is only a theoretical

component and not an actual direct cost. The Methodology Decision specifically called for

counting only direct costs in the interchange fee calculation. Second, this cost is derived from

the credit function to cardholders. Merchants do not have benefit from the cost of capital that

is needed to guarantee credit given to cardholders. The cardholders are the direct beneficiaries

of this credit. The cost of capital is not a direct cost that issuers incur for the benefit of

merchants, as required for inclusion by the Methodology Decision.

509. In my view, "payments to banks" should also not be included in the calculation of the

interchange fee. Most payment cards are issued with the cooperation of the bank in which the

cardholder has an account. Banks grant their customers unsecured credit lines (overdraft).

Customers can use their credit lines in various ways. Customers can withdraw cash, write

checks or use their payment cards up to the limit of the credit line. The payment guarantee does

not add any significant risk beyond that which the bank incurs anyway. The credit function of

payment cards is one possible unsecured channel of credit line banks give their customers.898

Banks already bear the risks of clients that default. The fact that a cardholder choses to use the

credit line via a payment card, does not increase the risk of default to the bank more than if the

cardholder would have used the credit line by cash withdrawals or any other way.899

896 AT 610/06 (Final Report by Dr. Parizat); Fumiko Hayashi, Payment Card Interchange Fees and Merchant Service

Charges - an International Comparison, supra note 166, at 19-21. 897 AT 610/06 Leumi V. Antitrust General Director (Expert Opinion of Dr. Shlomi Parizat on the Calculation of the

Interchange Fee - Final Report) at 28, 35 (May 23, 2011). 898 For comparison, in U.S., payment guarantee is considered a service to cardholders and not to merchants, see ¶ 642. 899 Wilko Bolt et al., Consumer Credit and Payment Cards, at 28 (ECB Working Paper 1387, 2011).

Page 214: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

214

510. Another criticism of the cost-based methodology is from a theoretical point of view. Cost-based

methodology is not founded on any economic model. There is a consensus in literature that

cost-based interchange fees cannot yield optimal outcome.900 Interchange fee is a balancing

mechanism and not a payment for service that bears a “price tag”.901 From a theoretical point

of view, the services that are purportedly paid for through the interchange fee are not given only

to merchants. They are given to all “customers” of payment cards as a whole, cardholders and

merchants. The processing and the authorization of transactions are not being made only for the

benefit of merchants. Cardholders also enjoy from these services. As explained above,

cardholders also enjoy from the payment guarantee and the free funding period.902

The cost-based methodology wrongly assumes a vertical structure of a production chain in

which issuers are at the top, acquirers are downstream and thereafter merchants and

cardholders.903 This approach ignores the fact that consumers, and not only merchants, are also

customers of issuers for card services. Therefore, allocation of costs to the issuing (or acquiring)

900 Evans & Schmalensee, The Economics of Interchange Fees and their Regulation, supra note 165, at 102: “"A robust

conclusion of the economic literature on interchange fees and two-sided markets is that cost-based interchange fees are

generally not socially optimal… There is no basis in economic theory or fact for cost-based regulation of interchange

fees such as the regime adopted in Australia or by the European Commission.”;

Semeraro, Credit Cards Interchange Fees: Three Decades of Antitrust Uncertainty, supra note 64, at 959: “Economists

have shown that, except by happenstance, the optimal interchange fee will be neither zero nor determinable by any

strictly cost-based measure.”;

Emilio Calvano, Note on the Economic Theory of Interchange (Feb. 22, 2011) : "[T]here is no economic basis for cost-

based regulation. That is, there is no reason to believe that cost-based regulation would improve social welfare relative

to market-set interchange fees.";

Julian Wright, Why Payment Card Fees are Biased Against Retailers, 43 RAND J. ECON. 761, 775 (2012): “There is

near unanimity among economists that setting interchange fees based on the costs faced by issuers, as has happened in

Australia (for credit cards) and in the United States (for debit cards) has no good theoretical basis.”;

Marc Rysman & Julian Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, at 34 (2015): “The problem with this approach is it

is not supported by any economic theory. None of the existing models that work out optimal interchange fees (either

those maximizing welfare or consumer surplus) imply interchange fees based on issuers' costs will be optimal, or will

indeed increase welfare relative to unregulated fees. This is the consensus reached in surveys of the literature”;

Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 64, at 48 (2009): "More importantly, the

economic theory underlying the efficient interchange fee provides no rationale for either a strictly cost-based

interchange fee".

Joshua S. Gans & Stephen P. King, Approaches to Regulating Interchange Fees in Payment Systems, 2 REV. NETWORK

ECON. 125 (2003); Julian Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees in Payment Systems, 52 J. INDUS.

ECON. 1 (2004); 901 See ch. 7.3 (interchange fee as a mechanism to internalize network externality). 902 Supra ¶¶ 491, 507, 508, 681. 903 Jean Charles Rochet, The Interchange Fee Mysteries, Commentary on Evans and Schmalensee, Payments System

Research Conferences 139, 142 (2005): “Interchange fees should be based on some fraction of the issuer’s cost...

this view is based on a wrong “vertical” model where only the merchant benefits from the payment service”. Éva Keszy-Harmath et al., The Role of the Interchange Fee in Card Payment Systems, at 19 (MNB Occasional papers

96. 2012): “As pointed out by Rochet and Tirole, the cost based method implicitly assumes a vertical structure in which

issuer banks provide a type of intermediary service to acquirer banks, and the acquirer banks provide an end service to

merchants. In this structure, the interchange fee is a fee paid for a service. Rochet and Tirole argue that the vertical

approach, however, is faulty, as it neglects cardholders as consumers of the card service, that is, that the card market is a

two-sided market with network externalities on which the two types of consumer demand need to be balanced. Thus,

the interchange fee not only affects the marginal cost of merchants, but also cardholders and card use".

Page 215: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

215

side only, is wrong, because costs are in fact shared by the two sides.904

For example, if the cost of printing a newspaper increases, then the cost increases for both

readers and advertisers. It would seem artificial to allocate this cost increase only to one side.

In the same manner, the salary of the CEO and the CFO of a payment card firm is common to

the issuing and acquiring side. It is artificial to allocate joint costs or even part of them, to one

of the sides.905

511. For completeness, it must be noted that there is an answer to the last criticism. The fact that

some costs are common to the two sides, and cannot be specifically allocated, does not mean

that it is not possible to estimate a reasonable allocation to each side. One way to allocate

common costs is by attaching coefficients to the common costs. For instance, one can think of

allocating the cost of printing a newspaper between advertisers and readers according to the

ratio between the costs of ink used for articles and the ink used for advertisements, or the ratio

between content area and advertisement area in the newspaper. The cost of the CEO can be

allocated by the ratio of time she dedicates to issuing activities compared to the time dedicated

to the acquiring activities. Overhead and indirect costs can be allocated according to number of

employers.906 Most of the work of the expert in Israel was to allocate eligible parts of common

costs to the interchange fee. The expert used coefficients to allocate the eligible part of common

costs.907

Regulation of Isracard

512. A major disadvantage of regulating payment cards via interchange fees is that closed networks

that do not have interchange fees, are excluded from the regulation.

513. Isracard (the company) is the sole owner of a local payment card, Isracart. Until 2012, Isracard

was the sole issuer and acquirer of Isracart. The market share of Isracart (the local card) was

904 Steven Semeraro, The Antitrust Economics (and Law) of Surcharging Credit Card Transactions, 14 STAN. J. L. BUS.

& FIN. 343, 355 n. 58 (2009): “Although total costs are relevant, they cannot be neatly segregated between cardholders

and merchants. Most costs are jointly caused and the benefits produced largely overlap between the two customer

groups”. 905 David S. Evans, The Antitrust Economics of Multi-Sided Markets, 20 YALE J. ON REG. 325, 345 (2003): “It is well

recognized by economists that in multi-product businesses the allocation of joint costs to a particular product is arbitrary

and that there is no economic rationale behind any proposed formula for doing so... Price-marginal cost relationships for

one side do not have any economic meaning either”. 906 Górka, Payment Behaviour in Poland, supra note 842, at 20: “Direct costs and revenues are allocated using

transactional cost drivers (the number and value of payment transactions and data about overnight deposits). It is more

difficult to distribute indirect costs between particular payment instruments”. 907 AT 610/06 (Interim Expert Report), supra note 864, at 35.

Page 216: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

216

less than 20% of all payment cards. Nevertheless as sole acquirer and issuer of Isracart cards,

Isracard had a monopoly of 100% market share in acquiring and issuing Isracart payment cards.

514. In 2005, the General Director used his authority to declare Isracard to be a monopoly in

acquiring Isracart cards. The General Director emphasized that the basis of the declaration was

that merchants could not refuse to accept Isracart cards, as other cards are no substitute when a

customer wants to pay with Isracart.908

American Express and Diners Club also operate in Israel as closed networks. Diners Club is a

closed network operated by CAL. American Express is a closed network operated by Isracard.

However, the market share of each of them is less than 5%. Merchants find it easier to reject

them than to refuse more popular card such as Isracart. In addition American Express and

Diners are often a second card whereas Isracart was often the only card of the cardholder, a

phenomenon called singlehoming.909 Therefore, American Express and Diners Card did not

present same concerns as Isracart, which was perceived as a "must take" card.910

However, no operative measures were taken against Isracard following the declaration. A

consent decree under Section 50 of the Antitrust Law was withdrawn by the General Director.911

515. The Trio Agreement from 2006 applied to Visa and MasterCard brands only. It did not apply

to Isracart, American Express and Diners Club. Issuing and acquiring Isracart continued to be

performed exclusively by Isracard, as a closed network. The Trio Agreement, however, limited

the autonomy of Isracard to charge any MSF for its Isracart brand. It determined that under

certain conditions Isracard must compare the MSF of Isracart to the MSF it charged for the

open MasterCard brand.912 No similar limitations were imposed on Diners Club or American

Express.

516. In August 2011, the Banking Law (Licensing) (Amendment No. 18), was enacted. This

amendment defines an issuer with a market share of 10% or more, as a "large-scale issuer". The

amendment applies to Isracart cards but not to American Express and Diners, because their

908 Declaration on Isracard as Monopoly in Acquiring Isracart and MasterCard, Antitrust 5000034 (May 22, 2005). 909 For expansion see ¶ 285 and ch. 6.6.2. 910 See ch. 6.4, especially ¶¶ 202-203. 911 AT 7011/02 Antitrust General Director v. Bank Hapoalim, Antitrust 5000874 (Aug. 14, 2006). 912 Article 2 of the Trio Agreement, in AT 610/06 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, (Motion to Approve a Restrictive

Arrangement), Antitrust 6652 (Oct. 30, 2006).

Page 217: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

217

market share is lower. The amendment provides that a "large-scale issuer" shall not

unreasonably refuse to contract with an acquirer for the purpose of cross-acquiring.913

517. In January 2012 the Banking Commissioner announced that Isracard, Leumi Card and CAL are

all large scale issuers.914 Isracard had to open its proprietary Isracart network to other acquirers.

Isracard demanded from LeumiCard and CAL royalties and additional fees on top of the

interchange fee, as a condition for permitting them to acquire Isracart brand cards. The General

Director temporarily exempted these fees,915 but after further inspection, allowed only a one-

time fixed license payment and an additional payment based on a percentage of Isracart

acquiring turnover, which was smaller than the payment that Isracard had demanded.916

Isracard did not accept the decision and submitted a motion to the Antitrust Tribunal, to approve

the additional fees. In March 2014 the Tribunal rejected Isracard’s motion.917 The Tribunal

based its ruling on several reasons: (a) the concern that additional fees may raise the floor of

the MSF to a higher level ("interchange fee plus the additional fees"), because acquirers would

align the MSF upwards, according to the highest interchange fee; (b) the concern that the

additional fees would raise Isracard’s rivals costs; (c) the concern that the additional payments

would act as entry barriers to new acquirers; and (d) the conclusion that the services Isracard

purportedly supplies for the additional fees are actually already included in the interchange fee.

518. In my opinion, the ruling of the Antitrust Tribunal is not only correct, but applying its logic,

should have even extend it to ban all additional fees Isracard demanded above the interchange

fee. First, the Tribunal’s reasoning about increasing the floor to the MSF and raising rivals’

costs applies equally to prohibiting any payments above the interchange fee, i.e., this reasoning

applies also to both the fixed payment and the percentage of turnover payment that Isracard is

allowed to collect.

Second, the Antitrust General Director found that the services of Isracard to its acquirers, as a

brand owner, were worth less than those of Visa and MasterCard. So under cost-based

methodology like the one applied in Israel, acquiring Isracard brand cards should be cheaper,

913 Article 36(13)(b) of the Banking Law (Licensing) 1981. 914 Directives of the Banks' Supervisor - Notice on Issuers with Large Scale of Activity (Dec. 20, 2011) available at

http://www.boi.org.il/he/NewsAndPublications/PressReleases/Pages/111220h.aspx . Directives of the Banks'

Supervisor - Notice on Issuers with Large Scale of Activity (Dec. 20, 2011) http://www.boi.org.il/he/NewsAndPublications/PressReleases/Pages/111220h.aspx 915 Exemption to Isracard, Leumicard and CAL, Antitrust 5001952 (May 14, 2012); Exemption to Isracard, Leumicard

and CAL, Antitrust, Antitrust 500207 (Aug. 8, 2012). 916 Exemption to Isracard, Leumicard and CAL, Antitrust 500226 (Sept. 13, 2012); IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF

EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note 21, at 11. 917 AT 11333-02-13 Isracard v. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 500647 (Mar. 9, 2014).

Page 218: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

218

and not more expensive than acquiring Visa or MasterCard cards.

Third, and perhaps most important, the entire purpose of the interchange fee is to be a

comprehensive payment from acquirer to issuer. Any additional payment that Isracard

demanded should have been part of the interchange fee, or not an eligible cost at all. In this

context, Article 5 of the European Regulation 2015/751 on Interchange Fees from May 2015

prohibits any circumvention of the interchange fee no matter how the parties design it.918

Applying this rule would have resulted in tossing all fees Isracard demanded which were on top

of the interchange fee.

519. Fourth, as the Tribunal noted, acquirers usually charge merchants one MSF for all cards, even

if some cards carry a larger MSF. This unification is called “blending”. Even if acquirers do not

blend, merchants do tend to blend. Merchants tend not to charge different prices to customers

who pay with a slightly more expensive payment instrument. I dedicated a chapter of this work

to explain this phenomenon.919

Blending prevents customers from internalizing that some cards are more expensive than others.

Blending leads to unification of prices for customers who pay with expensive and cheap

payment instruments. Blending leads to perversive cross-subsidization of expensive payment

cards by cheaper cards. Thus, under the logical assumption that merchants would not have

surcharged customers who pay with the more expensive (to merchants) Isracart, the effect of

the additional charges Isracard demanded, would have been (1) cross subsidy of Isracart by

other cards; (2) a small increase in goods' prices sold by merchants which accept Isracart. All

customers would have suffered from this increase, and not only those who pay with Isracart

cards. The Tribunal rightly rejected the demand of Isracard which is similar to imposing an

"Isracart Tax".920

918 EU Regulation 2015/751 on Interchange Fees for Card-Based Payment Transactions, O.J L 123/1, Article 5

(19.5.15): "Prohibition of circumvention… any agreed remuneration, including net compensation, with an equivalent

object or effect of the interchange fee, received by an issuer from the payment card scheme, acquirer or any other

intermediary in relation to payment transactions or related activities shall be treated as part of the interchange fee". See

also EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees, supra note 200, at 28: “[A]ny net compensation received by

an issuing bank from a payment card scheme in relation to payment transactions or related activities shall be treated as

part of the interchange fee”. See also id. at 23. 919 See ch. 11. 920 For expansion on the interchange fee as transaction tax see ¶¶ 224, 383, 695, 715, 783, 830.

Page 219: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

219

520. In June 2012, in accordance with the Trio Agreement, and after Isracard was no longer the sole

acquirer of its proprietary Isracart brand, the General Director repealed the monopoly

declaration on Isracard.921

Categories Of Interchange Fees

521. Merchants are heterogeneous in the benefit they derive from cards. Some merchants are more

willing to accept cards than others. Card networks can therefore use their market power to price-

discriminate between merchants, according to the merchants’ varying willingness to pay.922

522. Categories of interchange fees can be set according to types of cards (premium cards may bear

higher interchange fees), types of transaction (credit interchange fee is higher than debit, with

Israel as a twisted exception until April 2016), and types of merchants (e.g., supermarket,

groceries or gas stations).923

523. Historically, payment cards firms divided merchants into categories of different interchange

fees, based on sectors of activities, types of cards and size of merchants. These categories

enabled the card networks to price discriminate and extract surplus from merchants with higher

demand for cards, without losing merchants with lower demand.

524. The Methodology Decision determined that subject to two exceptions, there should be no

interchange fee categories. The Tribunal noted that categories are equivalent to price

discrimination, which can impede competition if two competing merchants pay different

interchange fees.924

921 Annulment of Declaration on Isracart as a Monopoly, Antitrust 4538 (Jul. 3, 2012). 922 Rochet & Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems, supra note 879, at 7: “Card payment

systems, whether proprietary or not-for-profit, to some extent try to account for this heterogeneity and offer lower

interchange fees/merchant discounts to certain classes of merchants. Such price discrimination however is necessarily

limited. Merchants with more limited convenience benefits from cards have a relative preference for lower interchange

fees (a lower volume of card transactions) compared to those with higher convenience benefits. The former may

therefore object to an interchange fee policy that in part reflects the average merchant’s concerns”. 923 Robin A. Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks: Economics, Industry Developments, and

Policy Issues, at 25 (F.R.B. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 23-09, 2009): “For many years, the interchange

fee for an individual card transaction at a given merchant has varied with transaction type (credit, signature debit, or

PIN debit) and purchase value. Interchange fees also vary across merchants according to merchant type (e.g.,

supermarket or gas station) and merchant sales volume, and the number of distinct merchant types listed in interchange

fee schedules continues to proliferate. Recently, Visa and MasterCard have introduced interchange fees that vary across

card programs, even for a given merchant type and sales volume”. 924 AT 4630/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, para. 48 (Aug. 31, 2006).

Page 220: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

220

Nevertheless, the Tribunal accepted the position of the Antitrust General Director, and allowed

categories of interchange fees under two exceptions:

524.1 Merchants, who allegedly do not benefit from the payment guarantee, should pay a

lower interchange fee.

524.2 Transactions in which the payment-guarantee is significantly different than that of

the unified category should have a different interchange fee. Lower interchange fee

should prevail in transactions in which the payment guarantee is significantly low,

and a higher interchange fee for transactions in which the payment guarantee is

significantly high.925

525. The Trio Agreement determined that effective July 1, 2010, the categories were to be unified,

except for merchants or transactions that qualify for a different interchange fee according to the

Methodology Decision.926

526. Worldwide there are different approaches towards categories, even within the same country.

The U.S. credit card market presents various interchange fee categories.927 MasterCard’s top

tier of interchange fee for its “world elite” cards is over 3.25%.928 As a rule of thumb, cards that

carry rewards are in a category of higher interchange fees.929 In Australia, the average

interchange fee is regulated but categories are allowed as long as the average does not exceed

the regulated fee. In the U.S., since Durbin Amendment, all debit card interchange fees of

regulated institutions are subject to the same cap. Categories are theoretically allowed but in

practice regulated institutions align the fee to the cap.930 The Durbin Amendment does not apply

925Id. Para. 53. 926 Annex A to the Trio Agreement, Antitrust 6652 (Oct. 30, 2006). 927 United States v. Am. Express Co., 2015 U.S. Dist. Lexis 20114, at 31 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015): “[T]he interchange

rate charged on the Visa and MasterCard network varies along two axes: (1) the industry the merchant belongs to, and

(2) the actual card product used by the cardholder. MasterCard, for example, has more than 240 different interchange

rate categories, and Visa has more than 70 categories.”; Rong Ding & Julian Wright, Payment Card Interchange Fees

and Price Discrimination, at 2 (2015): “MasterCard, for instance, had 36 different interchange fee categories in 2014

for consumer credit cards transactions in the U.S. reflecting different types of merchants such as Airlines, Insurance,

Lodging and Auto-rental, Petroleum Base, Public Sector, Real-Estate, Restaurants, Supermarkets, and Utilities”. 928 MasterCard 2015–2016 U.S. Region Interchange Programs and Rates (last visit Oct. 30, 2016) http://www.mastercard.com/us/merchant/pdf/Merchant_Rates_April_2014.pdf 929 Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? the Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L. REV. 1321, 1323

(2008): “Credit cards with rewards programs cost more for merchants to accept than cards without rewards”. Prager et

al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 923, at 26: “[I]nterchange fees associated with Visa’s

and MasterCard’s premium rewards cards are markedly higher than the interchange fees associated with their basic

credit cards”. 930 Rong Ding & Julian Wright, Payment Card Interchange Fees and Price Discrimination, at 5 (2015): “[I]n Australia,

policymakers have allowed platforms to set different credit card interchange fees subject to a cap on the average

interchange fee. In contrast, in the U.S., policymakers have required debit card interchange fees in all categories to be

subject to the same cap, thereby effectively ruling out discriminatory interchange fees”.

Page 221: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

221

to issuers with turnover of less than $ 10 billion. As a result, in the United States there are two

tiers of interchange fees: one regulated, and one for exempted issuers, which is, not surprisingly,

higher.931 The European Interchange Fee Regulation from 2015 (Regulation 2015/751), allows

categories of interchange fees for debit transactions, as long as the average interchange fee is

kept on 0.2%, but forbids categories for credit transactions (which are capped at 0.3%).932

527. Getting back to Israel, the experts (Dr. Bachar followed by Dr. Parizat), who were nominated

to implement the Methodology Decision, specifically had to address the issue of categories.

Transaction Categories

528. With respect to transactions, the experts identified three kinds of transactions as candidates for

a different category of interchange fee: (a) non-paper transactions, in which the payment

guarantee is lower, because it does not cover fraud; (b) multiple payments transactions, in which

the payment guarantee is higher, because the issuer guarantees default risks of the cardholder

for as long as payments continue; (c) transactions acquired in smart POSs in which the payment

guarantee is theoretically lower because of better identification. Ultimately, only payments

transactions received a 0.05% higher interchange fee.933

529. It is interesting to note that the most obvious category of transactions in which the payment

guarantee is lower - debit and prepaid transactions, was not even considered as candidate for

lower interchange fee. The distortion is noticeable because the difference in payment guarantee

is more than 100% lower and not just 0.05% lower. Debit transactions evidently passed under

the radar of the experts and the IAA. The reasons for this ignorance would probably be clarified

in a pending class-action, the undersigned is involved with, claiming, inter alia that debit and

prepaid interchange fees in Israel should have been lower than that of credit, specifically in

light of the Methodology Decision.934

530. With respect to non-paper transactions, such as internet or telephone transactions, effective July

1, 2012 the interchange fee in these transactions is the same as in documented transactions.935

931 Sandwith, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform, supra note 237, at 234-35, 240-41; Fumiko Hayashi, The New Debit

Card Regulations: Initial Effects on Networks and Banks, 4 FRB KANSAS CITY ECON' REV 79, 107 (2012): “Most card

networks have set two separate interchange fee schedules: one for regulated banks, conforming to the new caps on

interchange fees for those banks, and a separate one for exempt banks.”; Fumiko Hayashi, The New Debit Card

Regulations: Effects on Merchants, Consumers, and Payments System Efficiency, 1 FRB Kansas Q. REV. 89, 92 (2013). 932 Infra ¶ 584. 933 AT 610/06 (Interim Expert Report), supra note 864, at 67; AT 610/06 (Expert Opinion, Final Report), supra note

897, at 37. 934 Infra ¶ 553. 935 AT 610/06 Leumi V. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 500191 (Mar. 7, 2012).

Page 222: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

222

Until July 1, 2012 the interchange fee in those transactions was 0.15% higher.936 The payment

card firms claimed that higher fee is required because non-paper transactions are riskier. This

argument was flawed. According to the network rules, payment guarantee in non-paper

transactions is lower than in ordinary transactions, especially with regard to fraud.937 In U.S.

the court recognized this flaw as early as 2001.938 Unfortunately it took until 2012 for Israel to

recognize and correct this distortion.939

Merchant categories

531. As for categories of merchants who allegedly do not benefit from the payment guarantee, the

experts identified the state and its agencies as candidates to remain in a lower category of

0.5%.940

532. The payment card firms claimed that the Israel Electric Company (“IEC”) should also belong

to the category of lower interchange fees. The Antitrust Authority did not support this stance,

but was forced by the Antitrust Tribunal to accept the firms' position. As of July 2010, merchant

categories have been unified, except for the state, its agencies and the IEC.941

533. In my view, there should be no categories of merchant interchange fees. The fact that the

Methodology Decision determined “cost-based” interchange fee negates merchant categories

that are “benefit-based”, as this is contrary to the methodology. This conclusion should be

emphasized:

534. First, payment guarantee is same for all merchants. When a cardholder defaults, the payment

guarantee of the card's issuer covers all merchants at which the cardholders purchased.942

Therefore the state and the IEC should not be treated differently than any other merchant.

535. Second, the main goal of antitrust law is to maximize consumer welfare.943 Under this standard,

price discrimination is inferior to a competitive (cost based) pricing. In comparison to

936 AT 610/06 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director ¶ 17 (Aug. 7, 2011). 937 AT 610/06 (Expert Opinion, Final Report), supra note 897, at 38. 938 United States v. Visa U.S.A., 163 F. Supp. 2d 322, 341 (S.D.N.Y 2001): "Defendants rationalize this difference by

pointing to increased fraud in these merchant categories, but this explanation is belied by the fact that the Internet

merchant, not Visa/MasterCard or their member banks, bears virtually all the risk of loss from fraudulent transactions". 939 AT 610/06 Leumi V. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 500191, para. 9 (Mar. 7, 2012); AT 601/06 Isracard v.

Antitrust General Director (Jul. 18, 2010). 940 AT 610/06 (Interim Expert Report), supra note 864, at 67. 941 AT 601/06 Isracard v. Antitrust General Director (July 18, 2010). 942 AT 610/06 (Expert Opinion, Final Report), supra note 897, at 37. 943 FTC, Press Release, Principles regarding Enforcement of FTC Act as a Competition Statute (Aug. 13, 2015): “The

promotion of consumer welfare is a cornerstone of the FTC’s antitrust enforcement”;

Page 223: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

223

competitive outcome, price discrimination (i.e., categories) always reduces consumer-welfare.

The Tribunal held that an interchange fee which is based on direct costs, will lead to a

competitive result.944 By definition, competitive pricing and price discrimination cannot

coexist. The Former requires a uniform price that is equal to the marginal cost of production

(P=MC). The latter involves pricing above costs, and reducing consumer-welfare in comparison

to competitive pricing. Thus, under the antitrust standard for maximizing welfare, categories

should not have been allowed.

This criticism can have another angle. If the benefit from a product or a service is less than its

cost, it is efficient that the consumer will not buy the product or the service and there will be no

transaction. If, for example, the payment guarantee costs 0.7% of the transaction, then it is

efficient not to set an interchange fee for the state and the IEC at 0.5% (the level of the low

category). The approach of the Tribunal means that, absurdly, the state, its agencies and the

IEC receive a payment guarantee service that costs 0.7%, but pay only 0.5% for it. It is all the

more absurd because the 0.7% interchange fee in Israel is an average fee, so other merchants

could end up paying a little more, because the state and the IEC pay a little less. Merchants in

Israel actually subsidize the cost of the payment guarantee to the state, its agencies and the IEC.

This is unreasonable paternalism.

536. Third, the payment card firms tried to justify the categories by invoking the Ramsey Principle,

according to which, under certain conditions, price discrimination, (i.e. categories), may

BARAK ORBACH, THE GOALS OF ANTITRUST LAW IN PRACTICE, IN LEGAL AND ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST

LAW 63, 97 (Michal Gal & Menachem Perlman eds., 2008) (claiming competition enhances first and foremost

consumers, and citing Herbert Hovenkamp: “After thirty years, the debate over antitrust ideology has quieted. Most

now agree that the protection of consumer welfare should be the only goal of antitrust laws”);

COMPACT v. Metropolitan Government of Nashville & Davidson County, 594 F. Supp. 1567, 1572 (M.D. Tenn. 1984):

“[W]hile judicial pronouncements during the last fifty years have varied on the central policy intended by Congress in

its enactment of the Sherman Act, the current concensus among both courts and commentators embraces consumer

welfare as the objective served by enforcement of the antitrust laws.”;

Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 67, at 35: “The concept of consumers has been

further developed in the Commission’s Guidelines... where it is stated that the concept of consumers should encompass

all direct or indirect users of the product covered by the agreement, including producers that use the products as an

input, wholesalers, retailers and final consumers”;

OECD, POLICY ROUNDTABLE, EXCESSIVE PRICES, at 24 DAF/COMP(2011)18: “The concept of consumer harm has

been identified as the “intellectual cornerstone of competition policy”

See also Cr.A 4855/02 Borowitz v. State of Israel, 59 (6) 776, 861 (2005); SCL 4465/98 Tivol v. Shef Hayam, 56(1) 56,

80 (2001); HCJ 588/84 K.S.R Asbestos v. Chairman of Antitrust Council, 40(1) 29, 37 (1986); A.T 36014-12-10 Kaniel

v. IAA, para. 10 (June 10, 2012); Cf. Jean Charles Rochet, Competing Payment Systems: Key Insights from the

Academic Literature, at 7 (Paper Prepared for the Payments System Review Conference) (2007): “Farrell (2006) argues

that the target for a Competition Authority (as opposed to a regulator like the RBA) should be consumer surplus and not

social welfare.” 944 The Methodology Decision, AT 4630/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, para. 33 (Aug. 31, 2006).

Page 224: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

224

promote efficiency.945 They argued that interchange fee should reflect merchants' elasticity of

demand. i.e., merchants with rigid elasticity should pay more. The Tribunal rejected this

argument, but simultaneously accepted it for merchants who allegedly do not benefit from the

payment guarantee.946 It is not logical to accept and reject the same principle.947

Price discrimination might sometimes be efficient, but not in payment cards. Charging high

interchange fees from merchants with rigid demand is just another way for networks to use their

market power and exploit those merchants.948

Ramsey pricing argument was also rejected by the European Commission in the European

MasterCard Decision. There was no evidence in that case that issuers could not cover their fixed

costs without resorting to price discrimination. The mere fact that the interchange fee was used

to enhance card adoption and usage among cardholders was not accepted as a reason for

categories of interchange fees.949

537. Fourth, categories can be performed on the acquiring side via the MSF. The MSF is an overt

price. It is relatively easy for merchants to compare between different MSFs offered to them.

Discrimination in the interchange fee is more difficult to detect. Even if detected, it is

impossible for a merchant to dispute over it.950 If price discrimination is efficient it should be

in the revealed and transparent MSF, and not latent.

538. Fifth, merchants accept payment cards. They do not explicitly accept payment guarantee,

because there is no such product. Even assuming that the interchange fee should be based on

benefit, then such benefit should be with respect to the product as a whole, which is a payment

card. Benefits merchants gain from payment cards cannot be attributed only to the function of

payment guarantee, as a differentiated component. Benefit from payment guarantee cannot be

measured in isolation. It is part of a complete product, named a payment card.

945Id. para 53; See also Frank Ramsey, A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation, ECON. J. (1927); Hans Zenger,

Differentiated Interchange Fees, 115 Econ. Letters 276 (2012). 946 The Methodology Decision, AT 4630/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, para. 33 (Aug. 31, 2006). 947 See, in another context, the minority opinion (not in this issue) of Additional Civil Appeal 6811/04 Menahel Mas

Shevach v. Shadmi (Manager of real estate Tax v. Shadmi), 63(1) 778, 819 (2009). 948 Alan Frankel, Interchange in various Countries: Commentary on Weiner and Wright, FRB KANSAS 51, 58 (2005).

But see also Rong Ding & Julian Wright, Payment Card Interchange Fees and Price Discrimination (2015). 949 Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 44. 950 Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L. REV. 1321, 1333

(2008): “Because the interchange fee is an arrangement between the acquirer and the issuer, merchants cannot negotiate

the interchange rate”.

Page 225: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

225

Even assuming types of merchants who do not derive benefits from payment guarantee, e.g.,

because their customers never default, they may well have high benefits from payment cards as

a whole. Accepting cards might save them labor, collection array and costs of handling cash.

Thus, these merchants, whose very existence is doubtful, should not be in a lower category.

539. Sixth, if low benefit from the payment guarantee is the criterion for belonging to a category of

low interchange fee, other merchants should be classified in the lower category. Universities,

for example, do not benefit from the payment guarantee. A student who does not pay tuition

will not be permitted to take exams, and will not receive a graduation certification. If a

university would not accept payment cards, it is unlikely that its revenues would decrease.

Students would probably not go to another academy, because the university they desire does

not accept cards. It follows that if benefit from the payment guarantee is the criterion for a low

interchange fee, other merchants, of which universities are just an example, should also be

added.

Moreover, universities may well derive substantial benefits from payment cards, as a product.

Cards are convenient, easy to accept by phone or on-line, and they save alternative costs of

other payment instruments.951 Universities are just an example. In 2010, Bezeq, the Israeli

monopoly in immobile telephones, filed a civil suit for a declaratory order that it should be

included in the lower category, because of the purported claim that it does not benefit from

payment guarantee. This suit was later withdrawn by Bezeq.

540. Seventh, ironically, there is a strong basis to believe that the state, in fact, is the entity which

benefits the most from payment cards. Payment cards, especially debit cards, are a substitute

for cash.952 Studies estimate that replacing paper money with cards can save the state up to 1%

of GDP.953 Switching to electronic money also supports fight against black economy.954 Thus

the state should subsidize cards, and not be subsidized by them.

541. Eighth, the state, its agencies and the IEC are powerful merchants. They have strong buying

power over the payment card firms. They are responsible for a substantial share of the payment

card transaction volume. Without price discrimination in the form of categories, all merchants

951 For expansion see infra ch. 0 (Costs and Benefits of Payment Instruments). 952 IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note

21, at 13; Carlos Arango, Kim P. Huynh & Leonard Sabetti, Consumer Payment Choice: Merchant Card Acceptance

Versus Pricing Incentives, 55 J. BANK. FIN. 130, 138 (2015): “Our results also show that debit cards are a closer

substitute to cash than credit cards, as in Borzekowski et al. (2008) and Koulayev et al. (2012)”. 953 Infra ¶ 127. 954 Infra ¶ 146.

Page 226: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

226

and all consumers would have enjoyed any of their success in bargaining lower interchange

fees. Those powerful merchants are, in fact, the “marginal consumers”, who are positioned at

the intersection of the demand and supply curve. Marginal consumer is the one who pulls the

price down for all “infra-marginal” customers across the entire market. Isolating the marginal

consumer into a lower-fee category is what enabled the payment card firms to charge more

from the infra-marginal consumers.955

542. Ninth, separation of merchants into categories leads to one of two options, neither is desirable:

If the costs that make up the interchange fee are higher than 0.5%, then merchants, and

indirectly all consumers, subsidize the state, its agencies and the IEC. On the other hand, if

0.5% interchanges fee is profitable, then the expert was wrong, and notwithstanding categories

all merchants in Israel should pay less. Be what may, the current outcome is erroneous.

Debit Cards In Israel

543. The payment card market in Israel is degenerated, in terms of variety of cards and the

arrangements accompanying them. Debit card transactions are faster and cheaper than credit

transactions.956 Nevertheless, debit usage is rare. The degeneration is reflected firstly in the

volume of debit and prepaid cards, which is only about 1.5%.957

544. Debit and prepaid transactions in Israel, suffered until April 2016 from two distortions.

First, the interchange fee for debit and prepaid transactions in Israel was until April 2016 the

same as the interchange fee in deferred debit and credit transactions.958 The interchange fee in

Israel is cost-based. The payment guarantee is the main cost-driver of the interchange fee. The

payment guarantee in debit is significantly lower than in credit. According to the IAA, applying

the Methodology Decision on debit and prepaid transactions yields an interchange fee of

approx. 0.28% instead of 0.7%.959 Nevertheless, it took until April 2016 for the regulator to

955 Alex Chisholm, Speech given at the Regulatory Policy Institute Annual Conference (Sept. 10, 2014): "In any given

market you might have a mix of ‘engaged’ and 'Disengaged’ customers, who suffer from biases to different extents.

And if there is a sufficient number of engaged customers, and if firms cannot price-discriminate between the two

groups, then the actions of engaged customers can indirectly protect disengaged customers."; Cf. Ori BarAm & Elad

Man, Prohibit Price Discrimination [Leesor Al Aflayat Mehirim], THEMARKER, May 3, 2016; Ori BarAm & Elad Man,

One Price for Gas, Big Prize for Consumers, THEMARKER, Aug. 22, 2016. 956 IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note

21, at 12. See also infra ¶ 125. 957 IAA, id. at 8. 958 Banking Decree (Service to Customer) (Supervision on Service that an Issuer Gives Acquirer with Connection to

Interchange Acquiring of Debit Transactions) (Temporary Order), sec. 3 (2015). See also supra ¶ 18. 959 IAA DRAFT REPORT ON ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY AND COMPETITION IN PAYMENT CARDS, at 12 n. 29, Antitrust

500560 (Feb. 11, 2014).

Page 227: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

227

differentiate the interchange fees.

The second twist was that until April 2016 merchants were remitted for debit and prepaid all

payment card transactions, after 20 days (on average) from transaction date. This delay was

outrageous, because the money was taken from the cardholder immediately (in debit), or even

before the transaction (prepaid).960

545. Three different regulators emphasized the distortions and recommended a debit reform.

The first to note was the IAA’s initiative. In 2012, following the conclusion of a Governmental

Committee examining the cost of living (Trachtenberg Committee), the IAA established a new

department, aimed in the promotion of competition - the Competitive Division.961 In February

2014, the Competitive Division published its first (draft) report. This report examined the lack

of competition in the payment card sector.962 The IAA noted the oligopolistic features of the

payment card market: (a) few competitors with stable market shares; (b) only half of the

decrease in the interchange fee was passed through to the MSF. This conclusion was

subsequently proved wrong. The pass through from the interchange fee to the MSF is 100%

(see para. 97); (c) almost no debit cards; (d) technological barriers to entry such as no

interoperability of SHVA for new acquirers.

The IAA noted that according to the Methodology Decision the interchange fee calculation for

debit should be about 0.28% and not 0.7%.963 The IAA emphasized the distortion in delaying

debit and prepaid funds for twenty days (on average). The IAA went even further and

recommended that in deferred debit transactions, payment would be remitted to merchants close

to the transaction. The IAA explained this recommendation in that the card firms have lower

funding costs than merchants.964 Twenty days delay in debit and prepaid remittance to

merchants seemed to the IAA as an obvious distortion. The IAA recommended promotion of

debit cards by, inter alia, reducing the interchange fee in debit transactions, and obligating

960 Supra ¶496. 961 IAA website, “about” tab, http://www.antitrust.gov.il/about/about1.aspx 962 IAA DRAFT REPORT, supra note 959. 963Id. at 12 n. 29. 964Id. at 23-25 (11.2.14); IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL

REPORT), supra note 21, at 27-28.

Page 228: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

228

issuers to remit debit and prepaid funds to merchants (via acquirers) within two days of the

transaction, and not once per month.965

546. On September 11, 2014 the IAA published its final report. Again the report noted the high

concentration and the low competitiveness of the payment card market in Israel, and stressed

the need to enhance debit in Israel.966 The final report adopted the recommendations of the draft

report regarding (a) the low interchange fee that should prevail in debit and prepaid transactions,

and (b) the need to advance payments to merchants in these transactions.

In its final report, the IAA highlighted the advantages of debit and its desire to promote debit

cards in Israel. The IAA emphasized that debit cards operate with lower fees than credit cards,

and are cheaper, simpler and faster than credit cards. Debit systems are also a substitute for

cash, and they support combating “black economy”.967

The IAA indicated that low volume of debit transactions is derived from: (a) interchange fee

for debit transactions in Israel, was the same as for deferred debit transactions; (b) public

misperception that credit cards bear free credit, when in fact, they induce interest bearing

debt;968 (c) imposition of usage fees (action or line fee) on every debit transaction, which

diminishes cardholders’ incentive to use debit. This distortion was amended, and the fee was

canceled, on February 2015;969 (d) absence of any incentive for incumbent credit card firms to

develop debit card network, and by that cannibalize their profitable credit card business; (e)

absence of designated debit POSs at cashiers; (f) delay in remittance (20 days on average); (g)

absence of debit infrastructure.970

547. The IAA recommended that debit should be promoted both on the issuing side and on the

acquiring side. On the issuing side, the IAA recommended that issuers would be required to

offer debit cards to 90% of their active cardholders, and to effectively issue debit cards to 70%

of them, by the end of 2015. If issuers would not meet these targets, they would have to issue

965 Press Release, IAA Publishes Research on the Competition in Payment Cards, Antitrust 500561 (Feb. 12, 2014). 966 IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note

21, at 7, 8. 967Id. at 4, 12-14. 968 See infra ¶¶ 152, 159, 728 (the "seduction by plastic" phenomenon). 969 2015 Amendment to Banking Rules (Service to Customers) (Fees), 2008, effective Feb. 1, 2015. 970 Ibid, see also IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL

REPORT), supra note 21, at 13-20.

Page 229: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

229

combined cards (i.e., cards that can be used as both debit and credit cards) starting in the middle

of 2016.971

548. On the acquiring side, the IAA recommended: (a) setting a lower interchange fee for debit;972

(b) require issuers to remit debit funds to merchants (via acquirers) within 1-3 days of the

transaction date;973 (c) require banks to identify debit transactions as such in statements to their

clients, and not charge any fee for debit usage,974 (d) abolish HAC rule and enable merchants

to freely choose to accept only cheap payment instruments (i.e., debit and not credit);975 (e)

remove technological barriers and require full interoperability of SHVA's infrastructures for

new acquirers;976 (f) enable debit transactions to be routed on both the ATM network and the

credit card network, (g) encourage merchants to install debit POSs.977

In July 2015, the World Bank awarded the IAA a commendation for its activities to enhance

competition in the Israeli payment card market.978

549. Second encouragement to debit came from a government initiative. In September 2013, the

government decided to take steps to minimize the use of cash, in order to fight black

economy.979 In April 2014, a ministerial Committee regarding the cost of living decided to take

steps to enhance debit usage.980 In May 2014, an interim report of a government committee

(Locker Committee) that was nominated to examine how to limit the use of cash, included

recommendations for promoting debit cards.981 The final report of this committee was

submitted in July 2014.982

The committee stressed that debit payments combat black economy, because transactions are

monitored and registered. The final report recommended, inter alia, authorizing the Antitrust

971Id. recommendation 7 at 24. 972Id. see also Memorandum, Antitrust Law (Amendment 16 - Determination of Interchange Fee), Antitrust 500777

(Aug. 10, 2014). 973 IAA, FINAL REPORT, id. at 24, recommendation 2. 974Id. recommendations 3 and 4. 975Id. 976Id. 977 Id at 25, 31. 978 IAA, Press Release, World Bank awarded commendation to the IAA for Debit Reform, Antitrust 500811 (July, 8,

2015). 979 Government Decision 749 from Sept. 17, 2013 available at http://www.pmo.gov.il/Secretary/GovDecisions/2013/Pages/govdec749.aspx 980 Decision 1551 of Ministers’ Comity on cost of living, ENHANCEMENT OF COMPETITION AND EFFICIENCY IN

PAYMENT CARDS, (Apr. 2014) 981 THE COMMITTEE FOR REDUCING THE USE OF CASH (LOCKER COMMITTEE), INTERIM REPORT, at 17 (May 2014). 982 HAVAADA LEBHINAT TZIMZUM HASHIMUSH BEMEZUMAN BAMESHEK HAISRAELI [THE COMMITTEE FOR EXAMINING

REDUCTION OF CASH USAGE IN THE ISRAELI MARKET] (THE LOCKER COMMITTEE), FINAL REPORT (July 17, 2014).

Page 230: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

230

General Director to determine a different interchange fee for debit and fast remittance of debit

funds to merchants, in no more than three days.983

550. Third debit encouragement initiative came from Bank of Israel. In April 2014, the Bank

announced its intention to reduce the number of fees applying to payment cards.984 On February

1, 2015 an amendment to the Banking Rules (Service to Customers) (Fees), 2008 came into

force. Amendment to First Annex § 3 eliminated action fee (line-fee) on debit transactions. The

amendment also prohibited debit cardholder fee, for customers who already possess credit

cards, for 36 months from the issuance of the debit card.985

551. In February 2015 Bank of Israel promulgated a comprehensive report on payment cards

competition.986 The report recommended, inter alia: (a) to reduce interchange fees on debit

transactions; (b) expediting debit remittance to merchants, not later than 3 days from transaction

date; (c) obligate banks to offer their customers free debit cards; (d) educating the Israeli public

about debit advantages; (e) amending the Banking Law (Licensing), 1981, so as to enable

SHVA to serve acquirers that are not banks (i.e., repeal section 23 of the Banking Law

(Licensing) 1981);987 (f) ease equity demands from new debit acquirers.988

552. On June 30, 2015, Bank of Israel announced that the Governor of the Bank intended to declare

that debit interchange fee would be under the Bank’s supervision, and would be at a rate of

0.3% effective April 1, 2016. The reduced debit interchange fee indeed came into force on April

1, 2016 in a temporary order.989 The Bank also declared more steps to increase debit usage.

Beginning April 1, 2016, banks must offer free debit cards to all of their customers (if the

customer already has a credit card) or with a reduced cardholder fee (if the customer has no

previous payment card). Banks must remit merchants funds of debit transactions within 3 days,

983Id. at 17, 23. 984 Bank of Israel, Press Release, Announcement of Reduction in the Number of Payment Card Fees (Apr. 30, 2014), 985 Banking Rules (Service to Customer) (Fees), 2008, section 6(1) to part 6 of first Annex and section 2 to the second

Annex of Banking Rules (Service to Customer) (Fees), 2008. See also Israel Bank, Press Release, Fee Reduction in

Payment Cards (Feb. 1, 2015). 986 BANK OF ISRAEL, RECOMMENDATIONS FOR ENHANCEMENT OF COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR, FINAL

REPORT (Feb. 2015) available at http://www.boi.org.il/he/BankingSupervision/Survey/Pages/paymentcards.aspx . 987 Infra ¶ 799.3. 988 Bank of Israel, Final Report, id.; IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD

SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note 21, at 11, 16, 22. 989 Banking Decree (Service to Customer) (Pikuach al Sherut Shenoten Manpik Lesolek Bekesher Leslika Tzolevet Shel

Iskaot Hiuv Miadi) (Horaat Shaa), 2015 (Supervision on Service an Issuer Gives an Acquirer with Connection to

Interchange Acquiring of Debit Transactions) (Temporary Order), 2015.

Page 231: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

231

and disclose details of each debit card transaction in an explicit way both to customers and

merchants.990

553. For completeness, I am involved in a pending class action which claims, inter alia that the

payment card firms were parties to two unauthorized restrictive arrangements: (a) the

interchange fees in debit and prepaid cards (b) delay of payments to merchants in debit and

prepaid transactions.991 As of the end of 2017 the suit is still pending.

No Smart Acquiring (EMV)

554. The payment card firms in Israel did not promote the use of smart cards. A smart card is a card

with an EMV (Europay MasterCard Visa technical standard) chip, installed on it. Upon

payment, the cardholder types her PIN number that is verified by the EMV chip. Smart card

transactions are less prone to fraud than signature transactions. According to the rules of the

international organizations, the risk of fraud falls on the issuer, but if fraud occurs at a POS that

was not modified to read smart cards, and had the POS been so modified, the fraud would have

been prevented, then the responsibility for the fraud is transferred to the acquirer.

555. The payment card firms were specifically exempted by the Antitrust General Director, and were

allowed to collaborate in order to erect an EMV interface.992 Despite the approval they did not

promote neither EMV issuing nor acquiring nor EMV compatible terminals.

556. In June 2015, the Bank of Israel published instructions according to which EMV issuing will

become mandatory by October 2015, and EMV acquiring will become mandatory by July

2016. POS terminals installed from July 2016 forward must be EMV compatible.993

Market Concentration

557. Another drawback of the payment market in Israel is its structural obstruction. The three

payment card companies in Israel are controlled by four commercial banks. LeumiCard by

990 Press Release, Bank of Israel Publishes Instructions for Assimilation of Debit Cards and Enhancement of

Competition in Payment Cards (30.6.15); Bank of Israel, Communication 2498-06-ח, Acquiring Payment Cards, sec. 13

(Banking Proper Procedure, Instruction 472), (May 1, 2016); Bank of Israel, Expansion of Debit Card Distribution,

Letter from the Banks' Supervisor, section 4 (June 29, 2015); Bank of Israel, Banking Proper Procedure, Payment

Cards, sections 17, 19 (Instruction 470) available at

http://www.boi.org.il/he/BankingSupervision/SupervisorsDirectives/DocLib/470.pdf. 991 Civil Case (Center) 43283-4-14 Hajbi v. Isracard et al. (Motion to Approve a Class Action) (April 28, 2014). 992 Exemption with Conditions to Isracard, Leumi Card and CAL, Antitrust 5000623 (May 30, 2006). 993 Press Release, Bank of Israel Publishes Instructions for Assimilation of Debit Cards and Enhancement of

Competition in Payment Cards (June 30, 2015).

Page 232: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

232

Leumi, Isracard by Hapoalim, CAL by Discount and First International bank. The banks have

no interest in letting their subsidiaries compete with them for credit to cardholders.

558. Indeed, issuers offer attractive loans only to their non-bank cardholders. For this reason, inter

alia, Bills calling for divestiture of the payment card companies from their parent banks have

been submitted.994 These bills have not evolved into law. In 2016 the Shtrum committee

recommended again to divest the two bigger payment card companies, Isracart and LeumiCard

from their controlling banks.995 This time the committee’s recommendations were adopted.

However, until the end of 2017 such divestiture did not yet occur.

559. Cross-ownership and other cooperation between competitors also characterize the Israeli

payment card market.

CAL is jointly held by Bank Discount (72%) and First International Bank (28%).996 The joint

ownership of CAL by two competing banks can be considered as a restrictive arrangement for

itself. This was the opinion of the Antitrust General Director when CAL was jointly held by

Leumi and Discount.997 The IAA insisted that Leumi and Discount banks dissolve their joint

possession of CAL. Bank Discount bought out Bank Leumi, and the latter founded LeumiCard.

Probably the IAA is more tolerable to the current joint possession in CAL, than when CAL was

held by Bank Leumi, because the First International is smaller than Leumi.

560. The only other big bank in Israel that does not own a payment card firm is Mizrahi Tfachot

Bank.

Mizrahi Tfachot and Isracard are parties to a (restrictive) arrangement, according to which

Tfachot issues Isracard cards, in exchange for revenue sharing and an option to purchase

unknown number of shares in Isracard. This arrangement was not submitted for approval to the

IAA but it was advertised in the economic media.998

994 Banking Law (Licensing) Bill, Enhancement of Competition in the Credit Card Market, 2468/17/(2007) פ; Banking

Law (Licensing) Bill, Ownership of Issuing Undertakings /2475/17פ (2007); Banking Law (Licensing) Bill, Ownership

of Credit Card Issuers /157/18פ (2009); Banking Law (Licensing) Bill, Ownership of Credit Card Issuers /1066/19פ

(2013); Bill to Enhance Competition in Credit (Divestiture of Bank Ownership in Credit Card Firms) /2180/19פ (2014). 995 For further details on the Shtrum Committee, see infra ¶ 847. 996 Supra note 41. 997 David Gilo & Yossi Spiegel, The Credit Card Industry in Israel, 4 REV. NETWORK ECON. 266, 267 n. 3 (2005): " In

July 1998, the director of the IAA notified Bank Leumi and IDB that they should dissolve their joint ownership of CAL

by the end of 1999, otherwise he would open an investigation. The director’s claim was that the joint ownership was an

illegal restraint of trade under Section 2 of the Israeli Antitrust Act". 998 Eiran Peer, Isracard Will Issue to Customers of Mizrachi Tfachot Branded Credit Cards, GLOBES (Aug. 23, 2009)

Page 233: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

233

Such arrangement enables Mizrachi Tefachot to enjoy benefits of being an issuer's stakeholder,

and dissuades it from entering the issuing arena as an independent competitor.

561. The last independent bank in Israel, Union Bank, has an issuing agreement with CAL, according

to which Union bank issues CAL cards, in return for revenue sharing, and an option to purchase

3% of CAL.999 This is approximately the market share of Union Bank in the general banking

sector. Thus, the agreement promises Union Bank its market share in the issuing side of the

payment card market, without the need to compete.

562. In my opinion, the above mentioned arrangements are restrictive arrangements that should not

have been approved. Had Mizrachi Tfachot and Union Banks not sign those issuing

arrangements, they could not afford not to offer cards to their clients. They would have had to

purchase licenses from the international organizations, MasterCard and Visa, in order to issue

cards to their customers. It is reasonable to expect that under such scenario Mizrachi Tfachot

and Union banks would have had to compete for cardholders and merchants.

The effect of these agreements is that instead of competing, Tfachot and Union Banks receive

assured profits from the payment card industry, proportional to their market share in the banking

industry.1000 Their income and profits from payment cards is fixed according to their market

share in the overall banking industry, without the need for competing independently. In my

opinion this is exactly the kind of passive investments between competitors that antitrust laws

should prevent.1001 In my view banks should not hold stakes in payment card firms of rival

banks.

Single Routing Option

563. Israel has only one routing infrastructure through which payment cards transactions are

processed - SHVA.1002 This situation may seem normal for Israelis that are used to the

999 Exemption for CAL, Diners Cards and Union Bank, Antitrust 5001695 (Dec. 1, 2010). 1000 See also Sivan Eizensco, The Little Fee that Produces Additional 700 Million NIS to Banks from Credit Cards, THE

MARKER, (27.4.14) available at http://www.themarker.com/markets/1.2306467. 1001 David Gilo, Passive Investments between Competitors in Israel, 35 MISHPATIM 1 (2005); David Gilo, The

Anticompetitive Effect of Passive Investment, 99 MICH. L. REV. 1 (2000). 1002 IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note

21, at 5.

Page 234: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

234

concentrated banking sector, and are not aware of other possibilities, but many countries have

several routing infrastructures that compete against each other.

564. The Trio Agreement required the parties to establish an interface for acquiring and routing

payment card transactions. This interface was built and operated by “SHVA”, the company

which also operates the interbank ATM network infrastructure in Israel, and was the owner of

non-bank ATMs.

SHVA is a company owned by the banks, and as such it is cooperation between competitors in

the field of competition, which naturally raises competitive concerns. Therefore SHVA is a

restrictive arrangement by itself, which requires the approval of the Antitrust General Director

for its existence. Although SHVA was founded in the 1970s, it did not file for such approval

until 2002.1003

565. For a decade the General Director exempted SHVA, without requiring any structural

demands.1004 However, in 2012 the General Director conditioned the continuance of SHVA's

existence on several terms, one of which was to sell its ATMs.1005 Another condition was that

SHVA adapts its interface to accommodate new acquirers that want to connect to the payment

card network.1006 As of October 2017, SHVA had not yet adjusted its interface to be

interoperable with systems of new acquirers.

566. Remittance to merchants and access to accounts of non-bank cardholders are performed by

MASAV, an Automated Clearing House that operates interbank clearance in Israel. MASAV

is a sister firm of SHVA, owned by the banks, and similarly, by itself, a restrictive

arrangement.1007

1003 Exemption with Conditions in re: SHVA, Antitrust 4804 (June 18, 2002), (Sept. 17, 2002). 1004 Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust 5000714 (June 17, 2004); Exemption with

Conditions to Five Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust 5001307 (Nov. 5, 2008); Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in

re: SHVA, Antitrust 5001953 (May 22, 2012). 1005 Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust 500224 (Sept. 20, 2012); Exemption with

Conditions to Five Banks in re: SHVA (Feb. 9, 2014); Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust

5669 (Nov. 19, 2014). 1006 Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks on the Matter of SHVA, Antitrust 500459 (Aug. 26, 2013); See also IAA,

ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note 21. 1007 Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 3014681 (June 20, 2002); Exemption with

Conditions to Five Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 5667 (June 17, 2004); Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in

re: MASSAV, Antitrust 5001308 (Nov. 5, 2008); Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust

5001954 (May 22, 2012); Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 500223 (Sept. 20, 2012);

Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 500271 (Dec. 20, 2012); Exemption with

Conditions to Five Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 500368 (March 20, 2013). See also Interim Expert Report of Y.

Bachar in A.T 610/06 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, at 45 (1.1.09).

Page 235: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

235

567. The result of the existence of a single infrastructure controlled by the banks is, not surprisingly,

the inability to access this infrastructure by new acquirers. Access to infrastructure is of course

essential for new acquirers.1008 Notwithstanding the undisputed difficulties in erecting

interoperable infrastructure systems, these issues could be already solved long ago had there

been an independent payment infrastructure in Israel.

568. SHVA and MASAV are prohibited from dividing profit to their shareholders (the banks). They

can gain profit but cannot distribute it to their controlling banks. The reason is to dissuade

SHVA and MASAV from charging high fees which could have been transferred to their

controlling banks as profit, while concurrently serving as an entry barrier to new entrants.1009

8.2. Europe

569. The history of payment card networks in Europe began early in the second half of the 20th

century. In those years, Diners and American Express, and later also Visa and MasterCard,

expanded outside the United States.

570. The European Commission first examined the rules of open networks in 1977. Ibanco, the

predecessor of Visa, submitted its operating rules and requested approval. The Commission did

not give formal approval, but announced in a comfort letter that Ibanco's operating rules did not

violate EU regulations.1010 Until the 1990s, payment cards were barely regulated in Europe.

571. In the 1990s merchant organizations complained against the interchange fee of Visa and

MasterCard. The complaints alleged that cross-border interchange fees were a restrictive

arrangement prohibited by the treaty on the functioning of the European Union (“TFEU”). This

led to an investigation of the payment card sector. In 1999, the commission sent a Statement of

Objections to visa. In August 2001, the European Commission published a decision in which it

1008 Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees, supra note 884, at 28: “In order to promote efficiency in the payments

market authorities need to open the market to increased competition, which would imply requiring open access to

payment networks and interoperable standards from the processing technical point of view”. 1009 Exemption with Conditions in re: SHVA, Antitrust 4804 (June 18, 2002), (Sept. 17, 2002), Exemption with

Conditions in re: SHVA, Antitrust 4804, at 10 (June 18, 2002); Exemption with condition, in re: SHVA, antitrust

500459, at 7-8 (Aug. 26, 2013). 1010 COMP/29.373 − Visa International 2001/782/EC, paras. 1-2 (O.J. L 293 2001), http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:32001D0782:EN:HTML : “On 31 January 1977 Ibanco Ltd,

since 1979 known as Visa International, notified various rules and regulations governing the Visa association and its

members to the Commission, applying for negative clearance or, in the alternative, an exemption under Article 81(3) of

the Treaty. (2) After having initially sent a comfort letter, on 29 April 1985 the Commission reopened the investigation

in the Visa case, following a complaint by the British Retail Consortium against the "multilateral interchange fee" in the

Visa International payment scheme, and the comfort letter was withdrawn on 4 December 1992.”; Éva Keszy-Harmath

et al., The Role of the Interchange Fee in Card Payment Systems, para. 5.1.1 (MNB Occasional papers 96. 2012).

Page 236: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

236

found no grounds for action with respect to the NSR, the HAC and the “No Acquiring Without

Issuing” ("NAWI") rule. The commission noted that the interchange fee remained under

examination.1011

572. On July 24, 2002 the Commission exempted Visa’s interchange fee (“The Visa Decision”). The

Visa Decision was given with the consent of Visa, after Visa had made some changes and

reductions in the fees it charged merchants.1012

Visa agreed to reduce the level of its interchange fees in deferred debit and credit transactions

to an average of 0.7% in credit and €0.28 (regardless of the transaction’s amount) for debit

transactions. These were supposed to be upper bounds. The interchange fee could be lower if

three specific costs, which in the Commission's view corresponded to services provided by

issuers to merchants, yielded a lower interchange fee than 0.7% and €0.28. The services were:

(1) transaction processing costs; (2) Payment guarantee, which was defined as “the promise of

the cardholder's bank to honor payments made by cardholders, even those which turn out to be

fraudulent or for which the cardholder ultimately defaults, on condition that the retailer

undertakes all the necessary security checks”; (3) Free funding period, which was defined as

the time period until the cardholder must pay the card bill or roll over the debt to later months.

A rate of interest was applied to this period. The free funding period was considered by the

Commission to benefit merchants by stimulating additional sales.1013

These costs were similar to the eligible costs of the Methodology Decision in Israel that was

given few years later, as described above.

The Visa Decision also determined that Visa had to make a cost study, audited by an

independent accountant, to determine these costs. If the costs were found to be lower than the

caps, the interchange fees would have been lowered to match the costs. In practice, however,

in all of the five years in which the Visa Decision was in force, the audited costs Visa provided

always showed a result higher than 0.7% and €0.28, so the arbitrary caps prevailed. This, of

course, is no surprise given the criticisms of cost-based interchange fees explained earlier.1014

1011 COMP/29.373 − Visa International 2001/782/EC, O.J. L 293 (2001). 1012 Comp 29.373 Visa International — Multilateral Interchange Fee, O. J. L 318, (July 24, 2002), supra note 247. 1013 Ibid, see also Press Release, Antitrust, Commission Exempts Multilateral Interchange Fees for Cross Border VISA

Card Payments, IP/02/1138 (July 24, 2002). 1014 Supra ch. 8.1.1 especially ¶¶ 504-504.

Page 237: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

237

573. An important determination that was included in the Visa Decision was that interchange fee is

not essential for the operation of the Visa network.1015 Nevertheless, the Commission opined

that interchange fee is not a restrictive arrangement by object (i.e., designed to harm

competition), because an interchange fee could increase the efficiency and stability of open

systems, as well as the relative competitiveness of open networks versus closed networks.1016

574. In 2006, the Commission published, after thorough research, an Interim Report on payment

cards. A main conclusion of the report was that networks tilt the price structure in favor of

cardholders, at the expense of merchants.1017

The report also noted that the issuing side was highly profitable. 62% of issuers were found to

be profitable just from cardholder fee and interest from credit to cardholders, thus diminishing

the need for interchange fees as a mean to cover costs.1018

575. After the exemption granted by the Visa Decision expired, on December 31, 2007, the

Commission informed Visa Europe, which had taken over responsibility from Visa

International for the network rules applicable in Europe, that it was renewing its investigation

regarding the interchange fees and regarding merchant restraints such as the NSR and the

HAC.1019 On April 3, 2009, the Commission sent Visa Europe a Statement of Objections, stating

that the interchange fee was an alleged violation of Articles 101 and 102 (previously Articles

81, 82) of the TFEU.1020

576. On May 28, 2010, Visa and the Commission reached a partial settlement. The settlement

included a reduction in Visa’s debit card interchange fee to a rate of 0.2%, and partial abolition

of the HAC rule.1021 The commitments of Visa were published in September 2010.1022 Soon

1015 Comp 29.373 Visa International — Multilateral Interchange Fee, supra note 247, para. 8.2.3: “The Visa MIF is, on

the admission of Visa itself, not indispensable for the existence of the Visa system”. 1016Id. para. 69: “However, the Commission does not consider the MIF agreement to be a restriction of competition by

object, since a MIF agreement in a four-party payment system such as that of Visa has as its objective to increase the

stability and efficiency of operation of that system…, and indirectly to strengthen competition between payment

systems by thus allowing four-party systems to compete more effectively with three-party systems”. 1017EC, INTERIM REPORT, supra note 79, at iii: “The preliminary results of the inquiry show a picture of market

fragmentation. While consumers clearly reap benefits from card payment networks in the EU, businesses do less so and

largely foot the bill”. 1018Id. at 76: “It appears that 62% of all banks surveyed would still make profits with credit card issuing even if they did

not receive any interchange fee revenues at all”. 1019 Europa, Press Release, Antitrust, Commission Initiates Formal Proceedings Against Visa Europe Limited,

MEMO/08/170 (Mar. 26, 2008). 1020 Press Release, Antitrust: Commission Sends Statement of Objections to Visa, MEMO/09/151, (Apr. 6, 2009). 1021 Notice no 1/2003 in Case COMP/39.398 — Visa MIF, O.J (C 138) 34 (May 28, 2010). 1022 Case Comp/39.398 - Visa Europe Commitments Offered To The European Commission Pursuant To Article 9 Of

Council Regulation (Ec) No 1/2003 (Sept. 10, 2010).

Page 238: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

238

after, on December 8, 2010, the Commission announced the end of its investigation on the

agreed upon issues,1023 but credit card interchange fees and deferred debit interchange fees

remained under investigation. On July 31, 2012, after completion of the investigation, the

Commission sent Visa a supplementary statement of objection, stating the credit card

interchange fee was a restrictive arrangement.1024

577. Once again, Visa reached a settlement with the Commission. On May 14, 2013, the Commission

published a notice stating that it welcomed the proposal by Visa Europe to reduce its

interchange fee on cross-border credit card and deferred debit transactions to 0.3%. This

reduction applied also to ten European countries that followed the cross-border interchange

fee.1025 On February 26, 2014, the Commission announced that Visa’s proposal was binding,

and the cross-border interchange fee was to be reduced by January 2015, to 0.3% (on average).

The national interchange fees, in countries where Visa sets them, would be reduced to 0.3%

two years later. Visa also undertook to accede to merchants' requests to pay a MSF that is based

on the interchange fee (“interchange fee plus” MSF).1026

578. The proceedings of the European Commission against MasterCard advanced at a different pace.

In December 2007 the Commission published a comprehensive decision which declared the

cross-border interchange fee of MasterCard to be a restrictive arrangement.1027 This decision

repeated the 2002 conclusion of the Visa decision, and determined once again that the

interchange fee was not essential for the operation of an open network.1028 The Commission

1023 Commission Decision of 8.12.2010 relating to Proceedings Under Article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of

the European Union and Article 53 of the EEA Agreement (Case COMP/39.398 - Visa MIF), C(2010) 8760 final. See

also Summary of Commission Decision of 8 December 2010 Relating to a Proceeding Under Article 101 of the Treaty

on the Functioning of the European Union and Article 53 of the EEA Agreement (Case COMP/39.398 — VISA MIF),

C 79/8 (March 12, 2011). 1024 Press Release: Commission Sends Supplementary Statement of Objections to Visa, IP/2/871 (July 31, 2012). 1025 European Commission, Antitrust, Memo/13/431 Vice President Almunia Welcomes Visa Europe's Proposal to Cut

Inter-Bank Fees for Credit Cards (May 14, 2013); Commission Announcement in Case AT.39398 — VISA MIF O.J. C

168/22 (June 14, 2013). 1026 AT 39398 Visa - Commission Decision C(2014) 1199 Final (Feb. 26, 2014)

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/dec_docs/39398/39398_9728_3.pdf ; European Commission Press

Release, Antitrust, Commission Makes Visa Europe's Commitments to Cut Inter-Bank Fees and to Facilitate Cross-

Border Competition Legally Binding, IP/14/197 (Feb. 26, 2014); European Commission MEMO, Commission Makes

Visa Europe's Commitments Binding – Frequently Asked Questions (Feb. 26, 2014): “Visa Europe has offered to cap

the weighted average MIF for consumer credit card transactions at 30 basis points (bps), i.e. 0.30% per transaction for

all transactions where it sets the fee… Visa Europe commits: (i) to introduce a rule to make the prices paid by

merchants more transparent. Accordingly acquirers will be required to offer merchants merchant service charge

("MSC") pricing on a “MIF plus” basis. In other words, acquirers must, if requested, clearly break down in their

contracts and invoices the MSC into three components, namely the MIF, the acquirer fee and all the other applicable

payment system fees”. 1027 Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision (Dec. 19, 2007), available at

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/dec_docs/34579/34579_1889_2.pdf . 1028Id. Paras. 648, 608: “A MIF is not objectively necessary for the co-operation of banks in an open payment card

scheme such as MasterCard's”.

Page 239: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

239

explicitly highlighted the existence of successful open debit card networks, operating without

interchange fees.1029 MasterCard appealed this decision. The appeal was rejected in May 2012,

affirming the Commission’s arguments.1030 MasterCard appealed once again to the European

High Court of Justice (“ECJ”). In September 2014 the ECJ rejected MasterCard's appeal.1031

579. The ECJ determined once again that the interchange fee was not objectively necessary to the

functioning of MasterCard,1032 and that it sets a floor to the MSF. It upheld the lower court's

view that interchange fee has none of the redeeming objective advantages required by article

101(3) in order to be exempted. The ECJ rejected the argument that due to the HAC rule,

without interchange fee acquirers would be put at the mercy of issuers (i.e., issuers would be

allegedly able to extort any level of interchange fee, since acquirers must pay merchants

according to the Honor All Cards rule). The ECJ stated that as long as this is the argument for

interchange fee, it could be dealt in a more proportional and less anti-competitive manner, such

as prohibition on ex-post pricing by issuers.1033

1029Id. Paras. 562-608 and para. 751: “[S]everal payment schemes in the European Economic Area have successfully

been operating without a MIF for a long time. These Schemes have been established between 1979 and 1992 and they

are not merely viable but indeed successful."; EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees, supra note 200, at

10-11: “Denmark has one of the highest card usage rates in the EU at 216 transactions per capita with a zero-

Interchange Fee debit scheme. This is also true of international schemes: in Switzerland Maestro has no interchange fee

and is the main debit card system… In terms of viability, a debit card scheme without any interchange fee seems to be

perfectly viable from a commercial perspective without raising the costs of current accounts for consumers.”; Lukas

Repa, Agata Malczewska & Antonio Carlos Teixeira, Commission Prohibits MasterCard’s Multilateral Interchange

Fees for Cross-Border Card Payments in the EEA, COMPETITION POL'Y NEWSL., at 2 (Nov. 1, 2008): “A mechanism

such as a MIF that shifts profits between acquiring and issuing banks is not objectively necessary for the banks’

cooperation, as issuing and acquiring services can be remunerated directly by the respective consumer groups.

The decision demonstrates the viability of the MasterCard scheme in the absence of the crossborder MIF, amongst

others, by providing examples of five other domestic payment card schemes that operated for decades without any MIF

in Europe. These schemes are Pankkikortti in Finland, Bancomat in Luxembourg, Dankort in Denmark, PIN in the

Netherlands and BAX in Norway”. 1030 T-111/08 MasterCard v. Comm'n, (May 24, 2012) 1031 C-382/12 P MasterCard v. European Comm'n (Sept. 11, 2014). 1032Id. para. 113. 1033Id. para. 172: “[T]he Commission was fully entitled to conclude that ‘the possibility that some issuing banks might

hold up acquirers who are bound by the [Honour All Cards Rule] could be solved by a network rule that is less

restrictive of competition than MasterCard’s current solution that, by default, a certain level of interchange fees applies.

The alternative solution would be a rule that imposes a prohibition on ex post pricing on the banks in the absence of a

bilateral agreement between them”. See also Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 1027,

para. 554: "[T]he possibility that some issuing banks might hold up acquirers who are bound by the HACR could be

solved by a network rule that is less restrictive of competition than MasterCard’s current solution that, by default, a

certain level of interchange fees applies. The alternative solution would be a rule that imposes a prohibition on ex post

pricing on the banks in the absence of a bilateral agreement between them. The rule would oblige the creditor bank to

accept any payment validly entered into the system by a debtor bank while prohibiting each bank from charging the

other bank in the absence of a bilateral agreement on the level of such charges. That solution to “protect” acquirers if

issuers should indeed abuse their power under an HACR is less restrictive of competition than a MIF as it does not set a

minimum price level on either side of the scheme."; T-111/08 MasterCard v. Comm'n, paras. 95-97 (May 24, 2012). For

further details see infra ch. 8.3.5

Page 240: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

240

580. In June 2008, while the appeal was pending, MasterCard announced that it was temporarily

ceasing to charge interchange fees in European cross-border transactions.1034 In April 2009,

MasterCard, with the consent of the Commission, announced a huge reduction of cross border

interchange fees, to an average of 0.3% on credit card transactions and 0.2% for debit cards

transactions. This was a significant reduction compared to the previous 1.9% interchange fee

for credit cards and 0.4% to 0.9% for debit cards.1035

581. The European Commission has been working intensively in recent years to turn Europe into a

single payment area (SEPA - Single Euro Payments Area). In this framework, the European

Parliament enacted Regulation 924/2009 and Regulation 260/2012.1036 It is interesting to note

developments in non-card interchange fees according to these Regulations.

Regulation 924/2009 established a default 8.8 Eurocent interchange fee on cross-border direct

payments between financial institutions in Europe until November 2012.1037 Regulation

260/2012 established, inter alia, zero interchange fees for direct payments, beginning

November 2012. Cross-border direct payments are defined as “national or cross-border

payment service for debiting a payer’s payment account, where a payment transaction is

initiated by the payee on the basis of the payer’s consent”.1038 The regulation allows charging

cost-based interchange fee for refused transactions. Beginning in November 2017 a zero

interchange fee will apply also to direct payments between national financial institutions.1039

582. With regard to payment card interchange fees, in January 2012 the European Commission

published a Green Paper entitled: "Towards An Integrated European Market for Cards, Mobile

Payments and Internet".1040 This document generated hundreds of responses from interested

1034 Press Release, Antitrust, Commission Notes MasterCard's Decision to Temporarily Repeal its Cross-Border

Multilateral Interchange Fees within the EEA, MEMO/08/397 (2008). 1035 Press Release, Commissioner Kroes Takes Note of MasterCard's Decision to Cut Cross-Border Multilateral

Interchange Fees (MIFs) and to Repeal Recent Scheme Fee Increases, IP/09/515 (April 1, 2009). 1036 Regulation 924/2009 on Cross-Border Payments, O. J. L 266/11 (Sept. 16, 2009); Regulation 260/2012 Establishing

Technical and Business Requirements for Credit Transfers and Direct Debits in Euro and Amending Regulation (EC)

no 924/2009, O.J. L 94/22 (March 14, 2012). 1037 Regulation 924/2009 on Cross-Border Payments, O. J. L 266/11, Article 6 (2009): “In the absence of any bilateral

agreement between the payment service providers of the payee and of the payer, a multilateral interchange fee of EUR

0,088, payable by the payment service provider of the payee to the payment service provider of the payer, shall apply

for each cross-border direct debit transaction executed before 1 November 2012, unless a lower multilateral interchange

fee has been agreed upon between the payment service providers concerned”. 1038 Regulation 260/2012, supra note 1036, Article 2 (definition) and article 8.1: “[N]o MIF per direct debit transaction

or other agreed remuneration with an equivalent object or effect shall apply to direct debit transactions”. 1039Id. Article 6.3. 1040 European Commission, Green Paper, Towards an Integrated European Market for Card, Internet and Mobile

Payments, COM (2011) 941 final (Jan. 11, 2012).

Page 241: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

241

parties. The responses were summarized in a Feedback Statement.1041 In July 2013, the

European Commission published a comprehensive proposal for interchange fee regulation in

card-based payment transactions that summarized former years of work on this topic.1042

The proposal considered six scenarios for regulating interchange fee.1043 The commission

thoroughly analyzed each option. Its final recommendation was to cap the interchange fee and

cancel merchant restraints like the HAC rule.1044 The Proposal recommended a cross-border

interchange fee of 0.2% for debit cards and 0.3% for credit cards. These rates were to prevail

in the national systems two years later.1045

583. The interchange fee Proposal was accompanied by two additional detailed documents. The first

document was a new payment services directive proposal (PSD2), which, inter alia, enabled

non-bank acquirers to enter the market more easily and with fewer entry barriers. The PSD2

proposal recommended a relatively simple application process, easing equity and capital

1041 European Commission, Feedback Statement on European Commission Green Paper “Towards an Integrated

European Market for Card, Internet and Mobile Payments (June 27, 2012) available at

http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/payments/cim/index_en.htm 1042 EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees for Card-Based Payment Transactions, COM/2013/550, (July

24, 2013), available at http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=COM:2013:0550:FIN:EN:PDF. 1043Id. at 8: “The impact assessment considers six scenarios for interchange fees: (i) No action from the Commission,

(ii) Regulating cross-border acquiring and the level of interchange fees for cross-border transactions, (iii) Mandating

Member States to set domestic IFs on the basis of a common methodology, (iv) Regulating a common, EU-wide

maximum level for interchange fees (a) whether the maximum interchange fee cap – of a different level for debit and

for credit cards- covers both debit and credit cards or just debit cards and (b) whether the IFs for debit card transactions

are to be forbidden altogether or just reduced to a low level, (v) Whether or not to exempt (normally more expensive)

commercial cards and cards issued by three party schemes from the regulation of interchange fees and (vi) regulating

Merchant Service Charges i.e. regulating the fees paid by the retailer to its acquiring bank”. 1044Id. at 8-9: “The assessment concludes that the most beneficial option appears to be a combination of: • a series of

measures to enhance effective market functioning including the limitation of the HACR and allowing merchants to

determine the choice of card brand at the point of sale for all cards and card-based transactions based on four party

scheme models; and • capping the level of interchange fees for cross-border transactions with consumer debit and credit

cards (in the first stage) and, in a second stage, capping the level of interchange fees also for domestic transactions with

consumer credit cards and consumer debit cards”. 1045Id. Articles 3 and 4 of the Proposal:

Article 3 Interchange fees for cross-border consumer debit or credit card transactions

1. With effect from two months after the entry into force of this Regulation, payment services providers shall not offer

or request for cross-border debit card transactions a per transaction interchange fee or other agreed remuneration with

an equivalent object or effect of more than 0,2 % of the value of the transaction.

2. With effect from two months after the entry into force of this Regulation, payment services providers shall not offer

or request for cross-border credit card transactions a per transaction interchange fee or other agreed remuneration with

an equivalent object or effect of more than 0,3 % of the value of the transaction.

Article 4 Interchange fees for all consumer debit or credit card transactions

3. With effect from two years after the entry into force of this Regulation, payment service providers shall not offer or

request a per transaction interchange fee or other agreed remuneration with an equivalent object or effect of more than

0,2 % of the value of the transaction for any debit card based transactions.

4. With effect from two years after the entry into force of this Regulation, payment service providers shall not offer or

request a per transaction interchange fee or other agreed remuneration with an equivalent object or effect of more than

0,3 % of the value of the transaction for any credit card based transactions.

Page 242: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

242

demands and requiring interoperability of incumbent payment systems.1046 The second

document is an exhaustive impact assessment accompanying the interchange fee and the PSD2

proposals.1047

584. The interchange fee proposal was adopted by the European Parliament on April 29, 2015. The

Regulation was published in the Official Journal of the EU on May 19, 2015 (Regulation

2015/751).1048 Few articles are worth noting:

584.1 Article 3 determines the average interchange fee for debit transactions to be no more

than 0.2% until 2020. Thus, debit interchange fees can be higher or lower as long as

an average of no more than 0.2% is kept.1049

584.2 Article 4 sets a cap of 0.3% for credit card interchange fee.1050 Thus, credit card

interchange fee can be lower than 0.3%.

584.3 Article 5 prohibits circumvention of the interchange fee.1051

584.4 Article 8 presents an interesting idea, named “Co-badging and choice of payment

brand or payment application”. Co-Badging is defined in Article 2(31): "the inclusion

of two or more payment brands or payment applications of the same brand on the

same card-based payment instrument". Article 8 ensures that issuers cannot prevent

cardholders from co-badging their cards, e.g., using the same card as a credit and

debit card.

This article might be a useful to the IAA, if the payment card firms in Israel resist

issuing combined cards (cards that can be used either as credit or debit cards at the

cardholder's will).

1046 Proposal for a Directive on Payment Services (PSD2), Com (2013) 547 Final 2013/0264 (Cod) (July 24, 2013) 1047 Commission Staff Working Document Impact Assessment, SWD(2013) 288 Final, (July 24, 2013). 1048 Reg. (EU) 2015/751 of 29 April 2015 on Interchange Fees for Card-Based Payment Transactions, O.J L 123/1 (May

19, 2015). 1049Id. Article 3(3): "Until 9 December 2020, in relation to domestic debit card transactions, Member States may allow

payment service providers to apply a weighted average interchange fee of no more than the equivalent of 0,2 % of the

annual average transaction value of all domestic debit card transactions within each payment card scheme. Member

States may define a lower weighted average interchange fee cap applicable to all domestic debit card transactions". 1050 Ibid: "Payment service providers shall not offer or request a per transaction interchange fee of more than 0,3 % of

the value of the transaction for any credit card transaction. For domestic credit card transactions Member States may

define a lower per transaction interchange fee cap" 1051 Supra note 918.

Page 243: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

243

584.5 Article 9 requires "unblending" of fees. Acquirers are required to offer merchants

different MSFs, if the interchange fee of one card is different from the interchange

fee of another card, unless the merchant requests blended MSF.1052

584.6 Article 10 deals with the HAC rule. There are two types of HAC rule. “Product tying

HAC rule", obligates merchants who accept one payment instruments (e.g., debit

cards) to accept all payment instruments of that brand (e.g., credit). “Issuers tying

HAC rule" obligates merchants who accept a certain payment instrument to accept

all payment instruments of this type regardless of the issuer.

The Regulation permitted "product HAC" but prohibited "issuers HAC".1053

Merchants that accept cheap debit cards can refuse to accept expensive credit cards.

On the other hand a merchant that accepts a debit or credit card issued by X bank

cannot refuse to accept a debit or credit card of that brand, issued by Y bank.1054

In my view, this rule is correct. Indeed, merchants should not discriminate between

issuers who do not demand different prices, but should be able to discriminate and

even reject cards that are costlier.

584.7 Article 11 cancels the NSR rule. Merchants in Europe are allowed to surcharge

customers who pay with expensive payment instruments. NSR Regularization is

completed in two other legislations. Article 52(3) of the Payment Services Directive

(PSD), determines that surcharging is subject to state authority, in order to promote

efficient payment methods.1055 About half of the countries in Europe have banned

1052 Id. Article 9: “Each acquirer shall offer and charge its payee merchant service charges individually specified for

different categories and different brands of payment cards with different interchange fee levels unless payees request

the acquirer, in writing, to charge blended merchant service charges”; See also EU, Proposal for a Regulation on

Interchange Fees, supra note 1042, at 29, Art. 9. 1053Id. Article 10, titled ‘Honour All Cards’ rule: "1. Payment card schemes and payment service providers shall not

apply any rule that obliges payees accepting a card- based payment instrument issued by one issuer also to accept other

card-based payment instruments issued within the framework of the same payment card scheme. 2.Paragraph 1 shall not

apply to consumer card-based payment instruments of the same brand and of the same category of prepaid card, debit

card or credit card subject to interchange fees under Chapter II of this Regulation". 1054 EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees, supra note 1042, at 24: “The Honour all Cards Rule is a

twofold obligation imposed by issuing payment services providers and payment card schemes on payees to, on the one

hand, accept all the cards of the same brand ('Honour all Products' - element), irrespective of the different costs of these

cards, and on the other hand irrespective of the individual issuing bank which has issued the card ('Honour all Issuers' –

element)... the 'Honour all Issuers' element of the Honour all Cards Rule is a justifiable rule... the 'Honour all Products'

element is essentially a tying practice”. See also id. article 10 at 30. 1055 Directive 2007/64/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 November 2007 on payment services in

the internal market OJ L319/1 (Dec. 5, 2007): “The payment service provider shall not prevent the payee from

requesting from the payer a charge or from offering him a reduction for the use of a given payment instrument.

Page 244: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

244

surcharging.1056

The PSD2 Proposal from 2013 recommended limiting surcharges to the costs of the

payment instrument, and to prohibit merchants from surcharging payment

instruments in which interchange fees are regulated.1057 The proposal was adopted in

the Consumer Rights Directive. Article 19 of this directive determines that merchants

will not surcharge a payment instrument by an amount greater than its costs.1058

The Tourist Test

585. In Europe, the methodology used to examine appropriateness of the interchange fee, is no longer

a cost-based methodology. The Commission uses a methodology known as "the tourist test".

The tourist test tries to envisage the indifference point of the merchant between accepting cash

and cards, and is also known as the "Merchant Indifference Test".1059 The indifference criterion

was first denoted by Farrell.1060

586. The indifference test assesses the fee a merchant is willing to pay for a card, in order to avoid

costs of cash (time, deposit fees, security measures), but excluding other benefits merchants

derive from cards, such as increasing their turnover (this is why the test is pointed at a tourist

However, Member States may forbid or limit the right to request charges taking into account the need to encourage

competition and promote the use of efficient payment instruments”. 1056 Study on the impact of directive 2007/64/ec On payment services in the internal market And on the application of

regulation (ec) no 924/2009 on cross-border payments in the Community Contract market/2011/120/h3/st/op Final

report, sec. 24 (Feb. 2013): "Fourteen Member States representing about half of the EU Population have banned

altogether surcharging for the use of specific payment instruments”. 1057 Proposal for a Directive on Payment Services (PSD2), Com (2013) 547 Final 2013/0264 (Cod) (July 24, 2013),

Article 55(3) and (4): “The payment service provider shall not prevent the payee from requesting from the payer a

charge, offering him a reduction or otherwise steering him towards the use of a given payment instrument. Any charges

applied shall, however, not exceed the costs borne by the payee for the use the specific payment instrument.

(4) However, Member States shall ensure that the payee shall not request charges for the use of payment instruments for

which interchange fees are regulated under Regulation”. 1058 Directive 2011/83/EU on Consumer Rights, OJ L 304/64, Article 19 (Nov. 22, 2011): “Member States shall prohibit

traders from charging consumers, in respect of the use of a given means of payment, fees that exceed the cost borne by

the trader for the use of such means”. 1059 Marc Rysman & Julian Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, at 23 n. 22 (2015): “[T]he associated merchant

fee would be set at the level to leave the merchant indifferent ex-post (i.e., at the point of sale) between whether

consumers use cards or the relevant alternative (e.g. cash). The latter principle is known as the "merchant indifference

criterion" (Farrell, 2006) or the "tourist test" (Rochet and Tirole, 2011)… The tourist test asks: does the interchange

fee lead to a merchant fee that would induce the merchant to turn down the card for a tourist who is known to

have the cash and is already at the store, assuming that the merchant has this discretion and will not see the tourist

again? The highest interchange fee that does not lead the merchant to turn down the cards in such circumstances

is the tourist test interchange fee.”; EU Interchange Fee Proposal, supra note 1042, at 15: “The 0.2% and 0.3% caps

envisaged are based on the so-called 'Merchant Indifference Test', which identifies the fee level a merchant would be

willing to pay if he were to compare the cost of the customer’s use of a payment card with those of non-card (cash)

payments.” See also id. at 8. 1060 Joseph Farrell, Efficiency and Competition between Payment Instruments, 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 26 (2006).

Page 245: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

245

that is already at the cashier and intends to pay with cash).1061 Maximum interchange fee that

corresponds to a MSF that makes a merchant indifferent between accepting card or cash (given

that cash also has its costs), is the tourist test interchange fee.1062

The indifference test relates to the MSF and not to the interchange fee. However, the tourist test

methodology is relevant to the interchange fee because of the direct correlation between the

interchange fee and the MSF. When the acquiring fee (the gap between the interchange fee and

the MSF), is constant, the maximum MSF that passes the tourist test relates to a specific

interchange fee.

587. The indifference-test methodology was based on empirical studies that the European

Commission conducted and which examined merchants' costs of accepting cash.1063 The tourist

test is not cost-based. Maximum MSF that passes the indifference test will be at the level of the

avoided costs of cash. The avoided costs of cash are equivalent to the benefit merchants derive

from not having to accept cash.1064 Thus, the tourist test is a utility-based test.1065

588. If the network sets the MSF at a higher level than the avoided costs of cash, the merchant might

decline a card transaction and prefer to accept cash, even though the real costs of cash are higher

1061 For expansion on costs and benefits of payment instruments see ch. 0. 1062 EU Interchange Fee Proposal, supra note 1042, at 22: “Those caps are based on the so-called 'Merchant

Indifference Test' developed in economic literature, which identifies the fee level a merchant would be willing to pay if

he were to compare the cost of the customer’s use of a payment card with those of non-card (cash) payments (taking

into account the fee for service paid to acquiring banks, i.e. the merchant service charge coming on top of the

interchange fee)”. 1063 Ibid at 16: "The figures were calculated on the basis of this test, using data gathered by four national central banks". 1064 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Must-Take Cards: Merchant Discounts and Avoided Costs, 9 J. EUR. ECON.

ASS'N 462, 463 (2011): "This benchmark is not based on issuers’ costs, but on the retailer’s avoided-cost when a cash

(or check) payment is replaced by a card payment. The empirical counterpart of this benchmark, which we call the

tourist test, gives some operational content to the notion of must-take card: would the merchant want to refuse a card

payment when a non-repeat customer with enough cash in her pocket is about to pay at the cash register? Put

differently, the merchant discount passes the tourist test if and only if accepting the card does not increase the

merchant’s operating costs ". See also Jean-Charles Rochet & Julian Wright, Credit Card Interchange Fees, 34 J.

BANK. FIN. 1788, 1794 (2010); Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 67, at 18-19. 1065 Notice Published Pursuant to Article 27(4) of Council Regulation (EC) no 1/2003 in Case COMP/39.398 — Visa

MIF, 2010 O.J C-138/34, 35 (May 28, 2010): “Based on studies conducted by the central banks of several EEA

countries comparing the costs of cards with those of cash, the Commission is of the preliminary view that the MIF Visa

Europe has committed to apply to consumer immediate debit card transactions is in conformity with the ‘merchant

indifference methodology’ (or ‘tourist test’) developed in economic literature. The fee that meets this test (also referred

to as the balancing fee) is set at such a level that merchants are indifferent as to whether they receive a card or cash

payment. The balancing is such that merchants do not pay higher charges than the transactional benefit that the

card use generates for them. For instance, transactional benefits arise where card payments reduce merchants’

costs as compared to cash payments (e.g., because transportation and security expenses for cash are saved or check-

out times at cashier desks are reduced)”.

Page 246: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

246

than the costs of cards. The merchant saves card costs, although from a social point of view it

could be better if the merchant accepted the card.1066

589. Interchange fee that passes the tourist test prevents issuers from exploiting strategic

considerations of merchants. Strategic considerations, elaborated in Chapter 6.4, cause

merchants to accept cards even when the cost (i.e., the MSF), is higher than the utility they

derive from cards. For example, the fear of losing customers compels merchants to pay MSF

that is higher than their net benefit.1067 A tourist test interchange fee caps the MSF on the net

benefit of the merchant from not having to accept cash (without strategic considerations).

Criticism Of The Tourist Test

590. Usually, the surplus of a transaction is divided between the seller and the buyer. However the

MSF, in which the merchant is indifferent whether to accept cards or cash, extracts the

merchant’s entire surplus from not accepting cash.1068

Tourist test interchange fee captures the merchant’s entire surplus from cards compared to cash.

Even if cards are cheaper, so merchants would have strictly preferred them (had they been

priced according to their cost), a tourist-test fee eliminates any such preferences. It compels the

merchant to be indifferent between cash and card.

The indifference test does not incentivize merchants to accept cards. It does not enable the

merchant to enjoy any savings from use of cards instead of cash, even under the assumption

that cards are a cheaper payment instrument than cash.

1066 Nicole Jonker & Mirjam Plooij, Tourist Test Interchange Fees for Card Payments: Down Or Out? 1 J. FIN.

MARKET INFRASTRUCTURE 51, 55 (2013): “[I]f the level of the interchange fee is set too high, and consequently the

acquiring fee, a merchant who accepts card payments may still decide to turn down a card payment of a nonrepeat

customer (“the tourist”) with both cash and cards in their wallet. That way, the merchant reduces their operating

costs. However, from a social point of view it would have been better if this nonrepeat customer had used their

card”. 1067 Dominique Forest & Vaigauskaite Dovile, EC Competition Policy in the Payments Area: New Developments in

MIFs for Cards and SEPA Direct Debit, 2 EC COMPETITION POL'Y NEWSL. 38, 39 (2009): “The tourist test provides a

reasonable benchmark for assessing a MIF level that generates benefits to merchants and final consumers. It determines

a MIF that allows the promotion of efficient payment instruments, while at the same time preventing the MIF from

exploiting business-stealing effects to the detriment of the merchants and their subsequent customers, which would lead

to an inefficient promotion of payment instruments that impose invisible costs on consumers”. 1068 Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees, supra note 884, at 11: “The interchange according to the maximum Tourist

Test (MIFm0b) would transfer all net benefits from the acquiring/merchant side to the issuing/cardholder side. It can

therefore also be labelled the MIF resulting in merchant zero-level benefits”.

Page 247: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

247

591. Second, the indifference test does not account for the heterogeneity of merchants. One

interchange fee can be efficient only if merchants are homogeneous.1069 However, some

merchants have larger costs of handling cash than others. Whenever merchants are

heterogeneous (in the utility they derive from cards), then even if the fee is calibrated to fit the

average benefit of merchants, marginal merchants pay more than their utility, in contradiction

to the underlying logic of the tourist test.1070 Whenever merchants are heterogeneous, the

indifference test, by definition, yields multiple fees, and not just one uniform fee.1071

592. Third, the tourist test requires detailed data on the differences between the costs and benefits of

both cash and cards. Quantification of the avoided costs of cash is difficult to estimate,1072 and

varies between merchants who are heterogeneous.1073 In addition, the data does not only vary

between merchants, but even between the same merchant over time.1074

593. Fourth, the indifference test requires additional supervision to ensure its effectiveness. The

economic justification to charge a utility based fee is to transfer to cardholders the gap between

the (purportedly high) avoided costs of cash and the (purportedly low) costs of cards, as

discounts, rewards and rebates, so as to encourage them to use cards instead of cash. The tourist

test does not allow markups to remain with issuers or acquirers as profit. Any such profit

indicates a failure of the tourist test.1075

594. Fifth, the tourist test determines an interchange fee which is based on negative utility and not

on cost – merchants’ benefits from the avoided costs of cash. Pricing that is based on demand

(benefits) and not on supply (costs), is actually a shift from realm of competition, where price

1069 Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 67, at 19: "The tourist test is a reliable tool

in the case of constant issuer margins and homogeneous merchants (Rochet and Tirole (2011))”. 1070 Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards, supra note 1064, at 486: “[M]erchants are heterogenous, and an IF that properly

guides cardholders’ decisions must reflect the average, not the marginal merchant benefit. This implies that the

merchants who benefit least from the card, say the large retailers, are likely to fail the tourist test at the social

optimum”. 1071 Richard Schmalensee, Interchange Fees, Market Failure, and Remedies (June 15, 2011), available at

https://www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/assets/Free/Schmalensee-transcriptupdate.pdf: "[T]he test is not

defined when merchants differ, when merchants have different net convenience benefits from card transactions."; H

Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees, supra note 884, at 12: “The theoretical contributions do not indicate clearly

which parameters would be required for establishing the MIFopt or how market data should be collected for estimating

the parameters. This will be more difficult in practice, as neither cardholders nor merchants comprise a homogeneous

group of agents with identical benefit and cost structures”. 1072 For expansion on costs of payment instruments see infra ch. 5.1. 1073 Supra ¶ 591. 1074 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 923, at 48: “[T]he tourist test requires

detailed information on transactional costs and benefits of cards and cash to merchants. These benefits and costs are

likely complex and may vary substantially across merchants as well as across types of transactions, even for a given

merchant”. 1075 Emilio Calvano, Action on Payment Cards (a Few) Insights from Theory, at 6 (June 15, 2011): "Whenever there is

an epsilon markup somewhere the TTIF fails."

Page 248: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

248

is determined by costs (p=mc adjusted to our case: Pm+Pc=Ci+Ca),1076 to the world of market

power. This is problematic when done in a legally approved restrictive arrangement.

595. Sixth, costs of card transactions are constantly declining because of scale efficiencies and

technological improvements.1077 The cost of cash involves concreate inputs and labor which

become more expensive over time.1078 This means that the tourist test should increase with time.

The unfortunate implication is that progress and efficiency become a factor in price increases

instead of price reductions. This also reduces incentives of merchants to invest in smart

acquiring, because a tourist test fee implies they would not benefit from any cost savings.1079

596. Seventh, the tourist test ignores the inherent benefits of cardholders from cards.1080 If the benefit

to a cardholder from using her/his card is large enough, then the cardholder will use the card

(and not cash) anyway. When cardholders’ benefits from cards is sufficient, there is no need to

charge merchants a (high) MSF that extracts all of their utility from cards, in order to encourage

cardholders to use cards. Cardholders would use their cards anyway, even with a lower MSF,

and retail prices would be also lower.1081

8.3. United States

597. Until the end of the 1970s, interchange fees in U.S. payment card market were fixed by banks

who were members of the open networks, Visa and MasterCard. The banks were operating on

both sides of the networks as both issuers and acquirers.

1076 For expansion, see ¶ 171. 1077 See ¶¶ 143, 125. 1078 See ch. 0. 1079 Nicole Jonker & Mirjam Plooij, Tourist Test Interchange Fees for Card Payments: Down Or Out? 1 J. FIN.

MARKET INFRASTRUCTURE 51 (2013); Bolt, Pricing, Competition and Innovation in Retail Payment Systems: A Brief

Overview, supra note 12, at 73: “Due to large-scale effects, the average cost of a (debit) card transaction continues to

decrease, while the average cost of a cash payment is increasing. Applying the tourist test methodology would then

predict higher (future) interchange fees for payment cards, so as to maintain the indifference level between cash and

cards.”; Wilko Bolt, Nicole Jonker & Mirjam Plooij, Tourist Test or Tourist Trap?, supra note 209, at 25: “The main

drivers of the increase in Tourist Test MIF level are the rising costs for cash and declining costs for debit card payments

for merchants. Over time, scale and scope effects increase these cost differentials even further. If banks would base their

acquiring fees on the Tourist Test methodology for debit card payments, merchants are discouraged to invest in

acceptance and efficiency of debit card payments. The reason is that merchants would hardly benefit from any of the

efficiency gains that arise from increased debit card usage or improvements in the infrastructure for card payments, as

these are (partly) neutralized by rising acquiring fees. With merchants having less incentive to stimulate card payments,

the application of the Tourist Test could slow down the existing trend of increasing the use of debit cards. In a market

where the social costs of debit card payments are now lower than those of cash, this would mean that potential social

cost savings are not realized.”; Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees, supra note 302, at 9: “[S]etting the interchange

fee close to the "tourist test level" would result in almost total elimination of the development incentive”. 1080 See infra note 614. 1081 For expansion see infra ch. 6.9.4 (Consumer Welfare Optimal Interchange Fee).

Page 249: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

249

598. In 1979, NaBanco, a firm that served as an acquirers' processing agent, filed a suit against

Visa.1082 NaBanco was a back-office processor. It collected transaction slips for acquirers and

then presented them to issuers for payment to merchants. Issuers deducted the interchange fee

from the payments. NaBanco remitted to merchants funds it received from issuers, and shared

the MSF (minus the interchange fee that was deduced by the issuers) with the formal acquirers.

NaBanco therefore had a strong incentive to lower the interchange fee. The lower the

interchange fee the more profit could be retained by NaBanco.

However, all issuers to whom NaBanco applied demanded the same interchange fee, which was

the fee dictated by Visa or MasterCard organizations. Thus, in 1978, NaBanco filed a lawsuit

that challenged the interchange fee as a horizontal minimum price-fixing agreement. The claim

stated that the uniform interchange fee was a per-se price-fixing violation proscribed under

section 1 of the Sherman Act.

599. Visa submitted expert opinions explaining what today we would call the principles of a two-

sided market.1083 One of the experts was Professor Baxter, who later published the first major

article in this field.1084 Visa argued that contrary to a cartel that leads to lower output and higher

price than competitive equilibrium, the interchange fee was designated to increase output and

lower prices for cardholders.

600. The court accepted the position of Visa and dismissed the claim. The court held that Visa did

not possess significant market power,1085 because the relevant market included all payment

instruments, including cash and checks.1086 The court rejected the argument that interchange

fee was a per-se restrictive arrangement. It scrutinized and confirmed the legality of the

interchange fee under the rule of reason standard, as a necessary instrument for Visa to operate

efficiently.1087

601. The court's conclusion has been based on several foundations:

1082 National Bancard Corp. (NaBanco) v. VISA, 596 F. Supp. 1231 (S.D of Fla, LEXIS 23432 1984). 1083 For two-sided markets see infra ch. 7.1. 1084 For expansion on the model of Baxter see infra ch. 6.2. 1085 NaBanco, supra note 182, at 1251: “Consideration of the relevant market reveals that VISA has no significant

market power”. 1086Id. at 1257. 1087Id. at 1253: “Given this background of jurisprudence, the Court concludes that IRF should be analyzed under the

rule of reason because it is an agreement on the terms of interchange necessary for VISA to market its product and be

an effective competitor”.

Page 250: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

250

601.1 Thorough calculation of the interchange fee that was presented to court, and was

based on costs, led the court to conclude that without interchange fee, issuers’ costs

could not be covered (i.e., cardholder fees and interest on credit, were not sufficient

for covering all costs of issuers), thus without interchange fee issuers would be in

"deficit".

601.2 The court conceptualized interchange fee as similar to internal payments that exist in

closed networks like American Express.

601.3 The court held that interchange fees would not be set too high, because most issuers

were also acquirers who, presumably, would object paying excessively high

interchange fees.

601.4 The number of acquirers and issuers was too large for bilateral agreements. Without

a default interchange fee, transactions in which an issuer has no prior agreement with

an acquirer could occur. In such cases issuers could supposedly, extort excessive ex-

post interchange fees for their consent to transfer transactions' funds to acquirers.1088

602. Before continuing, it should be noted that the arguments of NaBanco are no longer valid in light

of changed realities.

Market Power

603. Market power is the ability to raise prices significantly above the competitive level without

suffering losses from this increase.1089 In 2001, a U.S. federal court held in a governmental

proceeding (discussed below),1090 that contrary to the holding in NaBanco, both Visa and

MasterCard had market power.1091 The reasoning was that merchants could not resist increases

in the fees they pay, because of fear of desertion by customers. Merchants weigh “strategic

considerations” that cause them to accept cards even in the presence of market power. The court

noted that even though Visa and MasterCard raised their interchange fees significantly, they

1088Id. at 1261-62. But see an answer to the "extortion" argument infra ch. 8.3.5, 1089 United States v. Am. Express Co., 21 F. Supp. 3d 187, 195 (E.D.N.Y. 2014): “Market power is the ability to raise

price significantly above the competitive level "without losing all of one's business”. For a different definition see

United States v. Am. Express Co., 2016 U.S. App. LEXIS 17502 (2d Cir. N.Y. Sept. 26, 2016): "Market power is the

power to force a purchaser to do something that he would not do in a competitive market." Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S….

see also E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. at 391 ("[Market] power is the power to control prices or exclude

competition.")." 1090 Infra ch. 8.3.6. 1091 United States v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 163 F. Supp. 2d 322, 340 (S.D.N.Y. 2001); aff'd in United States v. Visa U.S.A.,

Inc., 344 F.3d 229, 239-240 (2d Cir. N.Y. 2003).

Page 251: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

251

did not lose market share. This is a significant indicator of market power. Other indicators of

market power the court found were price discrimination between categories of merchants in the

MSF (as the ability to carry out price discrimination is also an indicator of market power),1092

and high barriers to entry. In the words of the court:

[Merchants] cannot refuse to accept Visa and MasterCard even in the face of

significant price increases because the cards are such preferred payment methods

that customers would choose not to shop at merchants who do not accept them. In

addition, both Visa and MasterCard have recently raised interchange rates charged

to merchants a number of times, without losing a single merchant customer as a

result... Defendants' ability to price discriminate also illustrates their market power.

Both Visa and MasterCard charge differing interchange fees based, in part, on the

degree to which a given merchant category needs to accept general purpose cards…

whether considered jointly or separately, the defendants have market power…

Furthermore, there are significant barriers to entry into the general purpose card

network services market.1093

Visa and MasterCard appealed this decision. Their appeal was denied, and the court held

again that they both have market power.1094

604. Market power in the field of payment cards is the ability to make a permanent and significant

increase in the price level, at least on one side (cardholders or merchants), without suffering a

loss from the price increase. This is in fact a SSNIP test, known for defining relevant markets,

adjusted for two-sided markets.1095 In the European MasterCard decision, the Commission

warned that like with ordinary products, SSNIP test may yield false results if at the initial stage

of the investigation, prices are already inflated because they reflect existing market power (a

situation known as the "Cellophane Fallacy").1096

605. In a more recent battle in the U.S. between the Department Of Justice and American Express

over anti-steering provisions in American Express contracts with merchants, the court ruled in

1092 OECD, POLICY ROUNDTABLE, COMPETITION AND EFFICIENT USAGE OF PAYMENT CARDS, at 9

DAF/COMP(2006)32: “[P]rice discrimination exists both for cards with large market shares and for cards with small

market shares… Some would interpret this price discrimination as an indication of market power". 1093 United States v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 163 F. Supp. 2d 322, 339-40 (S.D.N.Y. 2001). 1094 United States v. Visa, 344 F .3d 229 (CA 2d Dist. 2003): "We agree with the district court's finding that Visa U.S.A.

and MasterCard, jointly and separately, have power within the market for network services.”; cert. denied, Visa U. S. A.,

Inc. v. United States, 543 U.S. 811 (2004). 1095 United States v. Am. Express Co., 2015 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 20114, 85-86 (E.D.N.Y. Feb. 19, 2015): “[A] relevant

product market is properly defined if a hypothetical profit-maximizing monopolist that is the only seller of the

product(s) included in the proposed market could profitably impose a small but significant and non-transitory price

increase ("SSNIP") - i.e., without losing so many sales to other products that its price became unprofitable. By contrast,

if buyers are able and inclined to switch away from the product(s) in numbers sufficient to render the SSNIP

unprofitable, the proposed market definition likely needs to be expanded.”; Erich Emch, Market Definition and Market

Power in Payment Card Networks, 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 45 (2006); Lapo Filistrucchi, A SSNIP Test for Two-Sided

Markets: The Case of Media (NET Inst. Working Paper 08-34. 2008): "In a two-sided market as the payment cards one

the hypothetical monopolist should be thought of as raising the price level, adjusting optimally the price structure”. 1096 Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 1027, paras. 286-87.

Page 252: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

252

February 2015 that American Express also has market power.1097 The market share of American

Express in the U.S. is second to Visa but higher than MasterCard.1098 However, American

Express appealed successfully. The Court of Appeals for the 2nd district ruled on September

2016 that American Express's power to raise the MSF is not sufficient to indicate market power.

According to the court of appeals Amex's anti-steering rules, designed to enable low cardholder

fees, do not indicate market power.1099 The U.S. Government applied for rehearing en-banc,

and the petition is pending (November 2016).1100

606. Price discrimination (i.e., categories), and very high profitability, in comparison to other sectors

of the financial sector, also imply that networks possess market power.1101 Moreover, market

power indicators appear also on cardholders' side. An increase in cardholder fees had not

reduced payment cards adoption or usage, as would be expected to occur when firms without

market power increase their prices.1102

607. Since NaBanco decision, tribunals in other countries have also determined that contrary to

NaBanco ruling, both Visa and MasterCard have market power, on both sides of the market. In

1097 Am. Express Co., supra note 1095: “[T]he court concludes that American Express does possess antitrust market

power in the GPCC card network services market sufficient to cause an adverse effect on competition. Specifically, the

court finds that Defendants enjoy significant market share in a highly concentrated market with high barriers to entry,

and are able to exercise uncommon leverage over their merchant-consumers due to the amplifying effect of cardholder

insistence and derived demand. In addition, American Express's ability to impose significant price increases during its

Value Recapture initiatives between 2005 and 2010 without any meaningful merchant attrition is compelling evidence

of Defendants' power in the network service market”. 1098 Ibid: “Today, American Express is the second largest GPCC card network when measured by charge volume. As of

2013, Amex accounted for 26.4% of general purpose credit and charge card purchase volume in the United States. It

trails only Visa's 45% market share, and is larger than both MasterCard (23.3%) and Discover (5.3%)”. 1099 United States v. Am. Express Co., 2016 U.S. App. LEXIS 17502 (2d Cir. N.Y. Sept. 26, 2016). 1100 United States v. Am. Express Co., Petition Of The United States And Plaintiff States For Panel Rehearing And

Rehearing En Banc, (Nov. 10, 2016) https://www.justice.gov/atr/case-document/file/910116/download 1101 NICHOLAS ECONOMIDES, COMPETITION POLICY ISSUES IN THE CONSUMER PAYMENTS INDUSTRY, in MOVING

MONEY: THE FUTURE OF CONSUMER PAYMENT 113, 114 ( R. Litan & M. Baily eds., 2009): “Both Visa and MasterCard

charge fees (primarily to merchants) that are significantly above costs—some report that total card costs are only 13 to

15 percent of the fees charged and that total fees are about $30 to $48 billion per year. This combination of fees that are

significantly above cost and high market shares suggests that current fees reflect market power”.

1102 AT 4630/01 Leumi v. General Director (Aug. 31, 2006) ("The Methodology Decision"), at 20: (despite increase in

cardholders’ fees adoption and usage increased). For the same effect in Spain, see Santiago Carbo Valverde et al.,

Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation, at 8 (FED. RES. BANK OF CHICAGO WP 09-11 2009):

“Spanish consumers increased their holdings of credit cards even when annual fees increased suggesting that the market

for credit cards had not reached its saturation point and consumers are willing to pay higher fees in exchange for greater

merchant acceptance”.

Page 253: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

253

Europe,1103 in an OECD roundtable,1104 and in Israel,1105 the conclusions of the respective

Tribunals were that Visa and MasterCard have market power.

Cost Coverage

608. In NaBanco, the interchange fee was set according to the ratio between the average costs of

issuers (numerator) to the pecuniary volume of card transactions (denominator).1106 Interchange

fee at that rate covers total costs of issuers.

609. Regarding the numerator, costs have fallen dramatically over the years (causing the numerator

to decrease). Tremendous technological improvements in the payment industry have occurred

since NaBanco. Nowadays, processing, approval, authorization, clearance and payment phases

are all done electronically. At the time of NaBanco acquiring was done manually with

designated “irons” and paper slips that had to be manually collected and authorized. The process

was labor intensive and time consuming. Today, there is almost full digitization of the payment

process and manual acquiring has been replaced by cheaper and faster electronic process.

Economies of scale also have contributed to lower costs per transaction. Regarding the

denominator, volume of transactions has increased dramatically since NaBanco.1107

610. If the interchange fee was indeed purely a device for covering issuers’ costs, it should have

been reduced significantly since NaBanco.1108 In reality, however, the interchange fee in the

U.S., as a ratio between costs and volumes, has increased dramatically. It is obvious that U.S.

interchange fee is used not only for covering costs, as was the excuse in NaBanco. The

interchange fee in the U.S. is well above costs (supra note 1101). Without derogating from the

1103 EC, INTERIM REPORT, supra note 79, at 77: “[T]he high and persistent profit ratios found by this inquiry in

relatively mature markets, together with other evidence collected on entry barriers, suggest the existence and exercise of

market power in these markets”. 1104 OECD, ROUNDTABLE ON COMPETITION AND EFFICIENT USAGE OF PAYMENT CARDS, supra note 1092, at 8: "[I]t is

likely that payment systems do have market power towards merchants, even if a given payment system has a small

share of transactions, as long as the systems have broad acceptance". 1105 Monopoly Declaration on Isracart, supra note 908, at 11 (indications that the payment card firms have market

power over merchants). 1106 NaBanco, supra note 182 at 1262: “cost-based methodology using systemwide average costs ." 1107 Ann Kjos, The Merchant-Acquiring Side of the Payment Card Industry: Structure, Operations, and Challenges, at

11 (F.R.B Phil' Discussion Paper 2007): “Technological innovations, economies of scale, and low-risk business models

are characteristics that have helped shape the industry’s current structure". 1108 Semeraro, Credit Cards Interchange Fees: Three Decades of Antitrust Uncertainty, supra note 64, at 974-75: "As

technology has improved and transaction volume soared, one might expect per transaction costs, and thus interchange

fees, to fall. Unlike the non-interchange fee portion of the merchant discount, however, between 1995 and 2005,

interchange fees rose more than 25 percent."; David B. Humphrey, Payment Scale Economies, Competition, and

Pricing (ECB Working Paper No. 1136. 2009) (Graphs showing how costs per transactions decreased over time), at 26:

“relating bank operating cost to point of sale and bill payment transaction volumes across 11 European countries over

1987-2004 suggests that a doubling of payment volume increases operating expenses by only around 27%, so average

payment costs could potentially fall by 37%”.

Page 254: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

254

general criticism of cost-based interchange fees,1109 the "covering costs" excuse cited in

NaBanco, not only does not hold anymore, but has over the years evolved into a pretext for

profits.1110

The interchange Fee As Internal Transfer

611. In 2001, Ahlborn et al wrote:

"The interchange fee does not provide a source of profits to the co-operative or its

members. The co-operative itself does not receive the interchange fees; the fee is

simply a payment from acquirers to issuers".1111

612. With all due respect, this is not accurate. It is true that interchange fees are not directly

transferred to the international organizations like Visa or MasterCard. Nevertheless, contrary

to Ahlborn, interchange fee proceeds are transferred to issuers who are the owners of the

international organizations, and do serve as a major source of profit. Issuers control the

international organizations, and determine the interchange fee to maximize their profits.1112

613. The interchange fee is not an internal transfer payment. Interchange fees are paid by merchants

as part of their MSF, and are transferred to issuers via acquirers. This does not turn interchange

fee to be an internal payment. In fact, interchange fees inflate issuers’ income. As long as

acquirers are also connected directly or indirectly to the issuing side, acquirers also enjoy

interchange fee proceeds, according to their market share on the issuing side.1113 Even if a large

1109 Supra ch. 8.1.1(Criticism Of The Cost-Based Methodology). 1110 Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L. REV. 1321,

1332-33 n. 22 (2008): "Whatever underlying theoretical basis now might be concocted in defense of the interchange

fee, the credit card issuers themselves see it as a method of funding rewards programs (and other costs), as well as an

independent profit center.";

Steven Semerraro, The Reverse Robin Hood Cross Subsidy Hypothesis: Do Credit Cards Systems Tax the Poor and

Reward the Rich? 40 RUTGERS L.J. 419, 423 (2009): "Interchange fees essentially tax merchants by requiring them to

pay card issuers a fee for the right to accept cards that exceeds the issuers’ cost (plus normal profit) of the service that

the merchants receive.";

For the same conclusion in Europe see EC, INTERIM REPORT, supra note 79, at 77: "[T]he above findings on the

profitability of payment card issuing cast doubt on the assumption that in the absence of interchange fees, issuers could

not recoup their costs from card-holders . . . seem[ingly] . . . confirm[ing] some recent theoretical predictions in the

literature on two-sided markets suggesting that privately optimal interchange fees may be too high, notably if merchant

fees increase with interchange fees but issuers do not pass the additional interchange fee revenue back to cardholders. In

this case, high interchange fees are a way to transfer rents to the side of the scheme where they are least likely to be

competed away". 1111 Christian Ahlborn, Howard H. Chang & David S. Evans, The Problem of Interchange Fee Analysis: Case without a

Cause? 2 PAYMENT CARD REV. 183, 194 (2004). 1112 David Balto, The Problem of Interchange Fees: Costs without Benefits? E.C.L.R 215, 221 (2000); see also infra ch.

6.9.2 (Privately set interchange fee by issuers) . 1113 Case T-111/08 MasterCard v. Comm'n, para. 254(May 24, 2012): “[t]he MIF remains a source of revenue for the

banks in so far as they also have an issuing business... the NAWIR (No Acquiring Without Issuing Rule) — which

obliged banks wishing to acquire transactions also to have a card issuing business, virtually all banks engaged in the

Page 255: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

255

acquirer is only a small issuer, it enjoys a positive flow from the interchange fee, according to

its market share on the issuing side, while not “suffering" from the payment of the interchange

fee on the acquiring side, because it is passed through to merchants.1114 Thus, the reasoning in

NaBanco, viewing the interchange fee as an internal payment, cannot hold.

Bilateral Agreements

614. In NaBanco, the court held that it was not practical to cover the market with bilateral

agreements, because of the large number of issuers and acquirers. This argument is not

applicable in concentrated markets such as Israel, which has only three payment card firms.

Without the Trio Agreement only three agreements would have been required to cover the entire

market.1115 In addition, some scholars have argued that bilateral agreements are currently

applicable, because markets, on both sides, have become centralized, so only relatively small

number of agreements is needed to cover most of the market.1116

615. In my view, this argument from the NaBanco decision is still valid. Bilateral agreements are

not feasible. Transactions in which there are no prior agreement between the issuer and the

acquirer, e.g., tourists' transactions, would forever occur. Even if bilateral agreements were

feasible, bilateral interchange fee that would have been determined (in bilateral negotiations),

would not abate the competitive concerns. The problem is that as long as acquirers have

interests on the issuing side, the acquirer will forever agree to pay (in bilateral negotiation) high

acquiring business were also card issuers and benefited, to that extent, from the MIF.”; Comp/34.579 European

Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 570, para. 385; see also supra ¶ 35, (n.75) ([T]he setting of interchange fee

rates is not akin to a contentious process such as a price negotiation where opposing interests of buyers and sellers

meet). See also ¶ 0104 , ¶ 613 (Even if a large acquirer is only a small issuer, it enjoys a positive flow from the

interchange fee, according to its market share on the issuing side, while not “suffering" from the payment of the

interchange fee on the acquiring side, because it is passed through to merchants); ¶ 615, ¶ 620, ¶ 692, ¶ 781, Infra note

1436. For my proposal with respect to this distortion, see infra ch. 0 (Structural Separation Between Issuers And

Acquirers) 1114 See also supra ¶¶ 35, 97. 1115 Supra ¶ 85. 1116 NICHOLAS ECONOMIDES, COMPETITION POLICY ISSUES IN THE CONSUMER PAYMENTS INDUSTRY, supra note 1101, at

122: "[T]here is significant concentration among acquirers, with 86 percent of all Visa and MasterCard volume

generated by the top ten acquiring banks. Similarly, 84 percent of this volume is generated by the top ten issuers.

Therefore ninety contracts generate 72 percent of all MasterCard and Visa volume."; Frankel & Shampine, The

Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 64, at 640-41 (2006): “The top ten acquirers account for about 86

percent of all MasterCard and Visa bank card dollar charge volume, while the top ten issuers account for 84 percent

of charge volume. No more than 90 contracts— not millions—would therefore be required to cover 72 percent of

all charge volume. Individual banks not interested in direct contracts with many other banks need only shop for a

single correspondent services contract. Particularly with modern data processing and communications technology,

such correspondent relationships can be quick and efficient”.

Page 256: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

256

interchange fee, knowing that in its role as issuer, it will profit from this supra competitive fee.

This is true regardless the number of issuers or acquirers.1117

Issuers’ Extortion Position

616. The "hold-out" argument in favor of interchange fees was raised by Baxter and adopted in

NaBanco. According to this argument, in the absence of ex-ante agreement, and because of the

HAC rule that compels every merchant who accepts Visa or MasterCard, to accept all cards of

that brand (regardless of the issuer's identity), issuers have a strong upper hand and can extort

from acquirers ex-post monopolistic interchange fees.1118

The hold-out argument continues as follows: The extortion position of issuers could saddle not

only merchants but also cardholders, with constant uncertainty. In the absence of prior

agreement between the merchant’s acquirer and the cardholder’s issuer, merchants might totally

refuse to accept cards that might reveal ex-poste too costly (if the issuer extorts excessive

interchange fee). Cardholders in such case would always have to be prepared to pay with cash.

This would destroy one of the main advantages of payment card networks. If surcharging is

allowed, then merchants, who are compelled to pay high MSF, would pass through this high

price to cardholders. Cardholders again would have to be in constant alert, and be prepared to

pay with a different payment instrument. The value of cards would be diminished. The

interchange fee is thus required, according to this argument, to prevent this ex-post hold-out

position of issuers.1119

1117 For expansion see infra ch. 12.1 (Bilateral Interchange Fees). 1118 William F. Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper: Legal and Economic Perspectives 26 J.L. ECON. 541,

577 (1983): “Accordingly, It is essential that the participants in a four-party payment system collectively adopt some

internal mechanism that prevents individual exploitation of the monopsony power endemic to such systems”. 1119 Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations, 33 RAND J.

ECON. 549, 550 (2002): “To see the benefits of a centrally determined interchange fee cum the honor-all-cards rule, it

suffices to envision the complexity of bilateral bargaining among thousands of banks as well as the cost for issuers

(respectively, merchants) of informing consumers about the set of merchants (respectively, banks) with whom an

agreement has been reached. The latter transactions costs could be avoided by keeping the honor-all-cards rule while

letting issuers and acquirers set their pairwise interchange fees. However, an individual issuer would then be able to

impose an arbitrarily high interchange fee, since the acquirer would then face the grim choice between accepting

this fee on a fraction of his payments and exiting the industry altogether. Individual issuers would become

bottlenecks, and their free riding would dissuade acquirers from entering the industry.”;

Marc Rysman & Julian Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, at 18 (2015): “[I]t is difficult to combine the “honor

all cards” rule with bilateral interchange negotiation because it leads to a hold-up problem, in which a single issuer

might refuse to deal with acquirers unless they accept its demands for a particularly high interchange fee.”;

Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 923, at 19: “The logic is as follows: In the

absence of common terms of exchange between banks, each issuer could set its own interchange fee. However, an

honor-all-cards rule would require that every merchant that accepts a particular network brand and type of card (e.g.,

Visa credit card) accept every card with that brand and type, regardless of the level of the interchange fee set by the

issuer. As a result, an honor-all-cards rule with bilaterally negotiated interchange fees would introduce the possibility of

Page 257: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

257

617. The hold-out argument (that without ex-ante interchange fee, issuers would be in an ex-post

extortion position towards acquirers with whom they have no prior agreement), is flawed for

two main reasons:

618. First, Legally, Article 7 of the Payment Card Law anchors the fundamental obligation of

issuers, to pay merchants for all transactions performed by the issuers’ cardholders. In other

legal systems issuers are also obliged to remit to merchants the sums due for purchases made

by their cardholders. This obligation is binding even if the acquirer does not agree to pay any

interchange fee to the issuer. Therefore, acquirers could also allegedly extort issuers.1120

619. Second, the hold-out argument assumes a default rule, under which issuers are entitled to

demand interchange whatsoever. This assumption is incorrect. There is no such binding default

rule. On the contrary, the default rule might just as well be that in the absence of advance

agreement, the issuer must remit to the acquirer the full sums due (i.e., default rule of zero

interchange fee). Under this default, which is no less plausible, an issuer would be prohibited

from requiring ex post interchange fee, unless acceptable by the acquirer.1121 This will put an

end to any holdout argument.

a “holdup problem”... That is, an individual issuing bank could demand very high interchange fees from acquiring

banks. The acquirers would then factor the high fees charged by this issuer into the merchant discounts that they charge

their merchants. A merchant, in turn, could avoid those fees only by rejecting all of a network’s cards of that type, in

which case card acceptance could be inefficiently low. A common interchange fee avoids this holdup problem.”;

David S. Evans & Richard Schmalensee, The Economics of Interchange Fees and their Regulation: An Overview,

Payments System Research Conferences, 73, 84 (2005): ”As long as an honor-all-cards rule is in effect, so that

merchants are required to accept all cards of a given brand, an acquirer is at a significant disadvantage in negotiations

with other issuing banks, since its merchant is required to accept their cards, but it has no guarantee of payment by the

card issuer.”;

Ahlborn et al., The Problem of Interchange Fee, supra note 1111, at 193: "[W]ithout agreement, issuing banks could

refuse to honour acquiring bank transactions and thereby “hold up” the acquiring banks for huge interchange fees.";

Benjamin Klein et al., Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Antitrust Economics of Payment Card Interchange Fees,

73 ANTITRUST L.J. 571, 574 (2006): “Given an honor-all-cards rule, bilaterally negotiated interchange fees in the

absence of a default interchange fee would create an incentive for individual card issuers in an open-loop payment card

system to “hold up” acquirers by demanding arbitrarily high interchange fees on transactions made with their cards. In

particular, individual Visa and MasterCard issuers would have the incentive to take advantage of the fact that merchants

accepting Visa or MasterCard have agreed to honor-all-cards to make unreasonably high interchange fee demands. Such

demands would impose an externality on the entire payment card system, and eventually lead some merchants to drop

acceptance of the payment system's cards. A default interchange fee prevents such holdups by placing a cap on

interchange fees that can be bilaterally negotiated between individual issuers and individual acquirers in the Visa and

MasterCard payment systems”. 1120 John Simon, Payment Systems are Different: Shouldn’t their Regulation be Too?, 4 REV. NETWORK ECON. 364, 366

(2005): “[B]oth issuers and acquirers have hold-up power over any negotiations. This simultaneous hold-up power

means that, once established, it is difficult for interchange fees in a bilateral system to be reset as economic

circumstances change”. 1121 Alan S. Frankel & Allan L. Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 627, 642

(2006); K. Craig Wildfang & Ryan W. Marth, The Persistence of Antitrust Controversy and Litigation in Credit Card

Networks, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 675 (2006): "This argument, however, presumes that some interchange fee must be paid

for the network to function… For the hold-up problem to justify the collective setting of a fee, it is first necessary to

conclude that the transfer of some fee is necessary in the first place. The success of four-party networks that function

Page 258: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

258

620. On July 2016 the British Competition Appeal Tribunal entered a long judgement in the case of

Sainsbury v. MasterCard.1122 The tribunal analyzed what would be the consequences of a

transaction made without a prior interchange fee agreement. It concluded that the extortion

argument is flawed. Due to the Honor All Cards rule, without prior arrangement, issuers would

have to remit to acquirers transactions' funds with no deduction:

"We do not consider that it would be open to an Issuing Bank simply

to deduct from its settlement obligation any amount that it saw fit.

Indeed, it is significant that the Commission described this in

paragraph 554 of its Decision (The European MasterCard Decision –

O.B) as an “abuse”, and that is exactly what it would be. According

to the MasterCard Scheme Rules, a deduction from the settlement

obligation must be authorized – and if it is not authorized, it cannot

be made… Absent a bilateral agreement between the Issuing Bank

and the Acquiring Bank, no deduction representing a charge for

interchange would be permissible in the no-MIF or zero MIF world"

(ibid paras. 149-151).

Thus, the hold-out problem is not issuers' potential extortion position, because acquirers are

able to offset such position. The problem of the interchange fee is that as long as acquirers are

also issuers, or connected through ownership to issuers, acquirers would gladly surrender in

any ex-ante or ex-post negotiation, and agree to pay a high interchange fee, knowing that they

themselves will receive the same interchange fee, in another transaction, in which they will be

the issuers.1123

621. Getting back to the history of payment cards, after the NaBanco decision was given (in 1984),

there was a lull of years, without any attempt to challenge the interchange fee. Other restrictive

arrangements in open networks were more successfully challenged.

The Elimination Of Issuing Prohibitions

622. In 1998, the U.S. Department of Justice filed a civil suit against Visa and MasterCard. The suit

challenged the legality of the bylaws of Visa and MasterCard, which had prohibited banks that

issued Visa and MasterCard, from also issuing the competing cards of rivals Discover and

effectively without interchange fees is inconsistent with such a conclusion."; Steven Semeraro, The Antitrust Economics

(and Law) of Surcharging Credit Card Transactions, 14 STAN. J. L. BUS. & FIN. 343, 381 n. 162 (2009); see also supra

¶ 579 (ECJ MasterCard Decision). 1122 Sainsbury’s supermarkets v. MasterCard, (July 14, 2016) http://www.catribunal.org.uk/237-9006/1241-5-7-15-T-Sainsburys-Supermarkets-Ltd.html 1123 Supra ¶ 35 (n.75), 104, 613. For my proposal to correct this distortion see infra ch. 0.

Page 259: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

259

American Express.1124 Interestingly that same rule in the bylaws did not consider Visa and

MasterCard to be competitors, and therefore did not prohibit issuers of Visa from issuing

MasterCard, or vice versa…

623. In 2001, following the ruling that both Visa and MasterCard had market power,1125 the court

accepted the claim and prohibited Visa and MasterCard from preventing their members to issue

American Express or Discover cards.1126 Indeed, after the decision, American Express, which

operated until then as a closed system, began issuing cards through banks with whom it

partnered.1127

In 2007, The European Commission reached the same conclusion with respect to Visa's bylaws

that prevented Morgan Stanley Bank, issuer of Diners Cards, to be member of Visa.1128 In 2011,

the General Court affirmed this decision, opening doors for banks to be members of open

networks as well as closed networks.1129

Partial Cancellation Of The HAC Rule

624. In 1996, several class actions were filed against Visa and MasterCard, claiming that because of

the HAC rule, merchants were not allowed to accept only debit cards. In 2000, the court

certified, accepting plaintiffs' argument that the HAC rule is in fact a tying arrangement,

according to which cheap debit cards are tied to expensive credit cards, and although debit card

interchange fees should have been lower than credit card interchange fees, Visa and MasterCard

tied them together on the same level.1130 As a result a merchant that accepted cheaper Visa or

MasterCard debit cards was forced by the HAC rule to accept also more expensive credit cards.

1124 Commission Decision comp/d1/37860 Morgan Stanley / Visa International and Visa Europe, para. 17 (Oct. 3,

2007): "[O]n 4 December 1989, the Visa International Board of Directors adopted the following rule as an amendment

to Section 2.12b of the Visa International By-Laws:28 “… If permitted by applicable law, the Board (including

Regional Boards and Group Members) shall not accept for membership any Applicant which is deemed by the Board of

Directors to be a competitor of the corporation.”; United States v. Am. Express Co., LEXIS 20114 at 32-33 (E.D.N.Y

Feb. 19, 2015): “Visa and MasterCard maintained bylaws preventing their member banks from issuing credit cards on

competing networks, like Discover and American Express... these so-called "exclusionary rules" were removed

following the Department of Justice's successful antitrust enforcement action”. 1125 Supra ¶ 603. 1126 United Stated v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 183 F. Supp. 2d 613 (S.D.N.Y 2001), aff'd, United States v. Visa, 344 F.3d 229

(2d Cir. 2003), Cert. denied Mastercard v. United States, 543 U.S. 811 2004. 1127 United States v. Am. Express Co., LEXIS 20114 at 33 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015). 1128 Comp/d1/37860 Morgan Stanley / Visa International and Visa Europe, (Oct. 3, 2007) 1129 T‑461/07 Visa Europe Ltd v European Commission (Apr. 14, 2011). 1130 In re Visa Check/MasterMoney Antitrust Litig., 192 F.R.D. 68, 73 (E.D.N.Y. 2000): "In 1979, Visa and MasterCard

launched their off-line POS debit cards, VisaCheck and MasterMoney, respectively. Pursuant to the defendants' "honor

all cards" rule, any merchant accepting Visa or MasterCard credit cards was contractually obligated to accept

VisaCheck and MasterMoney as well. Also linked were the interchange fees: Visa and MasterCard set them for the off-

Page 260: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

260

625. These claims were consolidated into what is known as the Wall-Mart case. The litigation

continued for several years. A notable interim decision by the court held that credit cards and

debit cards are separate markets.1131 Meanwhile, in the DOJ case it was determined that both

Visa and MasterCard have market power.1132

626. In 2003, a settlement was reached whereby Visa and MasterCard paid merchants, a then record

compensation of over $ 3 billion, and partially canceled the HAC.1133 The settlement permitted

merchants to split their decision regarding the acceptance of credit and debit. Merchants could

choose to accept only debit cards or only credit cards (or both) of either Visa or MasterCard.

However, the HAC rule within debit and within credit card networks was not cancelled.

Merchants who accepted debit card (or credit card) still had to honor all the cards of the same

type, even if they bear a higher MSF. For example, premium credit cards carry a higher MSF

than regular credit cards, but merchants who chose to accept regular credit cards, had to also

accept premium credit cards, and pay their higher MSF.1134 Therefore, the HAC, even in its

restricted form, provoked criticism among scholars. The main argument was that the historical

development of the HAC and the NSR rule reveals that they were intended to protect the

network and increase certainty of card acceptance when networks were nascent.1135 Merchant

line POS debit cards at the same level as for credit cards. This equivalence occurred notwithstanding the fact that credit

cards are much more expensive for banks (due to the risks inherent in extending credit) than are debit cards… Without

the tie to credit cards, the plaintiffs allege that "retailers would not pay these fixed, supra-competitive and extortionate

VisaCheck and MasterMoney rates."... Visa and MasterCard have undertaken a number of measures to "deceive"

retailers about the off-line POS debit cards. They designed them to be "visually and electronically indistinguishable"

from credit cards so that retailers would not even know they were accepting a different form of payment, and they set

the interchange fees at the same level for debit and credit so that retailers would not notice the difference when they

were billed."; aff'd in In re Visa Check/Mastermoney Antitrust Litig. v. Visa, United States, 280 F.3d 124, 131 (2d Cir.

N.Y. 2001): "Defendants have set the interchange fees for Visa Check and MasterMoney at or near the same level as the

interchange fees for their respective credit cards despite the fact that, according to plaintiffs, credit card transactions -

which rely on the extension of credit - involve far more risk. The interchange fees for competing on-line debit cards -

where the risk of non-payment is substantially eliminated - is far lower."; cert. denied: Visa U.S.A., Inc. v. Wal-Mart

Stores, 2002 U.S. LEXIS 4394 (U.S. June 10, 2002). 1131 In re Visa Check/Mastermoney Antitrust Litig., 2003 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 4965 (E.D.N.Y. Apr. 1, 2003): "Merchant

demand for credit card services is distinct from merchant demand for debit card services". 1132 Supra ¶603. 1133 In Re Visa Check/Mastermoney Antitrust Litig. 297 F. Supp. 2d 503 (E.D.N.Y 19.12.03). 1134 Wildfang & Marth, The Persistence of Antitrust Controversy and Litigation in Credit Card Networks, 675; see also

infra ¶ 755. 1135 Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L. REV. 1321,

1328 (2008): “In the early days of credit cards, if consumers had been required to pay more at point of sale for using

cards, it is unlikely that credit cards would have become a mass-market product. No-surcharge rules allowed the card

networks to retain control over the perceived allocation of costs within the network and impose a cross subsidy on non-

cardholders so as to grow the network. Now, however, credit card networks are past the chicken-and-egg problem that

plagues new two-sided networks. Credit cards are now widely accepted by merchants and used by consumers. Credit

cards are an established product that does not need subsidization to thrive.”; See also United States v. Am. Express Co.

LEXIS 20114 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015).

Page 261: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

261

restraints were never intended to compel merchants to honor expensive cards against their will,

especially in mature networks and when cards are ubiquitous.1136

Interchange Fee Settlement

627. Since 2005, the interchange fee itself has again been under attack. In 2005 and 2006, dozens of

class actions challenging credit card interchange fees were filed, after interchange fees in the

U.S. reached very high levels relative to other countries. The lawsuits were consolidated into

the largest suit ever under the Sherman Act.1137

The plaintiffs alleged, inter alia that the interchange fee constituted prohibited horizontal price-

fixing, and that the justifications given in NaBanco allowing the interchange fee were no longer

valid. NSR rules were also challenged. The preliminary proceedings in the consolidated claim

were comprehensive and went on for years.1138

628. In July 2012 a proposed settlement agreement was submitted to the Court.1139 It provided, inter

alia: (a) Compensation to merchants of an estimated $7.25 billion (before reductions for opt-

outs); (b) Modifications to Visa and MasterCard NSR rules, so to permit merchants to surcharge

credit card transactions (Subject to few limitations, mentioned in Article 42 of the Visa

settlement and Article 55 of the MasterCard Settlement); (c) Obligations of Visa and

MasterCard to negotiate future interchange fees in good faith with merchant buying groups.1140

1136 Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs, id. at 1369: “[H]onor-all-card and no- differentiation rules have morphed

into a new role, which has nothing to do with network effects. Instead, these rules now allow all credit card networks to

lever new, more expensive product lines onto their existing merchant base."; id. at 1391: “The only reason for a

merchant to refuse to honor a particular card within a brand is because it is more expensive to accept than another of the

brand’s cards. The function served today by honor-all-cards rules is not ensuring the viability of a multi-issuer network,

but rather ensuring networks’ ability to issue high-cost cards... If the honor-all-cards rule was eliminated, merchants

would likely refuse to accept cards that had high interchange fees (and hence high merchant discount fees). This refusal

would create substantial market pressure on card issuers to stop issuing high interchange fee cards”. 1137 In re Payment Card Interchange Fee & Merchant Discount Antitrust Litigation, 398 F. Supp. 2d 1356 (J.P.M.L.

2005). See also Hearing before the S. Judiciary Comm., 109th Cong. 147 (2006) (Statement of Timothy J. Muris,

Former FTC Chairman): "[T]he largest private antitrust litigation in the hundred-plus year history of the Sherman Act". 1138 In re Payment Card Interchange Fee & Merchant Discount. Antitrust Litig., 986 F. Supp. 2d 207, 215 (E.D.N.Y.

2013): “This case has been extensively litigated for more than eight years. Discovery, which began in 2005, included

more than 400 depositions, the production and review of more than 80 million pages of documents, the exchange of 17

expert reports, and a full 32 days of expert deposition testimony”. 1139 In Re Payment Card Interchange Fee and Merchant Discount Antitrust Litigation (Settlement Agreement), 05-MD-

1720 (E.D.N.Y 2012). 1140 In re Payment Card Interchange Fee & Merchant Discount. Antitrust Litig., 986 F. Supp. 2d 207, 217 (E.D.N.Y.

2013): “On July 13, 2012, the parties filed a Memorandum of Understanding attaching a document setting forth the

terms of the settlement... The proposed Settlement Agreement provides for, among other things:• The creation of two

cash funds totaling up to an estimated $7.25 billion (before reductions for opt-outs). • Visa and MasterCard rule

modifications to permit merchants to surcharge on Visa- or MasterCard-branded credit card transactions at both the

brand and product levels. • An obligation on the part of Visa and MasterCard to negotiate interchange fees in good faith

with merchant buying groups. • Authorization for merchants that operate multiple businesses under different "trade

Page 262: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

262

On Dec. 13, 2013, the court granted final approval to the settlement, noting that: “The

settlement proceeds establish a guaranteed fund worth approximately $7.25 billion (before

reductions for opt-outs), the largest-ever cash settlement in an antitrust class action.”1141 In

January 2014, the court awarded Class Counsel Fees of $544.8 million and costs and expenses

of $27 million.1142

629. In my opinion, notwithstanding the huge amounts of compensation and attorney fees, the

settlement was insufficient. It did not resolve future interchange fees in a competitive manner.

In spite of the settlement, interchange fees in the U.S. are among the world's highest, and could

remain so. Many merchants have opted-out of the settlement, mainly because of absence future

regularization of the interchange fee.1143

630. Indeed, on June 30, 2016 the court of appeals held that plaintiffs were inadequately represented.

The appeal court vacated the district court's certification of the class action and reversed the

approval of the settlement.1144

The Durbin Amendment And Other Reforms

631. While the class action regarding credit cards proceeded, U.S. authorities initiated a

comprehensive debit reform, including deferred debit, in particular with respect to the

interchange fees.

632. In 2008, a bill was proposed to the Congress according to which, merchants could organize and

negotiate interchange fees collectively. The Bill also proposed to appoint a panel of judges that

would determine cost based "competitive" interchange fees that would prevail, if merchants and

names" or "banners" to accept Visa and/or MasterCard at fewer than all of its businesses. • The locking-in of the

reforms in the Durbin Amendment and the DOJ consent decree with Visa and MasterCard, even if those reforms are

repealed or otherwise undone”. 1141Id. at 229. 1142 In re Payment Card Interchange Fee & Merchant Discount. Antitrust Litig., 991 F. Supp. 2d 437, (E.D.N.Y. 2014) 1143 MarketWatch, Retail group opts out of Visa, MasterCard pact (Apr. 11, 2013) available at

http://www.marketwatch.com/story/retail-group-opts-out-of-visa-mastercard-pact-2013-04-11 : "They argue the

settlement will do little to keep the cost of interchange fees from rising and worry the deal grants overly broad releases

from future litigation to the defendants". 1144 In re Payment Card Interchange Fee & Merchant Discount. Antitrust Litig., 827 F.3d 223, 239-40 (2d Cir. 2016):

"The defendants never have to worry about future antitrust litigation based on their honor-all-cards rules and their

default interchange rules… we vacate the district court's certification of the class, reverse approval of the settlement,

and remand for further proceedings not inconsistent with this opinion".

Page 263: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

263

issuers would not reach an agreement.1145 This Bill did not ripe to a final statute, but winds of

reform began to blow.

633. In May 2009, Congress passed the Credit Card Accountability Responsibility and Disclosure

Act (“The Card Act”), which concentrated on the commercial relations between issuers and

cardholders. The Card Act increased the duty of disclosure with respect to interest rates and

cardholder fees. The act also limited penalties for arrears, and increased the transparency of

commercial terms in contracts between issuers and cardholders.1146

In February 2010, Regulations known as Regulation Z (truth in lending), were published. Those

regulations were intended to implement the Card Act and ensure its compliance with existing

legislation.1147

634. The interchange fees in debit cards (including deferred debit) were addressed in a

comprehensive reform enacted in July 2010, known as The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform

and Consumer Protection Act.1148 Section 1075 of this act, known as the Durbin Amendment,

added Section 920 of the Electronic Fund Transfer Act.1149 The Durbin Amendment was

intended, inter alia, to increase competition and relieve merchants from high interchange fees,

while increasing transparency in the way in which interchange fees are set.1150

635. Section 1075(a) of the Durbin Amendment refers to interchange fees in debit (including

deferred debit) and prepaid cards. Subsection (2) provides that interchange fee will be

calculated based on reasonable costs:

1145 Credit Card Fair Fee Act of 2008 H.R 5546 110 Cong. 1146 Credit Card Accountability Responsibility and Disclosure Act, Public Law 111–24, (2009). See also Sumit Agarwal

et al., Regulating Consumer Financial Products: Evidence from Credit Cards, at 6-8 SSRN Elibrary (Aug. 2014). 1147 Truth in Lending; Unfair Or Deceptive Acts Or Practices; Final Rules, 75 Fed. Reg. 7658 Parts 226 & 227 (Feb.

22, 2010) http://edocket.access.gpo.gov/2010/pdf/2010-624.pdf ; Board of Governors of the Fed. Res. System, Press

Release, (March 3, 2010). For criticism see Oren Bar-Gill & Ryan Bubb, Credit Card Pricing: The Card Act and

Beyond, 97 CORNELL L. REV. 967 (2012). 1148 Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Public Law Pub. L. 111-203, (2010) http://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/PLAW-111publ203/pdf/PLAW-111publ203.pdf 1149 Electronic Funds Transfer Act (EFTA), Pub. L. No. 95-630, 92 Stat. 3641 (1978). See also

Board of Governors of the Fed. Res. System, Compliance Guide to Small Entities (Aug. 2, 2013). 1150 Brad G. Hubbard, The Durbin Amendment, Two-Sided Markets, and Wealth Transfers: An Examination of

Unintended Consequences Three Years Later, at 3, SSRN (2013): “The Durbin Amendment had three major goals.

First, to relieve merchants from high interchange fees, which would, in turn, enable merchants to pass these cost savings

on to consumers, who would see lower retail prices. Second, to increase transparency in the way in which interchange

fees are set. Third, to increase competition among networks, such as Visa and MasterCard”.

Page 264: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

264

The amount of any interchange transaction fee that an issuer may receive or charge

with respect to an electronic debit transaction shall be reasonable and

proportional to the cost incurred by the issuer with respect to the transaction.

636. The amendment gave the Federal Reserve Board of Governors (the "Board”) the authority to

determine what constitutes reasonable costs. The Board’s discretion is limited by paragraph

4(B)(i), which instructs the Board to consider only incremental costs to issuers, with respect to

“authorization, clearance, or settlement” of the transaction provided:

[T]he incremental cost incurred by an issuer for the role of the issuer in the

authorization, clearance, or settlement of a particular electronic debit

transaction, which cost shall be considered… other costs incurred by an issuer

which are not specific to a particular electronic debit transaction, which costs shall

not be considered.

637. In December 2010, the Board promulgated draft regulations.1151 The draft regulations

recommended that debit issuers could charge an interchange fee which would be one of two

options: (a) a safe harbor of no more than a 7 cent interchange fee which would not be

scrutinized or; (b) an interchange fee of no more than 12 cents, subject to scrutiny of the costs'

compatibility to the Durbin Amendment. Both options posed a dramatic reduction compared to

the former 44-cent average interchange fee.1152

Had this draft been implemented in full, it would have reduced issuers' income significantly. It

is not surprising that Visa and MasterCard recruited leading experts who argued that if the draft

regulations were to be implemented, networks would be impeded and issuers would have to

raise cardholder fees. The networks' scenarios went on to conclude that the access of the

economically weak and disadvantaged population to bank accounts and debit cards would be

severely curtailed.1153 Some articles with these pessimistic forecasts addressed the European

market.1154

On the other hand, merchant organizations supported an even greater reduction in interchange

1151 Debit Card Interchange Fees and Routing, A Proposed Rule by the Federal Reserve System, 75 Fed. Reg. 81722,

(Dec. 28, 2010) available at http://edocket.access.gpo.gov/2010/pdf/2010-32061.pdf. 1152 Ibid at 81726 81736, 81738. 1153 David S. Evans, Howard H. Chang & Margaret M. Weichert, Economic Analysis of Claims in Support of the Durbin

Amendment to Regulate Debit Card Interchange Fees (2011) available at http://ssrn.com/paper=1843628 ;Martin Baily

& Robert E. Litan, Toward Reasonable Regulation of Debit Card Interchange Fees: The Case for Modifying the Fed.

Res. Board's December 16, 2010 Proposals (2011). 1154 David S. Evans & Abel M. Mateus, How Changes in Payment Card Interchange Fees Affect Consumers Fees and

Merchant Prices: An Economic Analysis with Applications to the European Union (2011) available at

http://ssrn.com/abstract=1878735.

Page 265: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

265

fees than the one proposed in the draft. All in all, the Board received thousands of comments to

the draft, both in support and in opposition to further reductions in the interchange fee.

638. The Board conducted a comprehensive survey in which costs of processing and fraud

prevention by debit card issuers were investigated.1155 On June 29, 2011, after referring to all

comments, the Board promulgated final regulations (with respect to fraud prevention they were

only interim regulations), known as Regulation II, which became effective October 1, 2011.1156

Regulation II contains, besides a cap on debit card interchange fees, two more important

provisions: (1) a prohibition against NSR and HAC rules; and (2) routing reform.1157

The pressures exerted by the networks and their financial lobby evidently significantly

influenced the final regulations. The final rule increased the maximum interchange fee to 21

cents plus a variable component of 5 basis points (0.05%).1158 Issuers that met the requirements

of fraud prevention adjustments mentioned in Section 235.4 were allowed to add an additional

one cent to the interchange fee. This 1-cent fraud-prevention adjustment, which was initially

temporary, became permanent as of October 2012.1159

639. The U.S. current debit interchange fee is 21 cents plus 0.05% of the transaction plus 1 cent for

fraud prevention. Still, this cap reflects a 45% decrease from the previous average interchange

fee prior to the Durbin Amendment.1160

1155 Board of Governors of the Fed. Res. System, Final Rule on Debit Card Interchange Fees and Routing and Interim

Final Rule on Fraud Prevention Adjustment, 12 C.F.R Pt. 235, 76 Fed. Reg. 43,394, 43,433 (July 20, 2011) http://federalregister.gov/a/2011-16861 : “[T]he types of costs that form the basis for the interchange fee standard are

costs incurred for processing electronic debit transactions, chargebacks, and similar transactions, including network

processing fees and transactions monitoring costs; and fraud losses”. 1156 Ibid at 43,402 43,420 . 1157 Fumiko Hayashi, The New Debit Card Regulations: Initial Effects on Networks and Banks, 4 FRB KANSAS CITY

ECON. REV. 79, 88 (2012): “Regulation II contains three main provisions: a cap on debit card interchange fees, a

prohibition on network exclusivity arrangements, and a prohibition on routing restrictions for debit card transactions”. 1158 Final Rule on Fraud Prevention Adjustment, 76 Fed. Reg. 43,394 at 43467, Sec 235.3(b), available at

https://www.federalregister.gov/documents/2011/07/20/2011-16861/debit-card-interchange-fees-and-routing : “An

issuer complies with the requirements of paragraph (a) of this section only if each interchange transaction fee received

or charged by the issuer for an electronic debit transaction is no more than the sum of— (1) 21 cents and; (2) 5 basis

points multiplied by the value of the transaction.”; Sandwith, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform, supra note 237, at

234: "To set the limitation on interchange fees in the final rule, the Fed conducted a survey of institutions covered by

the new interchange fee regulation to determine costs related to issuers' debit card programs. Based on the results of this

survey, the Fed rule limits interchange fees to a base fee of twenty-one cents per transaction plus five basis points of the

transaction's value. For eligible issuers, an additional cent per transaction can be added to cover fraud prevention costs.

The Fed's final rule became effective October 1, 2011”. 1159 77 Fed. Reg. 46279 (Aug. 3, 2012): “Under the final rule, if an issuer meets standards set forth by the Board, it may

receive or charge an adjustment of no more than 1 cent per transaction to any interchange transaction fee it receives or

charges.”; See also Federal Board of Governors of the Fed. Res. System, Press Release (July 27, 2012). 1160 Benjamin Kay, Mark D. Manuszak & Cindy M. Vojtech, Bank Profitability and Debit Card Interchange

Regulation: Bank Responses to the Durbin Amendment, at 9, (2014), available at

http://www.bostonfed.org/payments2014/papers/Cindy_M_Vojtech.pdf: “This cap implies a maximum interchange fee

of 24 cents for a $38 debit card transaction, a decline of 45 percent from the average value of 44 cents for the same

Page 266: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

266

640. The Board specifically emphasized that the Durbin Amendment is applicable not only to debit

cards but also to deferred debit cards.1161

641. Both the U.S methodology and the Israeli methodology are cost based. However, the application

of the methodology in the U.S. is much more limiting.

In Israel, the nominated experts used a Long Run Incremental Cost (LRIC) method to attribute

costs to the interchange fee. In LRIC methodology, all variable and fixed costs are considered

as variable, because in the long run they could be avoidable. Thus, in Israel fixed costs, and not

only variable costs, are included in the interchange fee calculation.1162 The methodology

established in the United States is a modified “stand alone” methodology that takes into account

only direct incremental costs of the examined service.1163

642. Perhaps the most striking practical difference between the cost-based methodologies in Israel

and U.S. is that according to the U.S methodology, the cost of the payment guarantee is

practically not counted. The cost of payment guarantee is not associated with “authorization,

clearance, or settlement” of specific transactions. The reason provided in the commentary is

that: “[I]f an issuer approves the transaction knowing there are insufficient funds in the

account… the issuer incurs this cost as a service to its cardholders, and generally imposes fees

to recover the associated risk”.1164 Thus, in U.S., the payment guarantee is considered a service

given by issuers to cardholders. In Israel, according to the Methodology Decision, the payment

guarantee is considered a service to merchants.1165 The difference between U.S. and Israel can

be explained in the artificialness of attributing a specific cost to one side only in two-sided

markets.

transaction in 2009 prior to the Durbin Amendment.”; Kathleen A. McConnell, The Durbin Amendment's Interchange

Fee and Network Non-Exclusivity Provisions: Did the Federal Reserve Board Overstep its Boundaries? 18 N.C.

BANKING INST. 627, 651 (March 2014): “It is estimated that in 2012, the first full year after the regulation went into

effect, card issuing banks lost approximately $ 7.3 billion in interchange fee revenue.” 1161 Commentary on Board of Governors of the Fed. Res. System, Final Rule on Debit Card Interchange Fees and

Routing and Interim Final Rule on Fraud Prevention Adjustment, 12 C.F.R Pt. 235, at 315 (2011): “Deferred debit

cards. The term ―debit card includes a card, or other payment code or device, that is used in connection with deferred

debit card arrangements in which transactions are not immediately posted to and funds are not debited from the

underlying transaction, savings, or other asset account upon settlement of the transaction... For example, under some

deferred debit card arrangements, the issuer may debit the consumer‘s account for all debit card transactions that

occurred during a particular month at the end of the month. Regardless of the time period between the transaction and

account posting, a card, or other payment code or device, that is used in connection with a deferred debit arrangement is

considered a debit card for purposes of the requirements of this part”. 1162 Supra ¶¶ 495-499. 1163 76 FR 43393, supra note 1158, at 43404: “For the interchange fee standards (§ 235.3), the final rule adopts a

modified version of proposed Alternative 2 (stand-alone cap)” 1164 76 FR 43393, supra note 1158, at 43429. 1165 Supra ¶ 492.

Page 267: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

267

Indeed, some of the specific costs, comprising the payment guarantee in Israel, are also

considered in the U.S, as being part of the fraud prevention costs. Nevertheless, in the U.S.,

fraud prevention costs amount to only 1 cent. Thus, the main cost drivers of payment guarantee

considered in the calculation of the interchange fee in Israel do not exist, or exist only

negligibly, in the U.S. interchange fee calculation.

643. Overhead is also a cost driver taken into consideration in the Israeli calculation of the

interchange fee, but not in the U.S. calculation, which is more limiting, because overheads

cannot be attributed to a specific transaction.1166

Routing Reform

644. Part (b) of Section 1075 of the Durbin Amendment, applies to all payment cards, including

credit cards.

Subsection 1 prohibits issuers from dictating to merchants how transactions should be

routed.1167 In the regulations this is interpreted as an obligation on issuers to offer merchants

(via acquirers) at least two routing options on unaffiliated networks’ infrastructure (i.e., Star

and Visa).1168 This provision may seem odd to Israelis, who live in a world of only one routing

option (SHVA).1169 As long as SHVA has no competitors, it is difficult to comprehend the

significance of the routing reform. Nevertheless, in the United States there are several routing

options, belonging to different networks.

645. The routing reform eliminated exclusive routing arrangements between issuers and networks

that were infrastructure owners. Prior to the reform, issuers could require merchants to route

1166 76 FR 43393, supra note 1158, at 43427: “The costs the Board did not consider in setting the standards include

costs associated with corporate overhead… these costs are not specific to any electronic debit transaction.”; Adam J.

Levitin, Interchange Regulation: Implications for Credit Unions (FILENE RESEARCH INSTITUTE, 2010): "The

amendment also provides that in its rule- making, the Fed shall only take into account issuers’ incremental costs for

debit transactions, thereby excluding sunk costs like overhead and marketing”. 1167 76 FR 43393, supra note 1158, at 43468 §235.7 : “(b) Limitation on payment card network restrictions )1(

Prohibitions against exclusivity arrangements (A) No exclusive network: The Board shall... prescribe regulations

providing that an issuer or payment card network shall not... restrict the number of payment card networks on which an

electronic debit transaction may be processed”. 1168 76 FR 43393, supra note 1158, at 43448: “[T]he final rule provides that the network exclusivity provision in §

235.7(a)(1) could be satisfied as long as an electronic debit transaction may be processed on at least two unaffiliated

payment card networks”. 1169 Supra ch. 8.1.7.

Page 268: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

268

transactions on the issuer's preferable route, even though it was a more expensive route.1170

After the reform, control over the choice of route passed to merchants. Thus, networks who

want transactions to be routed on their infrastructures must compete and convince merchants to

choose them, by reducing the routing price.1171 Merchants can also choose to route signature

debit transactions through PIN debit infrastructures, which are cheaper and faster.1172 Post-

Durbin, merchants have at least two routing options, and competition has driven prices down.

Some scholars opine that routing is the biggest success of the reform.1173 Furthermore, Durbin

reinstalled the proper competitive incentives to choose the cheapest infrastructure.1174

Cancelation Of Merchant Restraints

646. Section 1075(b) of the Durbin Amendment is titled: "Limitation on Payment Card Network

Restriction". Subsection 1075(b)(2) states that “a payment card network shall not… inhibit the

ability of any person to provide a discount or in-kind incentive for payment by the use of cash,

checks, debit cards, or credit cards”.

This section completed a final judgment from July 20, 2011 that approved a consent decree,

reached in a civil suit the DOJ initiated against Visa and MasterCard, regarding NSR rules.1175

The litigation in the same proceeding against American Express resumed. On Feb. 19, 2015 the

1170 NACS v. Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys., 746 F.3d 474, 479 (D.C. Cir. 2014): “Issuers and networks

often entered into mutually beneficial agreements under which issuers required merchants to route transactions on

certain networks that generally charged high processing fees so long as those networks also set high interchange fees.

Many of these agreements were exclusive, meaning that issuers agreed to activate only one network or only networks

affiliated with one company”. 1171 Hayashi, The New Debit Card Regulations: Effects on Merchants, Consumers, and Payments System Efficiency,

supra note 30, at 98: "Before the regulations, PIN networks had an incentive to set their interchange fees at levels

higher than those of rival networks. By offering higher fee revenue to banks, the networks were able to generate more

transactions because transaction routing was controlled by the banks. But the merchants’ new control over routing has

changed PIN networks’ incentives. Now they seek to set their interchange fees lower than their rivals to attract more

transaction volume". 1172 Ibid: “Many merchants now avoid Visa’s Interlink network, the largest PIN network prior to the regulations, and

instead choose other PIN networks whenever possible. As a result, in terms of transaction volume, Interlink has lost

significant market share to other PIN networks such as Maestro, Pulse, and STAR. Through their new control over

routing, merchants’ emerging influence over the market shares held by different PIN networks is likely to increase

competition among PIN networks for merchants”. 1173 Hubbard, supra note 1150, at 15: “[T]he provision allows the merchant to direct the routing of the transaction from

among the networks chosen by the issuer, providing merchants the ability and incentive to choose the network with the

lowest fees”. For a different view, see Tom Brown, Re-Routing the Exclusivity and Routing Provisions of the Durbin

Amendment, LYDIAN PAYMENT J. (2011) 1174 Hubbard, supra note 1150, at 15: “[N]etworks (and merchants) now have an incentive to push consumers back to

PIN networks because of the lower cost they incur, rather than to signature networks, as they were doing pre-Durbin

due to the higher interchange fees generated”. 1175 United States v. Am. Express Co., 2011 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 78835 (E.D.N.Y. July 20, 2011) (approval of settlement

with Visa and MasterCard); Scott Schuh, Oz Shy, Joanna Stavins & Robert Triest, An Economic Analysis of the 2011

Settlement Between the Department of Justice and Credit Card Networks, 8 J. COMPETITION L. ECON., 1 (2012).

Page 269: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

269

court ruled against American Express's NSR,1176 but in September 2016, a successful appeal

reversed the ruling.1177

647. The result of the combined legislative and judicial actions is the practical elimination of NSR

and HAC in Visa and MasterCard networks. Merchants that accept Visa or MasterCard (but not

American Express) can choose to surcharge cardholders who pay with them. Merchant

restraints still apply within a certain type of card. For example, a merchant who accepts without

surcharging Visa debit card issued by Chase Bank cannot surcharge Visa debit card issued by

HSBC.1178

648. Subsection (3) forbids payment card networks from inhibiting the ability of merchants to refuse

to accept credit cards for transactions valued under $10.00.1179

649. After the promulgation of the final regulations, merchant organizations sued the Board for the

significant increase it made in the interchange fee in the final rule compared to the draft. On

July 31, 2013 the Columbia District Court accepted their claim and vacated the interchange

transaction fee rule (12 C.F.R. § 235.3(b)) and the network non-exclusivity rule (12 C.F.R. §

235.7(a)(2)), on the ground that the Board exceeded its authority by inclusion of unqualified

costs.1180 The Board appealed. On March 21, 2014 the Court of Appeals reversed the District

Court and held that the board reasonably interpreted its authority.1181

The Effects Of The Reform

650. It is interesting to follow initial effects of the reform in the U.S.

The MSF in small value transactions have been raised (due to the transfer from proportional to

flat fee).1182 Except small value transactions, merchants have been the party benefitting the most

1176 United States v. Am. Express Co. LEXIS 20114 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015). 1177 Supra ¶ 605. 1178 See also supra ¶ 584.6 (similar arrangement in Europe) and infra ¶ 755. 1179 15 U.S. Code § 1693o–2 - Reasonable fees and rules for payment card transactions, Pub. L. 114-38: “(3) Limitation

On Restrictions On Setting Transaction Minimums Or Maximums. ‘‘(a) IN GENERAL.A payment card network shall

not... inhibit the ability—

‘‘(i) of any person to set a minimum dollar value for the acceptance by that person of credit cards, to the extent that —

‘‘(I) such minimum dollar value does not differentiate between issuers or between payment card networks; and

‘‘(II) such minimum dollar value does not exceed $10.00” 1180 NACS v. Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys., 958 F. Supp. 2d 85, 115 (D.D.C. 2013). 1181 NACS v. Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys., 746 F.3d 474 (D.C. Cir. 2014). Cert. denied by NACS v. Bd. of

Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys., 2015 U.S. LEXIS 731 (U.S., Jan. 20, 2015). 1182 Andrew R. Johnson, Fees on Cup of Coffee Raised From 8 Cent To 23 Cent, MasterCard, Visa Raising Small Debit

Buy Fees, MARKETWATCH (Sept. 22, 2011).

Page 270: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

270

from the reform. Their MSF reduced substantially. It is doubtful whether the merchants' savings

from lower interchange fee and the resulting lower MSF have been passed through to

consumers. In competitive markets, there should be full pass through to final consumers.1183

Issuers' revenue has decreased by billions of dollars because of the reduced interchange fees.1184

651. Banks have threatened to make up for lost revenues by eliminating free checking accounts, or

by imposing usage fees on debit cards. For example, Bank of America announced that it will

begin to charge $5 per month for checking accounts.1185 The announcement provoked some

severe reactions, including that of Senator Durbin, who had initiated the reform.1186 Eventually,

competition plus fear of losing customers restrained banks.1187 Other banks, such as Wells

Fargo, announced a cutback in rewards it had bestowed on cardholders before the Durbin

Amendment.1188 In my view, curtailing cardholders' rewards, as opposed to raising cardholder

fee, is a pro-competitive outcome.1189

652. Another interesting result of the reform is that competition between debit and credit might

intensify. As explained above,1190 the U.S. reform applies to prepaid, debit and deferred debit

but not to credit transactions. The reform lowered the cost of debit to merchants, deepening the

gap between the price of (cheap) debit from which merchants enjoy, to expensive credit from

which issuers benefit. Sandwith found that as a result of the reform merchants hope consumers

use debit cards more often because of low interchange fees. On the opposing side banks hope

to push consumers to payment cards with higher fees. i.e., credit cards. Thus an unseen battle

1183 Fumiko Hayashi, The New Debit Card Regulations: Effects on Merchants, Consumers, and Payments System

Efficiency, 1 FRB KANSAS Q. REV. 89, 102 (2013). 1184 Kay et al., Bank Profitability and Debit Card Interchange Regulation, supra note 1160, at 5: “Reg II clearly led to

significant reductions in interchange income for treated banks.”; Wilko Bolt & David Humphrey, Competition in Bank-

Provided Payment Services, 1539 ECB Occasional Paper Series, at 7 (2013): “It has been suggested that this legislation

may reduce bank payment revenues from credit cards by $5.6 billion annually”. 1185 BoA to Instate $5 Monthly Fee for Debit Card Purchases, PYMNTS. COM (Sept. 29, 2011) 1186 Richard J. Durbin, Letter to Bank of America (Oct. 3, 2011) available at

http://durbin.senate.gov/public/index.cfm/files/serve?File_id=c57f9acb-7a87-4bb9-a2d0-211189c364d0. 1187 Bolt & Humphrey, Competition in Bank-Provided Payment Services, supra note 1184, at 7: “An effort by large

banks to explicitly price debit card use through a monthly fee, however, was not successful due to a consumer

backlash”; Tara Siegel Bernard, In Retreat, Bank of America Cancels Debit Card Fee, N. Y. TIMES (Nov. 1, 2011);

Sandwith, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform, supra note 237, at 236-37, 241. 1188 Wells Fargo Ends Debit Rewards Program Entirely, PYMNTS. COM (Aug. 22, 2011) available at

http://pymnts.com/Wells-Fargo-Ends-Debit-Rewards-Program-Entirely/ ; Fumiko Hayashi, The New Debit Card

Regulations: Initial Effects on Networks and Banks, 4 FRB KANSAS CITY ECON. REV 79, 107 (2012): “After the new

rules removed the regulated banks’ incentive for promoting signature debit over PIN debit, the banks stopped offering

rewards programs”. 1189 See ¶ 351, see especially note 614. 1190 Supra ¶ 635.

Page 271: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

271

between merchants and banks is emerging.1191 Another study has found that issuers were unable

to offset the lost interchange fee revenue on debit, neither by higher debit volumes nor by

shifting consumers to credit cards (that have unregulated fees), despite issuers’ desire to do

so.1192 Hayashi claims that the reform also prompted intrabrand platform competition between

debit networks, routed on competing infrastructures. Hayashi indicated that Visa's debit lost

market share to cheaper PIN debit networks.1193

Other commentators, most of them identified with the payment networks, have argued that the

long-term effects of the Durbin reform will cause an increase in cardholder fees and banking

account fees.1194 Empirical study by Kay et al found that regulated banks increased account fees

in response to the reform, but these increases were insufficient to mitigate lost interchange fee

income. Changes in account fees were able to offset roughly 30 percent of the lost interchange

fee income.1195

Others claim that more time is needed until the final effects of the reform will be clear.1196

8.4. Australia

653. Australia was a pioneer country in regulating the interchange fee. At the end of the last century

and the beginning of the recent one, the Federal Reserve Bank of Australia (“RBA”), conducted

a comprehensive reform in payment card interchange fees. Following the reform, the Australian

1191 Sandwith, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform, supra note 237, at 238: “An unseen battle is emerging between

retailers that hope consumers use debit cards because of low interchange fees and banks hoping to push consumers to

payment cards with higher fees”. 1192 Kay et al., Bank Profitability and Debit Card Interchange Regulation, supra note 1160, at 5: “[T]reated banks have

been unable to offset the lost interchange income on debit cards by higher debit volumes or by shifting consumers to

credit cards that have unregulated fees”. 1193 Fumiko Hayashi, The New Debit Card Regulations: Initial Effects on Networks and Banks, 4 FRB KANSAS CITY

ECON. REV. 79, 107 (2012): “Apparent changes in market shares among debit card networks over the past two years

suggest that competition has risen among debit card networks. The decline of Visa’s market share, especially in the PIN

debit card market, is likely to be a sign of increased competition among the networks for merchants”. 1194 Todd Zywicki, Geoffrey A. Manne & Julian Morris, Price Controls on Payment Card Interchange Fees: The U.S.

Experience, ICLE (2014); David S. Evans, Howard Chang & Joyce Steven, The Impact of the U.S. Debit Card

Interchange Fee Regulation on Consumer Welfare: An Event Study Analysis, (University of Chicago, Institute for Law

and Economics Working Paper, 2013). 1195 Kay et al., Bank Profitability and Debit Card Interchange Regulation, supra note 1160, at 5: “[T]reated banks

increased their deposit fees in response to the regulation. While these increases are generally insufficient to mitigate all

of the lost interchange income, changes in deposit fees offset roughly 30 percent of the lost interchange income.”; see

also ibid at 30-31. 1196 Hayashi, The New Debit Card Regulations: Effects on Merchants, Consumers, and Payments System Efficiency,

supra note 30; Oz Shy, Measuring some Effects of the 2011 Debit Card Interchange Fee Reform, 32 CONTEMPORARY

ECON. POLICY 769 (2014).

Page 272: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

272

interchange fee in credit cards was reduced to 0.5%.1197 At that time, this was one of the lowest

interchange fees in open systems.

654. The RBA identified the usage externality as the major problem of payment systems.1198

Different payment instruments have different costs, but customers are not aware of them. Usage

externality occurs when customers choose to pay with the most cost effective payment

instruments for them (i.e., for the cardholder), even if this is the costliest payment instrument

to the merchant. Customers externalize the expensive cost of usage on merchants and solely

internalize the benefit of the payment instrument. When customers pay with inferior payment

instruments from a social point of view, then the usage externality becomes a social problem,

and not only the merchants' problem.

655. The RBA found significant differences between the costs of credit cards and debit cards. The

cost of a $100 debit card transaction (total average costs of transaction to the acquirer and the

issuer), was estimated at 41 cents. The transaction price for cardholders was approximately 50

cents, meaning debit payments were priced at cost plus 9 cent profit. However, the total cost of

an average credit card transaction was found to be 2.01 Australian dollars, but the price for the

cardholder was found to be negative, because of rewards, ranging from 42 cents to $ 1.04 per

transaction.-It should be weighted with longterm price. -The negative price is only a short 1199

term effects such as goods' price increase (due to rewards) or inclination to enter debt.1200

Interchange fees were a significant component in the rewards granted to cardholders.

Merchants, in turn, bore the brunt of the costs. Merchants paid an averaged MSF of 1.8% of the

transaction. Thus, merchants actually subsidized the usage of expensive payment instruments,

especially for them (credit cards), to their detriment.1201

1197 RESERVE BANK OF AUSTRALIA, REFORM OF CREDIT CARD SCHEMES, FINAL REFORMS AND REGULATION (2002). 1198 See ch. 7.2.2 (Usage Externality). 1199 RESERVE BANK OF AUSTRALIA, REFORM OF CREDIT CARD SCHEMES, FINAL REFORMS AND REGULATION, at 4-5

(2002): “The price signals facing consumers choosing between different payment instruments do not promote efficient

resource use in Australia’s retail payments system... In many circumstances, a debit card is a close substitute for a credit

card, particularly for cardholders who do not have a cash constraint. Consumers using a debit card typically face a

transaction fee of around $0.50 per transaction (beyond a fee-free threshold) for accessing their own funds; this fee is

broadly in line with the average cost of providing debit card services ($0.41). Credit cardholders who settle their

account in full each month (known as “transactors”) pay no transaction fee, and may be paid in the form of loyalty

points, for using the funds of their financial institution. In these cases, the benefits from using a credit card can be as

much as $1.04 for an average size transaction of around $100, compared to the average cost of $2.01 to provide this

transaction.”; Philip Lowe, Reform of the Payments System (March, 2005)" :In the case of credit cards, many people

face per-transaction prices that are effectively negative; that is they get paid to use the card!". 1200 See ¶ 160. 1201 RESERVE BANK OF AUSTRALIA, REFORM OF CREDIT CARD SCHEMES, FINAL REFORMS AND REGULATION, at 8

(2002): “Credit card interchange fees play a pivotal role in determining the incentives for consumers to use, and

Page 273: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

273

656. When evaluating net costs of a payment instruments, benefits should also be considered. Thus,

if credit cards were more beneficial to merchants than other (cheaper) payment instruments,

this could change the picture. The higher price for merchants could be worthy and profitable

for them. The RBA’s research found that the combined benefit to merchants and cardholders

from credit cards did not justify the difference in costs.1202

657. The RBA also found that interchange fee does not abide to ordinary rules of competition.

Multiplicity of competitors did not contribute to lower prices (reduction in the interchange fee),

but to an increase in the interchange fee. Below I dedicate a chapter to explain how, contrary to

ordinary products, competition in payment cards drives prices up (and not down).1203 In short,

competition for cardholders is fueled by interchange fee, which is a major source of rewards

and cardholder discounts. As competition intensifies, higher interchange fees are required. The

fee is imposed on merchants through the MSF, and causes price level to rise.

658. The Australian reform included a series of instructions, designed to reduce the interchange fee.

Other instructions were designed to enable merchants to surcharge customers who pay with

expensive payment instruments. The NSR was cancelled and merchants could charge more to

credit cardholders.1204

659. The open networks, particularly MasterCard, opposed the reform. Their major argument was

that reducing the interchange fee would lead payment card networks to a death spiral, that would

eventually destroy the open networks, and cause a transition to closed networks. The thrust of

the argument was: (1) reduction in the interchange fee would force issuers to compensate

themselves for the lost income by increase in cardholder fee; (2) raising cardholder fees would

merchants to accept, credit cards. Revenues from interchange fees allow credit card issuers effectively to “subsidise”

cardholders to use their credit cards, in the sense that they are charged less than the cost of the credit card payment

services they use (or are even offered rebates in the form of loyalty points). The burden of this subsidy falls initially on

merchants, but ultimately on the community as a whole”. 1202 Ibid at 30: “The Reserve Bank acknowledges the widespread acceptance of credit cards in Australia and the benefits

that they can provide to individual cardholders and merchants. At the same time, however, it is not persuaded by

arguments that allowing normal market mechanisms to operate more effectively in the Australian payments system is

against the community’s interest. It does not accept that continued growth in the use of credit cards at the expense of

alternative payment instruments necessarily adds to the community’s welfare. In particular, it remains of the view that

the benefits of credit cards to cardholders and merchants as a whole – in the form of a permanent increase in

sales or a reduction in transaction costs – are overstated. Other payment networks can also gain from being larger in

size and the mix of payment instruments in these circumstances ought to be one for consumers to decide in a

competitive market place, in response to efficient price signals. These conditions do not prevail in the retail payments

system in Australia”. 1203 Infra ch. 6.6. 1204 RESERVE BANK OF AUSTRALIA, REFORM OF CREDIT CARD SCHEMES, FINAL REFORMS AND REGULATION, at 46

(2002): “Neither the rules of the Scheme nor any participant in the Scheme shall prohibit a merchant from charging a

credit cardholder any fee or surcharge for a credit card transaction”.

Page 274: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

274

lead to abandonment of cardholders; (3) this, in turn, would lead to an inevitable diminution in

the attractiveness of payment cards for merchants; (4) merchant would cease to accept cards,

(5) Next step would be an even greater abandonment of cards by cardholders and back again

through the cycle., a similar argumentalso maintained the Visa firms had ,IsraelIn 1205

according to which an interchange fee reduction would cause a “snowball” effect that would

destroy the network.1206

This "death spiral" or "snowball" argument was empirically refuted. After the reform, open

networks still continued to flourish. Adoption among cardholders and acceptance among

merchants actually increased.1207 Transactions' volumes also mounted. In Israel the snowball

effect was also similarly refuted empirically.1208 In Europe it was also concluded that even when

interchange fees were reduced, adoption, usage and acceptance of cards increased.1209

660. Theoretical analysis also reveals that "snowball effect" predictions are without merit. True,

interchange fee reduction may theoretically cause an increase in cardholder fees. Even so, if

cardholder fee had been negative due to rewards, an increase the in cardholder fee to a higher

(but still negative) level would probably not result in significant cardholder abandonment.

Moreover, in mature networks, cardholders have inherent positive benefits from cards, and they

would not easily give-up cards.1210 All the more so it is unlikely that in mature networks, a

reduction in the interchange fee, the direct effect of which would be a lower MSF, would result

in abandonment by merchants. The certain and direct effect of a reduction in the interchange

fee (and the corresponding MSF) should probably overshadow any (questionable) indirect

effect from increase in cardholder fee.1211

1205 MasterCard's Submission to the Reserve Bank of Australia, at 10-11 (2001). 1206 The Methodology Decision, supra note 1102, at 8. 1207 Santiago Carbo Valverde et al., Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation, at 12 (Federal Reserve

Bank of Chicago Working Paper No. 09-11. 2009); Robin A. Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card

Networks: Economics, Industry Developments, and Policy Issues, at 39 (F.R.B. Finance and Economics Discussion

Series 23-09, 2009); Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1121, at 665-70;

Fumiko Hayashi & Stuart E. Weiner, Interchange Fees in Australia the U.K and the United States: Matching Theory

and Practice, FRB KANSAS ECON. REV. 75 (2006); Alan S. Frankel, Towards a Competitive Card Payments

Marketplace, RBA 27 (2007). For another view see Howard Chang, David S. Evans & Daniel D. Garcia Swartz, The

Effect of Regulatory Intervention in Two-Sided Markets: An Assessment of Interchange-Fee Capping in Australia, 4

REV. NETWORK ECON. 328 (2005). 1208 The Methodology Decision, supra note 1102, at 8 (despite decline in the interchange fee, systems flourished). 1209 EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees, supra note 1042, at 10: “A decrease of high interchange fees in

most countries generally seems to be associated with a higher acceptance of cards, and it seems that in countries with

low interchange fees cards usage is higher”. 1210 For expansion on inherent benefits of payment cards to cardholders see ¶¶ 137, 145, 151, 152-154. 1211 See also infra ¶¶ 461-470 and note 797.

Page 275: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

275

661. In 2008, the RBA evaluated its earlier reform. The RBA reported that the reform had increased

transparency, and consumers got better pricing signals about the true costs of the payment

instruments they used. Following the reassessment, the RBA announced that it would waive the

requirement to recalculate interchange fees, if market players would take steps to ensure that

interchange fees would not exceed 0.5% in credit card transactions and 12 cents in debit card

transactions.1212 The RBA continues to promulgate such waiver notices from time to time.1213

As a complementary step to deregulation, merchants can freely surcharge expensive payment

instruments.1214

662. Since the reform, the number of merchants that surcharge credit cards have increased.1215 The

interchange fee decreased and as a consequence, the MSF also decreased. Final prices of goods

possibly decreased, although not in a full pass through rate.1216 At the same time, there have

been reductions in cardholder rewards and increases in cardholder fees. However, as the initial

outset was high negative cardholder fees,1217 even the increase resulted in them being negative

or close to zero.1218

663. The Australian payment card firms complained that merchants were using the abolishment of

the NSR to surcharge excessively, i.e. more than is justified by the real costs of payment

1212 Media Release, RBA: Waiver of Requirement to Recalculate Interchange Fee Benchmark (Dec. 2008): “The

Reserve Bank waives the requirement to recalculate the cost-based measure and the common cost-based benchmark for

the 2009/10 year in the designated credit card systems”. 1213 RBA, Waiver of Requirement to Recalculate Interchange Fee Benchmark, March 2015: “The Reserve Bank waives

the requirement to recalculate the cost-based measure and the common cost-based benchmark for the 2015/16 year in

the designated credit card systems. The Bank previously waived the requirement for the 2009/10 and 2012/13 years. As

set out in the current standards, the benchmark of 0.50 per cent of transaction value calculated in September 2006 and

announced in media release 2006-08 will continue to apply until the next scheduled recalculation in the 2018/19 year...

The Reserve Bank waives the requirement to recalculate the benchmark for the 2015/16 year in the Visa Debit system.

The Bank previously waived the requirement for the 2009/10 and 2012/13 years. As set out in the current standards, the

benchmark of 12 cents per transaction calculated in September 2006 and announced in media release 2006-08 will

continue to apply until the next scheduled recalculation in the 2018/19 year". 1214 Reserve Bank of Australia, Conclusions of the 2007/08 Review (2008). 1215 Reserve Bank of Australia, REFORM OF AUSTRALIA’ S PAYMENTS SYSTEM, PRELIMINARY CONCLUSIONS OF THE

2007/08 REVIEW, 17 (2008): “Since the beginning of 2003, when the no-surcharge rule was removed, the number of

merchants surcharging has risen substantially”; RBA, REVIEW OF CARD SURCHARGING: A CONSULTATION DOCUMENT,

Reserve Bank of Australia at 2-3 (2011): “In recent years, though, the rate of surcharging appears to have grown

significantly... almost 30 per cent of merchants imposed a surcharge on at least one of the credit cards they accepted in

December 2010 (Graph 2.1). Surcharging appears to be more common among very large merchants (those with annual

turnover greater than $530 million), although around one-quarter of smaller merchants (those with annual turnover

between $1 million and $20 million) are also reported to impose surcharges. According to these data, most other

merchants are considering imposing surcharges, with only around 20 per cent of merchants having no surcharge plans”. 1216 United States v. Am. Express Co., LEXIS 20114, at 221 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015): “[T]he RBA's report actually

supports the court's determination that lower discount rates resulting from removal of the NDPs will benefit consumers

as merchants translate some amount of their lower credit card costs into lower prices”. 1217 Supra ¶655. 1218 Reserve Bank of Australia, Reform of Australia's Payments System Issues for the 2007/08 Review, at 19-23 (2007);

Allan L. Shampine, Testing Interchange Fee Models using the Australian Experience (Proceedings of the Bank of

Canada Economics of Payments VI conference, at 21-22 (May 24, 2012).

Page 276: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

276

instruments.1219 The RBA found these complaints justified. As a result, in March 2013, the

RBA published a new standard that limits the ability of merchants to surcharge. The changes

were aimed at improving the price signals consumers face when choosing a payment

instrument. The RBA allowed networks to limit surcharging by merchants to their reasonable

cost of acceptance. These costs include the MSF plus any additional expenses the merchant

carries in connection with acceptance of payment cards. Such expenses included, for example,

the costs of purchasing POS terminals, the costs of maintaining card acceptance infrastructure,

and the costs of other equipment required to accept card payments.1220

8.5. Romania

664. Similar to Israel, the national interchange fee in Romania is set by a single multilateral

agreement between issuers and acquirers that compose almost all (98%) of the market.1221 The

interchange fee in Romania was formerly set amongst the highest rates in Europe.1222 The EU

proceedings against Visa and MasterCard, in which the interchange fee was set at 0.2% (debit)

and 0.3% (credit), have been reflected in a Romanian announcement that the internal

interchange fees should not be higher than the international.1223

665. In my view, this conclusion also applies to Israel. There is no justification for the "local"

interchange fee (0.7%), to be hundreds of percent higher than the interchange fee paid to a

foreign European issuer for a tourist transaction (0.3% for credit; 0.2% for debit).

1219RBA, Reforms to Payment Card Surcharging, March 2013: “Although the Reserve Bank's surcharging reforms have

provided significant public benefit, the Reserve Bank has become concerned in recent years that some surcharging

practices have developed in a way that potentially distorts price signals. In particular, the Reserve Bank has been

concerned about cases where fees or surcharges appear to be well in excess of acceptance costs or where a single

‘blended’ surcharge is applied across several card schemes even though merchants' acceptance costs may be

significantly higher for some cards than others". 1220 RBA, ibid: “On 18 March 2013, a number of changes to the Reserve Bank's Standards relating to merchant

surcharging took effect. These changes are aimed at improving the price signals that consumers face when choosing the

payment method they use. The changes enable card schemes (such as American Express, Diners Club, MasterCard and

Visa) to limit surcharges and address cases where merchants are clearly surcharging at a higher level than is justified.

Merchants are nonetheless still able to fully recover their legitimate card acceptance costs.”; RBA, Guidance Note:

Interpretation of the Surcharging Standards (Nov. 2012). For a similar rule in Europe, supra note 1058. 1221 Anca-Iulia Gîrjob & Maria-Raluca Gîrbacea, The Impact of Interchange Fees on Merchants and Consumers, 2

ROMANIAN COMPETITION JOURNAL 83 (2013)

Gîrjob & Gîrbacea, id. at 87: “In Romania, according to the rules of the two cards systems, the interchange fee

applicable in the card payments national market is the result of a multilateral agreement between banks which hold

about 98 % of the national market”. 1222Id. at 85: “[I]n Romania the financial institutions set some of the highest rates for multilateral interchange fees”. 1223Id. at 89: “[A]ccording to the statements of Bogdan Chiriţoiu, the President of the Competition Council, at Antena 3,

on 06/01/2013, VISA has promised to the European Commission that it will reduce the fees to 0.3% because there is no

economic justification for the fact that an internal transaction in Romania costs more than a cross-border transaction”

see also ibid at 97: “As it was mentioned before the upper limits were established to 0.2% of the value of the transaction

for debit cards and 0.3% for credit cards. These measures will be applied in Romania also, because there is no

economical justification that an internal transaction costs more than a cross-border transaction”.

Page 277: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

277

This reasoning is even stronger given that the interchange fee in Israel is based on cost

methodology. The costs of the payment guarantee in international transactions are higher than

in internal transactions, as international transactions (i.e., tourist transactions) are subject to

higher rates of fraud, default and misuse than local transactions. In addition, the costs of

processing and authorization of an international transaction demands more resources than those

of an internal transaction. Thus, international interchange fee should be higher and not lower

than the local. Therefore if in Europe Visa and MasterCard charge 0.2% (debit) and 0.3%

(credit) interchange fees, interchange fee in Israel should be lower, not higher.

666. This is all truer because the tourist test methodology is a utility methodology. The tourist test

methodology is based on the avoided costs of cash which are saved if using a card. The

underlying assumption is that the costs of using cards are less than the costs of using cash. Thus,

the tourist test is supposed to yield a higher interchange fee than a cost based interchange fee.

Thus, if the fee in a higher yielding methodology, such as in Europe, results in a lower fee than

the cost based Israeli interchange fee, the Israeli interchange fee is surely too high.

8.6. New Zealand

667. In 2006, New Zealand's Commerce Commission initiated proceedings against Visa,

MasterCard and 11 financial institutions for antitrust violations. The allegations were that the

interchange fees amounted to anti-competitive collusion.1224 In 2009, the government reached

a settlement with seven banks,1225 after separate settlements were previously reached with

MasterCard and Visa.1226 All settlement agreements are published online.1227

The settlement agreements canceled restraints that network rules imposed on merchants, such

1224 New Zealand Commerce Commission, Media Release, Commission Alleges Price-Fixing in Credit Card

Interchange Fees (Nov. 10, 2006). 1225 N.Z. Commerce Commission, Media Release, Credit Card Settlements Lower New Zealand Business Costs, (Oct. 5,

2009). 1226 N.Z. Commerce Commission, Media Release, Commerce Commission and Visa Reach Agreement to Settle Credit

Card Interchange Fee Proceedings (Aug. 12, 2009); Media Release, N.Z., Commerce Commission and MasterCard

Agree to Settle Credit Card Interchange Fee Proceedings (Aug. 24, 2009). 1227 New Zealand settlements are available at:

http://www.comcom.govt.nz/business-competition/enforcement-response-register-commerce/detail/665

Page 278: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

278

as NSR and HAC, and included provisions intended to increase transparency, such as

publishing the various categories of interchange fees online.1228

668. The settlements also limited the ability of incumbent payment card firms to prevent new

acquirers from connecting to the network. Visa and MasterCard each agreed to allow new

acquirers to join the networks, provided they meet relevant criteria regarding security, financial

strength and risk avoidance.1229 In addition, Section 4.1.3 of the settlement agreements

specifically determines that: "New Zealand acquirers need not also be issuers, and vice

versa".1230

New Zealand further established that if an issuer and acquirer do not have an ex-ante agreement

with respect to interchange fees, issuers cannot demand ex-post interchange fees. Section 3.1.7

to the Settlements with Visa and MasterCard stipulates: "if there is neither an issuer rate nor a

bilaterally agreed rate notified to [MasterCard/Visa] that applies", then no interchange fee (zero

interchange fee) will be paid on that transaction.1231

669. At least from regulatory point of view, structural separation between issuers and acquirers is

feasible in New Zealand. Practically this separation never occurred for reasons explained in

chapter 13.1 below. Independent acquirers (i.e., acquirers which are not issuers), do not exist in

New Zealand.1232 Moreover, interchange fees in New Zealand can be over 2% which is among

the world's highest.1233

Just as in New Zealand, the Antitrust Tribunal in Israel also determined that new acquirers could

enter the market.1234 However, in Israel, too, there are no independent acquirers.

My innovation, discussed at chapter 0 below, is to turn to reality the desire of regulators which

1228 New Zealand Interchange Fees are available at http://www.westpac.co.nz/business/payment-solutions/pricing-and-

fees/ 1229 Articles 4.3, 4.1.4 to the Visa settlement, supra note .1227 1230 See also Peter R. Taylor, Cards and Payments Australasia (Payment Conference, Mar. 15, 2010): “Relevant for

specialist and self-acquirers, the schemes have confirmed that acquirers need not also be issuers and that applicants

need not be financial institutions”. 1231 Ibid: “[I]f an issuer does not stipulate or agree a fee with an acquirer, no interchange will be payable on that issuer’s

transaction."; Asia Pacific Banking ANF Finance, NZ uses market forces to bring card companies into line (May 21,

2010): "The manner in which interchange fees are now independently determined is unique to New Zealand –

significantly, if an issuer does not stipulate or agree a fee with an acquirer, no interchange will be payable on that

issuer’s transaction". 1232 Internal E-mails of the author with the Commerce Commission from Oct. 10 & 13, 2015. 1233 Infra ¶ 809. 1234 AT 610/06 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, para. 3 (11.11.07).

Page 279: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

279

was never fulfilled, of existence of independent acquirers. Moreover, my proposal is to give

such independent acquirers the bargaining power to determine the interchange fee they pay.

8.7. Other countries

670. There is literature reviewing worldwide regulation of interchange fees.1235 Several additional

countries are worth noting.

671. In Mexico, adoption and usage of payment cards were low, compared to other countries.1236

The Central Bank reached an agreement with the financial institutions to reduce the interchange

fees. As a consequence, the MSF decreased and the placement of POS devices accelerated.1237

672. In Spain, the regulator reduced credit card interchange fees from an average rate of 1.4% in

2006 to an average rate of 0.35% in 2009. The interchange fee for debit transactions decreased

from Euro 0.53 to Euro 0.35 per transaction. The methodology selected for calculating the

interchange fee was cost-based. The Spanish Authority determined that interchange fees should

reflect the variable cost of payment guarantee against fraud, and a fixed cost of processing

transactions.1238 The payment card firms threatened of "death spiral" which would destroy the

payment card network. In practice, adoption and usage of cards in Spain only increased after

the reform.1239

673. In Hungary, the Competition Authority decided in 2009 that acquirers and issuers of Visa and

MasterCard had been colluding as a cartel that had coordinated interchange fees from 1996 to

2008. The decision did not determine that interchange fee was per-se violation. The ruling was

1235 Fumiko Hayashi, Payment Card Interchange Fees and Merchant Service Charges - an International Comparison,

supra note 166; Stewart E. Weiner & Julian Wright, Interchange Fees in various Countries: Developments and

Determinants, 4 REV. NETWORK ECON. 290 (2005); Bradford & Hayashi, Developments in Interchange Fees in the

United States and Abroad, supra note 842; Fumiko Hayashi, Public Authority Involvement in Payment Card Markets:

Various Countries, August 2013 Update, PAYMENTS SYS. RESEARCH DEPARTMENT OF THE FED. RES. BANK OF KANSAS

CITY; Fumiko Hayashi & Jesse Leigh Maniff, Public Authority Involvement in Payment Card Markets: Various

Countries August 2014 Update, FRB KANSAS (Aug. 2014). 1236 José L. Negrín, The Regulation of Payment Cards: The Mexican Experience 4 Rev. NETWORK ECON. 243 (2005). 1237 Rachel L. Osband, Interchange Fee Reform in Mexico: A Bank Driven Approach, ANTITRUST BULL. (2009). 1238 Valverde, Empirical Investigation, supra note 1207, at 18: “Some TDC resolutions required the card networks to

only include two costs when setting domestic multilateral interchange fees (MIFs): a fixed cost for processing each

transaction and a variable ad valorem cost for the risk of fraud”. 1239 Infra ¶ 447.

Page 280: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

280

against the unapproved coordination between Visa and MasterCard, which prevented

competition between acquirers of Visa and MasterCard for merchants.1240

674. The Hungarian Authority did not rule out the possibility that an interchange fee agreement

between issuers and acquirers of Visa and MasterCard (such as in Israel) might be efficient, but

it did determine that the specific interchange fee rate in Hungary was not proportional to the

competitive concerns it created, and that possible benefits from the interchange fee did not pass

through to merchants and cardholders. It seems that if approval had been sought (along the lines

of the motion to approve the Trio Agreement in Israel that also involves MasterCard and Visa),

the agreement would be thoroughly investigated and the conclusion may have been different,

i.e., the unapproved arrangement would have been sanctioned.1241

675. In 2010, a draft law that regulated, among other things, the interchange fee, and the maximum

MSF was proposed in Hungary. This draft did not evolve into legislation.1242

676. United Kingdom - in 2000, the central bank promulgated a detailed report known as the

Cruickshank Report.1243 This report argued that issuers inflate the interchange fee and use it as

a barrier to entry.1244 The report also determined that banks charge interchange fees that are

way over and above their costs.1245

677. Following the Cruickshank report, the Office of Fair Trading ("OFT"), today the Competition

and Markets Authority ("CMA"), began a long investigation. In 2005, the OFT issued a

comprehensive decision regarding MasterCard's interchange fees. The decision stated that

MasterCard cards are a relevant market; that both issuers and acquirers were parties to a

restrictive arrangement that took two forms: First, the interchange fee set a floor to the MSF. It

prevented issuers from charging lower interchange fees for MasterCard transactions, thus

1240 BACKGROUND REPORT OF THE HUNGARIAN COMPETITION AUTHORITY ABOUT THE UNIFORM AND COMMON

INTERCHANGE FEES SET BY BANKS IN HUNGARY (2009): "[T]here was no real chance for competition between Visa and

MasterCard and competition between the acquiring banks was also restricted". 1241Id. at 2: “The GVH does not contest that collective multilateral agreements may produce substantial efficiencies.

However, the GVH did not find any evidences proving that - mostly due to the distortion of competition resulting from

the common treatment of both card payment schemes – the restriction has only reached the reasonable necessary level

at any time, and that a due share of the benefits reached the cardholders and retailers". 1242 Éva Keszy-Harmath et al., The Role of the Interchange Fee in Card Payment Systems, at 71 (MNB Occasional

papers 96. 2012). 1243 DON CRUICKSHANK, COMPETITION IN UK BANKING: A REPORT TO THE CHANCELLOR OF THE EXCHEQUER U.K.

STATIONERY OFFICE (2000). 1244Id. at 3.97: “First, the schemes have strong incentives to inflate interchange fees above costs. Second, schemes have

incentives to use interchange fees to restrict new entry”. 1245Id. at 3.114: “The Review’s analysis of interchange arrangements for the three major card scheme operators leads to

concerns that interchange fees for credit cards and the Visa debit card scheme are substantially higher than can be

justified by legitimate cost recovery”.

Page 281: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

281

preventing intrabrand competition that could otherwise arise between MasterCard’s issuers.

Second, the interchange fee included unjustified costs. It was further determined that the

interchange fee should be based on the payment guarantee and processing costs, but not on the

cost of the free funding period to cardholders.1246

678. This decision was suspended in 2006 for reasons of procedural discrimination of MasterCard

facing Visa. Thereafter, the OFT announced that it would again review interchange fees of

MasterCard and Visa.1247 In 2007, the OFT announced the expansion of the investigation to

also include debit card interchange fees.1248

679. Subsequently, the British investigation joined the European Commission proceedings against

MasterCard, in which Britain took the side of the Commission. After the European High Court

of Justice dismissed MasterCard’s appeal, and in light of the progress of the European

legislative procedures described above, the CMA decided not to conduct any further or separate

proceedings against Visa or MasterCard.1249 On May 2015 the CMA decided to close the

investigation.1250

680. Poland, in 2006, the competition authority determined that the interchange fee was a restrictive

arrangement that harms competition by setting a floor to the MSF. The Polish decision also

emphasized that competition between networks for issuers tends to increase the interchange fee,

because issuing banks are not willing to participate in a system that will not maximize their

profits, i.e., yield them the highest interchange fee. Thus competition for issuers actually

destroyed banks' incentives to introduce and issue cheaper payment instruments.1251 The Banks

successfully appealed to the Polish Court, and the decision was vacated. Thereafter, the Polish

Authority appealed to the Polish Supreme Court, which ruled in November 2013 in favor of the

1246 CA98/05/05 MasterCard UK Members Forum Limited, OFT (2005). 1247 Press Release, OFT to Refocus Credit Card Interchange Fees Work (Jun. 20, 2006). 1248 Press Releases, Statement regarding Expansion of OFT Investigation into Interchange Fees (Feb. 9, 2007). 1249 CMA Decides Not to Progress Interchange Fee Investigations at the Present Time (Nov. 4, 2014). 1250 CMA's statement regarding the decision to close its investigations of MasterCard's and Visa's interchange fee

arrangements on the grounds of administrative priority (May 2015); CMA Closes MasterCard and Visa Investigations

Following EU Regulation (May 6, 2015). 1251 Press Release, UOKIK, Decision On Determining The Interchange Fee In Visa And MasterCard Systems, at 2

(2007): “A potential consequence of the agreement on the interchange fee rates is also a hampered development of new

payment systems, which require participation of banks (e.g. as issuers) for their correct functioning. The banks may not

be willing to participate in a system that will not bring them profits comparable with the profit made on the collection of

the interchange fee on every transaction made with a card they issue. Consequently, even a more effective, lower cost

payment system may be hampered in its development, with detriment to innovation and consumers”. For expansion see

infra ch. 6.6.3 (Competition on Issuers).

Page 282: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

282

Polish authority, and determined that an anti-competitive agreement had been concluded

between the banks.1252

681. The Polish Authority determined that the interchange fee should be based on costs. However,

in a sharp contrast to Israel, the payment guarantee was not accepted as one of the eligible costs.

The Polish Authority determined that the costs of the payment guarantee are covered by

cardholders via the interest they pay on their credit. This interest compensates issuers for the

entire payment guarantee. Thus, including this cost in the interchange fee would be double

compensation of the same cost. In addition the Polish Authority concluded that providing

payment guarantee causes issuers to be less careful in granting credit to higher-risk cardholders,

thus causing moral hazard.1253

682. In Italy, banks were fined in 2010 for illegal fixing of the interchange fees.1254

9. The Restrictive Arrangement – Legal Assessment

683. Section 2 of the Israeli Antitrust law determines:

2. Restrictive Arrangement

(a) A restrictive arrangement is an arrangement entered into by persons conducting

business, according to which at least one of the parties restricts itself in a manner

liable to eliminate or reduce the business competition between it and the other

1252 EU, Press Release, Poland: The Court of Competition and Consumer Protection Confirms UOKiK’s Decision on

Multilateral Interchange Fees (Nov. 2013). 1253 Ann Borestam & Heiko Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, ECB Occasional Paper Series 131, at 32-

33 (2011): “The OCCP found that the costs of the payment guarantee were being paid twice: first, by cardholders to

their bank in the case of a lack of funds and, second, by merchants as part of the MIF. In addition, considering the

benefits arising from MIFs, banks might not pay sufficient attention to the “quality” of their customers, which could

contribute to increasing MIFs further”. 1254 AGCM, Annual Report, at 18 (2010): “MasterCard's coordinated setting of a specific Multilateral Interchange Fee

(MIF) for credit card transactions in Italy was classified as a competition-restricting agreement equivalent to the setting

of a joint and uniform minimum threshold for one of the price components for the corresponding payment service in the

absence of reasonable economic justifications... the Authority imposed over 6 million EUR of fines on the companies

involved”.

Page 283: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

283

parties to the arrangement, or any of them, or between it and a person not party to

the arrangement. (b) Without derogating from the generality of the provisions of subsection (a), an

arrangement involving a restraint relating to one of the following issues shall be

deemed to be a restrictive arrangement:

(1) The price to be demanded, offered or paid;

(2) The profit to be obtained;

(3) Division of all or part of the market, according to the location of the business

or according to the persons or type of persons with whom business is to be

conducted;

(4) The quantity, quality or type of assets or services in the business.

684. A Restrictive Arrangement under Section 2(a) of the Antitrust Law has four elements: A.

arrangement; B. between persons conducting business; C. binding restriction; D. probability of

harm to competition.1255

685. When an arrangement that sustains the first three elements involves one of the matters set out

in section 2(b), a private occurrence of the general definition in section 2(a) exists.1256 When

any of the four situations that are mentioned in section 2(b) occurs, there is a conclusive

presumption (presumption juris et de jure) that the fourth element, harm to competition, exists.

The fourth element does not need to be proven. It is sufficient to prove the first three

elements.1257

686. Since installing a vertical block exemption in June 2013, the conclusive presumptions do not

apply to vertical restraints and horizontal maximum resale price restrictions (RPM

Maximum).1258 The application of the per-se rule to horizontal agreements only was reinforced

1255 Cr.A 5672/05 Tagar v. State of Israel, para. 44 (Oct. 21, 2007) (English version available at the IAA web site).

http://www.antitrust.gov.il/subject/199/item/33368.aspx : “The definition of a cartel in the Antitrust Law includes four

elements: (1) the existence of an arrangement, (2) that the arrangement be “between persons who engage in business”;

(3) that the arrangement impose a restraint on at least one of the parties thereto; and (4) its interest lies in the essence of

the restraint appearing in the arrangement”. SCL 4465/98 Tivol v. Shef Hayam, 56(1) 56, 95-96 (2001); Cr.A 4855/02

State of Israel v. Borowitz, 59(6) 776, para. 78 (2005); CrA 7829/03 State of Israel v. Ariel, 60(2) 120, 137 (2005); CrA

5823/14 Supersal v. State of Israel, para. 32 (Aug. 10, 2015).

1256 CrA 2560/08 State of Israel v. Yaron Wol, at 36 (July 6, 2009); MICHAL GAL, RESTRICTIVE ARRANGEMENT -

ELEMENTS OF THE PROHIBITION, IN LEGAL AND ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST LAW, 193, 272 ( Michal Gal &

Menachem Perlman eds., 2008).

1257 CrA 2560/08 State of Israel v. Wol, supra note 1256, at 35 (Section 2(b) determines formal test, based on the per-se

rule, in which the prosecution is exempted from proving harm); SCL 4465/98 Tivol v. Shef Hayam, 56(1) 56, 97 (2001);

CrA 7829/03 State of Israel v. Ariel, supra note 1255, para. 16; CrA 5823/14 Supersal v. State of Israel, supra note

1255, at 66-67.

1258 Antitrust Rules (Block exemption for non-horizontal and certain price restrictions agreements) 2013. For expansion

see CA 6233/02 Akastel v. Kalma Vi, 48(2) 635, 647, (2004); David Gilo, Is it Appropriate to Break Antitrust Dam and

Block the Flood in Ad-Hoc Fences, 27(3) Iunei Mishpat 751 (2004); Memorandum, Antitrust Law (Amendment 9),

2005; David Gilo, Restriction that Harms Competition between the Beneficiary and its Competitors, 28 Iunei Mishpat

517 (2005); CrC 1274/00 State of Israel v. Mudgal (12.3.10).

Page 284: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

284

in August 2015 by the Supreme Court.1259 However, the interchange fee is clearly horizontal

price fixing between competitors, so the conclusive presumption applies.1260

687. The arrangement which determines the interchange fee includes all the elements of the

definition of restrictive arrangement. There is certainly no doubt about the first three elements:

688. The interchange fee is determined in a mutual acquiring arrangement. In Israel, it is the Trio

Agreement, which is a written agreement between competitors. The interchange fee

arrangement surely falls under the broad definition of the term "arrangement" in section 2 of

the Antitrust Law, which has been interpreted broadly in the case law, so as to include even a

wink or a nod of the head.1261

689. Issuers, acquirers and the banks that are parties to the Trio Agreement are, of course, persons

conducting business.1262 A person, according to Israeli Law, includes a firm.1263 All of the

payment card firms in Israel are not only “conducting business” entities, but banking auxiliary

corporations by definition.1264

690. Even when the interchange fee is determined by the international organization as an allegedly

unilateral act, it is still considered a restrictive arrangement between the members thereto.

MasterCard claimed, after its IPO that decisions about fees that were considered before the IPO

as joint decisions between competitors should be regarded after the IPO as unilateral decisions

of a single entity.1265 The European Commission rejected this claim. It stated that the

1259 CrA 5823/14 Supersal v. State of Israel, supra note 1255, at 73 (Generally, vertical restraints will be inspected

under section 2(a)and not 2(b) to the antitrust law). 1260 CrA 5672/08 Tagar v. State of Israel, at 27 (Oct. 21, 2007) (Question of the fourth element, harm to competition,

does not arise when agreement is horizontal under sec. 2(b)). 1261 CrA 4855/02 Borowitz, supra note 1255, at para. 79 (English version): “When we come forth to interpret the term

“arrangement” in view of the aforementioned intent of the antitrust laws, obviously the way in which the parties

expressed their consent to the cartel arrangement matters little. A cartel arrangement concluded orally or by a wink or

a nod of the head by one of the parties is no less liable to harm competition than a cartel created in writing with the

parties’ express consent. As stated above, the cartel need not even be legally binding to be considered an arrangement

under the Antitrust Law”; CrA 1042/03 Mezerples v. State of Israel, 58(1) 721, 728 (2003); CrA 5823/14 Supersal v.

State of Israel, supra note 1255, para. 32; Civ.C 396/87 Kisin v. PetrolGas, Dinim (1990). 1262 CrA 4855/02 Borowitz, supra note 1255 para. 81: “The term “persons” in the definition of a cartel

undoubtedly refers to corporations as well... A more complex question is what the expression “engage in business”...

The broad interpretation of the expression “engage in business”... [is] the correct one... The intent behind the

requirement that the arrangement must be concluded between “persons who engage in business” is not to distinguish

between different areas of business but to distinguish between businesses and non-business entities such as consumer

organizations or the State in its governmental function.”; CA 2768/90 PetrolGas v. State of Israel, 46 (3) 599, 604

(1992); Cr.C 366/99 State of Israel v. Ehud Svirsky, at 23 (Feb. 21, 2002); Determination According to Section 43(a)(1)

of the Antitrust Law to Information Exchange between Banks, Antitrust 501411, at 53 (26.4.09). 1263 Interpretation Law, 1981, sec. 4; Interpretation Command [new version], sec. 1. 1264 Banking Law (Licensing), 1981, Sec. 1. 1265 MacDonald A. Duncan, What MasterCard’s IPO Means for Merchant Suit, AM. BANKER (June 9, 2006).

Page 285: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

285

interchange fee is still a restrictive agreement between all members in the MasterCard

organization.1266 The European Court of Appeals rejected once again MasterCard’s position

and affirmed the Commission’s ruling.1267 The European Court of Justice rejected MasterCard’s

second appeal, and upheld the conclusion that, even after the IPO, the interchange fee is a

restrictive arrangement between the banks that issue and acquire MasterCard cards.1268 This

conclusion is in line with other decisions that determined that the interchange fee is an

agreement between competitors, or a decision of an association of competitors that restricts

competition by fixing prices.1269

691. With respect to the restriction element, the interchange fee agreement binds all issuers and

acquirers that are parties to it, to pay (or be paid) the exact rate agreed upon in the arrangement.

The parties waive discretion to agree that any acquirer will pay or any issuer will receive a

different interchange fee. All acquirers and issuers lose their business autonomy in this area.

Therefore the restriction element subsists.1270

692. The final element is the potential of harm to competition, unless the arrangement falls under

one of the conclusive presumptions (per-se rule). The interchange fee arrangement is a

horizontal minimum price-fixing which falls under the conclusive presumption of section

2(b)(1). The interchange fee is the exact price the acquirer pays to the issuer. The essence of

the interchange fee is to provide an arrangement, in which issuers determine the price they (in

their role as acquirers) will pay to themselves, in their role as issuers. Indeed, the general rule

is that a price that is fixed between a seller and a buyer is not regarded as restrictive

arrangement, otherwise every arrangement which includes the price as one of its terms, would

be deemed a restrictive arrangement.1271 However, the double role of issuers and acquirers, as

1266 Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 570, paras 350-367. 1267 T-111/08 MasterCard v. Comm'n, paras.238-60 (May 24, 2012). 1268 C-382/12 P MasterCard v. European Commission, paras. 62-77 (Sept. 11, 2014); id. at para. 76: “[T]he appellants

cannot maintain that a body such as MasterCard cannot be classified as an association of undertakings when adopting

decisions relating to the MIF, since it is apparent… that, when those decisions are taken, those undertakings intend or at

least agree to coordinate their conduct by means of those decisions…”. 1269 Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 684, at 30-31: “[T]he setting of a

multilateral interchange fee seems generally to be considered an agreement between competitors, or a decision of an

association of competitors, that restricts competition by fixing prices”. 1270 Cr.A 4855/02 State of Israel v. Borowitz, 59(6) 776, para. 87 (2005): “A restraint that would be deemed constitutive

of a cartel is one that narrows the latitude that one who engages in business enjoys... be this by forbidding him/her to do

something (e.g., contacting to a given population of clients) or by requiring him/her to act in a certain way only (e.g., to

sell his/her products only at some agreed-upon price); Moshe Boronovsky, On the Elements of the Restriction and its

Object - New and Not New, 5 Mechkarei Mishpat 125, 127, 132 (1987); CrC 1274/00 State of Israel v. Mudgal, at 92

(March 12, 2010). 1271 AA 6464/03 Real Estate Appraisers BAR v Department of Justice, 58(3) 293, 308-10 (2004); Board of Trade v.

United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238 (U.S. 1918): "Every agreement concerning trade, every regulation of trade, restrains.

To bind, to restrain, is of their very essence. The true test of legality is whether the restraint imposed is such as merely

Page 286: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

286

payers and payees at the same time, introduces a price fixing element into the interchange fee

arrangement. Interchange fee is not a price determined at arm's length negotiation but through

a self-dealing process.1272

693. Section 2(b)(1) is satisfied even if the restriction simply “regards” the price. There is no need

for the restriction to set the exact price, as is the case here.1273 Therefore the interchange fee

clearly falls under Section 2(b)(1) of the Antitrust Law, and there is a conclusive presumption

of its anti-competitive potential.

694. In addition to Section 2(b)(1), a simple competitive analysis reveals that the interchange fee has

a potential to harm competition, and therefore also falls under Section 2(a), which requires only

potential competitive harm as an element.1274 This is in line with the European Law, which

also satisfies with potential harm, and does not require proof of actual harm.1275 The potential

for competitive harm is what turns an arrangement to be restrictive under a rule of reason

analysis.

695. Price increase –The interchange fee is determined in an arrangement between acquirers and

issuers that are supposed to compete with each other. Cooperation between competitors

naturally raises fears of competitive harm.1276 This is especially true when the cooperation

between competitors relates to prices. The interchange fee is a major component of the MSF.1277

Coordinating the interchange fee is equivalent to fixing a floor to the MSF.1278 An acquirer

regulates and perhaps thereby promotes competition or whether it is such as may suppress or even destroy competition";

White Motor Co. v. United States, 372 U.S. 253, 261 (U.S. 1963); COMPACT v. Metropolitan Government of Nashville

& Davidson County, 594 F. Supp. 1567, 1572 (M.D. Tenn. 1984); National Bancard Corp. (NaBanco) v. VISA 596 F.

Supp. 1231 (1984); Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 130 S. Ct. 2201, 2217 (U.S. 2010). 1272 Supra ¶¶ 35 (n.75), 104, 613. 1273Cr.C 209/96 State of Israel v. Ohalecha Yaacov, at 54 (Aug. 4, 2002) 1274 CrA 7829/03 State of Israel v. Ariel 60(2) 120, 138 (2005) (The last element of potential harm does not penetrate to

the definition of restrictive arrangement a consequential element of actual harm, potential harm is enough); Cr.C 167/03

State of Israel v. Mordechai Cohen, para. 8 (Feb. 7, 2007). 1275 C‑8/08 T-Mobile Netherlands BV v Raad Van Bestuur Van De Nederlandse Mededingingsautoriteit, para. 31 (June

4, 2009): "[I]n order for a concerted practice to be regarded as having an anti‑competitive object, it is sufficient that it

has the potential to have a negative impact on competition. In other words, the concerted practice must simply be

capable in an individual case, having regard to the specific legal and economic context, of resulting in the prevention,

restriction or distortion of competition within the common market. Whether and to what extent, in fact, such anti-

competitive effects result can only be of relevance for determining the amount of any fine and assessing any claim for

damages". 1276 General Director's Opinion and Guidelines, Opinion 1/08 Cooperation among Institutional Investors with Regard to

Changing the Terms of Corporate Bonds, Antitrust 5001318 , at 4 (Nov. 25, 2008) (Cooperation between competitors

can limit the competition in the area in which they cooperate and can spill over into other activities in which they

compete with each other, actually or potentially); Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics

of Payment Card Associations, supra note 383, at 549: “At a general level, agreements among competitors can be

anticompetitive”. 1277 See supra ¶ 31. 1278 MILRED, supra note 58 (The interchange fee is a floor to the MSF); Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard

Decision, supra note 570, para. 435; Aff'd T-111/08 MasterCard v. Comm'n, para. 163 (May 24, 2012): “It is

Page 287: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

287

cannot offer merchants a MSF that is lower than the interchange fee.1279 If the MSF were lower

than the interchange fee, then the acquirer would have to pay the issuer more than then whole

of its revenue, and the acquirer would necessarily lose money in every transaction (except for

"On-Us" transactions).

696. The interchange fee is an input for the acquirer. Acquirers have no choice but to pass through

the interchange fee to the MSF. The exact pass through rate from the interchange fee to the

MSF depends on the degree of competition in the acquiring market. The higher the interchange

fee, the higher the floor, i.e., the minimum MSF acquirers are forced to charge merchants. Thus,

the MSF is a kind of sales tax merchants pay on card purchases.1280 As with any tax, merchants

pass it along to the prices of products and services they sell. The exact pass through rate from

the MSF to prices of products and services depends on the degree of competition in the relevant

market.1281

697. Thus, the effect of the interchange fee is a small but market wide increase in all prices of goods

which are bought with cards. Concern for a market-wide price increase, even a small one, is

sufficient to sustain any rule of reason analysis and especially the fourth element in the

definition of "restrictive arrangement" under section 2(a) of the Antitrust Law: potential harm

to competition.1282 In the next chapter I elaborate on the concern for price increase and other

competitive harms stemming from the interchange fee.

To sum, interchange fee is a horizontal price fixing agreement between competitors - issuers

and acquirers who are supposed to compete with each other. The direct effect of the interchange

apparent… that ‘the [MIF of the MasterCard payment organization] sets a floor to MSCs for both small and large

merchants”. Aff'd C-382/12 P MasterCard v. European Commission, para. 193 (Sept. 11, 2014); Comp 29.373 Visa

International — Multilateral Interchange Fee, supra note 247, para. 7.5.2: “The MIF therefore effectively imposes a

floor to the MSC”. 1279 Levitin, Priceless? The Social Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra n 633, at 10: “The merchant

discount fee is always the interchange fee plus an additional percentage taken by the acquirer bank”. 1280 Alan S. Frankel & Allan L. Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 627, 671

(2006): "An interchange fee… acts much like a sales tax, but it is privately imposed and collected by banks, not the

government. It significantly and arbitrarily raises prices based not on technologically and competitively determined

costs, but through a collective process". 1281 Harrison J. McAvoy, Regulation Or Competition?: The Durbin Amendment, the Sherman Act, and Intervention in

the Card Payment Industry, 37 SETON HALL LEGISLATIVE J. 17 (2013): “[M]erchants are charged an interchange fee up

front on every transaction that is processed, that charge is inevitably incorporated into each individual merchant’s cost

calculation, similar to overhead or cost of goods sold. If a merchant is in a competitive market, the merchant will have

to raise its prices to maintain the same profit margin it would have without a transaction fee. This phenomenon is

known as a pass through and is evidenced by pass through rates. In the case of sales tax, economists have found there is

a pass through rate of one hundred percent or greater. Therefore, there is a strong inference that the interchange fee is

essentially passed on to the unassuming consumer. Indeed, merchants estimated that the average household paid $427

towards interchange in 2008”. 1282 Supra note 1274.

Page 288: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

288

fee is to coordinate a minimum floor to the MSF. Thus the interchange fee falls under both

alternatives of section 2 of the Antitrust Law.

9.1. “Bylaws” Interchange Fee

698. In Israel the interchange fee is set in the Trio Agreement which is a territorial agreement

concerning the three card firms in Israel. Whenever there is no previous agreement between an

issuer and an acquirer, a default interchange fee prevails. Assume a tourist pays in Israel with

a payment card that was issued abroad by a foreign issuer, who has no acquiring agreement

with the Israeli acquirer. The Trio Agreement does not apply. A default interchange fee that is

set by the international organization, is the fee that applies.1283

A default interchange fee prevents coordination problems that allegedly could appear without

it, as explained in chapter 8.3.5 above. However, even when set as a default by the international

organizations, the interchange fee does not escape from being considered a restrictive

arrangement.

699. When open networks evolved, default rules such as the HAC were required to persuade issuers

and acquirers to join the networks with confidence.1284 As completion to the HAC rule networks

determined default interchange fees.1285 Without default rules, acquirers could refuse to acquire

cards of issuers that did not assure them in advance remittance of transaction funds. Issuers

would not have let acquirers, whom they did not have previous interchange agreements with,

to acquire their cards. The schemes argued that default interchange fees were required to

prevent situations in which in the absence of prior agreement, issuers could extort acquirers, or

be extorted by them.1286

1283 EC, INTERIM REPORT, supra note 278, at 19: “[W]here banks neither bilaterally nor multilaterally agree on the level

of domestic interchange fees, multilaterally set cross-border interchange fees will apply by default to domestic

payment card transactions as well… The effect of the “fallback” interchange fee system appears to be that in the

absence of an agreement between member banks, there will always be an interchange fee that acquirers pay to issuers,

whether a multilaterally agreed default rate at local level or a multilaterally agreed cross-border fee; this excludes the

possibility that acquirers pay no interchange fees to issuers”. 1284 For HAC rule see supra ¶¶ 53, 95, 586584.6 and ch. 11.2.2. 1285 See, for example, Rules 8.2-8.4 of MasterCard Rules. Rule 8.3 confirms the subordination of the default rule: "[I]t

being understood that all such fees set by the Corporation apply only if there is no applicable bilateral interchange fee or

service fee agreement between two Customers in place". https://www.mastercard.com/us/merchant/pdf/BM-

Entire_Manual_public.pdf 1286 Supra ¶ 52 (The international organizations determine default interchange fees. The default interchange fee applies

unless agreed otherwise in a specific agreement); ¶53 (HAC and NSR apply by default unless a superior rule determines

otherwise); ¶ 86 (due to multiplicity of issuers and acquirers bilateral agreements could not cover all possible

transactions. It became necessary to make general default rules at the association level, to be applied in instances where

there was no existing agreement); ¶ 87 (bylaws determined, inter alia, a default interchange fee to prevail, unless

otherwise provided in a bilateral agreement); ¶ 619 (the hold-out argument assumes a default rule, under which issuers

Page 289: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

289

Today cards are ubiquitous, but issuers still disseminate payment cards to their customers under

the same default rules (but not necessarily the same rates) they themselves created when

networks began to develop. Default interchange fees are subject to any contract or regulation

that determines otherwise.1287An issuer is prohibited from requiring ex-post interchange fee

other than the default, unless previously agreed otherwise with the acquirer. Default interchange

fees apply to all members in open networks in the bylaws of the international organizations.

700. Bylaws create a contract between the members of the organization.1288 Determination of the

interchange fee through bylaws dictated by the international organization, Visa or MasterCard,

is similar to a provision in a contract to which all parties to the bylaws are bound. Therefore,

rules set forth in bylaws, or any other kind of organization rules that contain provisions which

might possibly harm competition, are a restrictive arrangement.

701. In addition, any rule, or even a recommendation, by a trade association, which is liable to

eliminate or reduce business competition, is considered a restrictive arrangement, according to

section 5 of the Antitrust Law.1289

An international organization like Visa or MasterCard, which is comprised of competing

members, can be regarded as a trade association. A "trade association" is defined in section 1

are entitled to demand interchange whatsoever. This assumption is incorrect. There is no such binding default rule. On

the contrary, the default rule might just as well be that in the absence of advance agreement, the issuer must remit to the

acquirer the full sums due i.e., default rule of a zero interchange fee. Under this default, which is no less plausible, an

issuer would be prohibited from requiring ex post interchange fee, unless acceptable by the acquirer. This will put an

end to any holdout argument); ¶ 698 (the same argument may be applied vice versa. Default interchange fee also

prevents holdout situations by acquirers, who could demand transactions funds from issuers, without offering to pay the

issuers any interchange fee, knowing that issuers are obligated by contract or by law, to remit merchants for purchases

of the issuers' cardholders). 1287 U.S GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, GAO-08-558, CREDIT AND DEBIT CARDS: FEDERAL ENTITIES ARE TAKING

ACTIONS TO LIMIT THEIR INTERCHANGE FEES, BUT ADDITIONAL REVENUE COLLECTION COST SAVINGS MAY EXIST, at 2

n.4 (2008): "The default interchange rates apply when there are no other interchange fee arrangements in place between

an issuer and an acquirer". 1288 See, by syllogism, Sec. 17 of the Company Law (1999); see also CA 524/88 Pri Haemek v. Sde Yaacov, 45(4) 529,

542 (1991). 1289 Section 5 of the Antitrust Law titled: Determination of a Course of Action by a Trade Association, states: “A

course of action determined by a trade association for its members or some of them, which is liable to eliminate or

reduce business competition among them, or such course of action which the trade association recommended to them,

shall be deemed to be a restrictive arrangement as defined in Section 2, and the trade association and any member acting

in accordance with such course of action shall be deemed to be party to a restrictive arrangement”. For expansion:

Determination According to Section 43(a)(2) - Course of Action of Private Hospitals is a Restrictive Arrangement,

(Nevo, Dec. 31, 2007); Appeal 2/89 Moetzet Hamovilim v. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 3001546 (1991); C.C

(T-A) 1617/93 Volkan v. Igud Hamusachim, 1994 (3) 274 (1994); Exemption According to Section 14 - Arrangement

between Members of the Israeli Bar Association, Antitrust 5000697 (2004); Exemption for Members of the Israeli Bar

Association - Campaign "Apartment from Contractor", Antitrust 5000052 (2004); Determination - Course of Action of

Travel Agents, 3001432 Antitrust (1997); Decision regarding Actors Association, Antitrust 3003746 (1994); Exemption

to Insurance Companies Union, Dissemination of Research about Earthquakes Damages, Antitrust 3001359 (1996).

Page 290: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

290

of the Antitrust Law as: “a body of persons, whether or not incorporated, all or some of whose

purposes involve the promotion of the business interests of its members”. Members of the

organizations are payment card firms and their controlling banks. The organizations certainly

act for the promotion of the business interests of their members. Thus, the international

organizations Visa and MasterCard can be regarded as trade associations, as defined in the

Antitrust Law.

702. An interchange fee that is determined by trade associations can be seen as a "course of action",

which is deemed to be a restrictive arrangement. The interchange fee is a price constraint that

all parties to the association adhere to. It therefore falls under the conclusive presumptions of

section 2, which also applies in section 5. When a section 5 course of action involves one of the

matters set forth in Section 2(b), the conclusive presumption regarding the potential harm to

competition exists with respect to that "course of action".1290 In the matter of the Israeli

insurance cartel, in all three instances, courts ruled that section 5 broadens Section 2, and is not

intended to narrow the scope of section 2.1291

703. The purpose of Article 5 of the Antitrust Law is to prevent trade associations from imposing

restrictive arrangements disguised as unilateral decisions or recommendations of the

association.1292

MasterCard claimed before the European Commission that following its IPO, interchange fees

should be considered as a unilateral determination, and not a restrictive arrangement between

association of undertakings. The Commission rejected this argument on the grounds that

interchange fee, which is allegedly determined “unilaterally” by MasterCard as one

organization, is actually determined by all the financial institutions together that make up

MasterCard. The General Court and the Court of Justice of the European Union, to which

1290 Determination According to Section 43 of the Antitrust Law Regarding a Course of Action between Real Estate

Appraisers - Dissemination of a Minimum Tariff, Antitrust 3006353 (1995); Exemption to Restrictive Arrangement

between Members of the Bar Association - "Operation Will", Antitrust 5000697 (2004). 1291 Cr.C 417/97 State of Israel v. Haphenix, Dinim, para. 203 (Dec. 18, 2001); Cr.A 4855/02 Borowitz v. State of Israel,

59 (6) 776, 879 (2005); SCL 5189/05 Ayalon v. State of Israel, at 19-20 (Apr. 23, 2006). 1292 Cr. A 4855/02 Borowitz, ibid at 879: “The purpose of Section 5 of the Antitrust Law, in our view, is to cope with a

situation in which unrestrained competition in a given industry has been harmed by the action of a business association

that issues its members with “recommendations” to which they adjust their behavior.”;

Cr.C 4016-06-12 State of Israel v. Ezra Shoam, (Feb. 23, 2014); Exemption with Conditions to "Choices" Foundation,

Antitrust 5001365, part 4.3 (Feb. 15, 2009).

Page 291: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

291

MasterCard appealed, affirmed. Both courts ruled that even after the IPO, the interchange fee

is determined in practice by all MasterCard members, and not as a unilateral decision.1293

704. Therefore, an interchange fee that is a product of a bylaw or a trade association rule is also a

restrictive arrangement that sets the price floor for the MSF.

9.2. Adaptation To Existing Interchange Fee

705. An issuer or acquirer that adheres to an interchange fee arrangement that was set by third parties

is deemed to be seen as a direct party to the restrictive arrangement of the interchange fee.

Section 6 of the Antitrust Law, titled "Adaptation to a Restrictive Arrangement", states:

A person conducting business and aware of the existence of a restrictive

arrangement, who adapts his actions to such arrangement, in whole or in part, shall

be deemed to be party to such arrangement.

706. Therefore, even if an issuer or acquirer was not a party to the initial Trio Agreement or any

other (default) arrangement which sets the interchange fee, once that issuer or acquirer is aware

of the interchange fee restrictive arrangement and "only" adheres to it, this issuer or acquirer is

deemed to be a party to the restrictive arrangement of the interchange fee.1294

The conclusion is that the interchange fee arrangement is a restrictive arrangement whether

according to section 2, 5 or 6 of the Antitrust Law.

707. However, the fact that the interchange fee is a restrictive arrangement is not the end of the story,

but rather its beginning. Under the Antitrust Law, even a horizontal restrictive arrangement that

falls under the conclusive presumptions of section 2(b) can obtain legitimacy and be

approved.1295 Approval can be granted either by exemption from the General Director under

section 14; or a temporary permit from the court under section 13; or the Antitrust Tribunal's

approval under section 9; or compliance to a block exemption installed under section 15A of

the Antitrust Law.

1293 Supra ¶ 690. 1294 CrA 2929/02 State of Israel v. Svirsky, 57(3) 135, 144 (2003); Cr.C 377/04 State of Israel v. Yaron Wol, para. 37

(July 3, 2007) (Passive party to a restrictive arrangement who adopted it without being a side to its creation – is a side to

a restrictive arrangement). 1295 CrA 5672/05 Tagar v. State of Israel, para. 48 (Oct. 21, 2007): “[T]he Israeli judicial system allows for the

possibility of sanctioning a cartel. A cartel may be sanctioned by securing the approval of Antitrust Court or by

obtaining immunity from the General Director from the need to seek the court’s approval”;

AT 13/93 Adanim Bank v. Consumer Council, at 10 (Jan 27, 1997) (The Tribunal is permitted, and even must, consider

sanctioning a restrictive arrangement, whether of section 2(a) or 2(b), according to the conditions by law).

Page 292: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

292

708. Indeed, there are many situations in which cooperation between competitors is recognized as

legitimate, despite the inherent competitive concerns. Cooperation between competitors has

been approved with respect to inter alia, standard settings,1296 joint activities versus government

agencies,1297 actions within trade unions,1298 joint negotiations,1299 self-regulation of an entire

industry,1300 and in other instances.

709. Approval of restrictive arrangements between competitors was granted even in explicit areas of

Section 2(b).1301 This includes cases of horizontal price fixing. For example, a restrictive

arrangement among competitors regarding price-fixing is sanctioned in the selling of copyright

licenses by copyright management organizations.1302 Collective determination of termination

fees in telecommunications is also an approved price-fixing arrangement between competitors

that is similar in many ways to the interchange fees.1303

The question is, therefore, not whether the interchange fee is a restrictive arrangement, since

clearly it is. The question is whether the interchange fee is worthy of sanctioning, and if so,

under what conditions. Ostensibly, the answer has to be negative, for even the most liberal

competition authorities prohibit outright minimum price fixing between competitors.1304 The

prohibition against minimum price fixing between competitors is the keystone of Antitrust

Law.1305 Minimum price fixing leads to higher prices, lower outputs and diminution of

1296 Opinion 3/14 regarding Trade Associations and their Activities, Antitrust 500682, paras. 8, 44-46 (Sept. 24, 2014);

Exemption to Israeli Harbours, Antitrust 5001292, at 8-9 (Oct. 12, 2008); Guidelines on the Applicability of Article 101

to Horizontal Co-Operation Agreements, O.J C 11/1, at 55 (Jan. 14, 2011); ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW,

HANDBOOK ON THE ANTITRUST ASPECTS OF STANDARDS SETTING, at 24 (2004): “Many standards are created through

the formal collaboration of industry participants and include a variety of different types of standards”. 1297 Opinion 3/14 regarding Trade Associations and their Activities, paras. 34-39; Opinion 1/00 Cooperation between

Competitors Versus Governmental Authorities, Antitrust 3007119 (Feb. 6, 2000). 1298 Exemption regarding the “Choices Foundation”, supra note 1292; Exemption to Insurance Companies Union,

Antitrust 5001658 (2010).

1299 Exemption to Agreement between the Israel Hotels Association and its Members regarding Joint Negotiation with

Copyright Management Cooperation, Nevo (Oct. 16, 2002). 1300 AT 508/04 Taagid Haisuf v. Adam Teva Vadin, (Sept. 13, 2005); Exemption with Conditions to T.M.I.R, Antitrust

5001799 (June 30, 2011). 1301 For example, Exemption to Veolia and Tahel for Cooperation in Bids, Antitrust 5000999 (July 1, 2008); Exemption

regarding Common Holidays in Private Kinder Gardens, Antitrust 5001534 (Dec. 22, 2009). 1302 AT 3574/00 Music Federation v. Antitrust General Director (Apr. 29, 2004; Broadcast Music v. CBS, 441 U.S. 1

1979). 1303 Infra ¶ 455. 1304 CrA 2560/08 State of Israel v. Yaron Wol, at 80 (July 6, 2009) (Horizontal Price Fixing is the reason for antitrust

laws from the outset and citing United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co. 310 U.S. 150 (1940) “combination formed for

the purpose and with the effect of raising, depressing, fixing, pegging, or stabilizing the price of a commodity in

interstate or foreign commerce is illegal per se”). 1305 Carlton & Frankel, The Antitrust Economics of Credit Card Networks, supra note 433, at 644: “One standard reason

given for why certain joint conduct among competitors should be treated as illegal per se, whether or not the

participants collectively have market power, is that some activities (such as naked price-fixing) are deemed so unlikely

to have redeeming efficiency effects that it is simpler and less costly in the long run simply to ban those activities”.

Page 293: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

293

aggregate welfare, with particular harm to consumer welfare.

Despite all the factors weighing against it, the interchange fee has unique "redeeming" qualities

that call for different treatment from ordinary price-fixing rules, and indeed justify its approval

(though with conditions) all over the world. As explained in chapter 7, payment cards are a two-

sided network product. The interchange fee is a balancing mechanism to internalize network

and usage externalities. When interchange fee proceeds are used to cover costs and induce

efficient usage of cards, then interchange fee is justified, albeit being a minimum price fixing.

Only when the interchange fee rate exceeds its legitimate goals, the excessive part can be

considered illegitimate and to raise competitive concerns.

10. The Competitive Concerns

710. An arrangement is restrictive under Section 2(a) of the Antitrust Law, if it has the potential to

cause competitive harm. The potential for competitive harm is also what turns an arrangement

to be restrictive under a rule of reason analysis. Excessive interchange fee is liable to cause at

least three competitive harms.

10.1. Price Increase

711. The annual turnover of payment cards in Israel is above NIS 250 billion.1306 Every thousandth

of the interchange fee is equivalent to more than NIS 250 million collected annually. Merchants

pass through this input to final prices. The pass through rate is a function of the degree of

competition in the relevant market. The more the market is competitive, the larger is the pass

through rate. A rise in the interchange fee reflects in a small but market-wide price increase for

all customers.1307

712. The concern of increase in prices is intensified under common assumptions of rigid card

demand among merchants (mainly because of strategic considerations), and issuers that possess

market power. Under such assumptions the interchange fee is a tool to extract surplus from

1306 Supra ¶ 56. 1307 EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees, supra note 1042, at 2: “[H]igh Interchange Fees paid by

merchants result in higher final prices for goods and services, which are paid by all consumers.”; Robert J. Shapiro &

Jiwon Vellucci, The Costs of “Charging it” in America: Assessing the Economic Impact of Interchange Fees for Credit

Card and Debit Card Transactions, at 2 (2010): “[I]nterchange fees add approximately 1 to 3 percent to the price of

virtually everything”; id. at 11: “Since the largest direct effect of interchange fees is the higher prices that merchants

have to charge, and the credit card networks forbid price differentiation based on how a consumer pays for a good or

service, all consumers bear this cost whether or not they use credit cards”.

Page 294: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

294

merchants and remit it to the issuers’ side where it is less competed away.1308 Issuers keep part

of the revenue as profit, and reward cardholders the minimum that is necessary to keep them as

active users.1309 When the pass through rate on the issuing side is not full, issuers keep part of

interchange fee as profit, allegedly strengthening the need for interchange fee, but in fact

inflating it and using it as a profit source.1310 On the merchant side the interchange fee is raised

to the maximum level merchants can absorb.1311 The result is a price increase of goods.

713. The greater the inherent benefits from card usage cardholders have, the fewer rewards are

needed to keep the level of card usage from falling. The interchange fee is used as a tool to

exploit merchants for issuers' profit, at the cost of economy-wide price increases.1312

714. The concern of a rise in prices exists even if we assume full pass through. This assumption is

far from reflecting reality, but even under it, the interchange fee that maximizes the volume of

transactions, causes a rise in prices that has no redeeming value for all those who do not pay

with cards, or for those cardholders who do not enjoy rewards.1313

10.2. Cross-Subsidization

715. The claim that whoever pays by other payment instruments subsidizes card users, was first

raised by Carlton & Frankel in 1995, and then several times thereafter.1314 The thrust of the

argument is that since the interchange fee is a percentage of the sales, it can be viewed as a kind

of tax imposed on merchants. Merchants pass this tax on to all of their customers. Cardholders

receive a partial refund in the form of rewards, whereas other payers receive nothing and

1308 Supra note 1110.

Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1280, at 634. 1310 Julian Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees, supra note 681, at 25: “Privately optimal

interchange fees may be too high if merchant fees increase with interchange fees but issuers do not rebate the additional

interchange fee revenue back to cardholders.”;

Vickers, supra note 743, at 234: “[I]f rebates to cardholders move less than one-for-one with the interchange fee, raising

the interchange fee will tend to increase the aggregate profit of the banks. In that case, the banks would have a natural

commercial incentive to achieve and maintain high interchange fees”. See also supra ¶¶392-396. 1311 See supra ¶392 and note 686. 1312 GAO-10-45, supra note 28, at 27-28. 1313 Farrell, supra note 742, at 29: “The shift [in the interchange fee – O.B] instead just encourages cardholders to use

CARD rather than CASH, partly by lowering the full price to cardholders of buying the good using CARD, and partly

by raising the full price of doing so using CASH". 1314 Levitin, Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L. REV.

1321, 1356 (2008); Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 570, para. 707; Shapiro &

Vellucci, supra note 1307, at 11; Sujit Chakravorti, Theory of Credit Card Networks: A Survey of the Literature, 2 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 50, 64 (2003): “Economic models generally find that cash users subsidize card users when the cost to

merchants is greater than the benefits received”.

Page 295: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

295

effectively fund the full tax. Even with no rewards (let alone with them) payers with cheap

payment instruments subsidize cardholders:

Interchange fees can be viewed as a way to raise costs to merchants who then pass

those costs on to cash and credit customers alike by charging the same higher price

to both. Cash customers are essentially being taxed to finance credit customers

because the interchange fees eventually flow back to the card-issuing banks that

will be forced by competition to give back at least part of the interchange fees in

the form of rebates or lower fees to their credit card customers.1315

716. When cards are more expensive for merchants than other payment instruments, but merchants

do not surcharge, those who pay with the cheap payment instrument subsidize those who pay

with the expensive payment instrument. All customers pay the same price, but those who pay

with cheap payment instruments could pay less, if they did not have to subsidize the expensive

payment instrument.1316

Cross-subsidization between payment instruments occurs only if merchants do not surcharge.

Surcharging neutralizes the interchange fee and eliminates cross subsidization.1317

717. Cross subsidy occurs if and only if cards are more expensive than other payment instruments,

causing negative usage externality.1318 The higher the interchange fee is, the higher is the risk

of negative usage externality, and that cards are in fact subsidized by other payment

instruments.1319 If cards are in fact cheaper than cash (Pcards<Pcash), and merchants do not

surcharge, then cash payers subsidize card payers.1320

1315 Carlton & Frankel, The Antitrust Economics of Credit Card Networks, supra note 433, at 660-61. 1316 MICHAEL L. KATZ, REFORM OF CREDIT CARDS SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA II COMMISSIONED REPORT, at 41 (Reserve Bank

of Australia, 2001): "When card-based transactions are more costly to merchants than are non-card-based transactions,

non-card users are hurt by card use because merchants have incentives to raise retail prices to reflect their higher costs”;

Steven Semeraro, The Antitrust Economics (and Law) of Surcharging Credit Card Transactions, 14 STAN. J. L. BUS.

FIN. 343, 350 (2009); JACOB CHERTOF AND AMI TZADIK, CREDIT CARDS MARKET: ANALYSIS, REGULATION AND

INTERNATIONAL COMPARISON, KNESSET RESEARCH CENTER, at 6 (2010). 1317 Supra ch. 6.5. 1318 Supra ¶ 474. 1319 Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees, supra note 773, at 16: “The higher the MIF, the larger the cross-subsidy

for cash”. 1320 Leo Van Hove, Cost-Based Pricing of Payment Instruments: The State of the Debate, 152 DE ECONOMIST 79 (2004)

(Arguing that cash users subsidize card users); James J. Mcandrews & Zhu Wang, The Economics of Two-Sided

Payment Card Markets: Pricing, Adoption and Usage, at 25 (Fed. Res. Bank of Kansas City Research Working Paper

08-12. 2008): “[C]ash users are “subsidized” by card users”; Christian Ahlborn, Howard H. Chang & David S. Evans,

The Problem of Interchange Fee Analysis: Case without a Cause? 2 PAYMENT CARD REV. 183, 196 (2004): “Cash and

checks have been subsidized by the government and in some countries these subsidies continue. Moreover, in many

countries consumers do not pay the direct cost of using cash and checks and therefore tend to use them too much…

banks do not usually charge people for taking cash out at a bank branch counter or on their ATM card on the bank’s

ATMs, even though the bank incurs corresponding costs. Likewise, many customers get free checks. Card customers

therefore may subsidise cash and check customers at the banks”.

Page 296: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

296

718. The argument that cardholders are subsidized by cash payers, if true, has a social implication.

The most lucrative and expensive cards for merchants are less widespread among financially

weaker populations who tend to use cash or cheap cards.1321 In this situation, if merchants do

not surcharge, the weaker sectors finance the stronger sectors. An OECD report stated:

To the extent that retail prices are uniform for purchasers who use payment

mechanisms with different costs, the users of the high-cost payment mechanisms

are likely receiving benefits akin to a cross-subsidy from users of the low-costs

payment systems. That is, the users of the high cost payment mechanisms would

pay less than they would were they charged for the full cost of using their payment

system and the users of the low-cost payment mechanism would pay more than

they would in the absence of the high-cost payment mechanism. This pattern of

support may have perverse income distribution effects because the users of low

cost payment systems are more likely to be low income than the users of high-cost

payment systems.1322

719. In the U.S., a study by Hayashi & Stavins found that affluent population is more likely to use

credit cards and the weaker population is more likely to use debit.1323 This implies that when

merchants do not surcharge, lower-income debit users subsidize wealthy credit users. Schuh et

al. found that on average, each household that uses credit cards receives each year hundreds of

dollars from those who pay with other payment instruments (cash and debit cards), and that the

highest-income households receive $750 every year from lower-income households.1324

1321Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Social Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, at 43, SSRN (2008), available at

http://ssrn.com/paper=973970; Scott Schuh et al., Who Gains and Who Loses from Credit Card Payments? Theory and

Calibrations, at 6 (FRB of Boston Public Policy Discussion Papers No. 10-03. 2010): “The literature has found a

positive relationship between income and credit card adoption”. 1322 OECD, POLICY ROUNDTABLES COMPETITION AND EFFICIENT USAGE OF PAYMENT CARDS DAF/COMP 32, at 9

(2006). See also Levitin, Social Costs, id. at 18: “[C]onsumers holding rewards cards tend to be more affluent than

those holding regular cards, both because of targeted card issuer marketing and the greater financial sophistication

associated with more affluent consumers”; EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees, supra note 1042, at 3:

“The result of the collectively agreed fees and transparency reducing measures is that banks are not made to compete on

this element of their fees, which leads to higher retail prices to consumers, including those who do not pay with a card

or who pay with low fee cards. In fact, the latter consumers are subsidising the use by other often wealthier

consumers of more expensive means of payment through higher retail prices.”; Frankel & Shampine, The

Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1280, at 633 n. 19. 1323 Fumiko Hayashi & Joanna Stavins, Effects of Credit Scores on Consumer Payment Choice, FRB Boston Discussion

Paper no. 12-1, at 27 (2012): “[C]onsumers with higher credit scores are less likely to use debit cards and more likely to

use credit cards. We estimate the effect of credit scores on both adoption and use of debit and credit, and find that even

when controlling for several variables that affect payment behavior, higher credit score indicates a higher probability of

holding a credit card, and a lower probability of holding a debit card”. 1324 Schuh et al., Who Gains and Who Loses from Credit Card Payments?, supra note 1321, at 1: “On average, each

cash-using household pays $149 to card-using households and each card-using household receives $1,133 from cash

users every year. Because credit card spending and rewards are positively correlated with household income, the

payment instrument transfer also induces a regressive transfer from low-income to high-income households in general.

On average, and after accounting for rewards paid to households by banks, the lowest-income household ($20,000 or

less annually) pays $21 and the highest-income household ($150,000 or more annually) receives $750 every year". For

criticism: Steven Semeraro, Assessing the Costs & Benefits of Credit Card Rewards: A Response to Who Gains and

Who Loses from Credit Card Payments? Theory and Calibrations, (2012).

Page 297: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

297

Another study confirmed the finding of cross-subsidies in gas stations and groceries.1325 In

Australia, cross-subsidy of payment instruments with similar social implications was also

found.1326

720. Cross subsidy is not only between cash and card customers, but also between debit and credit

cardholders, and between 'light' payment card users who do not receive rewards, and heavy

users for whom some prices are lower due to rewards. All cardholders participate in the costs

of providing rewards such as flight points, because goods’ prices go up for everyone.

Nevertheless only heavy users enjoy the advantages of free flights.

721. Cross-subsidy between payment instruments is not only reflected in harm to customers of the

cheap payment instrument. It also causes harm to competition between payment instruments,

by raising rivals' costs. When merchants do not surcharge, the cost of the expensive payment

instrument blends with the costs of the cheap payment instrument. Lack of segregation raises

the price of the cheap payment instrument and reduces its attractiveness.1327

10.3. Overuse And Over-Issuance

722. The interchange fee raises concerns of over-issuance and overuse of payment cards. This is

actually a concern for a quantitative distortion in the market of payment instruments.

723. An interchange fee internalizes externalities. When the fee encourages adoption of cards, it

internalizes network externality. When the fee encourages efficient usage, it internalizes usage

externality. However, even network products have an optimal size.1328 When interchange fee

causes cardholder fees to be zero, or even negative, and bestowing rewards encourages even

1325 Efraim Berkovich, Card Rewards and Cross-Subsidization in the Gasoline and Grocery Markets, 11 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 1 (2012). 1326 Philip Lowe, Reform of the Payments System, at 14 (March, 2005): “It is, of course, true that the credit card reforms

have not affected everyone equally. Those that benefited most from the previous arrangements were those who used

credit cards heavily and paid off the balance before the due date. More often than not these people tended to be those

on high incomes. The reforms have undoubtedly made credit cards relatively less attractive for these people. It is easy

to forget, however, that the benefit that these people were receiving, and are still receiving, is paid for by someone else;

in particular, those who predominantly use cash or debit cards to make their payments. These people were effectively

paying higher prices for their goods and services than would otherwise have been the case, to pay for the subsidies to

credit card users. Not only is this inefficient, but it means that people on lower incomes were often effectively

subsidizing those on higher incomes”. 1327 Farrell, supra note 742, at 31: “In this way CARD’s seemingly internal choice of fee structure can in effect raise

rivals’ costs, or more precisely lower the joint surplus achieved by trade using payment-instrument rivals”.

AT 11333-02-13 Isracard v. Antitrust General Director, para. 36 Antitrust 500647 (March 9, 2014). 1328 Supra ¶ 418.

Page 298: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

298

more adoption and usage, then, as in any other product that is priced too low with respect to its

cost, there will be over-consumption of that product.1329

724. A distinction should be made between (1) over-issuance or over-supply that increases the

overall number of cards, and (2) over-usage of cards that increases the volume of (too many)

transactions.

Over-Usage

725. Once a payment instrument is more expensive, then seemingly all transactions made with it can

be considered over-usage from a social point of view. Therefore, as noted by Evans &

Schmalensee, the issue of over-usage should consider also the benefits and not only the

costs.1330 Also, the relative costs between payment instruments differ, depending on the value

of the transaction. Cash, for instance, is considered a cheap payment instrument for small

payments but expensive for large payments.1331

726. Payment cards may benefit merchants in such a way that it would be profitable for them to pay

more, in order to expand the volume of transactions being made with cards. The credit function,

which does not exist in cash and debit, enables a merchant to make more present sales at the

expense of its rivals and at the expense of future sales.1332 A merchant might prefer to pay a

higher fee for a credit transaction in which the cardholder needs the credit function. Such a

transaction made with credit should not be considered over-usage of credit.

This argument does not hold when the customer is liquid and does not need the credit function,

but nevertheless uses an expensive credit card. The use of expensive credit card is redundant

1329 Supra ¶ 229; see also KATZ, REFORM OF CREDIT CARDS SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA, supra note 1316, para. 98: “In the

presence of no-surcharge rules, setting relatively high interchange fees can promote inefficiently high levels of credit

and charge card usage”.

Rochet & Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems, supra note 710, at 12: “[T]he market

distortion, if any, must come from an excessive number and usage of cards.”; id. n. 33: “Or from an excessive use of

high-cost payment systems to the detriment of lower-cost ones.”;

Ozlem Bedre-Defolie & Emilio Calvano, Pricing Payment Cards, 5 AM. ECON. J. MICROECONOMICS 206, 207 (2013):

“[T]he profit maximizing price structure (so the interchange fee) oversubsidizes card usage at the expense of charging

inefficiently high fees to merchants”;

Oren Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, 98 N.W. L. REV. 1373, 1414 (2004): ”In addition, the absence of annual and per-

transaction fees implies that consumers will obtain too many credit cards and use these cards excessively for transacting

purposes (e.g., for $1 transactions)”;

REPORT OF THE INTER-MINISTRY COMMITTEE FOR INSPECTION OF MARKET FAILURES IN THE CREDIT CARD MARKET,

MINISTRY OF FINANCE, ACCOUNTANT GENERAL (BOAZ REPORT), at 25 (2007). 1330 David S. Evans & Richard Schmalensee, The Economics of Interchange Fees and their Regulation: An Overview,

Payments System Research Conferences 73, 96 (2005). 1331 Supra note 279. 1332 Supra ¶¶ 359-361.

Page 299: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

299

for transactors, certainly from social point of view (and of course from the merchant’s point of

view). In terms of efficiency between payment instruments, paying with a credit card in such a

transaction is over-usage.

727. In the model of Rochet & Tirole that relates to all payment cards in general, over-usage occurs

when merchants over-internalize the benefits of cardholders. Marginal cardholders are steered

to pay with cards because of the interchange fee, although they could pay with cash. The higher

fee is not necessary for them to make the purchase. It only steers them to pay with the expensive

card instead of cheap payment instrument that they carry anyway (otherwise they would not be

defined marginal).1333

In the model of Rochet & Wright that relates to debit cards versus credit cards, over-usage

occurs when consumers who need the card only as a payment instrument (over-)use expensive

credit cards in transactions that could be made with cheaper debit cards.1334

In the models of Rochet & Tirole and Rochet & Wright, over-usage occurs as a result of a price

reduction to cardholders (because of high interchange fee), which leads to over-usage of cards

in general (Rochet & Tirole) or over usage of credit cards in “ordinary” transactions (Rochet

and Wright). High subsidies bestowed upon cardholders cause them to overuse cards.

In the model of Bedre-Defolie, over-usage occurs because of the two-part tariff of fixed annual

cardholder fees, and then a zero or even negative fee for transaction. This two-part tariff

encourages cardholders to use cards as much as they can, once they have joined the network.

Merchants can only choose to accept or reject cards. Once cardholders pay annual fee, they do

not further internalize the cost of usage. They are eager to use cards. The result is over-usage.

The interchange fee supports this over-usage, because it increases rewards that in turn cause the

over-usage.1335

1333 Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations, supra note

383, at 559.

1334 Jean-Charles Rochet & Julian Wright, Credit Card Interchange Fees, 34 J. BANK. FIN. 1788, 1789 (2010): “For

ordinary purchases, we assume credit cards are inefficient given we assume there are additional costs of transacting

with credit cards. As a result, card networks which maximize profit by maximizing the number of card transactions

have an incentive to encourage over-usage of credit cards by convenience users (even when these consumers do not

need the credit facility) provided merchants still accept such credit card transactions. A card network does this by

setting interchange fees high enough to induce issuers to offer rewards and cash back bonuses (equivalent to negative

fees)”. 1335 Ozlem Bedre-Defolie & Emilio Calvano, Pricing Payment Cards, supra note 1329, at 218: “In our model there is

overusage in the sense that, in equilibrium, the proportion of buyers who choose to pay by card at an affiliated merchant

is always inefficiently high”.

Page 300: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

300

728. Over-usage exists whenever cardholder uses the card, even though the cardholder would have

used a more efficient payment instrument, if the interchange fee were not as high. Over usage

of credit relative to debit occurs, whenever transactors are steered to expensive credit because

of the interchange fee. This causes over-usage of credit and distorts competition between credit

and debit.

729. Another kind of over-usage occurs because of the weak willpower of some cardholders, who

are seduced to pay with credit cards and fall to indebtedness. This over usage is the result of the

“seduction by plastic” and insufficient control on budget constraint.1336 Although this kind of

over-usage should be attributed to the weak nature of cardholders, and cannot be regarded as

over-usage of cards with respect to other payment instruments, the interchange fee is still a

major contributor to it. There is a causal connection between the interchange fee and the

indebtedness of cardholders.

Indeed the interchange fee should not be responsible for all over-usage that is the result of the

“seduction by plastic”, as part of it would occur even if there were no interchange fee at all. It

is the result of the poor inclination of cardholders, who get confused by the seemingly painless

plastic.

However, interchange fee does contribute to default of cardholders, when this default is a result

of issuers' enticements - funded by the interchange fee (especially in the form of rewards and

rebates that are conditioned upon consumption thresholds) - that urge excessive card usage.

730. To conclude, over-usage occurs when: (1) interchange fee is too high and causes negative usage

externality; (2) when debit cardholders use credit when they are transactors; (3) when

cardholders default due to transactions they would have not done at all, if it were not for the

interchange fee.

1336 Supra ¶ 152. See also Adam J. Levitin, The Antitrust Super Bowl: America's Payment Systems, No-Surcharges

Rules And The Hidden Costs Of Credit, 3 BERKELEY BUS. L.J. 265, 288 (2005): “Not only will consumers shift more of

their purchases to credit, but they will also make more purchases because they feel less constrained in credit spending

than they do when spending cash on hand… Credit cards distort consumers' cost benefit analysis and increase

consumers' willingness to pay for goods and to make purchases they otherwise would not. When purchasing with credit

cards, consumers will pay more to get the same goods and services or pay more to acquire goods and services of

marginal value to them".

Page 301: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

301

Over-Issuance Of Cards

731. Payment card firms directly and aggressively market payment cards to the general public.

Marketing efforts are done virtually everywhere: in shopping centers, supermarkets, duty-free

stores, terminals, over the phone, and, of course, inside banks. Marketers try to insert more and

more cards to our wallets. The fixed cost of new cards is almost always zero for an initial period.

In addition the enticement efforts contain promises for rebates, if using the card above a certain

threshold.

However, there are no free lunches. The cost of these marketing efforts must be covered. The

remaining channel of income to issuers, when direct channel of income from cardholders is

blocked, is the interchange fee. It is merchants, ultimately, who finance, through the interchange

fee, the cost of issuers in marketing cards, including expensive cards which usage is to the

detriment of merchants. Absurdly, merchants can find themselves subsidizing the marketing

efforts of their rivals.1337

732. When most customers already have one card in their wallet, issuing the second and third card

does not have any significant social benefit that the first card did not have. This is all the more

the case when the costs of funding the activities related to the issuance of the second and third

card, are not borne by the cardholder, who receive the new card for free. Card-accepting

merchants are the ones who cover at least part of the issuance costs, via the interchange fee.

Merchants then pass through their costs to their customers in increased final prices.

From a social point of view, issuing redundant cards, does not contribute to welfare and is an

example of the “wasteful competition” discussed above.1338

733. Over issuance occurs when interchange fee funds issuing additional and redundant cards from

a social point of view. The costs fall on all merchants directly, and on final prices of goods

indirectly, without conferring redeeming benefits. "Issuing wars" distort efficient allocation of

resources, and result in too many cards held by cardholders who do not internalize the true cost

of the new card in their wallet.

1337 Supra ¶ 350 and n. 631. 1338 Supra ¶¶ 301, 480, supra notes 544, 814, infra ¶ 889.

Page 302: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

302

734. There is one positive side to over-issuance. Cardholders with several cards expand the number

of cardholders who multihome. This, in turn, improves of competition between networks.1339

Multihoming of cardholders increases the elasticity of demand of merchants, and enables them

to refuse expensive cards.1340 Unfortunately, empirical studies found that even under

multihoming in adoption, cardholders tend to singlehome in usage.1341 Thus, positive effect of

over issuance does not offset the negative affect, but only alleviates it.

10.4. Raising Entry Barriers

735. The interchange fee creates a classic chicken and egg problem. Interchange fee is a minimum

threshold income for issuers. New and cheap payment instruments would find it almost

impossible to convince incumbent issuers to waive high interchange fees and issue cards that

bear a lower interchange fee.1342 The European Commission emphasized this point:

Effects on market entry

Interchange fees also restrict market entry as their revenues for issuing payment

service providers function as a minimum threshold to convince issuing payment

service providers to issue payment cards or other payment instruments, such as

online and mobile payment solutions, offered by new entrants... new entrants

would have to offer interchange fees at least comparable to those prevailing in each

market they want to enter. This has an impact on the viability of their business

model i.e. affecting potential economies of scale and scope. This also explains why

in a number of Member States, national (normally cheaper) card schemes have

tended to disappear. The entry barriers interchange fees thus created for online and

mobile payment solutions also result in less innovation.1343

736. This problem worsens because new issuer would need an interchange fee for an initial start-up

period, to establish on the consumer side. New issuer would have to persuade cardholders to

join its network and use it, on account of competing payment instruments. Thus, a new network

would need high interchange fee for the warranted purpose of reducing cardholder fees and

incentivizing usage. The higher the interchange fee a new payment instrument would have to

allocate for satisfying incumbent banks, and convince them to issue its cards - the higher is the

entry barrier created by the interchange fee.

1339 Supra ch. 6.6. 1340 Christian Von Wizsacker, Comments regarding "Reform of Credit Card Schemes in Australia, supra note 743, at

12: “The more cards the purchaser carries around the lower is the pressure on merchants to accept additional payment

systems… merchants can become more selective in the choice of cards which they accept”. 1341 Supra ¶¶ 303-304, 331 note 600 (rewards have a significant positive effect on the use of the card that carries them,

only as long as the reward program exists). 1342 Supra ¶ 419. 1343 EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees, supra note 1042, at 3.

Page 303: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

303

11. Why Merchants Do Not Surcharge

737. The competitive concerns that were mentioned above can be eliminated, or at least be

substantially reduced, if merchants surcharge expensive payment instruments.1344 By

surcharging, merchants can signal their customers that the cost of a payment instrument they

use is higher for the merchant.1345 Empirical studies in the Netherlands and Australia have found

that surcharging indeed steers up to 50% of those who intended to pay with the surcharged

payment instrument.1346

Schuh reports that when Ikea U.K. began to surcharge 70 pence to credit card transactions, 37%

of credit transactions switched to debit, and the credit volume fell by 15%.1347 Other studies

have also found positive effects of surcharging.1348 Another Australian study found that only

4% of card transactions were surcharged, meaning cardholders find ways to avoid surcharges.

Customers who pay the surcharge are likely to place high value on rewards.1349

738. The notion of surcharging, if fully implemented, is that the merchant will have a menu of prices,

which he will submit to its customers, according to the net cost of each payment instrument.

The choice of the customer as to which payment instrument to use, will internalize the full costs

1344 Supra note 456. 1345 Alan S. Frankel & Allan L. Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 627, 648

(2006). 1346 Wilko Bolt, Nikole Jonker & Corry Van Renselaar, Incentives at the Counter: An Empirical Analysis of

Surcharging Card Payments and Payment Behaviour in the Netherlands, 34 J. BANK. FIN. 1738, 1740 (2010): "This

finding suggests that consumers are indeed steered towards the use of cash by retailers who apply debit card

surcharges… Around two-thirds indicate that, faced with such a debit card surcharge, they prefer to pay with cash...

These results suggest that consumers do react to payment fees and adapt their payment behaviour accordingly."; see

also ibid , 1741 note 10;

RBA, REVIEW OF CARD SURCHARGING: A CONSULTATION DOCUMENT, Reserve Bank of Australia, at 3 (2011):

“[A]round half of consumers that hold a credit card will seek to avoid paying a surcharge by either using a different

payment method that does not attract a surcharge (debit card or cash) or going to another store”

Nicole Jonker, Card Acceptance and Surcharging: The Role of Costs and Competition, 10 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1

(2011). 1347 Scott Schuh et al., An Economic Analysis of the 2011 Settlement between the Department of Justice and Credit Card

Networks, 8 J. COMPETITION L. ECON. 1, 23 (2012). 1348 David B. Humphrey, Retail Payments: New Contributions, Empirical Results, and Unanswered Questions, 34 J.

BANK. FIN. 1729, 1734 (2010): “[F]or the Netherlands using 2006 data where merchants are permitted to surcharge

debit card use and consumer and retailer survey data indicate a substitution to cash at merchants that impose a

surcharge”. 1349 Crystal Ossolinski, Tai Lam and David Emery, The Changing Way We Pay: Trends in Consumer Payments, at 43

(RBA Discussion Paper 2014-05): "Despite the strong growth in card use and online retail sales between 2010 and

2013, the frequency of surcharges was stable at around 4 per cent of card payments, indicating that individuals were

typically able to use alternative methods of payment if they were not willing to pay the surcharge. Furthermore, there is

evidence that consumers who pay surcharges are more likely to place a value on rewards programs than those who do

not pay surcharges".

Page 304: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

304

of the chosen payment instrument on the merchant.1350

In practice, surcharging is not a common phenomenon.1351 Merchants tend to price uniformly.

Frankel named this phenomenon: “price coherence”.1352 The reasons why merchants tend not

to surcharge will be described now.

11.1. Uncertainty As To The Appropriate Surcharge

739. How much should be the surcharge? There is no clear answer. The surcharge should not be the

full amount of the MSF, for there are some benefits of card acceptance which the merchant

would agree to pay for. The convenience benefits of the merchants from card use should

theoretically be deducted from the MSF.1353

To find the “right” surcharge, the merchant should first identify the MSF it pays (Pm) for each

card. In Israel, the MSF for a specific merchant is the same for all cards from the same brand.

Cards in other countries, even within the same brand, may carry different MSFs. Premium cards

(that provide greater rewards to cardholders) carry a higher MSF.1354 The cards themselves do

not carry any indication of the MSF that is charged on them. Merchants themselves are not

always aware of the MSF that each card bears.1355

740. Identifying the MSF is a first and necessary stage in the calculation of the surcharge. After

identifying the MSF, the merchant needs to reduce the part of it that reflects the 'right' MSF for

1350 Robin A. Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks: Economics, Industry Developments, and

Policy Issues, at 44 (F.R.B. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 23-09, 2009): “When choosing a payment

method, a consumer would face a menu of prices and would take into account both the price differentials and his or her

own private benefits and costs associated with different payment methods”. 1351 Zenger, Perfect Surcharging, supra note 805, at 2544: ”[S]urcharging very rarely occurs in practice.”; Marc

Rysman & Julian Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, at 12 (2015); Commission Staff Working Document

Impact Assessment, SWD(2013) 288 Final, at 131-34 (24.7.2013), (Tables showing only few percent of surcharging

merchants in Europe). 1352 Alan S. Frankel, Monopoly and Competition in the Supply and Exchange of Money 66 ANTITRUST L.J. 313, 316

(1998). 1353 Hélène Bourguignon, Renato Gomes & Jean Tirole, Shrouded Transaction Costs, at 42, CEPR Discussion Paper no.

DP10171 (Sept. 2014): “If surcharging is to be allowed, the optimal cap is equal to the merchant fee minus the

merchant’s convenience benefit from card payments”. 1354 United States v. Am. Express Co., 2015 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 20114, 39-40 (E.D.N.Y. Feb. 19, 2015): “[I]t is more

expensive for merchants to accept high-rewards Visa and MasterCard cards when compared to more basic cards on the

same networks”. 1355 Oz Shy & Joanna Stavins, Merchant Steering of Consumer Payment Choice: Lessons Learned from Consumer

Surveys, 13-1 FRB Boston, at 5 (2013): “Merchants… currently lack complete information on the exact merchant

discount fees for their customers’ credit cards”.

Page 305: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

305

the merchant, and surcharge only the difference. This seemingly simple step has no less than

three options.

Surcharging The Difference Between Price And Benefits

741. A merchant might want to surcharge the difference between the MSF and the benefits of the

card to the merchant.1356

When considering the price of cards, the merchant might want to add to the MSF other costs,

such as payments for infrastructure, point of sale devices, chargebacks, refunds, payments for

services from intermediaries who provide equipment, fraud detection, processing, factoring and

discounting services.1357

The net benefits a merchant derives from accepting a payment card, in comparison to another

payment instrument is Bm. If the MSF (and possible additional costs) is higher than Bm in the

amount of S1 (S for surcharge), the first option is to set a surcharge of S1 for cardholders who

pay with that card. It is easy see that S1 is a rather amorphous term. It is certainly not easy to

calculate.

The models of Rochet & Tirole and the model of Wright exhibit a private case, in which Pm is

the same size of the merchant’s benefit (Bm), plus cardholders’ average benefit (Bca). Thus the

'right' surcharge according to them should be S1=Bca. The term Bca for itself is amorphous. It is

the perceived benefit of the average cardholder in the merchant's view.

The effects of a surcharge in the size of Bca are that cardholders with an average benefit of Bca

and greater, will continue to pay with cards, while cardholders with transaction benefit that is

below Bca, will be deterred by the surcharge, and pay with another payment instrument.1358

1356 Bourguignon et al., Shrouded Transaction Costs, supra note 1353; Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment

Card Fee Structure: Policy Considerations of Payment Card Rewards, at 12 (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No.

08-08. 2008); Rochet & Tirole, Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations,

supra note 383, at 562. 1357 Bourguignon et al., id, at 2 n. 4: “[I]n the UK surcharge regulation, the attributable costs can include direct costs

beyond the merchant service charge, such as point of sale devices, risk management, charges for reversing or refunding

a payment, or payments for services from intermediaries who provide equipment, fraud detection and processing

services for card payments”. 1358 Julian Wright, The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees, supra note 681, at 8.

Page 306: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

306

742. To implement this exact surcharge the merchants must know exact card prices and benefits, as

well as estimate the average benefit of cardholders. This is not an easy task.

Surcharging The Difference Between Price And Costs

743. Levitin posits another option. If the perceived costs of the transaction in the merchant's view

are C, but the merchant is required to pay MSF which is higher than C (Pm=C+S2), the

merchant may surcharge S2.1359 In this scenario, the surcharge is the difference between the

MSF and what the merchant thinks is the cost of the transaction, or what the merchant perceives

the cost should have been in a competitive outset (when Pm=C).1360

744. In order to calculate the surcharge in this method (S2), the merchant is required to estimate the

costs of the payment card network, and attribute the part of them that in the opinion of the

merchant should be carried by the merchant. Estimation of these costs, such as processing costs,

authorization cost, and, if the merchant is generous, also the cost of payment guarantee is a

formidable task, as authorities in U.S., Europe, Australia, and Israel have discovered.1361 Exact

estimation is probably not within the reach of the merchant. Indeed Levitin was criticized for

this suggestion.1362

Free Surcharging

745. Another approach to setting the surcharge opines that the accurate size of the surcharge is not

of primary importance. The role of the surcharge is merely to signal to cardholders, which

payment instrument is expensive. Any effective signaling suffices. Neither prior knowledge nor

calculation of costs and benefits of the various payment instruments are necessary. The

surcharge should only signal, not even necessarily accurately, that a certain payment instrument

is more expensive than the other.1363

The criticism of this approach states that it is in fact very important to calculate the exact size

of the surcharge. Excessive surcharging might impede the network by over-deterring

1359 Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L. REV. 1321,

1335 (2008). 1360 id. 1361 Supra 495-499, for expansion see supra ch. 0. 1362 Steven Semeraro, The Economic Benefits of Credit Card Merchant Restraints: A Response to Adam Levitin, TJSL

Legal Studies Research Paper no. 1357840, at 32 (2009). 1363 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 1350, at 44: “[Surcharge] does not require

a great deal of information about costs and benefits accruing to the various parties in a transaction; rather, it relies upon

market forces to yield retail prices that reflect those costs and benefits”.

Page 307: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

307

cardholders. Excessive surcharging would eliminate efficient card transactions, and might be

used as a way to exert market power by merchants.1364 On the other hand, a too-low surcharge

fails to signal the real cost of the payment instrument being surcharged.

746. The theoretical concerns about excessive surcharging, when merchants can surcharge without

limitations, were found to exist in practice. The Australian central bank found in 2011 that

merchants tend to surcharge excessively, and not distinguish between cards bearing low and

high MSF.1365 Therefore in 2013 it permitted the networks to limit surcharges to "the reasonable

cost of acceptance".1366

According to a study for the Dutch market, merchants often surcharged up to 4 times the

MSF.1367 The issue was resolved by the European commission in Directive 2011/83/EU on

consumer rights.1368 Article 19 states that "Member States shall prohibit traders from charging

consumers, in respect of the use of a given means of payment, fees that exceed the cost borne

by the trader for the use of such means". The provision limits surcharging to the actual cost of

a payment instrument to the merchant.1369 A similar rule, limiting surcharging to costs, has been

applied in United Kingdom since August 2015.1370

Such limitations are still higher than the economic surcharge. Economically, the benefit of the

merchant, or at least the cost, should be deducted from the MSF. Nevertheless, in my view, as

a general rule, surcharging should be unlimited. Merchants prefer not to surcharge unless costs

1364 Julian Wright, Optimal Card Payment Systems, 47 EUR. ECON. REV. 587, 594 (2003): "When surcharging is

allowed, merchants with monopoly power will exploit their power by setting a price to extract surplus from

inframarginal cardholders.";

Rysman & Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, supra note 1351, at 34: "[I]n reality, merchants will not

surcharge perfectly, with some merchants not surcharging at all and others surcharging excessively in order to extract

fees from consumers with high demand, or perhaps with little information. Allowing surcharging is therefore, at best,

only going to partially solve the problem. In other words, allowing surcharging may be a relatively weak way to address

the concern of inflated interchange fees and may have other unintended consequences". 1365 RBA, REVIEW OF CARD SURCHARGING: A CONSULTATION DOCUMENT, Reserve Bank of Australia at 2-3 (2011). 1366 RBA, REFORMS TO PAYMENT CARD SURCHARGING (March 2013): “The Standards now allow card scheme rules to

limit a merchant's surcharge to ‘the reasonable cost of acceptance’, which includes – but is not limited to – the merchant

service fee that the merchant pays to its financial institution. The Standards therefore continue to ensure that merchants

have the freedom to impose surcharges on the cards they accept, and that they can fully recover their acceptance costs.”;

see also Supra ¶ 663. 1367Bolt & Chakravorti, Digitization of Retail Payments, supra note 726, at 25-26: “[M]erchants may surcharge up to

four times their fee”. 1368 Directive 2011/83/EU on Consumer Rights, OJ L 304/64, Article 19 (Nov. 22, 2011): “Member States shall prohibit

traders from charging consumers, in respect of the use of a given means of payment, fees that exceed the cost borne by

the trader for the use of such means”; see also supra ¶ 584.7. 1369 COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT, SWD(2013) 288 Final, at 136 (July 24, 2013). 1370 United Kingdom, Department for Business Innovation and Skills, Guidance on the Consumer Rights (Payment

Surcharges) Regulations, at 5 (Aug. 2015): “The Regulations: • Ban traders from charging consumers more than the

direct cost borne by them as a result of the consumer using a given means of payment”.

Page 308: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

308

are significantly higher than benefits. If this is the case, then merchants should be able not only

to signal but also to deter consumers from using expensive payment instruments. Merchants

that abuse their discretion to surcharge, should be treated specifically, and be capped in their

ability to surcharge. After all, merchants have benefits from cards. If they surcharge excessively

they would punish themselves. It is for the market forces to settle the equilibrium.1371

11.2. Merchant Restraints

747. A second reason why surcharge is not common is the presence of restraints on merchants,

sometimes by law but most often by covenants in merchants' agreements with acquirers.

Networks avoid surcharging by imposing restraints that prohibit merchants from discriminating

against those who pay with cards, compared to other customers ("Merchant Restraints").

The main merchant restraints are the no surcharge rule (“NSR”) which prevents discrimination

against cards, and the honor all cards rule (“HAC”) that obligates merchants to honor all cards

of the same brand.1372 The rules complement each other. If not for the HAC, a merchant could

refuse to accept the cards of certain issuers. If not for the NSR, a merchant could bypass the

HAC by honoring the card but surcharging astronomically, which is the equivalent of refusal.

748. NSR works in favor of costly payment instruments. For consumers, NSR equalizes the price of

the expensive instrument to that of the cheapest. Under NSR, merchants mostly set prices which

are based on the price of the expensive payment instrument, to prevent any loss on transactions

performed with it.1373

NSR also serves as a barrier to entry, and prevents the spread of cheap and innovative payment

instruments. Where NSR applies, the merchant cannot offer its customers a discount for using

the cheap instrument. For example, NSR can neutralize the merchant ability to signal its

customers that PIN debit is cheap, and hinder the penetration of PIN debit.1374

1371 Supra ¶¶ 272-281. 1372 Supra ¶ 53. For economic models regarding the NSR see supra 6.5. 1373 Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 1359, at 1358: “No-

surcharge rules equalize the price at the point of sale between all payment systems. This equalization accrues to the

benefit of costlier payment systems, particularly credit cards, because they are able to impose a cost externality on the

merchant who either absorbs it or passes it along to the consumers of other payment systems. Essentially, no-surcharge

rules increase the price of all other payment systems to match the price of credit cards”. 1374 Id. at 1358: “[F]or consumers who use credit cards only to transact, and not for their credit function (including

float), PIN-based debit cards offer the same convenience, but are cheaper and securer. For pure transacting, PIN debit is

Page 309: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

309

749. The HAC rule works on two levels. First, the rule requires a merchant who accepts a particular

brand, e.g., Visa, to accept all cards of that brand, regardless of the identity of the issuer.

Second, the rule requires the merchant to accept all of the brand’s products (debit, credit,

prepaid, premium etc.).1375 HAC is a tying arrangement. Once a merchant accepts one kind of

a brand's cards, HAC rule ties all cards of that brand to the merchant.1376

The HAC rule assists in penetration of new types of payment instruments, bearing an existing

brand name. By leveraging the brand name, acceptance of new products, immediately upon

entering the market, is maximal.1377

750. NSR and HAC both prevent the autonomy of merchants to freely price cards NSR ties the price

of expensive instruments to that of cheap. HAC ties products and brands. NSR is contrary to

the principle whereby competitive prices should reflect costs.1378 Therefore, NSR and HAC are

restrictive arrangements.1379 It has been debated in the literature if these rules are prohibited per

se,1380 or should be analyzed under the rule of reason.1381 Under the broad definition of the

Israeli law there is no doubt that they are restrictive arrangements:

NSR

751. In Israel merchant restraints fall under the broad definition of Article 2 of the Antitrust Law.1382

Already by 1993, the Antitrust General Director determined that NSR is a price restraint that

a superior payment system. The use of PIN-debit, however, may well be limited by the no-surcharge rule advantages

given to credit cards”. 1375 NICHOLAS ECONOMIDES, COMPETITION POLICY ISSUES IN THE CONSUMER PAYMENTS INDUSTRY, in MOVING

MONEY: THE FUTURE OF CONSUMER PAYMENT 113, 119-20 ( R. Litan & M. Baily eds., 2009): “There were two aspects

of this rule. First, if a merchant accepted a certain type of card (say, Visa debit) issued by one bank (say, Citibank), he

was required to accept the same type of card (in this case, Visa debit) issued by another bank. The rule also imposed the

requirement that a merchant accept any other Visa products (such as Visa credit cards) if he accepted one (such as a

Visa debit card)”. See also supra ¶ 584.6. 1376 Jean Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Tying in Two-Sided Markets and the Honor all Cards Rule, 26 INT'L J. INDUS.

ORG. 1333 (2008). 1377 Sujit Chakravorti, Externalities in Payment Card Networks: Theory and Evidence, 9 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1, 19

(2010): “Such a rule enables a card network to innovate by producing different products that when introduced will have

a large base of merchants that accept them. The introduction of payroll cards, a type of prepaid card, is an example of an

innovation that leverages a card network’s existing infrastructure”. 1378 Alberto Heimler, Payment Cards Pricing Patterns: The Role of Antitrust and Regulatory Authorities, at 8-9 (SSRN,

2010): “[T]he unfortunate impact of such rules is that they create a situation in which merchant costs differ according to

the payment instrument chosen, but prices that consumers pay do not reflect these cost differences. This mandatory

price coherence is inconsistent with the general principle that, in a market system, prices should be free to reflect costs”. 1379 NICHOLAS ECONOMIDES, COMPETITION POLICY ISSUES IN THE CONSUMER PAYMENTS INDUSTRY, supra note 1375, at

119; Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 1373, at 1400-02. 1380 Levitin, id. at 1399; Frankel, Towards, supra note 811, at 54. 1381 Semeraro, The Economic Benefits of Credit Card Merchant Restraints: A Response to Adam Levitin, , supra note

1362, at 33; Semeraro, The Antitrust Economics (and Law) of Surcharging, supra note 1316, at 376-82. 1382 Supra ch. 0.

Page 310: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

310

falls into the conclusive presumption of section 2(b)(1)1383.

Under the current approach, NSR does not fall under section 2(b) of the Antitrust Law

(conclusive presumptions do not apply to vertical restraints).1384 However, NSR falls within

section 2(a) of the Antitrust Law. NSR is an arrangement between undertakings conducting

business. The effects of merchant restraints raise significant competitive concerns. Both NSR

and HAC might have anti-competitive effects, if they sustain “Gresham's law”,1385 i.e., cause

bad (expensive) money to supplant good (cheap) money.1386 Moreover, NSR can cause prices

to adjust, fully or partially, to the price of the expensive payment instrument. If this risk

materializes then NSR causes a small but wide price increase of all products and services that

can be purchased with the expensive payment instrument. Small but market wide price increase

is a clear example of competitive harm that falls under section 2(a) of Restrictive Trade

Practices Law.

Surprisingly, the final report of the Antitrust Authority on enhancement of efficiency and

competition in the payment card sector noted that some payment card firms in Israel impose

merchant restraints such as NSR.1387 This is surprising because no approval was requested from

the IAA for this clear restrictive arrangement that was already declared a per-se violation in

1993. It is not clear how the IAA can reconcile with unapproved NSR after it was already

declared illegal.

752. In Australia, NSR was canceled in the reform of 2002. As explained above, in 2013 the RBA

allowed networks to limit surcharges to "the reasonable cost of acceptance".1388

In European Union countries, about half allow surcharging (Estonia, Finland, Germany,

Ireland, Malta, Netherlands, Poland, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, United Kingdom) and half

1383 Decision of the Antitrust General Director According to section 43 of the Restrictive Practices Law Regarding

Isracard, Antitrust 3006076 (1993); BANK OF ISRAEL, RECOMMENDATIONS FOR ENHANCEMENT OF COMPETITION IN THE

PAYMENT CARD SECTOR, FINAL REPORT, para. 15.5 at 36 (Feb. 2015). 1384 Supra ¶ 686. 1385 Supra ¶ 435. 1386 OECD, POLICY ROUNDTABLES COMPETITION AND EFFICIENT USAGE OF PAYMENT CARDS DAF/COMP 32, at 8

(2006): “[C]ertain rules have the effect of limiting the retailer's ability to influence the choice of payment mechanism by

the customer. These rules can make merchants less sensitive to merchant fees, by making their demand for card services

more inelastic. The rules also limit the ability of merchants to negotiate for lower rates. Certain of these rules appear to

have largely anti-competitive”. 1387 IAA, ISRAEL ANTITRUST AUTHORITY, HAGBARAT HAYEILUT VEHATAHARUT BETHUM KARTISEI HAHIUV

[ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR], FINAL REPORT, Antitrust 500680

(Sept. 8, 2014) 1388 Supra ¶ 746.

Page 311: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

311

prohibit it (Austria, Bulgaria, Cyprus, Czech Republic, France, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Latvia,

Lithuania, Luxembourg, Portugal, Romania, Sweden). Denmark permits surcharging credit but

bans it on debit.1389 Switzerland abolished NSR.1390 Surcharging, where permitted, is limited to

acceptance costs.1391 The 2015 Interchange Fee Directive prohibits surcharging in payment

instruments of which the interchange fee is regulated.1392

753. In the United States the NSR was practically canceled in the Durbin Amendment and the DOJ

proceedings.1393 However, surcharging was prohibited in some states, including California and

New York, by legislation.1394 This prohibition was recently held unconstitutional. In 2017, the

Supreme Court ruled that New York’s NSR limited merchants’ freedom of speech, which is

protected by the First Amendment, and remanded for the Court of Appeals to analyze the NSR

as a speech regulation.1395 In January 2018, the 9th District held that California’s NSR violates

the First Amendment (but only as applied to plaintiffs), because it prevents merchants from

conveying their customers the true cost of credit card usage.1396 I can only humbly concur and

note these rulings fit my view, as explained supra in ¶ 275.

HAC

754. In Israel, there is no difference in the MSF of cards within a specific brand. In general, the MSF

of American Express and Diners is higher than the MSF of Visa and MasterCard; but within a

brand itself, the MSF for all cards is the same.

Therefore, the HAC rule, which is meant to tie expensive cards to the acceptance of cheap cards,

1389 COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT, SWD(2013) 288 Final, at 131 (July, 24, 2013). 1390 OECD, POLICY ROUNDTABLES, COMPETITION AND EFFICIENT USAGE OF PAYMENT CARDS DAF/COMP 32, at 32

(2006); Heimler, Payment Cards Pricing Patterns, supra note 1378, sec. 3.1; Hayashi, Policy Considerations, supra

note 1356, at 11. 1391 Supra ¶ 746. 1392 Regulation (Eu) 2015/751 Of The European Parliament And Of The Council of 29 April 2015 on Interchange Fees

for Card-Based Payment Transactions, O.J L 123/1, para. 36 (May 19, 2015): “In situations where the payee steers the

payer towards the use of a specific payment instrument, no charges should be requested by the payee from the payer for

the use of payment instruments of which interchange fees are regulated within the scope of this Regulation”. 1393 Supra ch. 8.3.11. 1394 Hélène Bourguignon, Renato Gomes & Jean Tirole, Shrouded Transaction Costs, at 2 n. 2, CEPR Discussion Paper no.

DP10171 (Sept. 2014): “[S]ince January 2013, merchants in the United States are permitted to impose a surcharge on consumers

when they use a credit card, except in states with laws prohibiting surcharging, such as California, New York and Massachusetts”. 1395 Expressions Hair Design v. Schneiderman, 137 S. Ct. 1144 (Mar. 29, 2017). 1396 Italian Colors Rest. v. Becerra, 878 F.3d 1165, 1177 (9th Cir. Jan 3. 2018): “[t]he higher cost is a result of credit

card fees, and referring to the price differential as a discount prevents retailers from accurately conveying that causal

relationship… Section 1748.1 prevents retailer… from communicating with [their customers] in an effective and

informative manner" about the cost of credit card usage and why credit card customers are charged more than cash

users.”

Page 312: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

312

does not have practical significance in Israel. However, HAC applies in Israel as part of the

bylaws of the international organizations.1397

755. The HAC was abolished in Europe for "product tying", i.e., merchants can refuse to accept

expensive cards. However, merchants cannot refuse to accept cards of a certain issuer, if they

accept the same card when issued by another issuer.1398

In the U.S, HAC rule was partially canceled in 2003, following a settlement in the Wall-mart

class action.1399 According to the settlement, merchants can accept debit but refuse credit, or

vice versa. The HAC rule still applies within credit or debit cards, which means that if a

merchant chooses to accept credit (or debit) it must accept all cards of that type, including

premium cards with higher MSF. Therefore, it was claimed that the residual HAC rule that still

exists is anti-competitive.1400

756. Empirical studies in countries that canceled the NSR found that networks expanded; refuting

the claim that NSR is necessary to maintain the size of the network.1401 The effects of

eliminating NSR are discernible only after a period of years. Australia, in which the NSR was

abolished in the reform of 2002, experienced a steady increase over time in surcharges. As of

2012, about 40% of large merchants, and 20% of small businesses, surcharged.1402 In Europe,

surcharging is less common and ranges from 1% in Finland to 14% in Ireland and U.K.1403

757. To sum up, merchant restraints are a sufficient reason that explains why merchants do not

surcharge. Nevertheless, canceling merchant restraints is a necessary but insufficient condition

for merchants to surcharge. For even in the absence of merchant restraints, the majority of

merchants adhere to price coherence. Merchant restraints cannot fully explain why merchants

do not surcharge. The reasons for price coherence are latent in other factors.

1397 Section 6.2 of Visa International Operating Regulations Core Principles, titled “Honoring all Visa cards" states:

"Visa merchants may not refuse to accept a Visa product that is properly presented for payment”. 1398 Supra ¶ 584.6. 1399 Supra ¶ 625. 1400 Levitin, Priceless? The Social Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 1321. See also supra ¶626,

note 1178. 1401 Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 1373, at 1389: “Recent

experience shows that credit card networks have profited and grown in the absence of no-surcharge rules."; United

States v. Am. Express Co. LEXIS 20114 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015); For the claim NSR is necessary see supra ¶ 461. For

a contrary opinion that the expansion of networks was a result of economic growth, see Chang et al. supra note 1207. 1402 RBA, REVIEW OF CARD SURCHARGING: A CONSULTATION DOCUMENT, supra note 1365, at 2; COMMISSION STAFF

WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT, SWD(2013) 288 Final, at 193 (July 24, 2013): “[S]urcharging was slow to

develop among merchants, by the end of 2010 almost 30 per cent of merchants imposed surcharges on credit card

products”. 1403 Id. at 132 (July 24, 2013) (table 35 – proportion of merchants that surcharge, by country).

Page 313: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

313

11.3. Strategic Considerations

758. A main reason why merchants do not surcharge is their concern to not deter their customers and

their fear of losing business.

When cardholders, who are eager to pay with cards, find that they have to pay a surcharge, they

may shop elsewhere, if not for the current transaction, then for future ones. Accepting cards is

an important service that merchants provide. Merchants that surcharge, while their competitors

do not, risk loss of transactions and income.1404

759. Merchants that decide to surcharge extract higher profit from infra-marginal customers, who

still use cards. The downside for surcharging merchants is that they sacrifice marginal

cardholders, who switch to other payment instruments (in the good scenario) or worst - quit

purchasing at that merchant.

Loss of profit from a transaction is usually greater than any MSF, and is certainly greater than

that part of the MSF which a merchant might decide to surcharge.1405 It is sufficient that just a

small fraction of customers abandon the surcharging merchant to render surcharging as not

profitable.1406 In fact, these are the same strategic considerations that prevent merchants from

refusing to accept cards in the first place.1407 If surcharging leads to a fall in sales merchants

would probably refrain from it.1408

760. Nevertheless, the magnitude of strategic considerations is weaker when it comes to surcharging.

Before a merchant refuses to accept cards at all, the merchant would likely resort to surcharge.

If a merchant accepts cards when NSR applies (even if it is because of strategic considerations),

the merchant will probably continue to accept cards when NSR is lifted. At the most the

merchant would surcharge.1409

1404 Chakravorti & To, A Theory of Credit Cards, supra note 638, at 586: “Why merchants do not differentiate between

credit and cash purchases is a difficult question to answer. It may simply be the case that faced with a higher price for

credit purchases, consumers may choose to purchase elsewhere rather than pay a higher price". 1405 Supra ¶ 194. 1406 COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT, SWD(2013) 288 Final, at 135 (July 24, 2013):

“[M]ost merchants, in particular in the traditional retail sector, were reluctant to adopt them [surcharging – O.B], mostly

because of fears of losing customers to competition”. 1407 Supra ch. 6.4. (Rochet & Tirole – Strategic Considerations) 1408 Jonker, Card acceptance and surcharging: the role of costs and competition, supra note 1346, at 7. 1409 Chakravorti & To, A Theory of Credit Cards, supra note 638, at 586.

Page 314: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

314

761. For cardholders, surcharging leads to less negative feelings and less deterrence than total

rejection, so the intensity of strategic considerations that prevent a merchant from refusing to

honor cards is weaker when it comes to surcharging.

A situation, in which merchants do not surcharge because of strategic considerations, is similar

to the familiar prisoner's dilemma. Each merchant separately chooses not to surcharge, because

of fear of losing customers to its competitors. The result is that merchants fail to surcharge. If

all merchants could unite, a decision to surcharge would have put them all in a better

position.1410 Thus, strategic considerations are a good reason for why merchants do not

surcharge.1411

11.4. Surcharging Is Costly

762. Another reason why merchants do not surcharge, even if they can, is that surcharging has its

costs. These costs demand the allocation of special resources, and might be too expensive to

implement.1412

The merchant has to identify the exact surcharge it wishes to collect. Surcharging too little will

not suffice, while surcharging too much might deter more than the merchant wanted. Any

attempt to surcharge requires investment of resources to identify the proper amount.1413

Costs of surcharging include, inter alia, advertising and informing customers about the

existence of the surcharges;1414 allocation of additional human resources and salaries for

employees that are involved in the process of tagging different prices to products and services,

as well as responses to inquiries of customers seeking the best payment instrument to pay with,

1410 OECD POLICY ROUNDTABLES, COMPETITION AND EFFICIENT USAGE OF PAYMENT CARDS, supra note 1390, at 55:

“[M]erchants face a prisoners dilemma: they may have a preference for differential pricing, but individual merchants

are unlikely to introduce differential pricing, because it will irritate some customers and lead to customer loss”. 1411 Rong Ding, Merchant Internalization Revisited, 125 ECON. LETTERS 347 (2014): “[W]hen merchants set a single

price regardless of how consumers pay, merchants also accept cards for strategic reasons, even if their transactional

benefit of doing so is lower than the merchant fee they face. This has been used to explain why merchant fees may be

set too high”. 1412 John Vickers, Public Policy and the Invisible Price: Competition Law, Regulation and the Interchange Fee,

Payments Sys. Research Conference 231, 238 (2005): "[S]urcharging is by no means costless for retailers”. Tamás

Briglevics & Oz Shy, Why Don’t most Merchants use Price Discounts to Steer Consumer Payment Choice?, 12-9 Frb

Boston, at 20-21 (2012). 1413 Supra ch. 11.1. 1414 Briglevics & Shy, supra note 1412, at 20-21 (2012). Steven Semeraro, The Antitrust Economics (and Law) of

Surcharging Credit Card Transactions, 14 STAN. J. L. BUS. FIN. 343, 360 (2009): “Programming systems and training

employees to implement such a scheme would be a costly endeavor with uncertain returns”.

Page 315: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

315

and inquiring about prices. Technology improvements might reduce the cost of surcharging,

but not eliminate it.

763. Another cost of surcharging is notional. It occurs whenever merchants give a price discount to

those who pay with a preferred payment instrument. Customers, who would have purchased

with the favored payment instrument anyway, even absent the discount, still enjoy the discount.

The merchant loses revenue because these customers pay a discounted price instead of full

price.1415

The costlier it is for the merchant to apply the surcharge, the less likely the merchant will choose

to surcharge in the first place.

11.5. Psychological Reasons

764. In the U.S., the Cash Discount Act permits merchants to give discounts for use of cash.1416 This

act led some commentators to argue that cash discounts are equivalent to surcharging cards, so

in reality, nothing prevents merchants from differential pricing.1417

765. Other scholars have explained, based on cognitive psychological theories that there is a

difference between a cash discount and surcharging. While surcharging cards is perceived as a

penalty for cardholders, who might shy away from merchants who surcharge, cardholders have

less hard-feeling if somebody else (who pays with cash) gets a discount. The reason for this lies

in what is known as the "endowment effect". People place a higher value on money they are

losing (paying a surcharge) than on money of the same amount that they have not earned (cash

discount to somebody else).1418

1415 Shy & Stavins, Merchant Steering of consumer payment choice, supra note 1355, at 5: “[O]ffering buyers price

discounts on cash and debit transactions may not be profitable to merchants because cash and debit price discounts

reduce revenues from consumers who would use these lower-cost payment methods even in the absence of price

discounts”. 1416 For expansion see Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 1373, at

1380. 1417 Benjamin Klein et al., Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Antitrust Economics of Payment Card Interchange

Fees, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 571, 610 (2006): "A discount for cash and checks is analytically equivalent to a surcharge for

credit". 1418 Scott Schuh et al., Economic Analysis of the 2011 Settlement between the Department of Justice and Credit Card

Networks, 8 J. COMPETITION L. ECON. 1, 22 (2012): “[I]f consumers must pay a surcharge for credit card transactions,

they view the surcharge as a loss and are less likely to use a credit card, whereas if they are offered a discount for using

cash or debit, they view the discount as a gain”.

Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Social Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, at 48, SSRN (2008), available at

http://ssrn.com/paper=973970: “The endowment effect is a cognitive bias toward preferring assets one currently

possesses more than equivalent assets one does not have”.

Page 316: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

316

766. Another cognitive bias is known as the "framing effect". According to the framing effect, the

way things are presented affects the way they are perceived, even if things are identical.1419 A

cash discount is perceived as profit by those who pay cash, but eager cardholders are generally

not offended that cash payers receive the discounts. On the other hand, a surcharge is perceived

as a pecuniary punishment, and cardholders are irritated when merchants surcharge.

767. The official price, where a cash discount is given, is the higher price. The official price at

surcharging merchants is the lower price. Surcharging merchants risk loss of business, when

angry cardholders reveal they have to pay more than the official price. On the other hand,

cardholders are not offended when they pay the price they prepared for, and somebody else

(cash payers) gets discount.1420 Thus, merchants who want to avoid negative feelings from their

card paying customers, tend to avoid surcharging.

11.6. Small Cost Differences Do Not Justify Surcharges

768. The MSF is a few percent at most. Merchants, who want their surcharge to reflect the exact cost

difference between payment instruments, should surcharge less than the MSF, because the

merchants do derive some benefits from cards.1421

It has been argued that merchants routinely ignore small differentials in costs and pass them on

to all of their customers. Making customers internalize small cost differences is not cost

effective. Merchants prefer to give improved services for free to all customers, so the financial

burden is divided between all customers, even though only some customers use the services.

Merchants simply prefer to not deal with minor cost differences, and this is the reason they do

not bother to surcharge.1422

1419 Levitin, id. at 22; Levitin, The Antitrust Super Bowl, supra note 1336, at 280; Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The

Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L. REV. 1321, 1350 (2008) (points at footnote 93 to the

works of Amos Tversky & Nobel prize winner Daniel Kahneman about Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions) 1420 Levitin, The Antitrust Super Bowl, supra note 1336, at 308-09. 1421 Supra ch. 11.1. 1422 DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND

BORROWING 131 (2d ed. 2005); David S. Evans, Viewpoint: Bank Interchange Fees Balance Dual Demand, AM.

BANKER, Jan. 26, 2001: “All customers end up paying higher prices as a result of retailers offering parking, tailoring,

escalators, convenient store hours, gift-wrapping, and many other amenities that are used by only some customers.

Retailers don't try to charge for each of these services. So, just as with cards, some consumers pay higher retail prices

without getting the benefit of these freebies”.

Benjamin Klein et al., Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Antitrust Economics of Payment Card Interchange Fees,

supra note 1417, at 617: “It is common for merchants to incur costs for various services that do not benefit all

customers to the same extent without passing on these differential costs to the particular consumers using the services.

For example, merchants frequently offer without charge a number of amenities that only some customers use, including

parking, gift wrapping, extended store hours, and delivery. Another obvious example is the practice of restaurants to

offer free coffee refills. This presumably creates a usage externality by consumers of multiple cups of coffee and an

Page 317: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

317

For example, customers who arrive by bus to a shopping mall, share the costs of free parking

merchants pay for customers who arrive by car; customers who buy clothes already in just the

right size for them, fund the payment for free tailoring services the merchant provides to

customers who buy clothes that require adjustment; customers who do not use gift wrapping

services in a shop that gives this service subsidize other customers' use of this service.

769. Nevertheless, there is a significant distinction between the interchange fee and other small

differences such as the examples given above. The interchange fee is a horizontal restrictive

arrangement between competitors. Other subsidies, if any, result from unilateral decision of

merchants.1423 Therefore subsidy between payment instruments is a matter of antitrust concern,

while other subsidies are not. For example, if all owners of parking lots fixed parking fees for

shoppers, it would constitute a cartel that would very much interest antitrust authorities.1424

11.7. Other Reasons

770. Fear of a being a side to a restrictive arrangement. Merchants may fear that if they all

surcharge at the same rate, it will be perceived as a cartel. This is particularly true for competing

merchants. Evans and Schmalensee describe an incident in Denmark where merchants

surcharged a sum of 0.55 Danish Krona, and the competition authority started to investigate if

the uniform surcharge was a restrictive arrangement.1425

771. Regulation that requires price-marking. If regulation requires merchants to mark prices on

their products, the meaning of surcharging is a multiplicity of price tags. Otherwise, the price

at the cashier might not be the one marked on the product, and merchants can find themselves

in violation of the law.1426 To avoid the need of a multiplicity of price tags merchants simply

waive the surcharge, due to the relative costs and resources involved.

In my opinion, price-marking obligation actually applies only to legal tender. Cash is legal

excess coffee consumption inefficiency can be said to exist. However, such so-called cross-subsidization between

consumers is common throughout the economy and is imposed by firms without any market power.”;

Steven Semeraro, Assessing the Costs & Benefits of Credit Card Rewards: A Response to Who Gains and Who Loses

from Credit Card Payments? Theory and Calibrations, at 54-56 (2012). 1423 Supra ¶ 454. 1424 Supra note 772. 1425 Evans & Schmalensee, The Economics of Interchange Fees and their Regulation, supra note 1330, at 93 n. 59. 1426 Levitin, Priceless? The Social Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, supra note 1418, at 25: “A policy

implementing credit card surcharging or cash discounting would inevitably raise consumer protection issues related to

misleading advertising and inadequate or unclear price disclosure”.

Page 318: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

318

tender, but payment cards are not. So, even where regulation requires merchants to mark prices,

there is no duty to mark card prices. Merchants can inform customers about their surcharging

policies in different ways such as advertisements, signs and placards.

772. Lack of knowledge. Some merchants are simply not aware of the fact that they are allowed to

surcharge, give discounts or price-differentiate in other ways. According to Levitin, 3% of

Swedish merchants mentioned the lack of such knowledge as a reason for not surcharging.1427

773. Unique benefits from cards. Some merchants receive special benefits from cards. These

merchants are not good candidates for surcharging. A few non-exhaustive examples are:

773.1 Merchants who operate in a high-risk environment of robberies, theft, or

embezzlement might prefer cards, whose revenue is more difficult to steal;

773.2 Merchants who enjoy cards more than others, such as merchants who sell high value

goods with high profit margins (e.g., jewelry). Cash is not a realistic option for most

of their customers, and checks are risky. In addition, these merchants do not mind

paying a high MSF, as the MSF is minor compared to the profit margin. Such

merchants may have a strong preference for cards.1428

773.3 Merchants who operate online or by phone may find it harder to accept other payment

instruments, and might be willing to pay a high MSF for payment cards without

surcharging. Alternative payment instruments for such merchants such as Pay-Pal or

Bitcoin, which are not as popular as cards, might be even more expensive.1429

All of these merchants can be viewed in contrast to the marginal merchant. They are located

in the upper left edge of the demand curve. Their consumer surplus from cards is high, so it is

unlikely for them to surcharge.

774. Cards might not be more expensive. The underlying assumption when analyzing why

merchants do not surcharge is that the MSF exceeds the benefit from cards. If this assumption

1427 Levitin, The Antitrust Super Bowl, supra note 1336, at 310. 1428 Nicole Jonker, Card Acceptance and Surcharging: The Role of Costs and Competition, 10 REV. Network Econ. 1, 7

(2011): “Merchants selling many or high value products are expected to opt for uniform prices and to be against

surcharging on card payments. For them unit transaction costs fall once they accept card payments”. 1429 Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L. REV. 1321, 1352 (2008).

Page 319: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

319

is not true, then merchants are unlikely to surcharge cards in the first place. They would prefer

instead to surcharge cash or checks.1430

775. In my opinion as we move towards a cashless society the benefits to merchants from cards

increase in comparison to cash and checks. With the addition of all the factors above, merchants

simply prefer not to surcharge cards that yield them benefits. If surcharging is not the cure, are

there any other solutions to the competitive concerns raised by the interchange fee? I will survey

now other alternatives besides surcharging, to the competitive concerns the interchange fee

raises.

12. Alternatives To The Interchange Fee

776. The European commission claims that the interchange fee can be replaced by a rule which is

less restrictive. This stance was affirmed by the European High Court of Justice.1431 Following

are suggested alternatives that have been raised in the literature.

12.1. Bilateral Interchange Fee

777. Some scholars have suggested that there is no need for multilateral interchange fees. Each issuer

can contract bilaterally with each acquirer that acquires cards issued by the issuer. The terms of

the contract of each pair, including the interchange fee, can be set bilaterally.1432

778. One problem with bilateral interchange fees is that full coverage of the market with ex-ante

bilateral interchange fees is not feasible. In a multi-national payment system like Visa or

MasterCard, there are thousands of issuers and acquirers spread all over the world. Ex-ante

contracts between each issuer and acquirer are not practical, and even if they were, transaction

1430 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1345, at 647-48: “[A] merchant could

charge more for cash sales than for credit card sales if the latter saved significant costs”.

Dennis Carlton & S. Alan Frankel, Transaction Costs, Externalities, and "Two Sided" Payment Markets, 2005 COLUM.

BUS. L. REV. 617, 638 (2005): “Suppose Baxter is correct in contending that interchange fees are required to enable

merchants to charge a lower effective price to credit card customers. In such a case, merchants would not require a no-

surcharge rule-a rule preventing merchants from charging a higher price for credit cards because absent transaction

costs, merchants would want to charge a lower, not higher, price to credit card customers”. 1431 Supra note 1033. 1432 NICHOLAS ECONOMIDES, COMPETITION POLICY ISSUES IN THE CONSUMER PAYMENTS INDUSTRY, IN MOVING

MONEY: THE FUTURE OF CONSUMER PAYMENT 113, 122 (R. Litan & M. Baily eds., 2009): “To reduce the interchange

fee, I propose that the network no longer set the maximum interchange fee. Let it instead be determined in bilateral

negotiations between an issuer and an acquirer, starting from a zero fee basis (par)”.

David Balto, The Problem of Interchange Fees: Costs without Benefits?, E.C.L.R 215, 219 (2000): “What of the

transaction costs argument? First, in countries where there are relatively few firms in a market the savings in

transactions costs will not be substantial and the argument can not support interchange fees. Secondly, even where there

are a larger number of firms there may be greater opportunity for interchange fees to be replaced by bilateral

negotiations”.

Page 320: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

320

costs would be huge.1433

Proponents of the bilateral interchange fee have a counterargument. The aggregate market share

of the main issuers and acquirers covers most of the market. Interchange fee in the bulk of

transactions can be achieved through a relatively small number of agreements. A default

interchange fee would be required for the residual market share which is not covered by bilateral

agreements. The international organization might determine this default fee. Another option is

that small issuers and acquirers join one of the main bilateral agreements.1434

This counterargument is not convincing. Dozens of agreements are still required even when the

number of issuers and acquirers is relatively small. Number of required agreements is n*(n-1)/2

where n is the number of firms. There is no need for hundreds or thousands of firms in order to

make transaction costs prohibitively high.1435

779. In addition, bilateral agreements are doomed to fail covering all transactions. Even if most

issuers and acquirers will connect bilaterally, a transaction in which there is no prior contract

between an acquirer and the issuer will surely occur. Full coverage of all transactions in a

country with many issuers and acquirers is problematic, and certainly the worldwide market

cannot be covered through bilateral agreements.

780. Theoretically, Israel could be a very good candidate for bilateral agreements. Only three

bilateral agreements would be required to replace the Trio Agreement and cover the internal

market. International transactions such as tourist transactions would nevertheless, still require

a default interchange fee.

However, in my view, even when the number of issuers and acquirers is small, and bilateral

agreements are feasible, bilateral fees agreements do not abate the competitive concerns.

The concern that interchange fee, which would be the product of every bilateral agreement

separately, would still be set at a higher than optimal level, exists even when it is set by pairs

of issuers and acquirers. The inherent problem of the interchange fee remains all the more in

1433 Supra ¶¶ 85-86; see also Robert M. Hunt, An Introduction to the Economics of Payment Card Networks, 2 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 80, 85 (2003): "Setting the fee at the network level eliminates costs associated with bargaining

between individual card issuers and acquirers and uncertainty about the actual costs of a card transaction". 1434 Supra ¶ 614. 1435 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 1350, at 46: “However, in a country with

thousands of banks, the number of bilateral arrangements required in a four-party system could be prohibitively high”.

Page 321: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

321

bilateral agreements also: as long as the acquirer has an interest on the issuing side, the acquirer

will agree to pay - in a bilateral agreement - a high interchange fee, knowing that in its role as

issuer, it will earn from this high fee. The bilateral negotiation is artificial. The amount the

acquirer pays is borne by its customers, the merchants, but the profit it retains from the

interchange fee on the issuing side remains with the pair of issuers / acquirers.

This would be the case even if the market consisted of only two firms, as long as both of them

operated in issuance and acquiring. As more issuers and acquirers join, bilateral agreements

between each pair would still result in as high as possible a fee.

781. Contrary to early scholars, interchange fee is not a transfer fee from acquirers to issuers. It is a

source of revenue and profit from merchants to issuers. Interchange fees increase the revenue

and profits of issuers.

It is wrong to assume that if firms have a small market share on the issuing side and a large

market share on the acquiring side, these firms would demand to pay (in bilateral and

multilateral negotiations) low interchange fees. The right way to look at this is that no acquirer

“suffers” from having to pay an interchange fee, because this fee is not borne by it but by its

merchant customers. On the other hand, all firms enjoy the interchange fee, according to their

market share on the issuing side.1436 Interchange fee inflates the profit pie for all issuers. Even

small issuers enjoy a larger share of the larger pie, according to their market share on the issuing

side.1437

For example if there is one firm which has a 10% market share in issuing and another that has

a 90% market share, and they negotiate the interchange fee bilaterally, then it is incorrect to

assume that the 10% firm will try to lower the interchange fee it pays in 90% of the transactions

it acquires. It is correct, instead, to assume that both firms enjoy an increase in the interchange

fee according to their market shares in the issuing side. One firm enjoys 10% of any increase

in the revenue pie and the other enjoys 90%. They both have incentives to increase the pie.

782. Moreover, as I have showed above, competition for cardholders motivates issuers not to settle

for low interchange fee, even in bilateral agreements. Low interchange fee limits its receiver

1436 T-111/08 MasterCard v. Comm'n, para 254 (May 24, 2012): "[V]irtually all banks engaged in the acquiring

business were also card issuers and benefited, to that extent, from the MIF.”; Comp/34.579 European Comm'n

MasterCard Decision, supra note 570, para. 385. 1437 Supra ¶ 35.

Page 322: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

322

from offering attractive cards.1438 No issuer has any incentive to ask for a lower interchange fee

than its competitors. On the contrary, a higher interchange fee would enable the issuer to offer

more rewards to its cardholders. Therefore, bilateral negotiations will not yield more

competitive interchange fees than multilateral interchange fee.1439 On the contrary – it would

be a race upwards. Without cutting the connection between issuers and acquirers, as I propose

in chapter 0, even a default interchange fee of zero but permitting the interchange fee to be set

bilaterally, will yield higher than optimal interchange fees.

783. Another reason which in my view negates bilateral agreements is that the interchange fee

imposes a tax on card transactions. Taxes should be at an even rate for all. There is no reason

to let issuers with higher bargaining power to extract a higher interchange fee in bilateral

agreements. However, variety of interchange fees is exactly the result of using bilateral

agreements.

12.2. Zero Interchange Fee

784. Some scholars have suggested banning interchange fees. The idea is that clearance of

transactions would be made at par, like checks.1440 King & Maddock even propose to set the

MSF on zero.1441 The European commission also considers banning interchange fees, especially

for debit, as an option.1442

785. The discussion on banning interchange fees fascinatingly resembles trials that took place about

100 years ago in the United States, regarding the interchange fees in checks (see supra 865).

Before the 20th century, clearance of checks in the U.S. was not at par, as we are used today.

Par clearance was performed only at the counter of the issuing bank. Whenever a check was

presented for withdrawal not at the counter of the issuing bank, the acquiring bank (in which

1438 Supra ¶ 298. 1439 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1345, at 642: “it is not clear that

collectively set interchange fees resolve the problem, rather than transferring the exercise of market power from the

individual issuer to the network comprised of issuers. To that extent, bilateral negotiations may not be any less practical

than collectively set interchange fees”. 1440 See Alan S. Frankel, Monopoly and Competition in the Supply and Exchange of Money 66 ANTITRUST L.J. 313, 336

(1998): “Baxter's argument that a zero exchange charge is inefficient is inconsistent with the results of universal par

collection of checks”;

Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees, supra note 773, at 9: “This paper concludes that maintaining a zero

interchange fee and increasing the cost transparency would promote both competition and efficiency in retail payments,

as compared to a situation with high positive interchange fees.”; Balto, supra note 1432, 223 (2000). 1441 Stephen King & Rodney Maddock, Direct Charging of Card Fees (Monash University Working Paper, May 2017) 1442 COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT, SWD(2013) 288 Final, at 184 (24.7.2013): “The

option of banning IFs for debit cards is considered as it appears that a debit card without any IF would be viable from a

commercial perspective without necessarily raising the costs of current accounts”. See also id. at 185, sub-option 15.2

ans at 190 sub-option 15.4.

Page 323: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

323

the check was presented), had to pay interchange fee to assignees of the issuing bank, for taking

the check and presenting it at the counter of the issuing bank. In olden times checks were

actually transferred in carriages to the issuing banks. The interchange fee was negotiated

bilaterally. Rural banks therefore had (market) power to charge higher interchange fees.1443

The development of clearinghouses enabled checks to be cleared, at many places and not only

at the counters of the issuing banks. Clearinghouses also had multilateral interchange fees. As

the market became more elaborate interchange fee declined, until eventually the Federal Bank

intervened and forced the final stage to a zero interchange fee. Some banks opposed this, which

led to bitter check interchange fee trials. Checks today are all alike cleared at par.1444

786. The check trials inspire my second innovation, as they resemble the proceedings we experience

today, a century later, with respect to interchange fees in payment cards. The banks complained

then, as they threaten now, that eliminating interchange fees would impede their stability. This

did not happen with checks, and the banking system operates successfully at par, with no

interchange fees and with costs borne on the direct sides to the checks, the payer and the

payee.1445

787. However, absolute negation of interchange fee – in the form of zero interchange fee - is not

necessarily the right methodological solution. Indeed, under a zero interchange fee, there is no

restrictive arrangement, but theoretically this can have a negative effect on networks, especially

nascent networks. When a new issuer tries to penetrate the market, this issuer will need an

interchange fee to lower its cardholder fees and establish a critical mass of cardholders.

In mature networks a rule of zero interchange fee, is appealing, provided that cardholders have

sufficient benefits from card usage (Bc≥0), and issuers are able to cover their costs and profits

1443 For expansion see infra ch. 14.1. 1444 Id. 1445 ALBERT FOER, ELECTRONIC PAYMENT SYSTEMS AND INTERCHANGE FEES: BREAKING THE LOG JAM ON SOLUTIONS

TO MARKET POWER, Am. Antitrust Institute, at 21 (2010): “There is a long history in this country relating to so-called

check “exchange fees” that in the past made the use of checks difficult and expensive. Supra-competitive check

exchange fees, imposed on merchants by some banks with market power interfered with commerce, so Congress

authorized the Fed. Res. at the time of its formation to abolish them and provide a system for all checks to exchange at

par – the system with which we are all familiar today. Although some bankers at that time loudly complained, the

usefulness of checks as a means of payment was not destroyed as a result of the system of par collection put into

operation by the Fed. On the contrary, more than eight decades after the Fed began its efforts to ‘impose’ par collection,

checking accounts now are offered by virtually all financial institutions, whether they are net payers or net recipients in

the check settlement process . . . . Costs imposed by customers drawing checks or depositing checks, including costs

associated with membership in and use of clearinghouses, are recovered through fees charged directly to those

customers”.

Page 324: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

324

from the direct channels of cardholders' income. Zero interchange fee is a simple rule and cost

effective to implement, provided the network is not impeded. In fact, payment card networks

with zero interchange fees, manage to operate successfully.1446

788. Zero interchange fees would encourage transparency, minimize cross-subsidization between

payment instruments, and force issuers and acquirers to charge fees in a transparent manner.1447

Zero interchange fee is in line with zero termination fee, known as "bill and keep" in

telecommunications,1448 all the more if we accept the "need for consensus" approach in

termination fee and interchange fee, as Rochet & Tirole suggest.1449 Zero interchange fees

would also have a positive effect by reducing "wasteful competition" (i.e., redundant rewards)

or "cozy cartels" (using the interchange fee as a disguise for profits).1450

A caveat is that any attempt to lower the interchange fee towards zero should be done

gradually.1451 As Balto warned, the effects on reduction in the interchange fee on networks

should be examined step by step.1452

12.3. Split

789. Semeraro raised the idea that big issuers should operate as closed networks (without interchange

fees) and acquire their own cards only. In the U.S., the closed networks which would be created

according to his suggestion consist of Citibank, Chase, Bank of America, Capital One and Wells

Fargo.1453 Small issuers may be allowed to cooperate in a multilateral cross-acquiring

1446 Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 570, paras. 562-608; and at para. 751: “[S]everal

payment schemes in the European Economic Area have successfully been operating without a MIF for a long time.

These Schemes have been established between 1979 and 1992 and they are not merely viable but indeed successful.";

Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees for Card-Based Payment Transactions, EXPLANATORY MEMORANDUM,

COM(2013)550 Final 2013/0265 (Cod), at 10-11(Aug. 5, 2013): “Denmark has one of the highest card usage rates in

the EU at 216 transactions per capita with a zero-Interchange Fee debit scheme. This is also true of international

schemes: in Switzerland Maestro has no interchange fee and is the main debit card system… In terms of viability, a

debit card scheme without any IF seems to be perfectly viable from a commercial perspective without raising the costs

of current accounts for consumers”. See also supra n. 187. 1447 Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees, supra note 773, at 27: “[F]rom the competition point of view, there is

another interesting MIF level, that is, the zero-level. With MIFs set to zero, the acquiring side will set charges

independently of the issuing side and card transactions would therefore be processed at par in the payment networks.

At-par acquiring would create pressure for more transparent cardholder pricing and would reduce cross subsidization

effects”. 1448 Patrick DeGraba, Efficient Inter-Carrier Compensation for Competing Networks when Customers Share the Value

of a Call, (2002): "I concentrate on bill and keep, not because a zero inter-carrier compensation rate is likely to give rise

to theoretically optimal usage levels, but because the optimal rate may be very close to zero… Thus, as a policy matter,

society may be better off accepting the small usage distortions of bill and keep". 1449 Supra ¶455 1450 Supra ¶ 479. 1451 AT 4630/01 Leumi v. General Director, para. 46 (Aug. 31, 2006) ("The Methodology Decision"). 1452 Supra ¶ 469. 1453 Steven Semeraro, The Antitrust Economics (and Law) of Surcharging Credit Card Transactions, 14 STAN. J. L.

BUS. & FIN. 343, 380 n. 159 (2009).

Page 325: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

325

agreement and charge interchange fees. The idea is to increase the number of payment platforms

and to create platform competition, so merchants could choose to accept cards of cheap

networks, and reject cards of expensive networks.

Technology today is advanced enough to enable merchants to multihome easily. One POS is

capable to process cards of several networks. In the past, multihoming forced merchants to have

different acquiring equipment for each network. Today one terminal can connect with several

platforms at low cost and on a common single infrastructure. This makes the proposal

technologically feasible.

However, split requires separate contractual relationship between each acquirer and all

merchants. Although technologically possible, split is only a partial alternative to a multilateral

interchange fee. Similar to the problem of bilateral arrangements, despite large transaction

costs, full market coverage would not be achieved. For example, split is not an alternative for

international transactions. It cannot be expected from each issuer worldwide to connect with

each merchant. International transactions would still have to be performed under default

interchange fees set by the networks, so even under a split, the networks will include

interchange fees.

790. Semeraro argues that splitting open networks into closed networks would enlarge the number

of competing players, with no need for new entrants. Big issuers would enjoy economies of

scale which would enable them to offer merchants a low MSF. Inefficient issuers would be

unable to compete, consistent with competition law.1454 Competition would push the entire

market towards competitive fees.1455

However, platform competition in payment card networks, especially when cardholders tend to

single home, creates distorted equilibrium. Cardholder fees are reduced to negative (rewards).

Merchant fund all costs.1456 Nothing prevents this grim result here. In addition, under a split

regime, each issuer is a monopoly regarding the acquiring of its cards. When there are only a

few players, split actually means an oligopoly regime. Large issuers would be able to use their

market power to charge higher MSF, and not lower.1457 Empirical results, at least in Israel,

1454 See, e.g., Freeman v. San Diego Ass’n of Realtors, 322 F.3d 1133, 1154 (9th Cir. 2003). 1455 Semeraro, The Antitrust Economics (and Law) of Surcharging Credit Card Transactions, supra note 1453, at 379-

82; Semeraro, Credit Cards Interchange Fees: Three Decades of Antitrust Uncertainty, supra note 64, at 997-1000. 1456 Supra ch. 6.6.2. 1457 Supra ch. 6.6.3.

Page 326: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

326

confirm that under split, MSFs were actually higher. Until AlphaCard emerged, the market was

split between Isracard and CAL. Only when AlphaCard entered the market and the Visa card

firms started to operate as an open network, the MSF sharply decreased.1458

Semeraro is actually proposing competition between closed networks. But in closed networks

the fees are higher. Isracard was declared a monopoly when it was the only acquirer of its

proprietary cards, because of the high MSF it charged, even though it was in competition with

the Visa companies. Diners and American Express each charge a high MSF.

12.4. Multi-Cards

791. Frankel proposed an interesting idea of combining Semeraro's split with multihoming

cardholders (and merchants), thus placing the merchant (instead of the customer) in the driver's

seat.1459 The idea is letting the merchant, and not the cardholder, to choose the network through

which the transaction would be processed. Competition becomes for merchants, with lower

MSF. The proposal is to require networks to issue “multi-cards”.

The idea is that a cardholder would not have to carry separate cards. Her/his cards are going to

be unified to one "multi-card". The merchant would choose the routing option, including the

interchange fee, unless the cardholder demands otherwise, but then the merchant can surcharge.

Multi-cards bear the logos of several networks, e.g., MasterCard and Visa, and must be

interoperable with several networks simultaneously. Multi-cards enable competition between

several networks on the same card. The side that was previously exploited, i.e., the merchant,

is given the bargaining power. Merchants could then choose the cheapest network and route the

transaction through it, by using the interoperability feature of multi-bugging cards.1460

1458 C.A 2616/03 Isracard v Howard Rice, 59(5), 701 (2006); AT 4630/01 Leumi v. General Director, at 31 (Aug. 31,

2006) ("The Methodology Decision"). 1459 Compare supra ¶ 284. 1460 Fumiko Hayashi, The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: Policy Considerations of Payment Card

Rewards, at 9 (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No. 08-08. 2008): “[M]andating a single card to carry multiple card

networks may allow merchants to influence their customers’ payment choice toward less expensive payment methods

for the merchants.”;

Éva Keszy-Harmath et al., The Role of the Interchange Fee in Card Payment Systems, at 21 (MNB Occasional papers

96, 2012): “[I]f payment cards would be so-called multi-branded cards. In this case, merchants and their acquirer banks

would freely choose the network (brand) they wish to use for the settlement of a given transaction, and the payable

interchange fee would be set by the network (card company) conducting the given settlement.”; Frankel, Towards,

supra note 811, at 35: “[I]t is possible that a merchant could still accept many or all card transactions, irrespective of

brand, using one network – if cards were interoperable across networks and issuers accepted transactions presented to

them which originated over any network”.

Page 327: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

327

792. Prager notes that multi-cards exist in the U.S PIN debit market.1461 Prager explains that multi-

cards developed due to geographical limitations of PIN debit networks. When geographical

coverage of individual PIN debit networks was limited, multi-cards, i.e., ascription of the card

to several networks, enabled the card to be accepted by more merchants. When networks

expanded their geographical coverage, multi-cards enabled merchants to choose the cheapest

routing option between the card's brands. This increased competition between networks.

As explained in chapter 8.3.10, a major reform in the Durbin Amendment was the "routing

reform". Issuers must offer merchants (via acquirers) at least two routing options on unaffiliated

networks’ infrastructure (for expansion see supra 644). The routing reform eliminated

exclusive routing arrangements between issuers and networks that were infrastructure owners

(supra 644645). In Israel, the Shtrum committee also considered erection of another routing

option.1462 However, until today (March 2018) this initiative was not developed.

Contrary to the debit market, in the U.S. credit card market the situation is opposite. Credit

cards networks prohibit issuers from assimilating into one card multi brands.1463

793. This idea of multi-cards was adopted in Europe in the Green Paper from 2012.1464 Article 8 of

the European Interchange fee Directive from September 2015, not only permits but also

encourages multi cards. The Article prohibits networks' rules that prevent co-badging.1465

1461 Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 1350, at 27: “[T]he differential between

PIN and signature debit interchange fees may reflect more intense competition among PIN debit networks due to the

presence of multiple brands on a given card. In the early days of PIN debit, each network covered a fairly small

geographic area, and many banks sought to offer their customers wider merchant acceptance of their PIN debit cards by

“multi-bugging” the cards (i.e., issuing cards that bore the logos of and could be used on multiple PIN networks). Over

time, individual networks expanded their geographic coverage through a combination of mergers and organic growth,

and in some cases, networks’ geographic regions began to overlap one another. In this environment, merchant acquirers

or their processors could often choose which one of the networks whose brands appeared on a card would carry the

transaction. Merchants generally prefer that their acquirers route PIN debit transactions over the network with the

lowest interchange fee, resulting in direct price competition among PIN debit networks. 1462 Supra note 709, at 64 note 64. 1463 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1345, at 644: “Under network rules,

banks may not issue credit cards carrying both the MasterCard and Visa (or other) branded networks”. 1464 European Commission, Green Paper, Towards an Integrated European Market for Card, Internet and Mobile

Payments, at 9 para. 4.1.3, COM (2011) 941 final (Jan. 11, 2012): “Co-badging combines different payment brands on

the same card or device. Nowadays, the most promising way for new entrant schemes to access the market could be to

convince issuing PSPs to co-badge their payment cards that carry an existing (international) scheme’s brand with the

new entrant’s brand. This would allow consumers to choose between brands when paying (provided the merchant

accepts both brands), taking into consideration possible bonuses from their issuing PSP (air miles, etc.) and the possible

incentives from the merchant (surcharging, rebating, steering).”; See also EU, Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange

Fees, supra note 1042, Article 8. 1465 Regulation (EU) 2015/751 of 29 April 2015 on Interchange Fees for Card-Based Payment Transactions, O.J L

123/1, Article 8.1 (19.5.15): “Any payment card scheme rules and rules in licensing agreements or measures of

equivalent effect that hinder or prevent an issuer from co-badging two or more different payment brands or payment

applications on a card-based payment instrument shall be prohibited”.

Page 328: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

328

Customers may require co-badging of two or more different payment brands on one card,

provided that such a service is offered by the issuer.1466 Sections 3-5 of the Article 8 prohibit

issuers or networks or infrastructures from discriminating between the different payment

instruments that a multi-card combines. The most interesting section of Article 8 is the last,

section 6. It actually transfers the power to choose the payment instrument from the customer

to the merchant, unless the customer objects:

6. Payment card schemes, issuers, acquirers, processing entities and other technical

service providers shall not insert automatic mechanisms, software or devices on

the payment instrument or at equipment applied at the point of sale which limit the

choice of payment brand or payment application, or both, by the payer or the

payee when using a co-badged payment instrument. Payees shall retain the option of installing automatic mechanisms in the equipment

used at the point of sale which make a priority selection of a particular payment

brand or payment application but payees shall not prevent the payer from

overriding such an automatic priority selection made by the payee in its equipment

for the categories of cards or related payment instruments accepted by the

payee.1467

794. It is interesting to see, if in coming years, multi cards will become wide-spread, if merchants

will install technologies that automatically choose the cheapest payment instrument which the

card incorporates, if issuers will fight back by offering rewards to expensive cards, or if they

will cooperate by offering low interchange fees. If the analogy to checks holds, the increasing

options of merchants might push interchange fees downwards.1468

795. In my view, multi-card is a competitive idea, but which is facing high obstacles. Cardholders

do not have incentives to search for a “second” issuer, let alone a cheap issuer, that would be a

co-issuer of another issuer’s card. This is the interest of merchants, not cardholders. Issuers also

would not encourage multi-cards. Thus, no competitive force promotes their dispersion. In

addition, issuers do not tend to issue cards that do not carry sufficient interchange fees for them,

1466 id. Article 8.2: “[C]onsumer may require two or more different payment brands on a card-based payment instrument

provided that such a service is offered by the payment service provider”. 1467 Id. 1468 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1345, at 643: “The key factor that led

to the competitive elimination of interchange fees in currency and check markets was the ability of merchants and their

banks to choose the method used to transport financial claims back to the issuing bank for redemption. The ability of

acquirers to use competing transportation systems (and correspondent banks) led issuers to abandon their interchange

fees altogether and join par collection clearinghouses. If merchants, who typically must pay interchange fees today, had

the ability to choose the payment network over which to process the transaction (and issuers for legal or competitive

reasons continued to participate in multiple networks), the competitive result might be a par collection system, or at the

very least a system with significantly lower interchange fees. Just as an issuer tends to have an incentive to choose a

network with a higher interchange fee in the current system, a merchant would have an incentive to choose a lower

interchange fee if it had a choice. It is the lack of real competition and choice for those paying the fees that leads

networks to charge merchants (and therefore their customers) relatively high interchange fees in the current system”.

Page 329: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

329

and I do not think that the option to issue on a multi-card would change this. I hope to be wrong

and see that multi-cards thrive.

Part IV – New Proposals

13. Novelty #1 – Structural Separation

796. Thus far I have tried to shed light on every aspect of the interchange fee: origin, history,

theoretical models, competitive justifications, concerns and alternatives. Now it is the time to

introduce two novelties that in my view, if adopted, will reduce substantially the enormous

regulatory resources invested in the supervision of the interchange fee.

My first proposal is to require dissolution, in mature networks, between issuers and acquirers.

Financial institutions will have to choose whether to operate on the issuing side or on the

acquiring side (but not on both).

797. Historically, networks evolved in a way that acquirers were always issuers.1469 This structure

was formally anchored in the bylaws of Visa and MasterCard, in the “No Acquiring Without

Issuing” (“NAWI”) rule. The networks claimed the rule was intended to promote the

development of the networks and make it more attractive to merchants, by encouraging card

issuing side.1470 The NAWI rule prevented networks’ members from operating only in acquiring

activity.1471 The NAWI rule stipulated that before becoming acquirers, banks had to issue a

minimum number of cards.1472

1469 Comp/34.579 European Comm'n MasterCard Decision, supra note 570, para. 461: “Acquiring banks are typically

also Issuers for historic reasons518”; and at note 518: “MasterCard used to oblige acquirers to issue cards, as well, until

the abolution of the so-called “No acquiring without issuing rule” in 2005. This is why today most acquirers also issue

cards”. 1470 Pierre Bos, International Scrutiny of Payment Card Systems, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 739, 746 (2006): "Visa claimed the

rule was intended to promote the development of the card system by encouraging card issuing, which it claimed would

make the system more attractive for merchants."; see also infra note 1494. 1471 COMP/29.373 − Visa International 2001/782/EC, para 18, O. J. L 293 (2001): "Although according to the Visa

rules, principal members are formally obliged to issue cards and to acquire merchants, in practice Visa does not oblige

its members to acquire. However, if they want to acquire merchants for card acceptance, before starting acquiring

activities in a particular country the member has to issue a reasonable number of cards";

Ann Borestam & Heiko Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, ECB Occasional Paper Series 131, at 25

(2011): “The “no acquiring without issuing” rule, if applicable, prevents members of schemes from pursuing only

acquiring activity, as members are also required to be active in card issuance”. 1472 Fumiko Hayashi & Stuart E. Weiner, Interchange Fees in Australia the U.K and the United States: Matching

Theory and Practice, FRB KANSAS ECON. REV. 75, 77 (2006): “Net issuer rules require merchant acquiring banks to

issue a minimum level of cards in order to participate on the acquiring side of the market”.

Page 330: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

330

798. Since the beginning of the 2000s the NAWI rule was canceled in most jurisdictions.

Nevertheless, although this rule is de-jure not valid anymore, de-facto it still prevails. My

proposal is to make the cancelation of the NAWI rule mandatory and binding, and not only a

mere possibility which de-facto does not exist. The reasons for the continuance of the NAWI

rule (although in a more delicate way), despite its explicit cancelation, is a good introduction to

my proposal.

13.1. The De Facto Prevalence Of The NAWI Rule

Israel

799. In Israel, in November 2007 the Antitrust Tribunal held that independent acquirers (i.e.,

acquirers that are not related to the issuing side) could join the networks.1473 This would seem

to overcome any NAWI rule, but jumping to this conclusion is erroneous, since independent

acquirers do not exist in Israel. There are three main reasons for that, as explained herein:

799.1 First, according to the Israeli Banking Law, acquirers need a banking license from

the Banking Commissioner.1474 Activities of acquirers involve the administration of

merchants’ accounts and the provision of credit to merchants. Pursuant to banking

laws, this suffices for requiring acquirers to obtain a license from the Bank of Israel.

On December 31, 2013 Bank of Israel published a draft process for receiving an

acquiring license.1475 The draft was amended several times.1476 In May 2016, Bank

of Israel promulgated Instruction 472 regarding acquiring payment cards.1477 The

process to receive acquiring license is purportedly designed for non-bank acquirers

as well. Initial high equity demand and capital adequacy that only banks possess,

were modified to accommodate non-bank entrants.1478 However, the requirements of

the central bank still include, inter alia, high financial strength, reporting duties, high

security and information technology standards, limitations on fields of operation,

limitations on control block and on holdings above 5% of shares. In addition, a new

1473 AT 610/06 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 5000840, sec. 3 (Nov. 11, 2007); See also supra ¶ 669. 1474 Section 36(10) and (11) of the Banking Law (licensing) 1981 1475 Bank of Israel, Process of Receiving Acquirer's License, (Dec. 31, 2013). 1476 See, e.g., Bank of Israel, Draft for Comments, Process for Granting Acquiring License, (Dec. 17, 2015). 1477 Bank of Israel, Communication 2498-06-ח, Acquiring Payment Cards (Banking Proper Procedure, Instruction 472),

(May 1, 2016). 1478 Bank of Israel, Draft Process for Acquiring License, supra note 1476, sec.3.2.

Page 331: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

331

acquirer must collect transactions through EMV terminals, which can accept

contactless transactions, even though most merchants in Israel do not use such

terminals.

The result is that no non-bank acquirer received an acquiring license. Firms that

operate on the acquiring side, and provide part or all of the acquiring services, must

ultimately 'hide' behind a bank that has an acquiring license and acts as the official

acquirer.1479

799.2 The primary preference of banks is to operate on the issuing side, which is much

more profitable, mainly because of the interchange fee.1480 The issuing side would

remain more profitable, whether payment card companies are bank-controlled or

separated from banks (due to the expected divestiture of Leumi-Card and Isracard

from their controlling banks1481), mainly because the windfall of interchange fees to

the issuing side automatically tilts the profit of the issuing side to be higher than the

profit of the acquiring side, regardless of issuers' or acquirers' ownership. For

example, in Israel, the interchange fee in 2016 yielded income of almost NIS 2

Billion to the issuing side, out of NIS 2.9 billion in total, as opposed to only NIS 0.95

billion of fee income to the acquiring side.1482 In addition, interest income from

cardholders is a bigger source of income than interest from merchants (NIS 480

million compared to NIS 70 million in 2016).1483 Other factors that cause the

1479 Ann Kjos, The Merchant-Acquiring Side of the Payment Card Industry: Structure, Operations, and Challenges, at 8

(F.R.B Phil' Discussion Paper 2007): “[D]espite the sometimes complex chain of service providers, they are always

linked by contracts to the network member bank”. 1480 EC, INTERIM REPORT, supra note 278, at iv: "For both debit and credit cards, issuing is significantly more profitable

than acquiring. Although this general finding was to be anticipated, the difference in relative profitability is striking.";

Barbara Pacheco & Richard Sullivan, Interchange Fees in Credit and Debit Card Markets: What Role for Public

Authorities?, 1 FED. RES. BANK KANSAS ECON. REV. 87 (2006): "[I]n the United States, most agree that networks place

greater emphasis on issuer profits than acquirer profits and that acquirers pass along more of any changes in fees to their

customers compared to issuers."; aee also id. at 76: “The issuing of credit cards is very profitable”; Semeraro, Credit

Cards Interchange Fees: Three Decades of Antitrust Uncertainty, supra note 64, at 973; DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD

SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND BORROWING 16, 215, 237 (2d ed.

2005); See also supra ¶ 96 (issuing is more profitable than the acquiring side), ¶ 89 (interchange fees are determined

according to the interests of issuers, even though they are also acquirers, or directly by the networks (Visa and

MasterCard) which favor the interests of issuers); and infra note1506 (acquirer banks get fewer votes in the Visa and

MasterCard associations than issuing banks, and there is far less balance or representation of the interests of merchants

in the setting of the interchange fee)”. 1481 Section 11b(b) to the Bankin Law (licensing) amendment 23 (2017). See also infra ¶ 847. 1482 Bank of Israel, Information on the banking system, chapter J payment cards, Tables x-3.1, x-3.2, x-13, available at http://www.boi.org.il/he/BankingSupervision/Data/Pages/DataTable.aspx?Chapter=%D7%A4%D7%A8%D7%A7+%D7%99%27+-

+%D7%9B%D7%A8%D7%98%D7%99%D7%A1%D7%99+%D7%90%D7%A9%D7%A8%D7%90%D7%99&Years=2012-2016 (last entry July 24, 2017). 1483 Id.

Page 332: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

332

acquiring side to be more competitive is homogeneity and sophisticated customers,

compared to the issuing market.1484 Bottom line is that the issuing side is much more

attractive and profitable than the acquiring side.1485

799.3 Second, until 2017, section 23 of the Banking Law (licensing) (1981), determined

that an infrastructure firm, such as SHVA, could grant its services only to banks. This

requirement constituted a major entry barrier for non-bank independent acquirers,

which could not get access to the payment card infrastructure. Both the Antitrust

Authority and Bank of Israel noted that section 23 was an obstacle to entry of

independent acquirers.1486 Europe1487 and the U.S.1488 faced similar entry barriers.

Acquiring licenses and permissions to access the payment infrastructures were

traditionally granted only to financial institutions.

Apparently, Section 23 of the Banking Law was not at the focus of the Antitrust

Authority until 2014. In 2012 the Antitrust Authority approved the existence and

operation of SHVA, by noting that according to the above mentioned Tribunal

decision (dated November 2007), independent acquirers could supposedly enter the

market, but the Antitrust Authority did not mention section 23 of the Banking Law

1484 Supra ¶ 97. 1485 See also supra ¶ 98. 1486 IAA, ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY & COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD SECTOR (FINAL REPORT), supra note

1387, at 11; BANK OF ISRAEL, RECOMMENDATIONS FOR ENHANCEMENT OF COMPETITION IN THE PAYMENT CARD

SECTOR, FINAL REPORT, at 41 (Feb. 2015). 1487 REPORT ON THE RETAIL BANKING SECTOR INQUIRY [COM(2007) 33 Final], supra note 193, para. 18: “Access and

governance arrangements - 18. In international networks (Visa and MasterCard), as well as in national card payment

systems in Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal and Spain,

membership rules reserve the right of issuing and acquiring to credit and/or financial institutions, or to an entity

under direct control of such institutions. While it could be argued that this pre-condition is justified for supervisory

or financial stability reasons, it limits participation of merchants and processors in issuing and acquiring, hence

undermining the intra-network competition in these countries. Similar concerns appear with respect to access to

infrastructures . In Ireland, the Netherlands and Portugal the national system rules require the local presence of a foreign

entrant, by means of establishment of a local branch and/or a subsidiary. This requirement increases the costs of foreign

entry, which may limit the intra-network competition”; see also id. para. 26: “The ‘need to be a bank’ requirement:

Most clearing systems admit only banks. This scrutiny may help guaranteeing financial stability but could hinder the

entry of non-bank players in payment systems, in particular if there were other efficient ways to ensure the financial

reliability.”;

EC, INTERIM REPORT, supra note 278, at V: “Some payment system membership requirements may hinder non-banks

from domestic acquiring and new entrants from cross-border acquiring. Rules which may constitute barriers include

requirements to be a financial institution and to have a local establishment. About half of the domestic card

payment systems in the EU require issuers and acquirers to be financial institutions. Some systems also require banks to

establish a physical presence”. 1488 Andrew Kahr, Why Allow Only Banks to Issue Credit Cards? AM. BANKER, Aug. 22, 2012

http://www.americanbanker.com/bankthink/why-allow-only-banks-to-issue-credit-cards-1052029-1.html : “For years,

federal deposit insurance has been a prerequisite for issuing credit cards... Visa and MasterCard have permitted

credit card issuance on their networks only by institutions with federal deposit insurance from the FDIC or

NCUA”.

Page 333: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

333

that thwarted this.1489 Eventually the outdated Section 23 was amended, as the

Antitrust Authority and Bank of Israel have recommended,1490 in the Banking Law

(licensing) amendment #23 (2017), that added section 23(b). This amendment curbed

the exclusivity of infrastructure firm that operates a payment system. According to

the amendment such firm can grant its services to every person.

799.4 Third, MasterCard and Visa grant acquiring licenses only to licensed financial

entities.1491 As already explained, the license demand poses a regulatory entry barrier

for non-banks, and thus for independent acquirers. Until today (October 2016) only

banks are licensees. The primary interest of licensee banks is to operate on the more

profitable issuing side. Even if interchange fees would reduce, it is reasonable to

assume that the issuing side would remain more attractive as it is considered less

competitive.1492

800. The three obstacles mentioned above reduced the possibility of independent acquirers to

operate. However, after the amendment of section 23 to the Banking Law (Licensing(, it is

feasible that a non-bank acquirer would manage to obtain an acquiring license. Under the

current situation, in which all acquirers are also issuers, a new entry would not be enough, as

this would be the exception and not the rule. All other acquirers would still be issuers. The

determination of the interchange fee would remain in the hands of acquirers which are also

issuers. Therefore, as explained below, my proposal is not only to obligate acquirers to be

independent, but also to give independent acquirers, and only them, the bargaining power to

determine the interchange fee they pay.1493

Europe

801. In Europe, the NAWI rule was initially cleared in 2001 by the European Commission.1494 In the

following years the commission reexamined its position. Before the commission promulgated

1489 Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re: SHVA, text near n. 11, Antitrust 5001953 (May 22, 2012). 1490 Supra note 1486. 1491 European Financial Services Advisory Group (EFSAG), Acquiring License, 2016, available at

http://www.mybankinglicense.com/bank-formation-services/acquiring-license/: " In order to obtain an acquiring

license, you will first need to go through the bank license application process";

EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND BORROWING, supra note

1480, at 9: “MasterCard and Visa only allow financial institutions that belong to its network to enter into contracts with

merchants”. 1492 Supra ¶ 98 (issuing is less competitive and more profitable), ¶ 799.2 and note 1480 (issuing is significantly more

profitable than acquiring; interchange fees are determined according to the interests of issuers). 1493 See infra ¶ 832. 1494 COMP/29.373 − Visa International 2001/782/EC, para. 65, O. J. L 293 (2001): "However, the obligation to issue

cards may be said to promote the development of the Visa card system by ensuring a large card base, and thereby

Page 334: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

334

a new decision, the networks took preventive steps, and in 2005 the NAWI rule was canceled

by both Visa and MasterCard.1495 Thus, in Europe, acquirers, in theory, do not have to be

issuers. No rule obligates issuers to be acquirers or acquirers to be issuers, neither in the Visa

nor MasterCard networks.

802. The Payment Services Directive proposal (PSD2) from 2013 intended, inter alia, to lower entry

barriers for independent acquirers.1496 The PSD2 proposal recommended a relatively simple

application process, easing equity and capital demands and requiring interoperability of

incumbent payment systems.1497Article 6 of the Interchange Fee Regulation from 2015

(2015/751), prohibits, inter alia, national restrictions on independent acquirers.1498 In domestic

payment card networks, acquirers do not have to be issuers.1499

However, in practice most banks are both issuers and acquirers.1500 Moreover, banks limit

concentration of operations on one side. For example, in the case of Groupement des cartes

making the system more attractive for merchants. The no acquiring without issuing rule does not in itself create

significant barriers to entry on the acquiring market" 1495 Lukas Repa, MasterCard and VISA Modify Network Rules and Increase Transparency of Cross-Border Interchange

Fees, 2 ANTITRUST COMPETITION POL'Y NEWSL. 57, 58 (2005): “Both MasterCard and VISA also repealed the so called

‘No Acquiring Without Issuing’ (‘NAWI’) Rule, which obliged their acquiring banks to issue a substantial number of

payment cards before starting to acquire merchants for card acceptance. Merchant acquirers are therefore no longer

obliged to issue cards in the Visa or MasterCard systems”.

Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 1471, at 25: “Visa Europe used to have this

rule, which had been cleared by the EU Commission as not being harmful to competition. However, it was abolished in

January 2005. MasterCard, too, used to have this rule for credit cards, but it was likewise abolished in January 2005”. 1496 Supra ¶ 583, 1497 Proposal for a Directive on Payment Services (PSD2), at para. 23 (Com (2013) 547 Final 2013/0264, July 24,

2013): "The requirements for the payment institutions should reflect the fact that payment institutions engage in more

specialised and limited activities, thus generating risks that are narrower and easier to monitor and control than

those that arise across the broader spectrum of activities of credit institutions"; Article 6 to the proposal: "Initial

Capital… (a)where the payment institution provides only [Money remittance] …, its capital shall at no time be less than

EUR 20000; (b) where the payment institution provides [access to payment accounts provided by a payment service

provider who is not the account servicing payment service provider] its capital shall at no time be less than EUR 50000;

(c) where the payment institution provides any of the [residual payment services – O.B], its capital shall at no time be

less than EUR 125000; See also Article 29 (Access to Payment Systems): "Member States shall ensure that the rules on

access of authorised or registered payment service providers that are legal persons to payment systems shall be

objective, non-discriminatory and proportionate and that those rules do not inhibit access more than is necessary to

safeguard against specific risks such as settlement risk, operational risk and business risk and to protect the financial

and operational stability of the payment system. Annex III Legislative Financial Statement… Specific objective(s):

"Develop an EU-wide market for electronic payments, which will… Address standardisation and interoperability

gaps for card, internet and mobile payments. Eliminate hurdles for competition, in particular for card and internet

payments… Ensure a consistent application of the legislative framework (PSD) and align the practical operation of the

licensing and supervisory rules for payment services across Member States". 1498 EU Regulation 2015/751 on Interchange Fees for Card-Based Payment Transactions, O.J L 123/1, Article 6 (May

19, 2015): "Any territorial restrictions… for issuing payment cards or acquiring card-based payment transactions shall be

prohibited". 1499 Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 1471, at 26: "No national scheme has a “no

acquiring without issuing” rule"; Stewart E. Weiner & Julian Wright, Interchange Fees in various Countries:

Developments and Determinants, 4 REV. NETWORK ECON. 290, 298 (2005). 1500 Borestam & Schmiedel, id. at 26: "In practice, however, despite there being no compulsion, most banks are issuers

and acquirers at the same time".

Page 335: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

335

bancaires ("CB"), the European High Court of Justice ("HCJ") upheld an appeal of CB against

the annulment of a "mechanism for regulating the acquiring function" (‘MERFA’) which,

according to CB, was aimed to encourage members that are issuers more than acquirers to

expand their acquiring activities. MERFA levied fees on members whose ratio of acquiring

activities to issuing activities was less than 0.5.1501 The General Court annulled this mechanism

as a restriction by object, but the HCJ upheld the appeal and referred the case back to the

General Court on the ground that indirect network effects between issuance and acquiring in

two-sided markets do not support "per-se" analysis.1502 The result is that in Europe as well,

there are no independent acquirers, let alone independent acquirers who determine the

interchange fee they pay.

United States

803. In the U.S., in theory, acquirers that are not issuers can allegedly exist. Networks Bylaws

demand that the participants in the networks of Visa and MasterCard be financial

institutions,1503 but there is no pre-demand such as the NAWI rule, to issue cards. However, in

practice, acquirers are part of financial conglomerates that include banks. Acquirers are either

1501 C‑67/13 P Groupement Des Cartes Bancaires (CB) v European Commission, para 4 (Sep 11, 2014). 1502 Ibid paras. 73-74: "[I]n a card payment system that is by nature two-sided… issuing and acquisition activities are

‘essential’ to one another and to the operation of that system… Having therefore found… ‘interactions’ between the

issuing and acquisition activities of a payment system and that those activities produced ‘indirect network effects’, since

the extent of merchants’ acceptance of cards and the number of cards in circulation each affects the other, the General

Court could not, without erring in law, conclude that the measures at issue had as their object the restriction of

competition within the meaning of Article 81(1) EC". 1503 Visa inc. bylaws, Article 2, available at

https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1403161/000119312507140569/dex1016.htm: "Eligibility. Application for

membership in the Corporation may be made by any organization which is… (a) a financial institution eligible for

federal deposit or share insurance" (or related entities);

MasterCard bylaws, http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1141391/000119312505223344/dex32b.htm, Article 1

entitled Membership: "The following are eligible to become Class A Members or Affiliate Members of this

Corporation: (a)… any corporation or other organization that is a financial institution";

Kay, Manuszak & Vojtech, Bank Profitability and Debit Card Interchange Regulation: Bank Responses to the Durbin

Amendment, at 10 n. 14 (2014): “Technically, network rules require participants in card networks to be depository

institutions. Firms such as First Data enter into sponsorship agreements with banks in which those banks outsource

many or all of the acquiring functions to the sponsored processor.”;

Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 1350, at 33 n. 72: “First Data is not technically

a merchant acquirer. The payment card networks require that a merchant acquirer be a member of the respective

network. To qualify for membership, a firm must be an insured depository institution. First Data is granted access to the

respective networks by sponsoring banks”.

Ramon P. Degennaro, Merchant Acquirers and Payment Card Processors: A Look Inside the Black Box, FRB ATLANTA

ECON. REV. at 31 (2006): “Only a bank may join Visa or MasterCard; as a result, many merchant acquirers and

processors form an alliance or partnership with a sponsoring bank”.

Page 336: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

336

banks or bank affiliates.1504 The result is that acquirers in the U.S. are strongly influenced by

the interests of the issuing side.

804. The interchange fee in the U.S. is determined at the network level,1505 in which issuers have the

decisive role.1506 The outcome is that interchange fee in U.S., is determined by entities that have

an interest in raising it as high as possible.1507 No independent acquirers, let alone independent

acquirers that determine the interchange fee they pay, exist in the U.S.

Other Countries

805. Australia was a pioneering country in analyzing the NAWI rule, which was abolished in the

reform of 2002. The networks claimed that the NAWI rule is necessary to foster the "balanced

development" of the credit cards schemes, and to prevent free-riding of acquirers on the

network.1508 The RBA noted that this justification could have some merits when networks were

at their infancy, but not in mature networks.1509

1504 Supra ¶ 70 (Acquirers are financial institutions that are also issuers or connected by ownership bonds to issuers);

Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks, supra note 1350, at 85 table 4. 1505 Rule 9.1.1.3 of Visa Product and Service Rules, available at https://usa.visa.com/dam/VCOM/download/about-

visa/15-April-2015-Visa-Rules-Public.pdf :

"Interchange Reimbursement Fees are determined by Visa and provided on Visa’s published

fee schedule"; Rule 8.3 to MasterCard rules, available at https://www.mastercard.com/us/merchant/pdf/BM-

Entire_Manual_public.pdf : "The Corporation has the right to establish default interchange fees and default service

fees" 1506 Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1345, at 652 : “Merchants have little

say in the setting of interchange fees, and acquirer banks get systematically fewer votes in the Visa and MasterCard

associations than issuing banks”;

Balto, supra note 1432, at 215: “[T]here is now generally far less balance or representation of the interests of merchants

in the setting of the interchange fee”;

Richard Schmalensee, Payment Systems and Interchange Fees, 50 J. INDUS. ECON. 103, 105 (2002): “In the U.S., banks’

voting power in the Visa and MasterCard associations is more sensitive to issuing volume than to acquiring

volume.”;

Price & Wang, Why do Debit Card Networks Charge Percentage Fees?, supra note 32: “Interchange fees are set by

card networks on behalf of their issuers.”;

KENNETH A. POSNER, CLASH OF TITANS: RETAILERS, CARD ISSUERS AND INTERCHANGE (Industry Report: Morgan

Stanley,2006): "One side of the market (i.e., card issuers) owns the payment network and controls the board of

directors";

Hayashi & Weiner, Interchange Fees in Australia the U.K and the United States, supra note 1472, at 95: “[n]etwork

objectives are likely to be weighted more heavily toward issuers than acquirers in the United States. One reason is

that even the largest nonbank acquirers do not have voting power in association networks... A second reason is that

large bank acquirers are typically large issuers as well”. 1507 Balto, supra note 1432, at 221: “Since most banks now participate primarily in card issuing, they have far greater

incentives to increase the fee as much as possible and extract the highest revenue from merchants and consumers”. 1508 RBA, REFORM OF CREDIT CARD SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA: CONSULTATION DOCUMENT, at 104 (Dec. 2001): "The

justification… is that that such restrictions are necessary to foster the "balanced development" of the credit cards

schemes... "net issuer" rules are needed because specialist acquirers will attempt to "free ride" on the efforts of issuers; a

scheme's business interests will be better promoted if all members are "typically substantial issuers and acquirers"

(emphasis in the original). 1509 id. at 105 and 106.

Page 337: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

337

806. Another pretext of the networks was that without the NAWI rule, independent acquirers would

have little interest to promote the credit card network. The RBA rejected this argument. It noted

that acquirers have interests to acquire cards of all networks.1510 The RBA also rejected the

argument that the NAWI rule was necessary to prevent a situation in which interchange fees

may be "too low". The RBA stated that:

[T]he justifications for ‘net issuer’ rules in credit card schemes do not outweigh

their anti-competitive impact on the acquiring market... Whatever contribution ‘net

issuer’ rules might have made to their early development, the designated credit

card schemes are well-established in Australia and the rules now mainly serve to

increase acquiring costs for new scheme members and entrench the market

power of incumbents. From the public interest viewpoint, the consequence is that

merchant service fees are higher than they might otherwise be, the market is not

contestable by specialist acquirers that might have new skills and efficiencies to

offer and incentives for innovation and cost reduction are likely to be dampened...

The Reserve Bank has therefore concluded that ‘net issuer’ rules are not in

the public interest and should be abolished1511.

807. Acquiring might be desirable by technological firms, already engaged in back office acquiring

and with sufficient financial resources, or by factoring firms, or by other firms that want to enter

the acquiring side only. "Issuing only" might be desired by small banks or by financial entities

that are already connected to pecuniary accounts of their clients, but do not possess the required

technology for acquiring. For such a firm, the NAWI rule is an upright entry barrier, as it forces

entrance to the two sides of the market instead of one side. Thus, repealing the NAWI rule

should have encouraged entrance of such firms. However, as of 2016, no independent acquirers

entered the Australian payment market. The Australian Payments Clearing Association includes

about 100 members, all banks or financial entities related to banks.1512

808. New-Zealand is another good example of a regime that formally has no NAWI rule, but in

which the NAWI rule prevails in practice. In 2009, the Commerce Commission reached

settlement agreements with MasterCard and Visa. The agreements stipulated that independent

acquirers could technically join the networks based on financial strength, security and

prudential criteria. Section 4.1.3 of the settlement agreements specifically determines that:

"New Zealand acquirers need not also be issuers, and vice versa".1513

1510 Ibid: "acquirers have a clear interst in promoting any scheme for which they acquire, since without transactions they

earn no revenue". 1511 RBA, REFORM OF CREDIT CARD SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA: CONSULTATION DOCUMENT, at 107 (Dec. 2001). 1512 APCA (AUSTRALIAN PAYMENTS CLEARING ASSOCIATION) ANNUAL REVIEW 2015, at 26, available at

http://www.apca.com.au/docs/default-source/annual-reviews/apca-annual-review-2015.pdf . 1513 The settlements are available at:

http://www.comcom.govt.nz/business-competition/enforcement-response-register-commerce/detail/665

Page 338: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

338

809. Section 3.1.7 of the Settlements with Visa and MasterCard stipulates: "if there is neither an

issuer rate nor a bilaterally agreed rate notified to [MasterCard/Visa] that applies" then no

interchange fee (zero interchange fee) will be paid on that transaction.1514 However, the problem

I emphasized throughout this work is that as long as acquirers remain issuers, they gladly

consent to pay high interchange fees to themselves in another transaction (or to themselves in

the same transaction, if it is an “On-Us” transaction).1515 Indeed, until today, no independent

acquirer has entered the market in New-Zealand. The interchange fees in New Zealand for

MasterCard can be as high as 2.35%.1516 Visa interchange fees are up to 2.3%.1517

NAWI Rule in the Bylaws of the International Organizations

810. The default rule of MasterCard and Visa is still a NAWI rule, rephrased more carefully, and

subject to modifications in regulated territories. For example, rule 3.1 of MasterCard bylaws

entitled: "Obligation to Issue MasterCard Cards" determines: "Each Principal and

Association Licensed to use the MasterCard Marks, together with its Sponsored Affiliates, must

have issued and outstanding a reasonable number of MasterCard Cards based on such criteria

as the Corporation may deem appropriate from time to time. NOTE Modifications to this Rule

appear in the “Asia/Pacific Region,” “Europe Region,” “Latin America and the

Caribbean Region,” “Middle East/Africa Region,” and “United States Region” chapters”

(emphasis in the original – O.B.).1518 Needless to say, that in the absence of territorial

modification, if the primary obligation of members is to issue cards, then acquirers will always

be former issuers, i.e., a NAWI rule.

Visa Settlement, sec. 4.1.1: "Visa participation is, and will remain, open to all New Zealand entities, including financial

institutions and other entities, on application to Visa". sec 4.1.2: "Applications will be considered by Visa applying

criteria which are directed solely to confirming that the applicant has the capability (for example, capital / financial

strength, systems, risk practices – that is, credit, fraud and operational risk), operational readiness and skills to provide

intended services without undue credit, reputational or other risks to Visa". The settlement with MasterCard is similar;

Peter R. Taylor, Cards and Payments Australasia (Payment Conference, Mar. 15, 2010): “Relevant for specialist and

self-acquirers, the schemes have confirmed that acquirers need not also be issuers and that applicants need not be

financial institutions”. See also supra ¶ 669. 1514 See also Peter R. Taylor, ibid: “[I]f an issuer does not stipulate or agree a fee with an acquirer, no interchange will

be payable on that issuer’s transaction; Asia Pacific Banking ANF Finance, NZ uses market forces to bring card

companies into line (May 21, 2010): "The manner in which interchange fees are now independently determined is

unique to New Zealand – significantly, if an issuer does not stipulate or agree a fee with an acquirer, no interchange will

be payable on that issuer’s transaction". 1515 For “on-us” transactions see supra ch. 2.4.1. 1516 MasterCard interchange fees in New Zealand, available at http://www.mastercard.com/nz/merchants/interchange-

fees.html 1517 Visa interchange fees in New Zealand, available at http://www.visa.co.nz/aboutvisa/interchange/interchange.shtml 1518 Rule 3.1 of MasterCard Rules, (Dec. 2014), available at http://www.mastercard.com/us/merchant/pdf/BM-Entire_Manual_public.pdf

Page 339: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

339

811. As surveyed above, even in places where the NAWI rule was abolished, there are no

independent acquirers, let alone independent acquirers that participate in the determination of

the interchange fee they pay.

The paradox is that although theoretically independent acquirers can exist, on a practical level

only banks can be independent acquirers, but no bank wants to be only an acquirer. Thus, even

under regimes that permit independent acquirers to operate, this independency is not

implemented in practice, and acquirers remain issuers or tied to issuers.1519

13.2. Proposal to Separate Acquirers from Issuers

812. To solve the inherent conflict of interest that causes acquirers to “surrender” to issuers and agree

to pay high interchange fees, I suggest mandating a structural dissolution between issuers and

acquirers. My suggestion is to prohibit acquirers from having any interest on the issuing side,

and to provide independent acquirers the bargaining power to determine the interchange fee

they pay.

813. Separating issuers from acquirers is actually a mandatory implementation of the decisions to

cancel the NAWI rule. The ambition of regulators who canceled the NAWI rule, to reduce

interchange fees and remove entry barriers, was never fulfilled. The cancelation of the NAWI

rule was aimed to facilitate the entrance of independent acquirers, who could determine the

interchange fee they pay. However, this never occurred. The pervasive conflict of interest into

which acquirers are inherently trapped in, did not vanish, due to the existing connections

between issuers and acquirers. Thus, the divestiture I propose fulfills the legislative purpose

behind the cancelation of the NAWI rule that was thwarted in practice.

814. The interchange fee, according to my suggestion, would be determined in an annual single

multilateral process between independent acquirers on one side and independent issuers on the

other side. In the absence of consent, the default interchange fee would be zero. When issuers'

considerations are weighed in the determination of the interchange fee, the interchange fee is

inflated, because this suits the interest of acquirers which are also issuers to be paid as much as

possible, in their role as issuers. Under my proposal, the determination of the interchange fee

1519 Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 1471, at 25: “No national scheme has a “no

acquiring without issuing” rule. In practice, however, despite there being no compulsion, most banks are issuers

and acquirers at the same time”.

DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND

BORROWING 250 (2d ed. 2005): "[O]nly bank members of Visa and MasterCard can formally be acquirers".

Page 340: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

340

would cease to be a self-dealing process. The paying party, i.e., the acquirer, would no longer

be at an inherent conflict of interest, resulting from its interest as a payee, i.e., an issuer.

The simplicity of the proposal stems from the fact that when independent acquirers that are not

connected to the issuing side, and do not have any interest other than as payers, determine the

interchange fee they pay, and the default in the case of no consent is zero, the interchange fee

itself ceases to be a restrictive arrangement! The only reason the interchange fee would still be

considered restrictive arrangement, would be in case the determination process involves joint

negotiation of competing acquirers from one side and competing issuers from the other,

However, joint negotiation is a familiar restrictive arrangement, which can be relatively easy

treated.1520 In addition, even the joint negotiation can be avoided, as explained in para. 823

below.

815. My proposal starts with a default interchange fee of zero. The idea of imposing zero interchange

fees is not novel and has been suggested before.1521 However, the fact that a default interchange

fee is required does not, for itself, mean that it should be zero. Indeed, networks set positive

interchange fees as default. I do not adopt the idea of zero interchange fees as a target, but as a

starting point, acknowledging the special features of the interchange fee discussed widely in

this work.1522 Zero interchange fee as a target ignores the two-sided features of payment cards.

Zero interchange fee might not be sufficient when the issuing side requires encouragement to

cover issuers' costs including incentives to cardholders. Therefore, what I propose is not a

target of zero interchange fee, but a default of zero interchange fee.

Starting from zero, independent acquirers may agree to increase the interchange fee they pay.

The idea is that if acquirers would be independent, and as such would determine the interchange

fee they pay, they would collectively internalize the network and usage externalities.1523 They

would consent to an increase in the interchange fee, only if the increase would confer benefits

to each of them individually and all of them as a group.

The acquiring market is considered to be competitive with full pass through rates.1524

1520 Infra ¶ 823. 1521 Supra ch. 12.2 (zero interchange fee). See also ¶ 809 (In New Zealand, the settlements state that if no previously

determined interchange fee exist, then no interchange fee will be paid on that transaction); ¶ 668 (issuers cannot demand

ex-post interchange fees). 1522 Supra ch. 7 (The Special Feaures of the Interchange Fee). 1523 Supra ch. 7.2 1524 Supra ¶97; see also BANK OF ISRAEL, THE BANKING SYSTEM IN ISRAEL, 2015 ANNUAL REVIEW, at 27, 30 (2016).

Page 341: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

341

Competitiveness means that each acquirer desires to maximize its volume of transactions.1525

The main mean in this competition is the lowest MSF an acquirer can offer. The consumer

welfare optimal interchange fee also aims to maximize efficient transactions subject to lowest

fees.1526

Interchange fee is an input for acquirers. Generally, every buyer wants to buy inputs at the

lowest price possible. Acquirers would consent to a raise in the interchange fee, only if the

higher price contributes to increasing their volume of transactions, because of indirect network

effect of the two-sided market. When this occurs, then paying higher interchange fee increases

the volume of transactions not only for each acquirer individually but also for all of them as a

group. As a byproduct, under the assumption that card transactions are efficient when the

interchange fee is not excessive, interchange fee would be raised only if this contributes to the

consumer welfare.1527

816. A supplementary rule must prohibit any circumvention of the interchange fee. As explained

above, Article 5 of the European Regulation 2015/751 on Interchange Fees from May 2015

prohibits any circumvention of the interchange fee no matter how the parties design it.1528 This

rule forbids any payments from acquirers to issuers other than the interchange fee. This rule

should be supplemented by a prohibition of payments also from issuers to acquirers, aiming to

"bribe" acquirers to consent to higher interchange fees. Any such side deal should be prohibited

and declared a punishable violation. The voting process should be under a rule of fiduciary duty

towards the acquirers' group.

817. The whip for issuers in the case of no consent would be zero interchange fee. This would give

independent acquirers the bargaining power in the negotiation. Issuers would have to convince

acquirers that raising the interchange fee would benefit the acquirers. This could be done only

if the interchange fee would indeed be used to expand volume of transactions and acquirers'

turnover in a manner revealed to the acquirers, and in an amount that would overcome the

increase in the fee acquirers pay. Otherwise, acquirers would prefer to pay less (they

determine!) and save money in each transaction.

1525 214. Ann Kjos, The Merchant-Acquiring Side of the Payment Card Industry: Structure, Operations, and Challenges,

at 9 (FRB Philadelphia Discussion Paper 2007): “Data processing is, at its heart, a scale-oriented business wherein size

and volumes drive profitability… Acquiring quickly became recognized as a volume business.”; See also Supra ¶97. 1526 Supra ch. 6.9.4; infra ¶858. 1527 Supra ch. 6.9.4; see also ¶¶ 36, 406 1528 Supra ¶¶ 518 and 584.3.

Page 342: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

342

818. Acquirers would agree to pay interchange fee, only to the extent it increases the volume of

transactions, in a manner that outweighs the increase in the transaction price for each of them.

Just like the example of a dating club, in which one gender agrees to pay more if he or she gets

a higher benefit,1529 acquirers would agree to pay a higher interchange fee, when it deems

profitable for them, due to higher volumes of card usage genuinely derived by the interchange

fee. Acquirers are best positioned to weigh the effects of interchange fees on the volume of

transactions, because they are side to these transactions.

819. As explained in Chapter 6.9.4 (socially optimal interchange fee), from a consumer welfare point

of view, which includes merchants and all customers (cash and card payers alike), the optimal

interchange fee maximizes efficient card transactions, subject to the condition that final prices

of goods should be equal to the cost of production. Independent acquirers (as opposed to

acquirers that are also issuers), would pursue this aim as a by-product, because their interest

would become like those of final consumers.1530 Independent acquirers would like to set the

interchange fee on the lowest level, because it is an input for them, unless they acknowledge its

special features as an internalization mechanism which induces more efficient card transactions.

i.e., to boost usage.

Acquirers do not weigh the impact of their decisions on other payment instruments such as cash

and checks. If my proposal expands card usage, this should reflect a decline in the usage of cash

and checks. Such move is efficient, only if payment cards are cheaper and more efficient than

cash and checks. The empirical studies support such a move. Except small coin-size

transactions, for which cash is most efficient, payment card, especially debit, is the most

efficient payment instrument.1531 Actually interchange fee which is higher than optimal, is the

main cause for "inverse usage externality", which distorts efficient usage of payment

instruments, because it inflates the MSF, i.e., the price of card transactions.1532 Thus, reducing

the interchange fee would lower the price of card transactions with respect to cash and checks,

and under the assumption that cards are more efficient, enhanced usage of cards on account of

(expensive) cash and checks, is another benefit of my proposal.

1529 Supra ¶ 452 (in two sided markets, contrary to "one-sided" markets, customers might actually prefer to pay more,

because of the indirect market effect on the other side, which benefits them). 1530 See supra note 74. 1531 Supra ¶¶ 125 and 143. 1532 See supra ¶¶ 257, 480, 717, 730.

Page 343: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

343

820. Acquirers would not consent to an increase in the interchange fee which is a tool for issuers'

profits or redundant rewards. Even in the unlikely event of full pass through from interchange

fee to rewards, acquirers would probably not agree to pay interchange fee which is used for

rewards that do not induce more card transactions (but cause cardholder fees to be negative).

Under the assumption that cardholders derive sufficient inherent benefits from cards, they

would use cards anyway. When rewards are given to cardholders who would use their cards

anyway, the effect of rewards is mainly to inflate the MSF (and final prices of goods), and shift

usage from cheap non-rewarding cards to cards that offer the rewards, which are more

expensive.1533 Acquirers would not agree to pay for such unnecessary rewards, because such

rewards for them are reflected in a higher price they pay with no redeeming value. Under my

proposal, the competitive pressures on the acquiring side would not be distorted anymore.

Acquirers' interest to maximize their profit would align with their interest to purchase their main

input, the interchange fee, at the lowest price.

821. Under the Honor All Cards rule, if independent acquirers would not agree with issuers on the

rate of the interchange fee, cross transactions (i.e., transactions in which the acquirer and the

issuer are different entities), would still be executed, under the default interchange fee. Visa

and MasterCard acquirers cannot refuse to acquire cards bearing the logo of Visa or

MasterCard, even if there is no prior agreement regarding the interchange fee. Issuers must

remit to acquirers all transactions' funds, even if no interchange fee is paid at all.1534 As

explained above, the "extortion" argument, according to which acquirers "must" allegedly pay

issuers interchange fee that suffices the issuers, is flawed.1535 Thus, Split, as explained in

Chapter 12.3 above, would not occur.1536

822. Issuers might try to resort to the default interchange fees of the international organizations, in

order to avoid zero interchange fees.1537 However, the interchange fees that are set in the bylaws

of international organizations, are just a restrictive arrangement as any other bilateral or

multilateral interchange fee.1538 Thus any bylaws' interchange fee would also be subject to the

default zero interchange fee rule of my proposal, unless independent acquirers in that territory

1533 Supra ¶¶ 236 - 237, 343. 1534 See e.g., section 1.7.6 of Visa Core Rules, titled Settlement

https://usa.visa.com/dam/VCOM/download/about-visa/15-April-2015-Visa-Rules-Public.pdf :

"An Issuer must pay the Acquirer the amount due for a Transaction occurring with the use of a valid Card. This includes

Transactions resulting from geographically restricted Card use outside the country of issuance." 1535 Supra ch. 8.3.5 and ¶ 579. 1536 Supra ch. 11.2.2. See also Sainsbury’s supermarkets v. MasterCard, paras. 143, 149-51 (July 14, 2016) 1537 For default interchange fees set by the international organizations see supra ¶¶ 52, 698 and note 1283. 1538 Supra ch. 9.1 (Bylaws interchange fee).

Page 344: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

344

determine otherwise. Indeed, the bylaws of the international organizations subject themselves

to any territorial rule that determines otherwise.1539

823. I offer two mechanisms of setting the interchange fee. The first mechanism is collective

bargaining. The second mechanism is an on-line tender process. Each of them has its pros and

cons discussed below.

According to the first mechanism the interchange fee would be determined in a periodic (e.g.,

annual) meeting between representatives of independent acquirers from one side and issuers’

representatives from the other side.

Each acquirer and issuer would have the right to send a representative to this periodic meeting.

This authority can be delegated to a third party, general counsel, board member, external lawyer

or an outer agent.1540 Due to the importance of the interchange fee, the representatives would

most probably come with a prior position regarding the desired interchange fee, discussed with

their board.

The idea is to enable issuers’ representatives to persuade independent acquirers’

representatives, in the necessity of a positive interchange fee. Issuers should be permitted to

present their costs and their cardholders’ incomes, to convince acquirers that a certain rate of

interchange fee is necessary and would be beneficial to the acquirers. The default, in case of no

consent, would be zero.

After consummation of the negotiation, independent acquirers would vote. The negotiation

process should yield one interchange fee for every kind of card transactions (credit, debit,

prepaid etc.). The chosen interchange fee would obligate also acquirers that are not present.

The second mechanism I propose is a periodic (e.g., annually) electronic tender. On the

appointed time each acquirer would vote on-line for the chosen interchange fee (e.g., 0.1% for

credit, 0.05% for debit). The tender process should be secured against integrity or

confidentiality violations and other computer threats.1541

1539 Supra ¶ 53; see also supra note 1287. 1540 See infra ¶ 839 for antitrust benefits of delegation of the joint negotiation to third parties. 1541 For expansion on E-Tenders threats see Martin Betts, Peter Black, Sharon Christensen, Ed Dawson, Rong Du,

William Duncan, Ernest Foo, Juan González Nieto, Security, legal and risk issues relating to e-tendering, at 19 (2006);

Page 345: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

345

Prior to submitting the electronic bids issuers would be permitted to meet acquirers, and to

persuade acquirers in the necessity of a positive interchange fee. This mechanism is no different

from any negotiation between a supplier and a purchaser, which can include meetings and

presentations, except for the price which ordinarily is a product of consent and here it would be

determined solely by the buyer (the acquirers). Exchange of information between acquirers

prior to voting should be permitted, to increase transparency and elaborate the competitive

process. The competitive concerns of information exchange, which in this case are aimed to

lower the interchange fee, do not seem to appear here, as discussed in para. 835 below.

The default mechanism would be electronic voting. However, issuers or acquirers above a

threshold, should be able to summon a meeting, (i.e., the first mechanism), in order to present

market wide innovations or other information relevant to the determination of the interchange

fee.

In both mechanisms, the basic rule should be one vote for each acquirer. Although acquirers

are not identical, I believe their preferences about the interchange fee would be the same. Their

vote would probably be unanimous. After all, interchange fee is a major input for independent

acquirers so each of them would like to pay as little as possible. I cannot see how the benefits

interchange fee might inflict, which is the only reason an acquirer would vote for a positive

interchange fee, would affect one acquirer in a different manner than the other. The effect of

the interchange fee is probably identical across the board. In the absence of extraneous

considerations, it is difficult to see any conflict of interest between acquirers.

In case there are disparities among independent acquirers, which result from genuine

divergence in their subjective evaluations of the interchange fee, a decision rule is required.

The first decision rule I propose is an average rule. Mathematically, this rule would approximate

the chosen interchange fee to be closest to the collective choice of all acquirers as a group.

However, if there are significant differences between acquirers, the rule can vary according to

Larry O'Connell, Electronic Tendering: Recognising a More Effective Use of Information Communications Technology

in the Irish Construction Industry, Masters dissertation. Dublin Institute of Technology (2010).

Page 346: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

346

the relative weight of each acquirer. For example, if one acquirer has a market share of 90%

and its vote is for an interchange fee of 0.1% and the other acquirer has 10% market share and

its vote is for an interchange fee of 0.3% the interchange fee according to a weighted average

is not 0.2% but 0.12%.

I propose to use relative weights only if there are significant differences between acquirers,

such as in market shares or in merchant sectors of operation (e.g., one acquirer contracts with

Walmart size merchants and the other with small groceries). As explained in para. 97 above,

economies of scale exist on the acquiring side. Acquiring business is homogeneous by its

nature, and acquirers’ profit is derived from large volume of transactions, thus “niche” acquirers

are not expected to be viable. In addition, interchange fee is an input for niche acquirers just as

for large merchants’ acquirers. It is reasonable to assume that even niche acquirers would not

prefer different interchange fee than “general” acquirers. However, if significant disparities do

exist among acquirers then weighted average according to market share is appropriate.

Generally, voting can be biased due to manipulation or strategic considerations of voters.1542

Specifically, determination of the interchange fee based on average (or weighted average) can

be distorted due to extreme voting. For example, if 4 acquirers vote for interchange fee of 0.1%

but the fifth acquirer votes for 5%, an average rule would be distorted upwards. To prevent this

deviation, I suggest an alternative decision rule. In cases of extreme votes, which would be

defined as votes in which the gaps are larger than a threshold (e.g., 0.15% gap between the low

and high interchange fee) the decision rule would be automatically converted to be determined

by the median and not by the average.

A median rule eliminates distortions from genuine disparities. In addition, a median rule

alleviates, from the outset, distortions from strategic voting. If, for example, an acquirer wants

0.15% interchange fee, and it is aware of its peers’ intention to vote for 0.1% interchange fee,

that acquirer may deliberately vote higher than its preference, e.g., 0.3%. A median rule

eliminates extreme votes. Thus, a median rule, albeit not entirely strategy proof (because

strategic voting is possible within the threshold), reduces ex-ante incentives to vote

1542 For expansion see Jonathan Levin and Barry Nalebuff, An Introduction to Vote-Counting Schemes, 9 J. ECON.

PERSPECTIVES 3 (1995); David Easley and Jon Kleinberg, Voting in 735 NETWORKS, CROWDS, AND MARKETS:

REASONING ABOUT A HIGHLY CONNECTED WORLD (2010).

Page 347: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

347

strategically.1543 The vote of an acquirer who wants its voice to be considered, would be closer

to its real preferences, to avoid a disparity which would activate the median rule.

A combination of the average and median rule is also a possibility. For example, the LIBOR

interest rate is an average of the 50% middle bids after elimination of the 25% lower and 25%

upper bids. Such rule can be plausible in case there are large number of acquirers.

824. My proposal contains joint negotiation between competitors on each side. Actually, this would

be the only reason for the interchange fee still being a restrictive arrangement. However, the

competitive concerns of joint negotiation are familiar,1544 and can be mitigated in our case, as

discussed below. In addition, under the current situation this cooperation exists anyway in a

graver form.

As explained by the European Commission "Joint purchasing arrangements usually aim at the

creation of buying power which can lead to lower prices or better quality products or services

for consumers".1545 Indeed, creation of independent acquirers' buying power aimed to lower the

interchange fee and the resulting MSF is the motivation for the structural separation from the

outset.

In the next sub-chapter (Ch. 13.3) I explain why competitive concerns from acquirers’

collective actions do not seem to appear here. In short, under both mechanisms, given that the

default rule is zero, no buying market power that is not conferred to acquirers anyway, arises.

Second, all acquirers in a territory would be able to participate and be subject to the chosen

interchange fee. Thus, the usual concern that competitors who do not participate in the process,

would be in an inferior position, does not arise. Third, because acquiring market is considered

competitive, any savings from lower interchange fee are expected to pass through downstream

to merchants and consumers.1546

1543 Alex Gershkov, Benny Moldovanu and Xianwen Shi, Optimal Voting Rules, at 2 (2016) : “It is well known that,

under complete information, single-peaked preferences and simple majority, the “sophisticated” equilibrium outcome

(reached by backward induction) of the successive voting procedures (and of many other binary voting schemes) is the

Condorcet winner, i.e., the alternative preferred by the median voter”.”; see also VINCENT CONITZER AND TOBY

WALSH, Barriers to Manipulation in Voting, in 127 HANDBOOK OF COMPUTATIONAL SOCIAL CHOICE (Cambridge

2016). 1544 See infra ch. 13.4 (mitigating competitive concerns). See also Stephen P. King, Collective Bargaining By Business:

Economic And Legal Implications, 36 UNSW L. J. 107 (2013); David E. Feller, A General Theory of the Collective

Bargaining Agreement, 61 CAL. L. REV. 663 (1973); Camilo Rubiano, Collective Bargaining and Competition Law: A

Comparative Study on the Media, Arts and Entertainment Sectors, (July 2013); Jonathan C. Tyras, Collective

Bargaining and Antitrust After Brown v. Pro Football, Inc., 1 PENN J. BUS. L. 297 (1998). 1545 Guidelines on the applicability of Article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union to horizontal

co-operation agreements, para. 194 (2011). See also infra ¶ 841. 1546 For competitive concerns from joint purchasing agreements see the European Guidelines, ibid paras 200-216.

Page 348: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

348

Most importantly is that the interchange fee itself, as a minimum price fixing between

competitors, who are simultaneously its buyers and sellers, would cease to exist. The outcome

of the determination process would be a single market wide interchange fee for each kind of

card transactions (i.e., credit, debit, prepaid).

825. In 2008 a Bill was proposed to the U.S. Congress (H.R. 5546, the Credit Card Fair Fee Act of

2008, hereafter: "the Bill").1547 The Bill was aimed to "correct an imbalance that currently

exists between credit card companies on one side and merchants and consumers on the other".

The bill attempted to achieve this goal "[B]y giving a limited antitrust exemption to merchants

so they can negotiate with the credit card companies for interchange fee rates and rules".1548

The Bill, which was never enacted to a final law, defined a 'Voluntarily negotiated access

agreement' as an agreement negotiated between merchants and payment card networks

representatives, to set the terms and fees of card transactions.1549

826. My proposal resembles the Bill, in the sense of setting of the interchange fee, as an outcome of

an exempted negotiation between representatives of competitors. A major difference between

the Bill and my proposal is of course the identity of the side to negotiate the interchange fee it

pays. In the Bill it was merchants. In my proposal it is independent acquirers. In my view,

independent acquirers are a better party than merchants to negotiate interchange fee.

First and foremost, the interchange fee is a mechanism to internalize usage and network

externalities. It is naive to think merchants would internalize the benefits of interchange fees,

as an internalizing mechanism in two-sided markets, on a market wide scale, in a manner that

acquirers would do. Merchants are simply not capable of internalizing network and usage

externalities of the entire market. They would probably not agree to pay interchange fee at all.

Merchants are not able to weigh the two-sided features of payment cards, because contrary to

acquirers, each merchant internalizes the costs to itself, but cannot internalize the benefits to

the industry as a whole from a positive interchange fee. Most probably merchants' vote would

be always zero interchange fee.

1547 H.R 5546 110th Cong. (2008) Credit Card Fair Fee Act ("The Bill"). 1548 H.R Report 110-913 CREDIT CARD FAIR FEE ACT OF 2008, at 4-5 (Oct 3, 2008). 1549 § 2(a)(18) of the Bill: "Voluntarily negotiated access agreement'' means an executed agreement voluntarily

negotiated between 1 or more providers of a single covered electronic payment system and 1 or more merchants that

sets the rates and terms pursuant to which the 1 or more merchants can access that covered electronic payment system

to accept credit cards and/or debit cards from consumers for payment of goods and services, and receive payment for

such goods and services".

Page 349: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

349

Acceptance of payment instruments "costs" money for merchants.1550 Merchants are

supposedly in a better position than acquirers to appreciate the effects of the MSF they pay on

other payment instruments, such as checks and cash. For example, the tourist test envisages

how much a merchant is willing to pay, to divert a non-repeating cash payer to cards.1551 There

is a good reason to assume that interchange fee under my proposal would be lower than that of

the tourist test, meaning merchants would derive benefits from accepting cards and no other

(more expensive) payment instrument (under the tourist test merchants are indifferent). The

reason is that the net benefit of merchants from a card transaction, is higher than the cost of the

transaction. Independent acquirers with bargaining power would probably not pay issuers any

positive interchange fee, unless required to expand volume of transactions. This interchange

fee is, by definition, lower than the interchange fee that reflects merchants' benefits from

accepting card and not cash or check. Thus, my proposal enables merchants to enjoy the net

benefits of accepting cards, even though the acquirers and not the merchants determine the

interchange fee.

Acquirers also consider the benefit for themselves, but contrary to merchants, and especially if

the negotiation encompasses all acquirers as a group, their considerations and decisions are

made on a market-wide basis. Acquirers, as opposed to merchants, can see the benefits of a

positive interchange fee, from a bird's eye which covers all the market. Acquirers are capable

of internalizing that payment cards are two-sided network products. The network and usage

externalities can be internalized by acquirers, based on aggregate volume of transactions which

they acquire. Independent acquirers would weigh the profit from the volume of transactions

they process against their costs in each transaction. Their aim to maximize profits supports a

positive interchange fee, if and only if this fee is indeed used to expand the volume of

transactions to their benefit. Thus, independent acquirers (and not merchants) should be the

negotiating party to determine the interchange fee. Merchants would never be able to consider

the effect of the interchange fee they pay on the payment card industry as a whole, whereas

acquirers inherently can.

827. Second, the competitive concerns raised from cooperation between competing merchants are

far more serious than the concerns stemming from the same cooperation between competing

1550 See supra ch. 0 (Costs and Benefits of payment instruments), especially ¶¶ 156 and 159. 1551 See supra ch. 8.2.1for the tourist test. See also ¶¶ 666 and 261.

Page 350: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

350

acquirers. Indeed, the Department of Justice warned that the ability of merchants to jointly

negotiate, and agree upon fees and terms could lead to a collusion, spillover effects and

exchange of confidential information between competing merchants.1552

My second mechanism, of online voting, does not contain collective bargaining at all. As

explained in section 823 above and also in Chapter 13.3 below,1553 even under the first

mechanism, those concerns are alleviated when the joint negotiation is performed by acquirers

(in short, towards issuers, not the joint bargaining confers market power but the default rule of

zero; among acquirers there is no concern, because all acquirers participate in the cooperation

and no acquirer is left in an inferior position;1554 towards merchants the concern is mitigated

because of the competitiveness of the acquiring market that compels acquirers to offer cost-

based MSF).

828. Another difference is the default interchange fee in the event of no consent. Initially, the Bill

proposed a panel of three administrative judges to determine the interchange fee,1555 whereas

the fallback interchange fee according to my proposal is zero. The proposal to set the default

interchange fee by three judges was heavily criticized. The Department of Justice explained and

emphasized in an open letter the disadvantages of "panel of judges".1556 In response, the Bill

was amended, and supervision of the Department of Justice replaced the three panel judges.1557

However, this supervision is also not a solution in the case of no consent.

1552 Letter from Keith B. Nelson, Principal Deputy Assistant Attorney General to the Judiciary Committy, (June 23,

2008): "[T]he ability of merchants (and issuers) to discuss, jointly negotiate, and agree upon fees and terms with one

network could lead to an implicit understanding on what fees and terms to accept from other networks, including

networks not encompassed by this legislation. Such a spillover effect would diminish, not enhance, competition

between payment card networks". 1553 See specially Infra ¶¶ 837 - 840. 1554 Infra ¶ 830. 1555 H.R 5546 110th Cong. (2008), at 24: "If the parties cannot agree voluntarily to such terms and conditions, then the

parties are subject to an administrative procedure before a three judge panel that will determine the rates and terms for a

three year period. The three-judge panel will be selected and administered by the Department of Justice’s Antitrust

Division and the Federal Trade Commission". 1556 Letter from Keith B. Nelson, Principal Deputy Assistant Attorney General to the Judiciary Committee, (June 23,

2008) available at https://www.icba.org/files/ICBASites/PDFs/DOJResponsetoSmithLetter6-23-08.pdf : "The

Department does not support the creation of a regulatory panel to set rates and terms of access. Generally, regulation

should be confined to the fewest areas possible, and even then should be narrowly tailored to address a clearly

demonstrated market failure. Notwithstanding the best of intentions and goals, the regulator will be imperfect in its

attempt to replicate the terms that would be reached in a competitive market. Moreover, a panel of regulators cannot

replicate the flexibility that is found in the free market". 1557 House of Representatives H.R. Report 110-913 CREDIT CARD FAIR FEE ACT OF 2008, at 25 (Accompany H.R. 5546

110th Congress,2008) https://www.congress.gov/110/crpt/hrpt913/CRPT-110hrpt913.pdf : "Chairman Conyers

attempted to address these concerns by eliminating the three-judge panel and replacing it with DOJ oversight over the

negotiations".

Page 351: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

351

829. Another major difference between the Bill and my proposal is that the Bill did not limit the

joint negotiation to interchange fees. Merchants could discuss all "rates and terms of access to

payment systems".1558 Practically, this meant that the MSF (and other rates and terms) could

also be determined by collective bargaining. My proposal concerns only the interchange fee. In

my opinion, if the acquiring market is reasonably competitive (rather than monopolized or

suffers from another market failure), the gap between the interchange fee and the MSF should

not be determined in a collective bargaining.

The acquiring market world-wide is considered competitive with pass through rate close to

100%.1559 Thus there is no justification to forgo the setting of the MSF in a competitive manner.

In addition, even if interference in the MSF were warranted, and in my view it is not, it would

better be done through a non-discrimination rule than by price control.1560 The acquiring gap

between the interchange fee and the MSF is transparent, and when the acquiring market is

competitive it should be left open for competition.

830. The Bill did not obligate all merchants to participate in the joint negotiation. Thus, external

merchants could purportedly be disadvantaged if they did not take part in the negotiation. They

could find themselves ex-poste alone, against arbitrary high demands that their rivals, who

participated in the collective determination, would not face. Indeed, usually, the motivation for

allowing all players in a market to participate in a joint negotiation, is to prevent discrimination

against any player who is left outside the joint negotiation. The conventional concern is that

non-participating firms would not be able to reach the favorable terms reached in the collective

bargaining. My proposal does not suffer from this drawback. On the contrary, the motivation

behind obligating all (independent) acquirers to participate is opposite – to prevent external

acquirers' free riding. Due to the default of zero interchange fee, acquirers that would not

participate in the collective bargaining, would allegedly be put in a better and not a worse

position. Applying the chosen interchange fee on all acquirers in a territory, is the only way to

prevent free-riding by acquirers, who would not participate in the determination of the

interchange fee, and then refuse to pay.

1558 Sec. 2(b) of the Bill, titled: "limited antitrust immunity for negotiation 15 of access rates and terms to covered

electronic 16 payment systems" stated, in the relevant part: "[A]ny providers of a single covered electronic payment

system and any merchants may jointly negotiate and agree upon the rates and terms for access to the covered electronic

payment system". 1559 Supra ¶ 97 1560 See supra ¶¶ 524, 535-538, 541, 323, 830 and notes 922, 955.

Page 352: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

352

Issuers would not be able to charge non-participating acquirers more than the agreed upon

interchange fee. Actually, it is in the interest of issuers that all acquirers participate in the

determination of the interchange fee, thus preventing extortion by residual acquirers. However,

acquirers could try to limit the access of non-participating acquirers to the infrastructure of the

network. Thus, obligating all acquirers to participate in the interchange fee determination

prevents possible foreclosure of acquirers, and further supports that all acquirers should

participate in the setting of the interchange fee.1561

Interchange fee is equivalent to "transaction tax" on acquirers. Taxes should be imposed

equally. It is only fair that all competing acquirers in the market pay the same interchange fee,

just like it is fair to demand that competing rivals pay same tax rates. This means that a local

agreement like the Trio Agreement in Israel is indeed desirable. If this were not the case, then

an individual acquirer might not agree to pay any interchange fee, relying (and free-riding) on

other acquirers to pay the interchange fees that are required to incentivize optimal usage, from

which it will enjoy the benefits without incurring the costs. There is no justification for tax

discrimination among acquirers.1562

831. My proposal for a single interchange fee is with respect to each type of transaction. Debit card

transactions are different from credit card transactions which are different from prepaid

transactions.1563 Cheaper, faster and safer transactions should be awarded lower interchange

fees. In each category of transactions, independent acquirers should be able to choose different

interchange fees, which reflect the different costs and benefits of each type of transaction.1564

Thus, the rule should be one interchange fee for each type of transactions (credit; debit; prepaid

etc.). As explained in Chapter 8.1.3.2 above, I hold the opinion there should be no merchant

categories of interchange fees. This was also the proposal of the Bill.1565

832. A transition period for the divestiture should be granted. However, when several independent

acquirers enter the market, my proposal is to validate the proposal. Independent acquirers will

1561 Compare Guidelines on the Applicability of Article 101 to Horizontal Co-Operation Agreements, O.J C 11/1 §203

(Jan. 14, 2011): "Buying power of the parties to the joint purchasing arrangement could be used to foreclose competing

purchasers by limiting their access to efficient suppliers. This is most likely if there are a limited number of suppliers

and there are barriers to entry on the supply side of the upstream market". 1562 Supra ¶ 783 ([T]he interchange fee imposes a tax on card transactions. Taxes should be at an even rate). 1563 Supra ch. 6.8 (Debit v. Credit). 1564 Supra ch. 0. 1565 H.R. 5546 - Summary, 110th Cong. 2d sess. (2008), https://www.congress.gov/bill/110th-congress/house-bill/5546 :

"Requires the rates and terms of a voluntarily negotiated access agreement to be the same for all merchants and

participating providers, regardless of their respective category or volume of transactions".

Page 353: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

353

have the bargaining power to determine the interchange fee. Their determination would obligate

acquirers which remain attached to issuers, until all acquirers become independent. Acquirers

that would not qualify for the independency demand, would not be able to participate in the

interchange fee determination process, but they would be bound to pay the agreed upon

interchange fee.

833. For avoidance of constitutional doubts, my proposal should be anchored in a primary rule,1566

i.e., a statute and not secondary legislation or regulations.1567 In my view, the legal classification

for my proposal should be in an amendment to the Banking law (licensing), 1981. A sub section

should be added (possibly to §36), that enforces an "AWI rule", i.e., an Acquiring Without

Issuing rule. The law should stipulate that an acquirer cannot be issuer, or have direct or indirect

possessions at issuing activity. The determination process (on-line tender or periodical

meeting), should be regularized in an ordinance or secondary legislation

834. An exception should be made for nascent and small issuers, or for new and efficient kind of

transactions which require incentives at the payers' side.1568 Issuers at the take-off stage should

be able to demand a higher interchange fee for a limited period. New kinds of efficient

transactions should also be encouraged. This should enable new entrants or modern

technologies to grow, reward their users and establish a critical mass.

13.3. Mitigating Competitive Concerns

835. Collaboration among competitors for joint purchase of a main input, such as the interchange

fee, has potential to raise competitive concerns.

Under both mechanisms (on-line voting and periodic meeting), competing acquirers can

exchange information with respect to the interchange fee they would choose. Exchange of

information that is meant to be kept confidential removes the normal uncertainty concerning

1566 For expansion on primary rules see H.L.A. HART, THE CONCEPT OF LAW (Oxford, 1961). 1567 For the importance (and stronger validity) of arrangements made through primary rules, see HCJ 3267/97

Rubinshtein v. Minister of Defense, 52(5) 481, (1998) (Exemption of orthodox Jews from the army must be anchored in

a statute); but cf. HCJ 4491/13 Merkaz Academy Lemishpat Veasakim v. Government of Israel (July 2, 2014) (Gas

exportation policy can be determined by the government). 1568 Borestam & Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, supra note 1471, at 25: "This rule [the NAWI rule –

O.B] can contribute to the initial take-off of a scheme, since card payments take place on a two-sided market, where

both issuers and acquirers are needed. The “no acquiring without issuing” rule therefore ensures a certain balance

between the issuing and acquiring activities within each bank". See also Supra ¶ 526 (Durbin Amendment does not

apply to small financial institutions).

Page 354: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

354

the actions of the competitor providing the information.1569 Information exchange can be anti-

competitive, if it is liable to restrict competition.1570 However, here, the interchange fee is not

supposed to be confidential and the exchange of information between acquirers is aimed at

lowering the interchange fee, to the benefit of consumers. Exchange of information between

issuers cannot have restrictive effects, because under the default of zero, issuers do not have

market power. Thus, exchange of information cannot facilitate any collusion. On the contrary,

it contributes to informed decision-making based on full information.

836. The information exchange is part of a collective bargaining. Even if the result of collective

bargaining is cost savings to acquirers, then in order to justify such collective bargaining, the

benefits of the collective bargaining should be passed-on to the merchants and their

customers.1571 The acquiring side is considered competitive with full pass through rate, so any

reduction in costs would be passed to merchants. However, my proposal is guaranteed to

improve the market even if its consequences would not fully pass downstream to final

consumers, let alone if the cost savings would be passed-on to them.

1569 Commission Decision 92/157/EEC (UK Agricultural Tractor Registration Exchange), paragraph 43, Feb. 17, 1992:

“Uncertainty would lead the firms to compete more strongly than if they knew exactly how much of a response was

necessary to meet competition”. This decision was confirmed in the first instance - Case T-35/92, John Deere Ltd. v.

Comm'n, 1994 E.C.R II-00957, and appeal: Case C-7/95 and C-8/95 John Deere Ltd. v. Comm'n, 1998 E.C.R. I-3111. 1570 C 286/13 P Dole Food v. Comm'n, para. 121 (19.3.15): “[E]xchange of information between competitors is liable to

be incompatible with the competition rules if it reduces or removes the degree of uncertainty as to the operation of the

market in question, with the result that competition between undertakings is restricted”. 1571 Federal Trade Commission and the U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations among

Competitors, para. 3.2 (Apr. 2000): "The mere coordination of decisions on price… is not integration, and cost savings

without integration are not a basis for avoiding per se condemnation. The integration must be of a type that plausibly

would generate procompetitive benefits cognizable under the efficiencies analysis… Such procompetitive benefits may

enhance the participants’ ability or incentives to compete and thus may offset an agreement’s anticompetitive

tendencies";

ABA 1 ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS 469 (7th ed. 2012): "Courts have invalidated joint purchasing arrangements

where the arrangement had no did not (mistake in the original – O.B) produce efficiencies from the cooperative activity

and functioned simply as a buyer's cartel".

For Europe, Guidelines on the Applicability of Article 101 to Horizontal Co-Operation Agreements, O.J C 11/1, para.

201 (Jan. 14, 2011): "If downstream competitors purchase a significant part of their products together, their incentives

for price competition on the selling market or markets may be considerably reduced. If the parties have a significant

degree of market power (which does not necessarily amount to dominance) on the selling market or markets, the lower

purchase prices achieved by the joint purchasing arrangement are likely not to be passed on to consumers"; Ibid paras.

213-14: "Joint purchasing arrangements may lead to a collusive outcome if they facilitate the coordination of the

parties’ behaviour on the selling market. This can be the case if the parties achieve a high degree of commonality of

costs through joint purchasing, provided the parties have market power and the market characteristics are conducive to

coordination.

214.Restrictive effects on competition are more likely if the parties to the joint purchasing arrangement have a

significant proportion of their variable costs in the relevant downstream market in common. This is, for instance, the

case if retailers, which are active in the same relevant retail market or markets, jointly purchase a significant amount of

the products they offer for resale. It may also be the case if competing manufacturers and sellers of a final product

jointly purchase a high proportion of their input together".

For Israel, see Decision Not to Exempt a Joint Negotiation Arrangement between Physician Union and Health Insurers,

Antitrust 501009 (Jul. 13, 2016).

Page 355: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

355

837. First, the setting of the interchange fee is done in cooperation anyway. My proposal should be

compared to the but-for world, in which acquirers (which are also issuers) collectively bargain

for the interchange fee. Thus, I do not propose a collaboration which does not exist regardless

of my proposal. Moreover, currently, not only do acquirers (which are issuers at the same time)

jointly negotiate interchange fees, but acquirers frequently participate in unions or trade

associations.1572 From this point of view, the collaboration I propose does not increase the level

of cooperation or concentration that already exists anyway. The innovation is not to eliminate

an ongoing cooperation but to purify it. The collective bargaining should be clean of the self-

dealing element and the inherent conflict of interest that severely taints the current setting of

the interchange fee. The usual concern from competitors who determine prices is that they

would fix prices to the detriment of their customers. Here, the whole essence of the collective

bargaining is its aim to lower prices, to the benefit of consumers. Cost savings are guaranteed,

because independent acquirers would not agree to pay interchange fee, unless they realize it is

for their benefit.

838. Second, because the acquiring market is considered competitive, it is reasonable to assume that

cost savings would be translated into lower MSF and lower prices, at least in the long run.1573

Cost savings from reduced interchange fee would be passed through to downstream merchants

and their customers. This is exactly the kind of efficiencies recognized in collective bargaining

and joint purchasing.1574 However, the efficiencies are only the side effect of the main idea at

the base of the proposal, which is to solve the distortion that leads to inflated interchange fee,

by purifying its determination process from the self-dealing element.

Even if the acquiring market were not competitive, structural separation would make entrance

easier, and increase the level of competition. Instead of entering two sides (issuing and

acquiring), entrance to the acquiring side is subject to less demands (e.g., lower equity) and is

lower entry barriers. The acquiring market would become more contestable, at least in the long

1572 See e.g., Western States Acquiring Association https://www.westernstatesacquirers.com/index.php ; The UK Card

Association http://www.theukcardsassociation.org.uk/retailer_resources/ ; Australia Payment Clearing Association

http://www.apca.com.au/ 1573 Cf. Guidelines on the Applicability of Article 101 to Horizontal Co-Operation Agreements, O.J C 11/1 §217

(14.1.11): "Efficiency gains 217. Joint purchasing arrangements can give rise to significant efficiency gains. In

particular, they can lead to cost savings such as lower purchase prices or reduced transaction, transportation and storage

costs, thereby facilitating economies of scale. Moreover, joint purchasing arrangements may give rise to qualitative

efficiency gains by leading suppliers to innovate and introduce new or improved products on the markets". 1574 Federal Trade Commission and the U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations among

Competitors, para. 3.36 (Apr. 2000): "competitor collaboration may enable firms to offer goods or services that are

cheaper… such collaboration-generated efficiencies may enhance competition by permitting two or more ineffective

(e.g., high cost) participants to become more effective, lower cost competitors".

Page 356: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

356

run. In Israel, when termination fees (the equivalent of interchange fees in telecommunications)

decreased, new entrants (Golan, Hot-Mobile and several virtual operators) could enter the

market and offer attractive rates to consumers, which they could not offer under a regime of

high termination fees. This, in turn, caused a huge reduction in mobile fees. Similar entrance of

independent acquirers is expected to occur here, if interchange fee is reduced and entrance to

one side would become feasible.

839. Third, there are common remedies to alleviate "traditional" concerns of collective bargaining,

such as collusion and information exchange. For example, each acquirer can be required to

delegate a third-party representative, such as its lawyer or an outer agent, for conducting the

negotiation.1575 The negotiation meetings can be recorded and monitored. Spillover effects can

be minimized, because no sensitive information (except the agreed upon rate of the interchange

fee) would be dispersed among acquirers.1576

840. Fourth, the collective negotiation process should be subject to a detailed exemption, which

should stress the terms and conditions of the negotiation process.1577 Strictly followed, this

would immunize acquirers from antitrust liability. The immunity should be limited to

negotiating the interchange fee. This is even a narrower immunity than the one suggested in the

1575 ABA 1 ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS, 471 (7 ed. 2012): "[A]ntitrust risk is reduced where negotiations are

conducted on behalf of the cooperative by an independent employee or agent who is not an employee of any of the

participants"; Federal Trade Commission and the U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations

among Competitors, para. 3.31(a), para. 3.34(e) (Apr. 2000): "A buying collaboration might use an independent third

party to handle negotiations in which its participants’ input requirements or other competitively sensitive information

could be revealed. In general, it is less likely that the collaboration will facilitate collusion on competitively sensitive

variables if appropriate safeguards governing information sharing are in place";

Guidelines on the Applicability of Article 101 to Horizontal Co-Operation Agreements, id. para. 215 (Jan 14, 2011):

"Spill-over effects from the exchange of commercially sensitive information can, for example, be minimised where data

is collated by a joint purchasing arrangement which does not pass on the information to the parties thereto". For Israel,

see Exemption to Gas Companies (Sonol, Delek, Dor) for Collective Bargaining and Joint Purchase of Jet Fuel

Insurance Policy, Antitrust 500526, (Dec. 24, 2013) 1576 Guidelines on the Applicability of Article 101 to Horizontal Co-Operation Agreements, id. para. 215 (Jan. 14,

2011): "Spill-over effects from the exchange of commercially sensitive information can, for example, be minimised

where data is collated by a joint purchasing arrangement which does not pass on the information to the parties thereto". 1577 Compare to the Bill, H.R. 5546 - Summary, 110th Cong. 2d Sess. sess., (2008)

https://www.congress.gov/bill/110th-congress/house-bill/5546 : "Requires the negotiating parties to file with the

Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice a schedule for negotiations within one month following enactment of

this Act. Directs the Antitrust Division to issue such a schedule, and inform the negotiating parties, if they fail to file a

schedule before the deadline… Requires a representative of the Antitrust Division to attend all negotiation sessions

conducted under the authority of this Act… Requires the negotiating parties to file jointly with the Antitrust Division

any voluntarily negotiated access agreement that affects any market in the United States or elsewhere, including the

various components of the interchange fee, and a description of how access fees that merchants pay are allocated among

financial institutions and how they are spent".

Page 357: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

357

U.S. Bill, which permitted negotiation under immunity of all "terms and rates" of access to

payment systems.1578

841. Fifth, collective bargaining of the interchange fee (only) by independent acquirers, is less

restrictive than joint purchasing arrangements in which competitors not only negotiate, but also

jointly purchase assets. However, even joint purchasing agreements can be recognized as pro-

competitive, if they lead to cost savings which are passed-on downstream.1579 Joint purchase

arrangements are recognized as legal even when they encompass large market shares, in

pharmaceutical,1580 copyrights,1581 and, of course, in the current setting of the interchange fee.

Remembering that "Cooperation is the norm in network industries",1582 joint negotiation of the

interchange fee by independent acquirers, which is a less restrictive arrangement than joint

purchasing, would probably result in lower costs for acquirers. Savings would most probably

diffuse downstream.

13.4. Divestiture As Part Of Regulation

842. Structural separation raises constitutional questions, specifically the question of

proportionality.1583 This chapter deals with these concerns.

1578 Section 2(b) to the Bill, titled "Limited Antitrust Immunity For Negotiation Of Access Rates And Terms To

Covered Electronic Payment Systems", stated: "[N]otwithstanding any provision of the antitrust laws, in negotiating

access rates and terms any providers of a single covered electronic payment system and any merchants may jointly

negotiate and agree upon the rates and terms for access to the covered electronic payment system, including through the

use of common agents that represent either providers of a single covered electronic payment system or merchants on a

non-exclusive basis". 1579 Northwest Wholesale Stationers, Inc. v. Pacific Stationery & Printing Co., 472 U.S. 284, 296 (U.S. 1985); Instant

Delivery Corp. v. City Stores Co., 284 F. Supp. 941 (E.D. Pa. 1968); Federal Trade Commission and the U.S.

Department of Justice, Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations among Competitors, para. 3.31(a) (Apr. 2000): "Buying

Collaborations. Competitor collaborations may involve agreements jointly to purchase necessary inputs. Many such

agreements do not raise antitrust concerns and indeed may be procompetitive. Purchasing collaborations, for example,

may enable participants to centralize ordering, to combine warehousing or distribution functions more efficiently, or to

achieve other efficiencies". 1580 N. Jackson Pharm., Inc. v. Caremark RX, Inc. 385 F. Supp. 2d 740 (N.D. 2005); see also Statements of Antitrust

Enforcement Policy in Health Care, Issued by the U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission,

statement #7 (August 1996). For a joint purchasing arrangement of medical equipment between hospitals in Israel, see

Sarel Logistics Sollutions and Products for Advanced Medicine Ltd. http://www.sarel.co.il/eng/ 1581 For U.S., see Broadcast Music v. CBS, 441 U.S. 1, 23 (1979). In Israel - AT 3574/00 Music Federation v.

Antitrust General Director (29.4.04). 1582 ABA 1 ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS 472 (7 ed. 2012). 1583 For expansion see HCJ 1661/05 Local Council Hof Aza v the Knesset, 59(2) 481, (2005); SCL 1333/02 Local

Zoning Committee v Judith Horoviz, 58(6) 289, (2004).

Page 358: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

358

Regulation often involves structural reforms. A salient example is divestitures that occurred in

electricity and telecommunication networks.1584 Divestiture was used in numerous occasions to

reorganize a market that was controlled by incumbent monopolies, even though the incumbent

has not been engaged in unlawful trade practices.1585 In many countries, networks that were

operated by incumbent monopolies were forced to unbundle and separate their activities.1586

The terminology for divestiture of incumbents through regulatory reforms is sometimes treated

in literature as a "regulatory taking".1587

843. The power to obligate divestiture, as part of regulatory reforms, stems from the sovereign

authority of the state to regulate economic activities, especially in vital areas.1588 There is a

consensus in the literature that the state may force structural changes in regulated industries as

part of reforms it conducts. The main conflict in literature regards the extent of compensation.

Sidak & Spulber compared structural reforms, in which firms are deprived of their assets, to

takings. They argued for generous compensation.1589 The approach of most commentators is

1584 Cf. Lina Rainiene, Functional and Structural Separation Models, TAIEX Workshop on Regulatory Framework,

Belgrade, at 27-39 (April 2010); David Havyatt , Why Vertical Structural Separation is in the Interests of Incumbent

Telcos, and Why they don’t See it, http://www.havyatt.com.au/docs/wps/TJA1.pdf . 1585 United States v. AT&T Co. 552 F. Supp. 131 (D.D.C. 1982); Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1 (1911);

United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d 416, 429 (2d Cir. N.Y. 1945): “In several decisions the Supreme

Court has decreed the dissolution of such combinations, although they had engaged in no unlawful trade

practices”; United States v. E. I. Du Pont De Nemours & Co. 366 U.S. 316, 329-31 (1961): “Divestiture or dissolution

has traditionally been the remedy for Sherman Act violations whose heart is intercorporate combination and control

Divestiture has been called the most important of antitrust remedies. It is simple, relatively easy to administer, and

sure". P. E. AREEDA, III ANTITRUST LAW, 147; United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 577 (U.S. 1966):

“adequate relief in a monopolization case should put an end to the combination and deprive the defendants of any of the

benefits of the illegal conduct, and break up or render impotent the monopoly power found to be in violation of the

Act". For Europe see Reg. (EC) no 1/2003 on the Implementation of the Rules on Competition Laid Down in Articles

81 and 82 of the Treaty, Art. 7 (Dec. 16, 2002). 1586J. GREGORY SIDAK & DANIEL F. SPULBER, DEREGULATORY TAKINGS AND THE REGULATORY CONTRACT, 47 (1998):

"Deregulation of networks industries often is accompanied by regulatory policies requiring the incumbent utility to

provide "open access" to its transmission facilities. Deregulation in electricity and communication has been

accompanied by regulations aimed at vertical divestiture or separation of vertically integrated activities of

incumbent utilities." 1587Susan Rose-Ackerman & Jim Rossi, Disentangling Deregulatory Takings, 86 VIR. L. REV. 1435, 1438 (2000):

"Any commercial enterprise is subject to changes in the state's tax and regulatory laws, but these risks loom especially

large for infrastructure industries.";

Daniel F. Spulber & Christopher F. Yoo, Antitrust, the Internet, and the Economics of Networks, at 23 (Faculty

Scholarship Series. Paper 583, 2013): "One of the most common remedies sought during antitrust litigation in

network industries is structural separation. For example, the 1956 consent decree settling the second major case

against AT&T abandoned the government’s initial request for divestiture of AT&T’s equipment subsidiary, opting

instead to restrict AT&T to furnishing common carrier communications services. The 1982 court order that broke up

AT&T required that the local telephone services that remained monopolized be structurally separated from the portions

of the business in which competition had become possible: long distance, telephone equipment, and “information

services” that combined transmission with data processing. More recently, the federal government initially asked the

court hearing the case against Microsoft to require the company to spin off its applications businesses into a separate

subsidiary";

SHARON YADIN, REGULATION: ADMINISTRATIVE LAW IN THE AGE OF REGULATORY CONTRACTS (2016). 1588 See e.g., Verizon Communs., Inc. v. FCC, 535 U.S. 467 (2002). 1589 J. GREGORY SIDAK & DANIEL F. SPULBER, DEREGULATORY TAKINGS AND THE REGULATORY CONTRACT (1998)

Page 359: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

359

less generous. The main argument is that structural changes, which are actually a by-product of

removing structural barriers to competition, are not an action that the public should pay for.1590

This argument seems to be even more valid when the divestiture is aimed in breaking a

restrictive arrangement, as the right to be a party to a restrictive arrangement, let alone price-

fixing, is not a vested right, which deserves compensation when taken.1591

From this point of view, my proposal is much less dramatic than it may initially seem. The

controversial question of compensation, which accompanies regulatory reforms that involve

takings, does not arise in this case. My proposal is not a "taking" of the acquiring business. It

is ending a price fixing restrictive arrangement, which the parties have no vested right to be part

of in the first place. Thus, the setup for structural separation is more favorable from the outset

than in other dissolutions in which the deprived incumbent did not commit any wrong.

844. Previous divestitures can be useful precedents. In Israel, a divestiture that was also meant to

eliminate inherent conflict of interests, occurred in 2005. The Bachar Reform ordered the

divestiture of provident funds from the banks that owned them. Banks operated in multiple

roles, and were subject to inherent conflict of interest.1592 The main concern was that banks use

their customers' funds for channels of investment they had interest in, even if those were less

attractive than competing channels of investment. However, possession of provident funds by

banks does not raise such grave conflict of interest, and is not per-se illegal. First, the mere

possession of provident fund is not an illegal price fixing. Second, the purported conflict of

interest the Bachar committee dealt with, could be solved with less drastic measures, e.g.,

forbidding or limiting banks from investing in channels they have interest in.

Third, if banks invest in inferior channels, competition could correct this bias. The Bachar

reform was aimed to stop banks' priority in channels they had interest in. But if investments of

banks were biased towards unprofitable (own) investment channels, interbank competition

could strengthen, and correct this inherent conflict of interest. This cannot be said on the

1590 __________ Herbert Hovenkamp, The Taking Clause and Improvident Regulatory Bargains, 108 YALE L.J. 801

(1999); Oliver E. Williamson, Deregulatory Takings and Breach of the Regulatory Contract: Some Precautions, 71 N.

Y.U. L. REV. 1007 (1996); Jim Rossi, The Irony of Deregulatory Takings, 197 TEX. L. REV. 77 (1998). 1591 AT 3276/99 Arutzei Zahav v. Association of Movie Directors, Sec. 36, (July 6, 2000); AT 3574/00 Music

Federation v. Antitrust General Director, Sec. 100 (Apr. 29, 2004); AT 19545-04-10 Shovarei Bar v. Antitrust General

Director, sec. 49 (Jan. 24, 2012) (no person has a vested right to be a party to a restrictive arrangement). 1592 INTER-MINISTERIAL COMMITTEE REPORT (BACHAR REPORT), STRUCTURAL REFORM IN THE CAPITAL MARKET,

Executive Summary, at 5 (Sept. 2004):" The broad range of activities in which Israel's banks engage, creates material

conflicts of interest between their own business interests and their customers’ interests."; id. at 9: "Against the

background of concentration and conflicts of interest, we propose that banks will not be permitted to hold any interest at

all in a company that manages a provident or mutual fund"; Law for Advancement of Competition and Reduction of

Concentration and Conflicts of Interests in the Capital Markets in Israel (2005).

Page 360: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

360

interchange fee. No self-correcting mechanism can fix the inherent conflict of interest, which

results from issuers and acquirers being the same entities. To the contrary, as explained in

chapter 6.6 above, competition, which is usually a market self-correcting mechanism, does not

work well in two-sided markets such as payment cards. As competition intensifies, it inflates

and not reduces the interchange fee, which serves as a source for profits and wasteful

competition. Thus, the conclusions of the Bachar Reform, which justified divestiture in the

banking sector, hold even more with respect to my proposal.

845. Another divestiture in the Israeli market occurred, when Amendment 11 to the Banking Law

(Licensing) 1981 implemented the Brodet Report, and prohibited banks to possess more than

20% in industrial corporation. This reform forced banks to sell their holdings in major

corporations.1593

In 2013, the Law for Advancement of Competition and Reduction in Concentration was

enacted.1594 This law went even further, in order to implement recommendations of a

governmental committee appointed to offer steps to increase the competitiveness of the Israeli

market.1595 The Law prohibited pyramidal holdings of more than two levels in public

companies.1596 This was intended to prevent leveraged control over complicated structures of

companies through relatively minor investment.1597 In addition the law mandated structural

separation between significant financial and non-financial firms.1598 This structural separation

was also explained in the inherent conflict of interest of single economic units, which included

financial and non-financial entities, to lend or to invest in the same economic unit.1599 However,

the same arguments which were raised against the divestiture of the Bachar reform are valid

here. The conflict of interest is not inherent, and it could potentially be solved through the

"invisible hand" of competition or by less restrictive means than divestiture. Thus, my proposal

is certainly proportional when compared to the divestiture of the Law for Advancement of

Competition and Reduction in Concentration.

1593 Proposal for Banking Law (Licensing) 1981 (Amendment 11), Bills 2352, at 662, 663, 667 (March 11, 1996);

Banking Law (Licensing), Sec. 11, (1981). 1594 Law for Advancement of Competition and Reduction in Concentration (2013). 1595 Proposal for a Law for Advancement of Competition and Reduction in Concentration, Government Bills 706, 1084

(Jul. 9, 2012); COMMITTEE ON INCREASING COMPETITIVENESS IN THE ECONOMY [HAVAADA LEHAGBARAT

HATAHARUTIUT BAMESHEK] FINAL REPORT (2012)

http://mof.gov.il/Committees/PreviouslyCommittees/Pages/CompetitivenessCommittee.aspx . 1596 Law for Advancement of Competition and Reduction in Concentration, Sec. 21 (2013). 1597 Committee on Increasing Competitiveness in the Economy, supra note 1595, at 10. 1598 Law for Advancement of Competition and Reduction in Concentration, Chapter D (2013). 1599 COMMITTEE ON INCREASING COMPETITIVENESS IN THE ECONOMY, DRAFT RECOMMENDATIONS at 13-14, 20 (2011).

Page 361: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

361

846. Separation of financial and non-financial holding took place in other countries. The arguments

were different from the reasoning in Israel. The economic crisis of 2008 caused numerous

financial institutions to collapse. Huge state aid and guarantees were required to stabilize the

financial markets. Desire to limit the effects of banks' breakdown on the economy, i.e., the "too

big to fail" narrative, was the main reasoning for structural separation.1600

In United Kingdom, the Vickers Report recommended "ring fencing" i.e., separation of banking

activities, especially between retail and investment activities.1601 In the U.S., Section 619 of the

Dodd–Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, 2010 added a new section 13

to the Bank Holding Company Act, commonly referred to as the ‘Volcker Rule’. This rule

prohibited banking entities from engaging in proprietary trading and from having certain

relationships with a hedge fund or private equity fund.1602 Prior to the Volcker Rule, banks

invested heavily in these areas.

In the E.U., the Liikanen report recommended structural reforms to strengthen the financial

stability of the banking sector. The first recommendation was separation of proprietary trading

and other high-risk trading from commercial banks.1603 Another report for the G20 leaders also

concluded that separation of financial activities through prohibitions such as ‘ring-fencing’

promote financial stability by reducing systemic risks.1604 These structural separations were

more drastic than my proposal.

1600 Adrian Blundell-Wignall, Paul Atkinson & Caroline Roulet, Bank Business Models and the Separation Issue, 2

OECD J. FIN. MARKET TRENDS, at 9 (2013): "Following the 2008 crisis, the OECD Secretariat was amongst the first to

propose separation as necessary for the future stability of the financial system. It proposes a nonoperating holding

company (NOHC) structure for banks that require separation". 1601 INDEPENDENT COMMISSION ON BANKING FINAL REPORT RECOMMENDATIONS (VICKERS REPORT), at 9 (Sept. 2011):

"A number of UK banks combine domestic retail services with global wholesale and investment banking operations.

Both sets of activities are economically valuable while both also entail risks – for example, relating to residential

property values in the case of retail banking. Their unstructured combination does, however, give rise to public policy

concerns, which structural reform proposals – notably forms of separation between retail banking and

wholesale/investment banking – seek to address". For explanation on ring fencing, id. at 11. 1602 Pub. L. No. 111-203; Dodd–Frank Act § 619; 12 U.S.C. § 1851; see also STUDY & RECOMMENDATIONS ON

PROHIBITIONS ON PROPRIETARY TRADING & CERTAIN RELATIONSHIPS WITH HEDGE FUNDS & PRIVATE EQUITY FUNDS;

FINANCIAL STABILITY OVERSIGHT COUNCIL (January 2011). 1603 HIGH-LEVEL EXPERT GROUP ON REFORMING THE STRUCTURE OF THE EU BANKING SECTOR (LIIKANEN REPORT), at

III (Oct. 2012): " [P]roprietary trading and other significant trading activities should be assigned to a separate legal

entity if the activities to be separated amount to a significant share of a bank's business. This would ensure that trading

activities beyond the threshold are carried out on a stand-alone basis and separate from the deposit bank. As a

consequence, deposits, and the explicit and implicit guarantee they carry, would no longer directly support risky trading

activities". Cf. Proposal for a Regulation Of The European Parliament And Of The Council on Structural Measures

Improving the Resilience of EU Credit Institutions COM/2014/043 Final - 2014/0020 (COD), (2014). 1604 STRUCTURAL BANKING REFORMS CROSS-BORDER CONSISTENCIES AND GLOBAL FINANCIAL STABILITY

IMPLICATIONS REPORT TO G20 LEADERS FOR THE NOVEMBER 2014 SUMMIT FINANCIAL STABILITY BOARD, 1-2 (Oct. 27,

2014).

Page 362: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

362

Entities that hold and operate financial and non-financial assets, or financial entities which

invest their own money (nostro) in considerably risky activities, do not raise inherent

competitive concerns, such as entities that hold and operate issuing and acquiring activities.

Stability issues could be solved with less drastic remedies than structural separation, such as

limitations on holdings and limitations on financial risk-ratios. If stability concerns, which are

not inherent, justify structural separation, then inherent conflict of interest, which raises

undoubted concerns of general price increase in the market,1605 should in my view justify

structural separation.

847. Another support for my proposal can be found at the recent report, dated September 2016, of

the Committee for Enhancement of Competition in Common Banking & Financial Services

(Shtrum Committee). The main recommendation of this committee was to divest Leumi-Card

and Isracard from their controlling banks (Leumi & Poalim respectively). The Shtrum

Committee actually adopted previous proposals to divest payment card companies from their

controlling banks.1606 The purpose of Shtrum's Committee divestiture proposal was to induce

entrance of new competitors, the buyers of these firms, to the financial market. The report did

not address constitutional considerations. The report just noted in one paragraph, without

elaboration, that its recommendation to divest payment card firms from their controlling banks

is proportional.1607 However, the desire to elaborate competition in the banking sector does not

imply that the incumbents (Leumi and Hapoalim banks in this case) did anything wrong. In

fact, they did not breach any law neither were they parties to a restrictive arrangement.

Nevertheless, the Shtrum Committee, in line with previous proposals, recommended divestiture

of the payment card companies from their parent banks. These recommendations were partly

anchored into section 11b of the Banking Law (Licensing), amendment 23 (2017). The

amendment determines that big banks, i.e., Leumi and Hapoalim, would not control firms

engaged in issuing or acquiring of payment cards. In comparison to these recommendations my

proposal is even more proportional and a fortiori less drastic.

Another advantage of separating acquirers from issuers and not payment card companies from

their controlling banks is that even if separated from banks, acquirers who are also issuers would

remain in inherent conflict of interest that would cause them to agree to pay high interchange

1605 Supra ch. 10.1 (interchange fee raises competitive concerns of market wide price increase). 1606 For prior Bills aiming for this divestiture see supra ¶ 558. 1607 COMMITTEE FOR ENHANCEMENT OF COMPETITION IN COMMON BANKING & FINANCIAL SERVICES (SHTRUM

COMMITTEE) FINAL REPORT, at 56 (Sep 1, 2016).

Page 363: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

363

fee to themselves as issuers. My suggestion aims at preventing this inherent conflict of interest,

which would remain even if LeumiCard and Isracard would be divested from Leumi and

Hapoalim banks respectively. My proposal applies whether payment card firms would become

separated from their controlling banks, or not.

13.5. Divestiture as an antitrust remedy

848. Divestiture might indeed be an important part of structural reforms. Divestiture is one of the

most important antitrust remedies.1608 Divestiture is the "most drastic, but most effective"

antitrust remedy.1609 Mergers are a primary arena in which divestitures occur.1610 It is worthy

to analyze my proposal also considering this traditional remedy.

849. Divestiture is a remedy aimed to restore or preserve competition.1611 Merger remedy rules that

include divestiture are well recognized and commonly used.1612 When a merger eliminates a

competitor, divestiture seeks to restore the lost competitor and preserve the competitiveness of

1608 Schine Chain Theatres, Inc. v. United States, 334 U.S. 110, 128-129 (U.S. 1948): "Divestiture or dissolution must

take account of the present and future conditions in the particular industry as well as past violations. It serves several

functions: (1) It puts an end to the combination or conspiracy when that is itself the violation. (2) It deprives the

antitrust defendants of the benefits of their conspiracy. [*129] (3) It is designed to break up or render impotent the

monopoly power which violates the Act. See United States v. Crescent Amusement Co., supra, pp. 188-190; United

States v. Griffith, ante, p. 100.";

See also AT 103/09 Antitrust General Director v. Tnuva (Dec. 28, 2009) (Consent Decree to a dissolution of a milk

plant, Machlavot Ramat Hagolan, held by major competitors). 1609 United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 366 U.S. 316, 326. 1610 IVO VAN BAEL & JEAN-FRANCOIS BELLIS, COMPETITION LAW OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY 779 (5th ed. 2010):

"[I]n the vast majority of [merger – O.B] cases, competition concerns have been addressed by means of divestment". 1611 DOJ Antitrust Division Policy Guide To Merger Remedies, at 3 (June 2011);

United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 366 U.S. 316, 326 (U.S. 1961): "The key to the whole question of an

antitrust remedy is of course the discovery of measures effective to restore competition";

Opinion 2/11: Guidelines on Remedies to Mergers that Raise Concerns of Significant Harm to Competition, Antitrust

5001804, at 7 (July 18, 2011);

DOJ Antitrust Division Policy Guide to Merger Remedies, at 7 (Jun. 2011): "The goal of a divestiture is to ensure that

the purchaser possesses both the means and the incentive to effectively preserve competition";

Europe, Commission Notice On Remedies Acceptable Under Council Regulation, para. 22: "Where a proposed

concentration threatens to significantly impede effective competition the most effective way to maintain effective

competition, apart from prohibition, is to create the conditions for the emergence of a new competitive entity".

British Merger Remedies: Competition Commission Guidelines, para. 2.5;

Canadian Merger Remedies para 12(i): "Divestitures seek to: (i) preserve competition through the sale of asset(s) to a

new market participant";

French Merger Guideline, para. 528: "When seeking adequate remedies, the Autorité de la concurrence gives priority to

structural remedies that are intended to preserve effective competition through divestitures of activities or of certain

assets to an appropriate buyer that is likely to exert actual competitive constraint, or through the elimination of capitalist

ties between competitors". 1612 U.S. DOJ Policy Guide To Merger Remedies (June 2011); British Competition Commission, Merger Remedies:

Competition Commission Guidelines, November 2008; Europe, Commission Notice On Remedies Acceptable Under

Council Regulation (Ec) No 139/2004 And Under Commission Regulation (Ec) No 802/2004 (2008/C 267/01);

Australian Competition And Consumer Commission, Merger Guidelines (Nov. 2008); France, Autorite de la

concurrence, Merger Control Guidelines; Canada Competition Bureau, Information Bulletin On Merger Remedies In

Canada (Sept. 22, 2006).

Page 364: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

364

the market.1613 To see that my proposal is in line with merger remedies, the main principles of

divestiture in the merger remedies should be recalled:

850. First, to be aligned with constitutional principles, divestiture must address the competitive

concern and be proportionate.1614 As explained in the previous part, this condition is satisfied

in our case. In comparison to the distortions the interchange fee creates, especially the concern

for price increase and the inherent conflict of interest, my proposal is proportional and

constitutional. Moreover, the divestiture in our context is aimed to correct consequences of

horizontal price fixing between competitors, which is a per-se violation, and not merely a

merger, which is not prohibited per-se. Justification for divestiture in our context, is even

stronger than in the merger context.

851. Second, as a structural remedy, divestiture is preferable to behavioral remedies. The latter

requires ongoing supervision and is not as effective as structural remedies.1615 Divestiture, in

principal, does not require ongoing monitoring.1616 Indeed divestiture would end the

interchange fee from being a restrictive arrangement. Only the collective bargaining would

remain to be supervised, but as explained, this is a relatively minor concern.

852. Third, divested assets should include all parts of a viable business. An effective divestiture

must include all the assets, physical and intangible, necessary for the purchaser to compete

1613 British Merger Remedies: Competition Commission Guidelines, paras. 2.5 (Nov. 2008); see also id., 3.1: "[A]

divestiture seeks to remedy an SLC [substantial lessening of competition – O.B] by either creating a new source of

competition through disposal of a business or set of assets to a new market participant". 1614 C-202/06 P Cementbouw Handel & Industrie BV v Commission, para. 54 (Dec. 18, 2007): "[W]hen reviewing the

proportionality of conditions or obligations which the Commission may... impose on the parties to a concentration…

those conditions and those obligations are proportionate to and would entirely eliminate the competition problem that

has been identified".

See also IAA Merger Remedies Guideline, para 15;

British Merger Remedies: Competition Commission Guidelines, para. 1.9 (Nov. 2008): "In order to be reasonable and

proportionate the CC will seek to select the least costly remedy, or package of remedies, that it considers will be

effective. If the CC is choosing between two remedies which it considers will be equally effective, it will select the

remedy that imposes the least cost or that is least restrictive. The CC will seek to ensure, as outlined in paragraph 1.12,

that no remedy is disproportionate in relation to the SLC and its adverse effects.";

New Zealand Merger guidelines, Appendix 3 at para. 17 (Nov. 2008): "[T]he divestiture remedy should be

proportionate to the competition concerns or detriments and be effective in restoring or maintaining competition". 1615 British Merger Remedies: Competition Commission Guidelines, at 6 (Nov. 2008): "Restoring this process of rivalry

through remedies that re-establish the structure of the market expected in the absence of the merger (so-called structural

remedies such as divestitures) should be expected to address the adverse effects at source. Such remedies are normally

preferable to measures that seek to regulate the ongoing behaviour of the relevant parties (so-called behavioural

remedies such as price caps, supply commitments or restrictions on use of long term contracts) as these are unlikely to

deal with an SLC and its adverse effects as comprehensively as structural remedies and may result in distortions

compared with a competitive market outcome". 1616 British Merger guidelines, para. 2.6: "Divestitures will generally not require detailed monitoring following

implementation".

Page 365: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

365

effectively.1617 Divestiture is applicable when the divested asset is viable as an independent

business.1618 Acquiring is definitely a stand-alone, viable and profitable business.1619 Acquiring

activities that are to be separated are relatively easy to identify. The rights and liabilities of

acquirers towards merchants are distinguished from rights and liabilities of issuers towards

cardholders. Assets of acquirers are relatively easy to allocate to a purchaser as an ongoing

business. Creating independent acquirers, preserves the competitive ability of acquirers,

without the distortion that causes acquirers to agree to pay high interchange fees to themselves

in their role as issuers.

In fact, my proposal lacks divestiture's difficulty known as "composition risks", which is the

concern, that the scope of the divestiture package may not be appropriately configured to allow

a suitable purchaser to operate effectively.1620 Acquiring is a stand-alone, identified, viable and

profitable business.

1617 DOJ Antitrust Division Policy Guide to Merger Remedies, at 7 (Jun. 2011): "First and foremost, to ensure an

effective structural remedy, any divestiture must include all the assets, physical and intangible, necessary for the

purchaser to compete effectively… The goal of a divestiture is to ensure that the purchaser possesses both the means

and the incentive to effectively preserve competition"; see also id. at 8: "The divestiture assets must be substantial

enough to enable the purchaser to effectively preserve competition… the Division often will insist on the divestiture of

an existing business entity that already has demonstrated its ability to compete in the relevant market".

European Commission Notice on Remedies Acceptable Under Council Regulation (EC), para. 23: "The divested

activities must consist of a viable business that, if operated by a suitable purchaser, can compete effectively"; id. para

30: "The business to be divested has to be viable as such" ¶ 35: "[N]ormally the divestiture of an existing viable stand-

alone business is required";

British Merger guidelines, paras. 3.6-3.9:" In identifying a divestiture package, the CC will take, as its starting point,

divestiture of all or part of the acquired business… the CC will normally seek to identify the smallest viable, stand-

alone business that can compete successfully on an ongoing basis and that includes all the relevant operations pertinent

to the area of competitive overlap… The CC will generally prefer divestiture of an existing business that can compete

effectively on a stand-alone basis independently of the merger parties";

Canada Merger Remedies, para 15: "A divestiture of a standalone operating business(es) means that the whole of one of

the merging parties’ overlapping businesses is to be divested. This includes all necessary management, personnel,

manufacturing and distribution facilities, retail locations, individual products or product lines, intellectual property (e.g.

including patents or brands), administrative functions, supply arrangements, customer contracts, government and

regulatory approvals, leases, and other components of an operating business";

French Merger Guideline para. 528: "For a divestiture to be able to effectively remedy anticompetitive effects, it is

indispensable that the divested activity should be viable and competitive". 1618 IVO VAN BAEL & JEAN-FRANCOIS BELLIS, COMPETITION LAW OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY 778 (5th ed. 2010):

"[D]ivested activities must consist of a viable business that can compete effectively";

Opinion 2/11: Guidelines on Remedies to Mergers that Raise Concerns of Significant Harm to Competition, Antitrust

5001804, at 8 (Jul. 18, 2011); DOJ Antitrust Division Policy Guide to Merger Remedies, at 11-12 (Jun. 2011). 1619 RESERVE BANK OF AUSTRALIA, REFORM OF CREDIT CARD SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA: A CONSULTATION DOCUMENT,

sec. 4.2 (December 2001): "Credit card issuing and acquiring are currently very profitable activities in Australia…

provision of credit card services generates revenues well above average costs, especially for financial institutions which

are both significant card issuers and acquirers. The margins are particularly wide in credit card acquiring (Table 4.1).";

IAA, FINAL REPORT ON ENHANCEMENT OF COMPETITION IN PAYMENT CARDS, at 6-7, Antitrust 500680 (Sept. 8, 2014).

See also supra ¶¶ 60, 97, 574, supra note 788. 1620 New Zealand merger Guidelines at Appendix 3 p. 64: "Each of the key aspects of the divestiture may be susceptible

to a number of risks such as: • composition risks—the scope of the divestiture package may not be appropriately

configured (or sufficiently wide, say, in product range) to attract a suitable purchaser or allow a suitable purchaser to

operate effectively".

Page 366: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

366

853. Fourth, the purchaser is required to be independent of and unconnected to the parties.1621

Purchasers of divested assets should not be linked or associated to sellers, as such links may

compromise purchaser’s ability to compete, or soften competition between the buyer and the

seller.1622 Indeed, this is the crux of my proposal. Divested assets should be sold to an

independent purchaser who would operate the acquiring business, and shall not be connected

in any way to the selling side.

854. Fifth, the customary condition in the guidelines is that divested assets would be sold only to

capable purchasers with appropriate financial resources and expertise.1623 This goes without

saying in my proposal. Acquiring is a financial activity that requires a license under the Banking

Law. Independent acquirers must be entities with financial strength and verified corporate

governance. Indeed, independent acquirers are deemed to stand up to any merger guidelines

capability demands.

1621 European Commission Notice on Remedies Acceptable Under Council Regulation (EC), paras. 47- 48: "The

intended effect of the divestiture will only be achieved if and once the business is transferred to a suitable purchaser in

whose hands it will become an active competitive force in the market... 48. The standard purchaser requirements are the

following: — the purchaser is required to be independent of and unconnected to the parties".

Opinion 2/11: Guidelines on Remedies to Mergers that Raise Concerns of Significant Harm to Competition, Antitrust

5001804, para 22 (July 18, 2011);

DOJ Antitrust Division Policy Guide to Merger Remedies, at 28 (Jun. 2011);

British Merger Remedies: Competition Commission Guidelines, para. 3.15 (Nov. 2008): "The identity and capability of

a purchaser will be of major importance in ensuring the success of a divestiture remedy... The CC will wish to satisfy

itself that a prospective purchaser is independent of the merger parties… (a) Independence—The purchaser should have

no significant connection to the merger parties that may compromise the purchaser’s incentives to compete… for

example, an equity interest, shared directors, reciprocal trading relationships or continuing financial assistance".

Australian ACCC Merger Guidelines, Appendix 3, at 64 (2008): "As a general rule, divestiture undertakings aim to

ensure that the ultimate purchaser of the divestiture assets will be a viable, long-term, independent and effective

competitor… purchasers should be independent of the merged firm and possess the necessary expertise, experience and

resources to be an effective long-term competitor in the market";

Canada, Competition Bureau, Information Bulletin on Merger Remedies in Canada, para. 13 (Sept. 22, 2006): "[T]he

buyer must be independent and have both the ability and intention to be an effective competitor in the relevant

market(s)."; id. para. 58: "[T]he buyer must be independent (i.e., at arm’s length) from the vendor";

New Zealand, Commerce Commission, Mergers and Acquisitions: Divestment Remedies Guidelines, para 4.19 (Jun.

2010): "Examples of attributes that may make a buyer acceptable are: it is independent of the merged entity". 1622 British Merger Guidelines, para. 3.18: A purchaser should not have continuing links with the merger

parties after divestiture that may compromise the purchaser’s incentives to compete with these parties. 1623 British Merger Guidelines para. 3.15(b): "Capability—The purchaser must have access to appropriate financial

resources, expertise and assets to enable the divested business to be an effective competitor in the market. This access

should be sufficient to enable the divestiture package to continue to develop as an effective competitor";

Canada Merger Remedies: "An acceptable buyer must have both the ability and incentive to compete, so that

competition will be preserved in the relevant market(s). The buyer must operate independently of the merged entity in

all aspects of competition, even if various means of support (e.g. supply arrangements and other forms of technical

assistance) are part of the remedy package for a transitional period of time";

French Merger Guideline para. 535: "A divestiture is only efficient if the buyer is suitable, i.e. if: the buyer is

independent of the parties, in capitalistic as well as in contractual terms; it must have the adequate competence and

financial capacity in order to develop the activity and efficiently compete with the merging parties";

Page 367: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

367

855. Sixth, "purchaser risk", which is the risk that: "a suitable purchaser may not be available",1624

and which is a regular concern in divestitures, would probably not arise here. Independent

entities that currently operate back-office acquiring are perfect candidates to be acquirers. They

have the financial strength, the technology, the know-how and the proper corporate governance.

In fact, current back-office factoring and processing firms, such as Gama, already applied for

an acquiring license.1625 Other international firms that currently operate back-office acquiring,

such as Gemalto, Verifone, Credorax, TSYS1626 and more, are also perfect candidates to

become independent acquirers.

The acquiring side is also attractive to credit suppliers, as it can easily be expanded for loans to

merchants. Thus, purchasing acquiring activity might be attractive for smaller banks, which are

not involved in issuing (such as Jerusalem or Igud banks in Israel), and for other financial

entities such as pension funds or insurance companies. Those entities might want to expand

their activities and become acquirers, alone or in a joint venture with current back-office

acquirers. Thus, in my view, purchaser risks do not arise.

856. Seventh, another difficulty of divestiture in merger context, which does not arise here, is known

as "asset risk". This concern is that the competitive capability of a divestiture package may

deteriorate significantly before completion of a divestment.1627 The reason this concern does

not arise here is pinned to the unique features of two-sided markets. Because each transaction

requires issuer and acquirer, harm to the acquiring (or issuing) side before selling it would first

and foremost damage the issuing (or acquiring) sellers. Any deterioration of one side would

reflect in worsening the other side and is equivalent to a deterioration of the network as a whole.

857. As with post-merger divestitures, the buyer should have full access to infrastructures. Presently,

acquirers have full access to the payment card infrastructure. This must remain with

independent acquirers. Otherwise, incumbent issuers can use the necessity of access to

1624 NIGEL PARR ET AL., UK MERGER CONTROL: LAW AND PRACTICE §9.104 (2nd ed. 2005): "The second risk factor

highlighted by the commission is that a suitable purchaser for the business to be divested may not be available". See

also New Zealand merger Guidelines, Appendix 3 at 64. 1625 Tomer Varon, Gama on its Way to Become Fourth Competitor in the Credit Market, Calcalist (Aug. 8, 2015). 1626 See their websites for description of their acquiring capabilities: http://www.gemalto.com/ ;

http://www.verifone.com/ ; https://www.credorax.com/ ; http://tsys.com/solutions-services/acquiring-services/ . 1627 British Merger Guidelines para. 3.3(c): "Asset risks—these are risks that the competitive capability of a divestiture

package will deteriorate before completion of divestiture, for example through loss of customers or key members of

staff". See also New Zealand merger Guidelines, Appendix 3 at 64.

Page 368: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

368

infrastructure (in which they sometimes control, like in Israel via SHVA and MASAV) as an

entry barrier.1628

13.6. Final remarks

858. Interchange fee that would be determined by independent acquirers, would eliminate the self-

dealing mechanism that distorts its setting. Such an interchange fee would not for itself be a

restrictive arrangement. Given the default of zero, the probable result is that the interchange fee

would be close to the optimal interchange fee from the consumer welfare standard, i.e., the

lowest fee that will maximize the volume of efficient transactions.1629 If acquirers would not

have any ownership interest on the issuing side, they would not agree to pay any interchange

fee that is used to finance issuers’ profits (cozy cartels) or “wasteful competition”.1630

859. The direct effect of lowering the interchange fee reflects significant cost savings and a possible

small but market-wide price reduction of final goods. In Israel, every 0.1% decrease in

interchange fees is tantamount to more than NIS 260 million annual savings for merchants.1631

Merchants who operate in competitive markets are likely to pass through their savings to final

prices, at least in the long run. However, even in the absence of significant pass through, as

Rochet & Tirole explain, from allocative efficiency point of view, it is more efficient if cost-

savings stay with merchants than delivered to issuers.1632 Indeed, the consumer welfare standard

is comprised of merchants and consumers (and not issuers and acquirers). The consumer

welfare standard is satisfied if the surplus of merchants expands, even with no pass through to

final prices, as merchants are the consumers, let alone if competitive constraints compel pass

through to final prices of goods.1633

860. The cost savings of not having to monitor and scrutinize the interchange fee level are

substantial. Enormous resources are invested today by regulators, such as Courts, Tribunals,

1628 British Merger Guidelines para. 3.18: "[P]urchasers may require access to key inputs or services at appropriate

terms from the merger parties". 1629 Supra ch. 6.9.4 (Conumer Welfare Optimal Interchange Fee). 1630 Supra ¶ 299 (Competition for cardholders might yield lower cardholder fees and higher MSF than under a

monopoly, a phenomenon that is sometimes referred to as "wasteful competition"); ¶ 479 (Rochet & Tirole call issuers'

profits, which are derived from interchange fees, “cozy cartel”); ¶ 301, ¶ 480 notes 544, 814, 826 (the phenomenon in

which issuers artificially inflate their costs to justify high interchange fee is called “wasteful competition"), ¶ 732, ¶ 788

(Zero interchange fees would have a positive effect by reducing "wasteful competition" (i.e., redundant rewards) or

"cozy cartels" (using the interchange fee as a disguise for profits)). 1631 Supra ¶ 89. 1632 Supra ¶ 407 (Consumers of the payment card networks, i.e., merchants and customers, have greater utility from

money than ultimate beneficiaries of the supply side i.e., the shareholders of the issuers and the acquirers. Thus,

expanding consumer surplus contributes greater value to social welfare, even if it is at the expense of producer surplus). 1633 Supra ch. 6.9.4 (Consumer Welfare Optimal Interchange Fee)

Page 369: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

369

competition authorities and central banks, in supervising the levels of the interchange fees.

Despite the enormous efforts and resources, current regulation which is aimed at capping the

interchange fee, mostly cost-base caps, yields poor results.1634 Significant portion of those costs

might be substantially reduced. Considering the huge profit margins of issuers, and their

growing channels of direct income from interest and cardholder fees, my suggestion, even if

implemented, would not have a substantial effect on their stability. Both the acquiring and the

issuing sides would probably remain highly profitable.1635 However, as with any reform,

monitoring the stability of the payment card networks and their participants after the divestiture

is warranted.

14. Novelty # 2 Profit Limitation

861. My first innovation, discussed above, is a regulatory initiative that should be anchored in a

primary law, to bring about a structural reform in payment card networks. Structural separation

would “break” the interchange fee from being a restrictive arrangement of price fixing. The

innovation discussed in this chapter is an alternative and independent proposal. It may be

implemented alone. It is a regulatory policy aimed at incentivizing issuers to give up

interchange fees. It sets a standard that imitates the consumer-welfare socially optimal

interchange fee, i.e., maximizing efficient card transactions subject to keeping prices of goods

equal to their cost of production. Profit limitation does not “break” the interchange fee from

being a restrictive arrangement, but rather eliminates the competitive concerns and neutralizes

the negative consequences of interchange fee, i.e., price increase of goods and negative usage

externality. Profit limitation may be applied by a regulator or a tribunal, as a condition for

permitting an interchange fee arrangement. In countries where interchange fee is not regulated,

implementation of my proposal is more challenging. It requires an authority - i.e., a regulator

or another enforcer - that is empowered to initiate proceedings, after a former arrangement has

crossed scrutiny and even got approval. Such authority is not trivial and might require

anchorage in primary or secondary legislation.

That being said, regulators usually have sua sponte power (and duty) to scrutinize from time to

time restrictive arrangements, even those that were formerly approved. Regulators are often

obligated by rules of the administrative law, to weigh and consider if existing regulation is still

1634See supra ch. 8.1.1 (Criticism Of The Cost-Based Methodology); ch. 8.2.2 (Criticism Of The Tourist Test). 1635 Supra ¶¶ 60, 96, 503, 574 and note 370.

Page 370: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

370

beneficial to the public when considering time passage and circumstantial changes.1636

For example, under rule of reason and self-assessment analysis, some countries currently do

not regulate the interchange fee. However, this does not imply that interchange fee (which to

remind, is a minimum price fixing between competitors), is immunized from future regulatory

intervention. Imagine interchange fee in the U.S. jumps to 17%. Regulators would certainly not

sit idle and be barred from intervention. Lack of intervention in self-assessment regimes does

not immune the interchange fee from future intervention, if it is abused. If a regulator would be

convinced by my proposal that current approach (e.g., of no interference or capping fee level)

harms the public, but capping profit confers benefits, such regulator may have powers to initiate

proceedings and resume interference in the interchange fee setting.

My proposal is inspired by the policy of the U.S Federal Reserve System from over a century

ago that caused banks to give up interchange fees in checks.1637

14.1. Par Clearance of Checks

862. Since ancient times, issuers of money charged exchange fees for acquiring "their" money.

Frankel explains, that: "Market power in modern electronic payment systems… arises from the

same fundamental economic source as the market power once available only to emperors and

kings who issued coins stamped from precious metals".1638 First interchange fees were actually

seigniorage, i.e., fees that mints (belonged to the king) charged for exchanging "gold bullions

presented by merchants in exchange for gold coins."1639 Bullions were not redeemed (i.e., -

1636 AT 508/04 Taagid Haisuf v. Adam Teva Vadin, para. 14 (Sept. 13, 2005); CA 2063/16 Glik v. Israeli Police, para.

30 (Jan 19, 2017); HCJ 986/05 Peled v. Tel-Aviv Municipality, para. 14 (Apr. 13, 2005).

See also State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 20 (1997): "In the area of antitrust law, there is a competing interest, well-

represented in this Court's decisions, in recognizing and adapting to changed circumstances and the lessons of

accumulated experience."; Maislin Indus., U.S. v. Primary Steel, 497 U.S. 116, 122 n.4 (1990): "[i]t would be . . . well

within this agency's authority (and indeed duty) to reinterpret the Interstate Commerce Act, based on upon experience

gained and changing circumstances." See also 19 U.S.C.S. § 1675(b) (Review upon information or request): "Whenever

the administering authority… receives information concerning… changed circumstances sufficient to warrant a review

of such determination, it shall conduct such a review". Subsection (c) determines a duty to conduct an additional five-

year review". 1637 William F. Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper: Legal and Economic Perspectives 26 J.L. ECON. 541,

566 (1983): "[T]he practices and rules of the Federal Reserve Board, which the legislation created, eventually tipped the

balance in for of par clearance in the United States." See also supra ¶ 785. 1638 Alan S. Frankel, Monopoly and Competition in the Supply and Exchange of Money 66 ANTITRUST L.J. 313, 314

(1998). 1639 Ibid at 315.

Page 371: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

371

acquired) at their PAR value, because of the seigniorage, i.e., the (interchange) fee merchants

had to pay to the mints.

In the U.S., bank notes were the first commercial paper money in circulation. "[B]ank notes

were promises by state chartered banks to remit to bearers on demand the stated amount in

specie (gold)."1640 The issuer bank was required to redeem notes at par if they were presented

physically over the counter at the issuing bank.1641 Bank notes were two-sided products.

Merchants wanted to accept only common payment instruments. Consumers wanted to pay only

with payment instruments that were widely accepted. Banks that wanted to convince merchants

and consumers to hold and accept bank notes they issued, had to find effortless ways for settling

them.1642 Banks entered bilateral agreements with other banks, for mutual acquiring of their

bank notes, in exchange for an (interchange) fee from the acquirer to the issuer. Bank notes

interchange fees reflected the saved shipping costs from not having to travel to the issuing bank

for redemption at the counter, and the travel back with specie.

As volume of transactions grew, banks formed the first clearing houses. Banks that belonged

to clearing houses could acquire at par, bank-notes of all other banks that belonged to the

clearing house. However, some rural banks did not join the clearing houses. They exploited

their (market) power from being located in remote areas to charge high interchange fees for

non-counter redemption of their notes.1643 On the other hand, notes of those non-par rural banks

circulated at par, because merchants tend to "price coherence" i.e., merchants did not surcharge

customers who paid with non-par bank notes bearing high interchange fees.1644 Absurdly, those

(expensive) notes were the most circulated, thus excluding cheaper bank notes.1645 The reason

was that neither merchants nor consumers wanted to be stuck with notes bearing high

interchange fees, thus fulfilling Gresham's Law – bad money drives out good money.1646

1640 Ibid at 320. 1641 Ibid at 322. 1642 Supra ¶72. 1643 Frankel, Monopoly and Competition in the Supply and Exchange of Money, supra note 1638, at 322 – 325. See also

DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND

BORROWING chapter 2 (2d ed. 2005); Baxter, supra note 1637 . 1644 For reasons why merchants do not surcharge see supra ch. 11. 1645 Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper, supra note 1637, at 557: "[I]nferior country bank notes of

uncertain value tended to drive sounder city bank notes out of circulation." 1646 Frankel, Monopoly and Competition in the Supply and Exchange of Money, supra note 1638, at 325-326: "Some

banks refused to participate in clearinghouse arrangements. In particular, rural banks lacking local competition found

that they could profit by imposing exchange charges on notes sent for redemption by city banks in the region. As the

general practice of par acceptance grew, it made less sense for merchants to slow down their transactions by going to

the trouble of identifying which notes incurred exchange charges and how much... Just as clipped and debased coins

tended to drive out coins of full gold content and value, nonpar bank notes tended to displace par notes circulating in the

Page 372: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

372

863. Checks gradually replaced bank notes. As with bank notes, banks that issued checks preferred

not to impose costs on the drawer (their customer) but on the receiver, often a distant merchant.

Except when checks were presented at the counter of the issuing bank, acquiring checks entailed

payment of interchange fee from the acquiring bank to the issuing bank. The interchange fee

reflected the cost saving for the payee, of not having to travel to the counter of the issuing bank

and return with specie. Increase in circulation of checks caused merchants not to bother with

surcharging. Hence goods were sold at the same price to check payers, albeit accepting

merchants had to pay interchange fees for redeeming them. As with bank notes, clearing houses

for checks, in which checks of members were cleared at par, were established. But many rural

banks did not join clearing houses, and enjoyed interchange fees imposed on banks with which

they had bilateral acquiring agreements.1647 However, the ultimate payer was the customer of

the acquiring bank, most often the merchant. Thus, just like ancient bullions or former bank

notes, acquiring checks of rural banks which were not members of the clearinghouses, entailed

payment of interchange fee to the issuing bank.1648

864. On that background the Federal Reserve System, created in 1913, was empowered to establish

a par collection system.1649 The Federal Reserve Act "provided that the Federal Reserve Board

would establish a check clearance system throughout the United States."1650 The federal

clearance system operated on national scale and cleared checks of member banks at par. The

federal clearing system gradually supplanted banks' clearing houses. The Federal Reserve

enticed banks to join its nation-wide (and par) clearing system, by enabling members to acquire

checks drawn on non-members banks, that were forwarded by a member bank to the clearing

system.1651 Nevertheless, thousands of banks still remained off the par list, i.e., demanded

interchange fees for non-counter clearance.1652 The next move of the Federal Reserve in order

to force non-member banks to waive interchange fees, was to collect and suddenly present at

the counter, checks of refusers banks:

[In 1919, the Federal Reserve] began to accept for clearance items drawn on

nonpar banks and then to demand that they be paid at par. If that request was

cities. This illustrates a second way to restate Gresham's Law: Restatement #2: Expensive forms of money tend to

displace the inexpensive". 1647 Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper, supra note 1637, at 563-64. 1648 Id. at 565. 1649 Frankel, Monopoly and Competition in the Supply and Exchange of Money, supra note 1638, at 335: "The Federal

Reserve System, established by the Federal Reserve Act of 1913, was empowered to establish a general system of par

collection for all member banks". 1650Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper, supra note 1637, at 567. 1651 Id. at 567-68. 1652 Id. at 569

Page 373: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

373

refused, as it often was, the local reserve bank gathered up the checks of the nonpar

banks and presented them at the bank's premises ("at the window"), demanding

payment in full in currency. This tactic proved to be very powerful… The batch

presentation of checks in the manner described often required more currency then

the bank had in its vault; yet if payment in full was not made, the checks could be

returned to the depositor dishonored, placing the drawee bank in violation of its

contractual obligations to its customer. Through this tactic the Fed succeeded in

forcing many recalcitrant banks onto the par list".1653

865. The legality of this practice was supported by the Federal Supreme Court. Judge Brandeis, who

delivered the opinion, held:

Country banks are not entitled to protection against legitimate competition. Their

loss here shown is of the kind or which business concerns are commonly subjected

when improved facilities are introduced by others, or a more efficient competitor

enters the field. It is damnum absque injuria.1654

866. The Federal Reserve never prohibited interchange fees in checks. It wisely managed to persuade

(or one might say coerce) banks to voluntarily give up interchange fees, by offering carrot to

par banks and a stick to nonpar banks. The practices of the federal bank were an important mean

to achieve a nationwide par clearing system.1655

867. Back to the future of payment cards, my idea is to persuade issuers to give up interchange fees,

by offering them a carrot if they do so and a stick if they do not. Interchange fees are a product

of arrangements that require regulatory approval. An approval can be conditioned. My proposal

is to impose a condition on any approval of interchange fee arrangement, which issuers would

prefer to refrain from, unless the interchange fee is indeed essential to cover costs or to

genuinely reward cardholders (which is also a “marketing” cost). Issuers have two channels of

income. Direct channel from cardholders and the interchange fee from merchants. The latter is

the sole income of issuers from merchants, and cannot be circumvented.1656 The carrot to issuers

that would agree to waive interchange fees, and be satisfied with the direct channel of income

from the cardholder side, would be no regulation on their rate of return, i.e., their profitability.

The condition, i.e., the stick, in the case issuers decide to continue charging interchange fees,

is to impose limitation on their profit. Given that the reasoning for interchange fee is not to be

a source of profit, but only to cover uncovered costs and to genuinely reward cardholders, the

1653 Id. at 570. 1654 American Bank & Trust Company V. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, 262 U.S. 643, 648 (1923) 1655 Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper, supra note 1637, at 570; Evans & Schmalensee, The Economics

of Interchange Fees and their Regulation, supra note 1330, at 91: “The check system in the US is run by the Fed. Res.,

which essentially forced banks early in the last century to exchange checks at par—that is, to have a zero interchange

fee in the checking system”. 1656 Supra note 918 and accompanying text.

Page 374: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

374

condition would lead to an efficient result. Issuers would not charge interchange fee, unless

used for its legitimate purposes.

14.2. Profit Limitation

868. The basis to my proposal is that interchange fee is justified only by necessity to internalize

usage or network externalities. The argument is either that interchange fee is required to

reimburse issuers for uncovered costs, and to enable expansion of the network (the network

justification);1657 or to induce efficient usage by passing proceeds of the interchange fee (above

transaction cost) to cardholders, as discounts or rewards, and by that incentivize efficient card

usage (the usage justification).1658 Come what may, under both justifications for interchange

fees, it is not meant to be a source of profit:

868.1 When the interchange fee is required to cover costs of transaction, then by definition

it cannot be a source of profit;

868.2 When the interchange fee is required to reward cardholders (which is also a kind of

cost), then also by definition it cannot be a source of profit;

869. When the interchange fee is used either to cover costs or to induce expansion of the network or

efficient card usage, using it as a source of profit causes it to fail its cause. If part of the

interchange fee is retained as issuers' profit, merchants could enjoy the same level of usage with

a lower MSF.1659 Any part of the interchange fee that is used as a source of profit cannot, by

definition, cover costs or induce efficient usage. It would have been better, from a social point

of view and under consumer welfare standard, if this part of the interchange fee would not be

granted a license, not be collected in the first place, and prices in the market would be a little

lower.1660 Simply put, interchange fee cannot serve as profit source under the pretext of

1657 Supra ¶¶ 488, 174-175. 1658 Ann Borestam & Heiko Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, ECB Occasional Paper Series 131, at 30

(2011): "[I]nterchange fee is an indispensable income source for issuing banks, allowing them both to cover the costs

related to their card operations and to avoid charging cardholders."; see also ibid at 48, 53. for expansion, see supra ch.

6.7 (Cardholder fees and rewards). 1659 Supra note 1075 (In the terminology of Rochet & Tirole, under the consumer welfare standard, using interchange as

a source of profit causes it to fail the tourist test. Merchants would agree to pay interchange fee that is used to steer a

tourist to pay with efficient card because merchants derive benefit from steering to efficient payment instruments.

However, interchange fee that is used as a source of profit for issuers causes price increase and thus fails the tourist test.

Merchants (or consumers) derive no benefit from such profit). 1660 For expansion on price increase due to the interchange fee, see supra ch. 10.1. See supra ch. 10 for competitive

concerns raised by interchange fees in general.

Page 375: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

375

internalizing usage and network externality. The unique features of the interchange fee which

justify its initial approval, do not include profit as part of the justification.1661

However, issuers earn profits from the interchange fee, contrary to its declared purpose. Worse,

they do it under regulatory approval. Payment card firms earn average rate of return that is more

than twice the customary rate of return in the financial industry.1662 In practice, as opposed to

the opinion of early scholars, interchange fee is not neutral,1663 but a major source of profit for

issuers.1664 This is not a predestination. Interchange fee can and should be approved, subject to

conditions that would ensure it is not used contrary to its declared goals. It is warranted to

prohibit issuers from abusing the purposes underlying the interchange fee, which they

themselves claimed that interchange fee is required for.

870. Indeed, competition authorities and regulators find it legitimate to condition approval of

restrictive arrangements in general and interchange fees specifically, in terms aimed to prevent

abuse.1665 Until today, regulators conditioned the approval of the interchange fee by capping its

level.1666 Scholars, regulators and competition authorities, attempted to combat the competitive

concerns by capping the level of the interchange fee.1667 No previous work proposed to combat

the market power of issuers by limiting their profits. My proposal is to condition the approval

of the interchange fee by capping it from being a source of profit.

1661 For expansion on the special features of the interchange fee that justify its approval, see supra ch. 7. For a legal

analysis, which (of course) do not contain profits as a basis for the interchange fee approval, see supra ch. 0. 1662 Supra ¶¶ 60, 96; see also supra notes 127, 370, 371, 1480, 1619.

See also EUROPE ECONOMICS, THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF INTERCHANGE FEE REGULATION IN THE UK FINAL REPORT, at

52 (June 28, 2013): "[C]ompared to most other commercial bank activities credit cards still remain more profitable than

these.";

GAO-10-45, RISING INTERCHANGE FEES HAVE INCREASED COSTS FOR MERCHANTS, BUT OPTIONS FOR REDUCING FEES

POSE CHALLENGES, at 1 (2009): "Issuers, particularly smaller issuers such as community banks and credit unions, report

relying on interchange fees as a significant source of revenue for their credit card operations, and analyses by banking

regulators indicate such operations traditionally have been among the most profitable types of activities for large

banks." 1663 For neutrality of interchange fee, see supra ¶103. For negation of the neutrality see supra ch. 8.3.3. 1664 Balto, supra note 1432, at 221; Frankel & Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, supra note 1345,

at 634 n. 23. See also Thomas A. Durkin, Gregory Elliehausen & Todd J. Zywicki, An Assessment of Behavioral Law

and Economics Contentions and what we Know Empirically about Credit Card use by Consumers, at 38 (George

Mason Law & Econ. Research Paper no. 14-46, 2014): "[I]n every year after 1991, except 1998, revenue from

interchange actually exceeded net income after taxes (net profit) for the industry as a whole. Consequently, it seems

difficult to contend that interchange is not a “major” source of revenue".

See also supra ¶¶ 60, 96, 182. 1665 For an extensive survey see supra ch. 0 (Regulation of interchange fees around the world). 1666 Supra ¶ 373 (Rochet & Wright claim that capping privately determined interchange fee will decrease it, and

increase consumer surplus) .In Europe, the cap is based on demand features, primarily the alternative benefit to

merchants from not having to accept cash (avoided costs of cash or the "tourist test"), supra ch. 8.2). In Israel, Australia

and in the U.S. (for debit and deferred debit cards), the cap is based on supply features, which are mainly the cost of the

payment guarantee and the processing of transactions, see supra ch. 8.1, 8.1.1 (Israel), 8.3.9 (U.S.), 8.4 (Australia). 1667 Id.

Page 376: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

376

To be clear, my proposal is to limit total issuers' profits from all sources, to a modest rate of

return. I do not propose to limit only profit from interchange fee, as there is no such profit.

Interchange fee proceeds mix and merge with proceeds from other channels of issuers' income,

and cannot be segregated.

If issuers are also acquirers the profits from the two-sided merge. According to my proposal,

issuers would not be able to claim that they use the entire proceeds from interchange fee to

cover costs and to reduce cardholder fees, but simultaneously use other channels of income,

such as cardholder fees or interest, for profit. This would be a forbidden wisecrack. As long as

issuers are also acquirers, then the profit limitation should apply to all of their activities, i.e.,

profit from issuing and acquiring should be limited.

Applying for interchange fee should be a last resort, after exhausting all other channels of

income available for issuers. Applying for interchange fee, but simultaneously gaining profits

from other channels of income (e.g., from the acquiring side or from cardholder fees or from

interest on credit to cardholders or merchants), is contradictory. If issuers' income apart from

interchange fee is high enough to cover costs and to allow a prosperous cardholder side, let

alone make profits, this pulls the rug under the justifications for interchange fee. Only if other

channels of income do not suffice, then the interchange fee excuses are recruited (to cover

uncovered costs and reward cardholders).

My proposal stems directly from asymmetric pricing, which is a basic feature in two-sided

markets. In two-sided markets, before resorting to price fixing, one side should finance the

other.1668 If issuers and acquirers are not separated, profits from the acquiring side should be

recruited to finance pecuniary demands of the issuing side, before resorting to interchange fees.

For example, a newspaper cannot claim it does not earn enough from readers, as an excuse for

fixing the prices of advertisements with other newspapers. In the same manner, shopping malls

cannot fix parking fees, to cover purported "deficit" on the customer side. Two sided platforms

must use their proceeds from the two sides to cover their costs, exactly the way they use their

proceeds from the two sides to make profits. Asymmetric pricing is a fundamental feature of

two sided platforms, which also applies to payment cards.

1668 Supra ¶¶ 449-454.

Page 377: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

377

In Israel, each payment card firm is a separate legal entity. Each payment card firm operates a

payment card business as its sole activity, and is a distinguished profit center for its

shareholders. Hence in Israel, there is no problem for immediate application of my proposal. In

the unlikely event that payment card firms are not unified as separate legal entities, or at least

as separate profit centers, it is still possible to delineate their cost and income,1669 and assure

that if they charge interchange fee, their profit would be limited. Payment card business is a

distinguished field of operation, different from other financial activities, and its costs and

income can be isolated effortlessly. Thus, even in the unlikely event that issuers are not separate

entities, my proposal can be easily implemented. However, for facilitation of the proposal it

would be simpler to require issuers to unite into a distinguished form of association.

My proposal can be illustrated in the following example. Assume beggars need a license to beg

for alms, and this license is conditioned in that the beggar does not have other income. If he

does have other income he must use it and he is not entitled for a license to beg. A beggar that

drives to his luxurious house in a fancy car abuses his license and probably is not entitled for

license from the outset. The idea is that interchange fee should not be double compensation.

The observation point should be comprehensive. All sources of income should be considered

and recruited, before granting a license that depends on the need to cover costs.

871. Baxter's interchange fee was a mean to cover "issuers' deficit", and not a tool for profit.1670

Rochet & Tirole explained that in addition to cost coverage, interchange fee can stimulate

efficient usage of cards. They referred to market power of issuers as a cause for raising the

interchange fee, in order to offset the unfortunate results of that market power, which allegedly

causes sub-usage of cards. Thus, even according to Rochet & Tirole, the profit-part of the

interchange fee was an unpleasant consequence of issuers' market power, and not a justification

to its initial approval. To combat such an unpleasant result, Rochet & Tirole proposed that under

the consumer welfare standard, profit from interchange fee should not be counted in the

interchange fee calculation.1671 Otherwise, Rochet & Tirole explained, profit of issuers who do

not compete but enjoy the "easy life" created by the interchange fee, is tantamount to a “cozy

cartel”:

Cozy cartel: In this first view, issuers’ markup stems from tacit collusion among

large issuers protected from effective entry by barriers to entry. Furthermore, the

1669 See, e.g., ¶ 463 (The European Commission calculated the profitability of payment card activities of banks). 1670 For expansion, supra ch. 6.2. (Baxter model of balancing costs). See also ¶ 339. 1671 For expansion, supra ch. 6.4 (The model of Rochet & Tirole).

Page 378: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

378

resulting supra-normal profits are either dissipated through an “easy life” and

inefficient production of card services, or go to wealthy shareholders whose

marginal utility of income is much lower than that of the average consumer. Then

issuers’ markup should not be counted as part of social welfare.1672

872. The proposal of Rochet & Tirole (under consumer welfare standard), was to ignore issuers'

profit in calculating the level of interchange fee ("markup should not be counted"), and to cap

the level of the interchange fee, so it would not account for issuers profit. They did not propose

to limit profitability of issuers as I do.

Vickers also argued that the initial market power of issuers should not be contemplated with.

He argued that allowing issuers to earn profits from interchange fee, which is collected in order

to satiate hunger for profits, is tantamount to subsidizing cartels.1673 Vickers also did not

propose to limit profits but to cap the level of the interchange fee, as did Rochet & Tirole.

Indeed, regulators all over the world cap the level of the interchange fee.

However, capping the level is often arbitrary, because the chosen level does not purport to be

optimization of any welfare standard. A cap assures issuers a certain amount of money, without

considering other sources of income.1674 Under my proposal the interchange fee can be larger

or smaller than any percentage or cap. What is important under my proposal is not the amount

of money collected by the interchange fee, but the designation of the proceeds. Interchange fee

cannot be a source for double compensation but collected only for justified causes, i.e., covering

uncovered costs or rewards to induce efficient usage, but not for profits.

My proposal is actually a solution to the problem of finding the optimal interchange fee, with

no need to solve the incredibly sophisticated equations of the economic models which attempted

to depict the optimal interchange fee. My solution is not mathematical but rather a principal

1672 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems, 5 REV. NETWORK

ECON. 1, 11 (2006); See also Steven Semeraro, The Antitrust Economics (and Law) of Surcharging Credit Card

Transactions, 14 STAN. J. L. BUS. FIN. 343, 345-46 (2009): “Card issuers may then retain some revenue as

supracompetitive profit and wastefully compete some away in pursuit of highly profitable cardholders.”;

Jean Tirole, Payment Card Regulation and the use of Economic Analysis in Antitrust, supra note 951, at17: “If the

profits associated with cardholders’ installed base are dissipated through wasteful advertising expenditures to “acquire”

cardholders, profits should not enter social welfare calculations.”.

see also supra notes 708,710,1676. 1673 John Vickers, Public Policy and the Invisible Price: Competition Law, Regulation and the Interchange Fee,

Payments Sys. Research Conference 231, 235 (2005); Alan S. Frankel, Towards a Competitive Card Payments

Marketplace, RBA 27, 46 (2007); Alan Frankel, Interchange in various Countries: Commentary on Weiner and Wright,

FRB Kansas 51, 54 (2005). 1674 Supra ¶ 510 especially notes 900 and 905.

Page 379: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

379

that is guaranteed to bring interchange fee to the optimum. Prohibiting interchange fee from

being a source of profit would compel it to its legitimate original boundaries, and no more.

873. Consumer welfare standard is the standard to be maximized under current view of antitrust

law.1675 Under consumer welfare standard, optimal interchange fee excludes profit of issuers

and acquirers.1676 Of course issuers and acquirers can earn unlimited and unregulated profits,

but not through a cartel. It is legitimate to demand that profits would not stem from the

restrictive arrangement of the interchange fee, but from the transparent competitive arenas they

compete in.

Optimization of consumer welfare does not derive a specific level of interchange fee. There is

no formula that yields an exact rate of optimal interchange fee, which is used solely for

legitimate purposes, and that can be translated to a level of interchange fee.1677 However, the

true economic condition for maximizing consumer welfare does imply that the optimal

interchange fee is the one which issuers earn zero profits from, and prices of goods are set

according to costs.1678

My proposal imitates the economic condition for optimal interchange fee according to the

consumer welfare standard. The idea is to permit issuers to charge interchange fee in one

1675 Supra note 943; see also supra ch. 6.9.4. 1676 Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Must-Take Cards: Merchant Discounts and Avoided Costs, 9 J. EUR. ECON.

ASS'N 462, 486 (2011): “TUS, equal to cardholders’ plus merchants’ surplus, that is not including issuer markups”. For

a further expansion see supra ¶¶ 408-410. See also Rochet & Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment

Systems, supra note 710, at 10-11; Marc Rysman & Julian Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, at 34-35 (2015):

"[T]he Baxter interchange fee does have some grounding in economic theory. In some standard theoretical settings, it

corresponds to the socially optimal interchange fee absent issuer margins. And, with positive issuer margins, it can

be justified either as providing a lower bound for the socially optimal interchange fee or being the interchange fee

which maximizes total user surplus (or consumer surplus). Rochet and Tirole (2011) have developed a related

alternative to the Baxter interchange fee in terms of a merchant indifference test, which they called the tourist-test (as

discussed in Section 4). It implies the same interchange fee as Baxter's except that it is lower than Baxter's to the extent

acquirers make positive margins. The European Commission is proposing to use this tourist-test interchange fee to

determine the regulatory cap". id. at 35: “Whether this approach is considered a reasonable benchmark depends on

whether one thinks total welfare or consumer surplus is the relevant objective. To the extent that issuers obtain positive

margins, a welfare standard would require an interchange fee above the Baxter level in order to offset these margins.

Thus, a Baxter interchange fee would be a lower bound to the desired interchange fee. Some policy-makers and

economists have criticized a welfare standard arguing it would be equivalent to subsidizing a monopolist in order to

reduce its price to cost (see Vickers, 2005 in particular), certainly an unusual government intervention. If one rejects

the welfare standard in favor of consumer surplus, then the Baxter interchange fee remains the theoretically

relevant standard even in the presence of issuer margins. Note that if regulators adopt a consumer-surplus standard,

then in case there are any acquiring margins, these should also not be used to decrease interchange fees (by a symmetric

argument), which is one reason why the Baxter interchange fee might be preferred over interchange fees based on

merchant indifference". 1677 Supra ¶ 510 especially notes 900 and 905. 1678 Supra ch. 6.9.4. See also Rochet & Tirole, Must-Take Cards, ibid at 469: "The maximum interchange fee that

passes the tourist test, aT , thus corresponds to the socially optimal IF when banks are perfectly competitive (m = 0)…

When issuers have market power (m > 0), the socially optimal interchange fee does not pass the tourist test ".

Page 380: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

380

condition: issuers would be forbidden to earn profits above a modest rate of return, which would

reflect the rate of return on risk-free investments.

874. The reason for a risk-free rate of return is that interchange fees makes issuing a risk-free

business activity. Interchange fee is a (restrictive) arrangement which ensures full cost

coverage. The implied stance at the base of the interchange fee is that it should be a source of

income for uncovered costs, and not a source for double compensation (i.e., profit), in a manner

of a cartel. A numerical demonstration might visualize.

The interchange fee in Israel yields an income of almost NIS 2 billion (0.7% of more than NIS

270 billion turnover).1679 This amount alone covers almost all issuers' standardized costs – NIS

2.5 billion (total issuers' costs are approximately NIS 2.8 billion,1680 but they should be reduced

and amended because of inflated payments to issuers' controlling banks).1681 Hence, almost all

of issuers costs are covered by the interchange fee. In addition, issuers receive a 'windfall' of

approximately NIS 1.4 billion from cardholder fees and interest.1682 In this situation there is

almost nothing to compete on! This situation reminds of Vickers warning about the distortion

in the merchant side, when under the pretext of cost coverage, income of issuers from

interchange fee alone is larger than all costs.1683 Indeed, in Europe it was found already in 2007

that most issuers remain profitable without resorting to interchange fees.1684

Even in the case interchange fee alone does not cover all of issuers' costs, the residual is easily

covered with cardholder fees and interest from cardholders, which accrued with the interchange

fee, "compels" issuers to profit.1685 When issuers are also acquirers, all their income from the

acquiring side should also be recruited before resorting to price fixing. After all, the interchange

fee is a minimum price fixing arrangement.1686

1679 Bank of Israel, ongoing information on bank corporations, table X-6 (last updated June 4, 2017)

http://www.boi.org.il/he/BankingSupervision/Data/Pages/Tables.aspx?ChapterId=9 1680 Bank of Israel, annual information on the banking system, payment cards, Table X-13 (last entry July 26, 2017). http://www.boi.org.il/he/BankingSupervision/Data/Pages/DataTable.aspx?Chapter=%D7%A4%D7%A8%D7%A7+%D7%99%27+-

+%D7%9B%D7%A8%D7%98%D7%99%D7%A1%D7%99+%D7%90%D7%A9%D7%A8%D7%90%D7%99&Years=2012-2016 1681 ITAMAR MILRED, TEUR SHUK KARTISEI HASHRAI VENITUAH HAMIMSHAKIM BEIN HEVROT KARTISEI HASHRAI

LEBEIN HABANKIM (DESCRIPTION OF CREDIT CARD MARKET AND ANALYZING INTERFACES BETWEEN CREDIT CARD

FIRMS AND THE BANKS), THE KNESSET CENTER FOR RESEARCH AND INFORMATION, at 9 (Feb, 2014)

https://www.knesset.gov.il/mmm/data/pdf/m03356.pdf ; JACOB CHERTOF AND AMI TZADIK, CREDIT CARDS MARKET:

ANALYSIS, REGULATION AND INTERNATIONAL COMPARISON, KNESSET RESEARCH CENTER, at 11 (2010)

http://www.knesset.gov.il/mmm/data/pdf/m02668.pdf. 1682 Supra note 1680. 1683 Supra ¶¶ 500-501. 1684 Supra ¶¶ 574 (note 1018), 463. 1685 See e.g., supra ¶¶ 500 - 501 (interchange fee amounts to all or almost all of issuers' costs) 1686 Supra ch. 9 (Legal assessment of the interchange fee).

Page 381: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

381

If issuers claim they need revenues from the interchange fee to cover costs or to subsidize

cardholders, then they cannot, at the same time, use it as a source for their own profits. Issuers

can never lose if all their costs are deemed to be covered through a protected and authorized

cartel. Interchange fee, which under the pretext of cost coverage and rewards becomes a source

of profit, turns card issuance into a risk-free business.

The essence of the interchange fee is to cover issuers' uncovered costs and induce cardholders'

usage. But when proceeds from interchange fee are higher than any "deficit" (i.e., uncovered

costs), then the interchange fee forces issuers to profit.1687 This profit is riskless.

875. The legal authority of regulators to limit profit stems from the fact that these profits result from

horizontal minimum price fixing arrangement among competitors.1688 The law in various legal

jurisdictions around the globe tolerates the interchange fee, even though it is a per-se price

fixing,1689 because of its special features as a mechanism to internalize network and usage

externalities.1690 However, recognition in the necessity of interchange fee is not a carte-blanche

to charge any rate of it. There is a difference between the essence of a right to its coverage. For

example, freedom of speech does not permit exposure of state secrets. Indeed, regulators and

Tribunals do condition approval of price arrangements in terms.1691 Any part of a price fixing

agreement, that is approved under the pretext of internalizing network and usage externalities,

but which in fact serves as a profit source, is an abuse. It is certainly not indispensable and does

not confer benefits to the public.1692 Only when direct channels of income are not sufficient,

interchange fee may be reasonable or indispensable. Nevertheless, even under this scenario,

interchange fee ceases to fulfill its legitimate purpose if used for generating profits. Thus,

authorities are entitled to limit interchange fees arrangements to their declared purposes and no

more, because those (i.e., cost coverage and genuine rewards) are the only reasonable,

indispensable and legitimate justifications to interchange fees.

876. A major difference between my proposal and the current cap/ level regulation is that capping

interchange fee level would not prevent it from being a source of profit, whenever the regulated

1687 See supra ¶¶ 500, 503, 574, 463, supra note 208 1688 For expanded legal analysis see supra ch. 9. 1689 For expansion see Supra ch. 8. 1690 For expansion on the special features of the interchange fee as a mechanism to internalize network and usage

externalities, see supra ch. 7. 1691 MICHAEL L. KATZ, REFORM OF CREDIT CARDS SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA II COMMISSIONED REPORT, paras 97-98 (Aug.

2001); see also supra ¶ 709; supra note 222. 1692 Supra note 826.

Page 382: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

382

level plus additional income yield higher proceeds than the costs the interchange fee was

allegedly aimed to cover. Apparently, this is the situation worldwide, as can be seen in the

prosperous bottom line of issuers' financial reports all over the world. The caps are apparently

too high, a familiar weakness of price caps.1693 My proposal, however, prohibits profits, and

caps the level of the interchange fee, not on a number but on the standard which consumer

welfare dictates. My proposal is in line with the literature that emphasized that profits should

be ignored.

Similar to the practices of the Federal Reserve from a century ago,1694 the condition I propose

would take the edge off issuers' desire to apply for interchange fee higher than essential to cover

costs including rewards, especially when issuers' other channels of income, i.e., direct income

from cardholders (cardholder fees and interest on credit), are profitable enough.

877. Rochet & Tirole reconcile with interchange fee which derives profits to issuers, because the

part of the interchange fee which issuers are kind enough to pass through to cardholders as

rewards, incentivize efficient card usage. Economists do not always bother with normative

questions. A jurist, however, may and should pose doubts, if profit which is a result of initial

market power of issuers, is undeniable. The conclusion might be that such a market power

should not be contemplated with in the first place.

In my view, the argument according to which it is allegedly efficient that interchange fees

should be raised to offset market power of issuers, as raised by Rochet & Tirole to justify

interchange fee which is a source of profit, contrary to its initial economic justification, is

analogous to a situation in which one would say it is efficient that merchants pay protection to

the organized crime. Even under the assumption that paying for protection is economically

efficient under the circumstances of the (market) power of the organized crime, normatively we

must not accept protection phenomena in the first place, and we should enforce "no protection"

law as a better and more efficient solution.

Economically speaking, if a gun is attached to your temple it is efficient to pay protection.

However, normatively it is more efficient to have a rule that prohibits protection payments than

1693 Catherine Liston, Price-Cap versus Rate-of-Return Regulation, 5 J. Regulatory Econ. 25, 28 (1993): “[w]hen there

is considerable uncertainty about cost fluctuations, the regulator may have to set the cap on prices so high that transfers

of surplus to consumers are eliminated (Schmalensee 1989).” 1694 Supra ch. 14.1.

Page 383: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

383

allowing them. The analogy is that we should not tolerate a situation whereby merchants are

being forced to pay interchange fee to offset issuers' market power, reflected in interchange fee

being a source of profit. Let alone so when the interchange fee is a restrictive arrangement that

must be approved by regulators. Regulators should prohibit interchange fees from being a

source of profit from the outset.

878. Given the competitive concerns raised by the interchange fee, especially the concern for a small

but market-wide price increase,1695 issuers should not be able to claim they need interchange

fee for reimbursement of uncovered costs, or to induce efficient card usage (the only two

acceptable justifications for charging interchange fees), but in practice use interchange fee

proceeds as a source for profit. On the other hand, if interchange fee is indeed required for

covering costs or to induce usage, then issuers do not expect to make any profit from it anyway.

Hence, restricting issuers' profitability does not frustrate any legitimate expectation issuers

could possibly have.

Under my proposal, issuers would be able to charge interchange fees, only to the extent

proceeds are used to cover costs of issuers which are not covered by other channels of issuers'

income. Any difference above costs would have to be remitted to cardholders as reduction in

cardholder fees. This would substantially reduce the attractiveness of interchange fees for

issuers' shareholders. The possibility of giving up interchange fees and be able to earn unlimited

profits from the direct channel, i.e., the cardholder side, would turn to be more appealing for

issuers.

879. It is interesting to note that the position of the Israeli Visa firms which was supported by an

expert opinion of Professor Rochet, in the Israeli proceedings (AT 4630/01), was that the

interchange fee is required to cover an "issuing deficit" plus reasonable profit.1696 This is

actually what I propose, with the reservation that reasonable profit is, in our case, a risk-free

return. In fact, the profits achieved by the Israeli payment cards in practice, since they submitted

their stance to the Antitrust Tribunal in AT 4630/01, far exceeds any reasonable profit they

could ask for. In other words, the denial of their stance was, paradoxically, in their favor. They

earned much more under the cost methodology.

My slight change in the profit standard (risk free interest instead of reasonable profit), cannot

1695 Supra ch. 10.1. 1696 Supra ¶ 488.

Page 384: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

384

eliminate the fact, that my proposal is in line with the Visa firms claims before the Israeli

Antitrust Tribunal. Both me and the Visa firms claim that only issuers' "deficit" plus a certain

rate of return, should be acknowledged as legitimate interchange fee. This is Baxter’s

interchange fee,1697 achieved with a simple condition and almost no regulation.

880. Payment card firms are (usually large) financial institutions. Their books are mostly open to the

public and profits are published and cannot be concealed. If an issuer that collects interchange

fee shows profit, this profit is detectable, and can easily be disgorged to offset the interchange

fee for the next period. On the other hand, capping the level of the interchange fee is

complicated and demands vast resources, as can be learned from the experience of Israel,

Europe, U.S. and other countries. Moreover, even after this heavy investment there is no

assurance for optimization.1698 Thus, to detect profit, no deep accounting is required, as opposed

to setting a cap.

881. Under my proposal issuers, who would gain profits above the risk-free permitted rate of return

in a certain period, would have to reduce the interchange fee they charge in the following period,

to offset the illegal profit. Disgorgement, and even penalties and other remedies, should be

available if offset does not occur. What is more important is that no dividends can be distributed

to shareholders if there is no profit. I suspect shareholders would not agree to give up profits.

They would probably waive interchange fees altogether before giving up dividends.

There is no difference between keeping proceeds from interchange fees as profits (which should

be banned), or using interchange fees for covering costs (purportedly permitted aim), while

simultaneously using other income as profits. This latter situation should be also banned. Issuers

who charge interchange fee declare they operate a deficit business, that they need a price fixing

restrictive arrangement to survive, and that they are not entitled to profit. It is only legitimate

to demand that they should not be allowed to earn more than a modest risk-free rate of return.

Reducing profits obtained through interchange fee would lower costs of acquirers. The

acquiring side is considered competitive, thus savings would be passed through to merchants

in the form of a lower MSF.1699 Merchants are expected to pass through any lower MSF to final

prices, as a function of competition in the relevant markets. But even if merchants do not pass

through their savings to consumers, merchants are the “consumer” of payment cards and it

1697 Supra ch. 6.2. 1698 Supra ch. 8.1.1 (Criticism Of The Cost-Based Methodology). 1699 Supra ¶97; see also supra note 208.

Page 385: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

385

suffices, in terms of efficiency, to expand their surplus.1700 In addition, reduction in the MSF is

expected to expand the merchant side (direct effect) and make cards more attractive to

consumers (indirect network effect).1701

882. To conclude, my proposal identifies the point, above which there is no justification to charge

interchange fee, and sets the cap there, without the need to stipulate a specific rate, number or

a formula, but by using a simple principle. The principle is that interchange fee cannot be

regarded as legitimate any more when it is above costs, and when its proceeds are not returned

to cardholders in full to induce efficient usage. My proposal yields optimal interchange fee

under the consumer welfare standard.

An exception should be made for nascent issuers, or for new and efficient kind of transactions

which require incentives at the payers' side. New issuers at the take-off stage should be able to

earn profits for a limited initial period. This would encourage entrance. In addition, to induce

innovations, new kinds of transactions or technologies should also be encouraged, by allowing

a higher rate of return on specific investments. This should encourage new entrants or modern

technologies to enter.

883. My proposal offers a second option for issuers. Issuers may waive interchange fees entirely,

and no limitations should be imposed on their profits. I believe that most issuers have sufficient

income from direct channels, i.e., cardholder fees and interest on credit.1702 They would waive

interchange fees entirely and prefer to operate without profit limits. In this sense my proposal

resembles the incentive taken by the Federal Reserve Bank in the U.S., about a century ago,

which was aimed to eliminate interchange fees in checks.1703

14.3. Precedents

884. My proposal is not unprecedented. Profitability (or rate of return) regulation is recognized in

markets with natural monopolies.1704 Profit limitation is also found in public utilities which are

traditionally regulated, such as health-care, financial institutions, energy, gas, water, electricity,

1700 Supra ch. 6.9.4. 1701 Supra ¶¶ 446-448. 1702 Supra ¶ 463. 1703 Supra ch. 14.1 and ¶ 785. 1704 See Richard A. Posner, Natural Monopoly and its Regulation, 21 STAN. L. Rev. 548 (1969).

Page 386: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

386

construction and telecommunication.1705 In Israel, Nesher, a monopoly cement supplier is

restricted to 12% profit on its working capital.1706

The framework of rate-of-return regulation of public utilities fits my proposal. Payment systems

are the infrastructure of commerce and are often called the “plumbing” of economy (see supra

n. 2). Mature payment systems possess market power towards their customers (supra ¶¶ 603 -

607), which resemble the market power of public utilities towards their customers. Both face

rigid demand, high entry barriers and lack of close substitutes. However, there is a major

difference between rate-of-return regulation on public utilities and my proposal, which renders

my proposal even more plausible. Public utilities are not illegal by their nature. Their regulation

creates tension between their constitutional rights and public needs, although the constitutional

defense is not high.1707 Issuers, on the other hand, do not have a vested right nor a constitutional

protection to enjoy a minimum price fixing arrangement. Thus, limiting issuers’ rate-of-return

is inherently less intrusive. After all, issuers cannot claim they are deprived of a right to make

profit from an arrangement which was approved at the first place, only to cover costs. Such

right does not exist.

Rate-of-return regulation on public utilities in the U.S. began in the 19th century and since then

has been repeatedly approved by the Supreme Court.1708 The main principle under rate-of-return

regulation is that earnings should be "equal to that generally being made… in other business

1705 David M Newbery, Rate-of-return regulation versus price regulation for public utilities, 1 (Cambridge 1997):

"Public utility regulation arose naturally in the nineteenth century for gas, water, rail, telegraph, and later, electricity and

telephony". 1706 The supervision is derived from sec.12(b) of Control of Commodities and Services Law, 1985 and "Suari Formula",

see Ministry of Economy and Industry, Cement Regulation, available at

http://economy.gov.il/Industry/Industry_and_Environment/Chemical_Industry/Pages/CementImports.aspx 1707 Duquesne Light Co. v. Barasch, 488 U.S. 299, 307 (1989): “The Constitution protects utilities from being limited to

a charge for their property serving the public which is so "unjust" as to be confiscatory.”; Verizon Communs., Inc. v.

FCC, 535 U.S. 467, 484 (2002): "Rates which enable the company to operate successfully, to maintain its financial

integrity, to attract capital, and to compensate its investors for the risks assumed certainly cannot be condemned as

invalid, even though they might produce only a meager return on the so-called 'fair value' rate base.”; See also FPC v.

Nat. Gas Pipeline Co., 315 U.S. 575, 585-86 (1942); Federal Power Com. v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591, 605

(1944); cf. Covington & lexington tpk. Rd. Co. V. Sandford, 164 U.S. 578, 597 (1896): “[i]f a corporation cannot

maintain such a highway and earn dividends for stockholders, it is a misfortune for it and them which the Constitution

does not require to be remedied by imposing unjust burdens upon the public”; P.R. Tel. Co. v. Telecomms. Regulatory

Bd. of P.R., 665 F.3d 309, 324 (1st Cir. 2011): “All that is protected against, in a constitutional sense, is that the rates

fixed by the Commission be higher than a confiscatory level... the 'lowest reasonable rate' is one which is not

confiscatory in the constitutional sense... rates can be regulated so long as they are not so 'unjust' as to be confiscatory”. 1708See, inter alia, Smyth v. Ames, 169 U.S. 466, 515 (1898); Covington & lexington tpk. Rd. Co. V. Sandford, 164 U.S.

578, 597 (1896); Mo. ex rel. Sw. Bell Tel. Co. v. Pub. Serv. Com., 262 U.S. 276 (1923); FPC v. Nat. Gas Pipeline Co.,

315 U.S. 575, 585-86 (1942); Federal Power Com. v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591, 605 (1944); Duquesne

Light Co. v. Barasch, 488 U.S. 299, 307 (1989).

Page 387: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

387

undertakings which are attended by corresponding risks and uncertainties."1709 In our context,

as I explained above, other businesses which are to be compared to, are risk-free investments.

Issuers, which are forever guaranteed to cover all costs, are effectively operating without risk,

and risk-free investment is thus the proper standard to equate. Any higher rate of return causes

the interchange fee to fail its declared goals, and should be considered as abuse, just like a

public utility would - in the absence of regulation - abuse it market power by charging supra-

competitive prices.1710

For completeness it should be noted, that current approach of rate regulation which is applied

to some public utilities in the U.S., at least in the telecommunication sector, deviates from the

traditional rate-of-return methodology, and is based on a total element long-run incremental

cost methodology (TELRIC). Allegedly TELRIC methodology does not account for the rate of

return.1711 However, the cost of capital, which is another name for a rate of return, is

included.1712

885. SHVA and MASAV, the infrastructure firms of the payment industry in Israel,1713 are not

allowed to divide profits. They can earn, but not distribute, their profit.1714 This condition

continues to apply to SHVA1715 and MASAV until today.1716 SHVA and MASAV are both

1709 Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, 390 U.S. 747, 806, 88 S. Ct. 1344, 1380 (1968) 1710 P.R. Tel. Co. v. Telecomms. Regulatory Bd. of P.R., 665 F.3d 309, 316 (2011): “In order to prevent monopoly power

from leading to exorbitant prices, legislatures and administrative agencies became involved in setting the rates utilities

could charge consumers”; see also Consol. Edison Co. v. Pub. Serv. Comm'n, 447 U.S. 530, 553 (1980). 1711 Verizon Communs., Inc. v. FCC, 535 U.S. 467, 493 (2002) :In setting these rates, the state commissions are,

however, subject to that important limitation previously unknown to utility regulation: the rate must be "determined

without reference to a rate-of-return or other rate-based proceeding."; P.R. Tel. Co. v. Telecomms. Regulatory Bd. of

P.R., 665 F.3d 309, 316-17 (2011): “the FCC's TELRIC methodology -- which presumes a "forward-looking," "most

efficient," and "lowest cost" hypothetical network in the local market… represents a significant break from traditional

rate-setting models.”; See also Verizon Communs., Inc. v. FCC. At 489: “While the Act is like its predecessors in tying

the methodology to the objectives of "just and reasonable" and nondiscriminatory rates, 47 U.S.C. § 252 (d)(1), it is

radically unlike all previous statutes in providing that rates be set "without reference to a rate-of-return or other rate

based proceeding " § 252(d)(1)(A)(i). The Act thus appears to be an explicit disavowal of the familiar public-utility

model of rate regulation (whether in its fair-value or cost-of-service incarnations) presumably still being applied by

many States for retail sales… in favor of novel rate setting designed to give aspiring competitors every possible

incentive to enter local retail telephone markets, short of confiscating the incumbents' property.”; also id. At note 31. 1712 Id., at 496: “The TELRIC of an element has three components, the operating expenses, the depreciation cost, and

the appropriate risk-adjusted cost of capital." 1713 Supra ch. 8.1.7. 1714 Exemption with Conditions in re: SHVA, at 10 Antitrust 4804 (June 18, 2002); Exemption with Conditions in re:

SHVA, Antitrust 500549 (Sept 17, 2002). 1715 Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust 5001307 (Condition 2) (Nov. 5, 2008); Exemption

with Conditions to Five Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust 5001953 (May 22, 2012); Exemption with Conditions to Five

Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust 500224 (Sept. 20, 2012); Exemption with Conditions to SHVA, Antitrust 500369 (March

20, 2013); Exemption with Conditions to SHVA, Antitrust 500393 (1.5.13); Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in

re: SHVA, Antitrust 500459 (Aug. 26, 2013). 1716 Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 3014681, at 5 (condition 2) (June 20, 2002);

Exemption with Conditions to Five Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 5001308 (Nov. 5, 2008); Exemption with

Page 388: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

388

owned and controlled solely by their customers, which are the big banks. When the banks

negotiate prices with SHVA and MASAV, they have two inherent conflicts of interest:

885.1 In the role as customers (payers) the banks want to pay as little as possible. In their

role as SHVA or MASAV (payees) they have an interest to increase fees to the

maximum.

885.2 In addition, banks can use inflated payments to SHVA and MASAV as an entry

barrier. If SHVA and MASAV charge high fees, banks would be harmed as payers,

but at the same time inflated fees raise entry barriers for new competitors, which

would like to use the infrastructures of SHVA and MASAV. For the banks that own

SHVA and MASAV it is worthy to sacrifice expenditures, and let SHVA and

MASAV inflate prices, in order to raise entry barriers.

Banks that own SHVA and MASAV might expect that accrued profits in SHVA and MASAV

would eventually be transferred to them. As long as this does not happen, the profit limitation

imposed on SHVA and MASAV resembles my proposal, as it weakens part of the incentives

of SHVA and MASAV to inflate prices. However, the profit limitation on SHVA and MASAV

does not alleviate the second conflict of interest (inflated rates as an entry barrier).

My proposal does not suffer from such drawbacks. Under my proposal issuers cannot earn

profits (above a modest rate), all the more so issuers cannot accumulate undivided profits as

SHVA and MASAV can. As opposed to the owners of SHVA and MASAV, which derive

benefits from inflated rates even if profits cannot be distributed, issuers' owners do not have

any latent benefits from interchange fees that would mean no profit for them.

886. In the U.S., the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act requires insurance companies to

spend at least 80% to 85% of premium dollars on medical care. Insurance companies that fail

to meet this standard are required to provide a rebate to their customers.1717 This is very similar

Conditions to Five Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 5001954, at 6 (May 22, 2012); Exemption with Conditions to Five

Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 500368 (March 20, 2013). 1717 Richard A. Epstein & Paula M. Stannard, Constitutional Ratemaking and the Affordable Care Act: A New Source of

Vulnerability, 38 AM. J. L. & MED 243, 259 (2012): "[T]he ACA requires that health insurance issuers… spend at least

eighty percent of premium revenue, and that health insurance issuers in the large group market spend at least eighty-five

percent of premium revenue on medical claims or clinical services, and healthcare quality activities. If they do not, they

are required to refund the difference to enrollees on an annual basis.";

The Center for Consumer Information & Insurance Oversight, Medical Loss Ratio,

https://www.cms.gov/CCIIO/Programs-and-Initiatives/Health-Insurance-Market-Reforms/Medical-Loss-Ratio.html :

"MLR requires insurance companies to spend at least 80% or 85% of premium dollars on medical care, with the review

provisions imposing tighter limits on health insurance rate increases. If they fail to meet these standards, the insurance

companies will be required to provide a rebate to their customers starting in 2012".

Page 389: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

389

to limiting profits on medical insurance schemes to 15% or 20% of gross income.

My proposal is less intrusive because health insurers are not parties to any restrictive

arrangements and each insurer does not possess a monopoly position.1718 Therefore, the

arguments against imposing profit limitations are stronger against health insurers. Albeit this

criticism, profit limitations have been imposed on health insurers. This renders my proposal, to

limit profits on parties to a price fixing restrictive arrangement, even more plausible.

14.4. Additional Remarks

887. Supervision and regulation of the interchange fee exist worldwide anyway.1719 My proposal

does not interfere with business practices that were previously unregulated. On the contrary,

capping the level of the interchange fee is far more complicated than my proposal. Capping the

level requires a methodology to determine the cap, and then a calculation which implements

the methodology. Both stages consume vast regulatory resources, as shown in the survey of the

international regulation in chapter 8 above. My proposal consumes far less resources in

comparison to the extremely high regulatory efforts required to assess the information and to

calculate the "right" level of interchange fee.

888. My proposal bypasses the regulatory weakness known as "Regulatory lag” i.e., the period of

delay between the determination of the rate by regulators and the time it is applied.1720 For

example, the level of the interchange fee in Israel until 2018 was calculated on the basis of costs

and volumes of 2007-2009. The Antitrust General Director and the experts on his behalf had to

examine all issuers' costs, select their eligible part, quantify them and compute the numerator

and denominator of the fraction which comprise the interchange fee. This took years and

demanded vast resources.1721 When the "right" fee was finally calculated, it was already

outdated. Technology improvements and other innovations reduce costs (numerator reduction)

and at the same time volume of transaction increases annually (denominator increase).

Interchange fee, if calculated today in Israel, should probably be lower than the existing

0.7%,1722 which amounts to almost NIS 2 billion, as the volume of transactions in Israel

1718 Epstein & Stannard, id. 1719 Supra ch. 0. 1720 E.g., Richard A. Posner, Natural Monopoly and its Regulation, 21 STAN. L. REV. 548, 594 (1969): "[I]n the

considerable intervals of “regulatory lag” the profits of the regulated firm will pierce the ceiling imposed by the

regulatory agency if, as has frequently been the case in the regulated industries in recent years, costs are falling rapidly". 1721 Supra ¶¶ 0488 -499. 1722 Supra ¶ 502.

Page 390: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

390

exceeded NIS 260 billion in 2016.1723 I pointed to the ridiculous results of this in paras. 500-

503 above.

My proposal skips this difficulty. Increase in turnovers (denominator) or improvements in the

cost structure of payment card firms (numerator), which make the interchange fee a profit

source, are immediately detectable. Profits sticks-out from financial reports, and cannot be

concealed, especially in large financial firms, as explained in the next paragraph.

Implementation of the profit limitation can be done automatically by offset in the following

period. Any profit above a small rate of return, would be illegal, and thus automatically

deducted from the interchange fee in the next period.1724 I hope my proposal could be applied

when the current Trio Arrangement approval in Israel period ends (in 2018), so the limitation

on payment card companies in their next cross acquiring agreement would be a profit limitation

instead of a "level limitation".

889. Profit limitations can often be bypassed by inflating expenditures.1725 This concern was also

expressed by Rochet & Tirole. They recognized that interchange fee could be a source of profit

for issuers in a "cozy cartel" manner.1726 However, they also discussed second situation, in

which profits are dissipated as redundant expenditures and rewards, a situation they call

"wasteful competition":

Perhaps more complex is the case of wasteful competition. Suppose that issuers do

not tacitly collude, but compete in ways that bring limited benefits to consumers.

Then, if one cannot directly confront the source of wasteful competition, indeed it

seems reasonable not to account for issuer profits.1727

Rochet & Tirole agree that if the situation is of "wasteful competition" then just like in the

"cozy cartel" situation: "[I]t seems reasonable not to account for issuer profits". My proposal

fulfills this ambition, as it does not account for issuers' profit.

With respect to the crux of the "wasteful competition" argument, controlling shareholders of

issuers would gain nothing from inflating costs or bestowing redundant rewards on cardholders.

This is a good enough reason for not adopting a strategy of inflated costs and redundant rewards.

1723 Supra ch. 3.1 (payment card market data). 1724 Supra ¶ 887. 1725 Posner, Natural Monopoly and its Regulation, supra note 1728, at 601. 1726 Supra ¶¶ 479, 871. 1727 Rochet & Tirole, Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems, supra note 1672, at 11; Jean Tirole,

Payment Card Regulation and the use of Economic Analysis in Antitrust, 4 TOULOUSE SCHOOL ECON., at 17 (2011): “If

the profits associated with cardholders’ installed base are dissipated through wasteful advertising expenditures to

“acquire” cardholders, profits should not enter social welfare calculations”.

Page 391: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

391

In addition, the ability to dissipate costs and conceal profits in large scale is limited, for the

following reasons:

Payment card firms have well established bookkeeping that reveal their profits. Payment card

firms are not Mom-and-Pop stores, in which profits could be disguised as salaries or

management fees. Payment card firms are financial institutions whose shareholders are not their

managers. Those firms are not managed as small sized firms in which there is a mixture of

ownership and control. As Posner noted, in large financial institutions such as payment card

firms, wisecracks aimed to conceal profits cannot be substantial:

Most important, in a corporation with annual revenues of hundreds of millions of

dollars, the amounts diverted by management to its own use (whether directly or

in perquisites) above reasonable compensation are not likely to be substantial in

relation to the corporation's sales or even profits.1728

890. Inflating expenditures is not an attractive option for issuers, and thus would not frustrate my

proposal, for several additional reasons:

First, shareholders of issuers would gain nothing from any attempt to conceal profits as

expenditures (wasteful competition). Shareholders of issuers would definitely not sit aside if all

profits above a modest rate of return would evaporate for them, and there would be a sanction

of disgorgement of any profit and a strict prohibition on distribution of profits. They would

probably prefer to waive interchange fee from the outset.

Second, if the MSF rise, due to inflated expenditures (that must be returned to cardholders),

merchants might resort to surcharging, or refuse to accept the card carrying high rewards.

Third, rewards cause marginal cardholders (with less utility from cards) to adopt and use cards.

This, in turn, causes increase in the merchants' resistance to high fees.1729 Thus, following an

increase in (redundant) rewards (that is financed through interchange fees) merchants would be

less willing to accept expensive cards and more willing to surcharge them.1730

Fourth, even a substantial number multiplied by zero, is zeroed. If the rate of return is very

small, as risk-free rate of return is, multiplying it by a larger rate base such as inflated volume

1728 Richard A. Posner, Natural Monopoly and its Regulation, 21 STAN. L. REV. 548, 575 (1969). 1729 Supra ¶ 404. 1730 Rysman & Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, supra note 1676, at 11: "The reason merchants are still

somewhat sensitive to changes in the fee structure and less likely to accept cards when interchange fees are higher, is

due to the following additional effect. Facing higher rewards, some consumers will start using cards that previously did

not. These consumers therefore have a benefit of using cards that is lower than the average consumer. Thus, the mix of

consumers shifts towards those with lower values of using cards. Given that merchants also internalize the benefit their

customers get from using cards, merchants will be less likely to accept cards following an increase in interchange fees".

Page 392: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

392

of transactions driven by rewards would still be small and unattractive.

Fifth, rewards bestowed on cardholders increase volume of transactions, but not profit.

Calculation of permittable profit could be made by multiplying the risk free rate-of-return by a

base that is not sensitive to the volume of transactions and thus does not include rewards.1731

For example, permittable profit could be calculated by multiplying the rate of return in the

working capital. In Israel, profitability of payment card firms was measured by ROE – return

on equity (supra ¶ 60). This is in line with the idea of Rochet and Tirole, not to account for

issuers’ profit which is a result of wasteful competition. Thus, if the rate-base is not dependent

on volume, even if rewards increase volume of transaction, they would not increase profit. The

incentive to inflate rewards is curtailed at the outset.

Sixth, wasteful competition occurs when rewards are too high and cardholder fees become

negative. But before rewards turn cardholder fees to negative, cardholder fees should pass

through zero point. Zero cardholder fees, as opposed to negative cardholder fees (rewards),

raises less competitive concerns of usage externality.1732 The more probable result, if my

proposal would be implemented, is that issuers would give up interchange fee, so that the

massive rewards bestowed on cardholders, which are effectively bribes for shopping, would be

reduced.1733 Curtailing rewards is a pro-competitive outcome.1734

Seventh, in mature networks the network-effect of rewards is exhausted (see ¶ 336). Rewards

are set at an equilibrium level. Thus, opening “reward wars” would probably not be reflected

in larger market shares but mainly in a higher MSF, with no aggregate effect on the network.

In addition, wars must be financed, and higher MSF is funded by annoying merchants. This

poses a significant risk for an individual issuer who considers opening a reward war. Because

marginal utility of the newly attracted cardholders is small (marginal), an issuer that rewards

excessively risks surcharging or even total rejection of its cards by merchants. Lastly, when

issuers would know that the “prize” for conquering an additional market share, is only a tiny

rate of return, and considering the risks involved, they would probably be dissuaded from

engagement in excessive rewards from the outset.

Eight, the concern for excessive rewards is not unique to my proposal. Rewards are an

1731 Catherine Liston, Price-Cap versus Rate-of-Return Regulation, 5 J. Regulatory Econ. 25, 26 (1993): “Rate of return

regulation: Under ROR regulation, the regulator typically determines a revenue requirement based on a firm's

accounting costs during a test year. Such accounting costs incorporate operating costs, taxes, allowances for

depreciation, and allowed returns. The allowed return is a "reasonable" rate (an estimate of the cost of capital to the

firm) multiplied by a rate base which includes the undepreciated portion of investments relevant to regulated

operations, valued on a historical expenditure basis.” See also infra ¶ 892. 1732 Supra ¶¶ 651, 351 - 357. 1733 See supra ¶¶ 889 - 890. 1734 Supra ¶¶ 343 - 357; for further expansion see ch. 6.7.

Page 393: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

393

expenditure and as such, the concern for their inflation exists also under cost-based fee. In the

unlikely event issuers engage in wasteful competition, and bestow excessive rewards, although

gaining nothing from this, and the factors above do not restrain these redundant rewards, the

solution should be to limit rewards, a suggestion that has already been made in literature.1735

891. Another criticism of rate regulation is the difficulty to calculate the "proper" rate. Posner claims

that "[T]he determination of a “fair rate of return” on equity capital presents formidable

difficulties".1736 However, the main point of my proposal is not to hit a specific target, i.e., an

exact rate. The rate of return should not be an accurate number, which is a result of complicated

calculations. The rate of return should enable issuers to operate a viable risk-free business. For

issuers that are used to current profit ratios, any rate of return which reflects risk-free

investment, even on the high side, would be much lower than the profit rates issuers are used

to, and very unattractive. Issuers would probably prefer to waive interchange fees entirely and

be free to earn unlimited profits.

892. Posner claims that profit limitation ensures non-efficient monopoly a promised rate of return

without "materially increasing the penalty for failing to minimize costs."1737 However, this

criticism may be right only if the regulated profit is too high, so regulation stimulates

inefficiency without penalty. My proposal for a modest risk-free rate of return cannot, by

definition, be too high as the range of permitted profits rates are the lowest in the market (return

on risk free investments).

I do not purport to determine in this work the exact risk-free profitability which is to prevail

under my proposal. However, as a preliminary thought, the rate of return should be based on a

low benchmark such as the LIBOR (London Interbank Offered Rate) or the interest on U.S.

Treasury bills. A normal rate-of-return in the industry, e.g., the weighted average cost of capital

(WACC) does not fit, because it embodies a risk which does not exist for issuers that collect

interchange fee. I propose to calculate the maximum profitability by multiplying the risk-free

rate of return and a base rate. The base rate could be working capital or volume of transactions,

or equity (ROE), or any other base. The IAA General Director proposed other indices, i.e.,

ROCE or TIRR which can measure profitability, based on the company's performances, as

1735 Supra ch. 6.7 and ¶ 340. 1736 Posner, Natural Monopoly and its Regulation, supra note 1728, at 594. 1737 Ibid at 599.

Page 394: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

394

reflected in its financial statements.1738 I leave the determination of the accurate profitability

limitation for future research.

893. It has been argued that leaving profit margin to issuers will contribute to innovation, research

and development.1739 This argument, however, cannot be accepted as an excuse for a supra-

competitive interchange fee. Innovation is indeed important, but it should not be financed by a

cartel, let alone a cartel that derives its justification from spurious needs. In addition, to the

extent innovation is in the acquiring side, then if high profits are required to finance it, the

argument supports lower interchange fees.1740 Verdier gives an example where, in order to

finance innovation in the acquiring side of the British market (smart card readers), the

interchange fee had to be reduced.1741 Lastly, innovation costs are recognized and eligible costs.

As long as R&D expenses are not abused, interchange fee proceeds can finance them. My

proposal does not purport to limit innovation.

14.5. Reciprocal Relations Between My Proposals

894. My proposals are not complementarities. The proposal to divest issuers from acquirers is a

legislative proposal that would break up the interchange fee from being a restrictive

arrangement (apart from the minor joint negotiation). The proposal to limit profits alleviates

the competitive concerns from the interchange fee. Each of the proposals suffices on its own.

1738 Public Statement 1/17: The Antitrust Director General's Considerations In Enforcing The Prohibition Against

Unfairly High Prices (Feb. 28, 2017) http://www.antitrust.gov.il/eng/subject/177/item/34609.aspx : “[t]wo types of

indices standard for this are ROCE, which represents the yield created by the company's assets and which is calculated

by dividing the company's profits, excluding financing expenses, by the total active capital at a particular point in time;

and IRR or TIRR, which are the yield brought in by total anticipated cash flow as a result of the company's future

activity, capitalized to the relevant point in time, to zero.” 1739 See Marc Bourreau & Marianne Verdier, Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in Two-Sided Markets, 13 REV.

Network Econ. 175 (2014); Aghion Philippe et al., Competition and Innovation: An Inverted-U Relationship, 120 Q. J.

ECON. 701 (2005). 1740 Marianne Verdier, Interchange Fees and Incentives to Invest in Payment Card Systems, 28 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG.

539, 540 (2010): "When the Acquirer's contribution to investments is high, and when the consumers benefit more from

investments than the merchants, the Acquirer's investments may decrease with the interchange fee. Hence, in this case,

the payment platform may increase banks' joint profit by lowering the interchange fee to provide the Acquirer with

incentives to invest in quality, as this impacts the cardholders' demand positively";

Marc Bourreau & Marianne Verdier, Interchange Fees and Innovation in Payment Systems, SSRN Elibrary, at 33 (Oct.

8, 2013): "[W]hen there are strong adoption externalities, innovation is stronger with a zero interchange fee.

Otherwise, if adoption externalities are of a lower magnitude, the interchange fee that maximizes innovation is strictly

greater than zero. Cooperation does not stimulate innovation but, on the contrary, reduces quality investment. When

there are strong adoption externalities, this negative effect of cooperation is magnified with a higher interchange fee.

Our results have several policy implications. First, the interchange fee cannot be considered as an instrument that

increases the benefits of cooperation for innovation in retail payment systems. Second, when merchants have fixed costs

of adopting innovations and when consumers do not pay transaction fees, positive interchange fees benefit consumer

adoption only in specific circumstances; that is, when the degree of externality is low". 1741 Marianne Verdier, Interchange Fees and Incentives to Invest in Payment Card Systems, supra note 1740, at 549.

Page 395: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

395

895. However, the proposals do not contradict one another. The proposal to limit profits of issuers

integrates with the proposal for structural separation in an unexpected manner. Divestiture

softens the consequences of profit limitations for the payment card firms. If issuers and

acquirers are not separated, then applying my proposal to issuers, which are also acquirers,

means that those firms would not be able to earn profits at all, neither from acquiring nor from

issuing (above a modest rate of return).

A company that includes issuing and acquiring activities should use its income from any side

to cover any uncovered costs of the other side, before resorting to price fixing with

competitors.1742 Thus, imposing profit limitation on separated issuers is a more lenient

limitation than imposing profit limitation on issuers which are also acquirers.

15. Summary

896. In this work I tried to explore every angle of interchange fees, and to shed light on its mysteries

and complexities. I began with basic terms and market data to acquaint the reader with the topic.

Then I surveyed the historical development of interchange fees in credit card open networks,

as opposed to the interchange fee in debit cards and ATMs.

The main factor that affected the creation of positive interchange fees in credit cards were the

higher merchants' demand for cards. This high willingness to pay was exploited by allocating

most costs on them, and using interchange fee as a vehicle to induce demand among

cardholders. With debit cards, the networks had to induce merchants to join, and accordingly

the interchange fees tilted to the merchants' favor, with zero interchange fees at the extreme. In

both networks, what started as cost-based interchange fees evolved into demand-based

interchange fees when networks gained market power.

897. I continued with a survey of the legal proceedings and regulation of the interchange fees in

Israel, Europe, United States, Australia and other selected countries. I included in this survey,

inter alia, references to categories of interchange fees and the discrimination debate between

open and closed networks. Next, I explained the cost and benefits of payment instruments on

which the economic models are based upon. I discussed the basic model of Baxter, the

development in the model of Schmalensee, the strategic considerations of Rochet & Tirole,

1742 Supra ¶ 870.

Page 396: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

396

models of neutrality, competition, rewards, credit versus debit, and models that discussed the

optimal interchange fee.

898. A legal assessment of the interchange fee led to the conclusion that it is a minimum price fixing

agreement between competitors, which theoretically should have been banned by competition

authorities worldwide. However, the unique features of the interchange fee, as a mechanism to

internalize network and usage externalities in payment cards, which are two-sided network

market, led to a different result. Interchange fees are sanctioned worldwide despite the

competitive concerns they raise. After summarizing the competitive concerns, I examined

possible alternatives to the interchange fees, and why merchants do not surcharge. I concluded

with two proposals which, in my view, would make unnecessary much of the resources invested

under the current regime in supervising this area. First, I offer to separate issuers from acquirers.

Second, I offer to impose profit limitations on issuers which charge interchange fee, in order to

induce them to waive charging interchange fees.

899. Structural separation between issuers and acquirers would accomplish the vision of the

legislators and regulators who canceled the NAWI rule. Their intention was to enable the

entrance of independent acquirers. However, no regulator went far enough to obligate such a

proposed structural change. My proposal enforces the desire of competition authorities to

promote independent acquirers (which was the original intent behind the cancellation of the

NAWI rule). This intent was de-facto frustrated, as no independent acquirers who determine

the interchange fee they pay entered the payment system arena. Thus, my proposal fulfills the

legally desirable outcome that has not been achieved.

900. The proposal to limit issuers profit if they charge interchange fee, is a tool to cause them to

waive interchange fees. In case the fee is charged, my proposal approximates the interchange

fee to the optimal fee according to the consumer welfare standard. This standard dictates that

profits of issuers should not be accounted for in the interchange fee, and this is my proposal.

901. An assumption in the background of my proposal calls for further empirical research. I presume

that the decisive majority of cardholders have a positive benefit from payment cards. This

positive benefit warrants sufficient card usage even without exogenous incentives such as the

interchange fee,1743 and this justifies a default of zero interchange fee. When cardholders derive

sufficient benefits from cards, the networks would not be jeopardized and high level of card

1743 Supra note 189 and note 610 (the majority of consumers who currently receive rewards on credit and/or debit cards

would continue to use those payment methods even if rewards were no longer offered).

Page 397: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

397

usage can still be achieved even with very low interchange fees (and with the additional benefit

of low prices of goods). This assumption calls for further empirical research which I hope to

conduct in the future. An empirical study may confirm that cardholders' willingness to pay for

cards is high enough to sustain an independent issuing system, with little or no need for

subsidization from the merchant side.

902. Further empirical research is required to investigate at which level of the MSF, merchants

would start surcharging and cease accepting cards. My null hypothesis is that merchants would

not reject (or surcharge) cards, even if the MSF is well above their net benefits (i.e., the tourist

test) let alone the cost-based interchange fee. If this is verified, it would demonstrate the market

power of networks (as well as the mismatch of the tourist test), and would render my proposals

to evade such market power even more plausible.

-----------------The end------------------------

Page 398: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

398

Bibliography

1. LITERATURE ................................................................................................................................. 398 2. U.S. CASES ................................................................................................................................. 416 3. U.S. AUTHORITIES ................................................................................................................................. 417 4. FOREIGN AUTHORITIES ....................................................................................................................................... 418 5. INTERNATIONAL CASES ................................................................................................................................. 422 6. PAYMENT CARD DATA ................................................................................................................................. 423 7. HEBREW LEGISLATION ................................................................................................................................. 424 8. HEBREW LITERATURE ................................................................................................................................. 426 9. HEBREW CASES ................................................................................................................................. 426 10. ANTITRUST GENERAL DIRECTOR DECISIONS ........................................................................................................... 429 11. MISCELLANEOUS ................................................................................................................................. 431 12. HEBREW MISCELLANEOUS ....................................................................................................................................... 431

1. Literature

1. ABA, ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS (7 ed. 2012).

2. ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW, HANDBOOK ON THE ANTITRUST ASPECTS OF STANDARDS

SETTING (2004).

3. Sumit Agarwal et al., Why do Banks Reward their Customers to use their Credit Cards?,

(Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper No. 2010-19. 2010).

4. Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet & Chunlin Liu, The Importance of Adverse

Selection in the Credit Card Market: Evidence from Randomized Trials of Credit Card

Solicitations, 42 J. MONEY, CREDIT & BANK. 743 (2010).

5. Sumit Agarwal et al., Regulating Consumer Financial Products: Evidence from Credit Cards,

SSRN Elibrary (Aug. 2014).

6. Christian Ahlborn, Howard H. Chang & David S. Evans, The Problem of Interchange Fee

Analysis: Case without a Cause? 2 PAYMENT CARD REV. 183 (2004).

7. Niati Ahuja, Interchange Fees and Credit Card Issuing: An Empirical Investigation

(Preliminary Working Paper 2008).

8. Douglas Akers et al., Overview of Recent Developments in the Credit Card Industry, 17 FDIC

BANKING REV. 23 (2005).

9. Fernando Alvarez & Francesco Lippi, Cash Burns: An Inventory Model with a Cash-Credit

Choice, (EIEF Working Paper 02/15).

10. Andrea Amelio, Antitrust Assessment of MIF and the Tourist Test (Conference Proceeding ,

June 15, 2011).

11. Carlos Arango et al., Why is Cash (Still) so Entrenched?, (Bank of Canada Discussion Paper 2.

2012).

12. Carlos Arango, Kim P. Huynh & Leonard Sabetti, Consumer Payment Choice: Merchant Card

Acceptance Versus Pricing Incentives, 55 J. BANK. FIN. 130 (2015).

13. Carlos Arango & Varya Taylor, Merchants’ Costs of Accepting Means of Payment: Is Cash the

Least Costly? BANK OF CANADA REV. 15 (2008).

14. Guerino Ardizzi, Card Versus Cash: Empirical Evidence of the Impact of Payment Card

Interchange Fees on End Users’ Choice of Payment Methods, 1 J. FIN. INTERMEDIATION 73

(2013).

15. P. E. AREEDA, III ANTITRUST LAW, 147.

Page 399: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

399

16. P. E. AREEDA & H. HOOVENKAMP, VII ANTITRUST LAW 370 ¶ 1505 (2d ed. 2003).

17. Mark Armstrong, Competition in Two-Sided Markets, 37 RAND J. ECON. 668 (2006).

18. Mark Armstrong & Julian Wright, Two-Sided Markets, Competitive Bottlenecks and Exclusive

Contracts, 32 ECO. THEORY 353 (2007).

19. MARK ARMSTRONG & DAVID E. M. SAPPINGTON, RECENT DEVELOPMENTS IN THE THEORY OF

REGULATION IN 3 HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION, ch. 27 (Asymmetric Cost

Information) (2007).

20. KENNETH J. ARROW, SOCIAL CHOICE AND INDIVIDUAL VALUES (2d ed. 1963).

21. Maria Aspan, New B of A Fee may Hasten Debit's Demise, Am. Banker, Sept. 29 2011, http://www.americanbanker.com/issues/176_190/bank-of-america-debit-card-fees-interchange-1042682-1.html.

22. Lawrence M. Ausubel, Adverse Selection in the Credit Card Market (University of Maryland

Working Paper 1999).

23. STRUCTURAL REFORM IN THE CAPITAL MARKET INTER-MINISTERIAL COMMITTEE REPORT

(BACHAR REPORT) (Sept. 2004).

24. Martin Baily & Robert E. Litan, Toward Reasonable Regulation of Debit Card Interchange

Fees: The Case for Modifying the Federal Reserve Board's December 16, 2010 Proposals

(2011), available at http://ideas.repec.org/p/reg/wpaper/642.html.

25. David Balto, The Problem of Interchange Fees: Costs without Benefits? E.C.L.R 215 (2000).

26. Oren Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, 98 N.W.L.R. 1373 (2004).

27. Oren Bar-Gill & Ryan Bubb, Credit Card Pricing: The Card Act and Beyond, 97 CORNELL L.

Rev. 967 (2012).

28. Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. PA. L. REV. 1 (2008).

29. Avner Bar-Ilan & Nancy Marion, Demand for Cash with Intra-Period Endogenous

Consumption, 37 J. ECON. DYNAMICS & CONTROL 2668 (2013).

30. William F. Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper: Legal and Economic

Perspectives, 26 J. L. ECON. 541 (1983).

31. Ozlem Bedre-Defolie & Emilio Calvano, Pricing Payment Cards, 5 AM. ECON. J.

MICROECONOMICS 206 (2013).

32. Mats A. Bergman, Two-Sided Network Effects, Bank Interchange Fees, and the Allocation of

Fixed Costs (Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. 185. 2005).

33. Mats Bergman et al., The Costs of Paying – Private and Social Costs of Cash and Card

Payments (Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper No 212. 2007).

34. Efraim Berkovich, Card Rewards and Cross-Subsidization in the Gasoline and Grocery

Markets, 11 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1 (2012).

35. Tara Siegel Bernard, In Retreat, Bank of America Cancels Debit Card Fee, N.Y. TIMES, Nov.

1, 2011.

36. Martin Betts, Peter Black, Sharon Christensen, Ed Dawson, Rong Du, William Duncan, Ernest

Foo, Juan González Nieto, Security, legal and risk issues relating to e-tendering, at 19 (2006)

37. Virag Ilona Blazsek, The 2009 Interchange Fee Decision of the Hungarian Competition

Authority: A Comparative Case Study (Central European University 2010).

38. Adrian Blundell-Wignall, Paul Atkinson & Caroline Roulet, Bank Business Models and the

Separation Issue, 2 OECD J. FIN. MARKET TRENDS (2013).

Page 400: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

400

39. DAVID BOAZ, CREDIT CARD MARKET IN ISRAEL, GENERAL ANALYSIS, CONCLUSIONS AND

RECOMMENDATIONS (Dec. 2009).

40. Wilko Bolt, Retail Payment Systems: Competition, Innovation, and Implications, DNB

Working Paper 362 (Dec. 2012).

41. ———. , Pricing, Competition and Innovation in Retail Payment Systems: A Brief Overview, 1

J. FIN. MARKET INFRASTRUCTURE 73 (2013).

42. ———. , The Role and Regulation of Interchange Fees in European Payments Cards

(Presentation in Conference entitled “The Role and Regulation of Interchange Fees in European

Payment Cards” held in Brussels. June 15, 2011.

43. Wilko Bolt & Sujit Chakravorti, Digitization of Retail Payments (DNB Working Paper 270.

2010).

44. ———. , A Review of Payment Card Economics (Aug. 15 2010) http://pymnts.com/a-review-of-payment-card-economics/.

45. ———. , Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment Media (FRB of Chicago

Working Paper No. 2008-11. 2008).

46. ———. , Economics of Payment Cards: A Status Report, 32 ECON. PERSPECTIVES 15 (2008).

47. Wilko Bolt et al., Consumer Credit and Payment Cards (ECB Working Paper 1387. 2011).

48. Wilko Bolt & David Humphrey, Competition in Bank-Provided Payment Services, 1539 ECB

Occasional Paper Series (2013).

49. Wilko Bolt, Nicole Jonker & Mirjam Plooij, Tourist Test Or Tourist Trap? Unintended

Consequences of Debit Card Interchange Fee Regulation, DNB Working Paper 405 (2013).

50. Wilko Bolt & Heiko Schmiedel, SEPA, EFFICIENCY, AND PAYMENT CARD COMPETITION (DNB

Working Paper 239/2009).

51. Wilko Bolt, Retail Payments in the Netherlands: Facts and Theory, 154 DE ECONOMIST 345

(2006).

52. Wilko Bolt, Nikole Jonker & corry Van Renselaar, Incentives at the Counter: An Empirical

Analysis of Surcharging Card Payments and Payment Behaviour in the Netherlands, 34 J.

BANK. FIN. 1738 (2010).

53. Ann Borestam & Heiko Schmiedel, Interchange Fees in Payment Cards, ECB Occasional

Paper Series 131 (2011).

54. Ron Borzekowski & Elizabeth k. Kiser, Consumers’ use of Debit Cards: Patterns, Preferences,

and Price Response, 40 J. MONEY, CREDIT & BANK. 149 (2008).

55. Pierre Bos, International Scrutiny of Payment Card Systems, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 739 (2006).

56. Hélène Bourguignon, Renato Gomes & Jean Tirole, Shrouded Transaction Costs, CEPR

Discussion Paper no. DP10171 (Sept. 2014).

57. Marc Bourreau & Marianne Verdier, Interchange Fees and Innovation In Payment Systems,

SSRN (Oct. 8, 2013).

58. ———. , Private Cards and the Bypass of Payment Systems by Merchants, 34 J. BANK. FIN.

1798 (2010).

59. _______. , Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in Two-Sided Markets, 13 REV. NETWORK

ECON. 175 (2014).

60. ———. , Cooperation Models for the Development of Mobile Payment Solutions, 1 LYDIAN

PAYMENT J. 23 (2010).

Page 401: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

401

61. Terri Bradford & Fumiko Hayashi, Developments in Interchange Fees in the United States and

Abroad (FRB Kansas Payments Sys. Res. Briefing, 2008).

62. Tamás Briglevics & Oz Shy, Why Don’t most Merchants use Price Discounts to Steer

Consumer Payment Choice?, (12-9 FRB Boston, 2012).

63. Hans Brits & Carlo Winder, Payments are no Free Lunch, 3 DNB Occasional Studies (2005).

64. Tom Brown, Re-Routing the Exclusivity and Routing Provisions of the Durbin Amendment,

LYDIAN PAYMENT J. (2011).

65. Luis Cabral, Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment, 5 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 15 (2005).

66. Guido Calabresi & Douglas Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules and Inalienability: One

View of the Cathedral, 85 HARV. L. REV. 1089 (1972).

67. Emilio Calvano, Note on the Economic Theory of Interchange (Market Platform Dynamics,

2011).

68. ———. , Action on Payment Cards (A Few) Insights from Theory (Conference Proceeding, 15

June, 2011).

69. Gabriele Camera, Marco Casari & Stefania Bortolotti, An Experiment on Retail Payments

Systems, ESI Working Paper (Jul. 2015).

70. Santiago Carbo Valverde et al., Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation

(Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper No. 09-11. 2009).

71. Santiago Carbo-Valverde & Jose Linares-Zegarra M., How Effective are Rewards Programs in

Promoting Payment Card Usage? Empirical Evidence, 35 J. BANK. FIN. 3275 (2011).

72. Dennis W. Carlton & Alan S. Frankel, The Antitrust Economics of Credit Card Networks, 63

ANTITRUST L.J. 643 (1995).

73. DENNIS W. CARLTON & JEFFREY M. PERLOFF, MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION (3d ed.

2000).

74. Dennis W. Carlton & Ralph A. Winter, Competition Policy and Regulation in Credit Card

Markets: Insights from Single-Sided Market Analysis (2014).

75. ———. , Vertical Restraints in Two-Sided Markets: Credit Card No Surcharge Rules

(Presentation), (Jul 5, 2015).

76. Dennis Carlton & S. Alan Frankel, Transaction Costs, Externalities, and "Two Sided" Payment

Markets, 2005 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 617 (2005).

77. Sujit Chakravorti, Externalities in Payment Card Networks: Theory and Evidence, 9 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 1 (2010).

78. ———. , Theory of Credit Card Networks: A Survey of the Literature, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON.

50 (2003).

79. Sujit Chakravorti & William R. Emmons, Who Pays for Credit Cards? 37 J. CONSUMER AFF.

208 (2003).

80. Sujit Chakravorti & Roberto Roson, Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Case of

Payment Networks, 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 118 (2006).

81. Sujit Chakravorti & Alpa Shah, Underlying Incentives in Credit Card Networks, 48 ANTITRUST

BULL. 53 (2003).

82. Sujit Chakravorti & Ted To, A Theory of Credit Cards, 25 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 583 (2007).

Page 402: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

402

83. Howard H. Chang, Payment Card Industry Primer, 2 PAYMENT CARD REV. 29 (2004).

84. ———. , Interchange Fees in the Courts and Regulatory Authorities 1 PAYMENT CARD REV.

13 (2003).

85. Howard H. Chang & David S. Evans, The Competitive Effects of the Collective Setting of

Interchange Fees by Payment Card Systems, 45 ANTITRUST BULL. 641 (2000).

86. Howard H. Chang, David S. Evans & Richard Schmalensee, Some Economic Principles for

Guiding Antitrust Policy Towards Joint Ventures (1997).

87. Howard Chang, David S. Evans & Daniel D. Garcia Swartz, The Effect of Regulatory

Intervention in Two-Sided Markets: An Assessment of Interchange-Fee Capping in Australia, 4

REV. NETWORK ECON. 328 (2005).

88. Julia S. Cheney, Prepaid Cards: An Important Innovation in Financial Services, Fed. Res.

Bank Phila. (2006).

89. JACOB CHERTOF AND AMI TZADIK, CREDIT CARDS MARKET: ANALYSIS, REGULATION AND

INTERNATIONAL COMPARISON, Knesset Research Center (2010).

90. Andrew T. Ching & Fumiko Hayashi, Payment Card Rewards Programs and Consumer

Payment Choice, 34 J. BANK. FIN. 1773 (2010).

91. Alex Chisholm, Speech given at the Regulatory Policy Institute Annual Conference (Sept. 10,

2014).

92. Fennee Chong, Credit Card Dues, Annual Summit on Business and Entrepreneurial Studies,

196 (2011)

93. Ronald Coase, The Problem of Social Costs, 3 J. L. & ECON. 1 (1960).

94. VINCENT CONITZER AND TOBY WALSH, Barriers to Manipulation in Voting in 127 HANDBOOK

OF COMPUTATIONAL SOCIAL CHOICE (Cambridge 2016)

95. Lloyd Constantine, Jeffrey I. Shinder & Kerin E. Coughlin, In Re Visa Check/Mastermoney

Antitrust Litigation: A Study of Market Failure in a Two-Sided Market, 2005 COLUM. BUS. L.

REV. 599 (2005).

96. Don Cruickshank, Competition in UK Banking: A Report to the Chancellor of the Exchequer

U.K. Stationery Office (2000).

97. Amy Dawson and Carl Hugener, A New Business Model for Card Payments (WayToHigh.com:

Diamond Management and Technology Consultants, Inc., 2008), http://waytoohigh.wordpress.com/2008/07/18/a-new-business-model-for-card-payments-via-diamond-management-technology-consultants/.

98. Ramon P. Degennaro, Merchant Acquirers and Payment Card Processors: A Look Inside the

Black Box (FRB ATLANTA ECON. REV., 2006).

99. Patrick DeGraba, Efficient Inter-Carrier Compensation for Competing Networks when

Customers Share the Value of a Call (2002).

100. Allard E. Dembe & Leslie I. Boden, Moral Hazard: A Question of Morality? 3 NEW

SOLUTIONS 257 (2000).

101. Christopher C. DeMuth, The Case Against Credit Card Interest Rate Regulation, 3 YALE J.

REG. 201 (1986).

102. Weisman L. Dennis, Optimal Price Allocations in Two-Sided Markets, 9 REV. NETWORK ECON.

1 (2010).

Page 403: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

403

103. Avril McKean Dieser, Antitrust Implications of the Credit Card Interchange Fee and an

International Survey, 17 LOY. CONSUMER L. REV. 451 (2005).

104. Rong Ding, Merchant Internalization Revisited, 125 ECON. LETTERS 347 (2014).

105. Rong Ding & Julian Wright, Payment Card Interchange Fees and Price Discrimination (2015).

106. Jocelyn Donze & Isabelle Dubec, Article 3, ATM Direct Charging Reform: The Effect of

Independent Deployers on Welfare, 10 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1 (2011).

107. Duncan B. Douglass, An Examination of the Fraud Liability Shift in Consumer Card-Based

Payment Systems, FRB Chicago 43 (2009).

108. ANTHONY J. DUKES, ADVERTISING AND COMPETITION, in ISSUES IN COMPETITION LAW AND

POLICY 515 (ABA Section of Antitrust Law, 2008).

109. MacDonald A. Duncan, What MasterCard’s IPO Means for Merchant Suit, AM. BANKER (June

9, 2006).

110. Richard J. Durbin, Letter to Bank of America (Oct. 3, 2011) http://durbin.senate.gov/public/index.cfm/files/serve?File_id=c57f9acb-7a87-4bb9-a2d0-211189c364d0.

111. Thomas A. Durkin, Gregory Elliehausen & Todd J. Zywicki, An Assessment of Behavioral Law

and Economics Contentions and what we Know Empirically about Credit Card use by

Consumers, George Mason Law & Econ. Research Paper no. 14-46 (2014).

112. David Easley and Jon Kleinberg, Voting, in 735 NETWORKS, CROWDS, AND MARKETS:

REASONING ABOUT A HIGHLY CONNECTED WORLD (2010).

113. NICHOLAS ECONOMIDES, COMPETITION POLICY ISSUES IN THE CONSUMER PAYMENTS INDUSTRY,

in MOVING MONEY: THE FUTURE OF CONSUMER PAYMENT 113 (R. Litan & M. Baily eds.,

2009).

114. Nicholas Economides & David Henriques, To Surcharge Or Not to Surcharge? A Two-Sided

Market Perspective of the no-Surcharge Rule (ECB Working Paper No. 1338, Oct. 2011).

115. Benjamin Edelman & Julian Wright, Price Coherence and Excessive Intermediation, (2014).

116. Erich Emch, Market Definition and Market Power in Payment Card Networks, 5 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 45 (2006).

117. Richard A. Epstein & Paula M. Stannard, Constitutional Ratemaking and the Affordable Care

Act: A New Source of Vulnerability, 38 AM. J. L. & MED 243 (2012).

118. EUROPE ECONOMICS, THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF INTERCHANGE FEE REGULATION IN THE UK, Final

Report, (June 28, 2013).

119. David S. Evans, The Antitrust Economics of Multi-Sided Markets, 20 YALE J. ON REG. 325

(2003).

120. ———. , The Antitrust Economics of Two-Sided Markets, SSRN (2002).

121. ———. Viewpoint: Bank Interchange Fees Balance Dual Demand, AM. BANKER (Jan. 26,

2001).

122. David S. Evans, Howard H. Chang & Margaret M. Weichert, Economic Analysis of Claims in

Support of the Durbin Amendment to Regulate Debit Card Interchange Fees, SSRN (2011).

123. David S. Evans, Robert E. Litan & Richard Schmalensee, Economic Analysis of the Effects of

the Federal Reserve Board's Proposed Debit Card Interchange Fee Regulations on Consumers

and Small Businesses (2011) available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1769887.

Page 404: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

404

124. David S. Evans & Abel M. Mateus, How Changes in Payment Card Interchange Fees Affect

Consumers Fees and Merchant Prices: An Economic Analysis with Applications to the

European Union, SSRN (2011) available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1878735.

125. David S. Evans & Richard Schmalansee, Failure to Launch: Critical Mass in Platform

Businesses, 9 REV. NETWORK ECON. (2010).

126. ———. , MARKETS WITH TWO-SIDED PLATFORMS, in 1 ISSUES IN COMPETITION LAW AND

POLICY 667 (ABA Section of Antitrust Law 2008).

127. ______. , The Economics of Interchange Fees and their Regulation: An Overview, Payments

System Research Conferences 73 (2005).

128. ———. , Economic Aspects of Payment Card Systems and Antitrust Policy Toward Joint

Ventures, 2 ANTITRUST L.J. 861 (1995).

129. David S. Evans, Howard Chang & Joyce Steven, The Impact of the U.S. Debit Card

Interchange Fee Regulation on Consumer Welfare: An Event Study Analysis, University of

Chicago, Institute for Law and Economics Working Paper (2013).

130. DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION

IN BUYING AND BORROWING (2d ed. 2005).

131. David S. Evans, More than Money: The Development of a Competitive Electronic Payments

Industry in the United States, 2 PAYMENT CARD REV. 1 (2004).

132. Joseph Farrell, Efficiency and Competition between Payment Instruments, 5 REV. NETWORK

ECON. 26 (2006).

133. David E. Feller, A General Theory of the Collective Bargaining Agreement, 61 Cal. L.REV. 663

(1973).

134. Lapo Filistrucchi, A SSNIP Test for Two-Sided Markets: The Case of Media (NET Inst.

Working Paper 08-34, 2008).

135. Tom Fish & Roy Whymark, How has Cash Usage Evolved in Recent Decades? What Might

Drive Demand in the Future? 3 BANK OF ENGLAND Q. BULL. (2015).

136. Amelia Fletcher, Predatory Pricing in Two-Sided Markets: A Brief Comment, 3 COMPETITION

POL'Y INTE'L 221 (2007).

137. Albert Foer, Electronic Payment Systems and Interchange Fees: Breaking the Log Jam on

Solutions to Market Power, American Antitrust Institute (2010).

138. Albert A. Foer, Our $48 Billion Credit Card Bill, N.Y TIMES (Apr. 20, 2010).

139. Dominique Forest & Vaigauskaite Dovile, EC Competition Policy in the Payments Area: New

Developments in MIFs for Cards and SEPA Direct Debit, 2 EC COMPETITION POL'Y NEWSL. 38

(2009).

140. Alan S. Frankel, Towards a Competitive Card Payments Marketplace, RBA 27 (2007).

141. ———. , Monopoly and Competition in the Supply and Exchange of Money 66 ANTITRUST L.J.

313 (1998).

142. ———. , Interchange in various Countries: Commentary on Weiner and Wright, FRB Kansas

51 (2005).

143. Alan S. Frankel & Allan L. Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, 73

ANTITRUST L.J. 627 (2006).

144. Colin Graham Fraser, An Illinois Brick Wall without Foundation: The “Price Paid” Rule and

the Roadmap to Antitrust Immunity (2013).

Page 405: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

405

145. Mark Furletti, Prepaid Card Markets & Regulation, Fed. Res. Bank Phila. (2004).

146. M. Anthony Fusaro, Why do People use Debit Cards: Evidence from Checking Accounts, 51

ECON. INQUIRY (2013).

147. Joshua S. Gans & Stephen P. King, Approaches to Regulating Interchange Fees in Payment

Systems, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 125 (2003).

148. ———. , The Neutrality of Interchange Fees in Payment Systems, 3 TOPICS ECON. ANALYSIS &

POL'Y 1 (2003).

149. Stephen King & Rodney Maddock, Direct Charging of Card Fees (Monash University

Working Paper, May 2017)

150. Daniel D. Garcia Swartz, Robert W. Hahn & Anne Layne-Farrar, The Move Toward a Cashless

Society: A Closer Look at Payment Instrument Economics, 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 175

(2006).

151. ———. , The Move Toward a Cashless Society: Calculating the Costs and Benefits, 5 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 199 (2006).

152. Daniel Garcia-Swarz, Robert W. Hahn & Anne Layne-Farrar, Further Thoughts on the

Cashless Society: A Reply to Dr. Shampine, 6 REV. NETWORK ECON. 509 (2007).

153. Alex Gershkov, Benny Moldovanu and Xianwen Shi, Optimal Voting Rules (2016)

154. David Gilo, The Anticompetitive Effect of Passive Investment, 99 MICH. L. REV. 1 (2000).

155. David Gilo & Yossi Spiegel, The Credit Card Industry in Israel, 4 REV. NETWORK ECON. 266

(2005).

156. ——. , Network Interconnection with Competitive Transit, 16 INFO. ECON. POL'Y 439 (2004).

157. ——. , VERTICAL RESTRAINTS, in A LEGAL AND ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST LAW 323

(Michal Gal and Menahem Perlman eds., 2008)

158. Anca-Iulia Gîrjob & Maria-Raluca Gîrbacea, The Impact of Interchange Fees on Merchants

and Consumers, 2 ROMANIAN COMPETITION J. 83 (2013).

159. Jakub Gorka, Payment Behaviour in Poland – the Benefits and Costs of Cash, Cards and Other

Non-Cash Payment Instruments (Draft), (2012).

160. Hugh Green, Australia’s 2009 ATM Reforms: Transparency for Transparency’s Sake, 19

AGENDA 1 (2012).

161. Olaf Gresvik & Harald Haare, Costs in the Norwegian Payment System, 4 Norges Bank Staff

Memo (2009).

162. ———. , Costs in the Payment System, 80 NORGES BANK ECON. BULLETIN 16 (2009).

163. Margaret Guerin-Calvert & Janusz a. Ordover, Merchant Benefits and Public Policy Towards

Interchange: An Economic Assessment, 4 REV. NETWORK ECON. 384 (2005).

164. Gonenc Gurkaynak et al., Multisided Markets and the Challenge of Incorporating Multisided

Considerations into Competition Law Analysis, J. ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 1 (2016).

165. Graeme Guthrie & Julian Wright, Competing Payment Schemes, 55 J. INDUS. ECON. 37 (2007).

166. Andrei Hagiu & Julian Wright, Multi-Sided Platforms (2011).

167. H. L. A. HART, THE CONCEPT OF LAW (1961).

168. Iftekhar Hasan, Tanya De Renzis & Heiko Schmiedel, Retail Payments and the Real Economy,

ECB Working Paper 1572 (Aug. 2013).

Page 406: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

406

169. Iftekhar Hasan, Emmi Martikainen & Tuomas Takalo, Promoting Efficient Retail Payments in

Europe, 20 Bank of Finland Research Discussion Papers (2014).

170. David Havyatt , Why Vertical Structural Separation is in the Interests of Incumbent Telcos, and

Why they don’t See it, available at http://www.havyatt.com.au/docs/wps/TJA1.pdf.

171. Fumiko Hayashi, The New Debit Card Regulations: Effects on Merchants, Consumers, and

Payments System Efficiency, 1 FRB KANSAS Q. REV. 89 (2013).

172. ———. , Discounts and Surcharges: Implications for Consumer Payment Choice, Payments

Sys. Research Briefing FRB Kansas City (2012).

173. ———. , The New Debit Card Regulations: Initial Effects on Networks and Banks, 4 FRB

KANSAS CITY ECON. REV 79 (2012).

174. ———. , Do U.S Consumers really Benefit from Payment Card Rewards? FRB KANSAS ECON.

REV. 37 (2009).

175. ———. , The Economics of Payment Cards Fee Structure: What Drives Payment Card

Rewards? (FRB Of Kansas City Working paper 08-07, 2009).

176. ———. , The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: Policy Considerations of Payment

Card Rewards (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No. 08-08, 2008).

177. ———. , The Economics of Payment Card Fee Structure: What is the Optimal Balance

between Merchant Fee and Payment Card Rewards? (FRB of Kansas City Working Paper No.

08-06. 2008).

178. ———. , Network Competition and Merchant Discount Fees (FRB Kansas City, Payments

System Research Department Working Paper 05-04, 2006).

179. ———. , Pricing and Welfare Implications of Payment Card Network Competition (FRB

Kansas City Working Paper 06-03, 2006).

180. ———. , A Puzzle of Card Payment Pricing: Why are Merchants Still Accepting Card

Payments? 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 144 (2006).

181. ———. , Public Authority Involvement in Payment Card Markets: Various Countries August

2013 Update (Payments Sys. Research Department of the Fed. Res. Bank of Kansas City).

182. Fumiko Hayashi & Emily Cuddy, General Purpose Reloadable Prepaid Cards: Penetration,

Use, Fees and Fraud Risks, FRB Kansas (Feb. 2014).

183. Fumiko Hayashi & William R. Keeton, Measuring the Costs of Retail Payment Methods (Fed.

Bank of Kansas City Paper, 2012).

184. Fumiko Hayashi & Jesse Leigh Maniff, Public Authority Involvement in Payment Card

Markets: Various Countries August 2014 Update (FRB Kansas, Aug. 2014).

185. Fumiko Hayashi & Joanna Stavins, Effects of Credit Scores on Consumer Payment Choice,

FRB Boston Discussion Paper 12-1 (2012).

186. Fumiko Hayashi et al., A Guide to the ATM and Debit Card Industry 2006 Update (Payment

System Research Department FRB of Kansas City ed.

187. Fumiko Hayashi, Richard Sullivan and Stuart E. Weiner, A Guide to the ATM and Debit Card

Industry (Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas, 2003).

188. Fumiko Hayashi & Stuart E. Weiner, Interchange Fees in Australia the U.K and the United

States: Matching Theory and Practice, FRB KANSAS ECON. REV. 75 (2006).

189. Fumiko Hayashi, Payment Card Interchange Fees and Merchant Service Charges - an

International Comparison, 1 LYDIAN PAYMENT J. 6 (2010).

Page 407: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

407

190. Alberto Heimler, Payment Cards Pricing Patterns: The Role of Antitrust and Regulatory

Authorities, SSRN (2010) available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1574292.

191. ———. , The Economics of Card Payments (Conference Proceeding June 15, 2011).

192. Herbert Hovenkamp, Quantification of Harm in Private Antitrust Actions in the United States

(OECD POLICY ROUNDTABLE QUANTIFICATION OF HARM 209 DAF/COMP(2011)25)

193. ——. , The Taking Clause and Improvident Regulatory Bargains, 108 YALE L.J. 801 (1999).

194. Brad G. Hubbard, The Durbin Amendment, Two-Sided Markets, and Wealth Transfers: An

Examination of Unintended Consequences Three Years Later, SSRN (2013).

195. David B. Humphrey, Retail Payments: New Contributions, Empirical Results, and Unanswered

Questions, 34 J. BANK. FIN. 1729 (2010).

196. ———. , Payment Scale Economies, Competition, and Pricing (ECB Working Paper No. 1136,

2009).

197. David B. Humphrey, Moshe Kim & Bent Vale, Realizing the Gains from Electronic Payments:

Costs, Pricing, and Payment Choice, 33 J. MONEY, CREDIT & BANK. 216 (2001).

198. David Humphrey et al., What does it Cost to make a Payment? 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 159

(2003).

199. Robert M. Hunt, An Introduction to the Economics of Payment Card Networks, 2 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 80 (2003).

200. Frederic Jenny, Competition Policy Issues in the Financial Services Sector: Regulation of the

Interchange Fees in Credit Card Systems (Conference Proceeding, 2008).

201. Ginger Zhe Jin & Marc Rysman, Platform Pricing at Sports Card Conventions (NBER

Working Paper 17959, 2012).

202. Andrew R. Johnson, Fees on Cup of Coffee Raised From 8 Cent to 23 Cent, MasterCard, Visa

Raising Small Debit Buy Fees, Marketwatch (Sept. 22, 2011).

203. Peter Jones, Will Europe’s Acquiring Market be Dominated by Non Banks? (2009).

204. ———. , The Uncomfortable Consequences of a Universal Multi-Lateral Interchange Fee

(MIF) for Europe, Payment Sys. Europe (2005).

205. Nicole Jonker, Social Costs of POS Payments in the Netherlands 2002–2012: Efficiency Gains

from Increased Debit Card Usage, 2 DNB Occasional Studies (2013).

206. ———. , Card Acceptance and Surcharging: The Role of Costs and Competition, 10 REV.

NETWORK ECON. (2011).

207. Nicole Jonker & Mirjam Plooij, Tourist Test Interchange Fees for Card Payments: Down Or

Out? 1 J. FIN. MARKET INFRASTRUCTURE 51 (2013).

208. M. Charles Kahn & William Roberds, Why Pay? Introduction to Payment Economics, 18 J.

FIN. INTERMEDIATION 1 (2009).

209. Andrew Kahr, Why Allow Only Banks to Issue Credit Cards? AM. BANKER (Aug. 22, 2012).

210. Ulf von Kalckreuth et al., Using Cash to Monitor Liquidity – Implications for Payments,

Currency Demand and Withdrawal Behavior (Deutsche Bundesbank Discussion Paper

22/2011).

211. Mika Kato, Jean Tirole, Nobel Prize Winner (Aug. 28, 2015).

Page 408: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

408

212. Michael L. Katz, What do we Know about Interchange Fees and what does it Mean for Public

Policy? Commentary on Evans and Schmalensee, FRB Kansas Payments Sys. Res. Conference

121 (2005).

213. MICHAEL L. KATZ, REFORM OF CREDIT CARDS SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA COMMISSIONED REPORT

(Reserve Bank of Australia, 2001).

214. BENJAMIN Kay, Mark D. Manuszak & Cindy M. Vojtech, Bank Profitability and Debit Card

Interchange Regulation: Bank Responses to the Durbin Amendment (2014).

215. Phillip Keitel, A Prepaid Case Study: Ready Credit’s General-Purpose & Transit-Fare

Programs (Fed. Reserve Bank of Phil. Discussion Paper. 2012).

216. ———. , Federal Regulation of the Prepaid Card Industry: Costs, Benefits, and Changing

Industry Dynamics (Conference Summary Payment Cards Center Fed. Res. Bank of

Philadelphia, 2010).

217. Éva Keszy-Harmath et al., The Role of the Interchange Fee in Card Payment Systems (MNB

Occasional papers 96, 2012).

218. Ann Kjos, The Merchant-Acquiring Side of the Payment Card Industry: Structure, Operations,

and Challenges (FRB of Philadelphia Discussion Paper 2007).

219. Benjamin Klein et al., Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Antitrust Economics of Payment

Card Interchange Fees, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 571 (2006).

220. Soren Korsgaard, Paying for Payments Free Payments and Optimal Interchange Fees, 1682

ECB Working Paper (2014).

221. Jean-Jacques Laffont, Patrick Rey & Jean Tirole, Network Competition 1. Overview and

Nondiscriminatory Pricing, 29 RAND J. ECON. 1 (1998).

222. Ian Lee et al., Credit Where It’s due: How Payment Cards Benefit Canadian Merchants and

Consumers, and how Regulation can Harm them, George Mason University Law and

Economics Research Paper Series 13-58 (Oct. 2013).

223. Sungbok Lee, The Effects of Issuer Competition on the Credit Card Industry: A Case Study of

the Two-Sided Market, (2010) available at http://www.javanfish.com/file/The%20Effects%20of%20Issuer%20Competition%20On%20the%20Credit%20Card%20Industry_October2010.pdf.

224. Harry Leinonen, Debit Card Interchange Fees Generally Lead to Cash-Promoting Cross-

Subsidisation (Bank of Finland Research Discussion Papers, 2011).

225. Jonathan Levin and Barry Nalebuff, An Introduction to Vote-Counting Schemes, 9 J. ECON.

PERSPECTIVES 3 (1995)

226. Adam J. Levitin, Interchange Regulation: Implications for Credit Unions, (Filene Research

Institute, 2010).

227. ———. , Priceless? the Econommic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L.

REV. 1321 (2008).

228. ———. , The Antitrust Super Bowl: America's Payment Systems, no-Surcharge Rules, and the

Hidden Costs of Credit, 3 BERKELEY BUS. L.J. 265 (2005).

229. Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? the Social Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, SSRN

(2008).

230. HIGH-LEVEL EXPERT GROUP ON REFORMING THE STRUCTURE OF THE EU BANKING SECTOR

(LIIKANEN REPORT), (Oct. 2012)

Page 409: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

409

231. Hoze Linares-Zegarra & John O. S. Wilson, Risk Based Pricing in the Credit Card Industry:

Evidence from US Survey Data (2012) http://ssrn.com/abstract=2141360.

232. Catherine Liston, Price-Cap versus Rate-of-Return Regulation, 5 J. Regulatory Econ. 25, 28

(1993).

233. Philip Lowe, Reform of the Payments System (Visa International Australia and New Zealand

Member Forum, March. 2005).

234. James M. Lyon, The Interchange Fee Debate: Issues and Economics, FRB Minneapolis (June

1, 2006).

235. I. J. Macfarlane, Greshams Law of Payments, (Address to Australasian Institute of Banking and

Finance Industry Forum, 2005) available at http://www.bis.org/review/r050323l.pdf.

236. Ronald J. Mann, Charging Ahead: The Growth and Regulation of Payment Card Markets

(2006).

237. Fabio M. Manenti & Ernesto Somma, Plastic Clashes: Competition among Closed and Open

Systems in the Credit Card Industry (2002)

238. Fabio M. Manenti & Ernesto Somma, Plastic Clashes: Competition among Closed and Open

Systems in the Credit Card Industry (2010).

239. Andrew Martin, How Visa, using Card Fees, Dominates a Market, N.Y. TIMES (Jan. 4, 2010).

240. ANDREU MAS-COLELL ET AL., MICROECONOMIC THEORY, (Oxford 1995).

241. JAMES J. Mcandrews, Automated Teller Machine Network Pricing – A Review of the Literature,

2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 146 (2003).

242. James J. Mcandrews & Zhu Wang, The Economics of Two-Sided Payment Card Markets:

Pricing, Adoption and Usage (Fed. Res. Bank of Kansas City Working Paper 2008).

243. Harrison J. McAvoy, Regulation Or Competition?: The Durbin Amendment, the Sherman Act,

and Intervention in the Card Payment Industry, 37 SETON HALL LEGISLATIVE J. (2013).

244. Kathleen A. McConnell, The Durbin Amendment's Interchange Fee and Network Non-

Exclusivity Provisions: Did the Federal Reserve Board Overstep its Boundaries? 18 N.C.

BANKING INST. 627 (March 2014).

245. James McGrath, General-use Prepaid Cards: The Path to Gaining Mainstream Acceptance,

Fed. Res, Bank Philadelphia (2007).

246. Tim Mead, Renee Courtois Haltom & Margaretta Blackwell, The Role of Interchange Fees on

Debit and Credit Card Transactions in the Payments System, 11-05 Fed. Reserve Bank of

Richmond (2011).

247. Massimo Motta & Helder Vasconcelos, Exclusionary Pricing in a Two-Sided Market, CEPR

Discussion Paper 9164 (Oct. 2012).

248. Timothy J. Muris, Payment Card Regulation and the (MIS)Application of the Economics of

Two-Sided Markets, 3 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 515 (2005).

249. NECG, Visa's Response to the Reserve Bank of Australia and Australia Competition and

Consumer Commission Joint Study (2001).

250. José L. Negrín, The Regulation of Payment Cards: The Mexican Experience, 4 REV. NETWORK

ECON. 243 (2005).

251. David M Newbery, Rate-of-return regulation versus price regulation for public utilities

(Cambridge 1997)

Page 410: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

410

252. Larry O'Connell, Electronic Tendering: Recognising a More Effective Use of Information

Communications Technology in the Irish Construction Industry, Masters dissertation. Dublin

Institute of Technology (2010)

253. OFFICE OF FAIR TRADING, INVESTIGATION INTO INTERCHANGE FEES (2012) available at http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20140402142426/http://www.oft.gov.uk/OFTwork/competition-act-and-cartels/ca98-current/interchange-fees

254. BARAK ORBACH, THE GOALS OF ANTITRUST LAW IN PRACTICE, IN LEGAL AND ECONOMIC

ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST LAW 63 (Michal Gal & Menachem Perlman eds., 2008).

255. Janusz a. Ordover, Comments on Evans & Schmalensee’s “The Industrial Organization of

Markets with Two-Sided Platforms”, 3 Competition Pol'y Int'l 181 (2007).

256. Rachel L. Osband, Interchange Fee Reform in Mexico: A Bank Driven Approach, ANTITRUST

BULL. (2009).

257. Crystal Ossolinski, Tai Lam & David Emery, The Changing Way we Pay: Trends in Consumer

Payments, RBA Australia Research Discussion Paper (2014).

258. Barbara Pacheco & Richard Sullivan, Interchange Fees in Credit and Debit Card Markets:

What Role for Public Authorities? 1 FED. RES. BANK KANSAS ECON. REV. 87 (2006).

259. WILLIAM H. PAGE & JOHN E. LOPATKA, NETWORK EXTERNALITIES, in 1 ENCYCLOPEDIA OF

LAW AND ECONOMICS 952 (B. Bouckaert & G. Ed De Geest eds., 1999).

260. NIGEL PARR ET AL., UK MERGER CONTROL: LAW AND PRACTICE (2nd ed. 2005).

261. Craig T. Peters, Bargaining Power and the Effects of Joint Negotiation: The "Recapture Effect"

(Sept. 2014).

262. Aghion Philippe et al., Competition and Innovation: An Inverted-U Relationship, 120 Q. J.

ECON. 701 (2005).

263. KENNETH A. POSNER, CLASH OF TITANS: RETAILERS, CARD ISSUERS AND INTERCHANGE, INDUS.

REPORT (Morgan Stanley, 2006).

264. Richard A. Posner, Natural Monopoly and its Regulation, 21 STAN. L. REV. 548 (1969).

265. Robin A. Prager et al., Interchange Fees and Payment Card Networks: Economics, Industry

Developments, and Policy Issues (FRB Fin. and Econ. Discussion Series 23-09. 2009).

266. David A. Price & Zhu Wang, Why do Debit Card Networks Charge Percentage Fees? 13-02

Fed. Reserve Bank of Richmond (2013).

267. GEORGE L. PRIEST, NETWORKS AND ANTITRUST ANALYSIS, in 1 ISSUES IN COMPETITION LAW

AND POLICY 641 (ABA section of Antitrust Law 2008).

268. ———. , Rethinking Antitrust Law in an Age of Network Industries (John M. Olin Research

Paper 352, 2007).

269. Lina Rainiene, Functional and Structural Separation Models, TAIEX Workshop on Regulatory

Framework, Belgrade (April 2010).

270. Frank Ramsey, A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation, ECON. J. (1927).

271. Lukas Repa, MasterCard and VISA Modify Network Rules and Increase Antitrust

Transparency of Cross-Border Interchange Fees, 2 COMPETITION POL'Y NEWSL. 57 (2005).

272. Lukas Repa, Agata Malczewska & Antonio Carlos Teixeira, Commission Prohibits

MasterCard’s Multilateral Interchange Fees for Cross-Border Card Payments in the EEA,

COMPETITION POL'Y NEWSL. (Nov. 1, 2008).

Page 411: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

411

273. Jean Charles Rochet, Competing Payment Systems: Key Insights from the Academic Literature

(RBA Paper Prepared for the Payments System Review Conference, 2007).

274. ———. , The Interchange Fee Mysteries, Commentary on Evans and Schmalensee

(Conference on Payments Systems, 2005).

275. ———. , The Theory of Interchange Fees: A Synthesis of Recent Contributions, 2 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 97 (2003).

276. Jean Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report, 37 RAND J. ECON.

645 (2006).

277. ———. , Externalities and Regulation in Card Payment Systems 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1

(2006).

278. ———. , Two-Sided Markets: An Overview (2004).

279. ———. , An Economic Analysis of the Determination of Interchange Fees in Payment Card

Systems, 2 REV. NETWORK ECON. 69 (2003).

280. ———. , Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets, 1 J. EUR. ECON. ASS'N 990 (2003).

281. ———. , Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations,

33 RAND J. ECON. 549 (2002).

282. ———. , Must-Take Cards: Merchant Discounts and Avoided Costs, 9 J. EUR. ECON. ASS'N

462 (2011).

283. ———. , Tying in Two-Sided Markets and the Honor all Cards Rule, 26 Int'l j. Indus. Org.

1333 (2008).

284. Jean-Charles Rochet & Zhu Wang, Issuer Competition and the Credit Card Interchange Fee

Puzzle, (2010).

285. Jean-Charles Rochet & Julian Wright, Credit Card Interchange Fees, 34 J. BANKING FIN. 1788

(2010).

286. Susan Rose-Ackerman & Jim Rossi, Disentangling Deregulatory Takings, 86 VIR. L. REV.

1435 (2000).

287. Jim Rossi, The Irony of Deregulatory Takings, 197 TEX. L. REV. 77 (1998).

288. Camilo Rubiano, Collective Bargaining and Competition Law: A Comparative Study on the

Media, Arts and Entertainment Sectors (July 2013).

289. Michael H. Ryan, Structural Separation: A Prerequisite for Effective Telecoms Competition?

E.C.L.R 241 (2003).

290. Marc Rysman, The Economics of Two-Sided Markets, 23 J. ECON. PERSPECTIVES 125 (2009).

291. ———. , An Empirical Analysis of Payment Card Usage, 55 J. INDUS. ECON. 1 (2007).

292. Marc Rysman & Julian Wright, The Economics of Payment Cards, 13 REV. NETWORK ECON.

303 (2015).

293. M. Pierce Sandwith, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act: Debit

Card Interchange Fees and the Durbin Amendment's Small Bank Exemption, 16 N.C. BANKING

INST. 223 (2012).

294. Aaron Schiff, The "Waterbed" Effect and Price Regulation, 7 REV. NETWORK ECON. 392

(2008).

295. Richard Schmalensee, Payment Systems and Interchange Fees, 50 J. INDUS. ECON. 103 (2002).

Page 412: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

412

296. ———. , Interchange Fees, Market Failure, and Remedies (Presentation in Conference “The

Role and Regulation of Interchange Fees in European Payment Cards”, 2011) available at https://www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/assets/Free/Schmalensee-transcriptupdate.pdf.

297. ———. , Interchange Fees: A Review of the Literature, 1 PAYMENT CARD ECON. REV. 25

(2003).

298. Heiko Schmiedel, Gergana Kostova & Wiebe Ruttenberg, The Social and Private Costs of

Retail Payment Instruments A European Perspective, 137 ECB Occasional Paper Series (2012).

299. Barry Scholnick et al., The Economics of Credit Cards, Debit Cards and ATMs: A Survey and

some New Evidence, 32 J. BANK. FIN. 1468 (2008).

300. Scott Schuh et al., Who Gains and Who Loses from Credit Card Payments? Theory and

Calibrations (FRB of Boston Public Policy Discussion Papers No. 10-03, 2010).

301. ———. , An Economic Analysis of the 2011 Settlement between the Department of Justice and

Credit Card Networks, 8 J. COMPETITION L. ECON. 1 (2012).

302. Scott Schuh & Joanna Stavins, How Consumers Pay: Adoption and use of Payments (FRB of

Boston Working Paper, 2012).

303. ———. , Why Are (Some) Consumers (Finally) Writing Fewer Checks? The Role

of Payment Characteristics, 34 J. BANK. FIN. 1745 (2010).

304. Carl Schwartz et al., Payment Costs in Australia (RBA and ACCC Publication for a

Conference Held in Sydney on Nov. 29, 2007).

305. Marius Schwartz & Daniel R. Vincent, The No Surcharge Rule and Card User Rebates:

Vertical Control by a Payment Network, 5 REV. NETWORK ECON. 72 (2006).

306. Björn Segendorf & Thomas Jansson, The Cost of Consumer Payments in Sweden (Sveriges

Risbank Working Paper 262, 2012).

307. Steven Semeraro, Assessing the Costs & Benefits of Credit Card Rewards: A Response to Who

Gains and Who Loses from Credit Card Payments? Theory and Calibrations (2012).

308. ———. , The Antitrust Economics (and Law) of Surcharging Credit Card Transactions, 14

STAN. J. L. BUS. & FIN. 343 (2009).

309. ———. , Credit Cards Interchange Fees: Three Decades of Antitrust Uncertainty, 14 GEO.

MASON L. REV. 941 (2007).

310. ———. , The Economic Benefits of Credit Card Merchant Restraints: A Response to Adam

Levitin, TJSL Legal Studies Research Paper 1357840 (2009).

311. ———. , The Reverse Robin Hood Cross Subsidy Hypothesis: Do Credit Cards Systems Tax

the Poor and Reward the Rich? 40 RUTGERS L. J. 419 (2009).

312. Allan Shampine, An Evaluation of the Social Costs of Payment Methods Literature, SSRN

(2012).

313. ———. , Another Look at Payment Instrument Economics, 6 REV. NETWORK ECON. 495

(2007).

314. ———. , Testing Interchange Fee Models using the Australian Experience (Bank of Canada

Economics of Payments VI conference, May 24, 2012).

315. Robert J. Shapiro & Jiwon Vellucci, The Costs of “Charging it” in America: Assessing the

Economic Impact of Interchange Fees for Credit Card and Debit Card Transactions (2010).

316. STEVEN SHAVELL, FOUNDATIONS OF ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW (2004).

Page 413: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

413

317. COMMITTEE FOR ENHANCEMENT OF COMPETITION IN COMMON BANKING & FINANCIAL

SERVICES (SHTRUM COMMITTEE) FINAL REPORT (Sep 1, 2016)

318. Oz Shy, Measuring some Effects of the 2011 Debit Card Interchange Fee Reform, 32

CONTEMPORARY ECON. POL'Y 769 (2014).

319. Oz Shy & Joanna Stavins, Merchant Steering of Consumer Payment Choice: Lessons Learned

from Consumer Surveys, 13-1 FRB Boston (2013).

320. Oz Shy & Zhu Wang, Why do Payment Card Networks Charge Proportional Fees? 101 AM.

ECON. REV. 1575 (2011).

321. J. GREGORY SIDAK & DANIEL F. SPULBER, DEREGULATORY TAKINGS AND THE REGULATORY

CONTRACT (1998).

322. John Simon, Payment Systems are Different: Shouldn’t their Regulation be Too? 4 REV.

NETWORK ECON. 364 (2005).

323. John Simon, Kylie Smith & Tim West, Price Incentives and Consumer Payment Behaviour, 34

J. BANK. FIN. 1759 (2010).

324. Ewelina Sokołowska, Innovations in the Payment Card Market: The Case of Poland

(Electronic Commerce Research and Applications, 2015).

325. Daniel F. Spulber & Christopher F. Yoo, Antitrust, The Internet, and the Economics of

Networks, Faculty Scholarship Series Paper 583 (2013).

326. Joanna Stavins, Potential Effects of an Increase in Debit Card Fees (FRB of Boston Public

Policy Briefs No. 11-03, 2011).

327. Chris Stewart et al., The Evolution of Payment Costs in Australia, RBA Research Discussion

Paper 14 (2014).

328. STRUCTURAL BANKING REFORMS CROSS-BORDER CONSISTENCIES AND GLOBAL FINANCIAL

STABILITY IMPLICATIONS, Report to G20 Leaders for the November 2014 Summit Financial

Stability Board (Oct. 27, 2014).

329. Peter R. Taylor, Cards and Payments Australasia, Payment Conference 2010.

http://www.comcom.govt.nz/cards-and-payments-australasia-2010-conference-15-march-2010/.

330. Jean Tirole, Payment Card Regulation and the use of Economic Analysis in Antitrust, 4

TOULOUSE SCHOOL ECON. (2011).

331. Dr Anikó Turján et al., Nothing is Free: A Survey of the Social Cost of the Main Payment

Instruments in Hungary (93 MNB Occasional Papers 2011).

332. Jonathan C. Tyras, Collective Bargaining and Antitrust After Brown v. Pro Football, Inc, 1

PENN. J. BUS. L. 297 (1998).

333. Jens Uhlenbrock, Pricing and Regulation in Multi-Sided Markets - Implications for Payment

Card Networks and Smart Metering (2012).

334. United States Senate Committee on Judiciary, Credit Card Interchange Fee: Antitrust

Concerns? (2006).

335. Tommaso Valletti, Platform Regulation in Other Industries: Lessons from Telecoms

(Conference Presentation, The Role and Regulation of Interchange Fees in European Payment

Cards, Brussels. June 15, 2011).

336. IVO VAN BAEL & JEAN-FRANCOIS BELLIS, COMPETITION LAW OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY

(5ed. 2010).

Page 414: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

414

337. Leo Van Hove, Central Banks and Payment Instruments: A Serious Case of Schizophrenia, 66

COMMUNICATIONS & STRATEGIES 19 (2007).

338. ———. , Cost-Based Pricing of Payment Instruments: The State of the Debate, 152 DE

ECONOMIST 79 (2004).

339. Marianne Verdier, Interchange Fees in Payment Card Systems: A Survey of the Literature, 25

J. ECON. SURVEYS 273 (2011).

340. ———. , Interchange Fees and Incentives to Invest in Payment Card Systems, 28 INT'L J.

INDUS. ORG. 539 (2010).

341. Srikanth Verma & Satyanarayana Reddy, Global Credit Card Industry: Issues and Challenges,

(Jul. 2014) available at http://dawn-svims.in/wp-content/uploads/2014/12/4-Global-Credit-Card-Industry-Issues-and-Challenges.pdf .

342. John Vickers, Public Policy and the Invisible Price: Competition Law, Regulation and the

Interchange Fee, Payments Systems Research Conference 231 (2005).

343. U.K. INDEPENDENT COMMISSION ON BANKING FINAL REPORT RECOMMENDATIONS (VICKERS

REPORT), (Sept. 2011).

344. Sebastian Voigt & Oliver Hinz, Network Effects in Two-Sided Markets: Why a 50/50 User Split

is Not Necessarily Revenue Optimal, (2015).

345. Christian Von Wizsacker, Comments regarding "Reform of Credit Card Schemes in Australia

II" Commissioned Report by Professor Michael L. Katz (2002) available at http://www.rba.gov.au/payments-system/reforms/cc-schemes/consult-doc-responses/mastercard-0302-2.pdf.

346. Kevin Wack, Retailers Sue Fed Over Interchange Rule, AM. BANKER (Nov. 22, 2011).

347. Naoki Wakamori & Angelika Welte, Why do Shoppers use Cash? Evidence from Shopping

Diary Data (Bank of Canada WP 24-2012).

348. Zhu Wang, Demand Externalities and Price Cap Regulation: Learning from the U.S. Debit

Card Market (FRB Richmond Working Paper 2014).

349. Zhu Wang & Julian Wright, Ad-Valorem Platform Fees and Efficient Price Discrimination

(2012).

350. Liyuan Wei, Consumer Choice of Credit Cards, Usage and Retention (2015) available at

http://kuleuvencongres.be/EMAC2015/w/papers/ggkljel-fgmjhm-fm3vx8ou.pdf.

351. Stewart E. Weiner & Julian Wright, Interchange Fees in various Countries: Developments and

Determinants, 4 REV. NETWORK ECON. 290 (2005).

352. Tim Westrich & Malcolm Bush, Blindfolded into Debt: A Comparison of Credit Card Costs

and Conditions at Banks and Credit Unions, WOODSTOCK INST. (2005) available at

http://www.fdic.gov/news/conferences/affordable/woodstock2.pdf.

353. E. Glen Weyl, The Price Theory of Two-Sided Markets, SSRN (2009).

354. ———. , A Price Theory of Multi-Sided Platforms, 100 AM. ECON. REV. 1642 (2010).

355. ———. , Double Marginalization in Two-Sided Markets, SSRN (2008).

356. K. Craig Wildfang & Ryan W. Marth, The Persistence of Antitrust Controversy and Litigation

in Credit Card Networks, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 675 (2006).

357. Oliver E. Williamson, Deregulatory Takings and Breach of the Regulatory Contract: Some

Precautions, 71 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1007 (1996).

Page 415: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

415

358. Stephanie M. Wilshusen et al., Consumers’ use of Prepaid Cards: A Transaction-Based

Analysis (Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia discussion paper 2012).

359. Steve Worthington, Affinity Credit Cards a Critical Review, 29 INT. J. RETAIL & DISTRIBUTION

MANAGEMENT 485 (2001).

360. Julian Wright, Why Payment Card Fees Are Biased Against Retailers, 43 RAND J. ECON. 761

(2012).

361. ———. , Why do Merchants Accept Payment Cards? 9 REV. NETWORK ECON. 1 (2010).

362. ———. , The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees in Payment Systems, 52 J. INDUS.

ECON. 1 (2004).

363. ———. , One-Sided Logic in Two-Sided Markets 3 REV. NETWORK ECON. 44 (2004).

364. ———. , Optimal Card Payment Systems, 47 EUR. ECON. REV. 587 (2003).

365. ———. , Pricing in Debit and Credit Card Schemes, ECON. LETTERS (2003).

366. SHARON YADIN, REGULATION: ADMINISTRATIVE LAW IN THE AGE OF REGULATORY CONTRACTS

(2016)

367. Hans Zenger, Differentiated Interchange Fees, 115 ECON. LETTERS 276 (2012).

368. ———. , Perfect Surcharging and the Tourist Test Interchange Fee, 35 J. BANK. FIN. 2544

(2011).

369. Wang Zhu, Market Structure and Payment Card Pricing: What Drives the Interchange?, 28

INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 86 (2010).

370. Jonathan Zinman, Debit Or Credit?, 33 J. BANK. FIN. 358 (2009).

371. Todd Zywicki, Will Congress Take another Swipe at Credit Cards? WALL ST. J. (Jan. 5, 2010).

372. Todd Zywicki, Geoffrey A. Manne & Julian Morris, Price Controls on Payment Card

Interchange Fees: The U.S. Experience (2014) available at

http://www.laweconcenter.org/images/articles/icledurbin2014.pdf .

Page 416: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

416

2. U.S. Cases

1. United States v. Am. Express Co., 2016 U.S. App. LEXIS 17502 (2d Cir. N.Y. Sept. 26, 2016).

2. Brennan v. Concord Efs, U.S. LEXIS 6750 (U.S. Oct. 7, 2013).

3. United States v. Am. Express Co., 21 F. Supp. 3d 187 (E.D.N.Y May 7, 2014).

4. United States v. Am. Express Co., 2011 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 78835 (E.D.N.Y July 20, 2011).

5. United States v. Am. Express Co., 2015 U.S. Dist. Lexis 20114 (E.D.N.Y Feb. 19, 2015).

6. United States v. Am. Express, (April 30, 2015) http://www.justice.gov/file/485716/download.

7. Osborn v. Visa Inc., 797 F.3d 1057 (D.C. Cir. 2015).

8. In Re Payment Card Interchange Fee & Merchant Discount Antitrust Litig., 991 F. Supp. 2d

437 (E.D.N.Y. 2014).

9. NACS v. Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys., 746 F.3d 474 (D.C. Cir. 2014).

10. In Re Payment Card Interchange Fee & Merchant Discount Antitrust Litig., 986 F. Supp. 2d

207 (E.D.N.Y 2013).

11. NACS v. Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys., 958 F. Supp. 2d 85 115 (D.D.C. 2013).

12. In Re Payment Card Interchange Fee and Merchant Discount Antitrust Litigation (Settlement

Agreement), 05-MD-1720 (E.D.N.Y 2012).

13. In Re: ATM Fee Antitrust Litigation, 10-17354 LEXIS 14265 (C.A 9th cir. 2012).

14. In Re Payment Card Interchange Fee & Merchant Discount Antitrust Litig., 05-MD-1720

(E.D.N.Y 2008).

15. In Re Payment Card Interchange Fee & Merchant Discount. Antitrust Litig., U.S. Dist. LEXIS

104439 (E.D.N.Y 2008).

16. In Re Payment Card Interchange Fee & Merchant Discount Antitrust Litig., 398 F. Supp . 2d

1356 (J.P.M.L 2005).

17. N. Jackson Pharm., Inc. v. Caremark RX, Inc., 385 F. Supp. 2d 740 (N.D. 2005).

18. Wal-Mart v. Visa U.S.A., 396 F .3d 96 U.S. Ct. of Appeals 2nd cir. (2005).

19. Mastercard v. United States, 543 U.S. 811 (2004).

20. Verizon Communs., Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, (2004).

21. United States v. Visa, 344 F .3d 229 (CA 2d Dist. 2003).

22. Verizon Communs., Inc. v. FCC, 535 U.S. 467 (2002).

23. United Stated v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 183 F. Supp. 2d 613 (S.D.N.Y 2001).

24. United States v. Visa, 163 F. Supp. 2d 322 (S.D.N.Y 2001).

25. In Re Visa Check/MasterMoney Antitrust Litig., 192 F.R.D. 68 (2000).

26. National Bancard Corp. (NaBanco) v. VISA, 596 F. Supp. 1231 (S.D of Fla, LEXIS 23432

1984).

27. United States v. AT&T Co., 552 F. Supp. 131 (D.D.C. 1982).

28. Broadcast Music v. CBS, 441 U.S. 1 (1979).

29. Marquette Nat'l Bank v. First of Omaha Service Corp., 439 U.S. 299 (1978).

Page 417: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

417

30. Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720 (1977).

31. United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563 (1966).

32. United States v. E. I. Du Pont De Nemours & Co., 366 U.S. 316 (1961).

33. United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F. 2d 416 (2d Cir. N.Y. 1945).

34. United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150 (1940).

35. American Bank & Trust Company V. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, 262 U.S. 643 (1923).

36. Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1 (1911).

37. In Re Visa Check/Mastermoney Antitrust Litig., 297 F. Supp. 2d 503 (E.D.N.Y 2003).

38. In Re Visa Check/Mastermoney Antitrust Litig. 2003 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 4965 (E.D.N.Y 2003).

39. Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 130 S. Ct. 2201, 2217 (U.S. 2010).

40. Board of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238 (U.S. 1918).

41. Compact v. Metropolitan Government of Nashville & Davidson County, 594 F. Supp. 1567

(M.D. Tenn. 1984).

42. In Re Payment Card Interchange Fee and Merchant Discount Antitrust Litigation (Settlement

Agreement), 05-MD-1720 (E.D.N.Y 2012).

43. Instant Delivery Corp. v. City Stores Co., 284 F. Supp. 941 (E.D. Pa. 1968).

44. Marrero-Rolón v. Autoridad De Energía Eléctrica, U.S. Dist. LEXIS 134211(Sept. 28, 2015).

45. White Motor Co. v. United States, 372 U.S. 253 (U.S. 1963).

46. Expressions Hair Design v. Schneiderman, 137 S. Ct. 1144 (Mar. 29, 2017).

47. Italian Colors Rest. v. Becerra, 878 F.3d 1165 (9th Cir. Jan 3. 2018).

48. State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3 (1997)

49. Maislin Indus., U.S. v. Primary Steel, 497 U.S. 116 (1990)

50. Duquesne Light Co. v. Barasch, 488 U.S. 299 (1989)

51. FPC v. Nat. Gas Pipeline Co., 315 U.S. 575 (1942).

52. Federal Power Com. v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591(1944)

53. Covington & lexington tpk. Rd. Co. V. Sandford, 164 U.S. 578 (1896)

54. P.R. Tel. Co. v. Telecomms. Regulatory Bd. of P.R., 665 F.3d 309 (1st Cir. 2011)

55. Smyth v. Ames, 169 U.S. 466, 515 (1898)

56. Mo. ex rel. Sw. Bell Tel. Co. v. Pub. Serv. Com., 262 U.S. 276 (1923)

57. Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, 390 U.S. 747, 806, 88 S. Ct. 1344 (1968)

58. Consol. Edison Co. v. Pub. Serv. Comm'n, 447 U.S. 530 (1980)

3. U.S. Authorities

1. ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMMISSION, REPORT AND RECOMMENDATIONS 267-269 (2007).

2. BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM, COMPLIANCE GUIDE TO SMALL

ENTITIES (Aug. 2, 2013) http://www.federalreserve.gov/bankinforeg/regiicg.htm.

Page 418: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

418

3. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Final Rule on Debit Card Interchange Fees

and Routing and Interim Final Rule on Fraud Prevention Adjustment, 12 C.F.R pt. 235, (2011).

4. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Debit Card Interchange Fees and Routing,

Final Rule, 77 Fed. Reg. 150 § 46258 (Aug. 3, 2012).

5. Credit Card Accountability Responsibility and Disclosure Act, Pub. L. 111–24, (2009).

6. Credit Card Fair Fee Act of 2009: Hearing before the Committee on the Judiciary House of

Representatives 111th Cong. on H.R. 2695, 111–101 (April 28, 2010).

7. Debit Card Interchange Fees and Routing, 75 Fed. Reg. § 81722, (2010).

8. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division Policy Guide to Merger Remedies, (Jun. 2011).

9. Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Public Law Pub. L. 111-203,

(2010).

10. FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION AND DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE, ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR

COLLABORATIONS AMONG COMPETITORS (2000).

11. Hearing before the S. Judiciary Comm., 109th Cong. 147 (2006) (Statement of Timothy J.

Muris, Former FTC Chairman).

12. H.R 5546 110th Cong. (2008).

13. H.R. 5244, 110th Cong. (2008).

14. H.R. 5546 Summary , 110th Cong. (2008).

15. H.R. 110-913 (2008).

16. FINANCIAL STABILITY OVERSIGHT COUNCIL, STUDY & RECOMMENDATIONS ON PROHIBITIONS

ON PROPRIETARY TRADING & CERTAIN RELATIONSHIPS WITH HEDGE FUNDS & PRIVATE

EQUITY FUNDS (2011).

17. FTC, Press Release, FTC Issues Statement of Principles regarding Enforcement of FTC Act as

a Competition Statute (Aug. 13, 2015).

18. Justice News, Justice Department Sues American Express, MasterCard and Visa to Eliminate

Rules Restricting Price Competition; Reaches Settlement with Visa and MasterCard (Oct. 4,

2010).

19. Statements of Antitrust Enforcement Policy in Health Care, Issued by the U.S. Department of

Justice and the Federal Trade Commission August 1996 .

20. Truth in Lending; Unfair Or Deceptive Acts Or Practices; Final Rules, 75 Fed. Reg. 7658 pts.

226 & 227 (Feb. 22, 2010).

21. U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., GAO-08-558, FEDERAL ENTITIES ARE TAKING ACTIONS TO

LIMIT THEIR INTERCHANGE FEES, BUT ADDITIONAL REVENUE COLLECTION COST SAVINGS MAY

EXIST (2008).

22. U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., GAO-10-45, RISING INTERCHANGE FEES HAVE INCREASED

COSTS FOR MERCHANTS, BUT OPTIONS FOR REDUCING FEES POSE CHALLENGES (2009).

23. 19 U.S.C.S. § 1675(b)

4. Foreign Authorities

1. AUSTRALIAN COMPETITION AND CONSUMER COMMISSION, MERGER GUIDELINES (Nov. 2008).

2. Belgium, National Bank, Costs, Advantages and Drawbacks of the various Means of Payment,

NATIONAL BANK OF BELGIUM ECON. REV. 41 (2006).

Page 419: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

419

3. Canada Credit Card and Debit Card Systems, Senate Committee on Banking (2009)

http://www.parl.gc.ca/Content/SEN/Committee/402/bank/rep/rep04Jun09-e.pdf.

4. CANADA, CODE OF CONDUCT FOR THE CREDIT AND DEBIT CARD INDUSTRY (2010)

5. CANADA COMPETITION BUREAU, INFORMATION BULLETIN ON MERGER REMEDIES IN CANADA

(Sept. 22, 2006).

6. CANADA, DEPARTMENT OF FINANCE, NEWS RELEASE 2009-109, DRAFT CODE OF CONDUCT FOR

THE CREDIT AND DEBIT CARD INDUSTRY IN CANADA (2009).

7. EUROPEAN COMMISSION, ANNOUNCEMENT IN CASE AT.39398 — VISA MIF (2013/C 168/07),

(June 14, 2013) .

8. ———. , Directive 2007/64/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13

November 2007 on Payment Services in the Internal Market O J L319/1 (5 Dec., 2007).

9. ———. , Directive 2011/83/EU on Consumer Rights, OJ L 304/64 (Nov. 22, 2011).

10. ———. , FEEDBACK STATEMENT ON EUROPEAN COMMISSION GREEN PAPER “TOWARDS AN

INTEGRATED EUROPEAN MARKET FOR CARD, INTERNET AND MOBILE PAYMENTS (June 27, 2012)

available at http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/payments/cim/index_en.htm

11. ———. , Guidelines on the Applicability of Article 101 to Horizontal Co-Operation

Agreements, O.J (C 11) 1 (Jan. 14, 2011 http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52011XC0114(04)&from=EN

12. ———. , GREEN PAPER TOWARDS AN INTEGRATED EUROPEAN MARKET FOR CARD, INTERNET

AND MOBILE PAYMENTS COM(2011) 941 final.

13. ———. , INTERIM REPORT I PAYMENT CARDS SECTOR INQUIRY UNDER ARTICLE 17

REGULATION 1/2003 ON RETAIL BANKING (Apr. 12, 2006).

14. ———. , MEMO ANTITRUST: COMMISSION MAKES VISA EUROPE'S COMMITMENTS BINDING –

FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS (Feb. 26, 2014).

15. ———. , MEMO/13/431 VICE PRESIDENT ALMUNIA WELCOMES VISA EUROPE'S PROPOSAL TO

CUT INTER-BANK FEES FOR CREDIT CARDS (May 14, 2013).

16. ———. , Memo/08/170 COMMISSION INITIATES FORMAL PROCEEDINGS AGAINST VISA EUROPE

LIMITED, (Mar. 26, 2008) http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=MEMO/08/170&format=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en

17. ———. , Neelie Kroes, Commission Prohibits MasterCard's Intra-EEA Multilateral

Interchange Fees, Introductory Remarks at Press Conference SPEECH/07/832 (Dec. 19, 2007).

18. ———. , Notice on Remedies Acceptable Under Council Regulation (EC) no 139/2004 and

Under Commission Regulation (EC) no 802/2004 (2008/C 267/01), .

19. ———. , NOTICE IN CASE COMP/39.398 — VISA MIF, 2010 O.J. (C 138) 34 (May 28, 2010) http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:C:2010:138:0034:0036:EN:PDF

20. ———. , PRESS RELEASE, ANTITRUST, COMMISSION EXEMPTS MULTILATERAL INTERCHANGE

FEES FOR CROSS BORDER VISA CARD PAYMENTS IP/02/1138 (July 24, 2002).

21. ———. , PRESS RELEASE, EUROPA, ANTITRUST: COMMISSION SENDS STATEMENT OF

OBJECTIONS TO VISA MEMO/09/151 (Apr. 6, 2009).

22. ———. , PRESS RELEASE: COMMISSION SENDS SUPPLEMENTARY STATEMENT OF OBJECTIONS

TO VISA, IP/2/871 (Jul. 31, 2012).

Page 420: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

420

23. ———. , PRESS RELEASE, POLAND: THE COURT OF COMPETITION AND CONSUMER PROTECTION

CONFIRMS UOKIK’S DECISION ON MULTILATERAL INTERCHANGE FEES (Nov. 2013)

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/brief/05_2013/courtfees_pl.pdf.

24. ———. , PRESS RELEASE, ANTITRUST, COMMISSION NOTES MASTERCARD'S DECISION TO

TEMPORARILY REPEAL ITS CROSS-BORDER MULTILATERAL INTERCHANGE FEES WITHIN THE

EEA, MEMO/08/397 (2008),.

25. ———. , PRESS RELEASE, ANTITRUST: COMMISSION PROHIBITS MASTERCARD'S INTRA-EEA

MULTILATERAL INTERCHANGE FEES IP/07/1959 (Dec.19, 2007).

26. ———. , PRESS RELEASE, ANTITRUST, COMMISSION MAKES VISA EUROPE'S COMMITMENTS TO

CUT INTER-BANK FEES AND TO FACILITATE CROSS-BORDER COMPETITION LEGALLY BINDING

IP/14/197 (Feb. 26, 2014) http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-14-197_en.htm.

27. ———. , PRESS RELEASE, COMMISSIONER KROES TAKES NOTE OF MASTERCARD'S DECISION TO

CUT CROSS-BORDER MULTILATERAL INTERCHANGE FEES (MIFS) AND TO REPEAL RECENT

SCHEME FEE INCREASES, IP/09/515 (Apr. 1, 2009), available at

http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=IP/09/515.

28. ———. , PRESS RELEASE ANTITRUST, COMMISSION WELCOMES GENERAL COURT JUDGMENT IN

MASTERCARD CASE (May 26, 2012).

29. ———. , Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees for Card-Based Payment Transactions,

COM(2013)550 (July 24, 2013).

30. ———. , Proposal for a Regulation on Interchange Fees for Card-Based Payment Transactions,

EXPLANATORY MEMORANDUM, COM(2013) 550 Final 2013/0265 (Cod) (Aug. 5, 2013).

31. ———. , Proposal for a Regulation Of The European Parliament and of the Council on

Structural Measures Improving the Resilience of EU Credit Institutions COM/2014/043 Final -

2014/0020 (COD).

32. ———. , Proposal for a Directive on Payment Services (PSD2), Com (2013) 547 Final

2013/0264 (July 24, 2013) http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/ALL/?uri=CELEX:52013PC0547.

33. ———. , Regulation 924/2009 on Cross-Border Payments, O. J. (l 266) 11 (2009).

34. ———. , Reg. 1/2003 on the Implementation of the Rules on Competition Laid Down in

Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty (Dec. 16, 2002).

35. ———. , Regulation 2015/751 on Interchange Fees for Card-Based Payment Transactions, O.J

(L 123) 1 (May 19, 2015).

36. ———. , Regulation 260/2012 Establishing Technical and Business Requirements for Credit

Transfers and Direct Debits in Euro and Amending Regulation (EC) no 924/2009, O.J. (L 94)

22 (March 14, 2012).

37. ———. , Recommendation on the Regulatory Treatment of Fixed and Mobile Termination

Rates in the EU, O.J. L 124/67 (may 7, 2009), .

38. ———. , REPORT ON THE RETAIL BANKING SECTOR INQUIRY COMMISSION STAFF WORKING

DOCUMENT - SECTOR INQUIRY UNDER ART 17 OF REGULATION 1/2003 ON RETAIL BANKING

(FINAL REPORT) [COM(2007) 33 Final] SEC(2007) 106 (Jan 31, 2007).

39. ———. , SECTOR INQUIRY UNDER ARTICLE 17 OF REGULATION (EC) NO 1/2003 ON RETAIL

BANKING (FINAL REPORT){SEC(2007) 106} (Jan. 31, 2007).

Page 421: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

421

40. ———. , STUDY ON THE IMPACT OF DIRECTIVE 2007/64/EC ON PAYMENT SERVICES IN THE

INTERNAL MARKET AND ON THE APPLICATION OF REGULATION (EC) NO 924/2009 ON CROSS-

BORDER PAYMENTS IN THE COMMUNITY, FINAL REPORT (Feb. 2013).

41. ———. , SURVEY ON MERCHANTS' COSTS OF PROCESSING CASH AND CARD PAYMENTS FINAL

RESULTS (March 2015).

42. ———. , FINAL REPORT OF THE HEARING OFFICER COMMITMENTS DECISION VISA MIF, 2011

O.J (C 79) 4.

43. ———. , Working Document - Accompanying the Communication from the Commission -

Sector Inquiry Under Article 17 of Regulation (EC) no 1/2003 on Retail Banking

SEC/2007/0106FIN (Dec. 1, 2005).

44. ———. , Working Document - Annex to the Proposal for a Directive of the European

Parliament and of the Council on Payment Services in the Internal Market - Impact

Assessment, SEC/2005/1535 (Dec. 1, 2005).

45. ———. , Working Document Impact Assessment, SWD(2013) 288 Final (July 24, 2013).

46. ______., Payment card chargeback when paying over Internet MARKT/173/2000 (Jul. 12, 2000).

47. FRANCE, AUTORITE DE LA CONCURRENCE, MERGER CONTROL GUIDELINES

48. HUNGARIAN COMPETITION AUTHORITY, PRESS RELEASE, ANTICOMPETITIVE UNIFORM

INTERCHANGE FEES (Sept. 24, 2009) available at

http://www.gvh.hu/gvh/alpha?do=2&pg=133&st=2&m5_doc=6071.

49. ITALY, AUTORITA GARANTE DELLA CONCORRENZA E DEL MERCATO, ANNUAL REPORT (2010).

50. NEW ZEALAND COMMERCE COMMISSION, MEDIA RELEASE, COMMISSION ALLEGES PRICE-

FIXING IN CREDIT CARD INTERCHANGE FEES (Nov. 10,

2006) http://www.comcom.govt.nz/media-releases/detail/2006/commissionallegespricefixingincred/.

51. ———. , MEDIA RELEASE, COMMERCE COMMISSION AND VISA REACH AGREEMENT TO SETTLE

CREDIT CARD INTERCHANGE FEE PROCEEDINGS (Aug. 12, 2009)

52. ———. , MEDIA RELEASE, COMMERCE COMMISSION AND MASTERCARD AGREE TO SETTLE

CREDIT CARD INTERCHANGE FEE PROCEEDINGS, (AUG. 24, 2009).

53. ———. , MEDIA RELEASE, CREDIT CARD SETTLEMENTS LOWER NEW ZEALAND BUSINESS

COSTS (Oct. 5, 2009) available at http://www.comcom.govt.nz/media-releases/detail/2009/creditcardsettlementslowernewzeala/.

54. ———. , MERGER GUIDELINES (Nov. 2008)

55. ———. , MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: DIVESTMENT REMEDIES GUIDELINES (Jun. 2010).

56. OECD, DEVELOPMENTS IN MOBILE TERMINATION, OECD Digital Econ. Papers, no. 193 (2012).

57. ———. , ROUNDTABLE EXCESSIVE PRICES, DAF/comp(2011)18.

58. ———. , POLICY ROUNDTABLES COMPETITION AND EFFICIENT USAGE OF PAYMENT CARDS,

DAF/COMP 32, 2006.

59. POLAND, PRESS RELEASE, UOKIK, DECISION ON DETERMINING THE INTERCHANGE FEE IN VISA

AND MASTERCARD SYSTEMS (2007).

60. POLAND, UOKIK, PRESS RELEASE, UNLAWFUL PRACTICES OF BANKS (Jan 4, 2007).

61. POLAND, PRESS RELEASE, INTERCHANGE FEE – UOKIK WINS (Apr. 23, 2010).

Page 422: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

422

62. RESERVE BANK OF AUSTRALIA, MEDIA RELEASE, WAIVER OF REQUIREMENT TO RECALCULATE

INTERCHANGE FEE BENCHMARK (2008).

63. ———. , REFORM OF AUSTRALIA’ S PAYMENTS SYSTEM, PRELIMINARY CONCLUSIONS OF THE

2007/08 REVIEW (2008).

64. ———. , CONCLUSIONS OF THE 2007/08 REVIEW (2008).

65. ———. WAIVER OF REQUIREMENT TO RECALCULATE INTERCHANGE FEE BENCHMARK

(March 2015)

66. ———. REFORM OF CREDIT CARD SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA: CONSULTATION DOCUMENT

(Dec.2001).

67. ———. REVIEW OF CARD SURCHARGING: A CONSULTATION DOCUMENT RESERVE BANK OF

AUSTRALIA (2011),.

68. ———. , REFORMS TO PAYMENT CARD SURCHARGING, March 2013 .

69. ———. , REFORM OF AUSTRALIA'S PAYMENTS SYSTEM ISSUES FOR THE 2007/08 REVIEW

(2007), http://www.rba.gov.au/payments-system/reforms/review-card-reforms/pdf/review-0708-issues.pdf.

70. ———. , REFORM OF CREDIT CARD SCHEMES IN AUSTRALIA, FINAL REFORMS AND

REGULATION IMPACT STATEMENT (2002).

71. UNITED KINGDOM, MERGER REMEDIES: COMPETITION COMMISSION GUIDELINES (Nov. 2008).

72. UNITED KINGDOM, PRESS RELEASE, STATEMENT REGARDING EXPANSION OF OFT

INVESTIGATION INTO INTERCHANGE FEES (Feb, 9 2007).

73. UNITED KINGDOM, PRESS RELEASE, OFT TO REFOCUS CREDIT CARD INTERCHANGE FEES

WORK (2006).

74. UNITED KINGDOM, CMA DECIDES NOT TO PROGRESS INTERCHANGE FEE INVESTIGATIONS AT

THE PRESENT TIME (Nov. 4, 2014).

75. UNITED KINGDOM, CMA CLOSES MASTERCARD AND VISA INVESTIGATIONS FOLLOWING EU

REGULATION (May 6, 2015).

76. UNITED KINGDOM, STATEMENT REGARDING THE CMA'S DECISION TO CLOSE ITS

INVESTIGATIONS OF MASTERCARD'S AND VISA'S INTERCHANGE FEE ARRANGEMENTS ON THE

GROUNDS OF ADMINISTRATIVE PRIORITY (May 2015).

77. UNITED KINGDOM, DEPARTMENT FOR BUSINESS INNOVATION AND SKILLS, GUIDANCE ON THE

CONSUMER RIGHTS (PAYMENT SURCHARGES) REGULATIONS (Aug. 2015).

78. United States, Center for Consumer Information & Insurance Oversight, Medical Loss

Ratio, https://www.cms.gov/CCIIO/Programs-and-Initiatives/Health-Insurance-Market-Reforms/Medical-Loss-Ratio.html.

5. International Cases

1. Canada, CT-201O-0IO Commissioner of Competition Vs. Visa Canada and Mastercard

International, (2010)

2. Sainsbury’s supermarkets v. MasterCard (July 14, 2016) http://www.catribunal.org.uk/237-9006/1241-5-7-15-T-Sainsburys-Supermarkets-Ltd.html

3. European Commission Decision COMP/29.373 − Visa International 2001/782/EC, O.J. (L

293) 24 (Nov. 10, 2001)

Page 423: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

423

4. ———. , COMP 29.373 Visa International — Multilateral Interchange Fee, O.J L 318 (Jul. 24,

2002), http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:32002D0914:EN:HTML.

5. ———. , COMP/d1/37860 Morgan Stanley / Visa International and Visa Europe (Oct. 3,

2007), http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/dec_docs/37860/37860_629_1.pdf.

6. ———. , COMP 34.579 European Commission MasterCard Decision (Dec. 19, 2007)

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/dec_docs/34579/34579_1889_2.pdf.

7. ———. , COMP/39.398 - Visa Europe commitments Offered to the European Commission

Pursuant to Article 9 of Council Regulation (Ec) no 1/2003 (Sept. 10, 2010)

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/dec_docs/39398/39398_6186_3.pdf.

8. ———. , COMP/39.398 — VISA MIF, Summary of Commission Decision of 8 December

2010, C 79/8 (March 12, 2011) http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:C:2011:079:0008:0009:EN:PDF.

9. ———. , COMP/39.398 - Visa MIF, C(2010) 8760 final (Dec. 8, 2010)

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/dec_docs/39398/39398_6930_6.pdf.

10. ———. , Decision 92/157/EEC (UK Agricultural Tractor Registration Exchange), paragraph

43, Feb. 17, 1992:

11. AT 39398 Visa C(2014) 1199 Final (Feb. 26, 2014).

12. Case T-35/92, John Deere Ltd. v. Comm'n, 1994 E.C.R II-00957

13. Europe, Court Of Justice, C-67/13 P Groupement Des Cartes Bancaires (CB) v European

Commission (Sep 11, 2014), http://curia.europa.eu/juris/liste.jsf?num=C-67/13&language=en#

14. ———. , C-382/12 P MasterCard v. European Commission (11.9.14).

15. ———. , C-202/06 P Cementbouw Handel & Industrie BV v Commission (Dec. 18, 2007).

16. ———. , C-8/08 T-Mobile Netherlands BV v Raad Van Bestuur Van De Nederlandse

Mededingingsautoriteit, (June 4, 2009).

17. ———. , Case C-7/95 and C-8/95 John Deere Ltd. v. Comm'n, 1998 E.C.R. I-3111

18. ———. , C 286/13 P Dole Food v. Comm'n, para. 121 (19.3.15)

19. Europe, Court of First Instance, T-461/07 Visa Europe Ltd v European Commission (Apr. 14,

2011)

20. ———. , T-111/08 MasterCard v. Comm'n (May 24, 2012).

21. Hungary, Background Report of the Hungarian Competition Authority about the Uniform and

Common Interchange Fees Set by Banks in Hungary, (2009),

http://www.gvh.hu/domain2/files/modules/module25/10769E8D7015B1618.pdf.

22. United Kingdom, CA98/05/05 MasterCard UK Members Forum Limited (2005)

6. Payment card data

1. Bank of Israel, Table J-11, Income Statements of the Payment Card Firms (last visited, Oct. 30,

2016).

2. Bank of Israel, Data on banks, TableX-13 consolidated income statements 2014-2015, available

at http://www.boi.org.il/he/BankingSupervision/Data/Pages/Tables.aspx?ChapterId=12

3. Bank of Israel, Data on Payment Card Firms, Table J-13, Income Statements According to

Activity Sectors for 2014.

Page 424: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

424

4. CreditCards.com, Credit Card Statistics http://www.creditcards.com/credit-card-news/credit-card-industry-facts-personal-debt-statistics-1276.php

5. MasterCard Rules (Dec. 2014) http://www.mastercard.com/us/merchant/pdf/BM-Entire_Manual_public.pdf.

6. New Zealand Interchange Fees, 2015 http://www.westpac.co.nz/business/payment-solutions/pricing-and-fees/.

7. First Data Annual Report (10-K) (2014).

8. Interchange Fees of MasterCard https://www.mastercard.us/en-us/about-mastercard/what-we-do/interchange.html

9. MasterCard Merchant Rules (2016) https://www.mastercard.com/ca/merchant/en/getstarted/rules.html

10. Data on Visa (from its Website) http://corporate.visa.com/about-visa/our-business/visa-inc-and-visa-europe.shtml.

11. MasterCard Corporate Overview, http://phx.corporate-ir.net/External.File?item=UGFyZW50SUQ9NjQ1MzZ8Q2hpbGRJRD0tMXxUeXBlPTM=&t=1.

12. Mastercard Worldwide, Benefits of Payment Cards to Consumers

http://www.mastercard.com/us/company/en/docs/Benefits_of_Payment_Cards_to_Consumers.pdf.

13. Mastercard Worldwide, Benefits of Payment Cards to Merchants http://www.mastercard.com/us/company/en/docs/Benefits_of_Payment_Cards_to_Merchants.pdf

14. U.S. Visa Interchange Fees http://usa.visa.com/merchants/operations/interchange_rates.html.

15. Visa International Operating Regulations Core Principles

http://usa.visa.com/download/merchants/visa-international-operating-regulations-core.pdf.

16. Visa, Europe, Interchange Fees

http://www.visaeurope.com/en/about_us/what_we_do/fees_and_interchange/interchange_fees.aspx.

17. Visa Inc. Annual Report (Form 10-k) Sept. 30, 2014.

18. Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems, Statistics on Payment, Clearing and

Settlement Systems in the CPSS Countries, (Sept. 2014)

http://www.bis.org/cpmi/publ/d120.pdf .

7. Hebrew Legislation

1. Bank of Israel, Process of Receiving Acquirer's License (Dec. 31, 2013).

2. Bank of Israel Law, 2010.

3. Communication Regulations (Bezeq and Transmissions) (Payments for Termination

Fee), 2000.

4. Payment Cards Law, 1986.

5. Amendment 12 to the Banking Law (Service to Customer), 1981.

6. Banking Law (Licensing), 1981.

7. Divrei Haknesset 19, Sitting 177 at 46-62 (Nov. 12, 2014).

Page 425: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

425

8. Draft Bill Amending the Banking Law (Licensing) 1981 (Amendment 11), HH 2352 (Mar. 11,

1996).

9. Draft Bill for Enhancement of Competition and Reduction in Concentration Law, HH (Gov)

No. 706 p. 1084 (July 9, 2012).

10. Draft Bill to Promote and Defend the Written Press in Israel, 2014

www.knesset.gov.il/privatelaw/data/19/2464.rtf.

11. Draft Bill to Amend the Press Command (Restriction on Free Distribution of Newspaper with

National Circulation), 2010 http://www.knesset.gov.il/privatelaw/data/18/2196.rtf.

12. Draft Bill to amend the Banking Law (Licensing) - Enhancement of Competition in the Credit

Card Market, 2007 /2468/17פ ,

13. Draft Bill to amend the Banking Law (Licensing) - Ownership of Credit Card Issuers, 2009

157/18פ/ .

14. Draft Bill to amend the Banking Law (Licensing) - Ownership of Credit Card Issuers, 2013

. 1066/19פ/

15. Draft Bill to amend the Banking Law (Licensing) - Ownership of Issuing Undertakings, 2007

2475/17פ/ .

16. Draft Bill to Enhance Competition in Credit (Divestiture of Bank Ownership in Credit Card

Firms), 2014 /2180/19פ .

17. Bank of Israel, Banking Proper Procedure, Payment Cards (Instruction 470)

http://www.boi.org.il/he/BankingSupervision/SupervisorsDirectives/DocLib/470.pdf.

18. Banking Decree (Service to Customer) (Supervision on Service that an Issuer Grants an

Acquirer with Connection to Interchange Acquiring of Debit Transactions) (Temporary Order),

2015.

19. Banking Law (Licensing), 1981.

20. Banking Rules (Service to Customer) (Fees), 2008.

21. Directives of the Banks' Supervisor - Notice on Issuers with Large Scale of Activity (Dec. 20,

2011) http://www.boi.org.il/he/NewsAndPublications/PressReleases/Pages/111220h.aspx.

22. Government Decision 749, Sept. 17, 2013

http://www.pmo.gov.il/Secretary/GovDecisions/2013/Pages/govdec749.aspx.

23. Interpretation Command [New Version].

24. Interpretation Law, 1981.

25. Law for Enhancement of Competition and Reduction of Concentration and Conflicts of

Interests in the Capital Markets in Israel (Legislation Amendments), 2005.

26. Law for Advancement of Competition and Reduction in Concentration (Hok Lekidum

Hataharut Vezimzum Harikuziut), 2013.

27. Memorandum, Antitrust Law (Amendment 9), 2005 http://www.antitrust.gov.il/law.htm.

28. Memorandum, Antitrust Law (Amendment 16 - Determination of Interchange Fee), Antitrust

500777 (Aug. 10, 2014).

29. Opinion 2/11: Guidelines on Remedies to Mergers that Raise Concerns of Significant Harm to

Competition, Antitrust 5001804 (July 18, 2011).

30. Price Ordinance (Removal of Supervision on ATMs Withdrawal Fees), 2006.

Page 426: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

426

31. Prohibition of Discrimination in Products, Services and Entry to Places of Entertainment and

Public Facilities Law, 2000.

32. Supervision of Commodities and Services Order (Partial Removal of Supervision of Fee for

Cash Withdrawals through ATMs), 2006, KT 6452 p. 328

http://www.knesset.gov.il/laws/data/regulation/6452/6452.pdf.

8. Hebrew Literature

1. AHRON BARAK, INTERPRETRATION IN LAW - INTERPRETRATION OF LEGISLATION (1993).

2. ______, Prohibit Price Discrimination [Lesor Al Aflayat Mehirim], THEMARKER (May 3,

2016).

3. ——— , The Other Side of the Newspaper, THE 7TH EYE (Dec. 15, 2012).

4. Moshe Boronovsky, On the Elements of the Restriction and its Object - New and Not New, 5

MECHKAREI MISHPAT 125 (1987).

5. AVINASH DIXIT & BARRY NALEBUFF, GAME THEORY (Ilan Michal trans., Aliyat Hagag Books

2010).

6. MICHAL GAL, RESTRICTIVE ARRANGEMENT - ELEMENTS OF THE PROHIBITION, IN LEGAL AND

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST LAW 193 (Michal Gal & Menachem Perlman eds., 2008).

7. David Gilo, Passive Investments between Competitors in Israel, 35 MISHPATIM 1 (2005).

8. ———. , Restriction that Harms Competition between the Beneficiary and its Competitors, 28

IUNEI MISHPAT 517 (2005).

9. ———. , Is it Appropriate to Break Antitrust Dam and Block the Flood in Ad-Hok

Fences, 27(3) IUNEI MISHPAT 751 (2004).

10. ———. , CONTRACTS THAT RESTRICT COMPETITION, in 3 CONTRACTS 638 (Nili Cohen &

Daniel Fridman eds).

11. Ofer Groskoph, Paternalizm, Public Policy and Government Monopoly in the Gambling

Market, 7 HAMISHPAT 9 (2007).

12. ITAMAR MILRED, DESCRIPTION OF CREDIT CARDS MARKET AND ANALYZING INTERFACES

BETWEEN CREDIT CARD FIRMS AND THE BANKS, (The Knesset Center for Research and

Information, Feb, 2014).

13. Dror Reich, Summary of Conference on Payment Cards, THEMARKER (Sept. 22, 2011).

9. Hebrew Cases

1. AT 610/06 Leumi Et Al. v. Antitrust General Director (Opinion of the General Director), (Oct.

7, 2007).

2. Supplement Civil Litigation (SCL) 6811/04 Menahel Mas Shevach v Naftali Shadmi, PD 61(1)

778 (2009).

3. Cr.C 167/03 State of Israel v. Mordechai Cohen (Feb. 7, 2007).

4. AT 3276/99 Arutzei Zahav v. Association of Movie Directors (July 6, 2000).

5. CA 2706/11 Sybil Germany v. Harmatic (Sept. 4, 2015).

Page 427: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

427

6. Ci.C 5315/08 Nadav Lahat v. Forum Production (Claim) (Oct. 30, 2008).

7. Ci.C 5315/08 Nadav Lahat v. Forum Productions, (Dec. 26, 2011).

8. Cr.C (Jerusalem) 377/04 State of Israel v. Yaron Wol (July 3, 2007).

9. AT 3574/00 Music Federation v. Antitrust General Director, (April 29, 2004).

10. AT 103/09 Antitrust General Director v. Tnuva (Dec. 28, 2009).

11. AT 13/93 Adanim Bank v. Consumer Council (Jan. 27, 1997).

12. SCL 5189/05 Ayalon v. State of Israel (Apr. 23, 2006).

13. Cr.C 4016-06-12 State of Israel v. Ezra Shoam (Feb. 23, 2014).

14. Motion 34/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director (Dec. 22, 2002).

15. Appeal 9/99 Amana v. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 3013742 (Feb. 21, 2002).

16. C.A 2616/03 Isracard v Howard Rice, PD 59(5), 701 (2006).

17. CrA 7829/03 State of Israel v. Ariel, PD 60(2) 120 (2005).

18. HCJ 1661/05 Local Council Hof Aza v the Knesset, PD 59(2) 481 (2005).

19. AA 6464/03 Real Estate Appraisers BAR v Department of Justice, PD 58(3) 293 (2004).

20. CA 6233/02 Akastel v. Kalma Vi, PD 48(2) 635 , (2004).

21. SCL 1333/02 Local Zoning Committee v Judith Horoviz, PD 58(6) 289, (2004).

22. CrA 1042/03 Mezerples v. State of Israel, PD 58(1) 721, (2003).

23. Cr.C 366/99 State of Israel v. Ehud Svirsky (Feb. 21, 2002).

24. C.A 2299/99 Shfayer v. Diur Laole, PD 55(4) 213, (2001).

25. Cr.C 417/97 State of Israel v. Haphenix (Dec. 18, 2001).

26. HCJ 3267/97 Rubinshtein v. Minister of Defense, PD 52(5) 481, (1998).

27. Civil. C. (T-A) 1617/93 Volkan v. Igud Hamusachim, PDM 1994 (3) 274 (1994).

28. Civ. A. 105/92 Ram Engineering V. Nazereth Municipality, PD 47(5) 189, (1993).

29. CA 2768/90 PetrolGas v. State of Israel, PD 46 (3) 599 (1992).

30. Appeal 2/89 Moetzet Hamovilim v. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 3001546 (1991).

31. Civ. A. 524/88 Pri Haemek v. Sde Yaacov, PD 45(4) 529 (1991).

32. Civ.C. 396/87 Kisin v. PetrolGas, Dinim (1990).

33. HCJ 267/88 Reshet Kolel Haidra v. Court of Local Affairs, PD 43(3) 728, (1989).

34. Ci.C. 2786-06-12 Kobi Tzetzna v. Lord Bars Ltd (July 16, 2014).

35. Civ. Ap. 8821/09 Pavel Prozianski v. Laila Tov Productions (Nov. 16, 2011).

36. AT 508/04 Taagid Haisuf v. Adam Teva Vadin, (Sept. 13, 2005).

37. CA 2063/16 Glik v. Israeli Police, (Jan 19, 2017).

38. HCJ 986/05 Peled v. Tel-Aviv Municipality, para. 14 (Apr. 13, 2005).

39. A.T 36014-12-10 Kaniel v. Antitrust Authority (June 10, 2012).

40. A.T 601/06 Isracard v. Antitrust General Director (July 18, 2010).

41. AT 11333-02-13 Isracard v. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 500647 (Mar. 9, 2014).

Page 428: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

428

42. AT 19545-04-10 Shovarei Bar v. Antitrust General Director (Jan. 24, 2012).

43. AT 4630/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director (Application), Antitrust 4630 (Sept. 13, 2001).

44. AT 4630/01 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 5000592 (Aug. 31, 2006).

45. AT 4630/01 Leumicard v. Antitrust General Director, (Removal of Privileges), Antitrust

3015470 (Sept. 1, 2002).

46. AT 46791-03-14 El Rov v. General Director, (Dec. 4, 2014).

47. AT 491/98 Israel Electric Company v. Antitrust General Director (Mar. 22, 1999).

48. AT 601/06 Gas Companies Association V. Antitrust General Director (July 7, 2010).

49. AT 610/06 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director (Aug. 7, 2011).

50. AT 610/06 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director (Decision to Appoint an Expert), Antitrust

5000840 (Nov. 11, 2007).

51. AT 610/06 Leumi V. Antitrust General Director (Final Report of Shlomi Parizat) (May 23,

2011).

52. AT 610/06 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director (Interim Report of Yossi Bachar) (Jan. 1,

2009).

53. AT 610/06 Leumi v. Antitrust General Director, (Application), Antitrust 6652 (Oct. 30, 2006).

54. AT 610/06 Leumi V. Antitrust General Director, Antitrust 500191 (Mar 7, 2012).

55. AT 7011/02 Antitrust General Director v. Bank Hapoalim, Antitrust 5000874 (Aug. 14, 2006).

56. Civ. Ap. 449/85 General Attorney v. Gad Building Company, PD 43(1) 183 (1989).

57. Civ. C. (Center) 43283-4-14 Hajbi v. Isracart Et al. (Motion to Approve a Class Action) (Apr.

28, 2014).

58. Civ. C. (Center) 46010-07-11 Ophir Naor v. Tnuva, (April 5, 2016).

59. Civ. C. (Center) 53990-11-13 Hazlacha v. AU et al., (March 6, 2016).

60. Civ. C. (Center) 41838-09-14 Weinstein v Mifalei Yam Hamelach (29.1.17)

61. Civ. Ap. 5529/10 Gas Companies Association v. Antitrust General Director (Aug. 12, 2010).

62. Cr. Ap. 4855/02 Borowitz v. State of Israel, PD 59 (6) 776 (2005).

63. Cr. C. 209/96 State of Israel v. Ohalecha Yaacov (Aug. 4, 2002).

64. Cr. Ap. 2560/08 State of Israel v. Yaron Wol (Jul. 6, 2009).

65. Cr. Ap. 2929/02 State of Israel v. Svirsky, PD 57(3) 135.

66. Cr. Ap. 5672/08 Tagar v. State of Israel (Oct. 21, 2010).

67. Cr. Ap. 5823/14 Supersal v. State of Israel (Aug. 10, 2015).

68. Cr. C. 1274/00 State of Israel v. Mudgal (Mar. 12, 2010).

69. HCJ 2194/06 Shinui Party v. Head of Election Commity (Mar. 12, 2006).

70. HCJ 4491/13 Merkaz Academy Lemishpat Veasakim v. Government of Israel (July 2, 2014).

71. HCJ 588/84 K.S.R Asbestos v. Chairman of Antitrust Council, PD 40(1) 29 (1986).

72. SCL 4465/98 Tivol v. Shef Hayam, PD 56(1) 56 (2001).

Page 429: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

429

10. Antitrust General Director Decisions

1. Exemption to Gas Companies (Sonol, Delek, Dor) for Collective Bargaining and Joint

Purchase of Jet Fuel Insurance Policy, Antitrust 500526 (Dec. 24, 2013).

2. Exemption to Visa Issuers and Acquirers, Antitrust 3008827 (Aug. 24, 2000).

3. Opinion 1/14 Prohibition on Excessive Prices by a Monopoly, 500603 Antitrust (Apr. 9, 2014).

4. Opinion 1/00 Cooperation between Competitors versus Governmental Authorities, Antitrust

3007119 (Feb. 6, 2000).

5. Determination According to Section 43(a)(2) - Course of Action of Private Hospitals is a

Restrictive Arrangement, (Dec. 31, 2007).

6. Exemption with Conditions to T.M.I.R, Antitrust 5001799 (June 30, 2011).

7. Determination According to Section 43(a)(1) of the Antitrust Law to Information Exchange

between Banks, Antitrust 501411 (Apr. 26, 2009).

8. General Director's Guidelines, Opinion 1/08 Cooperation among Institutional Investors with

Regard to Changing the Terms of Corporate Bonds, Antitrust 5001318 (Nov. 25, 2008).

9. Opinion 3/14 Trade Associations and their Activities, Antitrust 500682 (Sept. 24, 2014).

10. Exemption for Common Holidays in Private Kinder Gardens, Antitrust 5001534 (Dec. 22,

2009).

11. Exemption to Insurance Companies Union, Antitrust 5001658 (2010).

12. Exemption to Arrangement between Members of the Israeli Bar Association, Antitrust 5000697

(2004).

13. Exemption for Members of the Israeli Bar Association - Campaign "Apartment from

Contractor", Antitrust 5000052 (2004).

14. Exemption to Restrictive Arrangement between Members of the Bar Association - "Operation

Will", Antitrust 5000697 (2004).

15. Exemption with Conditions to SHVA, 500369 Antitrust (20.3.13).

16. Determination - Course of Action of Travel Agents, 3001432 Antitrust (1997).

17. Exemption to Insurance Companies Union, Dissemination of Research about Earthquakes

Damages, 3001359 Antitrust (1996).

18. Determination According to Section 43 of the Antitrust Law regarding a Course of Action

between Real Estate Appraisers - Dissemination of a Minimum Tariff, Antitrust 3006353

(1995).

19. Decision regarding Actors Association, Antitrust 3003746 (1994).

20. Determination - Restrictive Arrangement regarding Isracard, Antitrust 3006076 (1993).

21. Exemption to Agreement between the Israel Hotels Association and its Members regarding

Joint Negotiation with Copyright Management Corporations (Oct. 16, 2002).

22. Exemption with Conditions to "Choices" Foundation, Antitrust 5001365 (Feb. 15, 2009).

23. Objection of the General Director to a Merger between Seebus and Millpas, Antitrust 5001982

(June 14, 2012).

24. Exemption to Israeli Harbors, Antitrust 5001292 (Oct. 12, 2008).

25. Exemption to Veolia and Tahel for Bids' Cooperation, Antitrust 5000999 (July 1, 2008).

Page 430: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

430

26. Exemption with Conditions to SHVA, Antitrust 500393 (May 1, 2013).

27. Annulment of Declaration on Isracart as a Monopoly, Antitrust 4538 (July 3, 2012).

28. Decision Not to Exempt a Joint Negotiation Arrangement between Physician Union and Health

Insurers, Antitrust 501009 (Jul. 13, 2016).

29. Declaration on Isracard as Monopoly in Acquiring Isracart and MasterCard, Antitrust

5000034 (May 22, 2005).

30. Exemption to Restrictive Agreement between CAL, Diners Cards and Union Bank, Antitrust

5001695 (Dec. 1, 2010).

31. Exemption to 5 Banks - Interchange Fee in ATMs, Antitrust 3015632 (Oct. 8, 2002).

32. Exemption to Isracard, Leumicard and CAL, Antitrust 5001952 (May 14, 2012).

33. Exemption to Isracard, Leumicard and CAL, Antitrust 500207 (Aug. 8, 2012) .

34. Exemption to Isracard, Leumicard and CAL, Antitrust 500226 (Sept. 13, 2012).

35. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust 5000714 (June 17, 2004).

36. Exemption with Conditions in re: SHVA, Antitrust 4804 (June 18, 2002), (Sept. 17, 2002).

37. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 3014681 (June 20, 2002).

38. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 5001308 (Nov. 5, 2008).

39. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 5001954 (May 22, 2012).

40. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 500271 (Dec. 20, 2012).

41. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 500368 (Mar. 20, 2013).

42. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 5667 (June 17, 2004).

43. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust 5669 (Nov. 19, 2014).

44. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: MASSAV, Antitrust 500223 (Sept. 20, 2012).

45. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: SHVA, (Feb. 9, 2014).

46. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust 5001307 (Nov. 5, 2008).

47. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust 5001953 (May 22, 2012).

48. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust 500224 (Sept. 20, 2012).

49. Exemption with Conditions to 5 Banks in re: SHVA, Antitrust 500459 (Aug. 26, 2013).

50. Exemption with Conditions to a Restrictive Arrangement between CAL et al., Antitrust

3014977 (July 22, 2002) .

51. Exemption with Conditions to a Restrictive Arrangement between CAL et al., Antitrust

3015230 (Aug. 12, 2002).

52. Exemption with Conditions to a Restrictive Arrangement between CAL et al., Antitrust

3019786 (March 1, 2004).

53. Exemption with Conditions to a Restrictive Arrangement between CAL et al., Antitrust

5000444 (Feb. 19, 2006).

54. Exemption with Conditions to a Restrictive Arrangement between Leumicard et al., Antitrust

3010373 (Mar 8, 2001).

55. Exemption with Conditions to a Restrictive Arrangement between Alpha Card et al., Antitrust

3007229 (July 7, 1998).

Page 431: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

431

56. Exemption with Conditions to Issuers and Acquirers in Visa Network, Antitrust 3009123 (May

18, 2000).

57. Exemption with Conditions to Issuers and Acquirers in Visa Network, Antitrust 3008373 (July

6, 2000).

58. Exemption with Conditions to the Isracard, LeumiCard and CAL, Antitrust 5000623 (May 30,

2006).

11. Miscellaneous

1. Visa core rules and visa product and service rules (April 15, 2015) https://usa.visa.com/dam/VCOM/download/about-visa/15-April-2015-Visa-Rules-Public.pdf

2. Letter from Keith B. Nelson, Principal Deputy Assistant Attorney General to the Judiciary

Committee (June 23, 2008).

3. Credit Card Interchange Fees: Antitrust Concerns? Congress Senate Committee on Judiciary

(U.S. Government Printing Office, 2006).

4. Visa Europe, Press Release, Visa Inc. to Acquire Visa Europe (Nov. 2, 2015)

https://www.visaeurope.com/newsroom/news/vi-to-acquire-ve.

5. APCA (Australian Payments Clearing Association), Annual Review 2015.

6. Boston Tea Party Historical Society, http://www.boston-tea-party.org/.

7. Monty Python - Life of Brian - the Haggle, Comedy Film, Directed by Terry Jones (1979)

http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=3n3LL338aGA.

8. BoA to Instate $5 Monthly Fee for Debit Card Purchases, Pymnts. Com (Sept. 29, 2011)

available at http://pymnts.com/BoA-to-Instate-5-Monthly-Fee-for-Debit-Card-Purchases.

9. Wells Fargo Ends Debit Rewards Program Entirely, PYMNTS. COM (Aug. 22, 2011) available

at http://pymnts.com/Wells-Fargo-Ends-Debit-Rewards-Program-Entirely/

10. THE European PAYMENTS COUNCIL, PRESS RELEASE, EPC LAUNCHES THE TWO SEPA DIRECT

DEBIT SCHEMES IN NOVEMBER 2009, (Apr. 1 2009), available at http://www.europeanpaymentscouncil.eu/knowledge_bank_download.cfm?file=EPC109-09%20%20Press%20Release%20Launch%20SEPA%20Direct%20Debit%202009-04-01.pdf.

11. Pressure on B of A Mounts as Rivals Ditch Debit Fees, AM. BANKER, Nov. 1, 2011.

12. MasterCard International, MasterCard's Submission to the Reserve Bank of Australia, (2001) http://www.rba.gov.au/payments-system/reforms/cc-schemes/iii-submissions-vol2/o1-mastercard-final.pdf.

13. U.S. Payment Card Interchange Fee Settlement Website

https://www.paymentcardsettlement.com/en.

12. Hebrew Miscellaneous

1. Ori BarAm, Note on Ruling 8821/09 Pavel Prozianski v. Laila Tov Productions, Nevo (2011).

2. Ori BarAm & Elad Man, One Price for Gas, Big Prize for Consumers, THEMARKER (Aug. 22,

2016).

3. Bank of Israel, Supervision of Banks, The Fee Reform (Oct. 30, 2010).

4. Bank of Israel, Communication 2498-06-ח, Acquiring Payment Cards, Banking Proper

Procedure, Instruction 472 (May 1, 2016).

Page 432: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

432

5. Bank of Israel, Chain of Transaction in Payment Card, (July 2016).

6. Bank of Israel, Press Release, Reduction of Payment Card Fees (Feb. 1, 2015).

7. Bank of Israel, Draft for Comments, Process for Granting Acquiring License (Dec. 17, 2015).

8. BANK OF ISRAEL, PRESS RELEASE, SPEECH OF KARNIT FLUG, GOVERNOR OF BANK OF ISRAEL IN

A CONVENTION MOONEY AND TECHNOLOGY (March 26, 2014).

9. BANK OF ISRAEL, THE BANKING SYSTEM IN ISRAEL, 2015 ANNUAL REVIEW (2016).

10. BANK OF ISRAEL, PAYMENT AND ACQUIRING SYSTEMS IN ISRAEL (THE RED BOOK) (2013).

11. BANK OF ISRAEL, PAYMENT AND ACQUIRING SYSTEMS IN ISRAEL (THE RED BOOK) (2014).

12. COMMITTEE ON INCREASING COMPETITIVENESS IN THE ECONOMY (SHANI COMMITTEE) FINAL

REPORT (2012).

13. REPORT OF INTER-MINISTRY COMMITTEE FOR INVESTIGATING MARKET FAILURES IN CREDIT

CARD MARKET, Ministry of Finance Accounting General, (2007).

14. REPORT OF THE INTER-MINISTRY COMMITTEE FOR INSPECTION OF MARKET FAILURES IN THE CREDIT

CARD MARKET, Ministry of Finance, accountant General (2007).

15. BANK OF ISRAEL, ECONOMIC SURVEY (March 18, 2013).

16. Central Bureau of Statistics, Financial Literacy Survey: Financial Situation of Israelis (Sept. 11,

2012).

17. ANTITRUST, PRESS RELEASE, THE CREDIT CARD FIRMS WILL DECREASE TOMORROW THE

AVERAGE INTERCHANGE FEE TO NO MORE THAN 0.875%, Antitrust 5001868 (Oct. 31, 2010).

18. ANTITRUST, PRESS RELEASE, FOLLOWING APPROVAL OF THE ACQUIRING SETTLEMENT, REPEAL

OF THE MONOPOLY DECLARATION ON ISRACARD, Antitrust 5001977 (June 17, 2012).

19. ANTITRUST, PRESS RELEASE, THE ANTITRUST TRIBUNAL APPROVED THE SETTLEMENT BETWEEN

THE GENERAL DIRECTOR AND THE CREDIT CARD FIRMS, Antitrust 5001903 (March 8, 2012).

20. ANTITRUST, PRESS RELEASE, THE GENERAL DIRECTOR CONDITIONED A MERGER BETWEEN

YATZIL AND CAL IN OPENING THE FACTORING MARKETS FOR COMPETITION, Antitrust 3018872

(2003).

21. ANTITRUST, PRESS RELEASE, TRIBUNAL REJECTED THE VISA FIRMS' MOTION FOR PRIVILEGE,

Antitrust 3015423 (Sept. 3, 2002).

22. ANTITRUST, PRESS RELEASE, THE GENERAL DIRECTOR AND THE CREDIT CARD FIRMS REACHED

AN AGREEMENT REGARDING A DRAMATIC INTERCHANGE FEE DECREASE AND EXTENSION OF

THE CROSS ACQUIRING AGREEMENT UNTIL 2018, Antitrust 5001886 (Dec. 28, 2011).

23. Bank of Israel, Expansion of Debit Card Distribution, Letter from the Banks' Supervisor (June

29, 2015).

24. BANK OF ISRAEL, PRESS RELEASE, ANNOUNCEMENT OF REDUCTION IN THE NUMBER OF

PAYMENT CARD FEES (Apr. 30, 2014), .

25. BANK OF ISRAEL, RECOMMENDATIONS FOR ENHANCEMENT OF COMPETITION IN PAYMENT

CARDS, FINAL REPORT (Feb. 2015).

26. Bank of Israel, the Supervision of Banks - Banking Consumerism, Advantages and

Disadvantages of Revolving Credit

27. THE COMMITTEE FOR REDUCING THE USE OF CASH (LOCKER COMMITTEE), FINAL REPORT (July

17. 2014).

Page 433: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

433

28. THE COMMITTEE FOR REDUCING THE USE OF CASH (LOCKER COMMITTEE), INTERIM REPORT

(May 2014).

29. Decision 1551 of Ministers’ Committee on Cost of Living Regarding the Enhancement of

Competition and Efficiency in Payment Cards (Apr. 2014).

30. Draft Recommendations, Committee for Increasing Competitiveness in the Economy.

31. Globes, Isracard Will Issue Payment Cards to Customers of Mizrachi Tfachot Branded Credit

Cards (Aug. 23, 2009).

32. ISRAEL ANTITRUST AUTHORITY DRAFT REPORT ON ENHANCEMENT OF EFFICIENCY AND

COMPETITION IN PAYMENT CARDS, Antitrust 500560 (Feb. 11, 2014).

33. ———. , FINAL REPORT ON ENHANCEMENT OF COMPETITION IN PAYMENT CARDS, Antitrust

500680 (Sept. 8, 2014).

34. ______. , Opinion 1/17 CONSIDERATIONS OF THE GENERAL DIRECTOR IN ENFORCING EXCESSIVE

PRICING, Antitrust 501194 (Feb. 28, 2017)..

35. ______. , PRESS RELEASE, WORLD BANK AWARDED COMMENDATION TO THE IAA FOR DEBIT

REFORM, Antitrust 500811 (July 8, 2015).

36. ______. , PRESS RELEASE, BANK OF ISRAEL PUBLISHES INSTRUCTIONS FOR ASSIMILATION OF

DEBIT CARDS AND ENHANCEMENT OF COMPETITION IN PAYMENT CARDS (June 30, 2015).

37. ______. , PRESS RELEASE, IAA PUBLISHES A RESEARCH ON COMPETITION IN PAYMENT CARDS,

Antitrust 500561 (Feb. 12, 2014).

38. Sivan Eizensco, The Little Fee that Produces Additional 700 Million NIS to Banks from Credit

Cards, THEMARKER (Apr. 27, 2014).

39. Tomer Varon, Gama on its Way to Become Fourth Competitor in the Credit

Market, CALCALIST (Aug. 5, 2015).

Page 434: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

434

תקציר עבודת דוקטורט בנושא:

הפרדה מבנית בין סולקים ומנפיקים,

והצעה להגבלת רווחיות

במערכות תשלומים עם עמלה צולבת

מוגש על ידי אורי ברעם

Page 435: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

435

מציע שני חידושים שאימוצם עשוי להביא לעמלה צולבת תחרותית, דבר שמשמעו חיסכון של מיליארדי אני .1

למשק הישראלי וטריליארדי דולר למשק העולמי; לירידה קטנה אך רוחבית וכלל משקית של כלל מחירי ₪

ומות ובמשאבים המוצרים והשירותים; לשימוש יעיל בכרטיסי חיוב. כל זאת תוך הפחתה ניכרת בעלויות העצ

האדירים שמושקעים כיום על ידי רגולטורים, טריבונלים ורשויות תחרות למיניהן ברחבי העולם בפיקוח על

העמלה הצולבת בכרטיסי חיוב.

עמלה צולבת היא התשלום שמשלמים סולקים של כרטיסי חיוב למנפיקים של כרטיסי חיוב במערכות .2

, שבהן הסולק של העסקה הוא לא בהכרח המנפיק של כרטיס תשלומים "פתוחות" )כמו ויזה ומסטרכארד(

החיוב עמו בוצעה העסקה.

בשנה. ברחבי ₪ בישראל בלבד, סכום העמלה הצולבת שסולקים משלמים למנפיקים מתקרב לשני מיליארד .3

העולם גובים מנפיקים מידי שנה עמלה צולבת בסדר גודל של טריליארדי דולרים.

ולק את "עמלת הסליקה", שאותה הסולק שומר לעצמו. סולקים גובים מבתי עסק לעמלה הצולבת מוסיף הס .4

"עמלת בית עסק", שהינה התשלום שמשלם בית עסק עבור כיבוד כרטיסי חיוב. עמלת בית עסק מורכבת

מהעמלה הצולבת )שמועברת למנפיק( בתוספת עמלת הסליקה )המרווח של הסולק(. העמלה הצולבת היא

לת בית העסק. ככל שהעמלה הצולבת גבוהה יותר, כך עמלת בית העסק תהיה גבוהה יותר. מרכיב עיקרי בעמ

עבור בתי עסק, עמלת בית העסק היא תשומה. בתי עסק מגלגלים תשומה זו, ככל תשומה אחרת, על מחירי .5

רוחבי, המוצרים והשירותים שהם מוכרים. על כן ככל שהעמלה הצולבת גבוהה יותר, כך עולים באופן קטן אך

כלל המחירים בבתי עסק שמכבדים כרטיסי חיוב.

העמלה הצולבת היא הסדר כובל לתיאום מחיר מינימום לעמלת בית עסק. הסיבה העיקרית לכך שעמלה .6

צולבת היא הסדר כובל הינה שמי שמשלם אותה )למשל בישראל, לאומי קארד, ישראכרט וכ.א.ל בכובען

לום )ישראכרט, לאומי קארד וכ.א.ל בכובען כמנפיקים(. הסולקים כסולקים(, הוא גם הצד שמקבל את התש

מגלגלים את העמלה הצולבת על לקוחותיהם, בתי העסק, כחלק מעמלת בית העסק. צד ההנפקה פחות תחרותי

ומנפיקים לא מעבירים את כל התקבולים מהעמלה הצולבת ללקוחותיהם, מחזיקי כרטיסי חיוב )להלן:

נהנים מהעמלה הצולבת שהינה עבורם מקור רווח משמעותי. חלוקת ההכנסות "(. המנפיקיםמחזיקים"

מהעמלה הצולבת נקבעת לפי נתחי השוק בצד ההנפקה. כתוצאה מדרך קביעתה המערבת "מסחר עצמי",

העמלה הצולבת לא נקבעת על שיעור תחרותי שהיה שורר אילו המו"מ לקביעתה היה מתנהל בין קונה )סולק(

וכר )מנפיק( מרצון. הסולקים )המשלמים את העמלה( נהנים ממנה בכובעם כמנפיקים, ולכן הם מרצון לבין מ

"מוותרים" במו"מ, ומסכימים לשלם מחיר הגבוה מהמחיר התחרותי.

עולמי בקרב רגולטורים, מלומדים, -בשל ניגוד עניינים מובנה זה בקביעת העמלה הצולבת, קיים קונצנזוס כלל

שהינם גם מנפיקים שפט ורשויות, שעמלה צולבת הנקבעת במשא ומתן חופשי בין סולקיםטריבונלים, בתי מ

תהיה "מנופחת" וגבוהה מזו האופטימלית. כאמור, עמלה צולבת גבוהה גורמת לעליית מחירים קטנה אך

ת רוחבית במשק, ודי בכך כדי לסווג את ההסדר לקביעתה כהסדר כובל. מעבר לכך, עמלה צולבת גבוהה גורמ

לסבסוד צולב בין אמצעי תשלום ולשימוש יתר באמצעי תשלום פחות יעילים על חשבון אמצעי תשלום יעילים

יותר, וגם מטעם זה ההסדר לקביעתה עולה כדי הסדר כובל.

ברגיל, דיני ההגבלים העסקיים של כל המדינות המתוקנות אוסרים מכל וכל על הסדרים כובלים לתיאום .7

העסקיים. אף על פי כן, העמלה איסור זה הוא מאבני היסוד של דיני ההגבלים תחרים.מחירי מינימום בין מ

Page 436: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

436

הצולבת היא הסדר כובל לתיאום מחיר מינימום בין סולקים ומנפיקים מתחרים, אשר זכה לאישור בכל

צדדי. למוצרי רשת דו -המדינות בעולם. הטעם לכך הינו שמערכות של כרטיסי חיוב הן בגדר מוצר רשת דו

צדדים יש מאפיינים מיוחדים, שמצדיקים החלת דין שונה מזה הנוהג במוצרים "רגילים". במערכות של

כרטיסי חיוב קיימות תופעות של החצנות, שאותה עמלה צולבת יעילה יכולה להפנים.

החצנה אחת שקיימת במערכות תשלומים של כרטיסי חיוב היא החצנת רשת. זו ההחצנה שנגרמת כאשר רשת

רטיסי החיוב קטנה מהגודל האופטימלי שלה, בגלל שהביקוש לכרטיסי חיוב בצד אחד )למשל בקרב כ

מחזיקים(, נמוך מהביקוש בצד שני )למשל בקרב בתי עסק(. כאשר הנכונות של הציבור לשלם עבור כרטיסי

צולבת יכולה חיוב נמוכה, אך בקרב בתי עסק יש נכונות גבוהה מספיק לשלם עבור כרטיסי חיוב, העמלה ה

להפנים את חוסר הסימטריה הגורם להחצנת רשת, על ידי העברת כסף מהצד שבו הביקוש גבוה יותר לצד

שבו הביקוש נמוך יותר, ולסייע בכך לגידול יעיל של הרשת.

החצנה שניה שקיימת במערכות כרטיסי חיוב ושאותה עמלה צולבת יעילה יכולה להפנים, היא החצנת שימוש.

צנה שנגרמת כאשר המחזיקה, בקופה, משתמשת באמצעי תשלום יקר ולא יעיל חברתית )למשל מזומן זו ההח

או שיק( ולא באמצעי תשלום זול ויעיל )למשל כרטיסי חיוב מיידי(, רק בגלל שהמחזיקה / המשלמת היא זו

בורה( אפילו שמקבלת את ההחלטה באיזה אמצעי תשלום לשלם, ויותר נוח לה לשלם באמצעי תשלום זול )ע

אם מבחינה חברתית זהו אמצעי תשלום יקר ולא יעיל. בעבודה מוקדש פרק לעלויות ולתועלות של אמצעי

התשלום. הממצאים האמפירים מעלים שכרטיסי חיוב )במיוחד כרטיס חיוב מיידי( הינו אמצעי תשלום יעיל

הן מזומן הוא אמצעי התשלום הזול וזול יותר מתשלום במזומן ובשיקים )למעט עסקאות ב"סכומי מטבע", שב

ביותר(. עמלה צולבת מפנימה את החצנת השימוש אם בלעדי העמלה הצולבת לא יהא מספיק שימוש באמצעי

התשלום היעיל )לדוגמה, עסקאות שיעיל לעשותן בכרטיס חיוב יתבצעו באמצעי תשלום נחות(. עמלה צולבת

ודד שימוש יעיל בכרטיסי חיוב, יכולה להפנים את החצנת שמועברת לצד ההנפקה על מנת להוזיל עלויות ולע

השימוש, ולתרום לשימוש יעיל באמצעי תשלום.

לפיו, כסף רע דוחק Gresham’s Law Of Payments))הנו "חוק גרישם" של החצנת שימוש כינוי אחר לתופעה

שני שטרות, האחד בלוי כםכך למשל, אם יש בארנק .Bad Money Drives Out The Good -מהמחזור כסף טוב

תעדיפו להשתמש בשטר הבלוי לפני השטר החדש, פן יקרע השטר הבלוי כשהוא ברשותכם. –והשני חדש

ידי המשלם שממהר להיפטר ממנו, וכך הלאה, והכסף הרע העלות היקרה של טיפול בשטר דהוי, מוחצנת על

.דוחק את הטוב מהמחזור

עולה שהעמלה הצולבת היא מצד אחד הסדר כובל לתיאום מחירי מינימום בין מתחרים שברגיל מן המקובץ .8

אסור מכל וכל על ידי דיני התחרות ברחבי העולם. מצד שני ובד בבד עמלה צולבת היא אמצעי יעיל להפנמת

ילה. ואכן, החצנות הקיימות במוצרי רשת דו צדדים. לפיכך רמה מסויימת של עמלה צולבת יכולה להיות יע

משאבים אדירים מושקעים ברחבי העולם על ידי רגולטורים, בנקים מרכזיים, טריבונלים תחרותיים, בתי

משפט ורשויות נוספות, כדי לאשר עמלה צולבת אך בו זמנית לזהות את שיעורה ה"נכון" ולפקח שהיא לא

גבוהה מידי מעוררת. כמבואר תהיה גבוהה מידי. בעבודה מוקדש פרק לחששות התחרותיים שעמלה צולבת

כבר לעיל, עמלה צולבת גבוהה מידי גורמת לעליית מחירים קטנה אך רוחבית בכלל המשק. שנית, עמלה צולבת

גבוהה מידי גורמת לסבסוד צולב בין אמצעי תשלום. במקום שהעמלה הצולבת תסייע להגדיל שימוש יעיל של

רמת לתשלום יתר באמצעי תשלום יקרים על חשבון אמצעי אמצעי תשלום זולים, כשהיא גבוהה מידי היא גו

תשלום זולים.

Page 437: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

437

בתחום של כרטיסי חיוב, היד הנעלמה של התחרות לא פועלת כהלכה. בניגוד למוצר רגיל שאותו הצרכן לא .9

יקנה, אם העלות שלו גבוהה מהתועלת שהוא מניב, בתי עסק חוששים לסרב לקבל כרטיסי חיוב, אף אם

עמלת בית העסק( גבוהה מהתועלת שיש לבית העסק מקבלת כרטיס חיוב לעומת אמצעי תשלום עלותם )כלומר

אחר. החשש העיקרי של בתי עסק הינו מנטישת לקוחות שלא ירצו לרכוש מוצרים ושירותים בבית עסק שלא

פעה זו ( בגין קבלת כרטיסי חיוב. תוsurchargeמכבד כרטיסי חיוב, או אפילו ש"רק" גובה תוספת תשלום )

"שיקולים אסטרטגיים" של בתי עסק. השיקולים האסטרטגיים מוחרפים Rochet & Tiroleכונתה על ידי

בשל תחרות בין רשתות כרטיסי חיוב על ליבם של מחזיקים. כאשר מחזיקים עושים שימוש עיקרי בכרטיס

הממומנות ולו -ת ( אזי תחרות בין רשתות מתבטאת בהרעפת הטבוsinglehomingאחד )תופעה המכונה

על מחזיקים. להיטות מחזיקים לשלם בכרטיסי חיוב נושאי הטבות -בחלקן על ידי העמלה הצולבת

)הממומנות על ידי עמלה צולבת( מעצימה עוד יותר את הקושי של בתי עסק לסרב לקבל כרטיסים )תופעה

, תחרות המתודלקת על ידי עמלה (. וכך, במקום שתחרות תוריד מחיריםmust take cards -שכונתה בספרות

צולבת, גורמת לעליית מחירים.

ברחבי העולם קיימים מספר מודלים של פיקוח על העמלה הצולבת )בעבודה מוקדש פרק שלם לרגולציה .10

(. לפי cost methodologyברחבי העולם(. מתודולוגיה רווחת לקביעת העמלה הצולבת היא לפי עלויות )

צולבת נקבעת בהתאם לעלויות ספציפיות של שירותים שמנפיקים כביכול מעניקים מתודולוגיה זו, העמלה ה

לסולקים. מתודולוגיה נוספת, בה עשתה שימוש הנציבות האירופית, היא לקבוע את העמלה הצולבת על שיעור

שיביא את עמלת בית העסק לנקודה שבה בית העסק יהא אדיש בין קבלת מזומן מלקוח מזדמן )תייר( לבין

(. the tourist testבלת כרטיס חיוב )ק

בעוד שביסודה של מתודולוגית העלויות לא עומד מודל כלכלי כלשהו, ביסוד המתודולוגיה המבוססת על מבחן

התייר עומדים מודלים כלכליים שהוצעו על ידי פרופסורים לכלכלה ידועי שם )בעבודה מוקדש פרק רחב

ות )עלויות ומבחן התייר( דורשות השקעת משאבים ניכרת לצורך למודלים הכלכליים(. שתי המתודולוגי

קביעת העמלה הצולבת ה"נכונה" על פיהן. על שתי המתודלוגיות נמתחה ביקורת, הנסקרת בעבודה בהרחבה,

ולפיה אין ביכולתן להביא את העמלה הצולבת לשיעור אופטימלי. הצעה נוספת שהוצעה כדרך לנטרל את

( ממי אשר משלם באמצעי surchargeהיא מתן אפשרות לבתי עסק לגבות תוספת )השפעת העמלה הצולבת

תשלום יקרים. ואולם תשלום דיפרנציאלי על בתי עסק אינו תמיד ישים ואינו שכיח )בעבודה מוקדש פרק שלם

לסיבות לכך(.

רכזי להפקת כשלון הפיקוח על העמלה הצולבת בא לידי ביטוי בכך שבפועל, העמלה הצולבת משמשת ככלי מ .11

Cozyבשם Rochet & Tiroleרווחי עתק עבור מנפיקים, בניגוד מוחלט למטרותיה. תופעה זו כונתה על ידי

Cartel הצידוקים המקוריים ביסוד אישורה מלכתחילה של העמלה הצולבת לא כללו הפקת רווח, אלא כיסוי .

בכרטיסי חיוב. חברות כרטיסי החיוב עלויות הנפקה שלא מכוסות על ידי המחזיקים ועידוד שימוש יעיל

מציגות שיעורי תשואה החורגים באופן משמעותי בגובהם מהמקובל בתעשיית הפיננסים, כאשר העמלה

הצולבת היא סיבה מרכזית לכך, וזאת בניגוד מוחלט לנימוקים לאישורה.

בת לרמה תחרותית, עבודת הדוקטורט שלי מציעה שני חידושים מהפכניים, שיישומם יביא את העמלה הצול .12

תוך ייתור כמעט מוחלט של הצורך בפיקוח על העמלה הצולבת.

Page 438: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

438

ההצעה הראשונה היא לחייב הפרדה מבנית בין סולקים לבין מנפיקים. גופים פיננסים ייצטרכו לבחור אם .13

לפעול בצד הסליקה או בצד ההנפקה, אך לא בשניהם. העמלה הצולבת תיקבע במשא ומתן תקופתי בין

)הצד המשלם( עצמאיים לבין מנפיקים בלתי קשורים לסולקים. ברירת המחדל בהעדר הסכמה תהיה סולקים

עמלה צולבת אפס. חידוש זה, לו ייושם, יביא לכך שהעמלה הצולבת תפסיק להיות הסדר כובל לתיאום

פיקים מחירים. ההסדר הכובל השיורי שיוותר יהיה משא ומתן משותף בין מתחרים )סולקים מצד אחד ומנ

בלתי קשורים לסולקים מהצד השני(. משא ומתן משותף הינו הסדר כובל "מינורי" שניתן לשליטה. חששות

ממשא ומתן משותף מופגים במיוחד ביחס למנפיקים, אשר לכאורה המו"מ המשותף שלהם בעייתי יותר, כי

)דביט, קרדיט, פריפייד( ברירת המחדל היא אפס. כוח המיקוח לקביעת העמלה הצולבת בכל סוג של עסקאות

יועבר לידי סולקים עצמאיים, שהם הצד המשלם את העמלה הצולבת. ככל שלעמלה הצולבת יש יתרונות

בהפנמת החצנת רשת ובהפנמת החצנת השימוש, הסולקים הם הגוף שיפנים זאת באורח מיטבי, כי הם צד

צולבת רק אם התשלום יביא לגידול לכל העסקאות בכרטיסי חיוב. סולקים עצמאיים יסכימו לשלם עמלה

במחזור העסקאות באופן שימקסם את רווחיהם.

צדדי אחר. מועדוני הכרויות הם מוצר דו צדדי הפונה בעת ובעונה -דוגמה לאמור ניתן למצוא בשוק רשת דו

הביקוש אחת לנשים ולגברים. נניח שתחת תמחור ראשוני כלשהו לגברים ולנשים, יש צד אחד )למשל גברים( ש

שלו גדול מהביקוש של הצד השני )הנשים( לשירותיו של מועדון ההיכרויות. במצב שכזה יש במועדון

ההיכרויות עודף גברים על נשים, באופן שגורם למועדון להיות לא אטרקטיבי ולא יעיל לשני הצדדים. על מנת

גדול מספיק )גברים/ סולקים(, להגדיל את מספר התועלת מהפלטפורמה לשני הצדדים עשוי הצד שבו הביקוש

, על מנת שחלק מהתשלום יועבר לצורך סבסוד המחירים הנגבים מבני המגדר יותרלהסכים מרצונו לשלם

השני )הוזלת התשלום לנשים / מחזיקים(. כלומר, אם נעניק לגברים )סולקים( את כוח המיקוח, הם עשויים

"רגילים", שבהם הרוכש לעולם יעדיף לשלם פחות(, אם כקבוצה להחליט לשלם יותר )הפוך מהמצב בשווקים

כתוצאה מכך תגדל הכמות בצד השני )הפנמת החצנת הרשת( ויגדל מספר האינטרקציות היעילות )הפנמת

החצנת השימוש(.

. כל חיסכון 100%-צד הסליקה נחשבת לתחרותי, ושיעור הגלגול בו מעמלה צולבת לעמלת בית עסק מתקרב ל .14

צולבת אמור להיות מגולגל, בשיעור מעבר מלא, אל בתי עסק. בתי עסק צפויים להעביר את שיושג בעמלה ה

החיסכון ללקוחותיהם, וזאת כתלות בשיעור המעבר של חיסכון בתשומות אל המחירים הסופיים בשווקים

לה הרלוונטיים. החשוב הוא שהפרדה מבנית תגדע מהשורש את ניגוד העניינים המובנה שביסוד קביעת העמ

הצולבת הנוכחית. כיום, בכל העולם, העמלה הצולבת נקבעת על ידי מנפיקים, שהם הצד שמקבל את התשלום.

אין אפוא פלא שהעמלה הצולבת נקבעת פעם אחר פעם ובמדינה אחר מדינה על שיעורים גבוהים

גורדי זה, מהאופטימום, המאפשרים למנפיקים באותה מדינה להפיק ממנה רווחי עתק. הצעתי גודעת קשר

ומנתקת בכך את העמלה הצולבת מהיותה הסדר כובל לתיאום מחירים.

תפגע ברווחיהן. לכן נקבעו -כמו זו המוצעת על ידי –רשתות כרטיסי החיוב היו ערות לכך שהפרדה מבנית .15

NAWIבתקנונים שלהן כלל האוסר על סולקים להיות עצמאיים, ומחייב סולקים להיות קודם כל מנפיקים )

– No acquiring without issuingעם השנים נפסל במקומות רבים כלל ה .)- NAWI ,על ידי רשויות

רגולטורים וטריבונלים שיפוטיים, באופן המאפשר, תיאורטית, את קיומם של סולקים עצמאיים כפי שאני

עצמאיים, בפועל מציע. ואולם, בפועל, על אף שתיאורטית מתיר הדין במדינות רבות את קיומם של סולקים

לא נכנסו לשווקים סולקים עצמאיים אשר קובעים את שיעור העמלה הצולבת שאותה הם משלמים. העמלה

AWI ,Acquiringהצולבת ממשיכה להיקבע על ידי מנפיקים. הצעתי היא למעשה לקבוע כלל מחייב של

Page 439: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

439

without issuingטורים ושל רשויות תחרות ברחבי , ולעגן זאת בחוק. בכך תוגשם השאיפה )שסוכלה( של רגול

, אך מטרתם סוכלה כי בפועל לא קיימים סולקים NAWI -העולם, אשר הביאו אמנם לביטולו של כלל ה

היה תנאי הכרחי אך בלתי NAWI -עצמאיים שקובעים את העמלה הצולבת שהם משלמים. ביטולו של כלל ה

מספיק לפתרון הבעיות שמעוררת העמלה הצולבת. התנאי הנוסף הוא שסולקים עצמאיים אכן ייכנסו לשוק

והם אלה שיקבעו את העמלה הצולבת שהם משלמים. זאת לא אירע בפועל. החידוש שאני מציע יגשים זאת.

רשויות תחרות, טריבונלים ורגולטורים שעליהם החידוש השני שאני מציע הינו כלי רגולטורי, שיכול לשמש .16

הוטלה המשימה הקשה של קביעת שיעור העמלה הצולבת ה"ראוי". חידוש זה מתאים לאימוץ על ידי בנק

ישראל, שיושב כיום על המדוכה במטרה לקבוע את שיעור העמלה הצולבת שיחול בישראל עם תום ההסדר

שוטה והיא למעשה ה"פתרון" של העמלה הצולבת האופטימלית . ההצעה היא פ2018הנוכחי המסתיים בשנת

על פי המודלים הכלכליים, כשהסטנדרט לאופטימליות הינו רווחת הצרכן. במקרה של כרטיסי חיוב,

האופטימום על פי סטנדרט רווחת הצרכן הינו מקסום העודף המצרפי של בתי עסק מצד אחד, והצרכנים )לא

ומן, שיקים ואמצעי תשלום אחרים( מצד שני. מוצרים דו צדדיים כמו כרטיסי רק מחזיקים אלא גם משלמי מז

חיוב פונים בעת ובעונה אחת לשני קהלי יעד ששניהם יחד הם בגדר הצרכן של המוצר הדו צדדי. זאת בדומה

לכך שקוראי עיתונים ומפרסמים הם הצרכן המשולב של עיתונות, ובדומה לכך שבעלי עסקים וציבור הלקוחות

המבקרים הם הצרכן המשולב של מרכזי קניות.

ההצעה שלי תיאלץ את העמלה הצולבת להתכנס למטרותיה החוקיות בלבד, ולא מעבר לכך. אני מציע להתנות

אישור לגביית עמלה צולבת באיסור על מנפיקים להפיק רווחים מעבר לרווח מינימלי על השקעת חסרת סיכון.

לבת לכיסוי עלויות, לרבות עלויות המועברות במלואן לצד המחזיקים כדי מנפיקים יוכלו לגבות עמלה צו

לעודד שימוש יעיל בכרטיסים, ואולם לא אגורה מעבר לכך. כלומר, מנפיקים לא יוכלו להפיק רווח מהעמלה

הצולבת.

וחי מנפיקים מנפיקים יוכלו להפיק רווחים ללא מגבלה, אם יוותרו על גביית עמלה צולבת לחלוטין. ואולם, רו

שיעדיפו לגבות עמלה צולבת יוגבלו. ככל שהרווח של מנפיקים בתקופה כלשהי יהיה גבוה יותר מרווחיות על

השקעה חסרת סיכון, אותם מנפיקים ייאלצו להפחית בתקופה שלאחר מהן את העמלה הצולבת שהם גובים,

באופן שיקזז את הרווח הלא חוקי.

למנפיקים )ליתר דיוק, לבעלי המניות של המנפיקים(, ממצב שבו עמלה הצעתי מעקרת את התועלת שיש

צולבת גבוהה ו"מנופחת" מורעפת ביתר על מחזיקים כהטבות סרק מופלגות, שמעודדות שימוש מוגזם ולא

. מנפיקים הם Wasteful Competitionבשם Rochet & Tiroleיעיל בכרטיסי חיוב, תופעה שכונתה על ידי

ים שיש להם בעלים שמצפים לרווח. בעלי מניות של מנפיקים לא יפיקו שום רווח מעמלה צולבת גופים פיננסי

גבוהה שמועברת למחזיקים כהטבות. בנוסף, הרעפת הטבות סרק היא בעלת תופעות שליליות שעליהן אני

נוספות עומד בעבודה, ושבעטין כבר הוצע בעבר להגביל את העמלה הצולבת מלשמש מקור להטבות. טכניקות

להסוואת רווחים, כמו דמי ניהול, הוצאות סרק ומשכורות מנופחות, אינן ישימות כשמדובר על גופים פיננסים

כמו מנפיקים.

אם תאומץ הצעתי הדבר "ייאלץ" את העמלה הצולבת להיות אופטימלית, וזאת על פי הסטנדרט המקובל .17

חד כאשר דיני ההגבלים העסקיים מתמודדים עם בדיני הגבלים עסקיים שהנו מקסום רווחת הצרכן. כך במיו

שווקים שבהם במצב המוצא, עודף היצרן כבר מנופח בשל הגבל עסקי כלשהו, כבענייננו. נימוק נוסף לסטנדרט

Page 440: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

440

ולפיו הערך השולי של כסף עבור הצרכן של כרטיסי חיוב )בתי Rochet & Tiroleשל רווחת הצרכן ניתן על ידי

ר מהערך השולי של הכסף עבור בעלי מניות של חברות כרטיסי חיוב. עסק והציבור( גבוה יות

תחת הסטנדרט של מקסום עודף הצרכן, עמלה צולבת אופטימלית היא זו שממקסמת עסקאות יעילות, תחת

(. התנאי מתקיים כאשר עמלה צולבת p=mcאילוץ שרמת המחירים של הטובין במשק תיקבע על פי עלויות )

ויות מנפיקים שלא מכוסות ממקור אחר )כגון דמי מחזיק או ריבית(. כאשר העמלה משמשת לכיסוי על

הצולבת משמשת לצורך עידוד שימוש בכרטיסי חיוב, שהינה המטרה הלגיטימית השניה בגינה הותרה גביית

עמלה צולבת ברחבי העולם מלכתחילה, אזי היא עשויה להפנים החצנת שימוש )ההחצנה שנגרמת כאשר

בקופה מעדיפה לשלם באמצעי תשלום יקר במקום באמצעי תשלום זול, כי האמצעי היקר הוא זול הלקוחה

עבורה(. ואולם, גם כאן, התנאי הוא שהעמלה הצולבת אכן תשמש לייעודה ותועבר למחזיקים כהטבות /

נקודות / הנחות וכיו"ב.

רים. הצידוק לאישורה הלכתחילי היה נזכור שעמלה צולבת היא הסדר כובל לתיאום מחירי מינימום בין מתח

לצורך עידוד שימוש יעיל בכרטיסים ותרומה לגידול יעיל של הרשת )הפנמת ההחצנות(. ואולם, הפקת רווח

אינה מטרה לגיטימית, בין תחת עמלה צולבת לכיסוי עלויות ובין תחת עמלה צולבת לעידוד שימוש וגידול יעיל

ות המורעפות על מחזיקים, לא יכול להיות תירוץ לרווח. לכן לא ייתכן של הרשת. כיסוי עלויות, לרבות הטב

שעמלה צולבת שמיועדת לכיסוי עלויות תשמש כמקור לרווח.

רשתות כרטיסי חיוב הן שוק בוגר שהגיע לדרגת חדירה מלאה. הצורך בעמלה צולבת להפנים את החצנת .18

צולבת תתרום להפנמה יעילה של אמצעי הרשת מוצה על פי רוב. באשר להחצנת השימוש, במקום שעמלה

תשלום על ידי הסטת לקוחות לשלם בכרטיסי חיוב זולים ויעילים, עמלה צולבת גבוהה יחד עם שיקולים

אסטרטגיים של בתי עסק שמונעים מהם לסרב לקבל כרטיסים, גורמים להחצנת שימוש הפוכה, בה בתי עסק

אמצעי תשלום זולים. ואולם, אפילו אם יש מקום לעמלה נאלצים לכבד כרטיסי חיוב יקרים עבורם, חלף

צולבת לצורך גידול נוסף של הרשת )הפנמה של החצנת רשת( או לצורך עידוד נוסף של שימוש בכרטיסים

)הפנמת החצנת שימוש(, ייעודה הלגיטימי של העמלה הצולבת, קרי כיסוי עלויות, עידוד שימוש יעיל בכרטיסי

, אינו כולל ואינו יכול לאפשר הפקת רווחים ממנה. חיוב או שניהם גם יחד

כיום, העמלה הצולבת היא כלי אשר במקום לשמש לכיסוי עלויות ולעודד שימוש יעיל בכרטיסים, "מאלץ" .19

את חברות כרטיסי החיוב לרווח. בכך חורגת העמלה הצולבת מהצידוקים לאישורה. התקבולים מהעמלה

בשנה. סכום זה מכסה לבדו, כמעט את כל עלויות ההנפקה ₪ מיליארד הצולבת לבדה מגיעים לכמעט שני

המתוקננות של מנפיקים בישראל. במצב שכזה, אין על מה להתחרות. כל, או כמעט כל, עלויות המנפיקים

( בזרם windfallמכוסים באמצעות העמלה הצולבת, כאשר בנוסף זוכים מנפיקים, בבחינת מתת חינם )

, כי מרבית 2006תי של דמי מחזיק וריבית על אשראי. באירופה נבחן ונמצא עוד בשנת הכנסות נוסף ומשמעו

המנפיקים כלל לא זקוקים לעמלה צולבת כדי לכסות את עלויותיהם ולהיות רווחיים. הנציבות האירופית

לבת ציינה כי הממצא מטיל ספק בנחיצות של עמלה צולבת. ואולם, כאמור, אף אם שיעור מסוים של עמלה צו

הוא חיוני ופרו תחרותי, אין שיעור זה מיועד לצרכי רווח אלא לכיסוי עלויות )כולל הטבות לעידוד שימוש יעיל

בכרטיסי חיוב(.

כמובן שאין להטיל על גופים עסקיים שום מגבלה על השגת רווחים בצורה חוקית. ואולם עמלה צולבת היא .20

ות קנויה להיות צד להסדר כובל שכזה. רווחים המושגים הסדר כובל לתיאום מחירי מינימום. אין לאדם זכ

Page 441: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

441

אשר מלכתחילה קיבל אישור רק בשל הצורך לכיסוי עלויות או לעודד שימוש -מהסדר כובל לתיאום מחירים

מוצדק, ראוי וצריך להגביל. -יעיל )אך כמובן שלא לצורך הפקת רווחים(

מנפיקים הם גם סולקים, אזי הגבלת הרווחיות תחול על חברות יחס הגומלין בין שני החידושים הינו שכל עוד .21

כרטיסי החיוב בשני הצדדים. אסור יהיה לחברת כרטיסי חיוב להרוויח מעל ומעבר לתשואה על השקעה חסרת

סיכון. אם חברת כרטיסי חיוב מפיקה רווחים בצד הסליקה, עליה להעבירם לצד ההנפקה לפני שהיא מבקשת

מלה צולבת שהינה הסדר כובל לתיאום מחירים. העמלה הצולבת לא נועדה להיות פיצוי היתר רגולטורי לע

( על עלויות שנגבות בפועל ממחזיקים או מבתי עסק, אלא רק לכסות עלויות double compensationכפול )

חיוב(. שלא כוסו בגבייה ישירה ממחזיקים או מבתי עסק )לרבות עלויות שנועדו לתמרץ שימוש יעיל בכרטיסי

על חברות כרטיסי החיוב לעשות שימוש בכל מקורות הכנסתן מכרטיסי חיוב, לפני שהן מבקשות ומקבלות

היתר רגולטורי לבצע קרטל בחסות הדין. הסדר כובל כמו העמלה הצולבת צריך לקבל אישור רק כשהוא חיוני,

ת המשמשת לצורך הפקת רווחים מידתי ובלעדיו לא ניתן להגשים את מטרתו החוקית של ההסדר. עמלה צולב

חורגת ממבחן זה, היא אינה מידתית ולו רק בשל עליית המחירים לה היא גורמת, ועל כן החלק הלא מידתי

שלה, קרי הרווח, אינו ראוי לאישור. זו היא בדיוק הצעתי.

וד במערכות אני מסביר מושגי יס 2העבודה כוללת את הפרקים הבאים. הפרק הראשון הינו פרק מבוא. בפרק .22

אני סוקר את 4מובאים נתונים על מערכות כרטיסי חיוב בישראל ובעולם. בפרק 3של כרטיסי חיוב. בפרק

סוקר בעין 5. פרק prepaidההיסטוריה של העמלה הצולבת בכרטיסי אשראי, כרטיסי חיוב מיידי וכרטיסי

ר את העלויות והתועלות של אמצעי מסבי 6ביקורתית את הרגולציה של העמלה הצולבת ברחבי העולם. פרק

סוקר את המודלים הכלכליים הקשורים לעמלה הצולבת וכולל תשעה פרקי משנה החל 7התשלום. פרק

, מודלים של ניטרליות Rochet & Tirole, השיקולים האסטרטגיים של Baxterמהמודל הראשון של

(neutrality of the interchange feeוגביית תוספת, מודלים ) של תחרות בין רשתות, מודלים שדנים ביחס

בין דמי מחזיק להטבות, מודלים שדנו בעמלה הצולבת של כרטיסי אשראי לעומת זו של כרטיסי חיוב מיידי

(debit v credit .ומודלים שהתחקו אחר העמלה הצולבת האופטימלית ,)

יר את המאפיינים הייחודיים של מסב 9הוא ניתוח משפטי של העמלה הצולבת כהסדר כובל. פרק 8פרק

כרטיסי חיוב כמוצר רשת דו צדדי, בעטיים מאושרת העמלה הצולבת בכל העולם חרף היותה הסדר כובל

מסביר את החששות התחרותיים 10)החצנת הרשת והחצנת השימוש, והפנמתן על ידי העמלה הצולבת(. פרק

וטים שלא לגבות תוספת ממי אשר משלם באמצעי מסביר מדוע בתי עסק נ 11שמעוררת העמלה הצולבת. פרק

מציג את החידוש 13מציג אלטרנטיבות לעמלה הצולבת ולחששות שהיא מעוררת. פרק 12תשלום יקרים. פרק

מסכם. 15מציג את החידוש של הגבלת הרווחיות. פרק 14של ההפרדה המבנית. פרק

-סוף תקציר -

Page 442: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

442

The Faculty of Law

The Zvi Meitar Center for Advanced Legal Studies

Separating Issuers from Acquirers

And Profit Limitations

In Payment Card Networks with Interchange Fees

By: Ori BarAm

Supervisor: Professor David Gilo

Thesis for the title "Doctor of Philosophy"

Submitted to the Senate of Tel Aviv University on 3 August, 2017

Page 443: Separating Issuers from Acquirers And Profit Limitations ...primage.tau.ac.il/libraries/theses/law/free/9932934258404146.pdf · complaints about their high fees, particularly from

443

פקולטה למשפטיםה

מרכז צבי מיתר ללימודי משפט מתקדם

פיצול סליקה והנפקה ומגבלות על רווחים

ברשתות כרטיסי חיוב עם עמלה צולבת

מאת: אורי ברעם דיויד גילה מנחה: פרופ' "דוקטור לפילוסופיה"חיבור לשם קבלת התואר

2017 באוגוסט 3יום אביב ב-הוגש לסנאט של אוניברסיטת תל