product market definition in the … market definition in the pharmaceutical industry m. howard...

44
PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a major target of antitrust investigations and litigation. Indeed, Federal Trade Commission officials have said that almost 25 percent of new competition investigations in recent years have involved pharmaceutical products, 1 though prescrip- tion drugs account for only about 10 percent of health care spending 2 and less than 2 percent of the U.S. gross domestic product. 3 Over the last several years, the FTC and state attorneys general have challenged both interim and permanent settlements of intellectual prop- erty litigation between pioneer and generic drug manufacturers alleged to delay generic entry. They have also attacked patent listings in the Food and Drug Administration “Orange Book” and have alleged monop- olization through fraud on the Patent and Trademark Office and sham litigation. Yet other cases have condemned distribution agreements as unlawful exclusive dealing. These government actions have led to sub- stantial private class action litigation against the pharmaceutical industry. The FTC has also challenged numerous mergers and acquisitions in the industry over the last decade. One common feature in all of these cases is the need to define a relevant market. In nonmerger cases, the FTC and private plaintiffs * Member of the District of Columbia Bar and former Assistant Director, Bureau of Competition, Federal Trade Commission, 1993–1998. The author thanks David Balto, Jonathan Gleklen, Amy Miner, Robin Sampson, and Robert Skitol for their assistance and helpful comments. 1 Timothy J. Muris, Everything Old Is New Again: Health Care and Competition in the 21st Century, Remarks Before 7th Annual Competition in Health Care Forum at 3 n.13 (Nov 7, 2002), available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/muris/murishealthcarespeech0211.pdf. 2 Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services, Dep’t of Health & Human Services, The Nation’s Health Dollar: 2001 ( Jan. 8, 2003), available at http://cms.hhs.gov/ statistics/nhe/historical/chart.asp. 3 Uwe E. Reinhardt, Perspectives on the Pharmaceutical Industry, 20 Health Affairs 136, 138 (Sept.–Oct. 2001). 633 71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved. This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Upload: vanhuong

Post on 20-May-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


5 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THEPHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY

M. Howard Morse*

I. INTRODUCTION

The pharmaceutical industry has become a major target of antitrustinvestigations and litigation. Indeed, Federal Trade Commission officialshave said that almost 25 percent of new competition investigations inrecent years have involved pharmaceutical products,1 though prescrip-tion drugs account for only about 10 percent of health care spending2

and less than 2 percent of the U.S. gross domestic product.3

Over the last several years, the FTC and state attorneys general havechallenged both interim and permanent settlements of intellectual prop-erty litigation between pioneer and generic drug manufacturers allegedto delay generic entry. They have also attacked patent listings in theFood and Drug Administration “Orange Book” and have alleged monop-olization through fraud on the Patent and Trademark Office and shamlitigation. Yet other cases have condemned distribution agreements asunlawful exclusive dealing. These government actions have led to sub-stantial private class action litigation against the pharmaceutical industry.The FTC has also challenged numerous mergers and acquisitions in theindustry over the last decade.

One common feature in all of these cases is the need to define arelevant market. In nonmerger cases, the FTC and private plaintiffs

* Member of the District of Columbia Bar and former Assistant Director, Bureau ofCompetition, Federal Trade Commission, 1993–1998. The author thanks David Balto,Jonathan Gleklen, Amy Miner, Robin Sampson, and Robert Skitol for their assistance andhelpful comments.

1 Timothy J. Muris, Everything Old Is New Again: Health Care and Competition in the21st Century, Remarks Before 7th Annual Competition in Health Care Forum at 3 n.13 (Nov7, 2002), available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/muris/murishealthcarespeech0211.pdf.

2 Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services, Dep’t of Health & Human Services,The Nation’s Health Dollar: 2001 ( Jan. 8, 2003), available at http://cms.hhs.gov/statistics/nhe/historical/chart.asp.

3 Uwe E. Reinhardt, Perspectives on the Pharmaceutical Industry, 20 Health Affairs 136,138 (Sept.–Oct. 2001).

633

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 2: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal634

generally allege narrow markets, limited to a single drug and its genericequivalent in some cases and to generic drugs excluding the bio-equivalent “brand-name” drug in other cases. In its merger challenges,on the other hand, the FTC has alleged markets ranging from thosebased upon a particular chemical compound, to broader markets basedupon various drugs’ manner of interaction or dosage form, to stillbroader markets of all drugs used to treat a disease or condition. Innumerous pharmaceutical merger challenges, the government hasincluded in the market not only currently marketed drugs but also otherdrugs under development, alleging “innovation markets.”4

It is not obvious how all of these cases can meet the Supreme Court’sproduct market test of “reasonable interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of demand between the product itself and substitutes for it.”5

Unfortunately, most of the government actions contain only barebonesmarket allegations so they provide little guidance. In the one case theFTC staff has litigated, an administrative law judge found that complaintcounsel failed to prove the alleged market definition and that the marketmust be broadened to include “therapeutically equivalent” drugs.6 Thatloss, even if reversed on appeal, suggests further attention to productmarket definition is needed.

The broad range of product market definitions alleged in the variouscases warrants close examination to ensure that the government andprivate plaintiffs are not gerrymandering market definitions to fit desiredoutcomes in each case. This is particularly true because, at least in mergercases, where the drugs at issue often account for only a small part ofthe transaction, companies have strong incentives to address governmentconcerns without litigation. Private actions also often settle, after motionsto dismiss or motions for summary judgment. Because market definitionissues are intensely factual and often not resolved until trial, there areonly a handful of court decisions providing guidance about how to definemarkets in the pharmaceutical industry.

Court decisions in pharmaceutical cases that address market definitioncome out differently on a number of important questions that deserve

4 The use of innovation markets to challenge such mergers, which has generated substan-tial controversy, is beyond the scope of this article. For a detailed analysis of innovationmarkets, see M. Howard Morse, The Limits of Innovation Markets, ABA, Antitrust andIntellectual Property Newsletter, Spring 2001, at 22–35, available at http://www.abanet.org/antitrust/mo/premium-at/ip/559817 2.pdf.

5 Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325 (1962).6 See Schering-Plough Corp., Upsher-Smith Labs. & Am. Home Prods. Corp., FTC Docket

No. 9297 ( June 27, 2002) (Initial Decision), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/07/scheringinitialdecisionp1.pdf.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 3: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 635

attention: Are pharmaceutical markets fundamentally different fromother markets? Who is the customer? Does price matter? Should a singledrug define the market? Should generic drugs be in the same marketas pioneer drugs or a distinct product market? Few cases address perhapsthe most important question of all, which is how one determines whetherthe “Cellophane trap” applies. This article will address all of these issues.

II. AN INDUSTRY OVERVIEW

Defining pharmaceutical product markets requires an understandingof the role of government regulation, technological innovation, andcompetition in the industry.

A. Government Regulation

Research and development, as well as marketing of pharmaceuticals,is heavily regulated by the FDA. Under the Federal Food, Drug andCosmetic Act,7 any person seeking to market a new drug (a so-called“pioneer” applicant), must first obtain FDA approval by filing a NewDrug Application (NDA) establishing the drug is safe and effective forits intended use.8 The Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restora-tion Act of 1984,9 commonly referred to as the Hatch-Waxman Act,established a streamlined approval process for “generic” versions ofapproved drugs with the same active ingredients. The Act authorizesAbbreviated New Drug Applications (ANDAs) for generic drugs that arebio-equivalent to pioneer drugs as well as paper new drug applications(paper NDAs) that rely on published literature to demonstrate safetyand efficacy.10

Intellectual property law also significantly influences the pharma-ceutical industry. Studies have shown that the industry is heavily depen-dent on intellectual property generally and the patent laws in particularto justify investment in research and development.11 Absent patent

7 21 U.S.C. §§ 301–397.8 Id. § 355.9 Pub. L. No. 98-417, 98 Stat. 1585 (1984).

10 21 U.S.C. § 355. See Eli Lilly & Co. v. Medtronic, Inc., 496 U.S. 661, 676 (1990).11 See Richard C. Levin, Testimony Before FTC/DOJ Joint Hearings on Competition and

Intellectual Property Law (Feb. 6, 2002) (“In most industries . . . patents were not regardedas highly effective in protecting a firm’s competitive advantage. The pharmaceutical andcertain other chemical industries were striking exceptions.”), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/comments/intelpropertycomments/levinrichardc.htm; Richard C. Levinet al., Appropriating the Returns from Industrial Research and Development, Brookings Paperson Economic Activity 783 (1987), available at http://cowles.econ.yale.edu/P/cp/p07a/p0714.pdf; Edwin Mansfield, Patents and Innovation: An Empirical Study, 32 Mgmt. Sci. 173,175 (1986) (65% of innovations in the pharmaceutical industry would not have been

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 4: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal636

protection or a similar barrier, imitators could free ride on innovators’R&D efforts.

B. Technological Innovation

The pharmaceutical industry is characterized by substantial expendi-tures on research and development, continual innovation, and introduc-tion of new drugs. Development of new pharmaceuticals is anincreasingly lengthy and costly business fraught with significant risk.12

Early-stage pharmaceutical R&D focuses on discovery of new molecularentities (NMEs) or new chemical entities (NCEs), which are new thera-peutic compounds not previously used or tested in humans. Prospectivedrugs are discovered through designing new molecules or screeningof existing compounds. Drug candidates must then undergo rigorouspreclinical testing in laboratories and animals and clinical testing inhumans to establish safety and effectiveness. Clinical testing proceedsthrough three successive phases, from testing on a small number ofusually healthy volunteers principally to explore pharmacokinetics andestablish safe dosages (Phase I), to testing relatively small numbers ofsubjects with the targeted disease or condition to obtain evidence onsafety and preliminary data on efficacy (Phase II), to large-scale, multi-center trials to establish efficacy and uncover side-effects that may occurinfrequently (Phase III). Even after a drug is approved and introduced,companies often undertake additional clinical R&D, as a condition ofapproval, to compare effectiveness with other products, or to test newtherapeutic uses to expand the market.13 Pharmaceutical companies alsoconduct R&D on new drug delivery mechanisms—such as implantabledrug infusion pumps or extended release tablets—to deliver therapeuticagents to the desired site in the body at the desired dose. Companiesmay also introduce follow-on products—new combinations, formula-tions, dosing forms, or dosing strengths—of existing compounds thatmust also be tested in humans before market introduction.

Drug development has been analogized to wildcatting in Texas, withmany dry holes and a few gushers.14 That is, many drugs that companies

developed if patent protection was not available; other industries are far less dependenton patents).

12 Technology and Innovation: Their Effects on Cost Growth of Healthcare, Before the U.S. Cong.Joint Economic Committee ( July 9, 2003) (Statement of FDA Commissioner Mark McClellan),available at http://www.fda.gov/ola/2003/healthcare0709.html.

13 See U.S. Food & Drug Admin., From Test Tube to Patient: Improving HealthThrough Human Drugs 6 (Sept. 1999), available at http://www.fda.gov/cder/about/whatwedo/testtube.pdf.

14 Philip J. Hilts, Seeking Limits to a Drug Monopoly, N.Y. Times, May 14, 1992, at D1.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 5: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 637

develop and test prove unsuccessful and are never marketed. One recentstudy, in fact, estimates the success rate for compounds entering clinicaltesting at only 22 percent, and few compounds that companies researchever even make it into clinical trials.15 The FDA has likened the processof discovering a new drug to searching for the proverbial needle in ahaystack, noting “literally hundreds and sometimes thousands of chemi-cal compounds must be made and tested to find one that can achievethe desirable result without too-serious side effects.”16

Recent studies have estimated that, on average, discovering and devel-oping a new drug takes ten to fifteen years and costs over $800 million(taking into account expenses of failed development efforts and the costof capital), more than twice what it cost a decade ago.17 Studies alsoshow that the top 10 percent of newly marketed drugs account for halfof the financial returns on all new drug development, and only one-third of newly introduced drugs generate returns that exceed averageR&D costs.18

C. Competition

Competition in the pharmaceutical industry occurs on two levels: thedevelopment of new drugs, and the sale of drugs.

Companies compete to be the first to market with a drug to meet anunmet medical need or with a drug that is safer or more effective attreating a condition or disease than current treatments. The first to

15 See Henry Grabowski & John Vernon, Effective Patent Life in Pharmaceuticals, 19 Int’lJ. Tech. Mgmt. 98 (2000). Only one of 5,000 screened compounds is ever approved asa new medicine according to the Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America;See Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America (PhRMA), Pharma-ceutical Industry Profile 2003 at 3, available at http://www.phrma.org/publications/publications/profile02/index.cfm.

16 Food & Drug Admin., supra note 13, at 14.17 See Joseph A. DiMasi et al., The Price of Innovation: New Estimates of Drug Development

Costs, 22 J. Health Econ. 151 (2003); Tufts Center for the Study of Drug Development,Post-Approval R&D Raises Total Drug Development Costs to $897 Million, Impact Report, vol.5, no. 3 (2003); Grabowski & Vernon, supra note 15; Congressional Budget Office,How Increased Competition from Generic Drugs Has Affected Prices and Returnsin the Pharmaceutical Industry xiii, 14–15 (1998), available at ftp://ftp.cbo.gov/6xx/doc655/pharm.pdf.

18 Henry Grabowski, John Vernon & Joseph DiMasi, Returns on Research and Developmentfor 1990s New Drug Introductions, 20 Pharmacoecon. suppl. 3, 11–29 (2002). The Congres-sional Budget Office reports that the present discounted value of the return from theaverage marketed drug—including both blockbusters and those that do not cover thecost of their own development—exceeded the capitalized costs of R&D by $22 to $36million in the 1980s and total returns from marketing a new drug have on average decreasedby about $27 million since 1984. Congressional Budget Office, supra note 17, at xv,14–15, 38, 47.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 6: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal638

market will often gain a substantial first-mover advantage, largely as aresult of establishing standard physician prescribing practices.19

Pharmaceutical companies also compete in marketing drugs. Severaldifferent market participants are involved today in purchasing pharma-ceuticals, which may complicate market definition analyses. The patientis the ultimate consumer, but patients cannot obtain prescription phar-maceuticals without a physician’s prescription. Traditionally, physiciansselected drugs for their patients without considering price. Pharma-ceutical companies still expend substantial sums on physician-directedmarketing efforts, including so-called “detailing” visits by sales represen-tatives, free samples, advertising in scientific and medical journals, andsponsorship of continuing medical education.20 These expenditures, likeadvertising in other industries, are viewed as procompetitive by someand as wasteful by others. Today, patients are also targeted by direct-to-consumer advertising aimed at influencing purchasing patterns, generat-ing complaints about consumer pressure on physicians.21

Third party payers also play an important role in the market today.Increasingly, employer-sponsored health insurance policies cover phar-maceutical expenses, with third-party payments now accounting for two-thirds of national spending on prescription drugs.22 In recent years,there has also been a shift of large numbers of patients from conventionalindemnity or fee-for-service health insurance plans to health mainte-nance organizations (HMOs), preferred provider organizations (PPOs),and other managed care organizations (MCOs). Many health care plans,including traditional fee-for-service plans, now rely on pharmacy benefitmanagers (PBMs) to administer pharmaceutical benefit plans and man-age drug utilization. PBMs negotiate discounts and rebates with suppliers,establish formularies of approved or preferred drugs, and influencedrug selection through multiple-tier reimbursement co-payment (fixedconsumer payment per prescription) or co-insurance (fixed consumerpercentage payment per prescription) and other policies. Drugs disfa-vored by the PBM can, for instance, be discouraged by higher co-

19 See F.M. Scherer & David Ross, Industrial Market Structure and EconomicPerformance 584–92 (1990).

20 Congressional Budget Office, supra note 17, at 19–21.21 See generally Meredith B. Rosenthal et al., Demand Effects of Recent Changes in Prescription

Drug Promotion ( June 2003), available at http://www.kff.org/content/2003/6085/DemandEffect revised 61803.pdf; John E. Calfee, Public Policy Issues in Direct-to -Consumer Advertising

of Prescription Drugs, 21 J. Pub. Pol’y & Mktg. 174 ( July 8, 2002); Meredith B. Rosenthalet al., Promotion of Prescription Drugs to Consumers, 346 New Eng. J. Med. 498 (2002); MichaelS. Wilkes et al., Direct-to -Consumer Prescription Drug Advertising: Trends, Impact and Implications,19 Health Affairs 110 (2000).

22 Reinhardt, supra note 3, at 138.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 7: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 639

payments or co-insurance rates and prior authorization requirementsthat impose additional costs on patients. PBMs also pay pharmacistshigher dispensing fees for favored drugs, use maximum allowable cost(MAC) programs to limit reimbursement to prices of low-cost drugs,and pay pharmacists incentives for achieving levels of performance indistributing favored drugs. They also monitor drug use by patients withchronic conditions through disease management (DM) programs andtrack physician prescribing practices to identify physicians for educa-tional interventions. Group purchasing organizations (GPOs) also nowput pressure on pharmaceutical companies for reduced prices. As aresult, manufacturers regularly offer discounts and rebates based in parton a firm’s ability to shift sales to the company’s drug.23

Pharmaceuticals are approved for sale by the FDA for particular indica-tions, though physicians may prescribe approved drugs for off-label use.While there are diseases or conditions for which there is only a singlepharmaceutical available, other diseases or conditions may be treatedby various drugs that compete to varying degrees. Alternative drugs maybe chemically similar or very different, and may have the same or differentmechanisms of action, yet be functionally similar. In such circumstances,drug prices are set considering length of use (whether the drug treatschronic or acute conditions), convenience of use, and relative safety andefficacy profiles. Studies have shown that the availability of alternativeslimits drug manufacturers’ pricing ability and “new drug prices tend toreflect the degree of price sensitivity in the market and the perceivedvalue of the product to patients.”24 In addition to drug alternatives, apatient with a particular disease or condition may at times be treatedwith an alternative form of medical therapy. While the suggestion thatpain is an alternative to medical treatment and should be included inthe relevant market as once proposed may be appropriately ridiculed,25

23 See generally David H. Kreling, Cost Control for Prescription Drug Programs: PharmacyBenefit Manager (PBM): Efforts, Effects and Implications, Prepared for U.S. Departmentof Health and Human Services Conference on Pharmaceutical Pricing Practices, Utilizationand Costs (Aug. 8–9, 2000), available at http://aspe.hhs.gov/health/reports/drug-papers/kreling-final.htm; Roy Levy, The Pharmaceutical Industry: A Discussion of Competi-tive and Antitrust Issues in an Environment of Change, FTC Bureau of EconomicsStaff Report 3–4, 24–30 (Mar. 1999), available at http://www.ftc.gov/reports/pharmaceu-tical/drugrep.pdf; Congressional Budget Office, supra note 17, at 5–11, 23–27.

24 Joseph DiMasi, Price Trends for Prescription Pharmaceuticals 1995–1999, Preparedfor U.S. Department of Health and Human Services Conference on Pharmaceutical PricingPractices, Utilization and Costs (Aug. 8–9, 2000), available at http://aspe.hhs.gov/health/reports/drug-papers/dimassi/dimasi-final.htm.; see also Congressional Budget Office,supra note 17, at xi, 18–23; Z. John Lu & William S. Comanor, Strategic Pricing of NewPharmaceuticals, 80 Rev. Econ. & Stat. 108–18 (1998).

25 See Can a High Pain Threshold Beat a Medical Cartel? FTC Watch No. 358, Jan. 13, 1992(“knowledgeable staff members reacted with shocked incredulity last month when an

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 8: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal640

surgery or other medical procedures may at times be a realistic alternativeto medication.

Much has been made of increasing drug expenditures in recent years,26

and data do show total expenditures for prescription drugs in the UnitedStates rising almost 16 percent per year on average from 1996 to 2001.27

But studies attribute those increases much more to new drugs andincreased utilization than to price increases on drugs on the market.The most recent study attributes 47 percent of recent price increases toincreased utilization, 27 percent to changes in the types of drugs used,and only 26 percent to price increases.28 It is surprising that increasedoutput and introduction of new products should be of concern to anti-trust officials, yet they continue to emphasize total expenditures in pub-lic speeches.29

It is worth noting that while there have been a number of majormergers and acquisitions among manufacturers in recent years, it iswidely recognized that the pharmaceutical industry as a whole is notconcentrated. The Department of Commerce identifies more than 700companies in the United States engaged in pharmaceutical manufactur-

agency economist suggested that kidney stone victims could defeat any cartel controllingaccess to machines which pulverize [kidney] stones sonically by showing patience,” quotingan internal FTC staff memo suggesting “an increase in the price of lithotripsy may leadsome patients with smaller stones to be more patient and let the stones pass withoutlithotripsy” and noting “[t]he economic analysis which triggered internal revulsion . . .was part of a discussion of ‘the relevant product market’”).

26 See generally John Carey & Amy Barrett, Drug Prices: What’s Fair? Bus. Wk., Dec. 10,2001, at 60; David Noonan, Why Drugs Cost So Much, Newsweek, Sept. 25, 2000, at 22.

27 Health Care Finance Administration, National Health Expenditure Table 2,Aggregate Amounts and Average Annual Percent Change by Type of Expenditure( Jan. 8, 2003), available at http://cms.hhs.gov/statistics/nhe/historical/t2.asp.

28 Kaiser Family Found., Prescription Drug Trends (2003), available at http://www.kff.org/content/2003/3057-03/3057-03.pdf.; see also Reinhardt, supra note 3, at 136;Michael Doonan, The Economics of Prescription Drug Pricing, Before the Council onthe Economic Impact of Health System Change (Mar. 2001), available at http://sihp.brandeis.edu/council/pubs/DoonanRxPricing.pdf; Robert W. Dubois et al., ExplainingDrug Spending Trends: Does Perception Match Reality? 19 Health Affairs 231 (2000).

29 See, e.g., FTC Testimony, An Overview of Federal Trade Commission Antitrust Activities,Remarks Before the U.S. House Committee on the Judiciary Antitrust Task Force ( July24, 2003) (“The growing cost of prescription drugs is a significant concern. . . Drugexpenditures doubled between 1995 and 2000. In response, the FTC has increased itspharmaceutical-related investigations.”), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/07/antitrustoversighttest.htm; FTC Testimony, Competition in the Pharmaceutical Marketplace:Antitrust Implications of Patent Settlements, Before the U.S. Senate Committee on theJudiciary (May 24, 2001) (“The surging cost of prescription drugs is a pressing nationalissue. Recent reports suggest expenditures for retail outpatient prescription drugs rose. . . 18.8% . . . from the previous year. This dramatic increase has helped focus attentionon the need to ensure competition in pharmaceutical markets.”), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2001/05/pharmtstmy.htm.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 9: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 641

ing, accounting for $67 billion in sales, with the eight largest accountingfor approximately 50 percent and the top 20 firms accounting for approx-imately 70 percent of total revenues.30 The largest firm, Pfizer has onlyabout an 11 percent share of U.S. drug sales, followed by GlaxoSmith-Kline with about a 7 percent share, and AstraZeneca, Johnson & Johnson,and Merck, rounding out the top five with about a 5 percent share each.Smaller competitors include Abbott, Aventis, Bristol-Myers Squibb, EliLilly, Novartis, Roche, Schering-Plough, and Wyeth, with about a 2–4percent share each.31 Concentration is of course higher in more narrowlydefined segments of the industry.

Generic drugs—which are bioequivalent to their brand counterparts—are also an important part of the competitive landscape. When a firmintroduces a generic drug, it typically does so at a substantial discountto the pioneer drug.32 The Supreme Court has explained, “[g]enericdrugs, also called ‘copycat’ or ‘me-too’ drugs, are usually marketed atrelatively low prices because their manufacturers do not incur theresearch, development, and promotional costs normally associated withthe creation and marketing of an original product.”33 Some studies havesuggested that drug prices may fall even further with the introductionof additional generics.34 Data also demonstrate that, increasingly, salesshift very rapidly to generic entrants.35 PBM policies often stronglyencourage use of generic drugs, particularly through use of lower co-payments required from consumers and higher dispensing fees paid topharmacists. The trend also appears to be attributable at least in part tostate generic substitution laws, which permit, and in some states require,pharmacists to dispense bioequivalent generic drugs (unless specifically

30 U.S. Dep’t of Commerce, Concentration Ratios in Manufacturing ( June 2001),available at http://www.census.gov/prod/ec97/m31s-cr.pdf (NACIS Code 325412 compris-ing establishments primarily engaged in manufacturing in-vivo diagnostic substances andpharmaceutical preparations except biologicals).

31 See IMS Health, IMS Drug Monitor (2002), available at http://www.ims-global.com/insight/insight.htm.

32 See Federal Trade Comm’n, Generic Drug Entry Prior to Patent Expiration 9( July 2002), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/07/genericdrugstudy.pdf; Congres-sional Budget Office, supra note 17, at 27–32 (1998).

33 United States v. Generix Drug Corp., 460 U.S. 453, 455 n.1 (1983).34 See David Reiffen & Michael R. Ward, Generic Drug Industry Dynamics, Bureau

of Economics Working Paper No. 248 (Feb. 2002), available at http://www.ftc.gov/be/workpapers/industrydynamicsreiffenwp.pdf; Richard E. Caves et al., Patent Expiration, Entry,and Competition in the U.S. Pharmaceutical Industry, in Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity: Microeconomics 1991, at 1 (1991).

35 See Grabowski & Vernon, supra note 15; Levy, supra note 23, at 13–14; CongressionalBudget Office, supra note 17, at 27–31; Henry Grabowski & John Vernon, Longer Patentsfor Increased Generic Competition: The Waxman-Hatch Act After One Decade, 10 PharmacoEcon.Supp. 2, at 110 (1996).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 10: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal642

overridden by a doctor’s order).36 It is also now well documented thatpioneer manufacturers often curtail detailing and raise the price of thepioneer drug in response to generic entry.37 The net effect may be areduction in the average price of off-patent drugs, but with reducedmarketing, a decline in total output rather than an increase in output,as one would normally expect with a price decrease.

III. FTC PHARMACEUTICAL MARKETDEFINITION ANALYSIS

The FTC’s approach to product market definition in its pharmaceuti-cal cases is not transparent. While the Commission has challenged atleast twenty mergers involving pharmaceuticals since 1990, includingthree in the last two years, each one was resolved through a consentorder38 or abandonment of the transaction before the Commission filedsuit.39 The Commission complaints accompanying consent orders inthese matters are not very detailed; they generally allege relevant productmarkets in a conclusory manner with little support. Further discussionof market definition in these complaints would help the public to under-stand the Commission’s analysis.

36 See National Institute for Health Care Management, A Primer: Generic Drugs,Patents and the Pharmaceutical Marketplace (2002), available at http://www.nihcm.org/GenericsPrimer.pdf.

37 See Levy, supra note 23, at 18–19; Congressional Budget Office, supra note 17, at29–31; Richard G. Frank & David S. Salkever, Generic Entry and the Pricing of Pharma-ceuticals, 6 J. Econ. & Mgmt. Strategy 75 (1997); see also Inwood Labs., Inc. v. Ives Labs.,Inc., 456 U.S. 844, 847 (1982) (“normal industry practice” for pioneer manufacturerto direct marketing efforts to convince physicians that product is superior, until genericentry).

38 See Pfizer Inc. & Pharmacia Corp., FTC Docket No. C-4075 (May 27, 2003); BaxterInt’l, Inc. & Wyeth, FTC Docket No. C-4068 (Feb. 3, 2003); Amgen Inc. & Immunex Corp.,FTC Docket No. C-4956, (Sep. 3, 2002); Glaxo Wellcome plc & SmithKline Beecham plc,FTC Docket No. C-3990 ( Jan. 26, 2001); Pfizer Inc. and Warner-Lambert Co., FTC DocketNo. C-3957 ( Jul. 27, 2000); Hoechst AG, FTC Docket No. C-3919 ( Jan. 18, 2000); ZenecaGroup plc, 127 F.T.C. 874 (1999); Merck & Co., Inc., 127 F.T.C. 156 (1999); RocheHolding Ltd., 125 F.T.C. 919 (1998); Am. Home Prods. Corp., 123 F.T.C. 1279 (1997);Ciba-Geigy, Ltd., 123 F.T.C. 842 (1997); Baxter Int’l, Inc., 123 F.T.C. 904 (1997); Upjohn,Co., 121 F.T.C. 44 (1996); Hoechst AG, 120 F.T.C. 1010 (1995); Eli Lilly & Co., 120 F.T.C.243 (1995); Glaxo plc, 119 F.T.C. 815 (1995); IVAX Corp., 119 F.T.C. 357 (1995); Am.Home Prods. Corp., 119 F.T.C. 217 (1995); Roche Holding Ltd., 118 F.T.C. 1140 (1994);Dow Chem. Co., 118 F.T.C. 730 (1994); Roche Holding Ltd., 113 F.T.C. 1086 (1990);Institut Merieux S.A., 113 F.T.C. 742 (1990).

39 Cytyc Corporation’s proposed acquisition of Digene Corporation was abandoned inJune 2002 after the FTC authorized its staff to file suit. See FTC Press Release, FTC Seeksto Block Cytyc Corp.’s Acquisition of Digene Corp. ( Jun. 24, 2002), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2002/06/cytyc digene.htm. In addition, a proposed acquisition byAbbott Laboratories of ALZA Corporation was abandoned in 2000 after the parties andthe staff could not agree on the terms of a consent decree. See Richard Parker & David

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 11: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 643

The FTC is required to allow public comment on proposed consentorders by publishing an explanation in the Federal Register,40 and someadditional understanding of agency thinking may be discerned fromreview of those “analyses to aid public comment” and from agency pressreleases. Unlike European Commission merger decisions following sec-ond phase investigations,41 however, such statements do not address evensignificant overlaps between the merging firms that the agency decidednot to challenge. Moreover, unlike EU decisions, such statements donot specifically address arguments presented to the agency by the merg-ing firms or other interested parties. The analyses to aid public commentdo not even constitute “official interpretations” and press releases areissued by the staff, under the direction of the FTC Chairman but generallywithout review by other Commissioners.42

A review of recent FTC enforcement actions in the pharmaceuticalindustry provides a flavor of the range of market definitions alleged bythe FTC. The various cases define markets based upon:

(1) whether drugs treat the same disease, condition, or indication;

(2) whether drugs treat a disease by interacting with the body inthe same manner (i.e., whether they have the same “mechanismof action”);

(3) whether drugs have the same specific chemical compounds;

Balto, The Evolving Approach to Merger Remedies, Antitrust Rep., May 2000, at 2, availableat http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/other/remedies.htm.

40 16 C.F.R. § 2.34(c) provides: “Promptly after the acceptance of the consent agreement,the Commission will place the order contained in the consent agreement, the complaint,and the consent agreement on the public record for a period of 30 days, or such otherperiod as the Commission may specify, for the receipt of comments or views from anyinterested person. At the same time, the Commission will place on the public record anexplanation of the provisions of the order and the relief to be obtained thereby and anyother information that it believes may help interested persons understand the order. TheCommission also will publish the explanation in the Federal Register.”

41 The European Commission issues detailed decisions at the conclusion of each investiga-tion whether it blocks the transaction, accepts “undertakings” from parties, or approvesit without relief. See, e.g., Case No. Comp/M.2922, Pfizer/Pharmacia (Feb. 27, 2003)(focusing on “therapeutic indications” as the “operational market definition” and consider-ing whether drugs are “substitutes for the treatment of a specific illness or disease,” takinginto account mechanism of action, diagnosis profile, patient profiles, active ingredients,pathologies, and method of administration, considering marketed drugs and drugs at an“advanced stage of development”); see also Case No. Comp/M.1878, Pfizer/Warner-Lambert (May 22, 2000); Case No. Comp/M.1846, GlaxoWellcome/SmithKline Beecham(May 8, 2000); Case No. Comp/M.1403, Astra/Zeneca (Feb. 26, 1999); Case No. Comp/M.1378, Hoechst/Rhone-Poulenc (Aug. 9, 1999).

42 See FTC Operating Manual, ¶¶ 6.10.6 & Ill. 7, 6.13.1, 17.2.2, available at http://www.ftc.gov/foia/adminstaffmanuals.htm.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 12: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal644

(4) whether drugs have the same dosage form such as injectable,liquid, capsule, tablets, or topical;

(5) whether drugs have the same frequency of dosage, such as once-a-day or extended release;

(6) whether drugs have the same strength of dosage, distinguishing,for example, 30mg and 60mg tablets;

(7) whether drugs are branded or generic;

(8) whether drugs require a prescription or are sold over-the-counter; and

(9) whether drugs are currently marketed or are in development.

Product markets alleged in recent merger enforcement actions include(i) drugs for the treatment of a particular disease or condition, (ii) drugsthat have the same mechanism of action, and (iii) specific compounds.

The broadest markets alleged cover all drugs for a disease or condition.For instance, in its most recent challenge to a blockbuster merger, PfizerInc.’s $60 billion acquisition of Pharmacia Corporation, in May 2003,the FTC alleged a market of “research and development, and the manu-facture and sale of prescription drugs for the treatment of ED” or erectiledysfunction. Pfizer’s Viagra was alleged to have a 95 percent share in thatmarket while Pharmacia had two drugs in early clinical development.43

Addressing Pfizer’s earlier $90 billion merger with Warner-Lambert in2000, the agency similarly alleged a market of “research, development,manufacture and sale of drugs for the treatment of Alzheimer’s disease.”There Pfizer was alleged to have a 98 percent market share while Warner-Lambert accounted for the rest of the market and a third firm had justlaunched a new product.44

In challenging Glaxo Wellcome plc’s $182 billion merger with Smith-Kline Beecham plc, the FTC also defined certain markets by indication,

43 Pfizer Inc. & Pharmacia Corp., FTC Docket No. C-4075 (May 27, 2003) (Complaint¶¶ 6, 20(c), 24), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/04/pfizercmp.htm; FTC PressRelease, Pfizer, Pharmacia Will Divest Assets to Settle FTC Charges (Apr. 14, 2003), availableat http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2003/04/pfizer.htm; Pfizer Inc. & Pharmacia Corp., FTCDocket No. C-4075 (Apr. 14, 2003) (Analysis of Proposed Consent Order to Aid PublicComment), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/04/pfizeranalysis.htm.

44 Pfizer Inc. & Warner-Lambert Co., FTC Docket No. C-3957 ( Jul. 27, 2000) (Complaint¶¶ 19(c), 23), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/06/pfizercmp.htm; FTC PressRelease, FTC Order Clears Way for $90 Billion Merger of Pfizer Inc. and Warner-LambertCompany ( June 19, 2000), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2000/06/pfizer.htm; PfizerInc. and Warner-Lambert Co., FTC Docket No. C-3957 ( June 19, 2000) (Analysis ofProposed Consent Order to Aid Public Comment), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/06/pfizeranalaysis.htm.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 13: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 645

alleging markets of “drugs for the treatment of irritable bowel syndrome”and “prophylactic herpes vaccines.”45 In each of these cases, the mergingparties were two of few firms marketing any drugs in the broad category,or one was marketing and the other was developing such a drug. Thatmay explain in part why one would expect substitution between drugsthat are based on different chemicals and different mechanisms of actionwith unique effectiveness and side effect profiles, in response to modestprice increases, in these cases but not others. But the agency’s rationaleis not clearly articulated.

Other alleged markets focus on mechanism of action or class of drug.In September 2002, for instance, addressing concerns raised by AmgenInc.’s $16 billion acquisition of Immunex Corporation, the Commissionalleged anticompetitive effects in three markets defined by mechanismof action. The agency alleged two separate markets (TNF inhibitors andIL-1 inhibitors) of drugs which block cytokines that trigger inflammation,for the treatment of rheumatoid arthritis and other autoimmune dis-eases. At the same time, the agency included distinct neutrophil regenera-tion or colony stimulating factors that stimulate different white bloodcells used to treat cancer patients with a low white blood cell count, inthe same market, without explanation.46

In challenging the Glaxo-SmithKline merger, the FTC also definedcertain markets by mechanism of action. There, the FTC alleged marketsof (1) “prescription pharmaceuticals of the topoisomerase 1 inhibitorclass . . . for the treatment of cancer,” (2) “drugs of the triptan chemicalclass . . . for the treatment of migraine headaches,” and (3) “any 5HT-3receptor antagonist prescription pharmaceutical compound indicatedfor the prevention and treatment of nausea and vomiting associated withmedical treatment.” 47

45 Glaxo Wellcome plc & SmithKline Beecham plc, FTC Docket No. C-3990 ( Jan. 26,2001) (Complaint ¶¶ 5,6), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/12/glaxosmithklinecmp.pdf; FTC Press Release, Resolving Competitive Concerns, FTC Agreement Clears$182 Billion Merger of SmithKline Beecham and Glaxo Wellcome (Dec. 18, 2000), availableat http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2000/12/skb.htm; Glaxo Wellcome plc & SmithKline Beechamplc, FTC Docket No. C-3990 (Dec. 18, 2000) (Analysis of Proposed Consent Order to AidPublic Comment), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/12/glaxoana.htm.

46 Amgen Inc. & Immunex Corp., FTC Docket No. C-4053 (Sept. 3, 2002) (Complaint¶¶ 7, 17, 19–21), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/07/amgencomplaint.pdf; FTCPress Release, Resolving Anticompetitive Concerns, FTC Clears $16 Billion Acquisition ofImmunex Corp. by Amgen Inc. ( July 12, 2002), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2002/07/amgen.htm; Amgen Inc. and Immunex Corp., FTC Docket No. C-4053 ( July 12, 2002)(Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Order to Aid Public Comment), available athttp://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/07/amgenanalysis.htm.

47 Glaxo Wellcome plc & SmithKline Beecham plc, FTC Docket No. C-3990 ( Jan. 26,2001) (Complaint ¶¶ 16 (a), (g), (i)), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/12/glaxo

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 14: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal646

In another recent action, in February 2003, the FTC focused primarilyon specific chemical compounds in addressing Baxter InternationalInc.’s acquisition of Wyeth Corporation’s generic injectable drug busi-ness. The Commission alleged that the acquisition would reduce competi-tion in five distinct markets. One market was defined as the manufactureand sale of Propofol, a specific general anesthetic commonly used duringsurgery and as a sedative for patients on mechanical ventilators. Theagency’s analysis to aid public comment emphasized the product’sunique characteristics and uses, compared to other anesthetics, notingits “many benefits” including “the ability to quickly adjust the amountof sedation and its superior safety profile,” and the fact that it is “thepreferred anesthetic agent for out-patient surgery.” Three other markets,for two specific neuromuscular block agents used to freeze musclesduring surgery and for patients mechanically ventilated, and a specificantiemetic used to prevent and treat nausea and vomiting in patientsundergoing certain types of chemotherapy and for post-operative treat-ment, were similarly defined to include branded and generic equivalentsof specific chemical compounds.48 In challenging the Glaxo/SmithKlinemerger, the FTC also defined one market narrowly as drugs that contain“ceftazidime . . . a semisynthetic, broad-spectrum antibacterial derivedfrom cephaloridine.”49 In none of these cases is there any discussion of

smithklinecmp.pdf; FTC Press Release, Resolving Competitive Concerns, FTC AgreementClears $182 Billion Merger of SmithKline Beecham and Glaxo Wellcome (Dec. 18, 2000),available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2000/12/skb.htm; Glaxo Wellcome plc & SmithKlineBeecham plc, FTC Docket No. C-3990 (Dec. 18, 2000) (Analysis of Proposed ConsentOrder to Aid Public Comment), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/12/glaxoana.htm.See also Pfizer Inc. & Warner-Lambert Co., FTC Docket No. C-3957 ( Jul. 27, 2000) (seroto-nin reuptake inhibitors (SRIs) and selective norepinephrine reuptake inhibitors (SNRIs)for the treatment of depression; Epidermal Growth Factor receptor tyrosine kinase(EGFr-tk) inhibitors for the treatment of solid cancerous tumors).

48 Baxter Int’l, Inc. & Wyeth, FTC Docket No. C-4068 (Feb. 3, 2003) (Complaint ¶¶ 14,16–20), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/12/baxter wyethcomplaint.pdf; FTCPress Release, FTC Requires Divestitures in Connection with Baxter’s Purchase of Wyeth’sGeneric Injectable Drug Business (Dec. 20, 2002), available at www.ftc.gov/opa/2002/12/baxter wyeth.htm; Baxter Int’l, Inc. & Wyeth, FTC Docket No. C-4068 (Dec. 20, 2002)(Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Orders to Aid Public Comment), available athttp://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/12/baxter wyethanalysis.htm. The fifth market, on the otherhand, was defined more broadly as “new injectable iron replacement therapies” to treatiron deficiency in patients undergoing hemodialysis. That market included both injectableiron gluconate and injectable iron sucrose, with no discussion of substitutability to explainwhy more than a single drug was included in the market.

49 Glaxo Wellcome plc & SmithKline Beecham plc, FTC Docket No. C-3990 ( Jan. 26,2001), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/12/glaxosmithklinecmp.pdf; FTC PressRelease, Resolving Competitive Concerns, FTC Agreement Clears $182 Billion Merger ofSmithKline Beecham and Glaxo Wellcome (Dec. 18, 2000), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2000/12/skb.htm; Glaxo Wellcome plc & SmithKline Beecham plc, FTC Docket No.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 15: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 647

substitution to explain why the market is not defined more broadly bymechanism of action or indication.

The FTC has also used dosage form and dosage frequency to narrowthe relevant market. For instance, in challenging Pfizer’s acquisition ofPharmacia, the FTC alleged one market limited to “extended releasedrugs for the treatment of overactive bladder.” The agency explainedin its analysis that extended release products, dosed at once or twice-a-day, “offer a more convenient dosing schedule and fewer side effects”than generic products that must be taken three times a day, but did nottie such convenience to the possibility of substitution.50 The marketsalleged in challenging the Glaxo/SmithKline merger similarly included“second generation oral and intravenous antiviral drugs for the treatmentof herpes” and “prescription topical herpes antiviral medications indi-cated for the treatment of . . . oral herpes.” Such markets were justifiedbased on the drugs’ “greater bioavailability, superior efficacy, andrequirements for less frequent dosing” over the first-generation drug.51

In one recent nonmerger case, also settled before the complaint issued,the FTC even divided a market by dosage strength, alleging separatemarkets for 30mg and 60mg tablets of a drug. In August 2002, theCommission issued a complaint against Biovail Corporation and ElanCorporation challenging a distribution agreement, which the agencysaid provided incentives for the firms not to introduce competing genericdrugs. The Commission alleged that the two firms had market power inU.S. markets for 30mg and 60mg dosages of a generic anti-hypertensiondrug, excluding the bio-equivalent brand-name drug, Adalat CC. Thereis no discussion at all of substitution between the 30mg and 60mg dosages(or generic and branded Adalat CC), though the agency did assert that

C-3990 (Dec. 18, 2000) (Analysis of Proposed Consent Order to Aid Public Comment),available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/12/glaxoana.htm.

50 Pfizer Inc. & Pharmacia Corp., FTC Docket No. C-4075 (May 27, 2003) (Complaint¶¶ 7, 13, 20(a), 22), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/04/pfizercmp.htm; FTC PressRelease, Pfizer, Pharmacia Will Divest Assets to Settle FTC Charges (Apr. 14, 2003), availableat http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2003/04/pfizer.htm; Pfizer Inc. & Pharmacia Corp., FTCDocket No. C-4075 (Apr. 14, 2003) (Analysis of Proposed Consent Order to Aid PublicComment), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/04/pfizeranalysis.htm.

51 Glaxo Wellcome plc & SmithKline Beecham plc, FTC Docket No. C-3990 ( Jan. 26,2001) (Complaint ¶¶ 5, 11, 16(b), (c), 19, 21), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/12/glaxosmithklinecmp.pdf; FTC Press Release, Resolving Competitive Concerns, FTCAgreement Clears $182 Billion Merger of SmithKline Beecham and Glaxo Wellcome (Dec.18, 2000), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2000/12/skb.htm; Glaxo Wellcome plc &SmithKline Beecham plc, FTC Docket No. C-3990 (Dec. 18, 2000) (Analysis of ProposedConsent Order to Aid Public Comment), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/12/glaxoana.htm; see also Zeneca Group plc, FTC Docket No. C-3880 ( June 7, 1999) (long-acting local anesthetics).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 16: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal648

“[e]ntry of a second generic product at each dosage level would likelycause a significant reduction in the price of, and hence the profits from,that dosage.”52

Most of the actions discussed above either explicitly or implicitlyfocus on prescription pharmaceuticals. The FTC has also specificallyalleged over-the-counter markets, including hydrocortisone creams andointments, motion sickness medications, and cough drops in the Pfizer-Pharmacia merger challenge53 and histamine 2 blockers for acid reliefin the Glaxo-SmithKline merger challenge.54

Another issue that has affected market definition is availability ofgeneric forms of a drug. The Propofol market alleged in the Baxter-Wyeth matter explicitly included both the pioneer drug (manufacturedby a company not involved in the transaction) and generics in the samemarket in challenging a merger between generic actual or potentialcompetitors.55 That case and others have also challenged mergers com-bining branded and generic drugs.56

52 Biovail Corp. & Elan Corp., FTC Docket No. C-4057 (Aug. 15, 2002) (Complaint ¶¶ 6,11, 16, 1), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/08/biovalcmp.pdf; FTC Press Release,Consent Order Resolves Charges that Biovail and Elan Agreement UnreasonablyRestrained Competition in Market for Generic Anti-Hypertension Drug ( June 27, 2002),available at www.ftc.gov/opa/2002/06/biovailelan.htm; Biovail Corp. & Elan Corp., PLC,FTC Docket No. C-4057 ( June 27, 2002) (Analysis to Aid Public Comment), available athttp://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/06/biovailelananalysis.pdf.

53 Pfizer Inc. & Pharmacia Corp., FTC Docket No. C-4075 (May 27, 2003) (Complaint¶¶ 20(g)(h)(i), 28, 29, 30), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/04/pfizercmp.htm;FTC Press Release, Pfizer, Pharmacia Will Divest Assets to Settle FTC Charges (Apr. 14,2003), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2003/04/pfizer.htm; Pfizer Inc. & PharmaciaCorp., FTC Docket No. C-4075 (Apr. 14, 2003) (Analysis of Proposed Consent Order toAid Public Comment), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/04/pfizeranalysis.htm.

54 Glaxo Wellcome plc & SmithKline Beecham plc, FTC Docket No. C-3990 ( Jan. 26,2001) (Complaint ¶¶ 9, 16(f), 23), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/12/glaxosmithklinecmp.pdf; FTC Press Release, Resolving Competitive Concerns, FTC Agreement Clears$182 Billion Merger of SmithKline Beecham and Glaxo Wellcome (Dec. 18, 2000), availableat http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2000/12/skb.htm; Glaxo Wellcome plc & SmithKline Beechamplc, FTC Docket No. C-3990 (Dec. 18, 2000) (Analysis of Proposed Consent Order to AidPublic Comment), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/12/glaxoana.htm.

55 Baxter Int’l, Inc. & Wyeth, FTC Docket No. C-4068 (Feb. 3, 2003) (Complaint ¶¶ 14,19), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/12/baxter wyethcomplaint.pdf; FTC PressRelease, FTC Requires Divestitures in Connection with Baxter’s Purchase of Wyeth’sGeneric Injectable Drug Business (Dec. 20, 2002), available at www.ftc.gov/opa/2002/12/baxter wyeth.htm; Baxter Int’l, Inc. & Wyeth, FTC Docket No. C-4068 (Dec. 20, 2002)(Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Orders to Aid Public Comment), available athttp://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/12/baxter wyethanalysis.htm.

56 Baxter Int’l, Inc. & Wyeth, FTC Docket No. C-4068 (Feb. 3, 2003) (Complaint ¶¶ 14,18) (Metoclopramide), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/12/baxter wyethcomplaint.pdf; FTC Press Release, FTC Requires Divestitures in Connection with Baxter’sPurchase of Wyeth’s Generic Injectable Drug Business (Dec. 20, 2002), available atwww.ftc.gov/opa/2002/12/baxter wyeth.htm; Baxter Int’l, Inc. & Wyeth, FTC Docket No.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 17: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 649

On the other hand, in at least one merger57 and two nonmerger58

cases, the agency has defined generic-only markets. In one early case,in a concurring statement, one Commissioner suggested that while itmay seem obvious that two bio-equivalent drugs must be in the samerelevant product market, “branded drugs and their generic counterpartstypically vary dramatically in price, suggesting that consumers may notview the products as equivalent or interchangeable.” She suggested that“[t]his price differential may be greatest where there is intense pricecompetition among different generic versions of a drug.”59 Most recently,in challenging Pfizer’s acquisition of Pharmacia, the agency includedprivate-label products in certain markets and noted that genericsaccounted for “a significant share of the market,” but at the same timethe FTC alleged the generics had “limited competitive significance andvirtually no impact on the pricing,” or “do not constrain the pricing ofthe branded products.”60 These statements suggest confusion in theagency’s approach to market definition because if substitution to analternative product does not constrain price, the alternative is generallyexcluded from the market.

A review of nonmerger matters is also instructive to understand FTCthinking. In October 2002, the Commission issued a final order inanother matter involving Biovail (in this case as a pioneer manufacturer),involving an alleged wrongful listing of a patent in the FDA “OrangeBook.” There the Commission alleged a market for Tiazac, a diltiazem-based prescription drug taken once a day to treat high blood pressure

C-4068 (Dec. 20, 2002) (Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Orders to Aid PublicComment), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/12/baxter wyethanalysis.htm;Hoechst AG, 120 F.T.C. 1010 (1995) (branded and generic rifampin); Dow Chem. Co.,118 F.T.C. 730 (1994) (branded and generic dicyclomine).

57 IVAX Corp., 119 F.T.C. 357 (1995) (generic verapamil market).58 Biovail Corp. & Elan Corp., FTC Docket No. C-4057 (Aug. 15, 2002) (Complaint ¶ 6)

(alleging separate markets for 30mg and 60mg dosage forms of generic Adalat), availableat http://www3.ftc.gov/os/2002/08/biovalcmp.pdf; FTC v. Mylan Labs., Inc., FTC DocketNo. 1:98CV03114 (Dec. 21, 1998) (alleging separate markets of generic lorazepam tab-lets and generic clorazepate tablets), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/1998/12/mylancmp.htm.

59 In Dow Chem. Co & Marion Merrell Dow Inc., File No. 941-0019, 1994 FTC Lexis 86at *7 (FTC May 24, 1994) (proposed consent) (Owen, Cmm’r, concurring) (“In general,where the price differential between the branded product and the generic product isgreat, the products are more likely to be in separate markets. Conversely, where the pricegap between the branded product and the generic product is relatively small (for example,where there is only one generic version available to consumers), the products are morelikely to be in the same market.”).

60 Pfizer Inc. & Pharmacia Corp., FTC Docket No. C-4075 (May 27, 2003) (Complaint¶¶ 20(g)(h)(i), 28, 29, 30), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/04/pfizercmp.htm;FTC Press Release, Pfizer, Pharmacia Will Divest Assets to Settle FTC Charges (Apr.14, 2003), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2003/04/pfizer.htm; Analysis of Proposed

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 18: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal650

(hypertension) and chronic chest pain (angina), including generic bio-equivalent versions of Tiazac. The Commission explained that othertherapeutic agents could be used to treat hypertension and angina,including other branded and generic formulations of once-a-day diltia-zem, but asserted those drugs “do not significantly constrain Tiazac’spricing.” In contrast, the Commission alleged entry of a generic versionof Tiazac “likely would result in a significant, immediate decrease in thesales of branded Tiazac and lead to a significant reduction in the averagemarket price paid for Tiazac and its generic bioequivalents.” Thus Biovailwas alleged to have a 100 percent market share and monopoly powerin the relevant market.61

The FTC challenges to agreements among firms involved in patentlitigation have garnered perhaps the most attention.62 In each of thesecases, the product market definition alleged is similar, limited to thepioneer drug and its generic equivalents. In Abbott/Geneva, the FTCalleged a market of terazosin hydrochloride, used principally to treatbenign prostatic hyperplasia or enlarged prostate, bioequivalent toAbbott’s Hytrin. The FTC complaint there alleged that “[o]ther drugsare not effective substitutes . . . because they are different in terms ofchemical composition, safety, efficacy, and side effects” and “[i]n addi-tion, there is little price sensitivity between terazosin HCL and non-terazosin HCL products.”63 In Hoechst/Andrx, the Commission alleged amarket of once-a-day time-release diltiazem in capsule form, designed tobe taken once every twenty-four hours. The Commission noted diltiazembelongs to a group of drugs known as calcium channel blockers, usedprincipally to treat hypertension and to decrease the occurrence ofangina. The agency complaint alleged that “[o]ther calcium channelblockers are not acceptable substitutes” for several reasons, includingdifferences in efficacy and side effects and risks associated with switching

Consent Order to Aid Public Comment, Pfizer Inc. & Pharmacia Corp., FTC Docket No.C-4075 (Apr. 14, 2003), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/04/pfizeranalysis.htm.

61 Biovail Corp., FTC Docket No. C-4060 (Oct. 2, 2002) (Complaint ¶¶ 18-20, 22), availableat http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/04/biovailcomplaint.htm; FTC Press Release, Wrongful“Orange Book” Listing Raises Red Flag with FTC; Leads to Consent Order with BiovailCorp. Concerning its Drug Tiazac (Apr. 23, 2002), available at www.ftc.gov/opa/2002/04/biovailtiazac.htm.

62 See generally M. Howard Morse, Settlement of Intellectual Property Disputes in the Pharmaceuti-cal and Medical Device Industries: Antitrust Rules, 10 Geo. Mason L. Rev. 359 (2002); David A.Balto, Pharmaceutical Patent Settlements: The Antitrust Risks, 55 Food & Drug L.J. 321 (2000).

63 Abbott Labs. & Geneva Pharm., Inc., FTC Docket Nos. C-3945, 3946 (May 22, 2000)(Complaint ¶ 12), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/05/c3945complaint.htm; seealso FTC Press Release, FTC Charges Drug Manufacturers with Stifling Competition inTwo Prescription Drug Markets (Mar. 16, 2000), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2000/03/hoechst.htm.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 19: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 651

patients from one calcium channel blocker to another.64 Notably, how-ever, there is no allegation that the loss of new patients to alternativechannel blockers (even if current patients were locked in) would rendera price increase unprofitable.65

In the one Commission litigated case, against Schering-Plough andUpsher-Smith (the one case challenging a permanent settlement oflitigation as opposed to an “interim” settlement), the Commission like-wise alleged a market of a single drug and bioequivalent generics. TheCommission alleged a market of 20 milliequivalent extended-releasepotassium chloride tablets and capsules, used to treat patients withdepleted potassium levels.66 The complaint asserted that such patientshave “no practical substitute for potassium chloride supplements” and“[f]or clinical reasons, among others, physicians and patients prefer 20milliequivalent extended-release potassium chloride tablets over otherforms and dosages of potassium chloride.” The complaint asserted fur-ther that “[t]he existence of other potassium chloride products has notsignificantly constrained Schering’s pricing of K-Dur 20.” According tothe complaint, Schering’s K-Dur 20 had 100 percent of the sales of 20milliequivalent extended-release potassium chloride tablets andcapsules.67

The Schering case is currently on appeal to the full Commission afterthe ALJ found, inter alia, that “Complaint Counsel failed to prove orproperly define the relevant product market.” The ALJ found that thethere are many “therapeutically equivalent” products, and concludedthat the relevant product market must be all oral potassium supplementsthat can be prescribed by a physician for a patient in need of a potassiumsupplement. The ALJ noted that advertisements urged doctors to substi-tute two 10 mEq pills for a 20 mEq pill and emphasized that the staff’s

64 Hoechst Marion Roussel, Inc. & Andrx Corp., FTC Docket No. 9293 (Mar. 16, 2000)(Complaint ¶ 12), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/03/hoechstandrxycomplaint.htm. See also FTC Press Release, FTC Charges Drug Manufacturers with Stifling Competitionin Two Prescription Drug Markets (Mar. 16, 2000), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2000/03/hoechst.htm.

65 Id.66 Schering-Plough Corp., Upsher-Smith Labs. & Am. Home Prods. Corp., FTC Docket

No. 9297 (Mar. 30, 2001) (Complaint ¶ 21), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2001/04/scheringpart3cmp.pdf. The Commission’s complaint also alleged a relevant market of “allpotassium chloride supplements approved by the FDA.” Id. The broader market, however,was dropped by the staff during the litigation. Schering-Plough Corp., Upsher-Smith Labs.& Am. Home Prods. Corp., FTC Docket No. 9297 ( June 27, 2002) (Initial Decision at87), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/07/scheringinitialdecisionp2.pdf.

67 Id. ¶¶ 21–27; FTC Press Release, FTC Charges Schering-Plough over Allegedly Anticom-petitive Agreements with Two Other Drug Manufacturers (Apr. 2, 2001), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2001/04/schering.htm.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 20: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal652

expert did not systematically study relative prices or rebates, in rejectingcomplaint counsel’s narrower proposed market.68

IV. PRODUCT MARKET IN LITIGATION

With little explanation of product market in most of the governmentcases resolved through consent agreement, one must look to litigationfor additional illumination. Case law teaches that (1) market definitionis critical to the outcome of antitrust litigation, (2) the burden of proofon market definition is on the government or private antitrust plaintiff,and (3) market definition is seldom resolved early in litigation, thoughjudicial standards do leave room for dismissing cases based on unsustaina-ble market definition allegations.

A. Market Definition Is Critical to the Outcomeof Antitrust Litigation

Market definition is often critical to the outcome of antitrust cases,whether brought under the Sherman Act, the Clayton Act, or the FederalTrade Commission Act.69 Unilateral conduct, including filing of baselesspatent infringement claims, does not raise antitrust concern unless thefirm engaging in the conduct is a monopolist or its conduct creates adangerous probability that it will become a monopolist. Similarly, mostforms of joint conduct, including agreements to settle litigation andmergers, pose no harm to competition in the absence of market power.In most cases, therefore, it is necessary to define a relevant market.

It has long been recognized that, other than for conduct that is illegalper se without inquiry into actual effect, “rule of reason” analysis underSection 1 of the Sherman Act generally requires a detailed examinationof a challenged agreement’s effect in a well-defined market. Withoutdefining the market, there is no meaningful context in which to assessa restraint’s competitive effects.70 If adverse effects are “obvious” and

68 Schering-Plough Corp., Upsher-Smith Labs. & Am. Home Prods. Corp., FTC DocketNo. 9297 (FTC June 27, 2002) (Initial Decision at 16, 19, 78–79, 87–95, 12), availableat http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/07/scheringinitialdecisionp1.pdf and http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/07/scheringinitialdecisionp2.pdf.

69 See, e.g., Robert Pitofsky, New Definitions of Relevant Market and the Assault on Antitrust,90 Colum. L. Rev. 1805, 1807 (1990) (“Knowledgeable antitrust practitioners have longknown that the most important single issue in most enforcement actions—because somuch depends on it—is market definition.”).

70 See, e.g., State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 10 (1997) (“[M]ost antitrust claims areanalyzed under a ‘rule of reason’. . . .”); Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp.,467 U.S. 752, 768 (1984) (rule of reason requires “an inquiry into market power andmarket structure designed to assess the combination’s actual effect”); Continental T.V.,

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 21: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 653

procompetitive effects are “implausible” or there is “proof of actualdetrimental effects, such as a reduction of output,” restraints may becondemned under a “quick look” analysis without defining the relevantmarket because market power is but “a surrogate for detrimental effect.”71

The Supreme Court has made clear, however, that an abbreviated analysisis appropriate only where “an observer with even a rudimentary under-standing of economics could conclude that the arrangements in questionhave an anticompetitive effect on customers and markets.”72

Proof of the relevant market is similarly an essential element of anyclaim for monopolization or attempted monopolization under Section 2of the Sherman Act. The Supreme Court has made clear that “[w]ithout

Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 45 (1977) (restraint must be examined “in lightof the competitive situation in ‘the product market as a whole’”); Tanaka v. Univ. of S.Cal., 252 F.3d 1059, 1063 (9th Cir. 2001) (“A restraint violates the rule of reason if therestraint’s harm to competition outweighs its procompetitive effects. The plaintiff bearsthe initial burden of showing that the restraint produces ‘significant anticompetitiveeffects’ within a ‘relevant market.’”); California Dental Ass’n v. FTC, 224 F.3d 942, 952(9th Cir. 2000) (‘ “Proving injury to competition in a rule of reason case almost uniformlyrequires a claimant to prove the relevant market and to show the effects of competitionwithin that market.’”); Polygram Holding, Inc., FTC Docket No. 9298, slip op. at 29 ( July24, 2003) (“In most cases, conduct cannot be adjudged illegal without an analysis of itsmarket context to determine whether those engaged in the conduct or restraint are likelyto have sufficient power to harm consumers.”), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/07/polygramopinion.pdf.

71 FTC v. Indiana Fed’n of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 458–61 (1986) (“‘[N]o elaborateindustry analysis is required’” to condemn direct restraint on output where evidence ofactual adverse effects on competition are clear.); NCAA v. Bd. of Regents, 468 U.S. 85,109–10 n.39 (1984) (“‘[N]o elaborate industry analysis is required to demonstrate theanticompetitive character of . . . an agreement’” where “‘the rule of reason can . . . beapplied in the twinkling of an eye.’” (quoting Phillip Areeda, The “Rule of Reason”in Antitrust Analysis: General Issues 37–38 (Federal Judicial Center, June 1981));Todd v. Exxon Corp., 275 F.3d 191, 206 (2d Cir. 2001) (“[A]n actual adverse effect oncompetition . . . arguably is more direct evidence of market power than calculations ofelusive market share figures.”).

72 California Dental Ass’n v. FTC, 526 U.S. 756, 770 (1999). See also Polygram Holding,Inc., slip op. at 29 (A “plaintiff may avoid . . . the pleading and proof of market power ifit demonstrates that the conduct at issue is inherently suspect owing to its likely tendencyto suppress competition” but such analysis is only appropriate for conduct where “pastjudicial experience and current economic learning have shown to warrant summary con-demnation.”), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/07/polygramopinion.pdf. At thesame time, California Dental teaches that there is “no categorical line to be drawn betweenrestraints that give rise to an intuitively obvious inference of anticompetitive effect andthose that call for more detailed treatment,” suggesting that a long, lingering look, shortof “the fullest market analysis,” might be sufficient in some cases and that not “every caseattacking a less obviously anticompetitive restraint . . . is a candidate for plenary marketexamination.” California Dental, 526 U.S. at 779–81. The FTC has also suggested that,depending on the circumstances and the degree to which courts have experience withsimilar restraints, a quick look “may or may not require evidence about the particularmarket at issue.” Polygram Holding, Inc., supra, at 32.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 22: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal654

a definition of [the] market there is no way to measure [a defendant’s]ability to lessen or destroy competition.”73

Proof of market definition is also essential to a plaintiff’s case underSection 7 of the Clayton Act, which prohibits mergers and acquisitionsthe effect of which may be substantially to lessen competition “in anyline of commerce . . . in any section of the country.” The SupremeCourt has explained that “[d]etermination of the relevant product andgeographic markets is a ‘necessary predicate’” to a Section 7 claim.74

Under the government’s Merger Guidelines, one must ask whether atransaction will significantly increase concentration in a relevant marketand create market power, allowing the combined firm, unilaterally orthrough coordinated action, to raise price above competitive levels.75

The Federal Trade Commission enforces the Sherman and ClaytonActs through the FTC Act’s prohibition on “unfair methods of competi-tion.” Although the reach of Section 5 of the FTC Act is generally viewedas coextensive with that of the Sherman and Clayton Acts, the SupremeCourt has held that the Commission may “define and proscribe an unfaircompetitive practice, even though the practice does not infringe eitherthe letter or the spirit of the antitrust laws.”76 Nonetheless, the Commis-

73 Walker Process Equip., Inc. v. Food Mach. and Chem. Corp., 382 U.S. 172, 177 (1965).See also Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 455–56, 459 (1993) (“[T]oestablish monopolization or attempt to monopolize under § 2 of the Sherman Act, it [is]necessary to appraise . . . the relevant market for the product involved.”); United Statesv. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570–71 (1966) (“The offense of monopoly under § 2 ofthe Sherman Act has two elements: (1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevantmarket and (2) the willful acquisition or maintenance of that power. . . .”); United Statesv. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 50, 81 (D.C. Cir.) (en banc) (“A court’s evaluation of anattempted monopolization claim must include a definition of the relevant market. Sucha definition establishes a context for evaluating the defendant’s actions as well as formeasuring whether the challenged conduct presented a dangerous probability of monopo-lization”); Intergraph Corp. v. Intel Corp., 195 F.3d 1346, 1355 (Fed. Cir. 1999) (relevantmarket is “an indispensable element of any monopolization . . . case”).

74 United States v. Marine Bancorp., 418 U.S. 602, 618 (1974) (quoting United Statesv. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 353 U.S. 586, 593 (1957)); Brown Shoe Co. v. UnitedStates, 370 U.S. 294, 324 (1962) (same). See also FTC v. H.J. Heinz Co., 246 F.3d 708, 715(D.C. Cir. 2001) (“First the government must show that the merger would produce ‘afirm controlling an undue percentage share of the relevant market, and [would] result[]in a significant increase in the concentration of firms in that market.’”); United States v.Engelhard Corp., 126 F.3d 1302, 1305 (11th Cir. 1997) (“[E]stablishing the relevantproduct market is an essential element in the Government’s case.”).

75 U.S. Dep’t of Justice & Federal Trade Comm’n, Horizontal Merger Guidelines § 1.0(1992) (“[T]he likely competitive impact of a merger [must be evaluated] within thecontext of economically meaningful markets; i.e., markets that could be subject to theexercise of market power”), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,104 [hereinafterHorizontal Merger Guidelines].

76 FTC v. Sperry & Hutchinson Co., 405 U.S. 233, 239–40 (1972). See also FTC v. BrownShoe Co., 384 U.S. 316, 319, 321–22 (1966) (The FTC has “broad power . . . [that] is

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 23: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 655

sion’s efforts to extend the FTC Act into areas beyond the limits ofthe Sherman and Clayton Acts have often been struck down,77 and theCommission has held that “[w]hile Section 5 may empower [it] to pursuethose activities which offend the ‘basic policies’ of the antitrust laws, wedo not believe that power should be used to reshape those policieswhen they have been clearly expressed and circumscribed.”78 Thus, theCommission generally relies upon Sherman Act and Clayton Act marketdefinition principles in condemning particular practices.79

Importantly, standards for determining relevant market are the sameunder the various antitrust statutes, and courts routinely rely on casesdecided under one statute when deciding cases under the other statutes.The Supreme Court has in fact explicitly held that there is “no reasonto differentiate between ‘line’ of commerce in the context of the ClaytonAct and ‘part’ of commerce for purposes of the Sherman Act.”80 And

particularly well established with regard to trade practices which conflict with the basicpolicies of the Sherman and Clayton Acts even though such practices may not actuallyviolate these laws.”); FTC v. Motion Picture Adver. Serv. Co., 344 U.S. 392, 394–95 (1953)(“[T]he Federal Trade Commission Act was designed to supplement and bolster theSherman Act and the Clayton Act—to stop in their incipiency acts and practices which,when full blown, would violate those Acts, as well as to condemn as ‘unfair methods ofcompetition’ existing violations of them.” (citations omitted)).

77 See, e.g., Boise Cascade Corp. v. FTC, 637 F.2d 573 (9th Cir. 1980); Official AirlineGuides, Inc. v. FTC, 630 F.2d 920 (2d Cir. 1980); E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co. v. FTC,729 F.2d 128 (2d Cir. 1984).

78 Gen. Foods Corp., 103 F.T.C. 204, 365 (1984).79 But see Dell Computer Corp., 121 F.T.C. 616 (1996) (alleging violation of FTC Act

based on unilateral conduct in failing to disclose patents to standard-setting organizationwithout alleging attempted or actual monopolization); Rambus Inc., FTC Docket No. 9302( June 18, 2002) (Complaint ¶¶ 122–24) (alleging failure to disclose patent applicationsduring standard setting unreasonably restrained trade in violation of the FTC Act inaddition to alleging monopolization and attempted monopolization in violation of theAct), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/06/rambuscmp.htm.

80 United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 573 (1966). See also Apani Southwest,Inc. v. Coca-Cola Enters., 300 F.3d 620, 627 (5th Cir. 2002) (“The same test applied fordetermining the relevant product and geographic markets for Clayton Act claims is alsoused for alleged violations of the Sherman Act.”); Image Technical Servs., Inc. v. EastmanKodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195, 1204 n.3 (9th Cir. 1997) (noting that “[t]he Supreme Courthas held that its precedent relating to the ‘line of commerce’ under § 7 of the ClaytonAct applies to market definition under the ‘part of commerce’ language in the ShermanAct”); Hornsby Oil Co. v. Champion Spark Plug Co., 714 F.2d 1384, 1393 n.9 (5th Cir.1983) (“Basic principles governing definition of the relevant product and geographicmarkets in section 2 cases may be applied in actions arising under section 1 of the ShermanAct, and section 7 of the Clayton Act.”); Borden, Inc. v. FTC, 674 F.2d 498, 509–10 (6thCir. 1982); Photovest Corp. v. Fotomat Corp., 606 F.2d 704, 712 (7th Cir. 1979) (“Therelevant factors for defining the market in a § 2 Sherman Act case are similar to thoseused to define the market in a § 7 Clayton Act case.”); United States v. Engelhard Corp.,970 F. Supp. 1463 (M.D. Ga. 1997) (“The standards applied in Sherman Act cases fordefining the relevant product market are the same as in cases involving Section 7 of theClayton Act.”), aff’d, 126 F.3d 1302 (11th Cir. 1997); United States v. Syufy Enters., 712

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 24: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal656

the FTC relied on the Merger Guidelines in defininig the market in itsmost recent monopolization decision.81

B. The Government and Private Antitrust PlaintiffsBear the Burden of Proof on Market Definition

The burden of establishing the relevant market falls on the govern-ment or private plaintiff in federal court and on the FTC staff supportingan administrative complaint, known as “complaint counsel.”82 Asexplained in one recent case, “any gap in the evidence is a flaw inplaintiff’s case—not defendants’.”83

C. Courts Seldom Resolve Market Definition Early inLitigation, Though May Dismiss Baseless Cases

Despite the critical importance of product market to antitrust cases,it is the rare case in which market definition issues are resolved early inthe litigation.

Because relevant market determinations are fact-intensive, and courtsmust accept the allegations in the complaint as true and construe themin the light most favorable to the plaintiff on motions to dismiss, courtsare often reluctant to grant such motions directed to the way the marketis defined, at least where the plaintiff has alleged a market.84

F. Supp. 1386, 1396 (N.D. Cal. 1989) (“The relevant market is generally the same forcases brought under either Section 2 of the Sherman Act or Section 7 of the ClaytonAct.”), aff’d 903 F.2d 659 (9th Cir. 1990); U.S. Dep’t of Justice & Federal Trade Comm’n,Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors § 3.32(a) (2000) (“[F]orgoods markets affected by a competitor collaboration, the Agencies approach relevantmarket definition as described in Section 1 of the Horizontal Merger Guidelines.”), reprintedin 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,161.

81 See Int’l Tel. & Tel. Corp., 104 F.T.C. 280, 409–11 (1984).82 See, e.g., United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 50, 81 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (plaintiffs

have the burden to “define the relevant market”); Double D Spotting Serv., Inc. v. Super-valu, Inc., 136 F.3d 554, 560 (8th Cir. 1998) (“It is the plaintiff’s burden to define therelevant market.”); Brokerage Concepts, Inc. v. U.S. Healthcare, Inc., 140 F.3d 494, 513(3d Cir. 1998) (“The burden is on the plaintiff to define both components [product andgeographic] of the relevant market.”); R.R. Donnelley & Sons Co., 120 F.T.C. 36, 38(1995) (“Complaint Counsel bear the burden of proving a relevant market within whichanticompetitive effects are likely as a result of the acquisition.”); Adventist Health Sys.,117 F.T.C. 224, 297 (1994) (dismissal of complaint by ALJ affirmed because “ComplaintCounsel failed to carry the burden of proof” on market definition).

83 United States v. Sungard Data Sys., Inc., 172 F. Supp. 2d 172, 185 (D.D.C. 2001).84 Todd v. Exxon Corp., 275 F.3d 191, 199–200 (2d Cir. 2001) (“Because market defini-

tion is a deeply fact-intensive inquiry, courts hesitate to grant motions to dismiss for failureto plead a relevant product market.”); Double D Spotting Serv., Inc. v. Supervalu, Inc.,136 F.3d 554, 560 (8th Cir. 1998) (“Most often, ‘proper market definition can be deter-mined only after a factual inquiry into the commercial realities faced by consumers.’ Thisgeneral rule, however, does not amount to ‘a per se prohibition against dismissal of antitrustclaims for failure to plead a relevant market under Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6).”); In re

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 25: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 657

A number of courts have held, however, that bare legal conclusionsare not enough to survive a motion to dismiss.85 The Third Circuit hassuggested a minimal pleading standard that should allow courts to dismisscomplaints based on market definition allegations that are internallyinconsistent or nonsensical. In Queen City Pizza, Inc. v. Domino’s Pizza,Inc.,86 the court explained:

Where the plaintiff fails to define its proposed relevant market withreference to the rule of reasonable interchangeability and cross-elasticity of demand, or alleges a proposed relevant market that clearlydoes not encompass all interchangeable substitute products even whenall factual inferences are granted in plaintiff’s favor, the relevant marketis legally insufficient and a motion to dismiss may be granted.87

Other courts have granted motions to dismiss where the plaintiff’s prod-uct market allegations failed to explain why apparent substitutes werenot interchangeable or were conclusory, internally inconsistent, orimplausible.88 Thus, unsupported narrow product market allegations may

Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 105 F. Supp. 2d 618, 681 (E.D. Mich. 2000) (“The determina-tion whether there are additional products that are ‘reasonably’ interchangeable withCardizem CD involves questions of fact not properly addressed in a Rule 12(b)(6) motionto dismiss.”).

85 See, e.g., Papasan v. Allain, 478 U.S. 265, 286 (1986) (“we are not bound to accept astrue a legal conclusion couched as a factual allegation.”) Knoll Pharms. Co. v. Teva Pharms.USA, Inc., 2001 WL 1001117, at *3 (N.D. Ill. 2001) (“The pleader may not evade theserequirements by merely alleging a bare legal conclusion . . . .”). See generally 5A CharlesAlan Wright & Arthur R. Miller, Federal Practice and Procedure § 1357 (2ded. 1997) (noting courts deciding 12(b)(6) motions have rejected “legal conclusions,”“unsupported conclusions,” “unwarranted inferences,” “unwarranted deductions,” “foot-less conclusions of law,” or “sweeping legal conclusions cast in the form of factualallegations”).

86 124 F.3d 430 (3d Cir. 1997).87 Id. at 436.88 See 42nd Parallel N. v. E Street Denim Co., 286 F.3d 401, 406 (7th Cir. 2002) (affirming

dismissal where plaintiff’s proposed market was “absurdly small” considering “any sensibleawareness of commercial reality”); Tanaka v. Univ. of S. Cal., 252 F.3d 1059, 1063 (9thCir. 2001) (affirming dismissal because plaintiff “failed to identify an appropriately definedproduct market”; “conclusory assertion that [product] is ‘unique’ and hence ‘not inter-changeable with [other products]’ is insufficient”); Hack v. President and Fellows of YaleCollege, 237 F.3d 81, 86 (2d Cir. 2000) (“[t]o survive a motion to dismiss, . . . the alleged. . . market must be plausible”); Big Bear Lodging Ass’n v. Snow Summit, Inc., 182 F.3d1096, 1105 (9th Cir. 1999) (complaint dismissed because it failed to allege that there wereno other goods or services that were reasonably interchangeable); E-Z Bowz, LLC v. Prof’lProd. Research Co., 2003 WL 22068573, at *26 (S.D.N.Y. 2003) (“[A]n antitrust complaintmust explain why the market it alleges is the relevant, economically significant productmarket. . . . ‘plaintiff’s failure to define its market by reference to the rule of reasonableinterchangeability is, standing alone, valid grounds for dismissal.’”); Intellective, Inc. v.Mass. Mut. Life Ins. Co., 190 F. Supp. 2d 600, 609–10 (S.D.N.Y. 2002) (“To survive a motionto dismiss, the alleged product must (1) ‘include all products reasonably interchangeable,determination of which requires consideration of cross-elasticity of demand,’ and (2) beplausible.”) (citations omitted); Fresh Made, Inc. v. Lifeway Foods, Inc., 2002-2 Trade Cas.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 26: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal658

be dismissed. This approach is consistent with the Supreme Court’scaution that in an antitrust case “a district court must retain the powerto insist upon some specificity in pleading before allowing a potentiallymassive factual controversy to proceed.”89

Motions for summary judgment90 based on the plaintiff’s failure toestablish a product market are more common. Of course, even at thatstage, “[t]he evidence of the [plaintiff] is to be believed, and all justifiableinferences are to be drawn in [the plaintiff’s] favor.”91 Thus, summaryadjudication is inappropriate where the pertinent economic facts aredisputed.

The reluctance of some courts to grant summary judgment can beseen in Mutual Pharmaceutical Co. v. Hoechst Marion Roussel, Inc.92 Theplaintiff there alleged monopolization based on manipulation of theFDA and pled a market of terfenadine, a non-sedating antihistaminesold under the brand name Seldane. The defendant moved for summaryjudgment on the ground that terfenadine competes with other antihista-mines. The court found that such drugs treat the same symptoms, havesimilar mechanisms of action, are priced similarly, and are aggressivelymarketed and promoted against one another. Mutual even concededthat terfenadine “competes with other non-sedating antihistamines forsome consumers” but asserted a relevant market of “consumers for whomonly terfenadine provides therapeutic relief.” The court agreed that theplaintiff had produced evidence that terfenadine had “unique therapeu-tic benefit to some consumers.” Therefore, despite finding other drugs

(CCH) ¶ 73,779 (E.D. Pa. 2002) (“[W]here a ‘complaint fails to allege facts regardingsubstitute products, to distinguish among apparently comparable products, or to allegeother pertinent facts relating to cross-elasticity of demand,’ a motion to dismiss may beproperly granted.”); Adidas Am., Inc. v. NCAA, 64 F. Supp. 2d 1097, 1103 (D. Kan. 1999)(plaintiff “failed to explain or even address why other similar [products] . . . are notreasonably interchangeable”); Syncsort, Inc. v. Sequential Software, Inc., 50 F. Supp. 2d318, 325, 327–33 (D.N.J. 1999) (“[a]n antitrust plaintiff must plead facts sufficient todemonstrate a viable relevant market” and “explain its rationale for ignoring other existingor potential sources of supply”; plaintiff did not state in its pleading that defendant’sproduct was “unique” and “inexplicably ignored the broader . . . market”); B.V. Optischev. Hologic, Inc., 909 F. Supp. 162, 171–72 (S.D.N.Y. 1995) (rejecting market for chestequalization radiography based on the failure of the complaint to “refer to any reasonablyinterchangeable alternatives” or to “offer an explanation” as to why the product marketwas defined “in such narrow terms”).

89 Associated Gen. Contractors of Cal., Inc. v. California State Council of Carpenters,459 U.S. 519, 528 n.17 (1983).

90 Under the federal rules, summary judgment will be entered “if the pleadings, deposi-tions, answers to interrogatories, and admissions on file, together with the affidavits, ifany, show that there is no genuine issue as to any material fact and the moving party isentitled to a judgment as a matter of law.” Fed. R. Civ. P. 56.

91 Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 456 (1992).92 1997-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 72,001 (E.D. Pa. 1997).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 27: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 659

“largely compete for the same customers,” and without suggesting a pricediscrimination theory, which might justify a narrower market in suchcircumstances, the court concluded that whether a relevant market forterfenadine exists “can only be decided on a full record at trial.”93

Other courts have held, however, that market definition is an appro-priate issue for summary judgment where relevant economic facts arenot in dispute or where the antitrust plaintiff with the burden of proofprovides only conclusory support for its alleged market.94 Courts hearingcases involving pharmaceutical products should follow these precedents.

V. ARE PHARMACEUTICAL MARKETS DIFFERENT?

The first question that one must ask in order to analyze market defini-tion in cases involving pharmaceuticals is whether pharmaceuticalmarkets are different—that is, do or should different rules apply topharmaceutical markets.

The case law offers two different answers. There are at least somecases that start from the premise that “the pharmaceutical market isfundamentally different from the market for other products.”95 On theother hand, the Supreme Court has long taught that while “[t]he ‘market’which one must study to determine when a producer has monopolypower will vary with the part of commerce under consideration, . . .[t]he tests are constant.”96 Markets are composed of products that “havereasonable interchangeability for the purposes for which they are

93 Id. at 80,944–46; see also Bristol-Myers Squibb Co. v. Ben Venue Labs., 90 F. Supp. 2d540, 547 (D.N.J. 2000) (“The relevant market element of an antitrust claim ‘can bedetermined only after a factual inquiry into the commercial realities’ of the market.”).

94 See, e.g., PepsiCo, Inc. v. Coca-Cola Co., 315 F.3d 101, 107 (2d Cir. 2002) (summaryjudgment affirmed where there was “no discrete class of customers that has such a strongpreference for [product] that it would not consider substitutes if other factors (especiallyprice) changed” and there was a “high sensitivity to price change”); Golan v. Pingel Enter.,Inc., 310 F.3d 1360, 1369 (Fed. Cir. 2002) (antitrust plaintiff “failed to provide sufficientevidence to establish a relevant market . . . only conclusory allegations”); Levine v. Cent.Florida Med. Affiliates, 72 F.3d 1538, 1551–53 (11th Cir. 1996) (holding that plaintiff’s“narrow definition of the relevant product market does not satisfy his burden of presentingprima facie evidence of the relevant market”); Rebel Oil Co. v. Atl. Richfield Co., 51 F.3d1421, 1435 (9th Cir. 1995) (If plaintiff’s “evidence cannot sustain a jury verdict on theissue of market definition, summary judgment is appropriate.”); W. Parcel Express v.United Parcel Serv. of Am., Inc., 65 F. Supp. 2d 1052, 1057–60 (N.D. Cal. 1998) (plaintifffailed to produce evidence rebutting defendant’s proof that customers viewed services asa broad “continuum of . . . options and prices”), aff’d, 190 F.3d 974 (9th Cir. 1999).

95 In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 200 F.R.D. 297, 311 (E.D. Mich. 2001); accordGeneva Pharms. Tech. Corp. v. Barr Labs., Inc., 201 F. Supp. 2d 236, 268 (S.D.N.Y. 2002).

96 United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 404 (1956); accord Int’lBoxing Club of N.Y., Inc. v. United States, 358 U.S. 242, 250 (1959).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 28: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal660

produced—price, use and qualities considered.”97 Indeed, these princi-ples were recognized by the Third Circuit in one of the few appellatedecisions addressing pharmaceutical market definition, SmithKline Corp.v. Eli Lilly & Co. 98

Thus, in defining markets—including pharmaceutical markets—Supreme Court precedent requires the application of common marketdefinition principles. Thus, one must examine evidence of “reasonableinterchangeability of use” and “cross-elasticity of demand” as well as theBrown Shoe “practical indicia” or “evidentiary proxies” for direct proof ofsubstitutability. Those indicia include “industry or public recognition. . . ,the product’s peculiar characteristics and uses, unique production facili-ties, distinct customers, distinct prices, sensitivity to price changes, andspecialized vendors.”99 For more than twenty years, practitioners havealso followed the government’s Merger Guidelines, which require oneto examine whether a “small but significant and nontransitory” priceincrease would cause enough buyers to shift to other products so thatthe increase would be unprofitable for a hypothetical monopolist.100 Thistest, called the “SSNIP test,” is now used regularly by the courts, as wellas by the enforcement agencies.101

97 du Pont, 351 U.S. at 404.98 575 F.2d 1056, 1062–63 (3d Cir. 1978) (quoting du Pont, 351 U.S. at 404); accord

Geneva Pharms. Tech. Corp. v. Barr Labs., Inc., 201 F. Supp. 2d 236, 267 (S.D.N.Y. 2002).99 Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325 (1962); Rothery Storage & Van

Co. v. Atlas Van Lines, Inc., 792 F.2d 210, 218 (D.C. Cir. 1986). While the Brown Shoefactors are certainly relevant to market definition, it is important to recognize that someof those factors are more important than others. Market analysis requires more thantabulating how many Brown Shoe factors support a proposed definition.

100 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, supra note 75, § 1.11.101 See United States v. Sungard Data Sys., Inc., 172 F. Supp. 2d 172, 182, 190 (D.D.C.

2001) (“in order to determine the relevant market, the critical question is whether ahypothetical monopolist could profitably raise price,” noting the Merger Guidelines’ hypo-thetical monopolist “methodology has been adopted by the courts”); United States v. VisaUSA, Inc., 163 F. Supp. 2d 322, 335 (S.D.N.Y. 2001) (“a market is properly defined whena hypothetical profit-maximizing firm could charge significantly more than a competitiveprice, i.e., without losing too many sales to other products to make its price unprofitable”);FTC v. Swedish Match, 131 F. Supp. 2d 151, 160 (D.D.C. 2000) (noting “one way toevaluate price sensitivity is to apply the . . . Horizontal Merger Guidelines’ ‘hypotheticalmonopolist’ test”); California v. Sutter Health Sys., 130 F. Supp. 2d 1109, 1120 (N.D. Cal.2001) (examining whether firms could “profitably impose at least a ‘small but significantand nontransitory’ increase in price,” noting “[a]lthough the Merger Guidelines are notbinding, courts have often adopted the standards set forth in the Merger Guidelines inanalyzing antitrust issues”); FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066, 1076 n.8 (D.D.C. 1997)(adopting 5% test). But see United States v. Engelhard Corp., 970 F. Supp. 1463, 1467–68,1484 (M.D. Ga.), (noting Merger Guidelines “‘are not binding on the courts,’” andcommenting that the government’s “steadfast application of the [5–10%] test as thefoundation of its market definition analysis resulted in a pervasive failure to acknowledgerelevant information through the evidence of record”), aff’d 126 F.3d 1302 (11th Cir. 1997).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 29: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 661

VI. WHO IS THE CUSTOMER?

In order to address whether customers will switch to alternative prod-ucts, one must first answer the question: “Who is the customer?”102 Evenon this basic question, the case law provides conflicting answers.

The district court in In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litigation 103 suggestsfocusing on the alternatives available to the patient. According to thecourt, once a physician prescribes a particular drug, a “consumer patient”may only purchase that drug or its FDA-approved AB-rated bioequivalent.Emphasizing that the relevant market for antitrust purposes is deter-mined by the choices available to “the consumer,” the court noted that“no . . . patient who entered a U.S. pharmacy with a physician’s prescrip-tion for [a particular drug] could obtain any drug other than [thatprescribed].”104 Complaint counsel in Schering-Plough similarly focus onthe patient, suggesting “the requirement that a physician must approveswitching a prescription . . . prevents significant switching.”105

Other courts have for many years focused on the options available tothe “prescribing physician.”106 The administrative law judge in Schering-Plough similarly concluded that the “doctor is the most important in thechain of those involved in the decision of which [drug] to prescribe”since the doctor diagnoses and is knowledgeable about what drugs areavailable to meet the patient’s needs. He reasoned that “the only logicalplace from which to determine the relevant product market is from thearray of therapeutically substitutable choices available to the doctor.”107

102 See generally W.E. Afield, Note, The New Drug Buyer: The Changing Definition of theConsumer for Antitrust Enforcement in the Pharmaceutical Industry, 2001 Colum. Bus. L. Rev.203 (2001); Matt Koehler, Comment, The Importance of Correctly Identifying the Consumer foran Antitrust Relevant Market Analysis, 67 UMKC L. Rev. 521 (1999).

103 105 F. Supp. 2d 618 (E.D. Mich. 2000), aff’d, 332 F.3d 896 (6th Cir. 2003).104 Id. at 680–81. This discussion in Cardizem is arguably dictum, as the court held the

agreement at issue between a pioneer manufacturer and prospective generic competitornot to compete to be per se unlawful, making market definition irrelevant. Id at 676–79,681 n.33. Moreover, even that court recognized “physician[ ] prescribing practices” arerelevant to defining the relevant market. Id. at 680.

105 Schering-Plough Corp., Upsher-Smith Labs. & Am. Home Prods. Corp., FTC DocketNo. 9297 (Oct. 21, 2002) (Reply Brief of Counsel Supporting the Complaint at 54),available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9297/021022ccrb.pdf.

106 See, e.g., SmithKline Corp. v. Eli Lilly & Co., 575 F.2d 1056, 1063–64 (3d Cir. 1978);see also United States v. Ciba Geigy Corp., 508 F. Supp. 1118, 1126 (D.N.J. 1976) (“Theprocess of marketing specialty drugs is largely directed at the prescribing physician. Whilethe doctor is not the consumer of the product, the patient-consumer is generally legallyincompetent to choose between different medications.”).

107 Schering-Plough Corp., Upsher-Smith Labs. & Am. Home Prods. Corp., FTC DocketNo. 9297 (FTC June 27, 2002) (Initial Decision at 8), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/07/scheringinitialdecisionp2.pdf.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 30: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal662

The Third Circuit in Barr Laboratories, Inc. v. Abbott Laboratories,108 infact, upheld jury instructions advising that “[i]n the case of prescriptiondrugs . . . the person who selects the particular product in the firstinstance is the prescribing physician.” The trial court there instructedthe jury that it should include in the relevant market drugs reasonablyinterchangeable in meeting the needs of patients. Barr argued that theinstructions impermissibly removed from the jury the decision whetherthe physician or the pharmacist was the consumer from whose perspectivethe relevant market should be determined. The Third Circuit, however,upheld the instruction as accurately informing the jury that the evidenceestablished that both physicians and pharmacists play a role in selectinga particular drug for patients. The court reasoned that the jury was leftfree to decide whether the pharmacist, the physician, or both should beconsidered the consumer for purposes of defining the relevant market.109

Third-party payers, including insurance companies and managed careorganizations, as well as PBMs acting on their behalf, are increasinglyinfluencing the choice of pharmaceuticals, as discussed above.110 There-fore, in the future, actions of pharmacists, patients, and third-party pay-ers, as well as physicians who influence selection of particular drugs, willhave to be considered in defining markets.

VII. DOES PRICE MATTER?

A key question in defining markets is the extent to which customersshift their purchases in response to changes in price. This analysis iscomplicated in the case of pharmaceutical markets because—like otherhealth care markets—they are sometimes said to be unresponsive toprice because of the complex interactions among providers, patientsand payers (who may be the patient, a third-party payer, or a combinationof the two where the patient is required to make co-payments).

Twenty-five years ago, the trial court in SmithKline reasoned that pricehas little to do with physician prescribing practices. The court colorfullystated, “The blunt truth is that most physicians and hospital administra-tors, in their daily practice, are no closer to the cost-benefit analysisadvocated by [the expert] than are little leaguers equal to the perfor-mance of the National League All-Star baseball team.”111 The court sug-gested that “[p]erhaps in the long run there will be some massivereceptivity” to cost-conscious drug therapy that will dramatically alter

108 978 F.2d 98 (3d Cir. 1992).109 Id. at 115–16.110 See supra notes 22–23 and accompanying text.111 SmithKline Corp. v. Eli Lilly & Co., 427 F. Supp. 1089, 1117 (E.D. Pa. 1976).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 31: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 663

the prescribing habits of physicians.112 However, the court reasoned itmust define the market on the basis of consumer-physician practices,“whether their practices are rational, irrational, or unnecessarilycostly.”113 At about the same time, the FTC seemed to be wishing forprice responsiveness. The Commission in one fully adjudicated casereasoned, “we cannot assume that all physicians are so fixed in theirprescribing habits that a substantial increase in the existing price differen-tial . . . would never cause some shift . . . [W]e can take notice that somephysicians, even if a minority, are conscious of price differences . . .we see no reason to believe that price would never enter into somephysicians’ decisions.”114

Cross-elasticity of demand is often, of course, a critical factor in defin-ing markets. That is, courts regularly consider “the extent to whichconsumers will change their consumption of one product in responseto a price change in another.”115 The relevant inquiry is not whetherproducts compete against each other in some broad sense, but whetherproducts are “sufficiently substitutable that they could constrain” eachother’s prices.116 The Supreme Court in du Pont explained that “[i]f aslight decrease in the price of cellophane causes a considerable numberof customers of other flexible wrappings to switch to cellophane, it wouldbe an indication that a high cross-elasticity of demand exists betweenthem; that the products compete in the same market.”117 Thus, in Smith-Kline, the Third Circuit emphasized that “cephalosporins and non-cephalosporin anti-infectives do not demonstrate significant positivecross-elasticity of demand,” in concluding that these classes of antibioticswere in separate antitrust markets.118

VIII. MUST PRODUCTS BE IDENTICAL?

It is well recognized that products need not be identical to be in thesame market. This principle is well established. The Supreme Court’sdu Pont decision teaches simply that it is not “a proper interpretation of

112 Id. at 1118.113 Id. ; see also United States v. Ciba Geigy Corp., 508 F. Supp. 1118, 1153 (D. N.J. 1976)

(“When the physician prescribes, he is casting his drug decision in terms of therapeuticefficiency and not in terms of price if indeed he is aware of price variations amongidentical drugs. Perhaps a wide price variation resulting in patient complaints mightinfluence the physician’s choice, but a small price differential will not. The blunt fact isthat patients do not ‘shop’ for ethical pharmaceuticals.”).

114 Warner-Lambert Co., 87 F.T.C. 812, 877 (1976).115 Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 469 (1992).116 Coca-Cola Bottling Co. of the Southwest, 118 F.T.C. 452, 541 (1994).117 351 U.S. 377, 400 (1956).118 575 F.2d 1056, 1064 (3d Cir. 1978).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 32: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal664

the Sherman Act to require that products be fungible to be consideredin the relevant market.”119 In any market with some degree of productdifferentiation, goods of a single brand will enjoy a certain degree ofuniqueness, but that fact, without more, does not suffice to establishthat the manufacturer enjoys monopoly power.120 As Judge Posner hasnoted, “[i]t would not be surprising . . . if every manufacturer of brandname prescription drugs had some market power.”121 That, however, isto say nothing more than every differentiated product has a downward-sloping demand curve.

The Supreme Court recognized in du Pont that “[w]here there aremarket alternatives that buyers may readily use for their purposes, illegalmonopoly does not exist merely because the product said to be monopo-lized differs from others.”122 Two products or services are reasonablyinterchangeable where there is sufficient cross-elasticity of demand.123

The Court there concluded that all flexible wrapping materials belongedin the same market, notwithstanding cellophane’s physical advantages.

It should also now be beyond question that preferences by somecustomers for a particular product is the beginning and not the end ofthe analysis. Absent an ability to discriminate against the customers withthe preference, one must consider whether other customers more willingto switch will protect such infra-marginal customers.

The task in defining the relevant market is to identify products thatcompete to some substantial degree. As the Third Circuit put it in Smith-Kline : “[D]efining a relevant product market is a process of describingthose groups of producers which, because of the similarity of theirproducts, have the ability—actual or potential—to take significantamounts of business away from each other.”124

The SmithKline court concluded that while there was some overlap intherapeutic capability, there were “sufficiently unique features,” includ-ing “significant differences” in effectiveness and toxicity or undesirableside effects between cephalosporins and other antibiotics, to warrant thecharacterization of cephalosporins as a discrete market. In reaching that

119 du Pont, 351 U.S. at 394.120 SMS Sys. Maint. Serv., Inc., v. Digital Equip. Corp., 188 F.3d 11, 17 (1st Cir. 1999).121 In re Brand Name Prescription Drugs Antitrust Litig., 186 F.3d 781, 787 (7th Cir. 1999).122 du Pont, 351 U.S. at 394; accord Geneva Pharms. Tech. Corp. v. Barr Labs., Inc., 201

F. Supp. 2d 236, 267 (S.D.N.Y. 2002).123 Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325 (1962).124 SmithKline Corp. v. Eli Lilly & Co., 575 F.2d 1056, 1063 (3d Cir. 1978).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 33: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 665

conclusion, the court emphasized that cephalosporins were generallyused to treat specialized (penicillin-allergic) patients.125

IX. MAY A SINGLE DRUG CONSTITUTEAN ANTITRUST MARKET?

It is also now hornbook law that “relevant markets generally cannot belimited to a single manufacturer’s products.”126 Courts are appropriatelyskeptical of claims that a manufacturer has “monopolized” its own prod-ucts. The Supreme Court in du Pont explained:

[O]ne can theorize that we have monopolistic competition in everynonstandardized commodity with each manufacturer having power overprice and production of his own product. However, this power . . . isnot the power that makes an illegal monopoly.127

The Supreme Court’s decision in Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image TechnicalServices, Inc. 128 is sometimes relied upon to support single-firm markets.129

The case can be quoted to the effect that “in some instances one brandof a product can constitute a separate market.”130 That statement, how-ever, must be read in the context of the unique claim at issue there.Kodak involved allegations that the company had tied the sale of servicefor Kodak machines to the sale of parts and had monopolized andattempted to monopolize aftermarket service for Kodak machines. Ineffect, the Court said the relevant market might be limited to partsand service for Kodak machines because once customers bought theequipment they were locked into buying only Kodak parts and service.

125 See id. at 1064; see also Mutual Pharm. Co. v. Hoechst Marion Roussel, Inc., 1997 WL805261, at *3 (E.D. Pa. 1997) (noting evidence to establish that a drug was “a uniquechemical compound with particular effectiveness and possibly a distinct set of con-sumer users”).

126 ABA Section of Antitrust Law, Antitrust Law Developments 566 (5th ed. 2002).127 du Pont, 351 U.S. at 393; see also Brokerage Concepts, Inc. v. U.S. Healthcare, Inc.,

140 F.3d 494, 513 (3d Cir. 1998) (rejecting plaintiff’s proposed “single brand marketconsisting solely of U.S. Healthcare members with prescription drug benefits”); TownSound & Custom Tops, Inc. v. Chrysler Motors Corp., 959 F.2d 468, 479–80 (3d Cir. 1992)(en banc) (refusing to find Chrysler brand formed its own product market); Mathias v.Daily News, L.P., 152 F. Supp. 2d 465, 482 (S.D.N.Y. 2001) (“[C]ourts have consistentlyheld that a brand name product cannot define a relevant market.”).

128 504 U.S. 451 (1992)129 See, e.g., In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 105 F. Supp. 2d 618, 680 (E.D. Mich.

2000) (“Contrary to Andrx’s argument, a single brand of a product can constitute arelevant market for antitrust purposes.” (citing Kodak, 504 U.S. at 481–82)); Mutual Pharm.Co. v. Hoechst Marion Roussel, Inc., 1997 WL 805261, at *3 (E.D. Pa. 1997) (“The SupremeCourt has held that in some instances a single brand of a product may constitute a relevantmarket or . . . submarket.”).

130 Kodak, 504 U.S. at 482. See, e.g., Knoll Pharms. Co. v. Teva Pharms. USA, Inc., 2001WL 1001117 (N.D. Ill. 2001).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 34: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal666

The Court held only that a proposed market in a unique and non-interchangeable derivative product or service cannot be defeated onsummary judgment by the assertion that the primary market is competi-tive, where there were allegations that information and switching costslimited cross-elasticity in the aftermarket. Kodak is inapposite where thereis no allegation of “lock-in” in an aftermarket.131

It should not be surprising, therefore, that in United States v. Ciba GeigyCorp.,132 the court rejected a narrow hydrochlorothiazide market andinstead found a market of all products indicated for the treatment ofhypertension.133 The court noted that “different patients react in theirown idiosyncratic ways to different drugs or to different combinationsof drugs”134 and patients typically were given various dosages and combi-nations to obtain optimum control of the disease.135 The court concludedthat the various medicines were, “from a medical point of view, reasonablyinterchangeable” and that interchangeability “translated into commer-cial competition.”136

Despite the law’s aversion to single firm markets, the FTC appears tostart with a presumption of narrow markets. FTC staff members summa-rized the Commission’s approach as follows:

In determining a relevant market, the Commission usually will startwith a presumption that the market is limited to a specific therapeuticcompound and then broaden the market as evidence is available thatphysicians and hospitals use other compounds as substitutes. If sufficientsubstitution occurs, the market may be expanded to a whole class ofdrugs used to treat a particular condition or illness.137

While this approach sounds much like the Merger Guidelines, the Guide-lines in fact examine whether the threat of substitution in response to

131 See Hack v. President and Fellows of Yale College, 237 F.3d 81, 86–87 (2d Cir. 2000)(noting “‘[c]ourts have consistently refused to consider one brand to be a relevant marketof its own when the brand competes with other potential substitutes,’” and Kodak “concernsare not present” where plaintiffs had “no ‘lock-in’ costs”); Brokerage Concepts, Inc. v.U.S. Healthcare, Inc., 140 F.3d 494, 515 (3d Cir. 1998) (distinguishing Kodak whereplaintiff did not identify high “switching costs”).

132 508 F. Supp. 1118 (D.N.J. 1976).133 Id. at 1155.134 Id. at 1154 n.28.135 Id. at 1153–55.136 Id. at 1154.137 David A. Balto & James F. Mongoven, Antitrust Enforcement in Pharmaceutical Industry

Mergers, 54 Food & Drug L. J. 255, 259 (1999); see also Robert E. Bloch et al., ProductMarket Definition in Pharmaceutical Mergers, Antitrust Rep., Sept. 1997, at 17 (“[T]he FTClikely starts with the presumption that the relevant product market is limited to a specificcompound or means of interaction and broadens the market only if it has specific evidenceof substitutability, such as consumer switching.”).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 35: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 667

a price increase would restrain a hypothetical monopolist. Evidence thatsellers base business decisions on the prospect of substitution as well asevidence buyers have considered shifting purchases is relevant as wellas evidence buyers have shifted purchases in response to relative changesin price.138

X. DO GENERICS COMPRISE A DISTINCTPRODUCT MARKET?

Another important question that may have implications beyond thepharmaceutical industry is whether generics should be treated as forminga distinct market.

In a 1999 article, two FTC officials explained the Commission’sapproach to this question. They advised that “FTC investigations typicallyhave found that because of the significant price difference betweengeneric and brand name versions, an increase in the price of the brandname version does not lead consumers to switch to the generic version,and vice versa.”139 Thus, they conclude that brand-name and genericdrugs “typically are not in the same product market.”140 The FTC’s marketdefinition allegations, however, are not consistent, sometimes alleging“generic only” markets, sometimes alleging “branded and generic” mar-kets, and sometimes alleging “branded only” markets, as discussedabove.141

The court cases that have addressed this issue directly, In re CardizemCD Antitrust Litigation 142 and Geneva Pharmaceuticals Technology Corp. v.Barr Laboratories, Inc.,143 start from the premise that generic drugs areessentially fungible and interchangeable with their branded bioequiva-lent. That is, there is a “government-assured complete interchangeabil-ity,”144 so that drugs and their AB-rated generics are “identical in allmaterial respects.”145 In order to obtain FDA approval, generic manufac-turers must demonstrate that their drugs are bioequivalent to the pioneerdrug and have the same active ingredient, conditions of use, route of

138 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, supra note 75, § 1.1.139 Balto & Mongoven, supra note 137, at 259.140 Id.141 See supra notes 55–68 and accompanying text.142 200 F.R.D. 297 (E.D. Mich. 2001).143 201 F. Supp. 2d 236 (S.D.N.Y. 2002).144 In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 200 F.R.D. 297, 311 (E.D. Mich. 2001); see also

Geneva Pharms. Tech. Corp. v. Barr Labs., Inc., 201 F. Supp. 2d 236, 268 (S.D.N.Y. 2002)(quoting In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig.).

145 In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 200 F.R.D. at 310; see also Geneva Pharms. Tech. Corp.,201 F. Supp. 2d at 267 (quoting In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig.).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 36: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal668

administration, dosage form, strength, and labeling.146 By law, genericdrugs are sold with the same package insert as the brand-name drugand are subject to the same prescribing indications and warnings.147 Theymay even be able to use the same tablet colors.148 As a result, courts haveheld that “AB-rated generics are freely substitutable and interchangeablewith their brand name counterparts.”149 Indeed, in many states, pharmac-ies are allowed, and in some states are required, to substitute genericversions of brand-name drugs absent a contrary instruction from thephysician or patient.150 Thus, by definition, a drug and its generic bioequi-valents are “two interchangeable versions . . . of the same drug prod-uct.”151 Courts that have addressed the issue have reasoned that since“[a]ntitrust law requires only that the two products at issue be closesubstitutes for each other,” a drug and its generic bioequivalents necessar-ily “meet this requirement.”152

Courts have further reasoned that “[m]arket behavior, which showsgenerics capturing a significant percentage of the branded drug marketsoon after they are introduced . . . supports the conclusion that the brandand generic drugs are essentially fungible and interchangeable.”153 Theyhave also noted that brand-name and generic drugs are sold to the samecustomers—wholesalers, hospitals, retail pharmacy chains, mail orderhouses, clinics, and managed care organizations.154 The fact that genericsare typically priced at a discount compared to pioneer drugs in order

146 Geneva Pharms. Tech. Corp., 201 F. Supp. 2d at 268.147 Id.148 See Qualitex Co. v. Jacobson Prods. Co., 514 U.S. 159, 169 (1995) (commenting that

competitors “might be free to copy the color of a medical pill where that color serves toidentify the kind of medicine . . . in addition to its source” (citing Inwood Labs., Inc. v.Ives Labs., Inc., 456 U.S. 844, 853, 858 n.20 (1982))); Shire US Inc. v. Barr Labs., Inc.,329 F.3d 348, 355, 358 (3d Cir. 2003) (affirming denial of injunction to block genericdrugs with same color scheme as pioneer since court found similarity in appearanceenhances patient safety by facilitating compliance with dosing regimens and “promotingpsychological acceptance” of generic drugs).

149 In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 200 F.R.D. at 310–11; see also Geneva Pharms. Tech.Corp., 201 F. Supp. 2d at 267–68 (quoting In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig.).

150 See Geneva Pharms. Tech. Corp., 201 F. Supp. 2d at 268 (discussing generic substitution);see also Inwood Labs., Inc. v. Ives Labs. Inc., 456 U.S. 844, 847 n.4 (1982) (“Since the early1970’s, most States have enacted laws allowing pharmacists to substitute generic drugs forbrand name drugs under certain conditions.”).

151 In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 200 F.R.D. at 311; see also Geneva Pharms. Tech. Corp.,201 F. Supp. 2d at 268 (quoting In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig.).

152 In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 200 F.R.D. at 311; see also Geneva Pharms. Tech. Corp.,201 F. Supp. 2d at 268 (quoting In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig.).

153 In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 200 F.R.D. at 311; see also Geneva Pharms. Tech. Corp.,201 F. Supp. 2d at 268 (quoting In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig.).

154 Geneva Pharms. Tech. Corp., 201 F. Supp. 2d at 268.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 37: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 669

to convince customers to switch to the generic has also been used tosupport including both in the same market.155

In cases involving other products, courts have sometimes consideredprice differences between products in finding products to be in differentmarkets,156 but the Supreme Court has made clear that the mere fact ofprice differences is not “determinative.”157 Thus, the fact that genericdrugs are typically priced lower than branded drugs should not be suffi-cient to define a separate market. Indeed, in Nifty Foods Corp. v. GreatAtlantic & Pacific Tea Co., Inc.,158 the Second Circuit determined thatnational and private label waffles were in the same market despite differ-ences in price.159 Under the Merger Guidelines or a cross-elasticity test,the proper focus should be on responsiveness to price changes ratherthan absolute price differences.160

In Warner-Lambert Co.,161 a pharmaceutical merger case litigated in the1970s, the FTC even rejected the argument that branded and unbrandedthyroid drugs should be in separate product markets where there was alack of price elasticity at existing price levels, reasoning that an increasein the existing price differential may cause a shift in prescribing habits.162

155 See id. at 269.156 See, e.g., United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 377 U.S. 271, 276–77 (1964) (empha-

sizing price differential between copper and aluminum); U.S. v. Archer-Daniel-MidlandCo., 866 F.2d 242, 246 (8th Cir. 1988) (finding sugar prices artificially inflated by govern-ment price supports such that high fructose corn syrup prices could increase even thoughproducts were functionally interchangeable).

157 United States v. Continental Can Co., 378 U.S. 441, 455 (1964); see also United Statesv. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 371, 401 (1956) (finding cellophane was inthe same market as aluminum foil, waxed paper, and other flexible packaging materialsdespite costing two to three times more).

158 614 F.2d 832 (2d Cir. 1980).159 Id. at 840–41. The Sixth Circuit has similarly held that generic heating, ventilating,

and air conditioning parts are in the same market as branded parts, Tarrant Serv. Agency,Inc. v. Am. Standard, Inc., 12 F.3d 609, 614–15 (6th Cir. 1993), and the Ninth Circuitfound that branded and private-label bread are in the same market, William Inglis & SonsBaking Co. v. Cont’l Baking Co., 942 F.2d 1332, 1346 (9th Cir. 1991) (Noonan, J., concur-ring and dissenting), modified, 970 F.2d 639 (1992), amended by 981 F.2d 1023 (1992). Onthe other hand, in one case, the Eleventh Circuit concluded as a matter of law that therelevant market was lightweight generic anchors despite functional interchangeability ofDanforth brand anchors finding a lack of significant cross-elasticity and given the “unusualcircumstance of severe price discrimination against a distinct group of consumers basedsolely on brand preference.” U.S. Anchor Mfg., Inc. v. Rule Indus., Inc., 7 F.3d 986, 996–97(11th Cir. 1993).

160 In Nifty Foods, the plaintiff argued that a private-label market was supported by a lackof sensitivity of demand for brand-name waffles to private-label price changes. 614 F.2dat 840 n.11. The court, however, found the evidence lacking. Id.

161 87 F.T.C. 812 (1976).162 Id. at 877.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 38: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal670

On the other hand, in adjudicating a merger between competing softdrink bottlers in 1994, the FTC rejected an “all soft drink” market andexcluded private-label soft drinks from the relevant market.163 After adetailed review of the evidence, the agency there concluded that privatelabel soft drinks did not constrain branded pricing, emphasizing, forexample, evidence that private-label soft drinks were not available incertain channels and that branded bottlers did not consider the priceof private-label soft drinks in setting prices.164 The Commission explainedthat branded soft drinks may constrain nonbranded soft drinks, butnonbranded soft drinks did not constrain branded soft drinks.165

The fact that pharmaceutical manufacturers may raise the price ofthe pioneer drug in response to introduction of low-priced generics hasnot led to different conclusions. At least one court has reasoned thatprice increases for branded drugs in response to generic entry demon-strate that “[c]learly there is some interrelationship” between the genericand branded drugs.166 Price movements over time are, of course, relevantto market determinations but can be difficult to interpret. With theburden of establishing market definition on the plaintiff, it is particularlyimportant that the plaintiff present expert evidence to establish separatemarkets where branded and generic drugs are interchangeable.167

XI. DOES THE “CELLOPHANE FALLACY” REQUIREA DIFFERENT APPROACH?

A. The Theory

There has been substantial academic criticism that the SupremeCourt’s United States v. E.I. duPont de Nemours & Co. 168 decision falls intowhat has become known as the “Cellophane fallacy” or “Cellophane trap.”Professor Herbert Hovenkamp, for example, advises that “the court’sdefinition of the relevant market was probably wrong.”169 That is because

163 Coca-Cola Bottling Co. of the Southwest, 118 F.T.C. 452, 574 (1994); see also Coca-Cola Co., 117 F.T.C. 795, 931–40 (1994) (finding branded soft drink concentrate, andnot all soft drink concentrate, to be the relevant market for assessing Coca-Cola’s proposedacquisition of Dr Pepper).

164 Id. at 553–74.165 Id. at 564.166 Geneva Pharms. Tech. Corp. v. Barr Labs., Inc., 201 F. Supp. 2d 236, 270

(S.D.N.Y. 2002).167 See id. (emphasizing that the plaintiff “failed to conduct a formal test regarding the

degree of purported differential impact” on price of a competitor’s entry).168 351 U.S. 377 (1956).169 Herbert Hovenkamp, Federal Antitrust Policy § 3.4b, at 104 (2d ed. 1999); see

also Dennis W. Carlton & Jeffrey M. Perloff, Modern Industrial Organization 614(3d ed. 1999) (“[I]t was an error to include other wrapping materials in the market

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 39: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 671

every firm, whether or not a monopolist, will price at a level wherefurther price increases will cause it to lose so many customers that theprice increase is unprofitable. Thus, the existence of a high cross-elasticity may be indicative that a firm is currently exercising marketpower, rather than that it lacks market power. As explained by theSecond Circuit:

The economic error allegedly committed by the Court in Cellophanewas in failing to recognize that a high cross-elasticity of demand may,in some cases, be the product of monopoly power rather than a beliefon the part of consumers that the products are good substitutes forone another. . . . “At a high enough price, even poor substitutes lookgood to the consumer.” That is, in the Cellophane case, the high cross-elasticity between cellophane and wax paper simply may have been afunction of the high price that du Pont demanded for cellophane.170

The Supreme Court in du Pont failed to recognize that a monopolistthat has reduced output and raised price may price its products so thateven inferior substitutes begin to look good to consumers, and maytherefore face highly elastic demand.

The difficulty is that determining whether or not the Cellophane fallacyapplies is not easy. Some commentators have suggested looking at profit-ability data to determine whether a firm is earning monopoly profits.171

There is ample literature, however, which demonstrates that standardaccounting data used to report corporate profits is an unreliable indicatorof true economic profits.172 Among other problems, defining marketswould require one to examine product-line, rather than firm, profitabil-ity. In addition, firms with monopoly power may become inefficient,with high costs rather than high profits.

definition because they did not prevent the exercise of market power and constrain theprice of cellophane to competitive levels.”); Richard A. Posner, Antitrust Law 150–51(2d ed. 2001) (criticizing the Court’s market definition in du Pont). Hovenkamp criticizesthe DOJ and FTC Horizontal Merger Guidelines for “commit[ing] a version of the Cello-phane fallacy by defining markets in terms of current prices.” Hovenkamp, supra, § 3.4b,at 105. The 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines in fact state that the government will baseits analysis on “prevailing prices of the products of the merging firms and possible substi-tutes for such products, unless premerger circumstances are strongly suggestive of coordi-nated interaction, in which case the [government] will use a price more reflective of thecompetitive price.” Horizontal Merger Guidelines, supra note 75, § 1.11.

170 United States v. Eastman Kodak Co., 63 F.3d 95, 105 (2d Cir. 1995) (citations omitted).171 See Robert Pitofsky, New Definitions of Relevant Market and the Assault on Antitrust, 90

Colum. L. Rev. 1805, 1818, 1823–24, 1847 (1990).172 See, e.g., George J. Benston, Accounting Numbers and Economic Values, 27 Antitrust

Bull. 161 (1982) (discussing limitations of accounting data for answering economicquestions); Franklin M. Fisher & John J. McGowan, On the Misuse of Accounting Rates ofReturn to Infer Monopoly Profits, 73 Am. Econ. Rev. 82 (1983) (discussing critical differencebetween accounting profits and economic profits).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 40: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal672

Hovenkamp advises that in deciding whether a group of productsbelong in the same market, one should consider looking for cost shocksthat affect the alleged monopolist but not other firms arguably in thesame market.173 A “true competitor, who faces a horizontal demandcurve, would be unable to respond to a firm specific cost increase byraising price,” while “a firm with a downward sloping demand curvewould calculate a new price that equated with its marginal cost andmarginal revenues.”174 Hovenkamp also suggests looking at past pricemovements and changes in output of allegedly competitive products.175

Carlton and Perloff similarly advise that “a reasonable first step in definingeconomic markets is to examine the price correlations (a statistical mea-sure of how closely prices move together) among different products.”176

B. The Cellophane Fallacy in the Courts

Despite its academic recognition, only a handful of antitrust caseshave ever discussed or even mentioned the Cellophane fallacy. TheSupreme Court in Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc. 177

recognized the theory, noting that the existence of significant substitu-tion at current prices does not disprove the existence of market powerbecause sellers may already be charging a monopoly price.178 But theCourt did not suggest any test to determine whether the fallacy applies.

Lower court cases that do discuss the Cellophane fallacy are skepticalof applying it to establish that a firm does have market power withoutcorroborating evidence. The Second Circuit directly addressed the fallacyin a 1995 decision, United States v. Eastman Kodak Co.179 The court thereaffirmed a trial court decision to terminate two old consent decrees,concluding that Kodak no longer possessed market power over the saleof film.180 The district court found that the relevant geographic marketfor film is worldwide while the government asserted Kodak still hadpower in a U.S. film market.181 According to the government, Kodakalready was pricing its products at monopolistic levels and therefore

173 Hovenkamp, supra note 169, § 3.4c, at 106.174 Id.175 Id. § 3.4c, at 106–07.176 Carlton & Perloff, supra note 169, at 614.177 504 U.S. 451 (1992).178 See id. at 471 (“‘[T]he existence of significant substitution in the event of further price

increases or even at the current price does not tell us whether the defendant already exercisessignificant market power.’” (quoting Phillip Areeda & Louis Kaplow, Antitrust Analy-sis ¶ 340(b) (4th ed. 1988))).

179 63 F.3d 95 (2d Cir. 1995).180 Id. at 109.181 Id. at 102–03.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 41: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 673

consumers’ willingness to switch to other brands “actually demonstratesthat Kodak possesses market power.”182 The appellate court rejected theargument that the district court “fell victim to the Cellophane fallacy.”183

The court explained that “the government’s contention assumes thatKodak film is priced well above competitive levels” and reasoned that thatview was “simply . . . conjecture” and “not sufficient to call in question” themarket definition.184 The Second Circuit noted in particular that thecase before it did not involve highly differentiated products like cello-phane and wax paper but rather products of comparable quality, suggest-ing that the Cellophane fallacy is inapposite where products are“excellent substitute[s].”185

Similarly, in Pepsico, Inc. v. Coca-Cola Co.,186 Pepsi “warn[ed] of theso-called Cellophane fallacy” and argued that Coca-Cola’s pricing tofoodservice distributors was “already at a supracompetitive level.”187 Pepsialleged Coca-Cola monopolized the market for fountain-dispensed softdrinks distributed through independent foodservice distributors.188 Thecourt noted, however, that there was no pricing evidence and no evi-dence of Coca-Cola’s margins in the record, while there was evidenceof discounting by Coca-Cola.189 Because Pepsi’s market definition couldnot be sustained, its monopolization and attempted monopolizationclaims failed.190

Where a plaintiff merely presumes the existence of the Cellophanefallacy, rather than proving its applicability to the case at hand, courtsshould continue to reject the argument.

C. Market Power and Intellectual Property

A further complication arises in measuring market power where thereis intellectual property.

It is well recognized by now, despite some contrary Supreme Courtauthority, that market power cannot be presumed from the existence

182 Id. at 105.183 Id.184 Id. at 105, 107, 108.185 See id. at 104–05.186 114 F. Supp. 2d 243 (S.D.N.Y. 2000), aff’d, 315 F.3d 101 (2d Cir. 2002).187 Id. at 257.188 Id. at 245.189 Id. at 258.190 Id. at 259; see also Aegerter v. City of Delafield, 174 F.3d 886, 892 (7th Cir. 1999)

(noting the “‘cellophane fallacy’”); Santa Cruz Med. Clinic v. Dominican Santa Cruz Hosp.,1995-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 71,254 at 76,096–97 (N.D. Cal. Sept. 7, 1995) (finding that agenuine issue of material fact as to evidence of supracompetitive pricing precludes sum-mary judgment as to the definition of the relevant market where Cellophane fallacy asserted).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 42: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal674

of a patent. Like real property, intellectual property gives one only theright to exclude, not a monopoly. Whether or not a patent confersmonopoly power depends on the availability of substitutes.191

For many goods protected by intellectual property, the most significantcosts are fixed sunk costs incurred in developing the intellectual propertythat do not vary with the number of goods produced. Marginal costsare often small relative to the costs of initial development. ProfessorsHovenkamp, Lemley, and Janis offer an example of a copyright-protectedmovie, costing $150 million to produce, which can be duplicated ontovideotape for $2 per copy but sells for $20 per copy.192 They explainthat, at a price of $2, the movie “would lose money and a firm thathad contemplated such a price would never have made [it] in the firstplace.”193 Therefore, they conclude that “price-cost relationships on aparticular patent or copyright do not provide useful evidence aboutmarket power.”194 Accordingly, they argue, the “technically correct way”to measure whether intellectual property produces returns above cost isto compare development costs with profits generated during a product’smarketable life.195 In a high-risk enterprise, moreover, one must takeinto account failed products as well as those that are successful.196 Thus,focusing on relationships between price and short-run marginal costcannot be said to provide useful evidence of market power.197

191 See Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 37 n.7 (1984) (O’Connor,J., concurring) (“[A] patent holder has no market power in any relevant sense if thereare close substitutes for the patented product.”); In re Indep. Serv. Orgs. Antitrust Litig.,203 F.3d 1322, 1325 (Fed. Cir. 2000) (“A patent alone does not demonstrate marketpower.”); C.R. Bard, Inc. v. M3 Systems, Inc., 157 F.3d 1340, 1368 (Fed. Cir. 1998) (“It isnot presumed that the patent-based right to exclude necessarily establishes market powerin antitrust terms.”); Schlafly v. Caro-Kann Corp., 1998-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 72,138, at81,903 (Fed. Cir. Apr. 29, 1998) (“Mere possession of a patent, or a family of patents,does not establish a presumption of antitrust market power.”); Abbott Labs. v. Brennan, 952F.2d 1346, 1354–55 (Fed. Cir. 1991) (“A patent does not of itself establish a presumption ofmarket power in the antitrust sense.”); CCPI, Inc. v. Am. Premier, Inc., 967 F. Supp. 813,817–18 (D. Del. 1997) (“‘[M]erely obtaining a patent for a product does not create aproduct market for antitrust purposes.’”); see also U.S. Dep’t of Justice & Federal TradeComm’n, Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property §§ 2.1, 2.2, 5.3(1995) (“The Agencies will not presume that a patent, copyright, or trade secret necessarilyconfers market power upon its owner.”), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,132.But see Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 16–17 (“[I]f the Government has granted the seller apatent or similar monopoly over a product, it is fair to presume that the inability to buythe product elsewhere gives the seller market power.”).

192 Herbert Hovenkamp, Mark D. Janis & Mark A. Lemley, IP and Antitrust § 4.1c,at 4–6 (2002).

193 Id.194 Id. § 4.1c, at 4–7.195 Id. § 4.1c, at 4–6.196 Id. § 4.1c, at 4–7.197 Id.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 43: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

2003] Product Market Definition 675

D. Application to the Pharmaceutical Industry

These problems are particularly acute in the pharmaceutical industrywhich, as discussed above, faces huge research and development costson drugs that are never introduced as well as on those that becomesuccessful, all of which must be recovered over the life of those drugsthat are successful.198 Unlike many industries, for which patents are notan important incentive for innovation, many pharmaceuticals wouldnot be developed but for patent protection. If firms price at short-runmarginal cost, one would not expect new research and developmentleading to the introduction of new drugs.

Notably, the FTC staff has explicitly invoked the Cellophane fallacy inits challenge to the intellectual property litigation settlement agreementsin Schering-Plough.199 Complaint counsel rely on the economic literaturethat generic drugs typically enter the market at a discount and pioneerdrugs lose sales in response to such entry to support their theory thatthe branded drug had monopoly power.200 Under mandatory genericsubstitution laws, however, pharmacists often must dispense AB-ratedgenerics, so it is not surprising that pioneer drugs lose sales and genericsgain sales. That phenomenon takes place, however, even where pioneerdrugs face good substitutes, and it seems particularly inappropriate toassume the Cellophane fallacy applies where drugs are good therapeuticsubstitutes. In fact, the same studies show that the price of the brand-name drug typically rises after generic entry.201 At the same time, themanufacturer of the brand-name drug typically reduces its promotionalefforts dramatically.202 The end result at times may be that output fallsrather than rises with generic entry, suggesting a higher average “quality-adjusted” price rather than a price decrease resulting from generic entry.

198 See supra notes 14–18 and accompanying text.199 Schering-Plough Corp., Upsher-Smith Labs. & Am. Home Prods. Corp., FTC Docket

No. 9297 (Oct. 24, 2002) (Reply Brief of Counsel Supporting the Complaint at 56),available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9297/021022ccrb.pdf.

200 Schering-Plough Corp., Upsher-Smith Labs. & Am. Home Prods. Corp., FTC DocketNo. 9297 (Aug. 9, 2002) (Appeal Brief of Counsel Supporting the Complaint at 48),available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/08/scheringtrialbrief.pdf.

201 See Congressional Budget Office, supra note 17, at xiii; see generally Richard E.Caves et al., Patent Expiration, Entry, and Competition in the U.S. Pharmaceutical Industry, inBrookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics 1991, at 1 (1991) (analyz-ing competition surrounding patent expiration and generic entry in pharmaceuticalsmarkets); Frank & Salkever, supra note 37 (discussing model of price response for genericdrug entry into brand-name and generic drug market); Henry Grabowski & John Vernon,Longer Patents for Increased Generic Competition: The Waxman-Hatch Act After One Decade, 10PharmacoEcon. Supp. 2, at 110 (1996) (reporting on investigation into effects of Waxman-Hatch Act on generic and brand-name drug prices); Henry Grabowski & John Vernon,Brand Loyalty, Entry and Price Competition in Pharmaceuticals After the 1984 Drug Act, 35 J.L.& Econ. 331 (1992) (same).

202 See Frank & Salkever, supra note 37, at 82.

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.

Page 44: PRODUCT MARKET DEFINITION IN THE … MARKET DEFINITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY M. Howard Morse* I. INTRODUCTION The pharmaceutical industry has become a …

[Vol. 71Antitrust Law Journal676

Plaintiffs in pharmaceutical cases cannot simply assume the existenceof market power from the existence of patents, from pricing above short-run marginal cost, from generic entry at prices below the price of abranded drug, or from reduced output of the branded drug upon genericentry. A plaintiff’s proposed narrow market definition that does notinclude therapeutic substitutes, like that in Geneva Pharmaceuticals Technol-ogy Corp. v. Barr Laboratories, Inc., should be rejected unless the plaintiffpresents a “formal test” showing the various drugs’ impact on the priceand quantity of sales.203

XII. CONCLUSION

Market definition in the pharmaceutical industry should not be differ-ent from that in other industries. The same rules apply. But they mustbe applied with sensitivity to the industry’s characteristics. It seems mostappropriate for the government and courts to begin product marketanalyses in the industry by focusing on the therapeutic indications, bothapproved and off-label, for the drugs at issue in any matter. That is, onemust consider whether drugs may be substitutes for the treatment of aparticular disease or condition, taking into account the drugs’ mecha-nisms of action, therapeutic profiles, side effects, and methods of admin-istration. The analysis must consider the impact of doctors, pharmacists,patients, and third-party payers on the use of drugs, to analyze thelikelihood of switching in response to relative price increases, and theimpact of such switching on profitability. While price differences maybe considered, one must analyze price movements over time and theimpact of such movements on the quantities of drugs sold. Evidencefrom knowledgeable witnesses and company documents, as well as data,will be relevant as in any other industry. Presumptions based on theexistence of patents or experience with other drugs should not substitutefor careful analysis of the facts.

203 See Geneva Pharms. Tech. Corp. v. Barr Labs., Inc., 201 F. Supp. 2d 236, 270 (S.D.N.Y.2002); see also Bailey v. Allgas, Inc., 284 F.3d 1237, 1247 (11th Cir. 2002) (rejecting plaintiff’sproposed market definition where its expert failed to determine cross-elasticity of demandamong possible substitutes); Alcatel USA, Inc. v. DGI Techs., Inc., 166 F.3d 772, 783(5th Cir. 1999) (rejecting plaintiff’s proposed market definition where plaintiff “nevercompared [defendant’s] prices to its competitors’ prices”); Lantec, Inc. v. Novell, Inc.,146 F. Supp. 2d 1140, 1147–49 (D. Utah 2001) (rejecting plaintiff’s proposed marketdefinition where there was “no evidence of price sensitivity”), aff’d, 306 F.3d 1003 (10thCir. 2002).

71 Antitrust Law Journal No. 2 (2003). Copyright 2003 American Bar Association. Reproduced by permission. All rights reserved.This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or downloaded or storedin an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.