poverty reduction and education decentralisation in uganda

40
POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA Consultancy Report May 2007 Field Trip Report 2007

Upload: the-bartlett-development-planning-unit-ucl

Post on 04-Oct-2014

348 views

Category:

Documents


6 download

DESCRIPTION

When Uganda’s home-based Poverty Eradication Action Plan (PEAP)was launched in 1997, the decentralisation process in this country wassignificantly scaled up with the expansion of local governments andresources for pro-poor service delivery. This was especiallypronounced in the case of Universal Primary Education (UPE), asignificant policy in the national programme for poverty reduction.However, UPE under decentralisation has led to both achievementsand many unexpected consequences in education service delivery.

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION

IN UGANDA Consultancy Report

May 2007

Field Trip Report 2007

Page 2: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

i

Contents

Executive Summary iii

Acknowledgement iv

Part I Inception Report General Background: The Ugandan Context 2 (Andrew Munk and Fredrick Wamalwa)

Theoretical Framework 4 (Ting YAN)

Scope and objectives of the study 9 (Matthew Bockarie)

Methodology 11 (Obeng-Odoom Franklin)

Institutional Landscape 14 (Fredrick Wamalwa and Ugochukwu Idika)

Part II Recommendations Report Field Trip findings 18

Recommendations 24 - Future Research Areas

- Strategy Guidelines

Bibliography 26

Appendices 30

Page 3: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

ii

Executive Summary

When Uganda’s home-based Poverty Eradication Action Plan (PEAP)

was launched in 1997, the decentralisation process in this country was

significantly scaled up with the expansion of local governments and

resources for pro-poor service delivery. This was especially

pronounced in the case of Universal Primary Education (UPE), a

significant policy in the national programme for poverty reduction.

However, UPE under decentralisation has led to both achievements

and many unexpected consequences in education service delivery.

This report is the result of a field trip undertaken in Mbarara District

aimed at examining the role of decentralisation in education service

delivery. Decentralisation improves service delivery thus reducing

poverty when local governments are given enough resources and

authority, along with effective local mechanisms of accountability.

After extensively reviewing secondary data and gathering primary data

through interviews from the field, our preliminary findings show that

local authorities in Mbarara District however have very limited

financial capacity and autonomy to effectively improve service

delivery and parents still lack effective mechanisms to hold local

authorities accountable.

Therefore, we recommend that future research areas and future PEAP

agenda need to address these crucial aspects to further improve

education service delivery for poor Ugandan people thus accelerating

the pace of poverty reduction.

Ting YAN

Project Manager

Education Decentralisation Group

Page 4: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

iii

Acknowledgement

This report has been prepared by the education decentralisation group

led by Ting YAN, teamed with Obeng-Odoom Franklin, Fredrick

Wamalwa, Andrew Munk, Matthew Bockarie, and Ugochukwu Idika

in Development Planning Unit, University College London.

The field trip in Uganda was directed by Julio Davila, Le-Yin Zhang,

Michael Walls, and Zeremariam Fre, and was assisted by Yukiko

Fujimoto. The education decentralisation group was guided and

advised by Moses Tukwasiibwe.

The team also benefited greatly from the following people who shared

their precious time and opinions with us.

Name of Respondent

Institution Title

Prof. Emannuel. T. Mutebille

Uganda Central Bank

Bank Governor

Lawyer Kafureeka

Centre for Basic Research

Researcher

Eric Hawthorne DFID Uganda Mario Obwona Economic policy

research Centre Principal Research Fellow

Lawrence Bategeka

Economic policy research Centre

Principal Research Fellow

Augustus Nuwagaba

Reevconsult & Makerere University

Chairman Academic Staff Association Makerere University

Robert Esuruku Uganda Martyrs University, Nkozi

Deputy Dean, Inst of Ethics and Dev Studies

Emmanuel Kyagaba

Mbarara University of Science and Technology

Dean of Students

Adoniaa Mbarara District Secretary of Education

Page 5: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

iv

Kabaribaa Education Office (LC 5)

and Health

Steven Mugume

Education Standards Agency

Inspector of Schools

John Agair Education Standards Agency

Inspector of Schools (Maths)

Deus Barigye Education Standards Agency

Snr. Inspector of Schools (Science)

Mary Frances Semambo

Kabateraine Memorial School

Proprietress

Francis Wayegumamya

Kabateraine Memorial School

Headteacher

Tuhule Probia Teacher Charles Malugu Kabateraine

Memorial School (Private Primary)

IT Teacher

Benson Arinetwe

Booma International School (Private Secondary)

Deputy Headmaster

Rev. Philemon Canon Tinka

Ankole Diocese Diocesean Secretary of Education

Johnson Muhumuza

Mbarara Juniour School (Primary section/UPE school)

Deputy Head (Primary)

Steven Sasiirwe Ministry of Education (Mbarara District)

Education Officer

Edward Mbabazi

Ministry of Education (Mbarara District)

Education Officer

Bornyenka Boniface

Ntare School Deputy Head

Birindwarugaba Blegious

Ntare School Deputy Head

Hannington Noowe

Parent

Basil Tibanyendera

Mbarara University of Science and Technology

Ag. Head, Foundation Education

All students Kabateraine Memorial School

-

Page 6: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

1

PART I Inception Report

Page 7: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

2

General Background: Decentralisation in Uganda

(Andrew Munk and Fredrick Wamalwa)

On assuming power towards the end of 1986, the National Resistance Movement

under President Museveni of Uganda, introduced political decentralization by

establishing the Resistance Councils at all sub-national government levels aimed at

increasing local participation in the decision-making processes and strengthening

democracy (Ahikire, 2002). Decentralization was seen as a tool to achieve national

consensus among different groups, given the past political instability and tribal

animosities (Ahamad et al., 2006). The central government opted to create districts as

the highest level of local governments in an attempt to satisfy regional and tribal

demands for political power (Makara, 1998).

Ahamad et al. (2006) suggest that this form of decentralization was primarily

administrative, aimed at building the managerial capacity at the local level and

increasing transparency and accountability in service delivery. It devolved

responsibility for a large number of key public services to the local level, including

primary education and health services. It was not until during 1994 that signs of

political decentralisation started to appear as local governments were granted specific

legal responsibilities and expenditure functions. In spite of these developments, the

central government retained important financing controls.

The need to ensure effective service delivery contributed to the strong expansion of

Uganda’s local government (Ahamad et al., 2006). This expansion took root as the

government focused its economic programme, supported by donors, more intently on

poverty reduction in the second half of the 1990s (Muduuli, 2006). When the

country’s home-based Poverty Eradication Action Plan (PEAP) was initiated in 1997,

Uganda significantly raised the resources allocated to pro-poor spending, in particular

those identified and tracked under the Poverty Action Fund (PAF), which received

strong financial support by the external donors (World Bank, 2002). The local

governments were, in fact, allocated with the responsibility to deliver a growing share

of pro-poor expenditures tracked under the PAF, a share that rose to 60–70 % in the

early 2000s (Saito, 2006).

Page 8: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

3

However, the design of Uganda’s decentralisation programme as a strategy to

alleviate poverty requires continued reassessment and refinement, specifically the

extent to which local governments have been effectively empowered to deliver key

public services (Ahamad et al., 2006). First, the multiple layers of local government

which decentralisation introduced, has further increased government expenditure due

to bureaucracy and financial leakages resulting from increased rent-seeking (Brixiova

1999). Also, despite the fact that pro-poor government policies receive strong donor

support, they have led to a significant increase in public expenditure, particularly in

terms of the number of local civil servants. Following the introduction of Universal

Primary Education (UPE) in 1997, teacher numbers have risen considerably. Central

government has been faced with mounting education costs, above all the rising

teachers’ wage bill, which it does not have the financial resources to meet (World

Bank, 2002). Local governments have been charged with the responsibility of

delivering UPE on the ground, yet receive insufficient grants from the centre to do so,

and lack the power to raise funds themselves, due to the lack of fiscal decentralisation

(Saito, 2000).

In order to assess the real impact of education decentralisation on poverty reduction in

Uganda, the following section sets up a theoretical framework to explore the linkage.

Page 9: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

4

Theoretical Framework: Relationship between Poverty Reduction and

Decentralisation (of Education)

(Ting YAN)

The relationship between poverty reduction and decentralisation of education is

established based on the Sustainable Livelihoods Framework (SLF) (DFID, 1999).

Within this linkage, in particular, a theoretical framework which guides the whole

field trip is developed to exploare the pro-poor conditions of decentralisation.

I. Poverty reduction and Education

Since the 1990s, poverty and the processes that lead to poverty are conceived as

multidimensional and highly context-specific. According to the World Bank (2000,

pp.34), poverty is the result of:

• Lack of income and assets to attain basic necessities—food, shelter, clothing,

and acceptable levels of health and education

• Sense of voicelessness and powerlessness in the institutions of state and

society

• Vulnerability to adverse shocks, linked to an inability to cope with them

The SLF developed by DFID (1999) also promotes a systematic analysis of the

underlying processes and causes of poverty. It identifies the five assets poor people

own or have access to (HNFSP), based on which they can achieve their livelihoods

through livelihood strategies that are available to them.

Figure 1 The asset pentagon

Source: ibid.

From the SLF perspective, education helps achieve livelihood outcomes thus reducing

poverty in the following senses:

Page 10: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

5

• increasing Human Capital (the skills, knowledge and ability to labour);

• helping the poor make better use of the four other types of assets;

• being regarded as an end itself by the poor.

II. Decentralisation and its linkage to poverty reduction

Definition and Typology

Decentralisation is defined by Rondinelli (1981) as the transfer of authority to plan,

make decisions and manage public functions from a higher level of government to any

individual organization or agency at a lower level.

The underlying rationale of decentralisation is that a more decentralised state

apparatus will be more exposed and therefore more responsive to local needs and

aspirations (Crook and Sverrisson, 2001), which will produce systems of governance

that are more effective and accountable to local people (Blair, 2000; Crook and Manor,

1998; Manor, 1999; Rondinelli et al.., 1989).

Power that is transferred can be political, administrative or fiscal. Four types of

decentralisation are commonly recognised (Martinussen, 1997, pp.210-211):

• Deconcentration: the handing over of administrative or managerial

responsibility to sub-national units within line ministries or other sector-

specific national agencies.

• Delegation: public enterprises and other semiautonomous government

agencies are assigned responsibility for implementing sector investments or

for operating public utilities and services.

• Devolution: the transfer of authority and responsibility to regional or local

governments with their own discretionary authority.

• Privatisation: government agencies divesting themselves of responsibility for

project implementation or for providing infrastructure and services.

Linkages to Sustainable Livelihoods

The above types of decentralisation have potentials to transform structures and

processes of the society in a pro-poor way:

Page 11: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

6

Structures operate in cascading levels with varying degrees of autonomy and scope of

authority, depending upon the extent and nature of decentralisation (DFID, 1999).

Decentralisation can transform structures by:

• building structures that represent the poor;

• increasing the responsiveness of various organisations to the local preferences;

• (through privatisation) creating competitive markets valued for their economic

efficiency and ‘built in’ responsiveness to clients.

Decentralisation can transform certain processes by:

• Utilising local information to support a more pro-poor policy-making process;

• Deepening and strengthening the contact between the poor and policy makers;

• Promoting participatory processes of policy formulation;

• Increasing the accountability and transparency of public decision-making;

By transforming structures and processes in the above ways, education

decentralisation can contribute to poor people’s sustainable livelihoods through (See

Figure 2)

• increasing the five livelihood assets by improving education service delivery;

and

• a direct impact upon people’s feeling of inclusion and well-being

Figure 2 Decentralisation in SLF

Source: adapted from DFID (1999) and modified by the author

Page 12: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

7

III. Conditions for a pro-poor decentralisation

Decentralisation does not automatically bring the above pro-poor transformation (See

Appendix 1 for pros and cons). Only when “carefully planned, effectively

implemented and appropriately managed” (Work, 1999, pp.1), can decentralisation

transform the structures and processes in a pro-poor way. According to the WB (2001,

pp.1), decentralisation promotes effectiveness and efficiency when “the devolution of

functions occurs within an institutional environment that provides political,

administrative and financial authority to local governments, along with effective

channels of local accountability and central oversight”. Therefore, there are two levels

of conditions illustrated in Figure 3: central-local relations and local mechanisms.

Figure 3 Pro-poor conditions of decentralisation

Source: the author

Central-local relations:

• A central government with a political commitment to poverty reduction

• Autonomy and fiscal decentralisation: Local authorities need to have

enough fiscal control to plan their activities (WB, 2000, pp.107) while

“balancing autonomy and accountability” (Johnson, 2001, pp.13).

Page 13: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

8

• Central support is required to ensure that “national policies are adhered to

and to coordinate the interregional interests of different administrative units”

(ibid.)

• Safeguards are also needed to monitor financial probity and discourage the

capture of local bodies by powerful elites (ibid.).

Local mechanisms should also be developed for poor people to hold local authorities

accountable in order to avoid the ‘elite capture’ (Crook, 2003):

• Voice mechanism: representative democracy and diverse forms of

participatory democracy are needed for poor people to influence policies and

hold local authorities accountable.

• Information: local citizens should be informed of local politics and events to

make possible an effective participation.

• Exit mechanism: poor people can switch to non-public service providers

(private sector or civil society organisations) or to move to other localities

(WB, 2001). However, the state should also provide regulations to ensure that

the privatisation is pro-poor.

Page 14: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

9

Mission Scope and Objectives

(Matthew Bockarie)

Scope of the study The theoretical framework shows that under certain pro-poor conditions, education

decentralisation can greatly enhance the state’s capacity to improve education service

delivery thus reducing poverty and accelerating development. It is revealed that the

central-local relations and local mechanisms of decentralisation are the two main

conditions that favour the poor. In the case of decentralisation of education in Uganda,

we narrowed down our scope to financial capacity and autonomy for the research of

central-local relations, whilst voice, information, and exit have been focused on as

local mechanisms.

Since the aim of the field study is to gain an improved understanding of the factors

behind the early success of Uganda in poverty reduction and the recent fallback of the

process, the first step of this field work was to get an updated look at the

achievements and challenges of education service delivery in Mbarara district before

undertaking further studies on the above pro-poor conditions.

This ten-day field research from 2nd to 13 May 2007 was undertaken in Mbarara

Municipality by interviewing parents, teachers, head teachers, proprietors, pupils,

faith-based organizations, Education Quality Officers (ESA), educationist, local

councillors and district education officers. Decentralisation of education in Uganda

was only introduced in the primary education sector before the Universal Primary

Education (UPE) was declared and introduced in 1997 (Ministry of Education and

Sports, 2001) by the Government of Uganda, therefore the research focus is mainly at

the primary school level, but still involves views of interviewees from the secondary

education sector.

Page 15: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

10

Objectives of the study

• To assess the challenges and achievements of education in Mbarara district

• To determine the level of financial capacity and autonomy of local authorities in

Mbarara district.

• To find out whether the local people in Mbarara district are informed and have the

‘voice’ & ‘exit’ mechanisms to hold local authorities accountable in educational

service delivery.

• To make recommendations for further research and policy guidelines to enhance

effectiveness of education decentralisation in Uganda.

Page 16: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

11

Methodology

(Obeng-Odoom Franklin)

This section discusses the Research Design of this study. It begins with a set of

Research Questions and ends with a comment on how we describe the data for this

study.

Based on the research objectives, the key research questions to the study are:

1. Has education decentralisation improved the provision of education service

delivery in Mbarara?

2. Do the local authorities of Mbarara District have the financial capacity and

autonomy to provide education service to the local residents?

3. Are there effective mechanisms for local people to influence education

policies and hold authorities accountable?

Data Collection and Sampling

Both primary and secondary data were used. A review of relevant literature on

decentralization of education in Uganda was done before the actual field visit in order

to find out the state of decentralisation in education in Uganda with particular

reference to Mbarara. Following the above research questions, detailed field questions

were developed (See Appendix 2).

Primary data was collected through semi- and unstructured individual and group

interviews as well as through observations (see Laws et al., 2003).

Secondary data was collected from among others, publications, studies, district profile

on educational decentralization in Mbarara from sources like Educational Standards

Agency, Mbarara University, EPRC and Mbarara University of Science and

Technology. We also obtained data from the Ministry of Education (Mbarara branch).

Drawing the Sample

Because of the limited time, the research was focused on Mbarara Municipality. We

drew the sample at our convenience, which means that we used the convenience

sampling approach, where we drew the sample according to the accessibility and

Page 17: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

12

availability of data, taking into account the brief period within which this exercise had

to be undertaken. We took a sample of most of the major stakeholders in education

service delivery: One private and one public secondary school were visited. We also

visited two primary schools, one private and one public. Three government offices

and two faith-based organisations were also visited. Finally, one headmaster, seven

teachers, two parents and two groups/classes (primary) of students were visited. Time

and ease of access were the main measures of convenience.

Data Analysis

Our Analysis was preceded by a separation of all data obtained for this study into

quantitative data and qualitative data (see Agyedu et al., 1999) and summarised.

Beyond this step, similar responses have been put into common themes. Finally, the

data has been presented under each of the objectives to compare the trends in the

data before and after the introduction of decentralisation. This Before-After

Approach has enabled us to have a fair assessment of the effect of

decentralisation on education service delivery.

Qualitative data has been transformed into quantitative data by quantifying qualitative

issues like perception of education quality. However, much more emphasis has been

placed on the concepts they convey per se (Laws et al., 2003 and Willis, 2006).

Also, our analysis was undertaken with the stakeholders of education as we constantly

briefed them on how we were doing the analysis and sought their views on the

conclusions we were drawing. It should be noted that even though this method of

analysis is not conventional, it was used to prevent the common pitfall of jumping to

conclusions and to actively promote stakeholder participation in development research

(Laws et al., 2003)

Data Description and Interpretation

We have used a combination of quantitative indicators like ratios and percentages for

the description of data gathered. However, these have been balanced with qualitative

descriptions like the perceptions of our respondents. Interpretation has been done by

Page 18: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

13

comparing and contrasting the data with existing literature on Mbarara in particular

and Uganda in general.

Page 19: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

14

Institutional Landscape

(Fredrick Wamalwa and Ugochukwu Idika )

Appendix 3 shows the key stakeholders within the education sector in Uganda. In

terms of the institutional context, the functioning of Uganda’s decentralized education

works through the influence and interaction of a number of organizations and

individuals that can be traced from the international to local levels as below.

International level: Donors (International Community)

External donors are major political actors in Uganda (Ahikire, 2002). Uganda’s

poverty reduction strategies such SAPs, PRSPs and PEAP depend on financial and

technical support from external donors (Ssewakiryanga, 2004). For example, out of a

total cost of US$311 million budget for Universal Primary Education between 1998

and 2000, US$155 million was provided by the International Development

Association, of which US$75 million was a grant in the context of the HIPC Initiative

(World Bank Group, 2007)1. Donors are not just powerful because the country is aid

dependent, but because of the sophisticated relationship they have with the President,

Ministers, government institutions and civil society (Norton et al.., 2004).

National level: Central Government Level (Ministry of Education, MoE)

Although education is decentralized to the lower levels, the Central Government,

through Ministry of Education (MoE) influences the sector through its control over

funding and other policy procedures (Gershberg et al.. 2003). Generally, the central

government budgetary allocation to the sector has been increasing over time. By 2001,

43 percent of the total discretionary budget was allocated to education compared to 24

percent in 1996 (World Bank 2002, Gershberg et al. 2003). The MoE influences the

amount of funds allocated to each district. It’s also the central point where donor

funding to the sector is negotiated and channelled to the district. It also issues policy

guidelines on how funds should be used in schools (Saito, 2006). It also enforces

measures to ensure transparent and effective use of the funds by the lower units.

1See (http://www.reliefweb.int/rw/RWB.NSF/db900SID/RMOI-72KM8N?OpenDocument)

Page 20: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

15

Sub-National Level: Local Council Level

At the Sub-National level, educational matters are addressed through a Local Council

(LC) system. As shown in figure 4 below, LC is a hierarchical structure of councils

and committees that stretch from village LC1 to District LC5, linking up to the NRC

through the district representative appointed by the president (Local Government Act,

1997). Each Council is a supreme political organ in its jurisdiction2.

Figure 4 Five-tier RC System

Source: Saito, 2006

Principally, educational matters at a local level are channeled up through the various

levels until it reaches LC 5 with sufficient authority. Equally, centrally planned

directives are channeled downward until they are implemented at the local level. LC 5,

which is the highest organ at the district level, allocates funds to the Sub-counties

(lower local government) that are the service delivery points. It also recruits Head-

2 It is important to note that each Local Council is under an elected Chairman and Vice Chairman and other elected Councilors who constitute Councils and Committees. Education and Sports is one of the Committees. Importantly, at LC 2, all Village Executive Committees in a parish form the Electoral College and elect another Executive Committee with similar positions at that level. Also at LC4 the elected representatives at LC3 constitute the Electoral College from which an executive Committee is elected (Ahikire, 2002). Alongside elected councilors are administrators and civil services who assist in administration and implementation roles and are answerable to the Local Councilors (Local Government Act, 1997).

Page 21: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

16

teachers, influences their postage and supervises the construction of schools (Saito,

2006).

Local Level: School and Grassroots Level

Each school has a School Management Committee (SMC) whose members include

Parents Teachers Association (PTA) representatives, appointed members of the

education committee and members appointed by the Chief Education Officer (Saito,

2006). The SMC is a policy-making body for the school and function together with

head teachers as a leadership team to provide educational programmes and services

that ensure quality teaching and learning (Kateeba, 2006). However studies have

shown that SMC’s role overlaps with that the PTA, creating two centres of power

(Saito, 2006). Also, teachers feel threatened by the SME because there influence and

control over the school management reduced after the launch SME (Ahikire, 2002).

At the grassroots level are parents, pupils and the community at large. They have the

power to ensure that there is efficiency and effectiveness on the part of the

educational service providers discussed above, by voting out those who fail to deliver

(Kateeba, 2006).

Page 22: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

17

PART II Recommendations Report

Page 23: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

18

Field Trip Findings

Given the limited time in Mbarara, the findings are still preliminary and need further

research in the future. The following findings based on our research questions are

closely linked to research objectives:

1. Achievements and challenges of education service delivery in Mbarara District

Achievements:

∙ Following the decentralisation of education and subsequent launch of the UPE

policy in 1997, primary school enrolment in Mbarara District has greatly

increased: the number of primary students was 68,000 in 1996 and rose to

230,000 in 1997, which is consistent with the national trend over the past decade

(3.4 to 5.7 millions).

∙ In Mbarara Municipality gender equity has improved from a pre-1997 boy-girl-

enrolment-ratio of 55:45 to 49:51 following UPE (GoU, 2005).

∙ Decentralisation of education has enhanced collaboration among key

stakeholders in education. In different ways, the government, faith-based

organisations, donors and parents partner each other by pooling resources to build

schools and classrooms, provide scholastic materials, hire teachers and offer ways

to monitor and evaluate the quality of education.

∙ More funds (Inadequate though) have been channelled to teacher training colleges

to improve teacher quality.

∙ The increased demand for schools has also resulted in the establishment of more

private schools, thus increasing local school places.

Page 24: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

19

Challenges:

∙ The introduction of UPE has caused demand for school places to substantially

outstrip the supply of resources. Immediately after 1997, the pupil-classroom

ratio worsened from an average 1:45 to 1:115 for primary 1-4 and 1:80 for

primary 5-7. Primary 1-4 are particularly overcrowded as large numbers of poorer

parents seek to take advantage of the free education provided by government.

However, from primary 4-7, classrooms became less crowded as increased

number of students exit government schools due to poor education quality and

parental financial hardship. In spite of significant school and classroom

constructions in recent times, the pupil-classroom ratio (1:55) remains worse than

prior to UPE.

∙ Although schools are provided with learning materials, there is an acute lack of

text books to meet increased enrolments. Compared with pre-1997 levels of 1:2,

the pupil-textbook ratio has increased to 1:3 post-1997. Furthermore, teachers are

not usually consulted on the choice of the textbooks being supplied; consequently

some textbooks are irrelevant to classroom teaching.

∙ The academic performance has also declined greatly in government schools,

which was followed by the mushrooming of private schools with more

widespread ‘drilling’ teaching methods. The result is a high exam success rate in

private schools. For example, the percentage of pupils passing exams to enter

secondary school is averagely about 100% in Kabateraine Memorial Primary

School (private) compared with 60% in Mbarara Primary School (government).

Overall, it appears that even though there was a worsening of the quality of education

immediately after UPE, the situation is improving and many of our respondents are

optimistic of the quality of education in future.

Page 25: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

20

2. Financial capacity and autonomy of local authorities

An analysis of the findings from our fieldwork suggests that decentralisation has been

characterised by ‘deconcentration’ and ‘delegation’; ‘devolution’ of power has not

taken place. In addition, decentralisation remains administrative, with few evidence of

fiscal or political decentralisation. Consequently local authorities do not have the

financial capacity and autonomy to actively respond to local needs even if they are

accountable.

Financial capacity

Following the introduction of UPE and the resultant rise in enrolment rates,

government schools have insufficient resources due to the inadequate funds

transferred from central to local government. However, local governments lack the

authority to raise funds to fill this funding gap, due to the absence of fiscal

decentralisation, especially after the abolition of local ‘graduated tax’. The lack of

funds is compounded by the illegality of parental contributions to schools.

Nonetheless in many areas parents appear to largely ignore this ban and raise money

amongst themselves to ‘top-up’ the funding gap. In urban compared with rural areas,

parents tend to raise significantly higher top-up fees due to greater financial resources.

The Education Standards Agency (ESA), a semi-autonomous government body, also

lacks the necessary financial capacity to effectively carry out quality assurance in

schools. Whilst ESA has itself put in place the necessary administrative structures

and procedures for widespread inspections it suffers from a severe lack of resources.

For example, for the whole of Western Uganda, ESA has just one vehicle to use to

travel to schools.

Autonomy of local government and schools

The ability to deliver education services to meet local needs is adversely affected by

the lack of autonomy of local authorities and schools. Local education budgets are

calculated by central government based on the number of students enrolled in an area.

Local governments are not however empowered with the authority to determine how

Page 26: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

21

this budget is then spent; rather the budget is already ‘earmarked’ by central

government. For example, whilst Mbarara district education committee is allowed to

determine the geographical locations for the building of new schools, the council does

not have the power to decide the percentage of their own education budget which can

be spent on building new schools. Local authorities and schools are not able to devote

a larger proportion of the education budget to hiring more teachers or to pay teachers

a higher wage to incentivise performance. In fact, the budget local governments have

to spend on teachers and salary levels are both determined centrally. As result, local

authorities and schools are powerless to take steps to address vastly overcrowded

classrooms or poor teaching quality.

Whilst the administration of education services has theoretically been decentralised, in

reality a number of time-consuming bureaucratic processes remain which constrain

the ability of local authorities to effectively respond to specific local requirements.

For example, head teachers lack the necessary autonomy to take full responsibility

and accountability for the performance of their school.

As noted, decisions regarding policies and financial resources devoted to specific

educational requirements are made at a central level. In addition, there is no feedback

loop for local authorities and schools to voice local concerns and influence decisions

in order to address these issues.

Lack of financial capacity and autonomy prevents local authorities and schools from

making key decisions in response to local needs, even if they are accountable to local

people. However, this is also understandable, given the lack of local accountability

mechanisms, to avoid the local ‘elite capture’.

Page 27: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

22

3. Local mechanisms

Voice mechanism The School Management Committee (SMC), which is the current governing body in

public primary schools, is the major form of participation of parents in school affairs.

Its main role is to ensure the effective and accountable use of resources in the

provision of primary education. Two/three members of the Parent Teacher

Association (PTA) who have children in the school will represent the general parents

in SMC. However, it is revealed that usually well-educated and better-off parents are

elected by the general parents. In some cases members representing the PTA in SMC

may have already sent their children to other schools but remain in SMC, which

significantly compromises their representativeness.

In addition, even the parent representatives in SMC are less influential compared with

the other members in day-to-day management and school decision making processes.

On the other hand, apart from the PTA meetings there are few other channels for

parents to express their needs or to complain.

At the national policy level, parents often feel that there are hardly any government

policies and plans that have consulted local level stakeholders in the absence of

participatory democracy in spite of periodic elections.

Information It seems that parents are much more familiar with the Universal Primary Education

(UPE) policies than education decentralisation policies. However, due to unclear

information, they generally misunderstand UPE policies as if the government is

providing all educational facilities and resources when it promises free primary

education. But this intensified their disappointment especially when they found out

that they have to ‘top-up’ fees to fill up the financial gap to meet their own demand

for quality.

But at the school level, parents are well-informed of school affairs and events through

PTA meetings, where parents can also discuss their concerns on school issues.

Page 28: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

23

Exit mechanism

After the introduction of UPE system, due to the general belief that the quality of

government schools declined tremendously, private schools have mushroomed.

Interestingly, the “exit mechanism” is controversial in a pro-poor sense.

There is a ‘clustering effect’ as a result of the exit mechanism. Since the financial

contribution is usually initiated by parents themselves, the amount of top-up fees is

decided through consensus building. Therefore, when poor parents cannot afford the

amount agreed upon, they either contribute in other forms (e.g. labour) or pull their

children out of this school (drop-out or switch to affordable schools). Usually local

awareness of high top-up fees can deter poorer parents from sending their children to

this school in the first place. On the other hand, rich parents who are willing to pay

more would pull their children out either to private schools or to richer public schools.

The result is a ‘clustering effect’ that poor children tend to remain together in poor

schools with relatively low education quality while rich parents tend to gather

together and top up fees to meet their higher demands.

This effect is also believed to be nationwide, as the result of the emergence of an

‘education market’ whereby the quality of a school a child attends is determined by

the financial resources of his/her parents. It exacerbates the rich/poor divide in

Uganda, which tends to coincide with the urban/rural divide. Whilst education

provides a means by which individuals can be lifted out of poverty, the existence of a

‘market’ inhibits education provision reaching the poorest in society.

Page 29: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

24

Recommendations

Based on the above findings, the following areas are recommended for future

research:

Financial capacity and autonomy of local authorities:

∙ The feasibility of fiscal decentralisation in Uganda to improve education

service delivery;

∙ How can financial resources and autonomy transferred to local authorities

be balanced with their accountability to avoid local ‘elite capture’?

Local mechanisms:

∙ The role of decentralisation in enabling greater participation amongst

parents in order to influence education policy and service delivery;

∙ The impact of an “education market” and the resulting “clustering effect”

on the equitable distribution of quality education provision.

Other:

∙ Since Universal Secondary Education (USE) has just been introduced in

Uganda, a comparison between decentralised UPE & centralised USE

would be possible in the future (e.g. in 5 years) to determine whether

decentralisation is a critical factor in education service provision.

Strategy Guidelines

Fully aware of the risk of ‘elite capture’ at the local level, we recommend that before

more financial resources and autonomy are transferred from the center to local

authorities, the PEAP policy needs to enhance local accountability mechanisms and

deepen the participatory democracy:

∙ Parent representatives in SMC need to have their children attending the

schools

∙ Create more channels for poor parents to participate in school affairs and

educational policy planning.

Page 30: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

25

∙ Inform and sensitise parents about education policies through mass media,

more contact between parents and local authorities, etc.

However, while enhancing local accountability, the financial resources and

autonomy of local authorities should also follow up gradually and cautiously:

∙ Create channels for local authorities to give feedback and influence the

budget allocation of the center.

∙ Empower local authorities to generate their own funds and determine the

use of their budget

∙ Grant more resources to school inspection agencies

Page 31: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

26

Bibliography

Agyedu et al., 1999, Teach Yourself Research Methods, UCEWK

Ahamad, E, Brosio, G, 2006, “Uganda: Managing More Effective Decentralization’

(IMF working Paper, December 2006) [http://www.Ahamad et

al., .org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2006/wp06279.pdf] (Accessed on 29.04.2007) Ahikire, J, 2006, “Decentralisation in Uganda Today: Institutions and Possible

Outcomes in the Context of Human Rights”, A Presentation of the

International Council on Human Rights Policy Decentralisation, Local

Government and Human

Rights,[ http://www.ichrp.org/paper_files/116_w_06.doc](accessed on

28.4.2007)

Avenstrup et al., 2004, Reducing Poverty, Sustaining Growth.What Works, What

Doesn”t, and Why A Global Exchange for Scaling Up Success, Scaling Up

Poverty Reduction: A Global Learning Process and Conference.

Blair, Harry, 2000, “Participation and Accountability at the Periphery: Democratic

Local Governance in Six Countries”, World Development, Vol.28, No.1,

pp.21-39

Brixiova, Z., 1998, “Public Service Reform,” Uganda: Selected Issues and Statistical

Appendix, AHAMAD ET AL., Staff Country Report No. 98/61 (Washington:

International Monetary Fund). June 1998

Brixiova, Z., 1998, “Public Service Reform,” Uganda: Selected Issues and Statistical

Appendix, IMF Staff Country Report No. 98/61 Washington: International

Monetary Fund). June 1998

Crook, Richard C. and James Manor, 1998, Democracy and Decentralisation in South

Asia and West Africa, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Crook, Richard C. and Alan Sturla Sverrisson, 2001, “Decentralisation and poverty

alleviation in developing countries: a comparative analysis or, is West Bengal

unique?” IDS Working Paper 130, Brighton: Institute of Development Studies.

Crook R, 2003, ‘Decentralisation and poverty reduction in Africa: The politics of

local-central relations’, Public Administration and Development, vol. 23, No.1,

pp. 77-88

Page 32: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

27

Dauda ,L, Carol, 2004 The Importance of De Facto Decentralization in Primary

Education in Sub-Saharan Africa PTAs and Local Accountability in Uganda

Published by www.sagepublications.

DFID, 1999, “Framework for Sustainable Livelihoods”, Sustainable Livelihoods

Guidance Sheets,

[http://www.livelihoods.org/info/guidance_sheets_pdfs/section2.pdf]

ICHRP, 2002, Local Rule: Decentralisation and Human Rights, International Council

on Human Rights Policy, Versoix, Switzerland.

Gershberg, Alec Ian, and Donald R. Winkler, 2003, Education Decentralisation in

Africa: A Review of Recent Policy and Practice, draft

[http://info.worldbank.org/etools/docs/library/94808/Education%20Decentrali

zation%20in%20Africa.pdf]

Goldman, Ian, 1998, “Decentralisation and Sustainable Rural Livelihoods”, in Carney,

D. (ed) Sustainable Rural Livelihoods: What Contribution Can We Make?

London, Department for International Development

Government of Uganda, Local Government Act 1997

Johnson, Craig, 2001, “Local Democracy, Democratic Decentralisation and Rural

Development: Theories, Challenges and Options for Policy”, Development

Policy Review, Forthcoming

Kappel R, Lay Jann and Steiner,2005 ‘Uganda:No More Pro-poor Growth?’ in

Development Policy Review, 2005, 23 (1):27-53

Kateeba, P, 2006, “Quality in Education Teaching and Leadership in Challenging

Times”, Aga Khan University, Karachi,

[http://www.aku.edu/ied/conference2006/abstracts/022.asp] (Accessed on

23.04.2007)

Langseth, Peter, 1995, “Civil Service Reform in Uganda: Lessons Learned,” Public

Administration and Development, Vol. 15, No. 4, pp. 365-90.

Laws S, Harper C and Marcus R, 2003, Research for Development, Sage Publications

Makara, S, 1998, Political and Administrative relations in decentralization, in A.

Nsibambi, (ed.) Decentralisation and Civil Society in Uganda: The Quest for

Good Governance, Fountain Publishers, Kampala

Manor, J., 1999, The Political Economy of Democratic Decentralisation, Washington

DC: World Bank.

Page 33: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

28

Martinussen, John, 1997, Society, State and Market: A Guide to Competing Theories

of Development, chapter 15, Zed Books, London

Ministry of Education and Sports Uganda, 2001,The Development of Education in

Uganda in the last ten years, Report on the Development of Education for the

46th Session of (ice) 5th, Geneva,

Muduuli, 2006, “Uganda’s Poverty Eradication Action Plan: National Sustainable

Development Strategy Principles Tested” A presentation at international

forum on national sustainable Development Strategies (NSDSs) (Accra, Ghana,

7-9 November 2001)

OECD and African Development Bank, 2005, ‘African Economic Outlook 2004/05:

Uganda’, OECD Emerging Economies, Number 5, pages 425-437, OECD

Development Centre, Paris

Piron L and Norton A, 2004, ‘Politics and the PRSP Approach: Ugandan Case Study’,

working paper presented at the Overseas Development Institute on March

2004

Republic of Uganda (ROU) The Local Governments Act 1997,

(http://www.opsi.gov.uk/ACTS/acts1997/1997065.htm)

Rondinelli, D.A., 1981, “Government Decentralization in Comparative Perspective:

Theory and Practice in Developing Countries”, International Review of

Administrative Sciences, Vol. 47: 22-42.

Rondinelli, Dennis, J.S. McCullough and R.W. Jonhnson, 1989, “Analyzing

decentralisation policies in developing countries: a political economy

framework”, Development and Change, Vol.20, No.1, pp.57-87

Saito, F, 2000, “Decentralization for Participatory Development in Uganda:

Limitations and Prospects,” Journal of Intercultural Studies, Ryukoku

University

Saito, F, 2006, “Decentralization in Uganda: Challenges for the 21st Century”, Yuck

University, Japan,

[http://www.world.ryukoku.ac.jp/~fumisait/en/ics2000.pdf](accessed on

12.4.2007).

Shaw M.Timothy and Mbabazi P, nd, ‘Two Africas? Two Ugandas? An African

Democratic Developmental State? Or another failed state?’, conference paper

Page 34: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

29

Steffensen, J, Per T, Harriet N, E Ssewankambo, Eke, M, 2004, “A Comparative

Analysis of Decentralization in Kenya, Tanzania, and Uganda,” Final

Synthesis Report, (Washington: The World Bank).

Sswwankiryanga, R, 2004, “Donor dependant Decentralisation and the political

Economy of Aid in Uganda”, Center for Basic Research, Working paper

No.91/2004

Willis K, 2006, ‘Interviewing’ in Desai V and Potter R.B.(editors) Doing

Development Research, Sage Publications, pp.144-152

Work, Robertson, 1999, The Role of Participation and Partnership in Decentralised

Governance: A Brief Synthesis of Policy Lessons and Recommendations of

Nine Country Case Studies on Service Delivery for the Poor

[http://www.unescap.org/pdd/mdg/sharedoc/busdirectory/doc/participationand

partnershippdf.pdf]

World Bank, 2000, World Development Report 2000/1: Attacking Poverty, Oxford

University Press, Oxford

World Bank, 2001, “Decentralisation and governance: does decentralisation improve

public service delivery?” PREM notes, June 2001, Number 55

World Bank, 2002, “Achieving Universal Primary Education in Uganda: The Big

Bang Approach”

[http://siteresources.worldbank.org/EDUCATION/Resources/Education-

World Bank, 2007, “A better managed education system in Uganda”,

[http://www.reliefweb.int/rw/RWB.NSF/db900SID/RMOI-

72KM8N?OpenDocument](Accessed on 12.4.2007)

WRI, World Resource Institute, n.d. “Decentralisation: Can It Help the Poor?”

[http://pubs.wri.org/pubs_content_text.cfm?ContentID=3782]

Page 35: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

30

Appendix 1

Pros and Cons of Decentralisation

Pros Cons

Promotes democracy because it provides better opportunities for local residents to participate in decision-making.

Undermines democracy by empowering local elites, beyond the reach or concern of central government.

Increases efficiency in delivery of public services; delegation of responsibility avoids bottlenecks and bureaucracy.

Worsens delivery of service in the absence of effective controls and oversight.

Provides a chance for poor households to participate in local institutions and have their concerns recognized.

Local institutions mirror the anti-poor biases present at the state level.

Leads to higher quality of public services because of local accountability and sensitivity to local needs.

Quality of services deteriorates due to lack of local capacity and insufficient funds.

Enhances social and economic development, which relies on local knowledge.

Gains arising from participation by local people offset by increased corruption and inequalities among regions.

Increases transparency, accountability, and the response-capacity of government institutions.

Promises too much and overloads capacity of local governments.

Allows greater political representation for diverse political, ethnic, religious, and economic groups in decision-making.

Creates new tensions or ignites dormant ethnic and religious rivalries.

Increases political stability and national unity by allowing citizens to better control public programs at the local level.

Weakens states because it can increase regional inequalities, lead to separatism, or undermine national financial governance.

Source: WRI, n.d. Adapted from ICHRP 2002

Page 36: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

31

Appendix 2

Research Questions (RQ)

1. Has education decentralisation improved the provision of education service

delivery in Mbarara?

2. Do the local authorities of Mbarara District have the financial capacity and

autonomy to provide education service to the local residents?

3. Are there effective mechanisms for local people to influence education

policies and hold authorities accountable?

4. RQ 1: Has education decentralisation improved the provision of

education service delivery in Mbarara?

‘Improved education service delivery’ is explained here as greater access to

education and higher quality education which also includes gender equality. To

measure this, the perceptions of all our respondents were sought.

In addition, Headmasters, Education Quality Inspectors, Teachers, Proprietors,

Parents and Education officers were as appropriate, asked questions like the

following (based on Shaw, nd, OECD and ADB, 2005, Kappel et al., 2005)

1. How many students have enrolled in schools from 1997 to date?

2. What is the rate of enrolment, pre and post UPE?

3. What are the Repetition and drop-out rates in the schools, before and after

UPE?

4. What is the completion rate of students, before and after UPE?

5. What has been the boy-girl ratio of total students enrolled before and after

UPE?

6. What has the Pupil-teacher ratio, before and after UPE?

7. What has the Pupil-textbook ratio been, before and after the introduction of

UPE?

Page 37: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

32

8. What types of textbooks are supplied? (All required or some of them?)

9. Has the introduction of UPE enhanced/worsened the supply of textbooks in

Q8

10. What is the Pupil-classroom ratio? Is it worse or better than before the

introduction UPE?

11. What has been the Pupil-desk ratio, pre and post UPE?

12. What is the Trained Teacher-Untrained Teacher ratio?

13. What is the Transition Gap from primary to secondary schools?

RQ 2: Do the local authorities of Mbarara District have the financial capacity

and autonomy to provide education service to the local residents?

This question broadly seeks to examine whether education decentralisation is

deconcentrated, delegated or devolved. In terms of ‘capacity’ institutions are to

have the financial ability and human resources to deliver decentralised education

services. ‘Autonomy’ refers to local authorities and schools having the necessary

independence from central government to meet specific local needs.

To measure this, the Education Quality Inspectors at ESA and the Education

Officers at MOE were interviewed. The Secretary of Education at Local Councillor

(LC5) and past members of SMCs were also interviewed using a semi-structured

interview approach and secondary data from the district education office. Key

questions to obtain evidence in this regard are based on Piron and Norton (2004):

1. Do local authorities receive sufficient funds from central government?

2. Do local authorities have the authority and capacity to raise funds locally?

3. Are schools permitted to ask parents to make contributions/pay top-up fees at

government schools?

4. To what extent are local authorities and schools able to independently

determine how education funds from central government are spent?

a. are the details of how the education budget is allocated calculated

locally in order to meet specific local needs?

5. How are headmasters recruited?

Page 38: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

33

6. Who determines changes in teacher salaries?

7. Who and How frequently are government schools inspected?

8. Are local authorities and schools able to recruit/train teachers independently?

9. Are schools able to effectively fire teachers as required?

10. Do schools/local authorities have the voice and authority to influence central

government education policy and spending, based on experiences from the

‘delivery side’.

RQ 3: Are there effective mechanisms for local people to influence education

policies and hold authorities accountable?

This question falls within the remit of participation. Participation is effective when

first there is greater inclusiveness. But it is not enough just to have many people

taking part in decision making. There should be quality of participation as well

which means gender balance. Finally participation can only be effective when what

participants’ preferences are heard/carried out (Crook, 2003). Inferentially, if

participants’ views are ignored or unheard, they should be able to exit.

In order to determine the effectiveness of participation within education

decentralisation, we interviewed past members of the SMC and Parents using semi

structured interview approach. The following questions were asked:

Voice

1. What is the composition of the SMC? (total number/gender etc)

2. How is the SMC formed (appointment/election by whom)?

3. How can the SMC be dissolved (ie if election how often? If appointment, how

can the committee’s mandate be ended?)?

4. What is the tenure of the SMC?

5. Are parents’ wishes carried out by the SMC/ Is the SMC responsive to what

parents want?

6. Is the decision-making process in SMC through consensus building or voting?

Page 39: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

34

7. Are there any other forms of participation for parents to be involved in school

affairs?

8. Do parents, as citizens themselves, have other channels to express their views at

other institutions (besides periodic elections)?

Information

9. Do parents understand the general education policies (both education

decentralisation and UPE policies) properly?

10. How are parents informed of school affairs and events as well as local politics?

Exit

11. What kinds of parents pull their children out of the UPE schools? Why?

12. Where do these parents take their children to after pulling them out of the

schools?

Do private schools generally provide better education quality than

government aided UPE schools?

Page 40: POVERTY REDUCTION AND EDUCATION DECENTRALISATION IN UGANDA

35

Appendix 3

Key Stakeholders in the education sector of Uganda

1. Donors

2. Ministry of Education

3. Ministry of Finance

4. Ministry of Local Government

5. Local Councillors (at levels LC1 to LC5)

6. Civil Servants and Administrators

7. Teachers

8. Parents

9. Pupils