sandulli article

25
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1325682 1 The Two Faces of Open Business Models Francesco Sandulli and Henry Chesbrough Introduction All companies have a business model. Some companies are not really aware of the existence of their business model, so they usually do not define it in a formal way. Other companies do grasp the characteristics of their business model which is often deployed in a formal and structured way. These companies tend to be in a better position to adapt their business model over time and thus continue to create value even when the competitive landscape changes. Business models that are open, in ways we will describe below, generally create more value, and enable greater adaptation over time. Yet these open business models are not well understood, nor is it clear how to implement such models. In this article, we seek to outline two different and equally important facets of open business models: a “buy side” perspective that incorporates external resources into one’s own business model, and a “sell side” view that places one’s own resources into others’ business models. Although there have been many different definitions of business model, usually there is some consensus on its two main functions: to define mechanisms for creating value and mechanisms to capture a certain proportion of that value (Chesbrough, 2006). The history of strategic management reveals how the limits within which business models were embedded have been expanded over time. A few years ago, when companies defined their business model they focused on value creation through the use of internal resources of the company. Over time firms initiated a process of opening up the boundaries of their business model as they began to analyze the contribution of suppliers, customers and other members of the firm’s ecosystem to the value created by internal resources of the company. However, at the present time, companies are beginning to ask why limit the use of their resources only to their business model. Why not include external resources as key components of the business model of the company?

Upload: alvinchua08

Post on 07-Mar-2015

20 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Sandulli Article

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1325682

1

The Two Faces of Open Business Models

Francesco Sandulli and Henry Chesbrough

Introduction

All companies have a business model. Some companies are not really aware of the

existence of their business model, so they usually do not define it in a formal way.

Other companies do grasp the characteristics of their business model which is often

deployed in a formal and structured way. These companies tend to be in a better

position to adapt their business model over time and thus continue to create value even

when the competitive landscape changes. Business models that are open, in ways we

will describe below, generally create more value, and enable greater adaptation over

time. Yet these open business models are not well understood, nor is it clear how to

implement such models. In this article, we seek to outline two different and equally

important facets of open business models: a “buy side” perspective that incorporates

external resources into one’s own business model, and a “sell side” view that places

one’s own resources into others’ business models.

Although there have been many different definitions of business model, usually there is

some consensus on its two main functions: to define mechanisms for creating value and

mechanisms to capture a certain proportion of that value (Chesbrough, 2006).

The history of strategic management reveals how the limits within which business

models were embedded have been expanded over time. A few years ago, when

companies defined their business model they focused on value creation through the use

of internal resources of the company. Over time firms initiated a process of opening up

the boundaries of their business model as they began to analyze the contribution of

suppliers, customers and other members of the firm’s ecosystem to the value created by

internal resources of the company. However, at the present time, companies are

beginning to ask why limit the use of their resources only to their business model. Why

not include external resources as key components of the business model of the

company?

Page 2: Sandulli Article

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1325682

2

Following this new approach, companies are beginning to share their internal resources

with a third party to create value, or the reverse, companies are beginning to incorporate

external resources in their own business model. These new business models have been

defined by Chesbrough (2006) as open business models.

The reason that companies are beginning to adopt open business models is to foster the

creation of value. As we will describe later, for the company that shares its resources the

open business model will improve the utilization rate of its resources and therefore the

return on the required investment to develop them. Moreover, companies that

incorporate other’s resources to its business obtain advantages in terms of speed of

development of new products, easier access to markets, to knowledge and ultimately to

resources that otherwise would have been more costly or difficult to develop.

Here is the outline of the remainder of this article. First we explore the role of key

resources, and how they can be aggregated into open business models. Next, we

examine how the nature of key resources influences the development of these models.

We pay particular attention to whether the resources are rivalrous or non-rivalrous, and

whether they are excludable or not. We then turn to the two faces of open business

models, considering the buy side and the sell side of how resources are accessed and

leveraged respectively in such models. We then examine one organization in more

detail, the El Bulli restaurant, to provide an indepth illustration of both sides of that

firm’s business model, and show its adaptability. We conclude with summary remarks.

The Open Business Model

Companies create value using resources to perform a number of activities that produce

utility to its customers. Not all business resources are equally important: a company

may capture a share of this value to the extent that her resources are rare, difficult to

imitate and have no close substitutes (Wernerfelt, 1984; Rumelt, 1984; Barney 1986;

Barney 1991 among others). The sustainable competitive advantage of a company relies

on its ability to identify, build, exploit, maintain and transform valuable resources

(Teece, 2007). The firm’s business model articulates what is the value proposition of

valuable resources for a target market, how to define the value chain and the network of

relationships within the ecosystem of the company to allow the construction of these

Page 3: Sandulli Article

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1325682

3

valuable resources, what are the revenue mechanisms that enables the capture of the

value generated by those valuable resources, and ultimately what is the competitive

strategy that allows sustain over time the value of the resources of the company

(Chesbrough and Rosenbloom, 2002).

Following the traditional conception of a closed business model, most companies have

tried to internally develop their resources and to exploit them within the boundaries of

their own business model. In recent years in many industries, this approach is beginning

to show some limits. On one hand, companies are increasingly aware that they do not

have and cannot develop internally all the resources needed to succeed in increasingly

complex environments. On the other hand, firms have also realized that the difficulties

in fully capturing the value of their resources which remain underexploited. The

management of innovation and knowledge assets has been one of the first areas where

the firms realized the limits of closed business models. On one side, the increasingly

rapid pace of scientific discoveries has increased the complexity of innovating with the

firm’s own internal R&D resources, while at the same time, a paradoxically high share

of the innovation done by the firms was not commercially exploited (Chesbrough,

2003).

Resource Rivalry and Excludability

Value capture is easier when the company shares resources that are excludable (Romer,

1986). However, sometimes the company shares resources such as open source software

that are not excludable. In these cases, the company must seek alternative mechanisms

to capture some of the value generated by the shared resource. For instance, West

(2007) suggests a few of these alternative mechanisms in the case of open source

software such as the dual license approach (a free license and a fee based license) or

selling complements. Chesbrough and Appleyard (2007) describe the creation of open

source business models, where value is also appropriated through lowering the cost of

inputs or complements.

Following the previous approach, we can deduce that opening the business model is

easier when the resources shared by the firm are not rivalrous, as the capacity of the

Page 4: Sandulli Article

4

resource is not a restriction, and excludable, as the firm is able to capture some of the

value created by the third (Table 1). For this reason, it will be more likely to observe

open business models based on assets such as brand, tacit knowledge and intellectual

property. In relation to rival resources, the greater its excess capacity and its scalability

greater the likelihood that they can support open business models. An example of a rival

resource that supports an open business model is the technological infrastructure of

Unience, a social network for investors where financial firms can build and offer

financial assets management tools to those investors. As it is based upon the Amazon

Cloud Computing concept, Unience's infrastructure is easily scalable, so that capacity

restrictions are lower.

However other resources less scalable as the logistics infrastructure or the human

resources may face more limitations when used in open business models. As discussed

above, supporting an open business model on non-rival resources presents the difficulty

of capturing value, and therefore it would be only feasible if the company is able to

detect valid mechanisms to capture value. However, this task is not easy as shown by

the so far unsuccessful attempt by the recording industry to identify alternative

mechanisms to capture value on P2P networks (Sandulli, 2007). Finally, rival and non-

excludable resources are characterized by limited capacity and the difficult to capture

value, so they are hardly applicable to an open business model.

Table 1. Feasibility of opening the business model in light of the nature of the assets.

Resource Rivalry RIVAL NON RIVAL

Resource

Excludability

Feasibility of an

Open Business

Model

Low High

EXCLUDABLE High Logistics

Infrastructure

Distribution Channels

Human Resources

IT Infrastructure

Manufacturing

Capabilities

Information

Market Knowledge

Intellectual Property

Brand

Page 5: Sandulli Article

5

NON

EXCLUDABLE

Low Open Wireless

Networks

Public Goods, e.g.,

public infrastructure

Open Source

Software

Unprotected

Knowledge

Secondly, the shared resource should not be competitive. This implies that sharing the

resource with another party does not reduce the value created by that resource in the

company’s own business model. The exception to this principle is when sharing an asset

reduces the value it generates in the business model of the company, but at the same

time the company is able to offset this loss through the capture of a proportion of the

value that the third party is creating. In the case of the shared network in the Telecom

Industry we describe below, when a carrier opens its APIs, some of the third party

applications may come into direct competition with the carrier’s own applications. In

this case, the shared resource is competitive as it is eroding the carrier normal revenue

sources. However at the same time, sharing the network may result in increased

revenues from the network traffic and the royalties the telecom operator gets from

sharing its resource with the application provider. As long as these new revenues offset

the loss in terms of traditional revenue sources, the carriers will be interested in opening

up the business model.

Having described the role of resources in constructing an Open Business Model, we will

move on to describe some challenges related to the implementation of an Open Business

Model, both from the standpoint of the company that decides to share its resources with

others, and from the point of the company that decides to use third-party resources in

her business model.

Use of External Resources in the Firm’s Business Model: The Buying Side of the

Open Business Model.

Opening the business model in the stages of identification and validation of the

opportunity is closely related to the practices of Open Innovation. People and

organizations outside the company are the source of new ideas and new business

opportunities for the firms. An increasing number of organizations are using external

Page 6: Sandulli Article

6

sources of knowledge for their R & D projects. For example, in 2006 IBM opened its

Innovation Jams, a forum created in 2001 in which employees contribute ideas on

which to base future research and development programs of the company, to individuals

outside the organization. The new open Innovation Jam involved 13,366 people,

generated 8,674 ideas, of which 31 became Great Ideas finalists, and finally 10 received

seed funding and were included into the IBM portfolio of research programs (Helander

et al., 2007). IBM now offers clients the opportunity to host their own Innovation Jams

through its IBM Global Services unit. And IBM is far from alone in this. Airbus,

Google, Microsoft, or the Spanish companies the Vocento Group or the building

company Visesa, have launched Ideas Challenges for identifying new areas of

innovation.

Moreover, Innocentive, Innovationxchange, Ninesigma, Big Idea Group or

Conectainnova in Spain are a bunch of new ventures whose business model is based on

intermediating between organizations that need ideas and people and organizations that

may be a potential source of ideas.

Crowdsourcing has not been used in the Innovation field until recently. Spanish Savings

Banks must give away through the trust the net profit which is not allocated to reserves.

Caja Navarra has recently started a pioneering project in Civic Banking where the

customers decide in which social projects the savings bank must invest. Startup

companies like Threadless.com utilize the crowd to submit designs for T shirts, and then

produce the ones receiving the highest approval from that crowd.

Not all organizations that are adopting Open Innovation to identify new ideas do

Crowdsourcing. Some prefer to have more control over the dynamics of ideas sourcing

and the relationship with the innovation partners. Philips has opened its Innovation

Campuses in Eindhoven and Shanghai. Where once stood a restricted series of facilities

accessible only to Philips staff, now stands an open industrial park, where the company

shares ideas with a selected and limited group of companies. Another example is the

small user focus groups employed by Shimano in the development of the new bike

Coasting Component Group.

There is a movement toward the creation of science parks within Spain, intended to

increase the utilization of university technologies in Spain. Kock and Torkkeli (2008)

Page 7: Sandulli Article

7

have found some initial empirical evidence (based on an unrepresentative sample) that

Spanish firms are more prone to lead to an efficient and effective transfer of knowledge.

Another way to open the business model is working with others to validate and test the

new ideas or products of the firm. Those companies that adopt this practice can expand

the scope and scale of their experiments and also reduce the resources required and the

product development time. This has been a powerful advantage of open source software

for many years.

This concept is now moving rapidly outside of software development to other areas of

business. New mobile application test is one of the product development tasks which

absorbs more time and resources in the mobile telecommunication industry (Nesse,

2008). Telefonica, O2, BT, Telenor and Verizon among other carriers have established

communities of users to validate the future applications and expect to get significant

reductions in the validation times. Philips has partnered with NH Hoteles to conduct

experiments on new lighting systems in Hoteles. Facebook users are being asked to

determine the packaging design for Lancashire Tea.

In the Telecom Industry several carriers decided to open their Application Program

Interfaces (APIs). Open MovilForum at Telefonica Moviles, 21C project at British

Telecom, Telenor Content Provider Access, Telecom Italia nextTime, SingTel Partners

Program, ODI Verizon, Sprint Business Mobility Framework or AT & T devCentral are

some of these open API projects. The goal of these carriers is to provide for the easy,

rapid and cost-effective development of mobile applications. A potentially large base

of application developers have now access to the carrier network, which is a valuable

resource as most of them could not develop by themselves such a distribution channel

for their services. On the other side, telecom companies expect both to share with the

application providers the revenues generated by these new services and to increase the

network traffic, since a network with more services provides more value to the

operator’s customers.

Open business models can even lead to cooperation with competitors. This cooperation

can be justified by the need to obtain synergies between resources (Das and Teng,

2000). A recent example of this phenomenon is the cooperation between Trek, Giant

Page 8: Sandulli Article

8

and Raleigh, competitors in the U.S. bicycle market, to design new bikes with the new

Shimano Automatic Coasting system. The bike manufacturers had to share ideas and

experiences due to the high technical complexity of the new system. The cooperation

between competitors is also explained by the need to share costs. For example, it is

common that in the initial stages of market entry small businesses develop collective

brands to reduce the costs of communication and marketing (Falcone, 2007). For

instance, using the social network Hi5, 29 small textile companies in Costa Rica have

created the fashion brand Abril to commercialize all their products.

Absorptive Capacity and Organizational Inertia

Companies that decide to use third-party resources into its own business model faces a

number of challenges associated with both their absorptive capacity and their

organizational inertia.

The absorptive capacity is a concept developed in the literature that analyzes the

exchange of knowledge among firms (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). Absorptive capacity

is related to three capabilities: resource search, integration and exploitation. Applying

this concept to our open business model framework, we can say that the success of a

company that decides to use third-party resources depends on her ability to identify

resources that may create value, her ability to integrate external and internal resources,

and her ability to exploit the external resource.

The search for new resources is an activity with diminishing returns: beyond one point,

broader and deeper resources search does not improve the results in terms of better

resources found (Ahuja and Katila, 2004). This means that the search for resources can

not be indiscriminate and that companies should set limits on the breadth and depth of

their search (Laursen and Salter, 2006). In fact, excessive attention to the search for

external resources can undermine the development of internal resources. For instance

Lou and Round (2006) show that in the pharmaceutical industry the search for in-

license compounds may adversely affect the development of self-originated compounds.

This external resources search process should not only consider the resource potential

value, but must also take into account other aspects such as partner commitment and

trust, the complementarity as it will impact the company's ability to integrate the

resource within her operations, the complexity of managing the partnership, the

Page 9: Sandulli Article

9

outcomes uncertainty and the ability to measure the exact outcomes of the partnership

(Shah and Swaminathan, 2008). So, companies will be more likely to integrate into their

business models external resources that are owned by trustful and committed partners,

that complement internal resources and fit the firm’s strategy, and whose value

contribution is not uncertain and can be measured.

The need for low uncertainty, complementarity and partner trust and commitment may

explain why the approach to open innovation of Spanish firms relies more on repeated

interactions with the same partners, instead of pursuing an unbounded partner search

(Kock and Torkkeli, 2008)1. This argument may also explain why in the initial stages

of development of an open business model, most telecom carriers or Google in its

Android project, have opened the APIs only to a selected and small group of application

providers.

The second important component of the absorptive capacity is the firm’s ability to

integrate external resources. Within the open business model framework, resource

exchanges are quasi-market mechanisms. These mechanisms will be more inefficient

than hierarchies the higher the complexity in the management of the resources exchange

(Roper et al., 2007). For this reason, the more complex the resource integration, the less

appropriate will be an open business model for the firm. So far current research has

given just a few clear clues about the capabilities a firm needs to integrate internal and

external resources. Acha (2007) noted the importance of the ability to design the points

of interaction between firms and the task partitioning between the firms. Zahra and

George (2002) suggested the importance of the ability to develop information systems

that support the resources exchange. The ability to integrate external and internal

resources is usually built up over time through a trial and error process (Cohen and

Levinthal, 1990). Therefore we should expect that the resource integration will be easier

in firms with more experience in the management and development of similar assets

(Cohen and Levinthal, 1989).

1 We have found some evidence apparently contradicting the Kock and Torkkeli (2008) conclusions. In fact, firms facing problems with great uncertainty tend to search widely across a variety of search channels. Companies with crowd sourcing initiatives, such as the IBM Innovation Jams, are examples of this wide search. However, all these firms that use crowd sourcing to fish new ideas, beyond the search phase tend to concentrate their efforts in very few ideas, confirming our argument that in high uncertainty environments openness has high costs.

Page 10: Sandulli Article

10

Time also is crucial in developing a large base of complementary assets, which will be

needed to successfully exploit external resources. Kock et al., (2007) suggest that large

firms will be more likely to use external resources in their business models because the

larger the asset base of the firm, the stronger the potential synergies for the integration

of external resources.

Finally, the company that incorporates external resources must be able to overcome its

own organizational inertia. The integration of external resources often requires

significant organizational changes. However, the high level of standardization of

organizational routines can make the company reluctant to implement those changes

and thus to integrate resources (Henderson and Clark, 1990). In the area of Open

Innovation, organizational inertia produces syndrome "not invented here", by which an

organization rejects external sources of knowledge simply because they were not

developed internally (Katz and Allen, 1982).

The firm Trek is a recent example of this syndrome. This bicycle manufacturer used to

support only internal knowledge of the market in defining the requirements for its future

products. However, shifting to the Open Innovation approach, part of the requirements

of the new model Trek Lime were obtained directly from outside the company,

precisely from occasional bicycle users through a series of focus groups. At the time of

translating those user based requirements into the design, the firm needed some effort to

convince the product development engineers of the benefits of the new design, as the

engineers were very reluctant to abandon their traditional design criteria very focused

on optimizing the aerodynamics and weight of the bicycles, to adopt the consumer

proposed approach more focused on functionality and aesthetics of the bike. Some of

the practices that may be considered to overcome organizational inertia by those

companies with open business models are cyclic reorganizations (Tushman and

Romanelli, 1985) or top-management turnover (Tripsas and Gavetti, 2000).

The figure below summarizes our discussion of the buy side face of an open business

model. Factors on the left of the figure cause models to be less open, such as when

absorptive capacity is poor. Right hand side factors, by contrast, support more open

business models, such as when absorptive capacity is high.

Page 11: Sandulli Article

11

Figure 1. Determinants of Open Business Models in the Buying Side.

+ Absortive Capacity

+ Internal Complementary Resources

-Organizational Inertia

- Outcome Uncertainty

- Absortive Capacity

- Internal Complementary Resources

+ Organizational Inertia

+ Outcome Uncertainty

OPENNESS BUYING SIDE

- +

Using the Firm’s Resources in the Business Model of Other Companies: The

Selling Side of an Open Business Model.

There are a number of companies that have decided to exploit their resources and

capabilities beyond its own business model. These companies create and capture value

from sharing their resources and capabilities. Companies such as Bankinter bank or the

Barrabés mountain gear online store have a deep understanding of the technology used

in their business model. Opening the business model and sharing this asset with other

banks in the case of Bankinter or other online shops in the case of Barrabés has created

a new revenue source. Companies such as Philips are obtaining a significant flow of

revenues from sharing their knowledge under patenting agreements. Besides technology

knowledge, some telecom operators such as Telefonica, Telenor and BT are beginning

to share market data with other companies.

Due to the non rival nature of most intangible assets such as knowledge or brand (see

for example Von Hippel and Von Krogh, 2003) it is easier to share them, yet some

companies have also started to share the excess capacity of some of their tangible assets

such as technological infrastructure, logistics assets or distribution channels as well.

Page 12: Sandulli Article

12

Amazon shares with other firms its computing capacity through its Elastic Compute

Cloud, Barrabés shares its logistics assets through the Rezepcion@ project, Ponoko

shares its manufacturing platform, Cal Celdoni share its vineyard and its manufacturing

capabilities, and telecom carriers such as Telefonica share the network.

Rational behavior suggests that a firm is willing to share a resource with a third party

when exploiting a resource in third party business models generates more value than

constraining the resource to the firm’s own business model. This is fairly clear in the

case of sharing the excess capacity of tangible assets. Sharing IT or logistics

infrastructure with other firms increases their rate of utilization and the return on the

investment on that infrastructure. A firm that shares a resource can also generate value

through the creation or further exploitation of complementary and cospecialized

resources (Teece, 1986). For instance, IBM shared with the open source community all

of its Eclipse code, valued at $40 million (Stolinsky, 2004). Sharing this resource, IBM

aimed at increasing the value created by the Rational product line, a suit of development

tools that complemented the free Eclipse platform. Open telecom platforms are another

example of a shared asset that increases the value of complementary resources. As

discussed above, mobile telecommunications operators have decided to share its

network with application developers. This decision may significantly boost the amount

of services offered by the network, thus increasing the value of this resource. In turn, the

higher value of the network can make potential distributors more interested in

distributing the carrier services, thus increasing the distribution channel reach. This

example shows that opening the business model can increase both the network value

and the value of complementary resources such as the distribution channel. Indeed,

opening the business model seems an interesting move for those carriers entering new

markets or segments, or for those operators without a strong distribution channel.

Companies must decide the extent to which share its resources with others. In this

regard companies must take into account the breadth and depth of the open business

model. Broadening the approach of Laursen and Salter (2006) we will consider that

breadth refers to the number of actors with whom you share a resource, while the depth

refers to the degrees of intensity and specificity of the relationship with those actors.

Normally, an open business model requires a tradeoff between breadth, depth and

control over the shared resources. In the extreme, an open business model would be

Page 13: Sandulli Article

13

both broad and deep. Namely, the firm would share her resources with a large amount

of partners and will actively manage all these partnerships so that she can capture the

maximum amount of value from theme. However, keeping deep relationships involves

high coordination costs. For this reason, it is more likely that the firms will deploy

either a broad but not deep business model such as the application development

communities in the telecom industry, where a large amount of partners share the

resource with the firm, who tends to establish standard relationships with them and is

not very involved in the partner’s daily management of the resource, or a narrow and

deep business model as is the case with the cobranding strategy of El Bulli we will

discuss in a later section, where the firm shares a resource with few partners, establishes

specific relationships with each of them, and is actively involved in the management of

the resource in the third party business model.

In defining an open business model, companies must first consider the opportunity cost

of sharing the asset. This opportunity cost is a function of the value of the asset and the

uncertainty in the outcome of the exchange. Higher the value of the asset, higher the

opportunity cost and less broad the open business model. This explains why large firms

prefer to exchange secondary or non core assets (Kock et al., 2007) or why when the

initial value of the platform is high, the sponsors of technology platforms prefer to take

profits directly instead of relying in external innovation (Parker and Van Alstyne,

2008).

In the case of cospecialized, highly specific and therefore very valuable assets such as

brands, companies prefer to establish dyadic relationships, as the risk in the event of

loss of control is very high. In the fashion industry brand is one of the most valuable

resources. When in the 70s the industry suffered a major crisis, some companies like

Gucci or Calvin Klein decided to license their brands to a large number of companies.

In the short term, the strategy worked generating substantial license fees. However, over

time the resource, the brand equity, was eroding, as many of the licensed products were

of poor quality. The lack of control over the brand pushed Gucci near bankruptcy, and

Calvin Klein was unable to find an investor interested in buying the company in 1999.

Today both companies, as well as others such as Dior, Givenchy and Yves St. Laurent

(Hill et al., 2001), are struggling to wriggle free of their licensing deals and to regain

control of the brand.

Page 14: Sandulli Article

14

The openness degrees of the business model also depend on the expected capability of

the partners to create follow-on products using the shared resource. If the company

believes that her partners are very capable of creating these follow-on products, the

model will tend to be more open. In these cases, the companies share their resources

with the aim of developing a large number of products and services. This was usually

the case of platforms sponsors such as Reuters, Unience, AirSage, operators of

telecommunications or Microsoft who decided to open their APIs. For example,

Microsoft has granted access to the source code to boost up the development of the

greatest number of open source applications that run on Windows rather than on Linux.

In an optimal situation a company should have a high number of partners with

capabilities to create significant value. However, in many cases the company does not

know ex ante the capabilities of potential partners and does not know which of them

will be able to use the resource in a more valuable way. That is why some companies

prefer to define business models with a high number of partnerships. Indeed, the breadth

of the business model reduces the uncertainty associated with the future follow-on

products of the resource (Parker and Van Alstyne, 2008). Many companies with a broad

open business model such as Reuters, Amazon, Telefonica, Microsoft or

Salesforces.com in sharing some of their resources pursue Long Tail business models,

trying to create a market with a large number of complementary products that

individually generate a small amount of revenues. In order to increase the number of

developers of complementary products, companies that own the resources may even

decide to sacrifice some part of the value amount they intended to capture from the

shared resource. For example, Indian mobile carriers prefer to sacrifice some of their

revenue share to promote the development of a strong Value Added Services market,

the lowest for those applications developed on new platforms for innovation, or Intel

established subsidies to the community of producers of complementary products for its

chips.

Parker and Van Alstyne (2008) argue that the sponsor of a technology platform prefers

to give developers pricing power, especially in the early stages of a technology where

there is increased uncertainty about the outcome of the resource exchange. In these early

Page 15: Sandulli Article

15

stages of a technology uncertainty will also related to deeper and more narrow open

business models. As discussed above, in the early stages of their open business model

both Google with Android or the telecom carriers preferred to open their APIs to a few

selected application developers. Laursen and Salter (2006) confirm that in environments

of radical innovation is more common for companies to establish close relations with a

very small number of partners. In this sense, it seems that greater uncertainty can justify

the management of resource portfolios using more hierarchical structures and business

models less broad but deeper, as opposed to managing those resources using modular

approaches which are closer to market mechanisms (Chesbrough and Kusunoki, 1999).

Firms with Long Tail open business models share either resources that are not rival,

such as knowledge or brands, either highly scalable resources, such IT infrastructure.

We must take a closer look to the coordination costs. Strategic alliance theory suggests

that the higher the mutual interdependence among partners, the greater the coordination

costs (Gulati and Singh, 1988). Establishing highly interdependent relationships will

difficult establishing open business models based on the Long Tail approach. Thompson

(1967) argues that coordination costs are lower when the relationship is coordinated by

standardization. Therefore, to mitigate the coordination costs associated with

maintaining a high number of partners and with Long Tail open business models,

companies must rely on standards that articulate the relationship with those partners.

For instance, when the firm is sharing codified knowledge it is easier to establish Long

Tail business models. For instance, several Long Tail open business models are based

on open APIs platforms that are developed on standard programming languages. On the

other hand, sharing knowledge which is not based on standards or resources such as

brands whose management implies specific partner interaction requires a greater effort

of coordination. In the fashion industry, Gucci or Calvin Klein tried to follow twenty

years ago a Long Tail open business model consisting of sharing a resource such as the

brand with a large number of partners. For example, Gucci had 13,000 licensed

products. This large amount of partnerships made it very difficult or almost impossible

to those two firms to effectively manage all these relationships. For months at a time,

Calvin Klein did not attend design meetings with Warnaco, the licensee company for

jeanswear brands who eventually diluted the CK trademark by selling it into discount

channels.

Page 16: Sandulli Article

16

The risk and the protection against opportunistic behavior should also be taken into

account when defining the breadth of the open business model. The lower the level of

trust in the potential partners and the higher the anticipated complexities in defining and

enforcing property rights, the more hierarchical the relationship with the partners that

will exploit the firm’s resources (Gulati and Singh, 1998).

These factors are summarized in the Figure below, in which factors that lead to more

controlled and narrow use of resources are on the left of the Figure (such as high mutual

interdependence), while those that support greater sharing of resources with more

parties are shown on the right (such as low mutual interdependence).

Figure 2. Determinants of Open Business Models in the Selling Side.

+ Mutual Interdependence

- Partner Trust

- Legal Protection

+ Internal Complementary Resources

-External Complementary Resources

- Scalability

OPENNESS SELLING SIDE

- Mutual Interdependence

+ Partner Trust

+ Legal Protection

- Internal Complementary Resources

+ External Complementary Resources

+ Scalability

- +

+ Mutual Interdependence

- Partner Trust

- Legal Protection

+ Internal Complementary Resources

-External Complementary Resources

- Scalability

OPENNESS SELLING SIDE

- Mutual Interdependence

+ Partner Trust

+ Legal Protection

- Internal Complementary Resources

+ External Complementary Resources

+ Scalability

- +

According to the degrees of openness of the selling or the buying side of a business

model we have found three different types of open business models:

� Partially Open Business Models (Buying-Side): In this category usually fall

firms that lack the capabilities to develop a specific resource by themselves, so

they embed third party resources in their business models. Within this category

we can find firms such as NH Hoteles, Lavazza, Kraft or Procter and Gamble

that are “customers” of companies with open business models in the Selling

Side, firms that cooperate to create a collective and shared resource, such as

Page 17: Sandulli Article

17

Trek, Giant or Raleigh creating common knowledge on the new Shimano’s

Automated Coasting System or the consortium of 29 Costa Rican firms creating

the Abril brand.

� Partially Open Business Models (Selling-Side): These are business models of

firms that share some of their resources with another firm which embeds them

into their business model. Firms following this business model try to maximize

the rate of utilization of the shared resource to maximize utilization rate, such as

the Brand licensees, reduce excess capacity, such as Amazon, obtain economies

of scope for that resource such as Barrabés or Bankinter, or to maximize the

production of complementary products which is normally the case of owners of

platforms such as Unience, Apple, Facebook, SAP, Telecom Carriers, Google,

Microsoft or Reuters.

� Fully Open Business Models: Those are firms that rely on both sides of an open

business model. We find firms such as El Bulli, IBM, Amazon, Merck or Philips

that relied on external resources to reinforce their business model and to

experiment with new business models, while also creating new revenue flows

from sharing the use of their resources to other firms. We also included within

this category a new group of firms such as Innocentive or Conectainnova that

are specializing in intermediating between firms with open business models in

the buying side and firms with open business models in the selling side. Except

for these intermediaries that already born open, there is a natural evolution from

Closed Business Model to Partially Open Busines Models, and then to Fully

Open Business Models. Merck or NH Hoteles are examples of firms that are

evolving from Partially Open Business Models in the Buying Side to Fully Open

Business Models incorporating the selling side of openness. More frequent are

the cases of firms that are evolving from Partially Open Business Models Selling

Side to Fully Open Business Models, especially when firms such as SAP,

Telefónica, Google or Apple are platform sponsors and really expect a large

crop of complementary partners from opening their business model.

Page 18: Sandulli Article

18

Figure 3. A Taxonomy of Open Business Models.

Opennes

Selling-Side

Open

ne

s

Bu

yin

g-S

ide

Open Business Model

Philips, IBM, Amazon, Merck, El Bulli, Conectainnova, Innocentive

Partially Open Business Model(Selling Side)

Telecom Carriers (Telefónica, BT, Telenor,…), Google, Microsoft, Reuters, Shimano, Unience, SAP,

Facebook, Gucci,Apple, Calvin Klein, Barrabés, Bankinter.

Partially Open Business

Model (Buying Side)

NH Hoteles, Lavazza, Kraft, Procter and Gamble, Trek,Abril

ClosedBusiness Model

Opennes

Selling-Side

Open

ne

s

Bu

yin

g-S

ide

Open Business Model

Philips, IBM, Amazon, Merck, El Bulli, Conectainnova, Innocentive

Partially Open Business Model(Selling Side)

Telecom Carriers (Telefónica, BT, Telenor,…), Google, Microsoft, Reuters, Shimano, Unience, SAP,

Facebook, Gucci,Apple, Calvin Klein, Barrabés, Bankinter.

Partially Open Business

Model (Buying Side)

NH Hoteles, Lavazza, Kraft, Procter and Gamble, Trek,Abril

ClosedBusiness Model

El Bulli – An Illustration of an Open Business Model

We have described a number of factors that affect the two faces of an open business

model. In this section, we bring these points together through an examination of a

unique organization, the world renown restaurant El Bulli. Based in Spain, El Bulli is

widely considered one of the world’s best and most influential restaurants. Restaurant

Magazine voted the restaurant #1 in the world four times, and the restaurant received its

third Michelin star in 1997, and has held it ever since. Don’t rush to book a reservation

however. The restaurant receives roughly 1 million requests for its 8,000 seatings each

year (it closes for half the year each year for further research and development), and

reservations are typically taken one day in October a year in advance.

Page 19: Sandulli Article

19

The restaurant and its chef, Ferran Adria, are best known for its investigations into

“molecular gastronomy”. By examining the micro-properties of specific foods, spices

and ingredients, the restaurant develops unique recipes that provide radically new dining

experiences. But this knowledge did not originate inside El Bulli. Illustrating the first

face of an open business model, Adria was among the eager collaborators of a series of

discoveries in molecular gastronomy by Hervé This, a French physical chemist.

Furthermore, El Bulli was a participant in the European Union funded project called

INICON, which intended to promote collaboration between scientists, chefs and

restaurants. While El Bulli has made tremendous contributions to this movement, the

core ideas initially emerged outside the organization, and were absorbed inside.

Recently, the School of Engineering and Applied Sciences at Harvard agreed to bring

scientific expertise and techniques in the formulation of foods, textures and structures to

el Bulli.

While its gastronomy is widely celebrated, El Bulli’s business model is largely

unstudied. As noted above, the restaurant closes for six months every year, and

reportedly loses money. However, the restaurant’s role in El Bulli’s model is one of an

R&D laboratory, which is not expected to earn a profit by itself. Instead, the restaurant

generates the knowledge needed for the profitable elements of El Bulli’s business

model. Most of these elements illustrate the second face of an open business model, by

allowing others to share El Bulli’s resources, including its brand and its knowledge.

In 1999 the restaurant decided to share its knowledge with the food manufacturer

Borges to design oils, sauces and snacks. Essentially this meant that Borges launches a

series of co-branded items with El Bulli in the consumer marketplace. This added a

new revenue stream for El Bulli. Other similar co-branding deals included

collaborations with Kaiku (an award winning book of recipes), Lavazza (coffee), NH

Hoteles (hospitality), Nestle (chocolate), Armand Bassi (tableware and kitchenware)

and Diageo Group (whisky cocktails). In another area, a recent collaboration was

launched between NH Hoteles and Iberia in 2007 to include Fast Good sandwiches in

the menu onboard Iberia. This benefited El Bulli by positioning its brand into a new

segment.

Page 20: Sandulli Article

20

This last relationship between NH Hoteles and El Bulli deserves further comment. In

order to reinforce the brand experience of their customers and to positioning in the

market as an innovative organization, NH Hoteles decided to create the concept of “Fast

Good”, a fast food restaurant delivering food of better quality, and Nhube, an initiative

that seeks to combine in a single space the lounge, the restaurant and the café-bar of the

hotels. To complete these projects NH Hoteles decided to rely on the capabilities and

resources of the restaurant Bulli and Ferran Adrià. Through the cooperation with El

Bulli, NH Hoteles was granted the access to resources such as the El Bulli’s expertise in

creating brand experiences or the El Bulli brand itself that reinforced the positioning of

NH Hoteles as an innovative brand.

The cobranding path of El Bulli, based on a few and deep specific partnerships, aims at

not making the same mistake and maintaining control over the brand. El Bulli

restaurant prefers dyadic and deep relationships with their partners because one of the

resources it shares is process technology which is more difficult to protect legally.

The high opportunity cost explains why these firms prefer to follow narrower and

deeper business models (Kock et al., 2007).

In sum, El Bulli’s business model embodies both faces of an open business model. On

the one hand, it actively engages with external research sources to learn about new

breakthroughs in gastronomy. It closes for extended periods of time in order to identify

and then absorb these new breakthroughs, which keeps El Bulli one step ahead of other

restauranteurs who strive to copy its successes. And El Bulli commercializes its brand

and its knowledge through a variety of closely managed relationships that have taken its

brand into a number of areas beyond those of a typical restaurant. So while the

restaurant itself does not make money, the company overall is profitable.

Conclusion

Companies operating in turbulent times need to become more agile and more open in

developing and advancing their business models. As we have shown here, some firms

have already or are in the process of developing open business models. In the past, those

few firms with open business models were usually open in a specific function of their

business model such as product development, internationalization or distribution, while

Page 21: Sandulli Article

21

the rest of the business model remained close. Today, firms are in the process of

redesigning all the aspects of their business models under the new open prism. While

openness is not a panacea, and is not always better, the two faces of open business

models provide a framework for companies to evaluate how best to innovate their own

business models. On one hand, the buy side offers many new ideas for a company’s

business model. An open approach may reduce the costs and the risk of experimenting

with new business models, transforming fixed costs into variable costs. On the other

hand, the sell side provides numerous possibilities for leveraging ones’ resources in

others’ business models. The sell side creates new solutions to the always difficult task

of maximizing the rate of utilization of the firm’s resources, and allows higher

investments in resources that would not be justified by the returns from the firm’s own

business model. El Bulli provides a stimulating illustration of both faces at work. We

hope that it may serves as an inspiration for the business creativity of others who seek to

create and capture value in more open and distinctive ways.

References

Acha, V. (2007) Open by Design: The Role of Design in Open Innovation. Department

of Innovation, Universities and Skills.

Ahuja, G., y Katila, R. 2004. “Where Do Resources Come From? The Role of

Idiosyncratic Situations”. Strategic Management Journal, 25(8-9), p. 887-907.

Baldwin, C. Y. y Clark, K.B. (2000). Design Rules. Volume 1: The Power of

Modularity. MIT Press: Cambridge, Ma.

Barney J. (1986) “Strategic factor markets: expectations, luck and business strategy”.

Manage Science, 42, p.1231– 1241.

Barney J. (1991) “Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage”. Journal of

Management, 17, p. 99– 120.

Page 22: Sandulli Article

22

Chesbrough H.W. y Kusunoki, K. (1999). “ The modularity trap: innovation,

technology phase shifts, and the resulting limits of virtual organizations”. En Nonaka I.

y Teece, D.J. (Eds.) Managing Industrial Knowledge—Creation, Transfer and

Utilization, SAGE Publications, London, p. 202–230.

Chesbrough, H.W. y Rosenbloom, R.S. (2002). “The role of the business model in

capturing value from innovation: evidence from Xerox Corporation's technology spin-

off companies”, Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 11 (3), 529-555.

Chesbrough, H.W. (2003) Open Innovation: The New Imperative for Creating and

Profiting from Technology, Boston, MA, Harvard Business School Press.

Chesbrough, H.W. (2006) Open Business Models: How to Thrive in the New

Innovation Landscape, Boston, MA, Harvard Business School Press.

Chesbrough, H. y Appleyard, M.M. (2007), “Open Innovation and Strategy ”,

California Management Review, 50(1), p. 57-76.

Cohen, W.M. y Levinthal, D.A. (1989). “Innovation and Learning: Two faces of R&D”.

Economics Journal, 99, p. 569 – 596.

Cohen, W. M. y Levinthal, D. A. (1990). “Absorptive-Capacity - a New Perspective on

Learning and Innovation”. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, p. 128-152.

Das, T.K. y Teng B. (2000). “A Resource Based Theory of Strategic Alliances”. Journal

of Management, 26(1), pp. 31-61.

Dyer, J.H. y Singh H. (1998).“The relational view: Cooperative strategy and sources of

interorganizational competitive advantage”. Academy of Management Review, 23(4), p.

660-679.

Falcone P. (2007) “Small and Medium Enterprise Clusters: Marketing and

Communication Management” en MacGregor R.C. y Hodgkinson A.T. (Eds.) Small

Page 23: Sandulli Article

23

Business Clustering Technologies, Application in Marketing Management, IT and

Economics, Idea Group, Hershey, PA, US, p. 29-60.

Gulati, R. y Singh, H. (1998). “Managing coordination costs and appropiation concerns

in Strategic Alliances”. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43 (4), p.781-814.

Helander, M; Lawrence, R.; Liu, Y.; Perlich, C.; Reddy C. y Rosset, S. (2007).

“Looking for Great Ideas: Analyzing the Innovation Jam”. The 13th ACM SIGKDD

International Conference on Knowledge Discovery and Data Mining, 12-15 Agosto,

San José (EEUU).

Henderson, R.M. y Clark, K.B. (1990) “Architectural innovation: The reconfiguration

of existing product technologies and the failure of established firms”. Administrative

Science Quarterly, 35, p.9-30.

Hill, S., Lederer, C. y Lane, K. (2001). The Infinite Asset: Managing Brands to Create

New Value. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, Ma.

Katz R. y Allen, T.J. (1982). “Investigating the not-invented-here (NIH) syndrome: A

look at the performance, tenure, and communication patterns of 50 R&D project

groups”. R&D Management, 12, p. 7–19.

Kock, C. J. y Torkkeli, M. (2008) “Open Innovation: A 'Swingers' Club' or 'Going

Steady'?”. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1134489

Kock, C.; Torkkeli, M. y Salmi, P. (2007) “The limits of the "Open Innovation"

paradigm, or: When does it pay to be open?”. Strategic Management Society 27th

Annual Conference, San Diego, EE UU.

Laursen, K. y Salter, A .(2006) “Open for innovation: the role of openness in explaining

innovation performance among UK manufacturing firms”, Strategic Management

Journal, 27, p. 131-150.

Page 24: Sandulli Article

24

Lou K. y de Rond, M. (2006). “The not invented here myth”. Nature Reviews Drug

Discovery, 5, p. 451-452.

Nesse P.J. (2008). “Open service innovation in telecom industry – case study of

partnership models enabling 3’rd party development of novel mobile services”, 12th

International Conference ICIN, Bordeaux, France.

Parker, G. y Van Alstyne, M. (2008). Innovation, Openness and Platform Control, (July

24, 2008). Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1079712.

Romer, P. M, (1986). “Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth,”. Journal of Political

Economy, vol. 94(5), p. 1002-37

Roper, S.; Love, J.H. y Du J. (2007). “The Limits Of Open Innovation: Openness And

(quasi-)markets In The Organization Of Innovation”. Aston Business School Working

Paper, RP 0713.

Rumelt R.P. (1984) “Theory, strategy and entrepreneurship”. En: Lamb R.B. (Ed.).

Competitive strategic management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-

Hall, p. 556– 70.

Sandulli, F.D. (2007). “CD music purchase behaviour of P2P users”. Technovation, 27

(6-7), p. 325-334.

Shah, R.H. y Swaminathan, V. (2008). “Factors influencing partner selection in

strategic alliances: The moderating role of alliance context”. Strategic Management

Journal, 29, p. 471-494.

Stolinsky, P. (2004). “The IBM Software Development Platform partner ecosystem”.

The Rational Edge. July 2004.

http://www.ibm.com/developerworks/rational/rationaledge/index.html

Teece D.J. (1986). “Profiting from technological innovation”. Research Policy, 15(6), p.

285–305.

Page 25: Sandulli Article

25

Teece D.J. (2007). “Explicating dynamic capabilities: the nature and microfoundations

of sustainable enterprise performance”. Strategic Management Journal, 28(13), p.1319–

1330.

Thomson, J.D. (1967). Organizations in action: Social Sciences Bases of

Administration. McGraw Hill: New York.

Tripsas, M. y Gavetti, G. (2000). “Capabilities, cognition and inertia: Evidence from

digital imaging”. Strategic Management Journal, 21, p. 1147–1161.

Tushman M.L. y Romanelli E. (1985). “Organizational evolution: a metamorphosis

model of convergence and reorientation” en Cummings L.L. y Staw, B.B. (Eds.)

Research in Organizational Behavior, Vol. 7, JAI Press, Greenwich, CT; p. 171–222.

Von Hippel, E., y Von Krogh, G. (2003). “Open source software and the private-

collective innovation model: issues for organization science”. Organization Science, 14

(2), p. 209–233.

Wernerfelt B. (1984). “A resource-based view of the firm”. Strategic Manage Journal,

5, p.171– 180.

West, J. (2007). “Value Capture and Value Networks in Open Source Vendor

Strategies”. Proceedings of the 40th Annual Hawaii International Conference on System

Sciences, Hawaii, EE UU.

Zahra, S. A. y George, G. (2002). “Absorptive Capacity: A Review,

Reconceptualization, and Extension”. Academy of Management Review, 27(2), p. 185-

203.