reputation, innovation, and externalities in venture capitalfarzad-pourbabaee.github.io › papers...

34
Reputation, Innovation, and Externalities in Venture Capital Farzad Pourbabaee Department of Economics UC Berkeley 1 / 27

Upload: others

Post on 14-Feb-2021

9 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Reputation, Innovation, and Externalities inVenture Capital

    Farzad Pourbabaee

    Department of EconomicsUC Berkeley

    1 / 27

  • Outline

    1. Motivations and contributions

    2. Model

    3. Equilibrium characterization

    4. Innovation spillovers

    5. Reputational externality

    6. Robust extensions

    2 / 27

  • Motivations

    • In the two-sided markets there is incomplete information aboutparticipants’ types⇒ there is room for reputation building.

    • Examples (of incomplete information):• Labor market �rm’s productivity

    • Educational market university’s quality

    • Venture capital market VC’s ability

    • Contributions of this paper:• develops a search and matching model where agents of one side of the

    market have reputational concerns;

    • studies two instances of market failure in venture capital: positivespillovers, and reputation-deal �ow externality.

    3 / 27

  • VCs’ ability and reputation (Sorensen 2007)A = net impact, C = after adjusting for the sorting

    Figure 1: VC’s in�uence disentangled from sorting

    4 / 27

  • Theoretical contributions

    • Developing a dynamic equilibrium model of search and matching inan economy where individuals on one side have symmetricincomplete information about their type.(Shimer and Smith 2000&2005), (Chade 2005), (Damiano et. al 2005), (Hoppeet. al 2009), (Anderson and Smith 2010), (Anderson 2015), (Chade andEeckhout 2017)

    • Methodological contribution: matching sets⇒ stopping timeproblems faced by investors⇒ applying the theory of monotonicityto the operators acting on function spaces (Krasnoselskij 1964)

    5 / 27

  • Contributions (to the economics of venture capital)

    • In equilibrium VCs earn reputation for their value-added skills,thereby rationalizing a number of stylized facts:

    • Later stage startups attract a wider range of investors (Gompers,Gornall, Kaplan and Strebulaev 2020)

    • More reputable VCs exhibit higher tolerance for failure (Manso2011), (Tian and Wang 2014)

    • Cost-reducing technological shocks enhances the variety of �nancedprojects: “spray and pray" (Ewens, Nanda and Rhodes-Kropf 2018)

    • Extending the baseline model to study two instances of marketfailure:

    • Reputation-deal �ow externality among VCs early termination ofstartups; sub-optimal mass of active high ability investors

    • Neglect of positive spillovers among startups

    • Other related literature: (Silveira and Wright 2016), (Akcigit et. al2019)

    6 / 27

  • Outline

    1. Motivations and contributions

    2. Model

    3. Equilibrium characterization

    4. Innovation spillovers

    5. Reputational externality

    6. Robust extensions

    7 / 27

  • Model diagram

    • A unit mass of VCs. A known fraction p have high type (θ = 1) while1− p have low type (θ = 0) their types are hidden to EVERYONE.

    • Two types of projects q ∈ {a, b} with measures ϕa, ϕb their typesare observable to EVERYONE.

    • VCs randomly meet the projects, subject to search friction withquadratic matching technology and frictional rate κ.

    • Upon the meeting VC either accepts or rejects the project, thuswaiting for the next chance.

    • If the partnership is formed• VC covers the �ow investment cost of c.• A successful outcome with unit payo� arrives with intensity θλq , whereq ∈ {a, b}, and λb > λa.

    • VC collects all the revenues, i.e entrepreneur has zero bargaining power(Ueda 2004) and (Hellman and Puri 2002).

    • VC has the option to terminate the project.8 / 27

  • Dynamic timeline

    reputation = π meetq-startup

    ∼ exp. time

    reject

    �ow cost=c,solve stopping

    time prob.

    accept

    success

    failure

    π ↑ 1

    π ↓

    9 / 27

  • Outline

    1. Motivations and contributions

    2. Model

    3. Equilibrium characterization

    4. Innovation spillovers

    5. Reputational externality

    6. Robust extensions

    10 / 27

  • VC strategy

    • Reputation is the market posterior belief about the VC’s type πt := P (θ = 1| It).

    • When unmatched the VC’s reputation is �xed, and when matched to aq-project:

    π̇t = −λqπt(1− πt) before successπt = 1 after success

    • What matters in the equilibrium is the matching setM:

    (q, π) ∈M⇔ rep. π VC �nds q pro�table.

    • this set encodes the decision to accept or reject a project.• it also encodes the decision to terminate or continue the funding.

    11 / 27

  • Value functions and the �xed-point• Matching value function v(π, q) non-recursive form :

    rv(π, q) = −c+ λqπ [1 + w(1)− v(π, q)]︸ ︷︷ ︸surplus upon

    success

    −λqπ(1− π)∂πv(π, q)︸ ︷︷ ︸marginal

    reputation loss

    • Reputation value function w(π) non-recursive form :rw(π) = κϕa [v(π, a)− w(π)]︸ ︷︷ ︸

    surplus gainedfrom a-project

    χa(π) + κϕb [v(π, b)− w(π)]︸ ︷︷ ︸surplus gainedfrom b-project

    χb(π)

    • Matching setM⊂ {a, b} × [0, 1]:M = {(q, π) : v(π, q) > w(π)}

    〈w〉 〈v,M〉Reputation function Matching variables

    Figure 2: Equilibrium feedbacks12 / 27

  • Equilibrium

    Theorem 1: Equilibrium existence and uniqueness

    ∀{ϕa, ϕb}, ∃ a stationary equilibrium with increasing value functions inπ. This equilibrium is unique for large discount rates.

    Regime determination:λa − c > κϕb(λb−c)κϕb+r+λb = Opportunity cost of forgoing the option to wait

    0

    1

    projecttype

    π

    a[ϕa] b[ϕb]

    αHC

    (a) high cost matching sets

    0

    1

    projecttype

    π

    a[ϕa] b[ϕb]

    αLC

    (b) low cost matching sets

    α =c

    λb (1 + w(1)) proxy for imperfect learning

    13 / 27

  • Outline

    1. Motivations and contributions

    2. Model

    3. Equilibrium characterization

    4. Innovation spillovers

    5. Reputational externality

    6. Robust extensions

    14 / 27

  • Spillovers and endogenous supply of startups

    • Interpretations of two types of projects ( λa < λb):• early vs. late stage startups.→ time dimension as 1

    λa> 1

    λb

    • radical vs. incremental innovation→ risk dimension as 1λ2a

    > 1λ2b

    • Spillovers from early stage small companies late stage businesses.

    failed to be internalized in private decisions

    • Examples (Mazzucato 2013):• iPhone depends on the Internet; the progenitor of the Internet wasARPANET : a program funded by DARPA in 1960’s.

    • Google maps depends on GPS: a US military project called NAVSTAR in1970’s.

    15 / 27

  • A framework to endogenize• A fraction ζ < 1 of successful early stage projects would translate into

    the late stage projects:

    κϕbn(1)︸ ︷︷ ︸out�ow from

    late stage

    = ζλama(1)χa(1)︸ ︷︷ ︸in�ow tolate stage

    ϕb =

    {ζϕa χa(1) = 1

    0 o.w

    〈w〉 〈v,M〉

    (ϕa, ϕb)

    steady state measures

    Reputationvalue

    Matchingvariables

    Figure 4: Equilibrium feedbacks withendogenous mass of projects

    • Recall that investment in early stage project takes place i�

    λa − c >κϕb (λb − c)κϕb + r + λb

    = Opportunity cost of forgoing the option to wait for b-projects16 / 27

  • Spillover externality

    0

    c

    λb

    κζϕa

    λa Full investment No investmentInvestment cycles

    Figure 5: Investment regimes under endogenous(ϕa, ϕb)

    λa − c >

    opportunity cost offorgoing the wait︷ ︸︸ ︷κϕb(λb − c)λb + r + κϕb

    ϕ̇b = ζλama(1)︸ ︷︷ ︸in�ow

    −κϕbn(1)︸ ︷︷ ︸out�ow

    17 / 27

  • Decentralizing the social optimum I

    • What would a hypothetical benevolent planner do? benchmark

    • What are the planner’s instruments? At best, the choice of matchingsets→ {(χa(π), χb(π)) : π ∈ [0, 1]}.

    • Social optimum:

    maxχ

    ∫ ∞0

    e−rt∑

    q∈{a,b}

    (λqπ − c)Mq(dπ)dt

    subject to law of motions for {mq(π), n(π), ϕb} dist. law of motion

    18 / 27

  • Decentralizing the social optimum II

    • Social marginal value functions (to be compared with private marginalvalue functions):

    rv∗(π, q) = −c+ λqπ [1 + w∗(1)− v∗(π, q)]− λqπ(1− π)∂πv∗(π, q)

    + ρζλaπ1{q=a}

    rw∗(π) =∑q

    κϕq [v∗(π, q)− w∗(π)]χ∗q(π)− ρκϕbχ∗b(π)

    • Optimal transfers (conceptual, not necessarily implementable from thepublic �nance viewpoint)

    • A tax on unmatched investors that choose to invest in late stage projects= ρκϕb

    • A subsidy to investors matched with early stage projects = ρζλaπ

    19 / 27

  • Outline

    1. Motivations and contributions

    2. Model

    3. Equilibrium characterization

    4. Innovation spillovers

    5. Reputational externality

    6. Robust extensions

    20 / 27

  • Reputation and deal �ow

    • Ample evidence that VCs reputation impact their deal �ow e.g(Gompers 1996), (Sorenson and Stuart 2001), (Hsu 2004), (Nanda,Samila and Sorenson 2020).

    • In the survey paper (Gompers, Gornall, Kaplan and Strebulaev 2020):23% of VC responded the deal �ow is the most important factor behindthe success.

    • sub-sample of low IPO rate investors→ 31%• sub-sample of high IPO rate investors→ 19%

    • Aggregate view: higher deal �ow for more reputable ones⇒ lowerdeal �ow for less reputable ones.

    21 / 27

  • Reputational externality in the meeting rate function• Suppose there is only one group of projects, i.e��ZZλa and λ = λb.• So far, uniform meeting rate⇒ κϕdt. Now, reputational weighting,

    i.e:κϕ

    ψ(π)∫ψ(π)dF∞(π)

    dt = κϕψ(π)

    E[ψ(π∞)]︸ ︷︷ ︸µ:=

    dt

    • Stationary economy→ let investors exogenously enter and leave atthe rate δ.

    0 10

    1

    π

    ψ(π)

    admissible space of weight functions

    Ψ := {ψ : [0, 1]→ [0, 1]|ψ(0) = 0, ψ(1) = 1, ψ′ ≥ 0, ψ′′ ≤ 0}

    22 / 27

  • (Symmetric) equilibrium vs. the optimum outcome

    0 α p 10

    m(π)

    m(1)

    n(p)

    n(1)

    n(α)

    π

    dist. of π∞

    23 / 27

  • (Symmetric) equilibrium vs. the optimum outcome

    0 α p 10

    m(π)

    m(1)

    n(p)

    n(1)

    n(α)

    π

    dist. of π∞Properties of symmetric equilibrium

    • cond (1) steady state µ:µ = E [ψ(π∞)] = M(µ, α).

    • cond (2) endogenous separation:α = c

    λ(1+w(1))= A(w(1))

    • cond (3) endogenous rep. value:w(1) = (r+δ)

    −1κϕ/µr+δ+λ+κϕ/µ

    (λ− c) =W(µ).

    Fixed-point µe = M

    µe, αe︷ ︸︸ ︷A ◦W(µe)

    23 / 27

  • (Symmetric) equilibrium vs. the optimum outcome

    0 α p 10

    m(π)

    m(1)

    n(p)

    n(1)

    n(α)

    π

    dist. of π∞Properties of symmetric equilibrium

    • cond (1) steady state µ:µ = E [ψ(π∞)] = M(µ, α).

    • cond (2) endogenous separation:α = c

    λ(1+w(1))= A(w(1))

    • cond (3) endogenous rep. value:w(1) = (r+δ)

    −1κϕ/µr+δ+λ+κϕ/µ

    (λ− c) =W(µ).

    Fixed-point µe = M

    µe, αe︷ ︸︸ ︷A ◦W(µe)

    Planner’s optimum:

    maxα

    rS(µ, α) = (λ− c)m(1) +∫ pα

    (λπ − c)m(π)dπ

    subject to µ = M(µ, α)23 / 27

  • Decentralized vs. centralized outcomes

    Proposition 2: Equilibrium vs planner outcomes

    In the described economy with reputational externality,

    (i) there always exists a symmetric equilibrium with 0 < αe < p.(ii) In particular, a local reduction in the termination point αe

    increases the social surplus.(iii) Comparative statics: ψ ↑⇒ w(1) ↓, µe ↑ and αe ↑

    α∗ αe p0

    α

    S(α)

    0 10

    1

    ψ1

    ψ2

    π

    ψ(π)

    24 / 27

  • Outline

    1. Motivations and contributions

    2. Model

    3. Equilibrium characterization

    4. Innovation spillovers

    5. Reputational externality

    6. Robust extensions

    25 / 27

  • Robust extension

    • Economy with short-lived investors, where individuals are subject toexogenous exits and exogenous birth.

    • General type space for project qualities, q ∼ φ(dq), and inconclusivebreakthroughs, i.e λq(θ) not necessarily equals θλq :

    • λq(θ) is increasing in q.

    • Increasing di�erences, i.e for every q′′ > q′:

    λq′′(H)− λq′′(L) ≥ λq′(H)− λq′(L) proof sketch

    26 / 27

  • Conclusion

    • Characterization of matching sets in the unique stationaryequilibrium with increasing value functions in reputation:

    • Higher tolerance for failure in more reputable VCs.• Higher search frictions could save the market from breakdown when

    there is spillover from early- to late-stage projects.

    • In presence of reputational externality:• Early termination of startups.• Size of active high-ability investors becomes ine�ciently small.• Strengthening the reputational externality (ψ ↑) leads to lower

    tolerance for failure (αe ↑).

    27 / 27

  • Model diagram

    High typeθ = 1 : p

    Low typeθ = 0 : 1− p

    Investors

    Incomplete information⇒ Reputation formationπt = P (θ = 1|It)

    Type-bq = b : ϕb

    Type-aq = a : ϕa

    Projects

    Who matchesto whom?

    s.t search frictions

    (q, π) ∈M

    Success rateθλq

    Back to the model1 / 5

  • Non-recursive form of the value functions

    • Matching value function:

    v(π, q) = supτ

    {E

    [e−rσ − c

    ∫ σ0

    e−rtdt+ e−rσw(πσ);σ ≤ τ]

    + E

    [−c∫ τ0

    e−rtdt+ e−rτw(πτ );σ > τ

    ]}• Reputation value function:

    w(π) = supM

    {E[e−rmin τqv(π, arg min τq)

    ]: (q, π) ∈M

    }Back to the recursive forms

    2 / 5

  • Distributional law of motions

    ṁq(π) = − λqπmq(π)︸ ︷︷ ︸successful projects

    out�ow

    +κϕqn(π)χq(π)︸ ︷︷ ︸in�ow of

    recent matches

    +λq∂π (π(1− π)mq(π))︸ ︷︷ ︸net learning in�ow

    ṅ(π) = −∑q

    κϕqn(π)χq(π)︸ ︷︷ ︸out�ow of

    recent matches

    ϕ̇b = ζλa

    (ma(1) +

    ∫πma(π)dπ

    )︸ ︷︷ ︸

    spillover from successful earlyto late stage projects

    − κϕb(n(1)χb(1) +

    ∫n(π)χb(π)dπ

    )︸ ︷︷ ︸

    out�ow due torecent partnerships

    .

    Back to planner’s problem

    3 / 5

  • Proof sketch for the general type space I

    • Projects’ type space q ∼ φ(dq). Assume λL(q) ≤ λH(q) ≤ λ.

    • Stopping time problem:reputationfunc. w(π)

    Stopping timeproblem

    Stopping timeproblem

    matching valuefunc.=Tqw

    • Fixed-point mapping w = Aw:

    [Aw](π) = sup{∫

    B[Tqw](π) φ(dq)1 + κr φ(B)

    : B ⊂ Supp(φ)}

    • Let L1[0, 1] be the underlying space for w, endowed by the partialorder % induced by L1+[0, 1].

    • Properties of A:• Positivity: Aw % 0, for every w % 0.• Monotonicity: if w2 % w1 ⇒ Aw2 % Aw1.• Every �xed-point of A is order-bounded by λ/r.

    4 / 5

  • Proof sketch for the general type space II

    • Let 〈0,λ/r〉 :={f ∈ L1+[0, 1] : 0 - f - λ/r

    }be the order interval,

    then A : 〈0,λ/r〉 → 〈0,λ/r〉 � Knaster–Tarski theorem �

    • Use a coupling argument along with the Strassen’s theorem to showA maps increasing functions to increasing functions.

    • Construct the sequence w0 = 0 and wn = Awn−1⇒ wn ↑ w∞pointwise, where w∞ is increasing.

    • Showing the L1 continuity: ‖Awn −Aw∞‖1 → 0, therefore

    w∞ = Aw∞.

    • Using the complementarity in λq(θ) to show ∃ α, the lowest boundarypoint ofMb, where b = sup{Supp(φ)}.

    back

    5 / 5

    Motivations and contributionsModelEquilibrium characterizationInnovation spilloversReputational externalityRobust extensionsAppendix