ph.d. dissertation in agricultural extension faculteit...while there is no consensus on a...

186
Shiraz University Faculty of Agriculture Ph.D. Dissertation In Agricultural Extension EXPLAINING THE EQUILIBRIUM BETWEEN LIVESTOCK AND RANGELAND USING FUZZY LOGIC By HOSSEIN AZADI NASRABAD Supervised by Dr. Mansour Shahvali Dr. Nezameddin Faghih December 2005

Upload: dinhdieu

Post on 22-May-2018

213 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Shiraz University

Faculty of Agriculture

Ph.D. Dissertation

In Agricultural Extension

EXPLAINING THE EQUILIBRIUM

BETWEEN LIVESTOCK AND RANGELAND

USING FUZZY LOGIC

By

HOSSEIN AZADI NASRABAD

Supervised by

Dr. Mansour Shahvali

Dr. Nezameddin Faghih

December 2005

IN THE NAME OF GOD

EXPLAINING THE EQUILIBRIUM

BETWEEN LIVESTOCK AND RANGELAND

USING FUZZY LOGIC

BY

HOSSEIN AZADI NASRABAD

DISSERTATION

SUBMITTED TO THE SCHOOL OF GRADUATE STUDIES IN PARTIAL

FULFILMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF

DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY (PH.D.)

IN

AGRICULTURAL EXTENSION

SHIRAZ UNIVERSITY

SHIRAZ

ISLAMIC REPUBLIC OF IRAN

EVALUATED AND APPROVED BY THE THESIS COMMITTEE AS: EXCELLENT

MANSOUR SHAHVALI, Ph.D., …………………………………………… ASSOCIATE PROF., DEPT. OF AGRICULTURAL EXTENSION & EDUCATION, SHIRAZ UNIVERSITY.

Supervisor

(Chairman)

NEZAMEDDIN FAGHIH, Ph.D., ……...……………...…………………… PROF., DEPT. OF MANAGEMENT, SHIRAZ UNINIVERSITY.

Supervisor

JAN VAN DEN BERG, Ph.D., ..…………………………………..………… ASSOCIATE PROF., DEPT. OF COMPUTER SCIENCE, ERASMUS UNIVERSITY ROTTERDAM.

Advisor

HOSSEIN MARZBAN, Ph.D., ……...……………………...……………….. ASSISSTANT PROF., DEPT. OF ECONOMICS, SHIRAZ UNIVERSITY.

Advisor

AHMAD KHTOONABADI, Ph.D., .…………………………...……………

ASSISSTANT PROF., DEPT. OF RURAL DEVELOPMENT, ISFAHAN UNIVERSITY OF TECHNOLOGY.

Advisor

MOHMMAD JAVAD ZAMIRI, Ph.D., …………………………………..... PROF., DEPT. OF ANIMAL SCIENCE, SHIRAZ UNIVERSITY.

Advisor

DECEMBER 2005

Dedicated to:

Anahita

for all her sympathies

i

Acknowledgements

All praises belong to Allah, The Most Gracious and Most Merciful, for His blessings that enabled me to accomplish this dissertation. This study is a product of many hands that directly and indirectly pushed me to gait the next steps. It is my pleasure to express my gratitude to individuals for their help and supports. My special word of thanks goes to Dr. Mansour Shahvali, my first supervisor, for his continuous supports not only during the course of this study but also in all other my academic activities. I am also grateful to Dr. Nezameddin Faghih, my second supervisor for his directions to set up this research, especially during the initial stages of planning the work. It would be a great honor for me to convey my sincere gratitude to Dr. Jan van den Berg, for his great contribution to solve my educational and residential problems during my stay in the Netherlands. My sincere gratitude goes to Dr. Hossein Marzban, Dr. Ahmad Khatoonabadi and Dr. Mohammad Javad Zamiri for sharing their knowledge and experiences to conduct this study. Many thanks go to Dr. Gholam Hossein Zamani; the head of Department of Agricultural Extension and Education at Shiraz University and my other respected teachers, Prof. Dr. Ezatollah Karami, Dr. Dariush Hayati and Mohammad Bagher Lari for all their supports during my university studies. I am also thankful to Mr. Ali Kheradmand, Mr. Asghar Sahranavard, Ms. Tooran Jezghani, Khalighzadeh, Adeli, and Paydar for all their helps. Special thanks go to my dearest classmate, Dr. Kiumars Zarafshani who is the best friend for me. Also, to my other classmates, especially Dr. Nozar Monfared and Dr. Ahmad Abedi. I am grateful to the pastoralists and the experts of various administrations in Fars province, especially Talati, Riahi, Haddadi, Mansoori and Mohseni. My greatest gratitude goes to my beloved wife, Anahita Aghaei for her supports, prayers, and unlimited patience during this long-term study. My special gratitude goes to Jozef Caluwaerts and my mother-in-law for all their continual supports. Finally, to my mother, father and family for all their endless supports.

Hossein Azadi Nasrabad

Shiraz University, Iran

December 2005

ii

Abstract

While there is no consensus on a definition, it is widely recognized that the concept of sustainability has economic, environmental and social dimensions. We used fuzzy logic as a well-suited tool to handle the vague, uncertain, and polymorphous concept of sustainability. For recognizing the major important indicators in defining sustainability in rangeland management, several semi-structured interviews with an open-ended questionnaire were held in three different areas of the Fars province in Southwest Iran. Different groups of ‘experts’ were chosen by using the ‘socio-metric’ sampling method, and were interviewed. Pastoralists’ experts recognized that sustainability in rangeland management is a function of three major components (inputs) which are the Stocking Rate in a rangeland, the amount of Plantation Density per hectare, and the Number of

Pastoralists who live in a rangeland where the output of the model is the Right

Rate of Stocking. Based on pastoralists’ insights we developed a model called Equilibrium Assessment by Fuzzy Logic (EAFL) which provides a mechanism for assessing sustainability in rangeland management. The EAFL model exhibits five important characteristics. First, it permits the combination of various aspects of sustainability with different units of measurement. Second, it overcomes the difficulty of assessing certain attributes or indicators of sustainability without precise quantitative criteria. Third, it supports researcher with an easy to use and interpret. Fourth, considering the sequence "crisp input – fuzzifier – inference engine – defuzzifier – crisp output", it illustrates the uncertainity that exists in such a complex vague concept as sustainable rangeland management, and fifth, it also well adjusts to usual ambigious linguistic statements of individuals. To deal with the heterogeneity of experts’ knowledge, which should be considered either as a reality or necessity, a multi-fuzzy model was developed. In order to find the final output of the multi-fuzzy model, different ‘voting’ methods were applied. The mean method simply uses the arithmetic average of the primary outputs as the final output of the multi-fuzzy model. This final output represents an estimation of the Right Rate of Stocking. By harmonizing the primary outputs such that outliers get less emphasis, an unsupervised voting method calculating a weighted estimate of the Right Rate of Stocking was introduced. This harmonizing method is expected to provide a new useful tool for policymakers in order to deal with heterogeneity in experts’ opinions: it is especially useful in cases where little field data is available and one is forced to rely on experts’ knowledge only. By constructing the three fuzzy models based on the heterogeneous knowledge and using some harmonized methods, our study tried to show the multi-dimensional vaguenesses which generally exist in rangeland management, and solve the conflict that especially exists in economical and conservational views in the Iranian rangeland management. Finally, by comparing the estimated Right Rate of

Stocking, which elicited from both experts' opinions and Matlab Fuzzytoolbox Editor, with its medium range, the models verified overgrazing in the three regions of the Fars province in Southwest Iran.

iii

Contents Acknowledgement ……………………………………………………………………… i Abstract ………………………………………………………………………………….. ii Chapter One – Introduction …………………………………………………………… 1

1.1. Prelude …………………………………………………………………………... 1

1.2. Population Growth ……………………………………………………………… 3

1.3. Current challenges in rangeland management ………………………………… 4

1.4. Defining the problem …………………………………………………………… 6

1.5. Objectives ……………………………………………………………………….. 9

1.5.1. General goal ………………………………………………………………… 9 1.5.2. Specific goals ……………………………………………………………….. 9

1.6. The structure of dissertation ……………………………………………………. 10

Chapter Two - Population Growth: Consequences …………………………………. 11

2.1. Population growth ………………………………………………………………. 11

2.1.1. A general view ……………………………………………………………… 11 2.1.2. Three possible scenarios ……………………………………………………. 13

2.1.2.1. Low scenario …………………………………………………………… 14 2.1.2.2. Medium scenario ……………………………………………………….. 16 2.1.2.3. High scenario …………………………………………………………… 18

2.2. Consequences …………………………………………………………………… 20

2.2.1. A historical challenge ………………………………………………………. 21 2.2.2. Food security ………………………………………………………………... 23 2.2.3. Food consumption …………………………………………………………... 26 2.2.4. Agricultural research ………………………………………………………... 28 2.2.5. Biotechnology ………………………………………………………………. 30 2.2.6. Arable land ………………………………………………………………….. 33 2.2.7. Water scarcity ………………………………………………………………. 37 2.2.8. Forestry and fisheries ……………………………………………………….. 42 2.2.9. Rangelands …………………………………..……………………………... 43

2.3. Conclusion ………………………………………………………………………. 45

Chapter Three - Sustainability: Basic Challenges ………………………………...… 48

3.1. Importance ……………………………………………………………………… 48

3.2. Definitions ……………………………………………………………………… 51

3.3. Dimensions ……………………………………………………………………… 53

3.4. Modeling problems ……………………………………………………………... 55

3.5. Conclusion ……………………………………………………………………… 59

Chapter Four - Rangeland Management: Basic Challenges and Principles ………. 61

4.1. A review of literature …………………………………………………………… 61

4.2. Rangeland management: Art or science? ……………………………………… 63

4.3. Equilibrium and disequilibrium systems in rangeland management …………. 64

4.4. Current challenges in rangeland management ………………………………… 66

4.4.1. Overgrazing ………………………………………………………………… 66 4.4.2. Carrying capacity …………………………………………………………… 68

4.5. Basic principles in rangeland management ……………………………………. 70

4.6. Conclusion ……………………………………………………………………… 77

Chapter Five - Application of Fuzzy Logic in Sustainable Rangeland Management ………………………………………………………

82

5.1. Fuzzy Logic: A shifting paradigm ……………………………………………... 82

iv

5.2. Foundations of fuzzy logic ……………………………………………………... 85

5.2.1. Crisp models ………………………………………………………………... 85 5.2.2. Boolean vs. Fuzzy ………………………………………………………….. 86 5.2.3. Towards soft computing ……………………………………………………. 87 5.2.4. Towards fuzzy sets ………………………………………………………….. 89 5.2.5. Operators on fuzzy sets ……………………………………………………... 89 5.2.6. Linguistic variables …………………………………………………………. 90 5.2.7. Knowledge representation by fuzzy IF-Then rules …………………………. 91 5.2.8. Architecture of fuzzy systems ………………………………………………. 92 5.2.9. Fuzzy reasoning …………………………………………………………….. 92

5.3. Theoretical frameworks ………………………………………………………… 94

5.3.1. Architecture the EAFL model ………………………………………………. 94 5.3.2. Architecture of multi-fuzzy model …………………………………………. 96

Chapter Six - Research Method ……………………………………………………….. 100

6.1. The population of study ………………………………………………………… 100

6.2. The area of study ………………………………………………………………... 103

6.3. Research method ………………………………………………………………... 106

6.3.1. Multiple-case study …………………………………………………………. 108

6.4. Sampling method ………………………………………………………………... 109

6.5. Data collection and applied techniques ………………………………………... 110

6.5.1. Data analysis ………………………………………………………………... 111 Chapter Seven - Fuzzy Analysis and Discussion ……………………………………. 112

7.1. Development the EAFL model ………………………………………………… 112

7.1.1. Determining the relevant input and output variables ……………………….. 112 7.1.2. Defining linguistic values …………………………………………………... 112 7.1.3. Constructing membership function …………………………………………. 113 7.1.4. Determining the fuzzy rules ………………………………………………… 114 7.1.5. Computing degree of membership of crisp inputs ………………………….. 116 7.1.6. Detemining approximate reasoning ………………………………………… 117 7.1.7. Computing crisp output (defuzzify) ………………………………………… 118 7.1.8. Assessing the model performance ………………………………………….. 119

7.2. Development the multi-fuzzy model …………………………………………... 121

7.2.1. Computing the crisp primary outputs ………………………………………. 124 7.2.2. Implementing voting ………………………………………………………... 128

7.2.2.1. Method 1: Calculating the mean of outputs ……………………………... 128 7.2.2.2. Method 2: Minimizing the sum of squared errors ……………………….. 130 7.2.2.3. Method 3: Minimizing an approximation of the sum of squared errors …... 130 7.2.2.4. Method 4: Harmonizing the primary outputs ……………………………. 131

7.2.3. Comparison of Method 1 and Method 4 ……………………………………. 134

Chapter Eight - Summary and Conclusions ………………………………………….. 139

8.1. Summary ………………………………………………………………………… 139

8.2. Conclusions ……………………………………………………………………... 141

Bibliography …………………………………………………………………………….. 145

APPENDIX 1 ………………………………………………………………………….... 165

APPENDIX 2 ………………………………………………………………………….... 166

v

Tables Table 2.1. The projection of world population (Medium scenario) 1950-2050. …………. 16 Table 2.2. Water scarcity by country groups. ……………………………………………. 41 Table 6.1. General information of the three regions of the study. ……………………….. 105 Table 6.2. Some personal characteristics of 9 nominated experts at the first round of

study……………………………………………………………………………

109 Table 7.1. Linguistic values used in the EAFL model. …………………………………... 113 Table 7.2. The complete rules base (33 = 27) used to construct the overall experts’

knowledge base. …...………………………………………………………….

115 Table 7.3. Assessing the performance of the EAFL model by using real data. ………….. 119 Table 7.4. Inputs, linguistic values and fuzzy range of each experts. ……………………. 122 Table 7.5. Characteristics of the output (RRS) for three fuzzy models. ………………….. 124 Table 7.6. Computing the outputs of the first model with 5 cases for each region. ……… 125 Table 7.7. Computing the outputs of the second model with 5 cases for each region. …... 126 Table 7.8. Computing the outputs of the third model with 5 cases for each region. …….. 127 Table 7.9. Finding the final outputs by calculating the mean of primary outputs. …….… 128 Table 7.10. Estimating the final output RRSf by calculating the sum of weighted outputs

for separated regions according to Method 4. ………………………………..

133

vi

Figures Fig. 2.1. World population: Three possible futures. ……………………………………... 13 Fig. 2.2. World Population and Arable Land, 1700 – 1990. ……………………………... 35 Fig. 5.1. Diagrammatic representation of the linguistic variable stocking rate in a

rangeland having linguistic values low, medium, and high defined by a corresponding membership function. …………………………………………..

91 Fig. 5.2. Building blocks of a Fuzzy Inference System (FIS). …………………………… 92 Fig. 5.3. Scheme of development of the EAFL model applying approximate reasoning to

assess the Right Rate of Stocking (RRSp) based on the inputs values (I1p, I2p, and

I3p). …...…………………………………………………………………………

95 Fig. 5.4. Architecture of the multi-fuzzy model to deal with different experts’

knowledge. ……………………………………………………………………...

98 Fig. 7.1. Membership functions for a) Stocking Rate, b) Plantation Density, and c)

Number of Pastoralists. ………………………………………………………...

114 Fig. 7.2. Linguistic values and fuzzification of crisp inputs for a) Stocking Rate, b)

Plantation Density, and c) Number of Pastoralists ……………………………..

116 Fig. 7.3. Graphical illustration of the EAFL model for approximate reasoning and

defuzzification. …………………………………………………………………

118 Fig. 7.4. Comparison of the RRSf for the harmonized method and mean method. ………. 135

1

Chapter One

Introduction

1.1. Prelude

At the beginning of this century, it is important to care the scarcity of

resources and food for everyone. This shortage has made a major

challenge for policy-makers. Population growth on one hand and

production diversification on the other has made a dilemma in natural

resources management. At the ecological level, land scarcity is

causing food scarcity for the ever-increasing population. Brown et al.,

(2000) believe that:

• Resources are becoming scarce,

• Natural species and forests are destroyed which also leads to

destruction of wildlife and fisheries, and

• Air pollution is causing contamination faster than it can be

recovered.

Scientists believe that the number one cause of environmental

contamination is “over consumption”. In spite of major development

in 1950s and 1960s, the recent socio-cultural and environmental crises

have caused a major destruction in sustaining natural resources. This

has led to the new development under the label of sustainability.

Sustainable Development (SD) is nowadays the goal in words at least,

of most politicians and decision makers (Rigby et al., 2001). Since

publication of the Brundtland report in 1987 (WCED, 1987; p. 43), the

concept of SD was defined as "development that meets the needs of

2

the present without compromising the ability of future generations to

meet their own needs".

Demands for natural resources are recently high among rural areas.

Most people in developing countries are agrarians and pastorals. In

1988 some 65 percent of the population in what the World Bank

classified as low-income countries were living in rural areas. The

share of the labour force engaged in agriculture in these countries was

a bit higher, and agriculture accounted for about 30 percent of GDP.

In industrial countries, by contrast, agriculture accounted for 6 percent

of the labour force and 2 percent of GDP (Dasgupta and Maler, 1995).

For most part developing countries have biomass-based subsistence

economies, in that rural people live on products obtained directly from

plants and animals (Dasgupta, 1996). Studies in Central and West

Africa have shown how vital natural resource products are to the lives

of rural inhabitants (Falconer, 1990; Falconer and Arnold, 1989).

Come what may, developing countries will remain largely rural

economies for sometimes. Thus, it seems obvious that any

management techniques in natural resources in developing countries

should take into account the enormous importance of these countries’

natural resources base. Forty years of research on maintaining

equilibrium between supply and demand on the natural resources

among pastorals has failed to do so. This is because the current

management strategies have taken a "black and white" logic in their

attitudes. In the case of range or pastures, the only way to reduce

degradation is to not use them, and this is unlikely to be the right

approach. However, an optimal pattern of use seems appropriate for

sustaining these resources. In order to reach an optimal pattern, we

need to reconsider our range management views. Thus, an informed

3

management must define values of rangeland use by pastorals as well

as values of natural resources as inputs in production. Of the many

factors that affect natural resource management, such as property

right, population growth, and discounting and access to markets,

population growth gains the most important.

1.2. Population Growth

Rapid population growth directly contributes to range and pasture

degradation. Also, population growth may break down social norms

and resource management systems, further contributing to natural

resource degradation. The relationship between population growth and

natural resource degradation is positive. Pastorals depend more on

basic natural resources. While, population growth rate and their

consumption level affect poverty and natural resource degradation,

degradation affects the capacity of the pastorals (Pender, 1999). The

future scenarios on population growth and its effects can be

summarized as follows:

• The world’s population is growing by 200,000 people a day. It

is expected to nearly double by 2050, from 5.7 billion in 1994

to about 10 billion people (Peterson, 1998). Nearly, all the

growth will occur in the developing world (UNFPA, 2005)1;

• Absolute number of poor will remain quite high (FAO, 2003);

• Land per capita availability will go down (PAI, 2005);

• Environmental pollution likely to worsen (UNEP, 2000); and

1. Between 1980 and 2030, the population of low- and middle-income countries will be more than

double - to 7.0 billion, compared with 1 billion for high-income countries. In the next 35 years, 2.5 billion people will be added to the current population of 6 billion (World Bank, 1998).

4

• Global climate change will have serious effect on agriculture

and rural pastorals (Kautza and Gronski, 2003).

Responding to the needs of a rapidly growing population can

challenge a country’s ability to manage its natural resources on a

sustainable basis. People may not be able to get access to safe water

because more and more households, farms and factories are using

increasing amounts of water. The air may become polluted as people

crowd into cities, the number of cars increases, people use more and

more energy, and economies continue to industrialize. Deforestation

may occur as trees are cut to provide fuel for cooking, building

materials, or land for grazing and agriculture. Desertification may

occur as land that has been intensively farmed becomes depleted of its

nutrients or eroded when trees whose roots systems once anchored the

soil are gone (World Bank, 1998). Land degradation is one of the

other consequences of mis-management of land and results frequently

from a mismatch between land quality and land use (Reich et al.,

2001).

1.3. Current challenges in rangeland management

Literature on rangeland grazing management is being published at an

accelerating rate, even though the use of rangelands for domestic

stock production is increasingly questioned on conservation and

sustainability grounds in the world (Walker and Hodgkinson, 2000).

There are some references which indicate that the only way to reduce

degradation is not to utilize natural resources, and this is unlikely to be

the right approach. However, an alternative pattern of use seems to be

possible where a balance is reached between grazing and conserving

5

these resources. In order to reach this pattern, we need to reconsider

our range management views. An informed management must define

values of pasture use by pastorals as well as values of natural

resources as inputs in production. Demand for natural resources is

recently high among rural areas. Most people in developing countries

are agrarian and pastoralist. There are an estimated 190 million

pastoralists in the world (NGO Forum for Food Sovereignty, 2002).

The majority of them suffer from the effects of settlement,

encroachment on their traditional rangelands, lack of infrastructure,

hostile market mechanisms, and difficulties of marketing their

products, forcing large numbers to abandon their rural livelihoods and

seek employment in cities. Human interference keeps numbers at

artificially high levels, e.g. by feeding imported fodder and household

residues to animals that then have the energy to go to the last

grasslands. “Without interference, livestock numbers respond to the

laws of population dynamics” (NGO Forum for Food Sovereignty,

2002; p. 3). In this case, therefore, with increasing population growth

(specially in developing countries like Iran), the increased number of

livestock would be expected. This continuous overgrazing has

changed the composition of the pasturage and is reflected in a decline

in the animal quality. Thus, it seems obvious that any management

techniques in natural resources in developing countries should take

into account the enormous importance of these countries’ natural

resources base. Forty years of research projects and activities on

maintaining equilibrium between supply and demand on the natural

resources among pastorals has failed to do so, because the projects

have focused mostly on grazing management. Although grazing

management is important, because this is where theory is put into

6

practice, however, successful grazing management will be based on

the ability to accomplish three objectives:

1. To control what animal graze,

2. To control where they graze, and

3. To monitor the impact on both the environment and the animal

(Walker, 1995).

Governments and international donor agencies have over the years

supported a variety of interventions aimed at improving the

rangelands. These interventions include (i) sedentarization, i.e. the

placing of pastoralists in permanent settlements and providing an

alternative livelihoods such as irrigated agriculture; (ii) controlled

grazing schemes, such activities established and enforced land

management rules which are conducting in Iran, Kenya and Tanzania;

and (iii) construction of boreholes to provide water for pastoralists and

their livestock (Azadi et al., 2003; Lusigi and Acquay, 1999).

1.4. Defining the problem

A claim is commonly made that the rangelands of the world are

overgrazed and hence producing edible forage and animal produce at

less than their potential. Globally, rangelands are also at risk from

numerous pressures. The most important pressure arises from

overgrazing of livestock. Livestock, therefore, have been a key factor

in the SD in rangeland management. But what will their role be in the

future and how should the science of rangeland management change

to meet the challenges of the future?

The recent literature on rangelands disequilibrium model calls into

question any specific measures of carrying capacity, whether the range

is stocked or unstocked, managed or mis-managed. Ideally, such

7

objections can be taken into account for any individual carrying

capacity estimated by accepting that it has to be determined on a case

- by - case basis in the field. Once one knows the size of the grazing

and browsing animals, and once one knows the biomass production of

the area, the pattern of range management, and so on, she/he can - so

this argument goes - produce a site specific carrying capacity

estimated for the range area under consideration. But, it cannot pack

livestock into a given rangeland, without at some point deteriorating

that range demonstrably. The fact get higher importance when we

notice that biomass production, surely is going down on rangelands

because carrying capacity has been exceeded for so long, even taking

into account factors such as drought and climate changes (Hardesty et

al., 1993).

As a result, carrying capacity is the most important variable in range

management (Walker, 1995). At a time, when the planet's limited

carrying capacity seems increasingly obvious, the rationale and

measures of rangelands carrying capacity are increasingly criticized.

One of the elements of rangeland capacity is stocking rate. According

to Roe (1997), if stocking rate is not close to the right level, then,

regardless of other grazing management practices, employed

objectives will not be met. Thus, a major problem facing range

management is the range disequilibrium. This applies to a regular

topic of books, articles and symposia, and a common justification for

further research in many countries, including Iran (Conference on

Sustainable Range Management, 2004; Iranian Nomadic

Organization, 1992).

It seems that under environmental conditions of great uncertainty, the

notion of rangeland equilibrium would still be ambiguous and

8

confused. Moreover, since environmental conditions are highly

uncertain for the dry rangelands of the world such as Iran, current

understanding of rangeland equilibrium turns out to be all the more

questionable. There is no workable, practical equation for rangeland

management in general, and carrying capacity in particular, nor could

there ever be. But fortunately, there is an alternative formulation for

rangeland equilibrium, which is considerably more realistic if not

more useful than even the conventional methods, named as fuzzy

logic.

Iran has approximately 90 million hectares of rangeland, 9.3 million

hectares of which are considered in ‘good’ conditions while the

remaining in ‘fair’ or ‘poor’ conditions. The country’s rangelands in a

normal year produce around 10 million tons of dry matter (dm), of

which 5.8 million tons may be available for grazing. The remaining

amount is the minimum required for reproduction and soil

conservation. The later amount of dm can support 38.5 million animal

units (au) for duration of 8 months. At the moment there are 115.5

million of au in Iran and only 16.5 of them are fed from other sources

including by agricultural products. The above figures prove that the

rangelands are being utilized at three times more than their peak

capacities in a non-drought year. This results in severe degradation of

the rangelands and accelerates soil erosion. As the rangeland is

considered by its users as "free resource" it is subject to heavy abuse,

which further exacerbates the drought (FAO, 2004a; Iranian Nomadic

Organization , 1992; Mesdaghi, 1995; UNCT, 2001).

The purpose of this dissertation is to design a model for solving the

mis-management of rangelands in Iran. Specifically, this study

9

discusses the application of fuzzy logic in rangeland management in

the Fars province of Southwest Iran.

1.5. Objectives

1.5.1. General goal

The above scenarios make it clear that the rangeland grazing

management is a complex and confusing phenomenon. Thus, the main

objective of this dissertation is “To Explain the equilibrium between

livestock and rangeland by using fuzzy logic”.

1.5.2. Specific goals

More specifically, we focus on the following goals:

1. Defining basic challenges and principles in rangeland

management;

2. Selecting the indicators of Sustainable Rangeland

Management (SRM) based on experts’ knowledge;

3. Explaining the applicability of fuzzy logic in SRM;

4. Estimating the Right Rate of Stocking (RRS) based on

homogenous experts’ knowledge;

5. Estimating primary the RRS based on heterogeneous experts’

knowledge;

6. Dealing with heterogeneous experts’ knowledge to find the

final the RRS; and

7. Evaluating the behaviour of fuzzy homogenous and

heterogeneous models.

10

1.6. The structure of dissertation

In this dissertation, fuzzy logic is proposed as a systematic

methodology for the assessment of sustainability in rangeland

management. Based on this methodology, we develop several fuzzy

systems, which use different experts’ knowledge to estimate carrying

capacity of the Fars rangelands in Southwest Iran.

A new model is developed, called Equilibrium Assessment by Fuzzy

Logic (EAFL), which provides a mechanism for assessing

sustainability in rangeland management in the studied areas.

Furthermore, to deal with the diversity of different experts’

knowledge, we construct a multi-fuzzy model. By introducing several

voting methods, we estimate the weights of each model. Finally, we

evaluate the behaviour of the models.

The dissertation is organized as follows: In Chapter 2, we review

population growth and its consequences. Chapter 3 gives a discussion

regarding sustainability and its major concerned issues. Chapter 4

explains basic challenges and principals in rangeland management,

which cause (dis)equilibrium. In Chapter 5, we introduce fuzzy logic

as a powerful tool to deal with these challenges. Designing theoretical

frameworks in this chapter, we conduct a field study that is reported in

Chapter 6. Findings and their fuzzy analyses are extensively explained

in Chapter 7. Finally, Chapter 8 presents a summary and conclusions.

11

Chapter Two

Population Growth: Consequences

Mahatma Gandhi: "The world has enough for everybody’s

need, but not for everybody’s greed" (Takle, 2001).

2.1. Population growth

2.1.1. A general view

Overpopulation is the greatest problem of our age. In the next hour,

9,000 babies will be born. By this time, tomorrow, the world will have

an additional 200,000 mouths to feed. Each baby will be a unique

individual with the potential to live a full life and be a contributing

world citizen. Unfortunately, most of these babies will be born into

poverty and hunger. Many will die in infancy (Brown et al., 2000).

The earth is increasing its population by 90 million people per year,

and yet we still have approximately 6 billion people left to feed and to

give shelter (Mitchell, 1998). Along with the increase in the

population, there are also more people on Earth who are living longer

lives. The global population boom has coincided with the

improvement of health, and of productivity, around the world. On

average, the human population today lives longer, eats better,

produces more, and consumes more than at any other time period in

the past. Agriculture feeds people, but will it be able to feed the

expanding global population, especially with its exponential increase

(Einstein, 1998).

12

Growth will not be uniform across the globe. In general, the

population booms now underway in South Asia and southern Africa

follow the reduction in infant mortality. According to the Population

Reference Bureau, 98 percent of today's population growth is taking

place in developing regions. Development and birth control, however,

tend to control population growth, and population is now stabilized in

the industrialized world. Asia will continue to be the largest, with 60

percent of the world's population. Asia alone will add almost 3 billion

people in the 21st century. Africa will experience spectacular

growth. Between now and 2100, its population will quadruple, and its

percentage of the world's population will double from 13 percent to 25

percent. Only 45 years ago Africa's population was 40 percent of

Europe's. Today they are equal. In 2100, Africa will be four times

larger. In fact, Africa is potentially a time bomb. Its huge population

growth will occur alongside the world's lowest standard of living,

greatest poverty, highest illiteracy, poorest infrastructure, least

industry, and shakiest history of stable governments. Latin America's

percentage will remain constant at 8 percent, while North America's

will drop from 5 percent today to 3 percent at the Year 2100. Europe's

population will actually shrink in the next 100 years: its percentage of

the world's population will fall from 13 percent now to 6 percent (van

der Werff, 1998).

One of the key variables determining future outcomes, the growth rate

of world population, has been on the decline since the second half of

the 1960s. The UN demographic assessment of 1996 has a variant

projection indicating further deceleration, from 1.4 percent currently

(1995-2000) to 1 percent in 2020 and to 0.4 percent by the middle of

the 21st annually. However, the absolute increments in world

13

population are currently very large, about 80 million persons, over 90

percent of who are added in the developing countries. Such high

annual increments may persist for another 15-20 years, but with

declines in prospect for the longer-term future, falling to some 40

million (30 million in the new projections) by 2050. Demographic

growth in sub-Saharan Africa will increasingly dominate the total

additions to world population: it will account for one half of the world

increment by 2050, compared with only one fifth currently

(Alexandratos, 1998).

The aboved-described projections may make individuals confused by

various figures. But what will really be happened in the future?

2.1.2. Three possible scenarios

Historically, as we come up to the new situations, especially by

economic, scientists in different disciplines would align in different

parties of prediction the world population. According to their

estimations, there are three possible scenarios, which are presented by

those who underestimate (low scenario), some who normal estimate

(medium scenario) and the rest who overestimate (high scenario).

They are shown in Fig. 2.1.

Fig. 2.1. World population: Three possible futures.

14

2.1.2.1. Low scenario

Many researchers expect the world's population to level off between

ten and eleven billion people. They predicted that "world food

production could grow significantly more slowly than the current rate,

and there would still be enough food for 10 billion mouths by the time

they come." They believe that the earth can provide all the food

needed for the foreseeable future (Milne, 2002). So why are so many

saying we must take powerful measures, like widespread abortion, to

control world population?

But the "present rate" was already declining, and the world now

doubles about every 82 years. And more conservative scholars had

pointed this out years ago. As the standard of living of a country

increases, its doubling time also increases. Thus, the developed

nations are close to stability now, and as less developed nations

become more industrialized their population growth also slows. That

is the basis on which many experts predict that the world population

will stabilize at about ten to eleven billion people (Milne, 2002).

The study reports that the most recent UN assessment of global

population trends indicates a drastic slowdown in world population

growth. The UN, for example, reset the 2010 population level of 7.2

billion people projected in 1995, in 1998 at 6.8 million, or about 400

million fewer people. This recalibration in population level is due in

part to changes in the world population growth rate, which has fallen

from 2.1 percent per year in the later half of the 1960's to 1.3 percent

in the late 1990's. This growth rate is predicted to continue dropping

over the next three decades, reaching 0.7 percent by 2030. According

to the latest UN projections, the most likely scenario for population in

2050 will be around 8.9 billion, and will peak out slightly above 10

15

billion after 2200. By 2050 the global population growth rate is

expected to have dropped as low as 0.3 percent. But population

estimates are notoriously inexact, especially those that peer deep into

the future. Even though the rate of growth is slowing, the two billion

people below age 20 will be raising a lot of children over the next

couple of decades. Contrary to popular belief, this group believes the

world's population is not increasing exponentially. Indeed, the growth

rate has fallen steadily since the late 1960’s and is now about 1.5

percent annually. The annual population increase peaked in the late

1980’s and has declined to 85 million/year. The increase will drop to

58 million/year in the second quarter of the 21st century and to 19

million/year by its end. It will be growing at an average of 1.1 percent

a year up to 2030, compared to 1.7 percent annually over the past 30

years. At the same time, an ever-increasing share of the world's

population is well-fed. As a result, the growth in world demand for

agricultural products is expected to slow further, from an average 2.2

percent annually over the past 30 years to 1.5 percent per year until

2030. In developing countries, the slowdown will be more dramatic,

from 3.7 percent for the past 30 years to an average of 2 percent until

2030. However, the developing countries with low to medium levels

of consumption, accounting for about half of the population in

developing countries, would see demand growth slowing only from

2.9 to 2.5 percent per year, and per caput consumption increasing

(FAO, 2002).

The number of hungry people in developing countries is expected to

decline from 777 million today to about 440 million in 2030. This

means, that the target of the World Food Summit in 1996, to reduce

the number of hungry will be met by 2030 (EuropaWorld, 2003).

16

2.1.2.2. Medium scenario

Interestingly, the number of births is expected to remain relatively

constant at 135 million/year for the next four decades or more,

whereas the number of deaths will rise steadily from the present 50

million/year (van der Werff, 1998).

According to Dr. Norman Borlaugh, a Noble Peace, called the father

of the "green revolution," the world will have to increase food

production 50 percent in 30 years, just to feed the world at today's

substandard level and double it to provide everyone with the quality

and abundance of food enjoyed in America. The world scientist noted

that world population stood at 1.6 billion people when he was born in

1914. In 1995 it stood at 5.7 billion. Borlaugh says, "We are adding

100 million (100,000,000) people each year, a billion per decade."

But, he says, "That (doubling) will never happen. That will be

impossible" (Serf Publishing Inc., 2001) (Table 2.1).

Table 2.1. The projection of world population (Medium scenario) 1950-2050.

Estimated population (millions)

Percentage distribution

Major Areas

1950 2000 2050 1950 2000 2050

Oceania 13 31 47 0.5 0.5 0.5 Northern America 172 314 438 6.8 5.2 4.7 Latin America and the Caribbean 167 519 806 6.6 8.6 8.6 Europe 548 727 603 21.8 12.0 6.5 Africa 221 794 2000 8.8 13.1 21.5 Asia 1399 3672 5428 55.5 60.6 58.2 World 2519 6057 9322 100 100 100

NOTE: Information for 2050 is from medium-fertility variant projections (UNPD, 2003).

Future demand for livestock and dairy products can be met, but the

consequences of increased production must be addressed. Production

will shift away from extensive grazing systems towards more

intensive and industrial methods. This could pose a threat to the

17

estimated 675 million rural poor whose livelihoods depend on

livestock. Without special measures, the poor will find it harder to

compete and may become marginalized, descending into still deeper

poverty. If the policy environment is right, the future growth in

demand for livestock products could provide an opportunity for poor

families to generate additional income and employment."

Environmental and health problems of industrial meat production

(waste disposals, pollution, the spread of animal diseases, overuse of

antibiotics) also need to be addressed (FAO, 2002).

Climate change could increase the dependency of some developing

countries on food imports. The overall effect of climate change on

global food production by 2030 is likely to be small. Production will

probably be boosted in developed countries. Hardest hit will be small-

scale farmers in areas affected by drought, flooding, salt-water

intrusion or sea surges. Some countries, mainly in Africa, are likely to

become more vulnerable to food insecurity. With many marine stocks

now fully exploited or overexploited, future fish supplies are likely to

be constrained by resource limits. The share of capture fisheries in

world production will continue to decline, and the contribution of

aquaculture to world fish production will continue to grow. The

capacity of the global fishing fleet should be brought to a level at

which fish stocks can be harvested sustainably. Past policies have

promoted the build-up of excess capacity and incited fishermen to

increase the catch beyond sustainable levels. Policy makers must act

to reverse this situation (FAO, 2002).

18

2.1.2.3. High scenario

If world population continues to grow at the current rate, world

population will be doubled from six billion to twelve billion in fifty

years (Harris, 2001). Half of this growth will occur in just six

countries; which are India, China, Pakistan, Nigeria, Bangladesh, and

Indonesia. Each of these nations faces a steady shrinkage of grainland

per person and thus risks heavy future dependence on grain imports.

This raises two important questions (Larsen, 2002): Will these

countries be able to afford to import large quantities of grain as land

hunger increases? And will grain markets be able to meet their

additional demands?

In India, where one out of every four people is undernourished, 16

million people are added to the population each year. The grain area

per person in India has shrunk steadily for several decades and is now

below 0.10 hectares—less than half that in 1950 (EDC News, 2003).

As land holdings are divided for inheritance with each succeeding

generation, the 48 million farms that averaged 2.7 hectares each in

1960 were split into 105 million farms half that size in 1990, when

India's grainland expansion peaked. The average Indian family, which

now has three children, will be hard pressed to pass on viable parcels

of land to future generations (Larsen, 2002).

Pakistan, with five children per family, is growing even more rapidly.

In 1988, Pakistan's National Commission on Agriculture was already

linking farm fragmentation and a rising reliance on marginal lands to

declining farm productivity in some areas. Since then, the country has

grown from just over 100 million to almost 150 million. Its per person

grain area is now less than 0.09 hectares (Larsen, 2002; Larsen, 2003).

19

In China, the grain area per person has also shrunk dramatically to a

diminutive 0.07 hectares, down from 0.17 hectares in 1950. Shifting

agricultural production to higher-value crops, like fruits and

vegetables, and converting farms to forest for conservation accounts

for some of the grainland contraction, along with losses to nonfarm

uses such as buildings and roads (Coulter, 2002).

Though the shrinkage of farmland available per person in China has

slowed in concert with declining family size, this country—whose

population of 1.3 billion is as large as the entire world's in 1850—is

still expected to add 187 million people to its ranks in the next 50

years. The robustness of China's economy enables it to turn to world

markets to import grain, but this does not guarantee that those markets

can support massive additional demand without hefty price increases

(Larsen, 2003).

The scarcity of arable cropland in sub-Saharan Africa helps to explain

the region's declining production per person in recent decades.

Nigeria, for example, Africa's most populous country, has seen its

population quadruple since 1950 while its grainland area doubled—

effectively halving the grainland per person. In northern Nigeria,

pastoralists and farmers fleeing the encroaching Sahara, which

annually claims 350,000 hectares of land (about half the size of the

U.S. state of Delaware), have increased demands on the already scarce

land elsewhere in the country, sparking ethnic tensions (Coulter, 2003;

Larsen, 2002; Larsen, 2003).

Most of the 3 billion people to be added to world population in the

next 50 years will be born in areas where land resources are scarce. If

world grainland area stays the same as in 2000, the 9 billion people

projected to inhabit the planet in 2050 would each be fed from less

20

than 0.07 hectares of grainland—an area smaller than what is

available per person today in land-hungry countries like Bangladesh,

Pakistan, and Afghanistan (EDC News, 2003).

By 2050, India and Nigeria would cultivate 0.06 hectares of grainland

for each person, less than one tenth the size of a soccer field. China,

Pakistan, Bangladesh, and Ethiopia would drop even lower, to 0.04-

0.05 hectares of grainland per person. Faring worse would be Egypt

and Afghanistan with 0.02 hectares, as well as Yemen, the Democratic

Republic of the Congo, and Uganda, with just 0.01 hectares. These

numbers are in stark contrast to those of the less densely populated

grain exporters, which may have upwards of 10 times as much

grainland per person. For Americans, who live in a country with 0.21

hectares of highly productive grain land per person, surviving from

such a small food production base is difficult to comprehend (UNDP,

2003).

With most of the planet's arable land already under the plow and with

additional cropland being paved over and built on each year, there is

little chance that the world grain area will rebound. At the same time,

the annual rise in cropland productivity of 2 percent from 1950 to

1990 has decreased to scarcely 1 percent since 1990, and may drop

further in the years ahead. This slowing of productivity gains at a time

when the land available per person is still shrinking underlines the

urgency of slowing world population growth (Coulter, 2003).

2.2. Consequences

Population growth will create some major threats to challenge. The

threats come from poverty, agriculture perhaps not sustaining its

21

productivity growth of recent decades, environmental degradation,

and scarcity of water for both agriculture and human health.

2.2.1. A historical challenge

Since Robert Thomas Malthus published his anonymous ‘Essay on the

Principle of Population’ in 1798, people have been disputing his

contention: “population grows exponentially, but food supplies grow

arithmetically”. This means that the graph of population curves

upward, while the graph of food supply is straight. Malthus said,

shortages of food would cause chaos and famine (Office of News and

Public Affairs, 1999). Malthus assumed that food supplies would

always limit population growth. But in the two hundred years since he

wrote, this has not been the case. The pronouncement was fearsome

enough to earn economics this splendid moniker: the "dismal science."

But it wasn't just economists who rebelled. Karl Marx also denounced

Malthus. By one means or another farmers and agricultural scientists

have always found a way to increase farm production to keep up with

population growth. But we have yet to find efficient ways to get food

from where it is produced to where it is needed most (Milne, 2002).

Afterwards, Paul Erhlich, in his 1968 book; The Population

Explosion, announced the approaching food crisis; “...Then, in 1965-

66 came the first dramatic blow...mankind suffered a shocking defeat

in...the war on hunger” (Dean, No date p.1). In 1966, while the

population of the world increased by some 70 million people, there

was no compensatory increase in food production. He continues by

laying out likely scenarios of the world being rocked by food

rebellions that will lead to nuclear war and the devastation of the

planet (Milne, 2002).

22

In 1989, Erhlich wrote another book, The Population Explosion.

Doom was again close: "In 1988, for the first time since World War II,

the United States consumed more grain than it grew...only the

presence of large carryover stocks prevented a serious food crisis. It is

not clear how easy it will be to restore those stocks."

Fortunately, Erhlich was wrong. In 1968, he quotes Louis H. Bean

approvingly: "My examination of the trend of India's grain production

over the last eighteen years leads me to the conclusion that the present

(1967-68) production...is at a maximum level." But in seven years,

India increased its grain production by nearly 26 percent! By 1992, it

had increased it 112 percent! By 1990, world grain production, again

came up by 50 percent from 1988! And it has continued to increase to

the present (Williams, 2000).

In the book of Genesis, Adam and Eve were given the command to

multiply and fill the earth. In Genesis, Noah is given the same charge.

We must consider the rest of the creation as we determine if we have

yet fulfilled that command. But world population is not the problem

(Milne, 2002).

We share the planet with 5.7 billion people. If one could stand all the

people in the world, men, women and children two feet apart, how

much of the world would they take up?

Famines are the exception in most countries, and even then absolute

lack of food is usually not the problem. In a Scientific American

article on world population one author says: "Food surpluses exist in

many nations, and even when famines do occur the cause is much less

the absence of food than its mal-distribution which is often

accentuated by politics and civil war, as in the Sudan." This passing

comment touches on the real problem. Most famines in the last twenty

23

years are a direct result of internal wars in African nations (Milne,

1995).

Whether in Ethiopia, Sudan, or Somalia, the devastating famines and

the hopeless faces of dying children we have all seen on TV are the

result of politics. As one segment of the population wars against

another, starvation is often a political weapon. And in each of the

famine-torn countries of Africa one can show that it has been

disrupted distribution more than low food production that has caused

people to starve to death (Milne, 2002).

2.2.2. Food security1

One of the most important questions facing most of societies today is,

how to produce enough food to feed the increasing human population

on this planet (Kanwar, 2003), which is discussed as the main goal of

development (Seers, 1982). Few who are alive today remember the

"great depression" and "dust bowl" of the 1930's or the food ration of

World War II in the 40's. American's, Briton's and other citizens of the

highly developed countries have enjoyed an almost unprecedented

abundance of the earth's blessings for over half a century. How long

can it continue?

World population has recently passed the sixth billion, however, the

number of hungry people is still growing who are stimated

approximately two billion people (Raven, 2004). FAO discussed

concerning the future, a number of projection studies have addressed

and largely answered in the positive the issue whether the resource

base of world agriculture, including its land component, can continue 1. The UN Food and Agriculture Organization defines food security as a "state of affairs where all

people at all times have access to safe and nutritious food to maintain a healthy and active life" (Blundon, 2001).

24

to evolve in a flexible and adaptable manner as it did in the past, and

also whether it can continue to exert downward pressure on the real

price of food (see for example Pinstrup-Andersen, and Pandya-Lorch,

1999). The largely positive answers mean essentially that for the

world as a whole there is enough, or more than enough, food

production to meet the growth of effective demand, but potentially

(FAO, 2004b).

Since the mid-1980s, the upward trend in annual per capita food

production appears to be levelling off. Per capita world food

availability grew by 6 percent in the 1960s and 1970s, then by 4.6

percent in the 1980s. Per capita crop production has been in decline

since 1985. Per capita grain production expanded by 40 percent

between 1950 and 1984 but has declined after this period. Some

economists argue that this decline is due more to economic policies

and low grain prices than to natural resource limits. The issue is

important, since grain provides more than half of all calories

consumed by people, directly or in (PAI, 2005).

These prospects, particularly the demographic ones, are somewhat

different from those used some five years ago to produce FAO’s

assessment of world food and agriculture prospects to 2010, with

particular reference to the developing countries, in the study "World

Agriculture: Towards 2010"(Alexandratos, 1998) and subsequent

modifications used in the technical documentation of the World Food

Summit of 1996. However, the essence of our findings as concerns

key variables of food security at the level of large country groups and

the world, as a whole, remains largely valid. The main findings,

including selected preliminary findings from ongoing work to update

25

the study and extend the time horizon to 2015 and 2030, are

summarized below:

The incidence of undernutrition in the developing countries may

decline in relative terms (from 21 percent to 12 percent of the

population) but, given population growth, there will be only modest

declines in the numbers undernourished. The current level of over 800

million persons is expected to decline to about 680 million by 2010.

The end result of the detailed projections (for individual countries and

crops) indicates that the growth of the average yields of the

developing countries (other than China) will be slower than in the

past, 1.5 percent (from 1.9 tons/ha in 88/90 to 2.6 tons/ha in 2010),

compared with 2.2 percent in the preceding 20 years (average yield of

wheat, rice paddy and coarse grains). Nine years into the projection

period (1989-98), the average cereal yield grew as predicted at 1.5

percent, though rice yield grew by less than predicted, that of maize

by more and that of wheat as predicted. Continued growth of average

yields, even at the lower rates projected here compared with the past,

will not come about without effort. Growth in average yields will

depend crucially on policies that attach high priority to efforts at

agricultural research and technology development and diffusion, as

well as on a more active role of the state in the areas of infrastructure,

education and the creation of conditions for markets to work

(Alexandratos, 1998).

The prospect that the production growth rate in the exporting countries

needs to be lower than in the past does not in itself guarantee that it is

a feasible proposition. In particular, environmental concerns related to

intensive agriculture in the high-income countries (nitrate pollution,

soil erosion, perceived risks from genetically modified organisms,

26

etc.) may contribute to slow down the rate at which progress may be

made in achieving the required yield increases. In fact, the rate of

growth in agricultural production is declining; world grain reserves

have fallen to record lows; the demand for imported grain is

increasing; and commitments of aid to agricultural development have

decreased. This against a backdrop of expanding world population,

intensifying demands on agricultural resources, and a growing

recognition that the agri-food system is not sustainable (The Online

Newsletter of the Bahá'í International Community, 1996).

2.2.3. Food consumption

By 2050, some 4.2 billion people may not have their daily basic needs

met (Council for Biotechnology Information, 2004). All the primary

sources of food crops, livestock and seafood depend on resources that

are renewable but finite. In each case, limits now coming into view

undermine the prospects for meeting future food demand (PAI, 2005).

Concurrent with a decreasing population growth rate, individual food

consumption rates (measured as Kcal/person/day) will continue to

raise in developing countries. Citing the latest FAO assessment of

under nourishment, the study reports that the percent of the world's

undernourished has been dropping since the late 1960s. Projections of

food consumption will continue to rise in developing countries over

the next 30 years, moving from an average of 2626 kcal in the 1990s

to nearly 3000 kcal in 2015. The average daily consumption rate in

developing countries is expected to exceed 3000 kcal by 2030. By

2015, the report estimates, 6 percent of the world population (412

million people) will still live in countries with very low food

consumption levels (under 2200 kcal) (FAO, 2000a).

27

The per-person food availability of the developing countries as a

whole will continue to increase from 2580 Kcal/day (in 1994/96) to

about 2750 Kcal/day by 2010. However, there will be only very

modest gains in the currently very low average food availability of

sub-Saharan Africa, while South Asia may still be in a middling

position by 2010. The other developing regions, already starting from

better levels now, are expected to be close, or above, 3000 Kcal/day

(Alexandratos, 1999).

One does not need sophisticated analytics to prove this point: any

country starting with per-person food supplies of 2000 Kcal/day (and

some countries start with less) and a population growth rate of 2.5

percent-3.0 percent would need a growth rate of aggregate food

demand of about 5 percent in 15 years if, by 2010, it were to have

2700 Kcal/day, a level usually associated with significantly reduced

undernutrition (provided inequality of distribution is not too high)

(Alexandratos, 1998). Obviously, this kind of growth rates of

aggregate demand for food can only occur in countries with "Asian-

tiger" rates of economic growth sustained over decades. Few of

today’s poorest countries with very low food consumption levels face

such prospects. As noted, the recent crisis that hit several economies

of East and South-East Asia will also take its toll. The rapid pace of

progress of the recent past, particularly in diet diversification towards

livestock products, is being interrupted and some countries (e.g.

Indonesia) are suffering outright reversals (FAO, 1999).

At the end of the 1980s, about 251 million people lived in 14 countries

where average per capita food supply was less than 2,100 calories per

day. Another 1.4 billion people lived in 31 countries in which daily

per capita availability was between 2,100 and 2,400 calories. In most

28

of these food-scarce countries, per capita production is declining. The

averages also hide wide disparities within countries. However, the

World Bank and the FAO are optimistic that global food supplies will

be adequate and prices low at least through 2010, but analysts with

both organizations assume that growth in yields and production will

continue along current trend lines. A recent independent analysis that

also considered potential environmental and socio-economic

constraints predicted that without increased investment in agricultural

research and technology, the next two decades will see food

production shortages and accelerated environmental degradation (PAI,

2005).

We simply cannot say for certain whether current or future

populations can be fed sustainably. No single ingredient can provide

such a guarantee. We know, however, one thing is the most important:

how we can increase the yield of agricultural production by research?

2.2.4. Agricultural research

One way for the over-population of today and tomorrow to live in

harmony in regards to nourishment provided by the environment is to

be able to intensify agricultural yields. With a projected population of

10 billion people, an increase of global average grain yields from 2 to

5 tons of grain per hectare would ensure a per capita diet of 6,000

calories and would save a land area twice the size of Alaska

(Waggoner, 1994). Most of the world’s increased output is no longer a

result of expansion of area used in agriculture, but resulting from the

intensification of production on existing agricultural areas (Einstein,

1998). The "Green Revolution" of Norman Borlaugh's day only served

to delay the growing crisis (Serf Publishing Inc., 2001).

29

In fact, some believe that agricultural researches can counteract the

population time bomb. Perhaps an extension agent will bring a more

productive variety of rice or demonstrate a more efficient method of

irrigation. Mark Rosegrant, Senior Research Fellow at the

Washington-based International Food Policy Research Institute and

co-author of a study of agricultural production in India believes that

investment in agricultural research and extension is and will continue

to be the driving force in India's increased ability to feed their growing

population. He also discussed, increased family incomes by growth in

agricultural production, together with improved education, results in a

reduction in population growth. This double benefit of agricultural

research will alleviate misery today and gradually ease the world’s

population woes (Rao, 1999).

FAO (2000a) reports that there is a need for continued support of

agricultural research and policies in developing countries. The report

states that by 2030 three-quarters of the projected world crop

production will occur in developing countries compared to just over

half of world production in the early 1960s. Most of these future

increases in crop productivity will come from a further intensification

of crop production. The bulk of the increases in production will come

from increasing plant yield and through more intensive land use (e.g.,

multicropping or high cropping intensities).

These projections and complex challenges facing the world’s future

food supply are prompting international food and agricultural experts

and policymakers - including the U.N. Food and Agriculture

Organization and the World Health Organization - to call plant

biotechnology a critical tool to help feed a growing population in the

21st century (Council for Biotechnology Information, 2002).

30

The Green Revolution’s success in fending off starvation even as Asia

and Latin America’s population doubled, from less than 2 billion to

nearly 4 billion people, was a remarkable feat. Millions of human

beings would not be able to survive today without the key innovations

that launched the revolution. Foremost among these were advanced

techniques of cross breeding that allowed development of rice, wheat

and corn strains with increasingly higher yields per hectare. With

sufficient access to irrigation water, fertilizers and pest controls,

farmers could gain higher yields and, often, multiple crops in the same

year, all with less labour. But there have been tradeoffs. Some Green

Revolution technologies accelerate soil erosion, often beyond the

thresholds of how much soil loss the land can tolerate without losing

productivity. Fertilizers and pesticides have polluted groundwater

supplies, while crop pests have developed resistance to common

pesticides. Irrigated land is being abandoned as soils become

waterlogged or contaminated by salt. Small-scale farmers, many of

them women, have been pushed from ownership to tenancy, or off the

land altogether, because the expenses and economies of scale required

by the Green Revolution favour large farms and affluent farmers (PAI,

2005).

2.2.5. Biotechnology

According to the Consultative Group on International Agricultural

Research (CGIAR), world crop productivity could increase by as

much as 25 percent through the use of biotechnology to grow plants

that resist pests and diseases, tolerate harsh growing conditions and

delay ripening to reduce spoilage. Biotechnology also offers the

possibility for scientists to design “farming systems that are

31

responsive to local needs and reflect sustainability requirements,” said

Calestous Juma, director of the Science, Technology and Innovation

Program at the Center for International Development and senior

research associate at the Belfer Center for Science and International

Affairs, both at Harvard University (Council for Biotechnology

Information, 2004).

Scientists are developing crops that can resist against diseases, pests,

viruses, bacteria and fungi, all of which reduce global production by

more than 35 percent at a cost estimated at more than $200 billion a

year (Council for Biotechnology Information, 2004).

Nowadays, scientists are busy with developing such crops, which can

tolerate extreme conditions, i.e. drought, flood and harsh soil. For

instance, researchers are working on a rice that can survive long

periods under water (Shah and Strong, 1999) as well as rice and corn

that can tolerate aluminium in soil (Council for Biotechnology

Information, 2004). A tomato plant has been developed to grow in

salty water that is 50 times higher in salt content than conventional

plants can tolerate and nearly half as salty as seawater (Owens, 2001).

About a third of the world’s irrigated land has become useless to

farmers because of high levels of accumulated salt (Council for

Biotechnology Information, 2004). Biotech crops could significantly

reduce malnutrition, which still affects more than 800 million people

worldwide, and would be especially valuable for poor farmers

working marginal lands in sub-Saharan Africa (UNDP, 2001).

While the Green Revolution kept mass starvation at bay and saw

global cereal production double as a result of improved crop varieties,

fertilizers, pesticides and irrigation, its benefits bypassed such regions

as sub-Saharan Africa. The new hybrids needed irrigation and

32

chemical inputs that farmers there couldn’t afford (Council for

Biotechnology Information, 2002). In contrast, the benefits of

biotechnology are passed on through a seed or plant cutting, so that

farmers anywhere around the world can easily adopt the technology.

That’s why biotechnology is particularly attractive to scientists and

rural development experts in poor countries where most of the people

farm for a living (Owens, 2001).

Biotech crops are “tailor-made for Africa’s farmers, because the new

technology is packaged in the seed, which all farmers know how to

handle," said Florence Wambugu, a Kenyan plant scientist who helped

develop a virus-resistant sweet potato (Council for Biotechnology

Information, 2004). Agreeing with Wambugu, the International

Society of African Scientists issued a statement in October 2001

calling plant biotechnology a major opportunity to enhance the

production of food crops (ISAS, 2001).

Despite, technology has been a viable part of higher productivity in

agriculture and innovations such as tractors, seeds, chemicals,

irrigation measures, fertilizers, pesticides, and genetic engineering

have played a major part in raising yields, however, is technology the

key to ensuring sustainable agriculture for a growing population?

(Einstein, 1998).

Many countries have tripled or even quadrupled the amount of grain

they produce. Unfortunately, yields have been decreasing while

population continues to increase. Grain yields per hectare have been

slowing since 1990, rising only 3 percent from 1990-1996 or 0.5

percent per year. This does not keep pace with population growth

which is at 1.6 percent per year (Brown, 1997).

33

Along with population growth, there is a growing demand for a more

calorie-filled diet, especially with the unprecedented rise in affluence

in Asia. Meat is becoming the food of choice rather than low calorie

wheat or vegetables. Since it takes more grain and water to produce

animal protein than vegetable protein, added pressure is placed on the

environment. From 1990 to 1995, China’s grain consumption

increased by 40 million tons; 33 million tons were consumed as

animal feeds (Brown, 1997). As economies grow, especially in

developing countries, consumption rates of resources rise in parallel.

For these countries, a choice needs to be made between slowing

population growth or sacrificing any hope of dietary improvement in

order to lessen the pressure that agriculture creates on environments

(UNFPA, 2003).

2.2.6. Arable land

Another important question is: how much crop land would be needed

to feed the growing population and what is the potential to further

expand land area for food grain production?

Increases in food production will have to come from existing

agricultural land (UN, 2000). Arable land could in theory be increased

by 40 percent, or 2 billion hectares, but most of the uncultivated land

is marginal, with poor soils and either not enough rainfall or too much.

Bringing it into production would require costly irrigation and water-

management systems and large-scale measures to enrich the soil.

Much of this land is now under forest, and clearing it would have

unforeseeable consequences for erosion, degradation and local climate

change, among others (UNFPA, 2003).

34

As population grows, subsistence farmers without access to new land

are forced to intensify production to feed their families. This can be

positive, if farmers can make the yield improvements last. Often,

however, the reality is quite different. As the National Research

Council notes, "fallow periods are often shortened to the point where

the land becomes so badly degraded that it is virtually useless for any

agricultural activity" (National Research Council, 1993).

The practice of leaving some land fallow was once universal in

agriculture, but in those areas where fallowing remains it is

disappearing. When farmers lack access to information and

technology—especially fertilizers—the abandonment of fallowing is

unsustainable and a contributor to declining yields (PAI, 2005).

Over the past three centuries, world population has increased eightfold

while the amount of arable land has increased only fivefold. More

intensive use of arable land has allowed food production to keep pace

with population growth despite the slower expansion of arable land.

There is limited potential, however, to expand arable land much

further. Continued population growth could result in unsustainable

demands on the earth's agricultural land and water resources in the

coming decades (Fig. 2.2).

35

Fig. 2.2. World Population and Arable Land, 1700 – 1990 (Richards, 1990).

Of the total of 13 billion hectares of land area on Earth, cropland

accounts for 11 percent, rangeland 27 per cent, forested land 32

percent, and urban lands 9 per cent. Most of the remaining 21 percent

is unsuitable for crops, pasture, and/or forests because the soil is too

infertile or shallow to support plant growth, or the climate and region

are too cold, dry, steep, stony, or wet (Richards, 1990).

In 1960, when the world population numbered only 3 billion,

approximately 0.5 hectare of cropland per capita was available, the

minimum area considered essential for the production of a diverse,

healthy, nutritious diet of plant and animal products like that enjoyed

widely in the United States and Europe. But as the human population

continues to increase and expand its economic activity and related

artifacts, including transport systems and urban structures, vital

cropland is being covered and lost from production (Pimentel and

Wilson, 2005).

36

The decline of per-capita cropland is aggravated by the degradation of

soils. Throughout the world, current erosion rates are higher than ever.

According to a study for the International Food Policy Research

Institute, each year an estimated 10 million hectares of cropland

worldwide are abandoned due to soil erosion and diminished

production caused by erosion. Another 10 million hectares are

critically damaged each year by salinization, in large part as a result of

irrigation and/or improper drainage methods. This loss amounts to

more than 1.3 percent of total cropland annually. Most of the

additional cropland needed to replace yearly losses comes from the

world's forest areas. The urgent need to increase crop production

accounts for more than 60 percent of the massive deforestation now

occurring worldwide (Pimentel et al., 1996).

Land expansion will continue to be a significant factor in the growth

of agriculture in those developing regions where the potential for

expansion exists (many countries in sub-Saharan Africa and South

America) and the prevailing farming systems and more general

demographic and socio-economic conditions favour land expansion

(FAO, 1999). It is estimated that the developing countries outside

China have some 2.5 billion ha of land of varying qualities, which has

potential for growing rainfed crops at yields above an "acceptable"

minimum level. Of this land, some 720 million ha (plus another 36

million ha of desert land reclaimed through irrigation) are already in

cultivation in the developing countries outside China (arable land and

land in permanent crops). Most of the remaining 1.8 billion ha is in

Latin America and sub-Saharan Africa (FAO, 2003). At the other

extreme, there is virtually no spare land available for agricultural

expansion in South Asia and the Near East/North Africa region. Even

37

within the relatively land-abundant regions, there is great diversity

among countries and sub-regions as concerns land availability per

person, both quantity and quality. For example, in sub-Saharan Africa

land is scarce in East Africa and relatively abundant in the Central

Africa. Land expansion may add some 90 million ha to the above

estimates of cultivated land of the developing countries (other than

China). Such expansion will account for about 20 percent of the

increase in their aggregate crop production (Alexandratos, 1998).

The intensification of agriculture, especially under irrigated

conditions, has brought new environmental problems including soil

erosion, land degradation and decreased water quality. Intensive

agricultural production systems were introduced in 1960’s with the

advances in improved crop varieties, mechanization, and increased

availability of pesticide and fertilizers. More recent experiences, in the

developed countries, especially Europe and USA, have shown that

modern and intensive agricultural production systems have increased

land degradation and water contamination (Kanwar, 2003).

2.2.7. Water scarcity

Another parallel question facing the society is, how much water would

be needed to produce enough food to feed the increasing population in

the world? Answer to this question is also not easy. Increased

population rates have added more than 4.4 billion people on earth

between 1900 and 2000, and average food production has kept pace

with the increases in population. Also, between 1900 and 2000,

irrigated area has increased from about 50 million hectares to 250

million hectares. Agricultural water use continues to make 85 percent

of all consumptive use on a global basis (Kanwar, 2003).

38

As a country struggles to feed its people, on one hand, vital resources

such as water for irrigation are dwindling (UNFPA, 2003). Scientists

are finding ways to replenish groundwater aquifers and use irrigation

in less wasteful ways that will not reduce food production (Rao,

1999). On the other hand, conflicts within countries are also of

mounting concern to national governments (UNFPA, 2003).

Among all contaminations, water pollution is a major threat to

maintaining ample fresh water resources. Although considerable water

pollution has been documented in developed nations like the United

States, the problem is of greatest concern in countries where water

regulations are not rigorously enforced or do not exist. This is

common in most developing countries, which (according to the World

Health Organization) discharge 95 percent of untreated urban sewage

directly into surface waters. For instance, of India's 3,119 towns and

cities, only 209 have even partial sewage treatment facilities, and a

mere eight possess full facilities. Downstream, the polluted water is

used for drinking, bathing, and washing (Pimentel and Wilson, 2005).

Also, of all the environmental trends, water shortages may be the

biggest. The report predicts, "By 2050, fully two-thirds of the

population could be living in regions with chronic, widespread

shortages of water." Agriculture must have adequate supplies of water

if we are to meet future food needs, and those needs are huge

(Truelsen, 2003). "Water scarcity is now the single greatest threat to

human health, the environment, and the global food supply," said

David Seckler, director general of the Water Institute and an author of

the study with Randolph Barker and Upali Amarasinghe. "It also

threatens global peace as countries in Asia and the Middle East seek to

cope with shortages."…"Water scarcity is already a major

39

destabilizing force within countries because different sectors of the

economy are vying for scarce water resources," said Seckler (Wilson,

1999). Within the next 25 years, there is great potential for more water

conflict not just within countries but also between them. Historically,

Egypt has threatened to go to war to protect its water supplies if

necessary. And just last week, President Gaddafi of Libya warned

that, “the next Middle East war would be over dwindling water

supplies” (Mesbahi, 2004).

The study divides the countries into four categories (Table 2.2). The

first category includes those countries that are most water scarce and

in 2025 will not have enough water to maintain 1990 levels of per

capita food production from irrigated agriculture and meet industry,

household, and environmental needs. The countries, defined as facing

"absolute water scarcity," include 17 countries in the Middle East,

South Africa, and the dryer regions of western and southern India and

northern China, which account for more than 1 billion people today

and are projected to account for as many as 1.8 billion in 2025. The

study notes that while India and China will not have major water

problems on average, there will be massive regional variations in

water availability.

The second category includes countries that have sufficient potential

water resources to meet projected 2025 requirements, but will have to

more than double their efforts to extract water to do so. Twenty-four

countries, mainly in Sub-Saharan Africa, are defined as extremely

water scarce and include some 348 million people today and are

projected to include some 894 million in 2025. Because it will be

extremely difficult for these countries to find the financial resources to

build enough water development projects, such as dams and irrigation

40

systems, they are classified as having "economic water scarcity"

(Wilson, 1999).

The remaining countries of the world are in categories three and four

and include North America and Europe. For these countries, there will

be substantially less pressure on water supplies with moderate needs

to increase water development efforts.

The single greatest impact of water scarcity will be on the food

supplies of the poor. To meet the world food supplies in 2025, the

study provides two scenarios a "business as usual scenario" where no

increases in irrigation efficiency are foreseen, and a scenario where

irrigation efficiency is dramatically increased. Under the business-as-

usual scenario, 60 percent more water will be required for irrigation to

meet the world food supplies in 2025. Even if irrigation efficiency is

greatly increased, between 13 and 17 percent more water will be

needed and still 2.7 billion people will remain short of water. The

study uses the United Nations "medium" projection for population

growth (Wilson, 1999).

Many countries, including China, India, Iran, Pakistan, Mexico and

nearly all of the countries of the Middle East and North Africa, have

literally been having a free ride over the past two or three decades by

rapidly depleting their groundwater resources, said Seckler. This could

have catastrophic results in terms of limiting their ability to produce

enough food to feed their populations (Table 2.2).

41

Table 2.2.Water scarcity by country groups (Wilson, 1999). Category 1 Afghanistan Egypt Iran Iraq Israel Jordan Kuwait Libya Oman Pakistan Saudi Arabia Singapore South Africa Syria Tunisia United Arab Emirates Yemen (China)* (India)*

Category 2 Angola Benin Botswana Burkina Faso Burundi Cameroon Chad Congo Cote d'Ivoire Ethiopia Gabon Ghana Guinea-Bissau Haiti Lesotho Liberia Mozambique Niger Nigeria Paraguay Somalia Sudan Uganda Zaire

Category 3 Albania Algeria Australia Belize Bolivia Brazil Cambodia Central African Republic Chile Colombia El Salvador Gambia Guatemala Guinea Honduras Indonesia Kenya Lebanon Madagascar Malaysia Mali Mauritania Morocco Myanmar Namibia Nepal New Zealand Nicaragua Peru Senegal Tanzania Turkey Venezuela Zambia Zimbabwe

Category 4 Argentina Austria Bangladesh Belgium Bulgaria Canada (China)* Costa Rica Cuba Denmark Dominican Republic Ecuador Finland France Germany Greece Guyana Hungary (India)* Italy Jamaica Japan Mexico Netherlands North Korea Norway Panama Philippines Poland Portugal Romania South Korea Spain Sri Lanka Surinam Sweden Switzerland Thailand UK Uruguay USA Vietnam

Definitions: Category 1: These countries face "absolute water scarcity." They will not be able to meet water

needs in the year 2025. Category 2: These countries face "economic water scarcity." They must more than double their

efforts to extract water to meet 2025 water needs, but they will not have the financial resources available to develop these water supplies.

Category 3: These countries have to increase water development between 25 and 100 percent to meet 2025 needs, but have more financial resources to do so.

Category 4: These countries will have to increase water development modestly overall on average, by only five percent to keep up with 2025 demands.

*These countries have severe regional water scarcity. A portion of their populations (381 million people in China in 1990 and 280 million people in India in 1990) are in Category 1. The rest of their populations are in Category 4.

42

2.2.8. Forestry and fisheries

Forest management goals will increasingly shift from wood

production to safeguarding the environmental functions of forests. The

role of industrial forest plantations to provide timber is expected to

increase strongly, with its share reaching one-third of total supply by

2015. Use of fuel wood is expected to continue to grow over the next

two decades before stabilizing or even declining marginally. More

than 60 percent of the wood harvested globally in 1995 was used as

fuel (FAO, 2004b).

Average world consumption of fish per person could grow from 16 kg

a year in 1997 to 19-20 kg by 2030, raising total food use of fish to

150-160 million tonnes. The yearly sustainable yield of marine

capture fisheries is estimated at no more than 100 million tonnes. "The

bulk of the increase in supply therefore will have to come from

aquaculture" (FAO, 2000b).

In some developing countries, fish provide a critical source of high-

quality protein and needed oils. Fisheries currently provide less than

one percent of the calories the world consumes, however, and this

percentage is almost certain to decline. The annual fish catch peaked

at 100 million metric tons in 1989 and has been stable at slightly

lower levels since. The Food and Agriculture Organization of the

United Nations has concluded that annual marine yields are adversely

affected at extraction levels exceeding 80 million tons, and the

organization predicts no growth in catches from lakes, streams and

inland seas. Aquaculture supplies about 12 million tons of fish, but its

growth is constrained by competition for fresh water and the challenge

of keeping fish free from disease (PAI, 2005).

43

2.2.9. Rangelands

With limited potential to expand food production either from fisheries

or range-fed livestock, cultivated land will be pressed to supply ever

increasing proportions of the world’s food. But arable land, too, faces

severe constraints. We appear to be entering a period in which all

food-producing systems must function well almost all the time.

Calculations of the sunlight, water and plant nutrients available for

growing crops suggest that farmers could feed—at least in theory—

many more people than the current world population. In the real

world, however, weather and pests may not cooperate, and farmers

and other food suppliers perform at human rather than theoretical

levels of efficiency. Storage and transportation of food on massive

scales contribute to spoilage (PAI, 2005).

For many food deficit low-income countries, feeding a growing

population means coaxing more food out of the same amount of land.

Canadian geographer Vaclav Smil estimated that the minimum

amount of land needed to supply a vegetarian diet for one person

without any use of artificial chemical inputs is 0.07 hectare, or slightly

less than a quarter of an acre. Based on this, Population Action

International estimated that currently some 420 million people live in

land-scarce developing countries. If fertility and population growth in

developing countries continue to fall, there could be 560 million by

2025. If not, there could be 1.04 billion such people (UNFPA, 2003).

According to IFPRI, a "demand-driven livestock revolution is under

way in the developing world with profound implications for global

agriculture, health, livelihoods and the environment". IFPRI projects

that meat demand in the developing world will double between 1995

and 2020 to 190 million metric tons. Demand for meat in the

44

developing world is expected to grow much faster than for cereals—

by close to 3 per cent per year for meat compared with 1.8 per cent for

cereals. In per capita terms, demand for meat will increase 40 per cent

between 1995 and 2020 (Pinstrup-Andersen, and Pandya-Lorch,

1999). What this means is that demand for cereals to feed livestock

will double in developing countries over the next generation. By 2020,

feed grain demand is projected to reach just less than 450 million

metric tons. Given this trend, well under way in much of Asia,

demand for maize (corn) will increase much faster than any other

cereal, growing by 2.35 per cent per year over the next 20 years.

Nearly two thirds of this increased demand will go towards feeding

livestock (UNFPA, 2003).

In China, rising incomes and changing diets have resulted in a

tremendous demand for meat, particularly poultry and pigs. Over the

next two decades total demand for meat will double, increasing

pressure on grain producers. It takes 4-5 kilograms of feed to produce

1 kilogram of meat (Pinstrup-Andersen and Cohen, 1998).

As urbanization develops and incomes grow, the world food economy

is increasingly fuelled by a demand for livestock products. The last 20

years have witnessed spectacular growth in meat demand in

developing countries - expanding at an annual rate of 5.5 percent -

although many countries with the greatest need for higher protein

consumption did not participate in this process. The poultry sector has

seen dramatic gains, with the share in meat output more than doubling

to 28 percent over the last three decades. As the developing world's

demand for meat begins to level off and with consumption slackening

in industrial countries, FAO projects a slowdown in the growth of the

world meat economy (FAO, 2000b).

45

On land, pastures and rangelands are being grazed at or beyond

capacity. Sustainable grazing of livestock is dependent on balancing

the scale of use with the capacity of land, water and vegetation to

tolerate that use over time. In most regions, grazing is now

accompanied by soil erosion and adverse changes in plant species

composition. At the same time, the world’s livestock population is

growing even more rapidly than its human one. Moreover, rangeland

alone can support only a portion of the world’s cattle and sheep, and it

is of no use for raising pigs and poultry. Today, 37 percent of the

world’s grain is used to feed livestock (World Resources Institute,

1994).

2.3. Conclusion

It is now well accepted that, at least over the medium term, there

appear to be no major global constraints to expanding world food

production at a rate sufficient to match the growth of the effective

demand for food. Yet the world still faces a fundamental food security

challenge. Despite steadily falling fertility rates and family sizes, the

world population is expected to grow. Despite progress on average per

capita consumption of food, people in many countries still suffer from

food insecurity, and malnutrition will still persist (Pretty and Hine,

2001).

The deceleration over time of the effective demand for food

contributes materially to this "happy" state of affairs. Such

deceleration results from both positive and negative developments

from the standpoint of human welfare. The positive ones are the

slowdown in population growth due to voluntary reductions in fertility

around the world and the fact that an ever growing proportion of

46

world population gradually achieves sufficient levels of nutrition

beyond which there is only limited scope for further increases in per-

person food demand. The negative aspects are the contributions of

higher mortality to the slowing of global population growth, and the

role of poverty in depressing demand for food. Even if demand for

food is decelerated, the reason is because a significant part of world

population with still very inadequate consumption levels lacks

purchasing power and has no way to express their need to increase

consumption in the form of solvable demand in the marketplace. This

is why the problems of food insecurity afflicting many countries and

population groups remain as severe as ever, regardless that price

trends in world markets indicate once again an overabundance of food

relative to effective demand at the global level. World market prices

do not reflect adequately the problems of the poor and the food

insecure (Alexandratos, 1998).

Concerning the environmental and sustainability dimensions of the

expansion and further intensification of agriculture, we note that (a)

the foreseen land expansion need not be associated with the rapid rates

of tropical deforestation observed in the past, though there is no

guarantee that this will be so; (b) there will be further increases in the

use of agrochemicals (fertilizer, pesticides) in the developing

countries, though at declining rates compared with the past; (c)

increased use of fertilizer is often indispensable for sustainability (to

prevent soil mining); and (d) the need to accept trade-offs between

production increases and the environment will continue to exist in the

foreseeable future and the policy problem is how to achieve such

increases while minimizing adverse impacts on natural resources and

the wider environment (Alexandratos, 1998). Considering these

47

consequences, the population monster must be controlled. At the

world's current rate of growth it will be impossible to fed the entire

world and insure food security for everyone. World population will far

outgrow food production. To avoid the harsh outcomes projected for

the future, we must stop world population growth, and conserve our

land, water, and energy resources that are vital for a sustainable

economy and environment (Pimentel and Giampietro, 2001). It is also

important to understand that each and every factor, political, gender,

population, and others too all intertwine and influence each other. Not

only must these factors be overcome but also other factors such as

environmental degradation, finances, and geographical factors must be

considered. If these factors are not overcome, our world will not be

able to feed itself in the twenty-first century (Blundon, 2001).

Effective and lasting solutions to problems related to food insecurity

must be found in the policies and actions which pay adequate attention

to those processes of development that aim primarily toward

strengthening the human (Nshimbani, 2004). In the next chapter, we

will show how these policies and resource management strategies can

be affected to intensify or decline the consequences of population

growth.

48

Chapter Three

Sustainability: Basic Challenges

3.1. Importance

As we enter the new millennium, one of the most challenging

questions, if not the most challenging one to be addressed, is how to

assess, build, and maintain a sustainable economy that will allow the

human society to enjoy a sufficiently high standard of living without

destroying its natural and biological support (Andriantiatsaholiniaina,

2001). The first in a new series on population and SD provides new

ways of thinking about population trends in the 21st century. While

the 20th century was the century of population growth with the

world's population increasing from 1.6 to 6.1 billion, the 21st century

is likely to see the end of world population growth and become the

century of population ageing. At the moment we are at the crossroads

of these two different demographic regimes, with some countries still

experiencing high population growth, while others are already faced

with rapid ageing. As it has become more and more clear that it is

technically feasible to provide enough food for projected populations,

the concept of sustainability has broadened to cover the environmental

impacts of agriculture. This is a welcome development, but it is not

enough as there are many ways in which food requirements and

demand can be met.

Based on general estimation of available natural resources, scientists

of the Royal Society and the U.S. National Academy of Sciences have

49

issued a joint statement reinforcing the concern about the growing

imbalance between the world's population and the resources that

support human lives (RS and NAS, 1992). This is the main reason

why sustainability issues have gained substantial importance on the

political agenda in the recent years.

SD is nowadays the goal, in words at least, of most politicians and

decision-makers. Since publication of the Brundtland report in 1987

(WCED, 1987), the concept of sustainability has gained increasing

attention among policy-makers and scientists, which culminated

during the 1992 Earth Summit held in Rio de Janeiro. Among the

results of the Earth Summit, Agenda 21 is a comprehensive list of

actions needed to achieve SD (UNCED, 1992). Leaders from over 150

states committed themselves to undertaking actions, which will render

future development sustainable but without scientific tools to guide

policy-making towards a sustainable path (HMSO, 1994). Decisions

leading to SD require a pragmatic approach to assess sustainability

based on good science and adequate information. The latter is

provided in the form of data about environmental, social, and

economical factors known as indicators of sustainability. Sustainable

projects and optimal strategies for development necessitate answering

four fundamental questions: “why unsustainable development occurs”,

“what is sustainability”, “how can it be measured”, and “which factors

affect it” (Atkinson et al., 1999).

There is evidence that development is currently unsustainable. Ozone

depletion, global warming, depletion of aquifers, species extinction,

collapse of fisheries, soil erosion, and air pollution are among the

obvious signs of ecological distress (Brown et al., 2000). Our society

is also showing similar signs due to poverty, illiteracy, AIDS, social

50

and political unrest, and violence (IUCN/UNEP/WWF, 1991; UNEP,

1992).

Sustainability is an inherent vague and complex concept. As pointed

out in the literature, it is not that sustainability indicators are lacking

but their fragmentary and polymorphous nature hampers their direct

usefulness in the quest of strategies for SD (Brink et al., 1990; OECD,

1994). Despite the fact that the concept of SD is ill-defined, policy-

makers should strive towards it and scientists should find scientific

ways to assess and improve upon it. The development of sustainable

policies is a necessity if we adopt the precautionary approach of

development and if we want to avoid nasty surprises species as the

ozone depletion or irreversible actions such as species extinction. Of

course, even then, no one can guarantee complete avoidance of

surprises given our incomplete state of knowledge of an extremely

complex environment, but at least we do our best.

Although sustainability is a goal for international and national policy-

makers, there is no measuring yardstick against which to assess

practical policy (WCED, 1987). Sustainability is difficult to define or

measure because it is an inherently vague and complex concept. Fuzzy

logic, due to its capability to emulate skilled humans and its

systematic approach in handling vague situations where traditional

mathematics are ineffective, seems to be a natural technical tool to

assess sustainability.

What we need is adequate information that is tailored to quantitative

sustainability objectives. Brink (1991) states that such information

should: (a) give a clear indication as to whether objectives of

sustainability are met, (b) concern the system as a whole, (c) have a

quantitative character, (d) be understandable to non-scientists, and (e)

51

contain parameters which can be used for periods of one or more

decades. The need for a practical tool to assess sustainability is crucial

to policy-makers if they are to secure future development. Since such

a tool is not available, management by trial-and-error instead of

management by knowledge and prediction is currently the only way

used to establish sustainable policies. A deadlock further impeding the

measurement of sustainability lies in the fact that scientists are waiting

for important political issues to be raised by policy-makers, while

policy-makers are waiting for important ecological issues and

ecological indicators of sustainability to be defined by scientists

(Brink, 1989). Unfortunately, unsustainability may not be easily

reversible because the natural and biological support systems of an

economy are subject to thermodynamic laws and irreversibility.

3.2. Definitions

The fundamental question is: “what is sustainability and how

sustainable is an economic system” (Procter and Gamble, 2005). Since

SD is a vague continually evolving concept, it is difficult to define it

in an appreciate way (McKeown et al., 2002; Pembleton, 2004). The

commonly used definition of SD was put forward by the Report of the

World Commission on Economy and Environment (the "Brundtland

Report") in 1986: "To meet the needs of the present without

compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own

needs" (WCED, 1987; p. 43). The precise meaning of SD has been

widely debated (Wikipedia, 2005). For example, two years after the

Brundtland Commission's Report popularised the term, over 140

definitions of SD had been catalogued. Before the widespread use of

the term sustainable industries, the terms sustainable economy and SD

52

were prevalent. Their popularization started with the United Nations

Conference for Environment and Development (the Earth Summit) in

1992. The conference was prompted by the report Our Common

Future (1987, World Commission on Environment and Development,

also known as the Brundtland Commission), which called for

strategies to strengthen efforts to promote sustainable and

environmentally sound development. Caring for natural resources and

promoting their sustainable use is an essential response of the world

community to ensure its own survival and well-being (Nationmaster,

2005). The issue of intergenerational responsibility also is raised. The

Bruntland report does not denounce the depletion of non-renewable

resources. Serageldin suggested that "sustainability is to leave future

generations as many opportunities as, if not more than, we have had

ourselves" (Takle, 2001). This is a very far-reaching principle that

admits a wide range of activities to allow residents of the planet -

present and future - to live fulfilling lives. One definition of SD that

appears to have more resonance with the general public is that used by

the United Kingdom government: "SD is about ensuring a better

quality of life for everyone, now and for generations to come." This

focus of SD on improving quality of life is becoming more widely

accepted by governments, companies, civil society organizations, and

others (Holliday and Pepper, 2005). A quality of life focus makes the

concept more aspirational, and it changes the tone and content of the

SD debate so that the emphasis is more on solutions than the

problems. Another definition of SD, demands that “we seek ways of

living, working and being that enable all people of the world to lead

healthy, fulfilling, and economically secure lives without destroying

the environment and without endangering the future welfare of people

53

and the planet” (Cumber, 2004). Based on this definition, we are

constantly required to re-evaluate our values and decisions: for

example, the present realities of malnutrition, lack of suitable housing,

and lack of safe drinking water, suggest that significant development

is needed for the present generation.

3.3. Dimensions

A series of seven UN conferences followed on environment and

development. The first UN Conference on Environment and

Development (UNCED or the Rio Summit) has emphasized this shift

of attention in the form of Agenda 21. Since then, countries and

regions have been formulating strategies towards the achievement of

sustainability in various sectors of national and regional development

(GLEAM, 2002). These strategies will have to cover the

environmental, social, economic (Hart, 2000), and recently, is more

defined by adding the fourth, which is institutional dimension

(GLEAM, 2002). SD is also one of the issues addressed by

international environmental law and focuses on the overall

performance or health of ecosystems. Social sustainability seeks to

reduce the vulnerability of various segments of the society,

particularly the poor, and maintain the health of social and cultural

systems. Economic sustainability aims to maximize the flow of

income, while maintaining the stock of assets required for these

benefits. The institutional dimension reflects the whole set of norms

and beliefs on which personal preferences and attitudes as well as

private and public organizations are built. Institutional sustainability

links to the availability of mechanisms to implement the other

dimensions of sustainability as well as the long-term viability of the

54

institutions in them. In all cases each system's capability to withstand

shocks (vulnerability and resilience) is an important aspect of

sustainability (Ibid). In other words, the environmental dimensions of

sustainability refer to the need to maintain (or restore) the physical

resource base so that it endures indefinitely to meet the needs of the

present without compromising the capacity of future generations to

meet their needs. This also highlights the underlying and fundamental

time component inherent in sustainability. Economic sustainability is

equally conditional on the use of resources so as to avoid their

overexploitation either in terms of their quality or quantity, or the use

of resources which results in the generation of waste in excess

capacity of the environment's to absorb it effectively. The balance

between environmental and economic sustainability is mediated

through the institutional arrangements that shape and condition the

management and use of the land, and those social norms that influence

community values. In effect, the different dimensions of sustainability

constitute the key components of the system, and act in concert to

either promote or constrain the achievement of sustainability (MAF,

2000). Land use is the visual expression of the interplay among those

different dimensions and as such can be an important indicator of the

health of the overall ecosystem. Therefore, SD calls for long-term

structural change in our economic and social systems, with the aim of

reducing the consumption of the environment and resources to a

permanently affordable level, while maintaining economic output

potential and social cohesion (ARE, 2005).

While, environmental sustainability identifies energy, fresh water, and

reversing land and soil degradations as priorities, especially for

developing countries to protect their natural resource base (EC, 2002;

55

Pembleton, 2004), social sustainability seeks to reduce the

vulnerability of various segments of the society, particularly the poor,

and maintain the health of social and cultural systems.

In general, we can divide all these dimensions in two categories: the

technical definition being "a sound balance among the interactions of

the impacts (positive and/or negative), or stresses, on the four major

quality systems: People, Economic Development, Environment and

Availability of Resources," and the none-technical definition being "a

sound balance among the interactions designed to create a healthy

economic growth, preserve environmental quality, make a wise use of

our resources, and enhance social benefits". When there is a need to

find a solution to a problem or a concern, a sound solution would be to

choose a measure or conduct an action, if possible, which causes

reversible damage as opposed to a measure or an action causing an

irreversible loss (Earth Government for Earth Community, 2003).

3.4. Modeling problems

Modeling sustainable systems has seen considerable improvement in

its application and utilization since the Rio Summit. This has been

driven partly by the development and negotiation about various

Multilateral Environmental Agreements and by the need for scientific

assessments in support of these negotiations. The UN Framework

Convention for Climate Change has generated a broad variety of

integrated assessment models focussing on the climate issue. Some

trend setting examples of these models are AIM (NIES, Japan),

MARIA (Tokyo University), IMAGE (RIVM, The Netherlands),

MESSAGE (IIASA, Austria) and MiniCam (PNNL, USA). Also, the

integrated models try to provide a powerful tool to undertake such

56

analyses and evaluations (Morita et al., 2000). Until recently, such

assessment modeling efforts have been typically limited in

geographical focus and in the sectors and issues covered. Some of

these models are gradually being expanded in order to cover the

broader perspectives of sustainability, vulnerability, durability and

human security, but they are still insufficient. Substantial model

development is required to cover the different dimensions of

sustainability and the spatial and temporal variety within these

dimensions. While some models try to include environmental

dimension, they neglect socio-economic dimensions. On the other

hand, while socio-economic dimensions are emphasized by the rest,

the environmental dimension has been neglected (GLEAM, 2002).

In practice, both researchers and policy-makers have found these

characteristics of sustainability difficult to handle. There is no good

conceptual framework available to untangle financial/environmental

links. The fundamental institutional changes that sustainability may

require, may themselves need strength of political will not readily

secured. Consequently, in most countries, policy efforts have focused

on the incorporation of sustainability within existing operational and

ideological frameworks. More effort has been spent on issues of inter-

generational transfer than to any redistribution of resources within any

one-generation. Equally more environmental legislation, determined

on traditional lines, has often been substituted for efforts to better

integrate environmental values into all decision making. To this extent

environmental policies more frequently remain a "tag-on" to existing

economic strategies, and production and environmental policies have

generally remained polarised and apart, despite rhetoric to the contrary

(MAF, 2000).

57

As the concept of sustainability represents a fundamental challenge at

the theoretical and methodological levels, reorientation within the

social sciences themselves is required, implying (UNESCO, 1996):

• Firstly, to give more attention to current vital issues such as

land use, social use of natural resources like water or wood,

production and consumption patterns, loss of biodiversity, etc.;

• Secondly, to expand the problem-oriented cooperation between

the social and the natural sciences on issues and questions of

sustainability. The crucial importance is that natural and social

sciences cooperate on an equal basis, starting from the phase of

defining the problems under study; and

• Thirdly, to develop and improve interdisciplinary cooperation

among the various disciplines. This is necessary to achieve a

more integrated and comprehensive understanding of

development processes, as well as the relationships between

individuals and the environment in their social, political,

economic, psychological and cultural aspects. With regard to

this, the historical boundaries between the disciplines must be

re-examined and methodologies of interdisciplinary research are

to be developed.

With the increasing attention given to the economic, social and

ecological impacts of SD, the need for interdisciplinary approaches in

agricultural research is likely to continue growing. However, the

experiences of the last few decades of interdisciplinary approaches

such as Farming Systems Research (FSR) and Farming Systems

Research/Extension (FSRE) are not very promising: disciplinary

conflict is common, productive interaction seems difficult to achieve

58

and practical results have been disappointing (Hawkins, 1997). Within

the realm of agricultural research, farming systems research (FSR) and

land use planning are areas where interdisciplinary is indispensable

(Aenis and Nagel, 2000). However, as Hawkins (1997) reports, only

few FSR projects have reached interdisciplinary status involving both,

technical and social sciences. Sustainability in social, economic, and

ecological terms is the central goal of R&D projects in the field of

natural resource management. Up until now, impacts seem to be

marginal (Pretty, 1995). As a consequence, a change with regard to

institutionalizing and organizing participation of all relevant actors is

necessary. But which efforts ensure participation? How to manage this

process? Which structures support efficient outputs? (Aenis and

Nagel, 2000).

Some practical experiences have been made in training small teams

for interdisciplinary studies and still, there is a growing scientific

knowledge on economic and ecological sound planning and

management techniques for natural resources. It is also argued that

interdisciplinary research requires: a) an appreciation of holistic

approaches; b) a common understanding of goals and objectives and

skills in planning methods to reach these; and c) effective

communication and management procedures to enable expert teams to

function efficiently (Hawkins, 1997a). This group of experts help to

give better understanding of assessing the SD in the situation. They

have a lot of information on dimensions, indicators, and assessment of

them (Meadows, 1998).

59

3.5. Conclusion

It is fair to say that some clear measures or, at least, indicators of

sustainability exist, but the effectiveness of policies towards a goal of

sustainability cannot be assessed. Attempts have been made to

measure sustainability using economic, ecological, or combined

economic- ecological approaches, but the results still lack universal

acceptance. Examples of existing sustainability measurements are

Pearce and Atkinson, 1993; OECD, 1994; Sherp, 1994; IUCN/IDRC,

1995; Rennings and Wiggering, 1997.

For the sake of analysis, researchers have broken down sustainability

into a large number of individual components or indicators whose

synthesis into one measure appears to be next to impossible. As

pointed out in the literature, it is not so much that environmental and

socio-economical information is lacking but the fragmentary, often

qualitative, and very detailed nature of this information hampers its

direct usefulness in policy making (Brink et al., 1990). Not only are

there no common units of measurement for the indicators of

sustainability but quantitative criteria for certain values are also

lacking. A systemic method based on a reliable scientific methodology

is needed to combine multidimensional components and assess

uncertainty. Such a method should be flexible in the sense that one

can add or remove indicators to achieve a better assessment of the

system according to the context. In reality the border between

sustainability and unsustainability is not sharp but rather fuzzy. This

means that it is not possible to determine exact reference values for

sustainability and a scientific evaluation of uncertainty must always be

considered in the procedure of sustainability assessment. For this

reason, the use of natural language and linguistic values based on the

60

fuzzy logic methodology (Munda et al., 1994) seems more suitable to

assess sustainability. In the two next following chapters, we will first

explain sustainability in rangeland management and some basic

concerned challenges, which can be the causes of (dis)equilibrium.

Then, in Chapter 5, we will introduce fuzzy logic as a powerful tool to

deal with these challenges.

61

Chapter Four

Rangeland Management:

Basic Challenges and Principles

4.1. A review of literature

An accelerating rate of literature is being published on rangeland

management, although, the use of rangelands for domestic productions

is increasingly questioned on conservation and sustainability grounds

in all over the world (Fleischner, 1994, Grigg, 1995). However, much

recent literature on grazing management, particularly literature from

the arid to sub-humid regions, is at a theoretical level (e.g. Westoby et

al., 1989). This is in part because adaptive management research - to

determine appropriate management practices for extensively managed

rangelands - is now just beginning at the operational scale. Simulation

modeling and decision support systems are currently the only way to

explore the many possible management alternatives. Grazing

managers do not just adopt a new grazing system but rather they adapt

a suite of management changes in conjunction with implementing a

new grazing system. Savory and Butterfield (1999) are right in stating

that grazing management may not be researched in the manner of

normal biological research. There is a need to develop principles that

can be integrated using simulation modeling into grazing management

systems. Business schools have extensively studied management

practices of successful businesses by interviewing managers and

observing how successful businesses are operated (Peters and

62

Waterman, 1982), not by setting up replicate corporations based on

different management challenges and collecting data on them over a

number of years. However, even while modeling approaches are being

developed and validated, there is still a need now for some practical

guidelines for grazing management. Thus for the present and

foreseeable future common sense and rule of thumb solutions to

grazing management problems may be the most useful. This chapter

reviews some practical recommendations for managing grazing on

rangelands. In doing so, as most of nomadic people in the world and

especially in Iran live in the arid to sub-arid rangeland areas

(McMurphy et al., 1990), our focus would be around the conditions of

these areas which are faced by socio-economic and ecological

challenges, rather than the more humid areas where agronomic

challenges are widely survived.

The debate in preparing this chapter has been to understand why we

propound especial principles and challenges to reach equilibrium in

rangeland management. The main reason is, as we have discussed in

Chapter 5, a need to develop a new model; using fuzzy logic, which

needs some criteria as inputs of the model. This is particularly because

over 4,000 papers and books were published on the subject since 1970

to show how we can arrive at the challenges of grazing management

in practice (Walker and Hodgkinson, 2000). In the following, at first,

we give a discussion to find the concept of rangeland management; if

it implicates to art or/and science. Secondly, we describe equilibrium

and disequilibrium systems in rangeland management. Then, we

explain current challenges in pastoral systems, and finally, we explain

basic principles to reach equilibrium.

63

4.2. Rangeland management: Art or science?

Although the definition of rangeland management has changed

somewhat over the years, the part that states it is both an art and a

science has not. In 1943, Stoddart and Smith defined rangeland

management as "the science and art of planning and directing

rangeland use so as to obtain the maximum livestock production

consistent with conservation of the range resources" (Stoddart and

Smith, 1943). This definition implies a sustained yield of livestock

over a long period of time. The book leaves no doubt that the main

objective was to produce livestock. In the second edition (1955) of

their book, rangeland management was the science and art of

obtaining maximum livestock production from rangeland consistent

with the conservation of land resources. This definition asserts

rangeland management is closely related to animal husbandry and

plant ecology; a movement from livestock production to land

management in 12 years. Twenty years later (in the third edition)

Stoddart et al., (1975) defined rangeland management as "the science

and art of optimizing the returns from rangelands in those

combinations most desired by and suitable to society through the

manipulation of rangeland ecosystems. The science portion of

rangeland management provides a body of knowledge in which

principles are developed. Principles should not dictate management,

but provide guidelines for management. An artful management is

therefore, the skillful and/or ingenious application of scientific

principles, experience, and creativity to land management practices.

In new definitions, however, rangeland management is a lot more of

an art than science, since there is so much we do not know about

rangeland ecosystems’ mechanisms and processes that drive rangeland

64

ecosystems. Ecosystems are too complex and too dynamic in both

time and space to ever have fully figured out. This makes it easy for

interest or user groups from all perspectives to challenge us. We are

also challenged because many land management decisions were not

made in an artful manner (Miller, 1995).

4.3. Equilibrium and disequilibrium systems in rangeland

management

For the objectives of this dissertation, we consider equilibrium versus

disequilibrium continuum in pastoral systems. Equilibrium systems

are those that may change plant species composition in response to

grazing, but when grazing pressure is reduced, will return to their

former composition. These systems typically have a long evolutionary

history of grazing, are not susceptible to invasion by undesirable

plants, either woody or herbaceous, and can be managed using simple

models of succession. Disequilibrium systems are those that never

reach a steady state and are controlled primarily by unpredictable

factors such as rainfall and fire. These systems typically have a short

evolutionary history of grazing, are prone to invasion by undesirable

plants and are best managed using the state and transition model of

community dynamics (Walker and Hodgkinson, 2000).

Management of equilibrium systems is fairly straightforward because

these systems respond to change in total grazing pressure. Outcomes

must be described and criteria established to monitor progress. A

grazing management plan could be developed based on manipulating

livestock species, grazing season, distribution and stocking rate to

accomplish goals. For instance, if maximum sustainable production of

livestock products is the objective and distribution is not considered a

65

problem, then year-long continuous grazing using sheep and cattle at a

variable stocking rate tied to annual rainfall would be appropriate.

Decision support systems are currently available to monitor and adjust

stocking rate to match animal demand with primary production (Stuth

and Lyons, 1993). In equilibrium ecosystems, management to

maintain the right rate of stocking is the most important factor of

grazing management. This can be done with a simple rotation or even

continuous grazing system. Season or timing of use, livestock species

and distribution can be adjusted to increase carrying capacity or

accomplish other management objectives such as multiple uses. The

objectives of multiple uses will complicate the grazing management of

equilibrium systems, but in many cases there is commonality of states

that meet different objectives. For example, grazing management that

retains all palatable plant species will probably meet both biodiversity

and sustainable production goals (Walker and Hodgkinson, 2000).

Disequilibrium systems are more difficult to manage because even in

the absence of livestock they may be unstable, particularly if invasion

by undesirable plant and animal species is a problem. Invasion by

woody plants is a widespread problem, which although potentially

accelerated by grazing, typically will also occur in the absence of

grazing (Archer, 1996). Fire is the best tool for controlling woody

plant invasion, but the ability to use this tool is dependent upon

grazing systems to accumulate and manage grass fuel levels. In these

systems grass production will usually need to be managed both as

forage and as fuel (Kothmann et al., 1997). Because of the tendencies

of disequilibrium systems to cross thresholds to less productive states,

grazing systems that have been shown to advance succession will have

the greatest potential for maintaining plant communities in the desired

66

vegetation state. Because of the long deferment periods and resultant

increased grazing intensity on the grazed units, these types of systems

tend to be very sensitive to stocking rate particularly as it affects

animal performance. Another advantage of grazing systems with long

deferment periods is that they are the ones best adapted to accumulate

the grass fuel required for a successful prescribed fire program

(Howery et al., 2000).

We have purposefully avoided discussing grazing systems per se,

because there is no evidence to indicate that they provide any

advantage other than the flexibility that cross fencing and grouping of

animals provide for managing livestock distribution and timing of

grazing. However, as we learn more about how timing may be used to

provide either rest or grazing pressure at critical times to accomplish

vegetation management goals, this flexibility will be increasingly

important. Likewise, when prescribed fire becomes an integral part of

the grazing management plan the flexibility of multiple rangelands to

manage grass as forage or fuel becomes very important (Walker and

Hodgkinson, 2000).

4.4. Current challenges in rangeland management

4.4.1. Overgrazing

The most contentious and emotional rangeland use issue now and in

the foreseeable future is balancing private rights with the public

interest. This debate often terminates to overgrazing (private rights)

and sustainability (public rights) (Box, 1995). This issue will surface

in such different rangeland use debates as historical preservation,

endangered species, location of waste disposal facilities, and public

rangeland management. The controversy of overgrazing on public

67

rangelands, therefore, is not just about cows and grass. It is about

ownership of the public lands and it is about what rights pastoralists

can hold in a common resource (Box, 2002; Deadman, 1999).

Whenever pastoralists prefer to focus on their own rights and to

neglect the public rights, rangeland degradation will be unavoidable,

especially for next generations (Azadi et al., 2003).

In general, rangeland degradation falls into two broad categories: that

resulting from extended periods of drought, and that resulting from

overuse through cultivation or overgrazing (Hiernaux, 1996). With

uncontrolled grazing, most rangelands are overgrazed and the

vegetation is depleted. Due to overuse of resources, especially

overgrazing, and the application of non-suitable management practices

such as low recognition of prevalent natural vegetation cycles in grass

and thorn bush savannahs without considering long-term degradation

processes, the rangeland quality of many rangeland areas has declined

(Buss and Nuppenau, 2002). A visible decreasing appearance of

natural composition of grass and bush cover, bush encroachment and a

decreasing biodiversity indicate lower stocking potentials for domestic

livestock on large areas of rangeland, especially in developing

countries such as Iran (Mesdaghi, 1995). In this case, rangeland

degradation becomes an economical threat to falling pastoralists’

income, a social threat to the continuation of rural-urban immigration,

and an environmental threat to desertification. As a response, on one

hand, many pastoralists increase their livestock and overgraze the

rangelands. On the other hand, economic and political pressures push

them to produce red meat for a growing population, especially for

urban people. Plantation density, therefore, will decrease and

degradation will happen. Sometimes, government policies

68

inadvertently provide incentives that encourage overgrazing.

Overgrazing occurs, even though analysis demonstrates that maximum

net economic returns will occur below the maximum sustainable level

of livestock off-take per unit area (Buxton and Stafford Smith, 1996).

Financial crisis is another factor tempting graziers to push stocking to

the limit. Pastoral businesses facing insolvency are greatly tempted to

increase stocking rates in an effort to sustain their operation until

commodity prices or climate take a favourable turn. Carrying capacity

and the appropriate stocking rate cannot be determined until the

decisions relative to so species of livestock, season of use and

distribution have been revised (Taghi Farvar and Jandaghi, 1998;

Walker and Hodgkinson, 2000).

4.4.2. Carrying capacity

The science of rangeland management adapted carrying capacity

concepts to grazing systems on the rangelands. The logic basis for this

concern is the concept of rangeland carrying capacity. Carrying

capacity is considered to be the average number of animals that a

particular rangeland or range can sustain over time. Stocking Rate

(SR) is expressed as the number of animal unit months (aum)1

supplied by unit of area (e.g. hectare). An animal unit month is the

amount of forage required by an animal unit (au)2 grazing for one

month (Kopp, 2004). The responsibility of rangeland managers is to

try to balance livestock grazing pressure with the natural regenerative

1. The term aum is commonly used in three ways: (a) Stocking rate, as in "X unit of area per aum";

(b) forage allocations, as in "X aum(s) in Allotment A"; (c) utilization, as in "X aum(s) taken from Unit B (Glossary of Terms Used in Range Management, 2002).

2. An animal unit (au) is defined as an "average" live body weight equal to 1000 lbs (453.59 kg) (NRCS, 2000).

69

capacity of rangeland plants. The estimations of carrying capacity are

usually based on assumptions about the impact of livestock on plants

and plant succession. Heavy livestock grazing is thought to lead to a

decline in rangeland condition, and reducing or removing grazing

pressure assumed plant successional processes would restore the

rangeland to its previous condition. By knowing the rangeland

condition class1, the proper use factor, or the amount of forage to

leave to allow plant nutrients to be restored, and taking into account

distance to water, slope steepness, and other factors, carrying

capacities for a particular rangeland or pasture could be determined

(Miller, 2005). These managerial estimations have usually been used

in many countries such as Iran.

Before turning to the next section, it should be noted that in most

instances where rangelands are being grazed by domestic livestock in

an unsustainable manner, the root cause is the lack of well-matched

theory on grazing management. However, we believe that the below-

discussed principles can be understood to alleviate the most of above-

discussed challenges associated with grazing by domestic livestock.

Pastoralists can be expected to make rational decisions from their

point of view. In general, it should be noticed where grazing

management is poor, the theory may be wrong or incomplete, or it

may apply to only part of a system being managed. Other factors such

as social and economic may override consideration of grazing

management.

1. Rangeland condition class is defined by the percent of climax for the range site, classified as

"Poor" (0-25), "Fair" (26-50), "Good" (51-75), and "Excellent" (76-100) (Glossary of Terms Used in Range Management, 2002).

70

4.5. Basic principles in rangeland management

The purposes of grazing management is to minimise the adverse

impacts of domestic livestock and other herbivores that comprise the

total grazing pressure on the natural resources of soil and biota and to

maximise the probability that the grazing enterprise will be

sustainable. This statement does not imply that grazing is not

sustainable or that grazing is not an important ecological force in

many rangeland ecosystems (Milchunas et al., 1988). However, at the

level of individual plants, defoliation decreases production in the vast

majority of instances (Jameson, 1963) and in most instances the

purpose of grazing management is to ameliorate this negative effect

and maintain a competitive balance among the plant assemblage.

There are now multiple desired outcomes for a sustainable grazing

enterprise (Walker, 1995), and this trend is likely to increase. The

goals of grazing management may include control of undesirable

vegetation (Olson and Lacey, 1994), enhancing wildlife habitat

(Mosley, 1994), reduction of fire hazard, maintenance of biodiversity

(Landsberg et al., 1999), animal traction, manure, banking livestock

capital and, of course, for the profitable production of food and fibre.

Herbivores, including domestic livestock, highly select the plants and

plant parts they graze (Leigh and Mulham, 1966) and the parts of the

landscape they favour for grazing (Landsberg and Stol, 1996, Roshier

and Nicol, 1998). Plants are the victims of defoliation, overgrazing,

and suffer through reduction in the plant's resource capturing ability.

Ultimately, such reduction impairs the ability of rangeland plants to

survive times of resource scarcity (Hodgkinson, 1996). Ecosystem

functioning may also change under the impact of grazing and other

anthropomorphic influences. For example, the chance of fire may be

71

greatly reduced (Hodgkinson and Harrington, 1985) and competitive

relationships among plant species may be altered because of elevated

atmospheric CO2 that has resulted from the burning of fossil fuels

(Polley, 1997).

Development of a grazing management strategy for a pastoral

enterprise requires definition of the desired outcomes and of the

inherent constraints. From these, the solution space of the problem can

be defined and management can then adjust the stocking rate, grazing

patterns, livestock species and distribution of grazing animals in

different seasons. It should be recognised that any time domestic

livestock are grazed, related decisions to livestock species, timing of

grazing and stocking rate have to be made, either consciously or

unconsciously. Improving grazing distribution, however, normally

requires the investment in capital improvements such as fencing or

water development. Stocking rate is usually considered the most

important factor as well as the most abused factor in grazing

management. The importance of season of grazing is dependent upon

the climate of an area and whether cross fencing is in place that would

allow the implementation of a grazing management system. Existing

conditions in many areas dictate that on a large percentage of grazing

lands, season of grazing is not a factor that can be managed readily.

However, resting from grazing to foster plant recovery and seed

production, and in some cases to prevent accelerated mortality of

domestic stock due to forage and water scarcity, is desirable in

ecosystems of non-seasonal rainfall. This can be achieved by lease

grazing, stock sale or feeding of livestock on forage reserved within

the property (Walker and Hodgkinson, 2000).

72

Choice of species of livestock is an under-utilized management tool at

the present time. The selection of the species of livestock best adapted

to a particular environment is often the simplest solution to grazing

management problems. However, many graziers are reluctant to make

such changes often for cultural reasons but also because of physical

reasons such as predators. In both developed countries with the

majority of pastoral business (e.g. the USA) and less developed

countries with the majority of nomadic people (e.g. Iran), the impact

of grazing on riparian areas, is one of the biggest grazing management

problems (Kauffman and Krueger, 1984). Overgrazing of riparian

areas affects biodiversity and water quality and is caused primarily by

a distribution problem. Whereas ribbon fencing of riparian areas is a

solution that has been used in some areas, a much simpler solution is

to change from cattle to sheep or goats, which prefer uplands to

riparian areas (Glimp and Swanson, 1994). Unfortunately, evaluating

the appropriate species of livestock, which should be the first

consideration in developing a grazing management plan, is seldom

considered. Control of undesirable plants is another example of a

problem that often is best solved by changing species of livestock. It is

a truism that plants dominating an area are the ones avoided by the

dominant herbivores in the system. Whereas determining the dietary

preferences of grazing livestock is often difficult, determining the

plants that are avoided is typically much easier. If a species of

livestock exists that has a preference for the undesirable plant,

changing livestock species is an easy solution. Classic examples

include the use of sheep or goats to control leafy spurge (Euphorbia

eusla L.; Johnson and Peake, 1960) or gorse (Ulex europaeus L.;

Radcliffe, 1985). Finally, if the management goal is to maximise

73

profit and minimise risk, then mixed species grazing, which has been

shown to accomplish this objective under a wide array of price ratios

(Connolly and Nolan, 1976) should be implemented. However, except

for a few areas where it is the cultural norm this practice is rarely used

(Walker, 1994).

Timing of defoliation may adversely affect a plant's ability to replace

tissue, reproduce and compete for resources. There are times when a

plant can be grazed safely and there are other times when grazing will

raise the probability of the plant's dying or its growth being impaired

(Blaisdell and Pechanec, 1949). Animal grazing preferences vary

seasonally and interact with seasonal plant responses. In temperate

climates with strong seasonal differences in temperature and

topography, seasonal grazing practices have evolved to meet stock and

natural resource requirements. Properties with contrasting soil types,

such as floodplains and runoff landscapes, also are a form of seasonal

grazing based on flooding patterns. Timing of grazing, for whatever

reason, will affect stocking rate because grazing at sensitive times will

reduce primary production and community stability unless grazing

levels are low. In areas with large topography differences,

phenological development may vary by 60 to 90 days between the

valley floor and the alpine grasslands. Grazing management

accommodates these differences in phenological development as

livestock are moved up the mountain following the green (Burkhart,

1996). Similarly, in those rangelands where properties are large and

rainfall is irregular in space and time, such as in semi-arid woodlands,

livestock may be moved to a paddock(s) where high rainfall from a

convective storm has generated a pulse of plant growth (Hodgkinson

and Freudenberger, 1997; Martin, 1978). Tactical grazing, particularly

74

in semi-arid areas, is a management option that is under-utilized. It is

time to reevaluate the appropriateness of continuous grazing (Holmes,

1996). The economic and ecological implications of grazing selected

rangeland areas only during the seasons or years with adequate rainfall

for plant requirements need urgent evaluation.

Landscape degradation and adverse vegetation change from

overgrazing was one of the primary factors leading to the development

of the discipline of range science. While the importance of proper

stocking rate is well recognised and techniques for assessing the

problem are available, overgrazing is still a major problem in many

countries such as Iran. However, it is more of a problem of wrong

mental models than inadequate technology and there are several

factors that tempt pastoralists to exceed the carrying capacity of a

property. These factors include the variable and unpredictable nature

of rainfall coupled with the overly optimistic attitude of graziers who

gamble on the ending of drought. Unfortunately, in many arid areas,

probability of a drought is greater than the probability of normal

rainfall (Riggio et al., 1987). Sometimes, government policies

inadvertently provide incentives that encourage overgrazing (Foran

and Stafford Smith, 1991; Holechek and Hess, 1995). Overgrazing

occurs even though analysis demonstrates that maximum net

economic returns will occur below the maximum sustainable level of

livestock per unit of area (Buxton and Stafford Smith, 1996).

Financial crisis is another factor tempting graziers to push stocking to

the limit. Pastoral businesses facing insolvency are greatly tempted to

increase stocking rates in an effort to sustain their operation until

commodity prices or climate take a favourable turn. Properties located

in the more arid regions with lower carrying capacities tend to be less

75

profitable because of higher fixed cost (Holechek and Hawkes, 1993).

Thus, the temptation to overgraze is often greatest in the areas that are

the most vulnerable. Carrying capacity and the right rate of stocking

cannot be determined until the decisions relative to species of

livestock, season of use and distribution have been made. Although,

the correct stocking rate is dependent upon these other three factors,

the overall success of the system will be dependent upon setting the

right rate of stocking. In general, when stocking rate is too high, the

system will not be sustainable even if the other components of grazing

management are correct.

Unsuitable spatial distribution is the cause of many problems

associated with grazing livestock (Holechek et al., 1989).

Furthermore, uneven distribution is caused by characteristics of both

the grazing animal as well as the plant community or landscape.

Distribution of livestock occurs at many levels and affects and is

affected by livestock species, season of use and stocking rate. Many

overgrazing problems are actually species of livestock or season of

grazing problems and are in a sense manifested as distribution

problems. Examples include overgrazing of riparian areas or grazing

prior to range readiness, both of which can cause adverse impacts at

very low grazing intensities. Carrying capacity in large pastures with

unsuitable livestock distribution is lower than on similar areas with

suitable distribution. Unsuitable distribution may buffer the effect of

changes in stocking rate on livestock performance compared to the

classic response curve where animals are well distributed (Stafford

Smith, 1996). Fencing and water development have traditionally been

used to improve distribution and the benefits from infrastructure

development can be modeled.

76

Grazing systems are based on manipulation of spatial and temporal

distribution of livestock grazing pressure. Because grazing systems

involve rotating animals among rangelands they actually determine

the distribution of livestock. There is a good evidence that any

production benefits that result from implementing grazing systems

arise from improved distribution and increased carrying capacity (Hart

et al., 1993) rather than altered foraging behaviour (Gammon and

Roberts, 1978) or increased primary production (Heitschmidt et al.,

1987). While most researches on animal distribution have been

conducted at the enclosure level, the effect of meta-scale distribution,

which involves transportation systems and grazing livestock only

during those seasons or years with adequate rainfall, deserves more

consideration in disequilibrium areas as a means of achieving

sustainable systems.

In contrast, when non-pastoral goals such as maintenance of

biodiversity become important grazing management objectives,

practices that improve livestock distribution may not be implemented

because they conflict with the other objectives (Landsberg et al.,

1997). Ensuring that parts of enclosures are ungrazed or lightly grazed

would meet biodiversity objectives at local scale. The most important

challenge and basic principles in rangeland management is, to devise

and implement strategies that will strike a balance between the needs

of pastoralists to consume rangeland at local level, and the needs of

future generations to conserve rangeland biodiversity at national

level.

The greatest impediment to these trade-offs is the value systems and

personality characteristics of pastoralists on one hand, and decision

makers, on the other hand (Thompson, 1995). These characteristics,

77

which are important for the successful settlement and development of

the current livestock production systems, tend to make people with

current tenure of the land very resistant to manage sustainably.

However, if one accepts the self-evident statement that "the only

sustainable rangeland management is profitable rangeland"

(Ainesworth, 1989) and the trends discussed above continue,

eventually economics will either transform pastoralists or cause a

change in ownership. Then the products and services produced on

rangelands will be more congruent with contemporary socio-economic

systems. This will also affect the types of information and technology

that will be demanded from rangeland specialists, although the

management principles can remain constantly (i.e., livestock species,

distribution, timing and stocking rate).

One of the best examples in this case is the current situation of Iranian

nomadic people. Where there is overstocking, this is environmentally

unfriendly since overgrazing and subsequent land degradation would

result. Iranian pastoralists have to be educated on limiting their

livestock according to the carrying capacity of the land somehow

overgrazing and degradation do not occur. In this case, a restocking

program for the districts is needed. Therefore, it is a challenge to

improve the management of livestock rising by introducing new

methods of rangeland management including zero grazing (Azadi et

al., In revision).

4.6. Conclusion

A claim is commonly made that the rangelands of the world are

overgrazed and hence producing edible forage and animal produce at

less than their potential (Wilson and Macleod, 1991). Globally,

78

rangelands are at risk from numerous pressures (Mitchell et al., 1999).

Some of these pressures arise from livestock/rangeland systems.

Livestock have been a key factor in the development of civilization,

but their role in the future is not clear as well as how the science of

rangeland management should change in order to meet the challenges

of the future. Carrying capacity is the most important variable in

rangeland management (Walker, 1995). At a time when the planet's

limited carrying capacity seems increasingly obvious, the rationale

and measures of rangelands carrying capacity are increasingly

criticized. One of the key elements of rangeland capacity is stocking

rate. Calculating stocking rate is relatively simple once the concept

and terminology are understood. The ability to calculate stocking rate

and make timely management decisions is vital to maximizing net

returns from the livestock operation (Redfearn and Bidwell, 2004). If

stocking rate is not close to the proper level related to equilibrium

rate, then, regardless of other grazing management practices employed

objectives will not be met (Roe, 1997).

The recent literatures on rangelands disequilibrium call in question

any specific measures of carrying capacity, whether the range is

stocked or unstocked, managed or mis-managed. The stocking rate of

a given area can vary in accordance with management decisions

(Kenny, 2004). Stocking rate should be based on average long-term

end-of-season standing crop values for an operation to remain

productive and sustainable. The procedure for calculating stocking

rates can be used on either forests or rangelands. Stocking rates are

based on the amount of forage that is standing at the end of the

growing season in an ungrazed condition. End-of-season standing

crop is not total production because much of the production has been

79

lost to decomposition and insects. Actual forage production is often

twice as large as the end-of-season standing crop. Forage production

information is useful but is very time consuming to obtain. That is

why end-of-season standing crop is used for estimating stocking rate

(Redfearn and Bidwell, 2004).

The common mathematical process used to estimate stocking rate

from herbage biomass is to determine the amount of herbage available

during the grazing season, which is the average value of the mean

monthly standing herbage biomass values for the grazing-season

months. The mean monthly standing herbage biomass should be

determined by clipping and weighing the dry herbage from each

pasture and averaging the weights over several years. The general

monthly herbage values on the herbage weight are the averages of

herbage production on well-managed pastures during years with

normal precipitation (Manske, 2004).

Recommended stocking rates are based upon results from grazing

research, local experience and clipped-plot yields (Lacey and Taylor,

2005). The recommended stocking rates for rangelands should also be

based on moderate utilization (economic long-term optimum) of the

annual forage standing crop and assume uniform grazing distribution.

It is also assumed that 50% of the annual peak standing crop can be

removed from the ecological site without negatively affecting the

plant community relative to species abundance or for beef cattle

production. This is the origin of the “take half and leave half” rule-of-

thumb that is often used. This is also the source of difference in

stocking rate management between rangeland and introduced forages

(Redfearn and Bidwell, 2004). The old rule of thumb “take half, leave

half” is well publicized, but may not be well understood. This rule

80

applies to average annual forage production. It does not mean that half

the forage can be allotted to grazing animals. Part of what is taken will

go to the animals, but part will disappear through trampling, decay

and insect damage. This disappearance is usually about 25 percent of

the average annual production. Therefore, only 25 percent is left for

the grazing animal (Lyons and Machen, 2005).

Ideally, such objections can be taken into account for any individual

carrying capacity estimated by accepting that it has to be determined

on a case - by - case basis in the field. Once one knows the size of the

grazing and browsing animals, the biomass production of the area, the

pattern of range management, and so on, he/she can - so this argument

goes - produce a site specific stocking rate estimated for the range area

under consideration. But, it cannot pack livestock into a given

rangeland, without at some point deteriorating that range

demonstrably. Surely, biomass production is going down on

rangelands precisely because stocking rate has been exceeded for so

long, even taking into account factors such as drought and climate

change (Hardesty et al., 1993).

The rationale and measures of rangeland carrying capacity are

increasingly criticized. It seems that even under environmental

conditions of great certainty, the notion of rangeland equilibrium

would still be ambiguous and confused. Moreover, since

environmental conditions are highly uncertain for the dry rangelands

of the world such as Iran, current understanding of rangeland

equilibrium turns out to be all the more questionable. There is no

workable, practical “equation” for rangeland management in general,

and carrying capacity in particular (Roe, 1997). Similar problems exist

in other field of sustainable rangeland management. Here, we have

81

observed a number of publications which used fuzzy logic as a

valuable tool (Andriantiatsaholiniaina, 2001; Cornelissen et al., 2001;

de Kok et al., 2000; Dunn et al., 1995; El-Awad, 1991; Ferraro, et al.,

2003; Gowing et al., 1996; Marks et al., 1995; Phillis and

Andriantiatsaholiniaina, 2001; Sam-Amoah and Gowing, 2001; Sicat

et al., 2005). In these studies, fuzzy logic is used to construct a model

for evaluating sustainability in different areas. These models promise

to be a valuable tool in evaluating the sustainability in general and

equilibrium specifically in this dissertation. The purpose of the next

chapter is to design a fuzzy model based on the experts’ knowledge

for solving the mis-management of the Iranian rangelands.

82

Chapter Five

Application of Fuzzy Logic in Sustainable

Rangeland Management

Albert Einstein: "So far as the laws of mathematics refer

to reality, they are not certain. And so far as they are

certain, they do not refer to reality" (Kosko, 1993).

5.1. Fuzzy Logic: A shifting paradigm

As we discussed in Chapter 4, there is a conflict that arises between

consumption (economic dimension) and conservation (environmental

dimension) in rangeland management. In general, interdisciplinary

problem-oriented projects have undergone substantial change over the

last few decades (Barendse and van der Hoek, 1996) since, social

scientists (social dimension) have tried to reconcile such a conflict

(Azadi et al., 2003) by creating interdisciplinary experts’ teams, which

are constructed by cooperation of technical scientists (Shaner et al.,

1982). This approach, which started in 1970s, has labelled differently1.

The interdisciplinary experts’ teams usually require not only thorough

specialist knowledge about problem sources, mechanisms and options

for solution(s), but also the ability to integrate knowledge from

different fields (Barendse and van der Hoek, 1996) to introduce new

methods of grazing management for reaching sustainability (Azadi et

1. FSA: Farming System Analysis, FSAR: Farming System Adaptive Research, FSCR: Farming

System Component Research, FSBDA: Farming System Base-line Data Analysis, NFSD: New Farming Systems Development, FSRAD: Farming Systems Research and Agricultural Development FSRE: Farming System Research Extension (Sands, 1986).

83

al., 2003). They try to develop a systematic approach for better

understanding the complex situation of pastoralists. But as the

interdisciplinary team tries to implement various ideas belonging

different experts for the same situation (FAO, 2004c; Shaner et al.,

1982; Zilberman and Alix, 2005), the members often fail to reach an

identical understanding of this complex situation (Shahvali and Azadi,

1999). More clearly, the main problems involved in interdisciplinary

teams are as follows:

� Misunderstandings and misconceptions because of different

disciplinary languages (jargons) (Pickett et al., 1999);

� Overestimating or underestimating the contribution of their own

discipline in analyzing and solving problems (Heemskerk et al.,

2003);

� Lack of knowledge about integrating knowledge and insights

from different disciplinary fields (Barendse and van der Hoek,

1996); and

� Lack of knowledge about integrating methods and techniques

(Barendse and van der Hoek, 1996; Pickett et al., 1999).

Thereby, when presenting their ideas concerning the sustainability in

rangeland management, they usually: (Azadi et al., 2003)

� Select rangeland equilibrium indicators differently;

� Weigh the indicators unequally; and

� Assess them in different ways.

84

The above-mentioned problems exist in other field of SD. To solve

these problems we use fuzzy sets theory to assess sustainability, and to

deal with different experts’ knowledge in rangeland management.

Fuzzy logic is one of the fastest growing methodologies in systems

engineering (Grint, 1997). In 1965, Lotfi A. Zadeh laid the foundation

of fuzzy logic theory. Since then and, especially, after the

announcement of the first fuzzy chips in 1987, the literature on both

theory and applications of fuzzy logic has been growing (Berkan and

Trubatch, 1997).

In a broad sense, fuzziness is the opposite of precision. Everything

that cannot be defined precisely (that is, according to some broadly

accepted criteria or norms of precision) and everything that has no

clearly described boundaries in space or time is considered a bearer of

fuzziness. In a narrow sense, fuzzy logic relates to the definition of

fuzzy sets as proposed by Zadeh (Zimmermann, 1996): sets, the

belongingness to which is measured by a membership function whose

values are between 1 (full belongingness) and 0 (non- belongingness).

According to ‘Principle of Incompatibility’, “as the complexity of a

system increases, human ability to make precious and relevant

(meaningful) statements about its behaviour diminishes until a

threshold is reached beyond which the precision and the relevance

become mutually exclusive characteristics” (Zadeh, 1973, p. 29). It is,

therefore, that fuzzy statements are the only bearers of meaning and

relevance. Zadeh used this principle for extending the applicability of

his fuzzy sets theory and fuzzy logic to the analysis of complex

systems. It is now realized that complex real-world problems require

intelligent systems that combine knowledge, techniques, and

methodologies from various sources. These intelligent systems are

85

supposed to do better in changing environment, and explain how they

make decisions or take actions (Jang et al., 1997). Ecological studies

are known to be complex in nature (Silvert, 1997) and therefore fuzzy

logic seems to be an appropriate technique to solve the dichotomy that

is inherent in sustainability of natural resources

(Andriantiatsaholiniaina, 2001; Cornelissen et al., 2001; Dunn et al.,

1995; Marks et al., 1995).

5.2. Foundations of fuzzy logic

The mathematics of fuzzy sets and fuzzy logic is discussed in detail in

many books (e.g., Lee, 1990; Driankov et al., 1996; Ruspini et al.,

1998; Zimmermann, 1996). Here, we provide only a very basic aspect

of the mathematics of fuzzy logic.

5.2.1. Crisp models

In quantitative sciences where mathematical models are used for

analyzing real-world phenomena, (stochastic) variables are introduced

having a ‘well-defined’ meaning. During their scientific work, the

corresponding scientists apply mathematical tools from calculus, from

the theory of differential equations, from discrete mathematics, from

(vector) algebra, from numerical methods, from (complex) function

theory, and more (van den Berg, 2004). The resulting models offer an

‘idealized’ world, an ‘objective and structured reality’ with, hopefully,

rather general validity. Uncertainty is usually described in

probabilistic and statistical terms like probabilities on crisp events (i.e.

events that do occur or do not occur at all), expected values, statistical

tests (that are either rejected or not rejected), interval estimations, et

cetera (Zimmermann, 1996). Propositions within these approaches are

86

usually supposed to be either true or false (and sometimes unknown).

In line with this way of working as applied in physics, chemistry,

econometrics, and other ‘hard sciences’, the first knowledge-based

systems developed in the community of Artificial Intelligence were

founded on the ‘physical symbol system hypothesis’ expressing that

symbols (and only symbols) can represent states of the world and

statements about the world. Again, the only ‘epistemological

commitments’ allowed for these statements are either true, false or

unknown. The physical symbol system hypothesis has still to be

proven (van den Berg, 2004).

5.2.2. Boolean vs. Fuzzy

Three hundred years B.C., the Greek philosopher, Aristotle came up

with binary logic (0,1), which is now the principle foundation of

Mathematics. It came down to one law: A or not A, either this or not

this. For example, a typical rose is either red or not red. It cannot be

red and not red. Every statement or sentence is true or false or has the

truth-value 1 or 0. This is Aristotle's law of bivalence and was

philosophically correct for over two thousand years (Kosko, 1993).

Two centuries before Aristotle, Buddha, had the belief which

contradicted the black-and-white world of worlds, which went beyond

the bivalent cocoon and see the world as it is, filled with

contradictions, with things and not things. He stated that a rose, could

be to a certain degree completely red, but at the same time could also

be at a certain degree not red. Meaning that it can be red and not red at

the same time. Conventional (Boolean) logic states that a glass can be

full or not full of water. However, suppose one were to fill the glass

only halfway. Then the glass can be half-full and half-not-full.

87

Clearly, this disproves Aristotle's law of bivalence. This concept of

certain degree or multivalence is the fundamental concept, which

propelled Zadeh at the University of California in 1965 to introduce

fuzzy logic. The essential characteristics of fuzzy logic founded by

him are as follows (Abdul Aziz, 1996):

• In fuzzy logic, exact reasoning is viewed as a limiting case of

approximate reasoning,

• In fuzzy logic everything is a matter of degree,

• Any logical system can be fuzzified,

• In fuzzy logic, knowledge is interpreted as a collection of

elastic or, equivalently, fuzzy constraint on a collection of

variables, and

• Inference is viewed as a process of propagation of elastic

constraints.

The third statement hence, defines Boolean logic as a subset of Fuzzy

logic.

5.2.3. Towards soft computing

It is clear from history that the hard sciences have been and still are

quite successful in many areas. Based on this success, they have

obtained a strong and predominant position and many scientists

working in this field seem to believe that their approach of crisp, two-

valued logical, precise mathematical modeling where uncertainty is

modeled within a probabilistic, statistical framework, is the one and

only true, applicable approach (van den Berg, 2004).

88

For several reasons, however, like ‘irrelevance’ and ‘complexity’, one

may doubt whether hard computing is always the right tool.

Considering ‘Principle of Incompatibility’, we try to answer the

following series of questions related to problems with increasing

complexity. They may convince you of the validity of Zadeh’s

principle: (1) How sustainable is a rangeland? (2) Which measures are

important for a sustainable rangeland management? (3) How much is

the stocking rate of a sustainable rangeland? (4) How much is its

plantation density? (5) How much annual rainfall is needed in a

sustainable rangeland? (6) How many pastoralists’ families can live

in?

Another, every-day, example related to the irrelevance of information

may also be illustrative. This example shows that offering some short,

incomplete information can be much more relevant than

communicating an extensive and precise message: if you are

sauntering on a road and a car is approaching you with high speed, the

warning “A car of length 4.65 m and height 1.54 m with mass 1348.7

kg is approaching you with a speed of 56.645 kmph” is probably

much less relevant than the quite fuzzy cry: “Look Out!!”. From the

context, the saunterer will probably immediately understand the

meaning of this message and undertake appropriate action (by running

away).

In the world of Artificial Intelligence, similar lessons have been

learned. While, implementing systems based on ideas like the above-

mentioned physical symbol hypothesis, problems arose related to the

modeling of the likeliness of a certain conclusion and to the lack of

robustness and flexibility. Apparently, the tools as made available by

the hard sciences also have their limitations when trying to apply

89

‘intelligent techniques’. In several cases, it has been shown that

alternative approaches with fuzzy or other ‘vague’ ingredients work

better. Successful fuzzy modeling projects exist since 1975 on topics

like automatic control, printed character recognition, target selection

for marketing purposes, financial modeling, SD, and more (van den

Berg, 2004).

5.2.4. Towards fuzzy sets

Let U be a collection of objects u which can be discrete or continuous.

U is called the universe of discourse and u represents an element of U.

A classical (crisp) subset C in a universe U can be denoted in several

ways like, in the discrete case, by enumeration of its elements: C =

{u1, u2 ,… , uP} with ∀i: ui ∈ U. Another way to define C (both in the

discrete and the continuous case) is by using the characteristic

function χF: U→{0, 1} according to χF (u) = 1 if u ∈ C, and χF (u) =

0 if u ∉ C. The latter type of definition can be generalized in order to

define fuzzy sets. A fuzzy set F in a universe of discourse U is

characterized by a membership function µF which takes values in the

interval [0, 1] namely, µF: U→[0, 1].

5.2.5. Operators on fuzzy sets

Let A and B be two fuzzy sets in U with membership functions µA and

µB, respectively. The fuzzy set resulting from operations of union,

intersection, etc. of fuzzy sets are defined using their membership

functions. Generally, several choices are possible:

90

Union: The membership function BA∪

µ of the union A∪B can be

defined by )}(),(max{: uuu BABA µµµ =∀ ∪ or by

).()()()(: uuuuuBABABA

µµµµµ −+=∀∪

Intersection: The membership function BA∩

µ of the union for all

A∩B can be defined by )}(),(min{: uuu BABA µµµ =∀ ∩ or by

).().(: uuu BABA µµµ =∀ ∩

Complement: The membership function of the

complementary fuzzy set Ac of A is usually defined by

)(1)(: uuu AAc µµ −=∀ .

5.2.6. Linguistic variables

Fuzzy logic enables the modeling of expert knowledge. The key

notion to do so is that of a linguistic variable (instead of a quantitative

variable) which takes linguistic values (instead of numerical ones).

For example, if stocking rate (SR) in a rangeland is interpreted as

linguistic variable, then its linguistic values could be one from the so-

called term-set T(SR) = {low, medium, high} where each term in

T(SR) is characterized by a fuzzy set in the universe of discourse, here,

e.g., U = [0, 5]. We might interpret low as a “stocking rate of less than

approximately 1.5 aum/ha”, medium as a “stocking rate close to 2

aum/ha”, and high as a “stocking rate of roughly more than 2.5

aum/ha” where the class boundaries are fuzzy. These linguistic values

are characterized by fuzzy sets whose membership functions are

shown in Fig. 5.1.

91

3 1

2

medium high low

5 0

1

SR (aum/ha)

µi(SR)

Fig. 5.1. Diagrammatic representation of the linguistic variable stocking rate in a rangeland having linguistic values low, medium, and high defined by a corresponding membership function.

5.2.7. Knowledge representation by fuzzy IF-Then rules

Fuzzy logic is a scientific tool that permits simulation of the dynamics

of a system without a detailed mathematical description. In an expert-

driven approach, knowledge is represented by fuzzy IF-THEN

linguistic rules having the general form

where x1, … , xm are linguistic input variables with linguistic values

A1, … , Am respectively and where y is the linguistic output variable

with linguistic value B.

To illuminate we consider animal unit and plantation density as the

principal factors for having equilibrium. Then the relevant fuzzy rules

could be:

- IF amount of animal unit is low AND plantation density is

poor THEN equilibrium is medium.

- IF amount of animal unit is medium AND plantation density

is poor THEN equilibrium is weak.

- IF amount of animal unit is high AND plantation density is

poor THEN equilibrium is very weak.

, is THEN is AND is AND is If 2211 ByAxAxAx mmΛ

92

5.2.8. Architecture of fuzzy systems

Fuzzy Inference Systems or, shortly, Fuzzy Systems (FSs) usually

implement a crisp input-output (IO) mapping consisting of basically

four units, namely

• A Fuzzifier transforming crisp inputs into the fuzzy domain,

• A Rule Base of fuzzy IF-THEN rules,

• An Inference Engine implementing fuzzy reasoning by

combining the fuzzified input with the rules of the Rule

Base,

• A Defuzzifier transforming the fuzzy output of the Inference

Engine to a crisp value (Fig. 5.2).

Fig. 5.2. Building blocks of a Fuzzy Inference System (FIS).

In some practical systems, the Fuzzifier or the Defuzzifier may be

absent namely in cases where fuzzy input data are available or the

fuzzy system output can be interpreted directly in linguistic terms.

Corresponding "approximate reasoning techniques" are available (see,

e.g., Jang et al., 1997).

5.2.9. Fuzzy reasoning

Probably, the hardest part to understand is the precise way fuzzy

reasoning can be implemented. An extensive discussion of this topic is

outside the scope of this dissertation so we limit ourselves here to

93

present just the basic idea. Classical logic is our starting point using

the classical reasoning pattern ‘modus ponens’:

Given fact “x is A” and rule “IF x is A, THEN y is B”, we conclude “y

is B”.

“Applying fuzzy reasoning, classical modus ponens can be

generalized to an ‘approximate reasoning’ scheme of type.”

Given fact “x is A' ” and rule “IF x is A, THEN y is B”, we conclude

that “y is B' ”.

Here, the assumption made is that the closer A' to A, the closer will B'

be to B. It turns out that especial combinations of operations on fuzzy

sets like ‘max-min’ and ‘max-product’ composition can fulfill this

requirement. The complete fuzzy reasoning in a FS can be set up as

follows:

1. The fuzzification module calculates the so-called ‘firing

rate’ (or degree of fulfillment) of each rule by taking into

account the similarity between the actual input A' defined by

membership function µA'(x) (and in case of a crisp input xp

defined by the value µA(xp) and the input A of each rule

defined by membership function µA(x).

2. Using the firing-rates calculated, the inference engine

determines the fuzzy output B' for each rule, defined by

membership function µB'(y).

3. The inference engine combines all fuzzy outputs B' into one

overall fuzzy output defined by membership function µ(y).

4. The defuzzification module calculates the crisp output yp

using a defuzzification operation like ‘centroïd of gravity

(area)’.

94

For a treatment in depth on FSs, its construction and corresponding

reasoning schemes (including the most popular systems like Mamdani

(Mamdani and Gaines, 1981) and Tagaki-Sugeno Fuzzy Models

(Tagaki and Sugeno, 1985), we refer to the above-mentioned

textbooks.

5.3. Theoretical frameworks

5.3.1. Architecture the EAFL model

Considering sustainability in rangeland management, we develop a

model called Equilibrium Assessment by Fuzzy Logic (EAFL) which

provides a mechanism to approach eqilibrium by assessing Right Rate

of Stocking. The scheme of the EAFL model applying approximate

reasoning to come up with RRS is shown in Fig. 5.3. In general, the

following basic steps should be done to construct a fuzzy model (van

den Berg, 2004):

1. Determining the relevant input and output variables;

2. Defining linguistic values;

3. Constructing membership function;

4. Determining the fuzzy rules;

5. Computing degree of membership of crisp inputs;

6. Determining approximate reasoning;

7. Computing crisp output (defuzzify); and

8. Assessing the model performance.

95

Fig. 5.3. Scheme of development of the EAFL model applying approximate reasoning to

assess the Right Rate of Stocking (RRSp) based on the inputs values (I1p, I2p, and

I3p)2 (adapted from Cornelissen, 2003, p.51).

1. To simplify the model, we have shown three inputs, however, the number can be higher or

lower. 2. The grey color notifies the fuzzy parts of the model.

Input3 1 Input2 Input1

L.V.(I3) L.V.(I2) L.V.(I1)

Determining inputs

Defining linguistic values

µi(I1), µj(I2), µk(I3)

Constructing membership functions

µi(I1p), µj(I2p), µk(I3p)

IF – THEN rules Determining fuzzy rules

Determining approximate reasoning

Computing degree of membership of crisp inputs

Step 1

Step 5

Step 6

Step 4

Step 3

Step 2

Given: µi(I1p), µj(I2p), µk(I3p) ; derive:µi(RRSp)

Computing crisp output (defuzzy) RRSp = COG µ(RRS)

Assessing the model performance

Step 7

Step 8 Assessing & fine-tuning

96

5.3.2. Architecture of multi-fuzzy model

While fuzzy specialists usually use homogeneous experts’ knowledge

to construct fuzzy models, it is much more difficult to deal with

knowledge elicited from a heterogeneous group of experts. They

usually try to elicit and deal with homogenous experts’ knowledge and

hardly refer to heterogeneous experts. Experts’ knowledge, however,

is influenced by individual perspectives and goals (Ford and Sterman,

1998). This issue especially holds in the area of the sustainable

rangeland management. One way to deal with the diversity of

opinions is to develop a fuzzy system for all experts and to combine

all these so-called primary systems into one multi-fuzzy model. When

constructing a fuzzy model, an important consideration is how to deal

with differences in personal experience. The effect of these

differences is assumed to be smaller in a homogeneous (e.g. only

pastoralists) than in a heterogeneous group (e.g. different experts). As

experts have graduated in different disciplines, they may come to a

different evaluation of sustainable rangeland management than, for

example, pastoralists. Such differences, however, are not necessarily

disadvantageous. A heterogeneous group of experts, can be an

advantage over a homogeneous group through considering all

knowledge and, compensating for dissenting points of view by more

liberal ones (Cornelissen, 2003). However, the heterogeneity in

experts’ knowledge makes unclear decisions in rangeland

management for reaching equilibrium in practice.

Here, based on three Mamdani-type of fuzzy models (three EAFL

models), we have designed a specific multi-fuzzy model (Fig. 5.4) to

assess the final Right Rate of Stocking (RRSf). The following basic

steps are also suggested to enable to calculate the final crisp output:

97

1. Constructing several EAFL models (described in the last

section); based on the experts’ knowledge resulting from the

semi-structured interviews (described in the next chapter);

2. Computing, for several typical cases, the crisp primary outputs

of the models and comparing them; and

3. Combining different outputs using a voting process and

calculating the final crisp output.

The architecture of the multi-fuzzy model is depicted in Fig. 5.4.

98

Ii

Ii

Ii

Ii

Ii

Ii

Ii

Ii

Ii

Fu

zzif

ier

1

Fu

zzif

ier

2

Fu

zzif

ier

3

Rules Base (ni)

Rules Base (ni)

Rules Base (ni)

Inference Engine1

Inference Engine 2

Inference Engine 3

Defu

zzif

ier

1

Defu

zzif

ier

2

Defu

zzif

ier

3

RRSi

RRSi

RRSi

Vo

tin

g P

roc

es

s

Fig. 5.4. Architecture of the multi-fuzzy model to deal with different experts’ knowledge. The primary outputs RRSi (i = 1,2,3,…n) of three Mamdani fuzzy systems having different input variables and different number of rules base (ni), are combined into output value RRSf using a weighted voting process to calculate final output.

Mo

de

l 1

M

od

el 3

M

od

el 2

W1

W2

W3

Mamdani fuzzy systems

RRSRRSRRSRRSffff = = = = i

i

i RRSw∑=

3

1

99

To apply the above holistic approach, we conducted a multiple case

study in three different areas of the Fars province in Southwest Iran.

In the next chapter, we give some details concerning the research

methodology of this study.

100

Chapter Six

Research Method

6.1. The population of study

It can be stated that the majority of the Iranian people were engaged in

pastoral subsistence and animal breeding for a long time (Sogol, No

date). One third of the total area in Iran (164 million hectares) is

unusable for any purpose other than pastoralism (Emadi, 2003).

Today, there are over 1.5 million nomads in Iran. Many of nomad

tribes such as the Kurds, Bakhtiyaris (Bactrians), Lors, Guilaks, and

the Baloochs are descendants of the original invaders who came from

Central Asia to settle in the Iranian plateau (Iran Rozaneh, 2003).

Most of the tribes of Central Iran are pure Aryan, while others such as

Khoozestan and Khorasan's Arabs, Qashqai, Turkaman (decendants of

Mongols), Shahsavan and Afshar's tribes in Azarbaijan had ancestors

who passed through Iran (Travel Explorations, 2004).

By 1920, nomadic pastoral tribes constituted over a quarter of the

Iranian population. Their number declined sharply as a result of forced

settlement between 1920s and 1930s. Continued pressures as well as

the lure of the cities and settled life have resulted in a further sharp

decline since 1960s (Iran Rozaneh, 2003).

A public census conducted on the Iranian nomadic tribes in 1987 puts

the number of tribes in 96 tribes and 547 clans consisting of 180,223

families or 1,152,099 people (597,774 men and 554,325 women).

Holding the results of next public census, some 96 independent tribes

101

and 547 clans have been registered in Iran in 1988. Iranian tribesmen

have been scattered throughout the country, mainly in the provinces of

East and West Azarbaijan, Kordestan, Gorgan and Gonbad, Lorestan,

Fars, Kerman, Khorasan, and Sistan and Balouchestan. In 1991, public

census on the Iranian population does not mention to the tribesmen. It

rather mentions urban and rural residents and non-resident people. It is

not known whether the non-residents, as mentioned in 1991, are the

same as tribesmen (Namey-e-Otaq-e-Bazargani, 1996).

According to the Statistic Centre of Iran in 1996, the number of non-

residents is approximately 2,110,406. Though the tribes and clans are

scattered in distinct areas of the country, this in itself denotes the

influence of the central rule on such realms. At times, due to political

reasons, tribes were compelled to migrate to other regions. Such an

example can be Kordestan's Kurds who migrated to the territory in

Northern Khorasan. But it can be stated that each tribe withheld its

own cultural and social traditions wherever they resided; such as

Shahsavan in Northern Azarbayjan and Kordestan's Kurds, even so,

between Qashqaie and Bakhtiyari's tribes. Historical surveys reveal

that some of the Iranian tribes have a common ancestor. A large

portion of the tribes in Central and Western Iran has Lor dialect.

These are divided in two groups; Lor-e-Bozorg (Greater Lors) and

Lor-e-Koochak (Smaller Lors). Branches of these tribes were

decamped to the mountainous regions in Central Iran. Tribes such as

the Bakhtiyari, Kohgilooyeh, Mamasani and Boyer Ahmad are of this

group, and yet are completely distinct from each other. During the

Safavid era, Afshar's tribes were decamped from Khorasan to

Azarbayjan, and still another group to Kohgilooyeh and Khoozestan.

By the Fars conquest tribes leaded Aqa Mohammad Khan Qajar in

102

1206 A.H., 12,000 families that proved rebellious were decamped

from Shiraz to Tehran. During Nasereddin Shah's regime, Hezareh's

tribe was decamped to Khorasan, but due to unrest and turmoil, was

compelled to scatter in smaller groups. Formerly, this dispersion

depended solely on the acquirement of pastoral vicinities. But

gradually this gained a political aspect, thus conserving limits and

distinctions as to the jurisdiction of tribes. Currently, the tribes are

dispersed in the following regions in Iran (Sogol, No date):

• North and Northwestern; the provinces of Golestan and

Khorasan - comprising of various clans such as the Turkaman

tribes.

• Northwestern; Shahsavan, Arasbaran, Afshar-e-Qezelbash,

Garahgozloo and various clans of Khamseh's tribe. These are

within the limits of Eastern and Western Azarbayjan, Hamadan,

Ardabil and Zanjan.

• Western; comprising of those having a Kurdish dialect, Kalhor,

Sanjabi, Gurkani and... They reside in the provinces of

Kermanshah, West Azarbayjan and Kordestan.

• Southwest and Southern; comprising of various clans such as

Khamseh, Qashqaie, Arab and Lor-e-Koochak which are settled

in the provinces of Fars, Khoozestan and Lorestan.

• Southeastern; comprising Baloochi tribes residing in the

province of Sistan and Baloochestan.

• Center; these are namely Bakhtiyari, Boyer Ahmad, Doshman

Ziyari, Charam, Bavi, Bahmehyi, Tayebi, Mokran and... which

reside within the limits of the provinces of Chahar Mahal and

Bakhtiyari, Khoozestan, Kohgilooyeh and Kerman.

103

• Eastern and Northeastern; which comprising of various clans

settled in the province of Khorasan.

As noticed, in South Iran, especially the Fars province is rich in

pastoral groups usually specialised in sheep and these are described in

a number of monographs (e.g. Barfield, 1981; Barth, 1961; Bates,

1973; Black-Michaud, 1986; Irons, 1975)1. For centuries, the Fars

province has been a multi-ethnic region, in which tribal and pastoral

nomadic groups compose a large part of the population as follows

(Qashqai.net., 2003): Qashqaie's tribe consists of the following clans:

Darreh Shouri (5,265 families), Kashkooli Bozorg (4,862 families),

Shesh Boluki (4,350 families), Kashkooli Kuchak (650 families),

Qaracheh (430 families), Safi Khani (235 families), Rahimi (370

families), Farsi Madan (1,505 families), and Amaleh (5,397 families).

The above-mentioned pastoral nomads move - with their herds of

sheep and goats - between summer rangelands in the higher elevations

of “Zagros” in North of Shiraz and winter rangelands at low

elevations in South of Shiraz. Their migration routes are considered to

be among the longest and most difficult in all Iranian pastoral tribes

(Oldcarpet, 2005).

6.2. The area of study

In this study, we have focused on three different regions of the Fars

province in Southwest Iran: first, Cheshme-Anjir from Shiraz county

which covers 2575 hectares, 3200 livestock and 12 pastoral families;

1. It should also be noted that a significant body of literature on pastoral nomadism such as the

works of Barth (1961); Beck (1986); Digard (1990); Fazel (1971); Irons and Dyson-Hudson (1972); Mortensen (1993); Swee (1981) and Tapper (1979, 1983 and 1997) contributed to the development of better understanding of the socio-economic organization and migratory patterns of the Iranian tribal society.

104

second, Morzion from Sepidan county having 2000 hectares, 1570

livestock and 19 pastoral families; and third, Kheshti from Lamerd

county with 6900 hectares, 3804 livestock and 20 pastoral families.

The regions have different climatic and geographical conditions

(Table 6.1).

105

Table 6.1. General information of the three regions of the study.

Region Area (ha)

No. of Livestock (aum)

No. of Pastoral Families

Average

Temperature (°C)

Average Annual Rainfall (mm)

Soil Texture

Height (m) (from see level)

Morzion 2000 1570 19 11.9 750 Sandy Loam 2300 Cheshme-Anjir 2575 3200 12 15.0 317 Sandy Loam 1400 Kheshti 6900 3804 20 22.8 244 Sandy Loam Clay 770

106

The main reason for selecting these regions was the management

activities done by the Natural Resources Administration of Fars

Province (NRAFP) to balance livestock number and rangeland

conditions in these regions.

6.3. Research method

There is a growing body of opinion that argues that qualitative

research, including the case study, has an important place among the

variety of research methods available to the researcher. ‘Yet the

traditional case study still remains firmly within the domain of the

qualitative researcher’ (Tesch, 1990; p. 69).

Burns (1994) has argued that the case study, because of its intense

nature and its ability to generate rich subjective data, may generate

more intensive research. The case study allows for in-depth probing of

phenomena, as Burns stated:

...typically involves the observation of an individual unit...

to qualify as a case study, it must be a bounded system, an

entity in itself. A case study should focus on a bounded

subject/unit that is either very representative or extremely

atypical (Burns, 1994; p. 312).

Many approaches have been taken in terms of the development of case

studies. Tesch (1990) argued that a case study is an ‘intensive and

detailed study of one individual or a group as an entity, through

observation, self-reports, and any other means’ (Tesch, 1990; p. 39).

Others see the case study in more elaborate terms.

The case study is judged to be appropriate for this study somehow it

would allow in-depth interviews of issues that are important in

sustainable rangeland management. At the same time, it would impose

structure on the research and allow for judgment (Niblo and Jackson,

107

1999). Generally, case studies are the preferred strategy when "how"

or ‘why" questions are being posed, when the investigator has little

control over events, and when focus is on a contemporary

phenomenon within some real-life context. In more precise definition,

a case study is an empirical inquiry that: (1) investigates a

contemporary phenomenon within its real-life context; when (2) the

boundaries between phenomenon and context are not clearly evident;

and in which (3) multiple sources of evidence are used (Yin, 1989; p.

13).

This research method explores the problems for the qualitative

researcher in trying to explore a hidden phenomenon. The questions

should be asked in depth and be probing (Niblo and Jackson, 1999).

‘These “how” and “why” questions, capturing what researcher is really

interested in answering, lead him\her to the case study as the

appropriate strategy...’ (Yin, 1989; p. 30). That is to say, the

researcher has to leave room for material and information to emerge

during the course of the research project. Nevertheless, Yin also

argued that every exploration still should have a purpose. Some basic

skills that need to be mastered by case studier are (Yin, 1989):

• being able to ask questions,

• interpreting the answers,

• being a good "listener",

• being adaptive and flexible,

• having a firm grasp of the issues being studied, and

• being unbiased by preconceived notions.

108

6.3.1. Multiple-case study

The specific approach implemented in this study is a multiple-case

study in the framework of an exploratory research design to find

sustainability indicators in rangeland management in the views of

selected experts.

For each region of the research1, a case study involving both

observation and interviews with pastoralist’ experts was conducted.

The implementation of multiple-case studies allowed us to gather

more evidences and to make comparisons between regions with

different socio-economic and environmental conditions. The approach

is open-ended in that it allows researchers to go as far as possible

before exhausting the sources of information. Yin has discussed the

difference between ‘replication, not sampling logic, for multiple-case

studies’ (Yin, 1989; p. 53). Burns (1994; p. 316) also elaborated on

the concept of replication:

“A collection of case studies, which is called the multiple-

case study, is not based on the sampling logic of multiple

subjects in an experimental design. If the cases are not

aggregated it is convenient to apply the term case study to

such an investigation.”

For each region, then, an extensive case study was conducted which

provided the materials of the present research. The first step involved

the preparation of the detailed case studies through procedures of

direct observation and extensive in-depth interviewing and second,

abstracting from observations and interview materials in each of these

which are drawn upon for the explication of material relevant to the

questions which guided this research.

1. Since, we will finally estimate the RRS for each "pasture" in the regions, the pasture can be

considered as the case or the unit of analysis of this study.

109

6.4. Sampling method

Since fuzzy models usually use the expert knowledge, it is important

to identify an expert properly. For example, there are some differences

between stakeholders and experts (Cornelissen, 2003) and also

differences between experts and those people who are selected to

interview based on a few personal contacts, or on the basis of

availability during a short-term period (Davis and Wagner, 2003). In

this dissertation, an expert is defined as a person whose knowledge in

a specific domain (e.g. equilibrium in a rangeland) is obtained

gradually through a period of learning and experience (Bromme, 1992

and Turban, 1995 in Cornelissen, 2003).

To call a holistic approach, both homogeneous and heterogeneous

experts were selected based on the ‘socio-metric’ method. According

on this method, concerned information is obtained directly from key

informant experts who are nominated by the majority of stakeholders

(Ortega, 2002). Totally, in this study, based on several discussions

with the stakeholders of NRAFP at the first round of study, 9 experts

in three different categories nominated by them were interviewed

(Table 6.2).

Table 6.2. Some personal characteristics of 9 nominated experts at the first round of study.

Pastoralist experts

Expert no. Age (yr.) Education level Discipline/Job Experience (yr.)

1 55 Diploma Pastoralist All his life 2 63 Reading & Writing Pastoralist All his life 3 65 Reading & Writing Pastoralist All his life

Administrative experts

Expert no. Age (yr.) Education level Discipline Experience (yr.)

1 33 M.Sc. Desert Management 8 2 45 M.Sc. Animal Husbandry 18 3 48 M.Sc. Rural Development 10 4 47 M.Sc. Admin. Management 16

Researcher experts

Expert no. Age (yr.) Education level Discipline Experience (yr.)

1 42 Ph.D. Animal Husbandry 8 2 48 Ph.D. Rage management 10

110

During three rounds of data collection in a period of 18 months, by

conducting 9 main interviews and 21 follow-ups, we were led to

remove one administrative expert and both two researchers by

discounting others or even themselves1. In other words, they

eliminated others or even themselves and pointed to the rest who are

more expertized in this field.

It should be noted again that the experts who have different personal

characteristics are expertized differently within and between groups

according to their last and present background. NRAFP, for instance,

has hired a large number of experts who hold in bachelor and master

degrees in different disciplines of rangeland management.

6.5. Data collection and applied techniques

In order to construct a multi-fuzzy model, several semi-structured

interviews were held with elites2 who are called, in fuzzy studies,

experts. As Jones (1985) described, a semi-structured interview is:

• a social interaction between two people (the researcher and one

of his\her experts);

• in which the interviewer (researcher) initiates and varyingly

controls the exchange with the respondents (the experts);

• for the purpose of obtaining quantifiable and comparable

information (defining sustainability indicators); and

• relevant to an emerging or stated hypothesis (if-then rules for

making the balance between the different levels of the

indicators).

1. See appendix 1. 2. Elite interview conducts with prominent people. This technique provides valuable information

which can be obtained because the position of interviewees; Elite also can provide overall view his/her (Marshall and Rossman, 1995).

111

The entire script was written ahead of time, with an eye to an almost

total standardization of the interview from one expert to the next. The

standardized, open-ended interview was used when it was important to

minimize the variation of the questions posed to interviewees. This

helps to reduce the bias that can occur from having different

interviews with different experts (Patton, 1987). The open-ended

questionnaire was used to conduct interviews included a set of

questions which were carefully worded and arranged for the purpose

of taking each expert through the same sequence and asking him the

same questions with essentially the same words (Gamble, 1989). More

specifically, the main questions were conducting the experts i) to

introduce the main indicators of sustainability in range management,

ii) to define the labels (linguistic values), iii) to determine the fuzzy

ranges of each value label, and iv) to express the fuzzy if-then rules.

6.5.1. Data analysis

The qualitative techniques were used to analyze the elicited

knowledge of experts. The main techniques included open and axial

coding to find the main indicators (Strauss and Corbin, 1990). The

Matlab Fuzzy Toolbox (version 7) was used to construct the fuzzy

model. Finally, to deal with different experts’ knowledge, we used

Microsoft Excel 2003. More details and extensive discussions

regarding data analysis are given in the next chapter.

112

Chapter Seven

Fuzzy Analysis and Discussion

This chapter presents the analysis of data using fuzzy logic and an

extensive related discussion. To come up with a holistic approach in

the area of sustainable rangeland management, based on the

theoretical frameworks presented in Chapter 5, we will first construct

a fuzzy model called EAFL and explain its eight steps, and second, to

deal with different experts’ knowledge, we will develop a multi-fuzzy

model and introduce voting methods including (un)supervised

techniques.

7.1. Development the EAFL model

7.1.1. Determining the relevant input and output variables

Equilibrium between stocking rate and plantation density is difficult to

define but many experts recognize that it is a function of three major

components (inputs) which are:

� Stocking Rate in a pasture (SR),

� the amount of Plantation Density per hectare (PD), and

� the Number of Pastoralists in a pasture (NP).

7.1.2. Defining linguistic values

In the EAFL model, the linguistic values of each variable are

recapitulated in Table 7.1.

113

7.1.3. Constructing membership functions

Based on Pedrycz (1994; 2001) the experts' experience and knowledge

can be considered as a guide to define all membership functions which

in this study none of them are expressed continuous values. Therefore,

both triangular and shoulder shapes were suggested. The suggestion

was based on special range of values, which are stated by the experts

for each linguistic value. All experts proposed the left-shoulder shape

for the smallest and the right-shoulder for the largest linguistic values

and the triangular for the rest (Fig. 7.1).

Table 7.1. Linguistic values used in the EAFL model.

Variable Linguistic values

Stocking Rate (SR) low, medium, high

Plantation Density (PD) poor, acceptable, rich

Number of Pastoralists (NP) low, medium, high

114

70 50 55

medium high low

0

1

SR (aum/km2)

a µi(SR)

b

50 10

30

acceptable rich poor

0

1

PD (tn/km2)

µj(PD)

c

0.5 0.1

0.3

medium high low

0

1

NP (p/km2)

µk(NP)

Fig. 7.1. Membership functions for a) Stocking Rate, b) Plantation Density, and c) Number of Pastoralists 1

7.1.4. Determining the fuzzy rules

In this study, the rules are expressions of the role of interdependencies

among factors of equilibrium, which were elicited from pastoralists’

1. While most of the ranges were elicited by interview, the rest were calculated by means.

115

experts by interviews. They state different dimensions of

sustainability in range management. To determine the overall

equilibrium, the rule base needs 33 = 27 rules since we have 3

linguistic values and 3 linguistic variables (SR, PD and NP), which are

stated by pastoralists’ experts. The complete rules base used to

construct the overall experts’ knowledge base are summarized in

Table 7.2 for different linguistic values. All rules-base was elicited by

interviews and all pastoralists’ experts were agreed at the end with

several follow-ups.

1. Considering long-term consequences which is certainly back to "overgrazing", none of

pastoralists express "high" as the linguistic value of the output variable (RRS).

Table 7.2. The complete rules base (33 = 27) used to construct the overall experts’ knowledge base.

Rule r

if Stocking Rate

is

and Plantation Density

Is

and Number of Pastoralists

is

Then Stocking Rate

must be1

1 low Poor low Low

2 low Poor medium Low 3 low Poor high low 4 low Acceptable low low 5 low Acceptable medium low

6 low Acceptable high low 7 low Rich low medium 8 low Rich medium medium 9 low Rich high medium

10 medium Poor low low

11 medium Poor medium low 12 medium Poor high low 13 medium Acceptable low medium 14 medium Acceptable medium low 15 medium Acceptable high low

16 medium Rich low medium 17 medium Rich medium medium 18 medium Rich high medium 19 high Poor low low

20 high Poor medium low 21 high Poor high low 22 high Acceptable low medium 23 high Acceptable medium medium 24 high Acceptable high low 25 high Rich low medium 26 high Rich medium medium 27 high Rich high medium

116

7.1.5. Computing degree of membership of crisp inputs

We present a numerical example illustrating how the EAFL model can

compute degree of membership of crisp inputs. Suppose that

information concerning the input variables is expressed numerically as

follows: SR = 75 (aum/km2) (Fig. 7.2a), PD = 35 (tn/km2) (Fig. 7.2b),

and NP = 0.4 (p/km2) (Fig. 7.2c).

70 50 55

medium high low

0

1

SR (aum/km2)

a µi(SR)

75

50 10

30

acceptable rich poor

0

1

PD (tn/km2)

35

0.5

0.75

0.25

40

b µj(PD)

c

0.5 0.1

0.3

medium high low

0

1

NP (p/km2)

0.4

0.5

µk(NP)

Fig. 7.2. Linguistic values and fuzzification of crisp inputs for a) Stocking Rate, b)

Plantation Density, and c) Number of Pastoralists.

117

Fuzzification yields the following inputs for the inference engine:

Input 1: SR is high with membership grade µh(SR) = µh(75) = 1;

Input 2: PD is acceptable with membership grade

µa(PD) = µa(35) = 0.75

and rich with membership grade

µr(PD) = µr(35) = 0.25;

Input 3: NP is medium with membership grade

µm(NP) = µm(0.4) = 0.5

and high with membership grade

µh(NP) = µh(0.4) = 0.5.

7.1.6. Detemining approximate reasoning

Now, we compute the degree to which each rule is applicable to the

input. The only consistent rules are those in which SR is high, PD is

either acceptable or rich, and NP is either medium or high. These are

rules 23, 24, 26, and 27 of Table 7.2. The conclusions of these rules

are expressed as follows:

Rule 23: If SR is high with membership grade 1 and PD is acceptable

with membership grade 0.75 and NP is medium with membership

grade 0.5, then the output SR must be low with membership grade:

µPREMISE23 = min ({1, 0.75, 0.5}) = 0.5

With the same calculation:

µPREMISE24 = min ({1, 0.75, 0.5}) = 0.5

µPREMISE26 = min ({1, 0.25, 0.5}) = 0.25

µPREMISE27 = min ({1, 0.25, 0.5}) = 0.25

118

For the remaining rules of the rule base, we have µPREMISEr = 0. We

observe that rules 23, 24 and 27 assign the same linguistic value low

to SR with membership degree 0.5, 0.5 and 0.25 respectively. Now,

based on degree of membership of inputs value, the fuzzy outputs

µB'(RRS) of each rule are calculated and combined into one fuzzy

output µ(RRS) (Fig. 7.3).

7.1.7. Computing crisp output (defuzzify)

Finally, we use “Center Of Gravity” (COG) for defuzzifying (Jang et

al., 1997; Zimmermann, 1996) yielding the RRS. In the example, the

RRS was assessed by using the Matlab Fuzzy Toolbox (version 7)

yielding RRS = 32.9 (aum/km2) = 0.329 (aum/ha) (Fig. 7.3).

Fig. 7.3. Graphical illustration of the EAFL model for approximate reasoning and defuzzification. Approximate reasoning starts with a two-steps process comprising the implication process and the aggregation process yielding the overall fuzzy output µ i(RRSp) based on the fuzzy conclusions of the inputs (SRp, PDp and NPp) for each rule. Finally, the center of gravity method divides the area under curve into two equal sub-areas hereby determining the crisp output value: RRSp = 32.9 (Fuzzytoolbox in Matlab 7).

Rule 23

Rule 24

Rule 26

Rule 27

119

7.1.8. Assessing the model performance

Having available a large set of input-output data, the performance of

the system can be evaluated and parameters of the system can be fine-

tuned in order to achieve a low ‘generalization error’. In such a data-

rich situation, a training set is used to fit the models, a validation set is

used to estimate the prediction error for model selection and a test set

is used for assessing the generalization error of the final model chosen

(Hastie et al., 2001). If, like in our case, no large data sets are

available, the best way to assess model performance and fine-tune the

system is based on experts’ judgements (Davis and Wagner, 2003). By

using different real inputs and observing crisp outputs, judgement is

possible by experts. They can assess several scenarios and conclude

whether the performance of the model is (not) reasonable.

In our case, a small set of real input-output data appeared to be

available. This data set was used to describe the behaviour of the

EAFL model (Table 7.3).

Table 7.3. Assessing the performance of the EAFL model by using real data. Real Inputs

Area SR (aum/km2)

PD (tn/km2)

NP (p/km2)

Active Rules

Output: RRS 1

(aum/km2)

∆SR: (RRS – SR) (aum/km2)

Cheshme-Anjir 124 18 0.4 20, 21, 23, 24 32.1 – 91.9 Morzion 94 12 0.9 20, 23 26.1 – 67.9 Kheshti 55 28 0.3 11, 14 26.1 – 28.9

Table 7.3 shows three different outputs (RRSs) corresponding to three

real input data. By comparing the Right Rate of Stocking (RRS) with

the current Stocking Rate (SR) for each area, it becomes clear that the

current SR values are considerably higher than the RRS values: RRS =

1. Using Membership Function Editor of Fuzzytoolbox to automatically define membership

functions of the inputs, the outputs (RRSs) would be 44.2, 16.3, and 21.8 for the studied areas respectively that also confirm "overgrazing" in these areas.

120

32.1, 26.1 and 26.1 when SR = 124, 94 and 55, respectively. The

negative ∆SRs (– 91.9, – 67.9 and – 28.9 respectively) exhibit the

exceeding rate of SR compared to that of RRS and therefore suggest

general overgrazing in the three-prototypical areas in Southwest Iran.

All pastoralists’ experts in the study areas, on one hand, agree with

this result. They believe that most important issue nowadays they are

challenging with, is overgrazing and this is actually the reason why

they did not consider the “high” value for RRS as the output of the

model (Table 7.2). They are afraid that, by choosing this value, even

the favourite conditions (e.g. rules 8 and 16), overgrazing will

continue to happen and further be encouraged in the future.

By comparing the current SR to the RRS, on the other hand, the correct

decision can easily be made by pastoralists. In all three areas, to return

to an equilibrium state, pastoralists should decrease the following

amounts of their livestock per square kilometer:

∆SR1 = RRS – SR = 32.1 – 124 = – 91.9 (aum/km2) = – 0.9 (aum/ha)

∆SR2 = RRS – SR = 26.1 – 94 = – 67.9 (aum/km2) = – 0.6 (aum/ha)

∆SR3 = RRS – SR = 26.1 – 55 = – 28.9 (aum/km2) = – 0.2 (aum/ha)

Such a decision has a lot of consequenses. In this case, for example, as

they would loose a part of their major income, they usually do not

consider this option (decrease). Consequently, pastoralists will

experience unbalance and unavoidable degradation in their

rangelands. For making money to return to balance (without any

overgrazing), the Natural Resourse Administrations in Iran have

started to offer them the other jobs since 2000. These are included

handcrafts, horticulture, agronomy, animal husbandry and other jobs

related to agriculture. These jobs can be varied due to different

121

climaticand geographical conditions as well as the pastoralists’

experiences.

The current state of the majority of the Iranian rangelands, namely

overgrazing, of course, may change in the future. In fact, a pastoral

system is a dynamic system, where socio-economic conditions change

over the time. Therefore, it may be needed to change or add input

variables to the model or to redefine the membership functions,

yielding in different output rates. If so, “overgrazing” may change to

“normal grazing” or even, “undergrazing” based on different socio-

economic and dynamic ecological conditions in the future.

7.2. Development the multi-fuzzy model

Due to heterogeneous experts’ knowledge as collected in the semi-

structured interviews, we have constructed three different Mamdani-

types of fuzzy models. Each model has its own specific inputs,

linguistic values, fuzzy range and if-then rules (Table 7.4).

122

Table 7.4. Inputs, linguistic values and fuzzy range of each expert.

Expert His discipline Inputs (Ii) Linguistic values Fuzzy range Unit

PA Verylow,Low,Medium,High,Veryhigh 500,2500,5000,10000,20000 ha AR Verylow,Low,Medium,High,Veryhigh 100,200,350,600,800 mm

1

Desert Management

PD Verylow,Low,Medium,High,Veryhigh 10,25,35,55,70 %

PA Low,Medium,High 500,1000,2000 ha FTP Negative,Stable,Positive 20,50,70 % SP Deserts,Mountains 5,12 %

TP Low,Medium,High 100,450,1700 m2

2

Rural

Development

AR Verylow,Low,Medium,High 50,100,250,500 mm

FTP Negative,Stable,Positive 0,50,100 %

CC Low,Medium,High,Veryhigh 0.5,2,5,6 aum

3

Animal Husbandry

PS Poor,Normal,Good,Rich 25,50,75,100 %

Abbreviations: PA: Pasture Area, AR: Annual Rainfall, PD: Plantation Density, FTP: Future Trend of a Pasture, SP: Slope

of Pasture, TP: Topography of Pasture, CC: Carrying Capacity, PS: Pastoralists Situation.

123

Considering the second column with the third of Table 7.4 makes clear that

the different administrative experts, graduated in different disciplines, have

different knowledge concerning the indicators influencing the balance

between ‘consumption’ and ‘conservation’ in sustainable rangeland

management. They usually introduce those indicators which are most

related to their own discipline. Thereby, based on the experts’ knowledge,

we constructed three fuzzy models. The inputs of the first model are

Pasture Area, Annual Rainfall, and Plantation Density, where the second

model holds Pasture Area, Future Trend of a Pasture, Slope of Pasture,

Topography of a Pasture, and Annual Rainfall and the third model includes

Future Trend of a Pasture, Carrying Capacity and Pastoralists Situation as

the inputs (Table 7.4).

The administrative experts introduced different linguistic values for their

inputs. The first expert, for example, considered five levels (Very low, Low,

Medium, High, Very high) for all three of his own inputs, while, the second

expert considered two, three and four levels for his own indicators. Also,

the third expert deemed three and four levels for his own inputs. Table 7.4

also shows that for the same inputs (e.g. variable AR and FTP), experts

may have different ideas regarding the linguistic values to be used.

We also asked the experts to define the fuzzy ranges of the linguistic

values, i.e., the membership functions that define the linguistic values

selected. All experts considered the trapezoidal shape for the smallest and

the largest linguistic values and the triangular for the rest. In this way, we

defined both triangular and trapezoidal membership functions based on

administrative experts’ knowledge.

124

The experts were also asked to express their own knowledge in a set of

‘fuzzy IF-THEN rules’ while offering all possibilities. We prepared all

combinations of the inputs and asked the experts to fill out the output

column. Thereby, the number of if-then rules was determined based on the

number of inputs variables and their linguistic values1:

The number of if-then rules (Model 1) = 5 * 5 * 5 = 125

The number of if-then rules (Model 2) = 3 * 3 * 2 * 3 * 4 = 216

The number of if-then rules (Model 3) = 3 * 4 * 4 = 48.

Although the inputs of the three fuzzy models are different due to quantity

and linguistic values, the Right Rate of Stocking (RRS) is chosen as the only

output of the model (Table 7.5).

Table 7.5. Characteristics of the output (RRS) for three fuzzy models.

Model Linguistic values Fuzzy ranges Unit

1 Verylow,Low,Medium,High,Veryhigh 0.5,1.0,2.5,4.0,6.0 aum/ha 2 Low,Medium,High 0.5,0.6,1.0 aum/ha 3 Low,Medium,High 1.0,2.0,3.0 aum/ha

7.2.1. Computing the crisp primary outputs

Before being able to compute a final crisp output value of the multi-fuzzy

model, we must first calculate the primary outputs, i.e., the output of each

fuzzy model. To do so, we need a representative set of data. We have been

able to collect the inputs data of five prototypical cases for each region of

our study. Next, we computed the primary output values RRSi of each the

three fuzzy models developed. The results of this procedure are

summarized in Tables 7.6, 7.7 and 7.8.

1. See appendix 2.

125

Table 7.6. Computing the outputs of the first model with 5 cases for each region.

Model: 1

First region: Morzion

Real Inputs

Case PA (ha) AR (mm) PD (%)

Active Rules

Output RRS1 (aum/ha)

1 100 750 12 16,17,21,22 0.68 2 100 750 11 16,17,21,22 0.56 3 200 750 12 16,17,21,22 0.68 4 50 750 13 16,17,21,22 0.77 5 250 750 12 16,17,21,22 0.68

Second region: Cheshme-Anjir

Real Inputs

Case PA (ha) AR (mm) PD (%)

Active Rules

Output RRS1 (aum/ha)

6 100 315 18 6,7,11,12 1.07 7 200 315 19 6,7,11,12 1.11 8 300 315 17 6,7,11,12 1.02 9 250 315 18 6,7,11,12 1.07 10 300 315 16 6,7,11,12 0.97

Third region: Kheshti

Real Inputs

Case PA (ha) AR (mm) PD (%)

Active Rules

Output RRS1 (aum/ha)

11 200 240 20 6,7,11,12 1.15 12 500 240 22 6,7,11,12 1.23 13 200 240 19 6,7,11,12 1.11 14 300 240 20 6,7,11,12 1.15 15 700 240 20 6,7,11,12 1.15

Abbreviations: PA: Pasture Area, AR: Annual Rainfall, PD: Plantation

Density, and RRS: Right Rate of Stocking.

126

Table 7.7. Computing the outputs of the second model with 5 cases for each region.

Model: 2

First region: Morzion

Real Inputs

Case PA

(ha) FTP (%)

SP (%)

TP

(m2) AR

(mm)

Active Rules

Output RRS2

(aum/ha)

1 100 50 15.7 100 750 40 0.70 2 100 50 15.7 120 750 40,44 0.85 3 200 50 15.7 115 750 40,44 0.82 4 50 50 15.7 130 750 40,44 0.91 5 250 50 15.7 145 750 40,44 0.98

Second region: Cheshme-Anjir

Real Inputs

Case PA

(ha) FTP

(degree) SP (%)

TP

(m2) AR

(mm)

Active Rules

Output RRS2

(aum/ha)

6 100 55 13.4 180 315 39,40,43,44,63,64,67,68 1.12 7 200 55 13.4 160 315 39,40,43,44,63,64,67,68 1.12 8 300 55 13.4 200 315 39,40,43,44,63,64,67,68 1.13 9 250 55 13.4 185 315 39,40,43,44,63,64,67,68 1.12

10 300 55 13.4 170 315 39,40,43,44,63,64,67,68 1.12

Third region: Kheshti

Real Inputs

Case PA

(ha) FTP

(degree) SP (%)

TP

(m2) AR

(mm)

Active Rules

Output RRS2

(aum/ha)

11 200 20 8.6 30 240 2,3,14,15 0.45 12 500 20 8.6 20 240 2,3,14,15 0.45 13 200 20 8.6 35 240 2,3,14,15 0.45 14 300 20 8.6 40 240 2,3,14,15 0.45 15 700 20 8.6 25 240 2,3,14,15,74,75,86,87 0.45

Abbreviations: PA: Pasture Area, FTP: Future Trend of a Pasture, SP: Slope of

Pasture, TP: Topography of Pasture, AR: Annual Rainfall, and

RRS: Right Rate of Stocking.

127

Table 7.8. Computing the outputs of the third model with 5 cases for each region. Model: 3

First region: Morzion

Real Inputs

Case FTP (%) CC (aum) PS (%)

Active Rules

Output RRS3 (aum/ha)

1 50 0.27 60 18,19 0.84 2 50 0.25 65 18,19 0.84 3 50 0.22 60 18,19 0.84 4 50 0.26 55 18,19 0.80 5 50 0.28 65 18,19 0.84

Second region: Cheshme-Anjir

Real Inputs

Case FTP (%) CC (aum) PS (%)

Active Rules

Output RRS3 (aum/ha)

6 50 0.36 65 18,19 0.84 7 50 0.34 50 18 0.76 8 50 0.36 70 18,19 0.80 9 50 0.38 60 18,19 0.84 10 50 0.35 60 18,19 0.84

Third region: Kheshti

Real Inputs

Case FTP (%) CC (aum) PS (%)

Active Rules

Output RRS3 (aum/ha)

11 20 0.42 30 1,2,17,18 0.84 12 20 0.40 35 1,2,17,18 0.84 13 20 0.43 40 1,2,17,18 0.84 14 20 0.44 30 1,2,17,18 0.84 15 20 0.41 35 1,17 0.84

Abbreviations: FTP: Future Trend of a Pasture, CC: Carrying Capacity, PS:

Pastoralists Situation, and RRS: Right Rate of Stocking.

Table 7.6, 7.7 and 7.8 show that, for equal cases, the primary outputs

RRSi (i = 1, 2, 3) are usually different. It clarifies that our decisions to

select the best final output as an estimation of the RRS is not a trivial

task. Actually, we need to find a solution for dealing with the

differences among the primary outputs. More formally, we should find

an 'optimal' way to combine the primary outputs RRSi(I), based on a

given input vector I, in order to calculate one final crisp output value

RRSf(I) of our multi-fuzzy model. This combining process is

sometimes, especially in environments of supervised learning, termed

‘voting’1 (Hastie et al., 2001).

1. Voting and rating activities require the gathering of participants' opinions from large distances,

and therefore, they are closely connected to network issues and distributed processing (Kovács and Micsik, 2005).

128

7.2.2. Implementing voting

In the next sections, we introduce and discuss several ways to

implement voting, i.e., to calculate the weights for combining the

primary outputs.

7.2.2.1. Method 1: Calculating the mean of outputs

Table 7.9 shows the primary outputs of models 1, 2 and 3, and the

final output RRSf of 15 cases (c = 1,2,…,15) in three different study

regions. In this approach, all final crisp outputs are simply equal to the

arithmetic mean of the primary outputs of the three models, i.e.,

∑=

==3

1

),(3

1Mean)(

i

cicf IRRSIRRS where Ic represents the input vector for

the cth case.

Table 7.9. Finding the final outputs by calculating the mean of primary outputs.

First region: Morzion

Primary outputs: RRSi

Case Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

SD Mean (RRSf)

1 0.68 0.70 0.84 0.08 0.74 2 0.56 0.85 0.84 0.16 0.75 3 0.68 0.82 0.84 0.08 0.78 4 0.77 0.91 0.80 0.07 0.82 5 0.68 0.98 0.84 0.15 0.83

Second region: Cheshme-Anjir

Primary outputs: RRSi

Case Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

SD Mean (RRSf)

6 1.07 1.12 0.84 0.14 1.01 7 1.11 1.12 0.76 0.20 0.99 8 1.02 1.13 0.80 0.16 0.98 9 1.07 1.12 0.84 0.14 1.01 10 0.97 1.12 0.84 0.14 0.97

Third region: Kheshti

Primary outputs: RRSi

Case Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

SD Mean (RRSf)

11 1.15 0.45 0.84 0.35 0.81 12 1.23 0.45 0.84 0.39 0.84 13 1.11 0.45 0.84 0.33 0.80 14 1.15 0.45 0.84 0.35 0.81 15 1.15 0.45 0.84 0.35 0.81

129

As table 7.9 shows, different regions have different RRSf as the means

of the primary outputs. Since, the second region (Cheshme-Anjir)

gains the highest and the first region (Morzion) has the lowest means,

the third region (Kheshti) stands between them. Therefore, according

to these estimations, the second region can hold the most aum/ha,

while the capacity of the first region is the least. The standard

deviations of RRSi in the three regions have also been calculated.

Table 7.9 shows that the highest deviations of the primary RRSi are

found in the third and the lowest in the first region. The method of

calculating the mean of the primary outputs has some strengths and

weaknesses. It has some strengths because it concerns a simple

calculation and it covers all three primary outputs. It has some

weaknesses, as it uses all data in our calculations with equal weights.

By doing so, outliers are equally important as points close to the

expected value of the output. Therefore, we think it would be better to

look for voting methods where the primary outputs are calculated as a

weighted mean, i.e.,

∑=

=N

i

ciicf IRRSwIRRS1

)()( (1)

Here, in a more general setting, N equals the number of primary

models, where the weights wi are subject to the following constraints:

∑=

=N

i

iw1

1 and .0: ≥∀ iwi The underlying assumption of this weighted

approach is that ‘each expert has something to say’ and, in addition,

that ‘certain experts have something more to say than others’. We now

discuss several methods for calculating ‘optimal’ weight values wi.

130

7.2.2.2. Method 2: Minimizing the sum of squared errors

Where a training set of C input-output cases (Ic,RRSc), (c = 1, 2, …, C)

is available, we can calculate optimal weights wi by choosing the

weights wi such that the following sum of squared errors SSE is

minimized:

∑ ∑∑= ==

−=−=C

cc

N

icii

C

cccf

RRSIRRSwRRSIRRSSSE1

2

11

2 ))(())(( . (2)

This approach of supervised learning can be considered as a

regression method where the final outputs RRSf(Ic) of the multi-fuzzy

model are as much as possible equated to the correct output values

RRSc. If desired and needed, even more sophisticated supervised

methods from predictive data mining like ‘bagging’ and ‘boosting’

(Hastie et al., 2001; Ishibuchi et al., 1999) can be considered for

implementing optimal voting schemes.

Unfortunately, like in our case, the above-given methods of

supervised learning are not applicable where a set of correct input-

output values is not available. Therefore, we will not further discuss

method 2 in this study. Instead, we are challenged to come up with an

unsupervised method for implementing voting, i.e., a method where

we try to optimize the ‘consistency’ of the final output values of the

system by harmonizing the values of the primary outputs.

7.2.2.3. Method 3: Minimizing an approximation of the sum of

squared errors

One might wonder whether we can approximate the approach of

method 2 by using an approximation RRS′c of the correct output

values RRSc. Knowing the primary outputs RRSi, we can use as an

131

approximation ∑=

==N

i

cic IRRSN

RRS1

)(1

Mean' and next try to minimize the

approximation of the sum of squared errors SSE' defined as

∑ ∑∑∑= ===

−=−=C

c

N

i

ci

N

i

cii

C

c

ccf IRRSN

IRRSwRRSIRRSSSE1

2

111

2 ))(1

)(()')((' , (3)

where the above-given constraints 0: ≥∀i

wi and 11

=∑=

N

i

iw still hold.

Unfortunately, this method does not work since equation (3) has a

trivial minimum equal to zero, namely, in case Nwii

/1: =∀ resulting

into Method 1 from section 4.3.1, therefore, we should look for

another approach.

Below we shall look for ‘harmonizing methods’ where the

dissimilarities between the primary outputs RRSi are minimized.

7.2.2.4. Method 4: Harmonizing the primary outputs

A natural approach for harmonizing existing differences in the

primary outputs is to put less emphasis on outliers. By doing so, we

hope to find a more unbiased estimation RRSf of the right rate of

stocking. In addition, a smaller standard deviation SD of the weighted

primary outputs ii RRSw is expected to be found simply because the

primary output values close to the mean get more weight in the voting

process.

The above-given idea can be formalized as follows. Given input

vector Ic, let |)()(|)(, cjcicji IRRSIRRSI −=∆ represent the absolute value

of the difference between the primary outputs of model i and j. Using

all input vectors Ic available, we can calculate the sum ∆i of the

absolute differences between primary ouput RRSi and all other primary

outputs RRSj, j ≠ i, defined by

132

))()()()(()( 1,

1

1,2,1,

1

, ΛΛ +∆+∆++∆+∆=∆=∆ +

=

= ≠

∑∑∑ cii

C

c

ciicici

C

c ij

cjii IIIII . (4)

If ,ji ∆>∆ this means that model i generates, on average, more

outlying output values than model j and therefore, in our approach,

should get a lower weight. This can be implemented by giving model i

a weight which equals the normalized inverse of ∆i or, more precisely,

Λ+∆+∆+∆

∆=

∆=∑ 321 /1/1/1

/1

/1

/1 i

j

j

iiw (5)

It should be clear that by providing the primary outputs RRSi the

weights wi as defined by equation (5), the above-mentioned

constraints 0: ≥∀i

wi and 11

=∑=i

iw are automatically fulfilled.

Having determined the weights of the primary outputs, the standard

deviation of the weighted primary outputs can be calculated. Since for

Method 4 outliers have received less weight, these standard deviations

are expected to be smaller than in case of using Method 1 where the

primary outputs have equal weights. Furthermore, the final output of

the multi-fuzzy model can be calculated using equation (1). We have

done these calculations using the available field data from each of the

different regions of study. The results found are summarized in Table

7.10.

133

Table 7.10. Estimating the final output RRSf by calculating the sum of weighted outputs for separated regions according to Method 4. First region: Morzion

Primary outputs (RRSi) Delta’s Sum of Deltas Weighted outputs

Case Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 ∆1-2 ∆2-3 ∆1-3 ∆1 ∆2 ∆3 w1RRS1 w2RRS2 w3RRS3

SD (RRSf)

Summation

1 0.68 0.70 0.84 0.02 0.14 0.16 0.18 0.16 0.3 0.18 0.24 0.31 0.06 0.74

2 0.56 0.85 0.84 0.29 0.01 0.28 0.57 0.3 0.29 0.15 0.29 0.31 0.09 0.76

3 0.68 0.82 0.84 0.14 0.02 0.16 0.3 0.16 0.18 0.18 0.28 0.31 0.06 0.78

4 0.77 0.91 0.80 0.14 0.11 0.03 0.17 0.25 0.14

0.21 0.31 0.30 0.05 0.83

5 0.68 0.98 0.84 0.3 0.14 0.16

0.46 0.44 0.3 Sum 0.18 0.34 0.31 0.08 0.84

Sum 1.68 1.31 1.21 4.2

Inverse 0.59 0.76 0.82 2.18

Weights(wi) 0.27 0.35 0.38 1.00

Second region: Cheshme-Anjir

Primary outputs (RRSi) Delta’s Sum of Deltas Weighted outputs

Case Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 ∆1-2 ∆2-3 ∆1-3 ∆1 ∆2 ∆3 w1RRS1 w2RRS2 w3RRS3

SD (RRSf)

Summation

6 1.07 1.12 0.84 0.05 0.28 0.23 0.28 0.33 0.51 0.45 0.38 0.20 0.12 1.03

7 1.11 1.12 0.76 0.01 0.36 0.35 0.36 0.37 0.71 0.46 0.38 0.18 0.14 1.02

8 1.02 1.13 0.80 0.11 0.33 0.22 0.33 0.44 0.55 0.43 0.383 0.19 0.12 1.00

9 1.07 1.12 0.84 0.05 0.28 0.23 0.28 0.33 0.51

0.45 0.38 0.20 0.12 1.03

10 0.97 1.12 0.84 0.15 0.28 0.13

0.28 0.43 0.41 Sum 0.40 0.38 0.20 0.11 0.98

Sum 1.53 1.9 2.69 6.12

Inverse 0.65 0.52 0.37 1.55

Weights(wi) 0.42 0.34 0.24 1.00

Third region: Kheshti

Primary outputs (RRSi) Delta’s Sum of Deltas Weighted outputs

Case Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 ∆1-2 ∆2-3 ∆1-3 ∆1 ∆2 ∆3 w1RRS1 w2RRS2 w3RRS3

SD (RRSf)

Summation

11 1.15 0.45 0.84 0.7 0.39 0.31 1.01 1.09 0.7 0.34 0.124 0.36 0.13 0.82

12 1.23 0.45 0.84 0.78 0.39 0.39 1.17 1.17 0.78 0.36 0.124 0.36 0.13 0.84

13 1.11 0.45 0.84 0.66 0.39 0.27 0.93 1.05 0.66 0.32 0.124 0.36 0.12 0.81

14 1.15 0.45 0.84 0.7 0.39 0.31 1.01 1.09 0.7

0.34 0.124 0.36 0.13 0.82

15 1.15 0.45 0.84 0.7 0.39 0.31

1.01 1.09 0.7 Sum 0.34 0.124 0.36 0.13 0.82

Sum 5.13 5.49 3.54 14.16

Inverse 0.19 0.18 0.28 0.65

Weights(wi) 0.29 0.28 0.43 1.00

134

As Table 7.10 shows, there are different weights for each region.

While the weights of the model 1, 2 and 3 for the first region are 0.27,

0.34, and 0.37, the weights for these models for the second region are

0.42, 0.33 and 0.23 and for the third region are 0.29, 0.27 and 0.42

respectively. In other words, when the first model gets the highest

weight in Cheshme-Anjir (w1 = 0.42), the second model gives the

highest weight in Morzion and Cheshme-Anjir (w2 = 0.34 and 0.33)

respectively, and the third model gains the highest weight in Kheshti

(w3 = 0.42). So, we have different weights in different regions showing

that the expertize of the experts in the various regions seems to be

different.

Now, by calculating the sum of weighted outputs, we can easily

estimate the final outputs:

∑=

=3

1i

iif RRSwRRS

Based on equation (6), again, we estimated the final output RRSf for

separated regions. As Table 7.10 shows, the estimations for various

regions are different. While the highest amount of RRSf (more than 1)

is estimated for the second region and the lowest for the first (less than

0.8), the third region has got more than 0.8. On the other hand,

although the estimations are different for the ‘between groups’, they

are approximately similar for the ‘within groups’. Comparing Table

7.9 and 7.10, the standard deviation has indeed been reduced, as

expected.

7.2.3. Comparison of Method 1 and Method 4

Based on the two applied methods (Mean and Harmonized), we

estimated the final Right Rate of Stocking (RRSf). In the first method

(6)

135

(Table 7.9), we estimated RRSf by calculating the average of the

primary outputs. The method considers the same weights for all

outputs of the three models and therefore, it treats outliers and

‘normal’ data equally. This approach may introduce some bias in our

calculations. To decrease this weakness, we introduced other voting

methods. As discussed, a good voting method is provided by a

‘supervised learning’ algorithm where optimal weights are calculated

by minimizing the sum of squared errors of the output values. A

necessary precondition for applying this method is the availability of a

representative data set. Otherwise, we can use a voting procedure

based on ‘unsupervised learning’. Using this method (the harmonized

method) and the first method (the mean method), we are able to

compare the assessments of the RRSf for all three regions of our study

(Fig. 7.4).

Fig. 7.4. Comparison of the RRSf for the harmonized method and mean method.

136

As Fig. 7.4 demonstrates both methods estimate the highest RRSf for

the second region and the least for the first where the third region

stands between them. Also, while the RRSf for the second region is

considerably different from the two other regions, the RRSf for the

first and third region are quite close. We observe here that differences,

even small ones, between the values of the Right Rate of Stocking

have serious consequences because of ‘scaling factor’. In other words,

since the total area of each region is very large (e.g. 2000 hectares in

Morzion, 2575 hectares in Cheshme-Anjir and 6900 hectares in

Kheshti), small differences become big ones if we multiply the

estimated values of the RRSf by the amount of pasture area.

A primary validation shows that all experts confirm the above-

mentioned outcomes. Considering our results, they believe that the

second region (Cheshme-Anjir) has the best conditions to reach

sustainability. These conditions include social, geographical and

environmental circumstances and are supposed to be strongly related

to the values of the input variables (indicators) of the fuzzy models

discussed above. The social problems are supped to be less in

Cheshme-Anjir because the region benefits by a good manager who

solves many of their problems, especially, those related to the usual

bureaucratic problems in the different Iranian administrations. The

region also benefits by higher education level of its expert. In

addition, the administrative experts believe that the second region has

better strategic conditions as it falls between the two main roads

which are near to Shiraz, the capital of the Fars province. Finally, as

the weather in this region is not very cold (like the first region in

Morzion) and not very warm (like the third region in Kheshti), the

temperate weather makes better environmental conditions in

137

Cheshme-Anjir. Thus, these conditions make the second region the

best prototypical case in comparison to the two other regions and can

explain the high differences between outcomes for the second area and

the rest.

The administrative experts also agree upon estimations of the RRSf for

the two other regions. As vegetation period in the third region

(Kheshti) is longer than the first region (Morzion), they expect a lower

and a higher RRSf for the first and third region respectively. They also

believe that the warm weather of Kheshti creates a longer time period

of grazing. In contrast, the cold weather of Morzion declines its

capacity to hold livestock to graze. The experts add, however, if we

neglect the time period of grazing, the capacity of the third region for

holding the RRS should decrease (as we have seen for the second

model). This can also be a good evidence to show that the experts

were differently expertized in the various regions.

In addition, since the experts consider 2-3 aum/ha as the medium

range of RRS (see Table 7.5), they believe that currently the three

regions of our study have a much smaller grazing capacity than might

be possible. This outcome confirms the general believe that many

pastoral regions in Iran are currently facing overgrazing and are

exacerbating by the unsustainable situation. By taking appropriate

measures, circumstances for SD may be improved in the future.

Consequently, the experts’ knowledge will change according to new

conditions and higher estimates are likely to be found.

As has been shown in Tables 7.4 and 7.5, the nominated experts in

Iran choose different indicators to estimate the Right Rate of Stocking,

even in the cases where the same social, environmental, and

geographical conditions hold. They come up with sustainability in

138

rangeland management by different environmental (e.g. Slope of

Pasture) and socio-economic indicators (e.g. Pastoralist Situations).

Therefore, our study supports the reality that sustainability in range

management is a multi-dimensional vague concept. We also wish to

emphasize here that the supervised voting process (Method 2) should

be tried out in future research, after we have collected a set of real

input-output data from the field. The collection of this data is,

however, a time consuming process, which may take several years.

139

Chapter Eight

Summary and Conclusions

8.1. Summary

A claim is commonly made that the rangelands around the world are

overgrazed and hence producing edible forage and animal products at

less than their potential Wilson and Macleod, 1991). Globally,

rangelands are at risk from numerous pressures (Mitchell et al., 1999).

Some of these pressures arise from livestock/rangeland systems.

Livestock have been a key factor in the development of civilization,

but their role in the future is not clear as well as how the science of

rangeland management should change in order to meet future

challenges in rangelands. Carrying capacity is the most important

issue in range management (Walker, 1995). At a time, when the

planet's limited carrying capacity seems increasingly obvious, the

rationale and measures of rangelands carrying capacity are

increasingly criticized. One of the key elements of rangeland capacity

is stocking rate. If stocking rate is not close to the proper level related

to equilibrium rate, then, regardless of other grazing management

practices employed equilibrium will not be met (Roe, 1997). This

applies to many countries, including Iran. It is a regular topic of

books, articles and symposia (Conference on Sustainable Range

Management, 2004; Iranian Nomadic Organization, 1992), and a

common justification for further research.

140

Iran has approximately 90 million hectares of rangeland, 9.3 million

hectares of which are considered in ‘good’ conditions while the

remaining in ‘fair’ or ‘poor’ conditions. The country’s rangelands in a

normal year produce around 10 million tons of dry matter (dm), of

which 5.8 million tons may be available for grazing. The remaining

amount is the minimum required for reproduction and soil

conservation. The later amount of dm can support 38.5 million animal

units (au) for duration of 8 months. At the moment there is 115.5

million of au in Iran and only 16.5 of them are fed from other sources

including by agricultural products. The above figures prove that the

rangelands are being utilized at three times more than their peak

capacities in a non-drought year. This results in severe degradation of

the rangelands and accelerates soil erosion. As the rangeland is

considered by its users as "free resource" it is subject to heavy abuse,

which further exacerbates the drought (FAO, 2004a; Iranian Nomadic

Organization, 1992; Mesdaghi, 1995; UNCT, 2001).

The recent literature on rangelands disequilibrium calls in question

any specific measures of carrying capacity, whether the range is

stocked or unstocked, and managed or mis-managed. Ideally, such

objections can be taken into account for any individual carrying

capacity estimated by accepting that it has to be determined on a case

- by - case basis in the field. Once one knows the size of the grazing

and browsing animals, the biomass production of the area, the pattern

of range management, and so on, she/he can - so this argument goes -

produce a site specific stocking rate estimated for the range area under

consideration. But, it cannot pack livestock into a given rangeland,

without at some point deteriorating that range demonstrably. Surely,

biomass production is going down on rangelands precisely because

141

stocking rate has been exceeded for so long, even taking into account

factors such as drought and climate changes (Hardesty et al., 1993).

However, the rationale and measures of rangeland carrying capacity

are increasingly criticized. It seems that even under environmental

conditions of great certainty, the notion of rangeland equilibrium

would still be ambiguous and confused. Moreover, since

environmental conditions are highly uncertain for the dry rangelands

of the world such as Iran, current understanding of rangeland

equilibrium turns out to be all the more questionable. There is no

workable and practical “equation” for rangeland management in

general, and carrying capacity in particular (Roe, 1997). Similar

problems exist in other field of SD. In most studies, Fuzzy Logic is

used to construct a model for evaluating sustainability in different

areas. These models promise to be a valuable tool in evaluating the

sustainability in general and equilibrium specifically in this study. The

main purpose of this dissertation was to design a fuzzy model based

on the experts’ knowledge for solving the mis-management of the Fars

rangelands in Southwest Iran.

8.2. Conclusions

Fuzzy logic appears to be well suited to provide quantitative answers

pertaining to sustainability in rangeland management. In this study,

we introduced a fuzzy logic-based model for sustainable rangeland

management where the RRS is assessed as the output of the model

from three input variables. All experts agreed with these three inputs

which are: Stocking Rate, Plantation Density and Number of

Pastoralists. By using the EAFL model, there will be three different

options:

142

i) increasing the Stocking Rate (pastoralists usually like to

do so),

ii) unchanging the Stocking Rate (the rangeland is already

in equilibrium), and

iii) decreasing the Stocking Rate (more probable option).

Evaluating the EAFL model presented in this dissertation, we

conclude that it exhibits three important characteristics:

• First, it permits the combination of various aspects of

sustainability with different units of measurement,

• Second, it overcomes the difficulty of assessing certain

attributes or indicators of sustainability without precise

quantitative criteria, and

• Third, the methodology is easy to use and interpret.

The model has, therefore, the potential to become a practical tool to

policy-makers and scientists. It is important to note that the model is

open for improvement, based on our better understanding of realities

in the future. For example, one may construct different fuzzy rules

(the number of indicators used to evaluate each linguistic variable of

sustainability may be changed according to need or the membership

functions of certain linguistic values can be redefined), or may enter

some other Boolean measurements (which are normally used by

rangelands’ scientists) in fuzzy analyses to emprove the validity of the

model.

We are aware that our EAFL model is just the first step. The

flexibility of our model is one of its advantages over existing static

methods. Considering the sequence "crisp input – fuzzifier – inference

143

engine – defuzzifier – crisp output" illustrates the uncertainity that

exists in such a complex vague concept as sustainable rangeland

management. It also well adjusts to usual ambigious linguistic

statements of individuals. Furthermore, fuzzy logic operations

compensate for the lack of full knowledge of our system. Uncertainty

is ubiquitous in sustainability problems, since we never have complete

knowledge of the complex interrelationship of ecological systems and

the human thinking. Therefore, the EAFL model is expected to

provide a new useful tool for policymakers in order to manage and to

predict the overall sustainability in rangelands.

Considering a multi-fuzzy model, which is developed in this

dissertation, we have come up with other conclusions. While fuzzy

specialists usually use homogeneous experts’ knowledge to construct

fuzzy models, it is generally much more difficult to deal with

knowledge elicited from a heterogeneous group of experts, especially

in the area of sustainable rangeland management. In this study, we

proposed a multi-fuzzy model to cope with the muti-dimensional

vagueness of sustainability in the field of range management. To deal

with the heterogeneity of experts’ knowledge, which should be

considered either as a reality or necessity, we introduced several

voting methods for estimating the Right Rate of Stocking as the final

output of several fuzzy models. The first method simply uses the

average of the primary outputs as the final right rate of stocking. We

also introduced a supervised voting method, which is applicable where

a real-world data set is available. In the absence of such a set, like in

our study, an unsupervised voting method can be applied which

estimates the weights of the primary right rate of stocking using a

harmonizing approach. Since this method puts less emphasis on

144

outliers, the harmonizing approach is supposed to result into a more

unbiased estimation. In addition, it turns out that the standard

deviation of the harmonized weighted primary outputs is smaller that

the standard deviation of equally weighted primary outputs.

The harmonized method is expected to provide a new useful tool for

policymakers in order to deal with heterogeneous experts’ knowledge.

By constructing the three fuzzy models based on the heterogeneous

knowledge and using some harmonized methods, our study tried to

show the multi-dimensional vaguenesses which generally exist in

rangeland management, and solve the conflict that especially exists in

economic and conservation views in the Iranian rangeland

management.

Finally, by comparing the estimated Right Rate of Stocking, which

elicited from both experts' opinions and Matlab Fuzzytoolbox Editor,

with its medium range, the models verified overgrazing in the three

regions of the Fars province in Southwest Iran.

145

Bibliography

Abdul Aziz, S., 1996. You fuzzyin' with me? Available on: http://www.doc.ic.ac.uk/~nd/surprise_96/journal/vol1/sbaa/articl

e1.html

Aenis, T. and Nagel, U.J., 2000. Participatory management of large interdisciplinary research teams - First experiences from a rural research and development project in Germany. Available on: http://www.zalf.de/home_zalf/sites/grano/publikation/aenis-

nagel2000.pdf

Ainesworth, E., 1989. LISA men have called you. Farm Journal, 113: 1.

Alexandratos, N., 1998. World Food and Agriculture: The Outlook for

the Medium and Longer Term. Rome: Global Perspective Studies Unit, FAO.

Alexandratos, N., 1999. Plants and population: Is there time? Available on: http://www.nap.edu/books/0309064279/html/5908.html

Andriantiatsaholiniaina, L.A., 2001. Sustainability Assessment Using

Fuzzy Logic. Ph.D. Dissertation. Chania: Department of Production Engineering and Management, Technical University of Crete, Greece.

Archer, S., 1996. Assessing and interpreting grass - woody plant dynamics. In: J. Hodgson, & A.W. Illius (Eds.), The Ecology and

Management of Grazing Systems (101-134). Wallingford: CAB International.

ARE., 2005. Sustainable development – Definition and constitutional status in Switzerland. Available on: http://www.are.admin.ch/are/en/nachhaltig/definition/

Atkinson, G., Dubourg, R., Hamilton K., Munashinge, M., Pearce, D. and Young, C. (Eds.), 1999. Measuring Sustainable

Development: Macroeconomics and the Environment (Second Edition). Northampton: Edward Elgar.

Azadi, H., Shahvali, M. and Faghih, N., 2003. Using fuzzy logic in solving conflict between sustainability and pasture. The

Proceedings of the 4th Seminar on Fuzzy Sets and its

Applications, 1-15. May 28-29, 2003, University of Mazandaran, Babolsar, Iran.

Azadi, H., Shahvali, M. and van den Berg, J., (In revision). Sustainable rangeland management using fuzzy Logic: A case study in Southwest Iran. Journal of Ecological Modeling.

146

Barendse, G.W.J. and van der Hoek, D., 1996. Interdisciplinary project teams on agriculture and environment: A problem-oriented approach. Journal of Agricultural Extension and

Education 1(3), 7. [online] Available on: http://library.wur.nl/ejae/v1n3-7.html

Barfield, T., 1981. The Central Asian Arabs of Afghanistan. Austin: University of Texas Press.

Barth, F., 1961. Nomads of South Persia: The Basseri Tribe of the

Khamseh Confederacy. London: Allen. Bates, D.G., 1973. Nomads and Farmers: A Study of the Yörük of

Southeastern Turkey. University of Michigan: Ann Arbor. Beck, L., 1986. The Qashqa’i of Iran. New Haven & London: Yale

University Press. Berkan, R.C. and Trubatch, S.L., 1997. Fuzzy Systems Design

Principles: Building Fuzzy IF-THEN Rule Bases. New York: IEEE Press.

Black-Michaud, J., 1986. Sheep and Land. The Economics of Power

in a Tribal Society. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Blaisdell, J.P. & Pechanec, J.F., 1949. Effects of herbage removal or

various dates on vigor of Bluebunch Wheatgrass and Arrowleaf Balsamroot. Ecology, 30, 298-305.

Blundon, A., 2001. The world food prize. Available on: http://www.worldfoodprize.org/Youthinstitute/2001YIProceeding

s/papers-html/Hoover%20High%20School.htm Box, T.W., 1995. Private Property Rights and Sustainable Rangeland

Use. University of California: Center for Forestry, UC Berkeley. Box, T.W., 2002. Future deserts and sustainable communities.

Available on: http://www.rala.is/rade/ralareport/Box.pdf Brink, B.J.E.T., 1989. Systematically in Search of Sustainable

Development. Memorandum GWWS 89.006, Tidal water division, The Hague.

Brink, B.J.E.T., Husper, S.H. and Colijn, F., 1990. A quantitative method for description and assessment of ecological systems: The AMOEBA approach. Proceedings of the International

Conference on the Environmental Management of Enclosed

Coastal Seas. Marine Pollution Bulletin, Kobe, Japan. Brink, B.J.E.T., 1991. The AMOEBA approach as a useful tool for

establishing sustainable development. In: O., Kuik, H., Verbruggen, (Eds.), Search of Indicators of Sustainable

Development. Kluwer Academic Publishers, The Netherlands.

147

Brown, L.R., 1997. Can we raise grain yields fast enough? Worldwatch, 10(4), 9-17.

Brown, L.R., Abramovitz, J.N., and Starke, L. (Eds.), 2000. State of

the World: A Worldwatch Institute Report on Progress Toward a

Sustainable Society. Publisher: W. W. Norton and Company, Inc. Burkhart, J.W., 1996. Herbivory in the Intermountain West: An

Overview of Evolutionary History, Historic Cultural Impacts and

Lessons from the Past. Station Bull. #58. Idaho Forest, Wildlife and Range Exp. Sta., Moscow Idaho.

Burns, R., 1994. Introduction to Research Methods. Melbourne: Longman.

Buss, H.J. and Nuppenau, E.A., 2002. More sustainable range use in semi-arid eco-systems through adapted management: A case study on Namibian farms based on bio-economic models. Contributed Paper and Poster, Deutscher Tropentag 2002,

Witzenhausen, 9. bis 11. October. Buxton, R. and Stafford Smith, M., 1996. Managing drought in

Australia's rangelands: Four weddings and a funeral. Rangeland

Journal, 18, 292-308. Conference on Sustainable Range Management, 2004. Proceedings of

the Conference on Sustainable Range Management, January 5 –

8. New Orleans, Louisiana. Connolly, J. & Nolan, T., 1976. Design and analysis of mixed grazing

experiments. Animal Production, 23, 63-71. Cornelissen, A.M.G., 2003. The Two Faces of Sustainability. Fuzzy

Evaluation of Sustainable Development. Ph.D. Thesis. Netherlands: Wageningen University.

Cornelissen, A.M.G., van den Berg, J., Koops, W.J., Grossman, M. and Udo, H.M.J., 2001. Assessment of the contribution of sustainability indicators to sustainable development: A novel approach using fuzzy set theory. Agriculture, Ecosystems and

Environment, 86, 173-185. Coulter, J., 2003. Sustainable population Australia. Available on:

http://www.population.org.au/pressrm/newslet/nl200303.pdf

Council for Biotechnology Information, 2002. Growing more food. How biotechnology in a seed can enhance global food security. Available on: http://www.whybiotech.com/index.asp?id=1821

Cumber, I.K., 2004. Chalmers. Annual Meeting of the Alliance for

Global Sustainability at Chalmers Workshop on Learning for

Sustainable Development, 22-24 March 2004.

148

Dasgupta, P., 1996. The economics of the environment. The British Academy. Proceedings of the British Academy, 90, 165-221.

Dasgupta, P. and Maler, K., 1995. Handbook of Development

Economics. Amsterdam: North Holland. Davis, A. and Wagner, J.R., 2003. Who knows? On the importance of

identifying “experts” when researching local ecological knowledge. Human Ecology, 31(3), 463-489.

Deadman, P.J., 1999. Modeling individual behavior and group performance in an intelligent agent based simulation of the tragedy of the commons. Journal of Environmental Management,

56,159-172 Dean, D., No date. World population. Available on:

http://www.ctm.org/arti/gentop/wdp.htm

de Kok, J.L., Titus, M. and Wind, H.G., 2000. Application of fuzzy sets and cognitive maps to incorporate social science scenarios in integrated assessment models: A case study of urbanization in Ujung Pandang, Indonesia. Integrated Assessment, 1, 177-188.

Digard, J-P., 1990. The Evolution of Nomadic Pastoralism in Iran 1960-1978: Problems and Interpretations. In: C. Salzman, & J.G. Galaty (Eds.), Nomads in a Changing World (165-175). Naples: Istituto Universitario Orientale.

Driankov, D., Hellendoorn, H. and Reinfrank, M., 1996. An

Introduction to Fuzzy Control. New York: Springer. Dunn, E.G., Keller, J.M., Marks, L.A., Ikerd, J.E., Fader, P.D. and

Godsey, L.D., 1995. Extending the application of fuzzy sets to the problem of agricultural sustainability. IEEE Proceedings of

ISUMA-NAFIPS ’95, Missouri-Columbia, USA. Earth Government for Earth Community, 2003. Earth government for

earth community: A grassroots process. Available on: http://members.shaw.ca/earthgov/ECGlobalConcepts.htm

EC., 2002. Strategic Guidelines and Priorities for Interventions to be

Financed in 2002 and 2003 under Regulation. No. 2493/2000 of the European Parliament and of the Council on Measures to Promote Environment in Developing Countries. European Commission, DG Development. DEV/2790/2002, Budget Line B7 – 6200.

EDC News, 2003. Population & land: Arable land per capita diminishing - serious implications. Available on: http://www.edcnews.se/Research/Population-Landhunger.html

El-Awad, O.M.A., 1991. Multicriterion Approach to the Evaluation of

Irrigation Systems Performance. Ph.D. Thesis. Greece:

149

University of Newcastle upon Tyne, Department of Civil Engineering.

Emadi, M.H., 2003. Bridging Epistemologies and Integrating

Indigenous Knowledge with Scientific Knowledge for Sustainable

Development: A Case Study. Research Deputy of Rural Research Center, (RRC), Tehran, Iran.

Einstein, D.E. 1998. Intensification: Can agriculture keep up with population growth? Available on: http://darwin.bio.uci.edu/~sustain/global/sensem/einstein298.htm

l

EuropaWorld, 2003. EuropaWorld. Available on: http://www.europaworld.org/week119/crowthinfood7303.htm

Falconer, J., 1990. The Major Significance of ’Minor’ Forest

Products. Rome: FAO. Falconer, J. and Arnold, J.E.M., 1989. Household Food Security and

Forestry: An Analysis of Socio-Economic Issues. Rome: FAO. FAO, 1999. Towards a hunger-free century. Available on:

http://www.fao.org/dg/1999/millen-e.htm

FAO, 2000a. FAO report: Enough food in the future--without genetically engineered crops. Available on: http://www.ucsusa.org/food_and_environment/biotechnology/pa

ge.cfm?pageID=331 FAO, 2000b. Food and population: FAO looks ahead. Available on:

http://www.fao.org/news/2000/000704-e.htm

FAO, 2002. World agriculture 2030: Main findings. Available on: http://www.fao.org/english/newsroom/news/2002/7833-en.html

FAO, 2003. World Agriculture: Towards 2015/2030. An FAO

Perspective. London: Earthscan Publications Ltd. FAO, 2004a. Grassland and pasture crops in the Islamic Republic of

Iran. Available on: http://www.fao.org/WAICENT/FAOINFO/AGRICULT/AGP/AGP

C/doc/Counprof/Iran/Iran.htm FAO, 2004b. Food topsource. Available on:

http://www.t21.ca/food/tp.htm

FAO, 2004c. Community Forestry. Rapid Appraisal. Note Number 3. FAO Corporate Document Repository. Forestry Department.

Fazel, G., 1971. Economic Organisation and Change among the Boyr

Ahmad: A Nomadic Pastoral Tribe in Southwest Iran. Ph.D. Thesis. Berkeley: University of California.

150

Foran, B.D. & Stafford Smith, D.M., 1991. Risk, biology and drought management strategies for cattle stations in Central Australia. Journal of Environmental Management, 33: 17-33.

Ford, D.N. and Sterman, J.D., 1998. Expert knowledge elicitation to improve mental and formal models. System Dynamics Review,

14(4), 309-30. Ferraro, D.O., Ghersa, C.M. & Sznaider, G.A., 2003. Evaluation of

environmental impact indicators using fuzzy logic to assess the mixed cropping systems of the Inland Pampa, Argentina. Agriculture Ecosystems & Environment, 96, 1-18.

Gamble, D., 1989. Two Techniques for Gathering Data and Building

Rich Pictures in Rural and Community Development Action

Research Projects. Hawkesbury: Hawkesbury Agricultural College.

Gammon, D. M. & Roberts, B. R., 1978. Patterns of defoliation during continuous and rotational grazing of the Matopos Sandveld of Rhodesia. 1. Selectivity of grazing. Rhodesian Journal of

Agricultural Research, 16, 117-31. Genesis, 2005. Online parallel Bible. Available on:

http://bible.cc/genesis/6-5.htm GLEAM., 2002. A Forum on sustainability modeling and assessment:

What's new? Available on: http://www.unu.edu/env/Gleam/Concept.html

Glimp, H.A. & Swanson, S.R., 1994. Sheep grazing and riparian and watershed management. Sheep Research Journal, Special Issue, 65-71.

Glossary of Terms Used in Range Management, 2002. Range sites of Florida. Glossary of terms used in range management. Available on: http://wfrec.ifas.ufl.edu/range/rangelands/glossary.htm

Gowing, J., Tarimo, A. and El-Awad, O., 1996. A rational methods for assessing irrigation performance at farm level with the aid of fuzzy set theory. Irrigation and Drainage Systems, 10, 319-339.

Grigg, G., 1995. Kangaroo harvesting for conservation of rangelands, kangaroos, and graziers. In: G.C. Grigg, P.T. Hale and Lunney D. (Eds.), Conservation Through Sustainable Use of Wildlife (161-165). Centre for Conservation Biology:University of Queensland.

Grint, K., 1997. Fuzzy Management. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hardesty, L., Lawrence, J.H., Gill, S.J. and Chapman, R.C., 1993.

Private forest landowner’s perceptions of forest grazing in Washington State. Journal of Range Management, 46, 49-55.

151

Harris, J.M., 2001. Agriculture in a global perspective. Global Development and Environment Institute. Working Paper No. 01-04. Available on: http://ase.tufts.edu/gdae/publications/working_papers/agric4.wo

rkingpaper.PDF Hart, M., 2000. An introduction to sustainability. Available on:

http://www.sustainablemeasures.com/Sustainability Hart, R.H., Bissio, J., Samuel, M.J. & Waggoner, J.W., 1993. Grazing

systems, pasture size, and cattle grazing behavior, distribution and gains. Journal of Range Management, 46, 81-87.

Hastie, T., Tibshirani, R. and Friedman, J., 2001. The Elements of

Statistical Learning. Data Mining, Inference and Prediction. New York: Springer.

Hawkins, R., 1997. Training in interdisciplinary team research for agricultural development: The experience of ICRA. European

Journal of Agricultural Education and Extension, 4(1), 49-66. Heitschmidt, R.K., Dowhower, S.L. & Walker, J.W., 1987. 14- Vs.

42-Paddock rotational grazing: Above ground biomass dynamics, forage production, and harvest efficiency. Journal of Range

Management, 40, 216-223. Hiernaux, P., 1996. The Crisis of Sahelian Pastoralism: Ecological or

Economic? ODI Pastoral Development Network Paper 39a. 20p. London: Overseas Development Institute.

Heemskerk, M., Wilson, K. & Pavao-Zuckerman, M., 2003. Conceptual models as tools for communication across disciplines. Conservation Ecology, 7(3), 8. [online] Available on: http://www.consecol.org/vol7/iss3/art8/

HMSO, 1994. Sustainable Development: The UK Strategy. Cm 2429. HMSO, London.

Hodgkinson, K.C., 1996. A model for perennial grass mortality under grazing. In: N.E. West (Ed.), Rangelands in a Sustainable

Biosphere. Proceedings Vth International Rangeland Congress, Vol. I., pp. 240-241. Denver: Society for Range Management.

Hodgkinson, K.C. & Freudenberger, D.O., 1997. Production pulses and flow-ons in rangeland landscapes. In: J.A. Ludwig, D.J. Tongway, D.O. Freudenberger, J.C. Noble & K.C. Hodgkinson (Eds.), Landscape Function, Ecology and Management:

Principles from Australia's Rangelands (23-34). Melbourne: CSIRO.

152

Hodgkinson, K.C. & Harrington, G.N., 1985. The case for prescribed burning to control shrubs in Eastern semi-arid woodlands. Australian Rangeland Journal, 7, 64-74.

Holechek, J.L., & Hawkes, J., 1993. Desert and prairie ranching profitability. Rangelands, 15, 104-109.

Holechek, J.L. & Hess, K., 1995. The emergency feed program. Rangelands, 17, 133-136.

Holechek, J.L., Pieper, R.D. & Herbel, C.H., 1989. Range

Management Principles and Practices. Englewood Cliffs: Regents/Prentice Hall.

Holliday, C. and Pepper, J., 2005. Sustainability through the market: Our opportunity. Available on: http://www1.dupont.com/dupontglobal/corp/documents/US/en_U

S/news/speeches/wbcsdreport.pdf

Holmes, J.H., 1996. Diversity and change in Australia's rangeland regions: Translating resource values into regional benefits. Rangeland Journal, 19, 3-25.

Howery, L.D., Sprinkle, J.E., and Bowns, J.E., 2000. A summary of

livestock grazing systems used on rangelands in the Western

United States and Canada. Cooperative Extension, College of Agriculture & Life Sciences, The University of Arizona.

Iranian Nomadic Organization, 1992. Proceedings of Development

Strategy of Iranian Nomadic Life. Iran: Ashayeri Publications. Iran Rozaneh, 2003. Nomads in Iran. Available on:

http://www.rozanehmagazine.com/janfeb2003/aculture.html

Irons, W. and Dyson-Hudson, N. (Eds.), 1972. Perspectives on

Nomadism. Leiden: Brill. Irons, W., 1975. The Yomut Turkmen: A Study of Social Organization

among a Central Asian Turkicspeaking Population. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan.

ISAS, 2001. Biotech ‘Tailor-Made’ for Africa, researcher tells tufts conference. Council for Biotechnology Information, Washington, D.C., November 19, 2001. Available on: <index.asp?id=1156&redirect=con1309mid17%2Ehtml>

Ishibuchi, H., Nakashima, T. and Morisawa, T., 1999. Voting in fuzzy rule-based systems for pattern classification problems. Fuzzy Sets

and Systems, 103(1), 223-238. IUCN/IDRC (International Union for the Conservation of

Nature/International Development Research Center), 1995. Assessing progress towards sustainability: a new approach. In:

153

Thadeus, Trzuna (Eds.), A Sustainable World: Defining and

Measuring Sustainable Development (172-182). Sacramento. IUCN/UNEP/WWF (International Union for the Conservation of

Nature/United Nations Environment Program/WorldWide Fund for Nature), 1991. Caring for the Earth: A Strategy for

Sustainable Living. IUCN, Gland, Switzerland. Jameson, D.A., 1963. Responses of individual plants to harvesting.

The Botanical Review, 29, 532-594. Jang, J.-S.R., Sun, C.-T. and Mizutani, E., 1997. Neuro-Fuzzy and Soft

Computing, A Computational Approach to Learning and

Machine Intelligence. Prentice Hall. Johnston, A. and Peake, R.W., 1960. Effect of selective grazing by

sheep on the control of leafy spurge (Euphorbia esula L.). Journal of Range Management, 13,192-195.

Jones, R.A., 1985. Research Methods in the Social and Behavioral

Sciences. Massachusetts: Sinauer Association Inc. Kanwar, R.S., 2003. Environmental degradation and water security for

the world population. Available on: http://www.ucowr.siu.edu/proc/T9B.pdf

Kautza, T. and Gronski, R., 2003. Water ethic to renew the earth. Catholic Rural Life Magazine, 45(2). Available on: http://www.ncrlc.com/crl-magazine-articles/vol45no2/Gronski-

Kautza.pdf Kauffman, J.B. & Krueger, W.C., 1984. Livestock impacts on riparian

ecosystems and streamside management implications: a review. Journal of Range Management, 37, 430-438.

Kenny, G., 2004. Report to the productivity commission. Cost and stocking rate data for the Murweh Shire. Available on: http://www.pc.gov.au/inquiry/nativevegetation/consultancy/murw

eh1/murweh1.pdf

Kopp, J., 2004. Stocking Rates and AUM- frequently Asked Questions. Alberta government. Department of Agriculture, Food and Rural Development.

Kosko, B., 1993. Fuzzy Thinking. New York: Hyperion. Kothmann, M.M., Hinnant, R.T. & Taylor, C.A., 1997. The role of

grazing management in overcoming juniper. Proc. Juniper

Symposium. Texas Agric. Exp. Stn. Tech. Rep. Kovács, L. and Micsik, A., 2005. The design of voting and rating

services within Web4Groups. Available on: http://dsd.sztaki.hu/publications/cscwid97-

bangkok/BankokCikkFinal.htm

154

Landsberg, J.J., James, C. and Morton, S., 1997. Assessing the effects of grazing on biodiversity in Australia's rangelands. Australian

Biologist, 10, 153-162. Landsberg, J.J., O'Connor, T. G. and Freudenberger, D.O., 1999. The

impacts of livestock grazing on biodiversity in natural ecosystems. In: Proceedings Vth International Symposium on the

Nutrition of Herbivores. Landsberg, J.J. and Stol, J., 1996. Spatial distribution of sheep, feral

goats and kangaroos in woody rangeland paddocks. Rangeland

Journal, 18, 270-291. Larsen, J., 2002. Earth times. Population growth leading to land

hunger. Available on: http://www.sdearthtimes.com/et0403/et0403s9.html

Larsen, J., 2003. Population growth leading to land hunger. Earth Policy Institute. Available on: http://www.earth-

policy.org/Updates/Update21.htm Lacey, J. and Taylor, J., 2005. Montana guide to range site, condition

and initial stocking rates. Available on: http://www.montana.edu/wwwpb/pubs/mt8515.html

Lee, C.C., 1990. Fuzzy logic in control systems: Fuzzy logic controller–part I and II. IEEE Trans. Syst. Man Cyber., 20, 404-435.

Leigh, J. H. & Mulham, W.E., 1966. Selection of diet by sheep grazing semi-arid pastures of the Riverine Plain. 1. A bladder saltbush (Atriplex vesicaria) - cotton bush (Kochia aphylla) community. Australian Journal of Experimental Agriculture and

Animal Husbandry, 6, 460-467. Lusigi, W. and Acquay, H., 1999. Challenges facing pastoralists in the

drylands of subSaharan Africa. VIth International Rangeland

Congress Proceedings, 2, 83-84. Lyons, R.K. and Machen, R.V., 2005. Stocking rate: The key grazing

management decision. Available on: http://rangeweb.tamu.edu/extension/rangedetect/l5400_sr.pdf

MAF, 2000. Impediments to optimising the economic and environmental performance of agriculture. Available on: http://www.maf.govt.nz/mafnet/rural-nz/profitability-and-

economics/performance/impediments-to-optimum-

performance/impopt-05.htm Mamdani, E.H. and Gaines, B.R., 1981. Fuzzy Reasoning and its

Applications. London: Academic Press.

155

Manske, L.L., 2004. A method of determining stocking rate based on monthly standing herbage biomass. Available on: http://www.ag.ndsu.nodak.edu/dickinso/research/2003/range03s.

htm Marks, L.A. Dunn, E.G. Keller, J.M. and Godsey, L.D., 1995.

Multiple Criteria Decision Making (MCDM) using fuzzy logic: An innovative approach to sustainable agriculture. IEEE

Proceedings of ISUMA-NAFIPS ’95, Missouri-Columbia, USA. Marshall, C. and Rossman G.B., 1995. Designing qualitative research.

Available on: http://www.geocities.com/zulkardi/turmudi.html

Martin, S.C., 1978. Grazing systems -- What can they accomplish? Rangeman's Journal, 5, 14-16.

McKeown, R., Hopkins, C., Rizzi, R. and Chrystalbridge, M., 2002. Education for Sustainable Development Toolkit. Energy, Environment and Resources Center, University of Tennessee.

McMurphy, W.E., Gillen, R.L., Engle, D.M. & McCollum, F.T., 1990. The philosophical difference between range and pasture management in Oklahoma. Rangelands, 12, 197-200.

Meadows, D., 1998. Indicators and Information Systems for

Sustainable Development. A Report to the Balaton Group. Hartland: The Sustainability Institute.

Mesbahi, M., 2004. Water wars. Available on: http://www.countercurrents.org/en-mesbahi251104.htm

Mesdaghi, M., 1995. Management of Iran’s Rangelands. Mashhad: Imam Reza University.

Milchunas, D. G., Sala, O.E., and Lauenroth, W.K., 1988. A generalized model of the effects of grazing by large herbivores on grassland community structure. The American Naturalist, 132, 87-106.

Miller, D.J., 2005. Rangeland management in the Hindu Kush-Himalayas. International Centre for Integrated Mountain Development (ICIMOD). Available on: http://www.icimod.org/focus/rangelands/range3.htm

Miller, R., 1995. Range Management: The Art and Science. The Pacific Northwest Section, Society for Range Management Newsletter.

Milne, R., 1995. World food issues: Past and present. A Christian perspective on “population alarmism”. Available on: http://www.agron.iastate.edu/courses/agron342/milne.html

Milne, R., 2002. World population. Available on: http://www.leaderu.com/orgs/probe/docs/worldpop.html

156

Mitchell, J.D., 1998. Before the next doubling. Available on: http://www.worldwatch.org/may/1998/98-1.html

Mitchell, J.E., Joyce, L.A. and Bryant, L.D., 1999. Applicability of Montreal process criteria and indicators to rangelands. VIth

International Rangeland Congress Proceedings, 1, 183-184. Morita, T., Nakicenovic, N. and Robinson, J., 2000. The Relationship

between Technological Development Path and the Stabilization

of Atmospheric Greenhouse Gas Concentrations in Global

Emissions Scenarios. Center of Global Environmental Research (CGER). National Institute for Environmental Studies.

Mortensen, I.D., 1993. Nomads of Luristan. History, Material Culture

and Pastoralism in Western Iran. London: Thames & Hudson / Copenhagen: Rhodos.

Mosley, J.C., 1994. Prescribed sheep grazing to enhance wildlife habitat on North American rangelands. Sheep Research Journal,

Special Issue, 79-91. Munda, G., Nijkamp, P. and Rietveld, P., 1994. Qualitative

multicriteria evaluation for environmental management. Ecological Economics, 10, 97-112.

Namey-e-Otaq-e-Bazargani, 1996. The Life and Economy of Iranian Tribesmen in Iran. Journal of Chamber of Commerce, 3, 63-66. (The publication of the Chamber of Commerce, Industries and Mines of the Islamic Republic of Iran). [online]: http://www.kkhec.ac.ir/Iran%20information/life_and_economy_o

f_iranian_trib.htm National Research Council. 1993. Sustainable Agriculture and the

Environment in the Humid Tropics. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

Nationmaster, 2005. Encyclopedia: Sustainable development. Available on: http://www.nationmaster.com/encyclopedia/sustainable-

development Niblo, D.M. and Jackson, M.S., 1999. Qualitative data & private

security in the hospitality industry: The hidden agenda. Available on: http://www.latrobe.edu.au/aqr/offer/papers/MNiblo.htm

NGO Forum for Food Sovereignty, 2002. Policies for mobile pastoralism, rangeland management, and arid lands. Available on: http://www.iucn.org/themes/ceep/Wkg_grp/SL/pastoralism%20p

olicies.pdf

157

NRCS, 2000. Animal unit. Delaware Nutrient Management Notes,

1(2). [online] Available on: http://www.state.de.us/deptagri/nutrients/newsltr/feb_00.shtml

Nshimbani, J., 2004. Zamculture for human and social development. Culture and Rural Development Research. Available on: http://africa.eduprojects.net/agriculture/index.php?action%5B%

5D=IArticleShow::showArticle('352') OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development),

1994. Environmental Indicators. OECD, Paris. Oldcarpet, 2005. Qashqai. Available on:

http://www.oldcarpet.com/qashqai.htm

Olson, B.E. & Lacey, J.R., 1994. Sheep: A method for controlling rangeland weeds. Sheep Research Journal, Special Issue, 105-112.

Ortega, R., 2002. Studies in the subject of opinion leadership. Available on: http://www.ciadvertising.org/student_account/spring_02/adv382j

/ortega/Theories.htm Owens, S., 2001. Salt of the earth. European Molecular Biology

Organization. Available on: http://www.monsanto.co.uk/news/ukshowlib.phtml?uid=5890

PAI, 2005. Conserving land. Population and sustainable food production. Committee for the National Institute for the Environment. Available on: http://www.cnie.org/pop/conserving/landuse.htm

Patton, M.Q., 1987. How to Use Qualitative Methods in Evaluation. London: SAGE Publications.

Pearce, D.W., Atkinson, G.D., 1993. Capital theory and the measurement of sustainable development: an indicator of weak sustainability. Ecological Economics, 8, 103-108.

Pedrycz, W., 1994. Why triangular membership function? Fuzzy Sets

and Systems, 64, 21-30. Pedrycz, W., 2001. Fuzzy equalization in the construction of fuzzy

sets. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 119, 329-335. Pembleton, P.N., 2004. Sustainability and Impacts. Technical

Analysis Report. California Department of Transportation, Transportation Energy Efficiency and Conservation Project.

Pender, J., 1999. Rural population growth, agricultural change and natural resource management in developing countries: A review of hypotheses and some evidence from Honduras. International Food Policy Research Institute. Environment and Production

158

Technology Division. Available on: http://www.ifpri.org/divs/eptd/dp/papers/eptdp48.pdf

Peters, T.J. & Waterman, R.H., 1982. In Search of Excellence Lessons

from America's Best-Run Companies. New York: New York Harper & Row, Publishers.

Peterson, E., 1998. What earth day means to minority citizens. Available on: http://www.nationalcenter.org/NPA193.html

Phillis, Y.A. and Andriantiatsaholiniania, L., 2001. Sustainability: An ill defined concept and its assessment using fuzzy logic. Ecological Economics, 39, 435-456.

Pickett, S.T.A., Burch, W.R., and Grove, J.M., 1999. Interdisciplinary research: maintaining the constructive impulse in a culture of criticism. Ecosystems, 2, 302-307.

Pimentel, D. and Wilson, A., 2005. World population, agriculture, and malnutrition. Available on: http://www.energybulletin.net/3834.html

Pimentel, D. and Giampietro, M., 2001. US population growth factsheet. Available on: http://www.balance.org/articles/factsheet2001.html

Pimentel, D., Huang, X., Cordova, A., and Pimentel, M. 1996. Impact of population growth on food supplies and environment. Available on: http://dieoff.org/page57.htm

Pinstrup-Andersen, P. and Cohen, M. J., 1998. Aid to developing country agriculture: Investing in poverty reduction and new export opportunities. International Food Policy Research Institute. Available on: <http://www.ifpri.org/2020/briefs/number56.htm>

Pinstrup-Andersen, P. and Pandya-Lorch, R., 1999. Meeting food needs in the 21st century. How many and who will be at risk? Available on: http://www.ifpri.org/pubs/jhu/fed21century/fed21century_chapte

r01.pdf Polley, H.W., 1997. Implications of rising atmospheric carbon dioxide

concentration for rangelands. Journal of Range Management, 50, 561-577.

Pretty, J.N., 1995. Regenerating Agriculture – Policies and Practice

for Sustainability and Self-Reliance. Washington D.C.: Joseph Henry Press.

Pretty, J. and Hine, R., 2001. Reducing food poverty with sustainable agriculture: A summary of new evidence. SAFE-World Research Project. University of Essex, Centre for Environment and

159

Society. Available on: http://www2.essex.ac.uk/ces/ResearchProgrammes/SAFEWexecs

ummfinalreport.htm

Qashqai.net., 2003. A short historical overview (A meta-narrative?). Available on: http://www.qashqai.net/history.htm

Radcliffe, J.E., 1985. Grazing management of goats and sheep for gorse control. New Zealand Journal of Experimental Agriculture,

13, 181-190. Rao, L., 1999. Future harvest: Agriculture & overpopulation.

Magazine of the Cousteau Society, October. Available on: http://www.futureharvest.org/news/calypso.shtml

Raven, P.H., 2004. Feeding a hungry world: The moral imperatives of biotechnology. The Pontifical Gregorian University, Rome. Available on: http://vatican.usembassy.it/policy/events/Biotech2004/Raven.pdf

Redfearn, D.D. and Bidwell, T.G., 2004. Stocking rate: The key to successful livestock production. Available on:

http://www.osuextra.com Reich, P.F., Numbem, S.T., Almaraz, R.A. and Eswaran, H., 2001.

Land resource stresses and desertification in Africa. In: E.M. Bridges, I.D. Hannam, L.R. Oldeman, F.W.T. Pening de Vries, S.J. Scherr, and S. Sompatpaint (Eds.), Responses to Land

Degradation. Proc. 2nd. International Conference on Land Degradation and Desertification, Khon Kaen, Thailand. Oxford Press, New Delhi, India.

Rennings, K. and Wiggering, H., 1997. Step towards indicators of sustainable development: Linking economic and ecological concepts. Ecological Economics, 20, 25-36.

Richards, J.F., 1990. Land Transformation. In: B.L. Turner (Ed.), The

Earth as Transformed by Human Action. New York: Cambridge with Clark University.

Rigby, D., Woodhouse, P., Young, T. and Burton, M., 2001. Constructing a farm level indicator of sustainable agricultural practice. Ecological Economics, 39, 463-478.

Riggio, R., Bomar, G. and Larkin, T., 1987. Texas Drought: Its Recent

History (1931-1985). Texas Water Commission, Austin Texas LP 87-04. 74 pp.

Roe, E.M., 1997. Viewpoint: On rangeland carrying capacity. Journal

of Range Management, 50(5), 467-472. Roshier, D.A. and Nicol, H.I., 1998. Implications of spatio-temporal

variation in forage production and utililisation for animal

160

productivity in extensive grazingsystems. Rangeland Journal, 20, 3-25.

RS and NAS, 1992. The Royal Society and the National Academy of Sciences on Population Growth and Sustainability. Population

and Development Review, 18 (2), 375-378. Ruspini, E.H., Bonissone, P.P. and Pedrycz, W. (Eds.), 1998.

Handbook of Fuzzy Computation. Bristol and Philadelphia: Institute of Physics Publishing.

Sam-Amoah L.K. and Gowing, J.W., 2001. Assessing the performance of irrigation schemes with minimum data on water deliveries. Irrigation and Drainage Systems, 50, 31-39.

Savory, A. and Butterfield, J., 1999. Holistic Management: A New

Framework for Decision Making. Washington D.C.: Island Press. Seers, D. 1982. The meaning of development. In: G.E. Jones and M.J.

Rolls (Eds.), Progress in Rural Extension and Community

Development, 1, 7-24. John Wiley and Sons, Ltd. Sands, D.M., 1986. Farming systems research: clarification of terms

and concepts. Expl. Agric. 22, 87-104. Serf Publishing Inc., 2001. Food & Agriculture...A Growing World

Crisis! The U.S. Dept. of Agriculture, the former Ambassador Agricultural Research Department, Agresource Management Associates, Agrotech Research Group.

Shah, M. and Strong, M., 1999. Food in the 21st century: From science to sustainable. Consultative Group on International Agricultural Research (CGIAR). Available on: http://www.worldbank.org/html/cgiar/publications/shahbook/sha

hbook.pdf

Shahvali, M. and Azadi, H., 1999. Designing of extension research on the basis of paradisciplinary. A Quarterly Journal of Ightesade

Kishavarzi Va Towse'e 2(4), 21-56. Shaner, W.W., Philip, P.F. and Schmehl, W.R., 1982. Farming

Systems Research and Development: Guidelines for Developing

Countries. Westview Press. Sherp, J., 1994. What does an economist need to know about the

environment? Directorate General for Economics and Financial Affairs. Economic Papers of the European Commission No. 107.

Sicat, R.S., Carranza, E.J.M. and Nidumolu, U.B., 2005. Fuzzy modeling of farmers’ knowledge for land suitability classification. Agricultural Systems 83, 49-75.

Silvert, W., 1997. Ecological impact classification with fuzzy sets. Ecological Modelling, 96, 1-10.

161

Sogol, No date. Tribes of Iran. Available on: http://www.sogol.com/WHP/IINT/IRTRIBE.htm

Stafford Smith, M., 1996. Management of rangelands: Paradigms at their limits. In: J. Hodgson and A.W. Illius (Eds.), The Ecology

and Management of Grazing Systems (325-357). Wallingford: CAB International.

Stoddart, L.A. and Smith, A.W., 1943. Range Management (First Edition). McGraw-Hill, New York.

Stoddart, L.A. and Smith, A.W., 1955. Range Management (Second Edition). McGraw-Hill, New York.

Stoddart, L.A., Smith, A.W. and Box, T., 1975. Range Management (Third Edition). McGraw-Hill, New York.

Strauss, A. and Corbin, J., 1990. Basic Qualitative Research

Grounded Theory Procedures and Techniques. London: SAGE.

Stuth, J.W. and Lyons, B.G. (Eds.), 1993. Decision Support Systems

for the Management of Grazing Lands: Emerging Issues. Carnforth: The Parthenon PublishingGroup Inc.

Swee, G.M., 1981. Sedentarization: Change and Adaptation among

the Kordshuli Pastoral Nomads of Southwestern Iran. Ph.D. Thesis. Michigan: Michigan State University.

Taghi Farvar, M. and Jandaghi, M., 1998. Thematic Programme

Network III for Regional Co-operation under the Convention to

Combat Desertification (CCD). Tehran: The Government of the Islamic Republic of Iran and the Interim Secretariat of the Convention to Combat Desertification.

Tagaki, T. and Sugeno, M., 1985. Fuzzy identification of systems and its applications to modeling and control. IEEE Transactions on

Systems, Man and Cybernetics, 15(1), 116–132. Takle, E.S., 2001. Sustainable development. Available on:

http://www.iitap.iastate.edu/gccourse/develop/sust_develop_lectu

re.html Tapper, R., 1979. Pasture and Politics: Economics, Conflict and

Ritual among the Shahsevan Nomads of Northwestern Iran. London: Academic Press.

Tapper, R. (Ed.), 1983. The Conflict of Tribe and State in Iran and

Afghanistan. London: Croom Helm. Tapper, R., 1997. Frontier Nomads of Iran. Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press. Tesch, R., 1990. Qualitative Research: Analysis Types and Software

Tools. New York: The Falmer Press.

162

Thompson, P.B., 1995. The Spirit of the Soil: Agriculture and

Environmental Ethics. New York: Routledge. The Online Newsletter of the Bahá'í International Community, 1996.

The importance of agriculture. The Online Newsletter of the

Bahá'í International Community, 8(2). [online] Available on: http://www.onecountry.org/oc82/oc8202as.html

Travel Explorations, 2004. Trekking through the lands of the Iranians nomads – Part 1 of 2. Available on: http://www.travelexplorations.com/cparticle175488-18553a.html

Truelsen, S., 2003. Agriculture Faces Huge Task in Scenario for the Future. Available on: http://www.fb.org/views/focus/fo2003/fo0113.html

UN, 2000. Sustainable agriculture and rural development. Available on: http://www.un.org/documents/ecosoc/cn17/2000/ecn172000-

7add3.htm UNCED (United Nations Conference on Environment and

Development), 1992. Agenda 21. New York: UNCED. UNCT, 2001. United Nations inter-agency assessment report on the

extreme drought in the Islamic Republic of Iran. Available on: http://www.reliefweb.int/w/Rwb.nsf/0/08951820c13c2bc5c1256a

85005081e0?OpenDocument UNDP, 2001. Human development report. Available on:

http://hdr.undp.org/reports/global/2001/en/pdf/pr2.pdf UNDP, 2003. Earth policy news – Population growth & land hunger.

Available on: http://www.undp.org.vn/mlist/envirovlc/012003/post74.htm

UNEP, 1992. Caring for the Earth: A Learner’s Guide to Sustainable

Living. New York: United Nations. UNEP, 2000. Atmosphere. Available on:

http://www.unep.org/geo2000/english/0048.htm UNESCO, 1996. Enhancing Social Scientific Understanding of

Sustainability. Declaration on the occasion of the conference "Sustainability as a Social Science Concept" within the UNESCO-MOST Programme, held in Frankfurt, November 1996. Available on: http://www.unesco.org/most/sustdecl.htm

UNFPA, 2003. State of World Population 2003. Making 1 Billion Count: Investing in Adolescents’ Health and Rights. United Nations Population Fund. Available on: http://www.unfpa.org/swp/2003/english/ch1/

UNFPA, 2005. Population & demographic dynamics. Available on: http://www.unfpa.org/sustainable/demographics.htm

163

UNPD, 2003. World Population Prospects. The 2002 Revision (Vol. I: Comprehensive Tables). New York: UN Population Division.

van den Berg, J., 2004. Fuzzy methodologies for evaluating sustainable development. ICMCS Conference, Nigeria: Lagos.

van der Werff, T.J., 1998. Threats and opportunities in a new century. Available on: http://www.globalfuture.com/9512.htm

Waggoner, P., 1994. How Much Land Can Ten Billion People Spare

for Nature? Council for Science and Technology, Ames, Iowa. Walker, J.W., 1994. Multi-species grazing: the ecological advantage.

Sheep Research Journal, Special Issue, 52-64. Walker, J.W., 1995. Viewpoint: Grazing management and research

now and in the next millennium. Journal of Range Management,

48(4), 350-357. Walker, J.W. and Hodgkinson, K.C., 2000. Grazing management:

New technologies for old problems. http://sanangelo.tamu.edu/walker/incpaper.htm

WCED (World Commission on Environment and Development), 1987. Our Common Future. Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Westoby, M., Walker, B.H. & Noy-Meir, I., 1989. Opportunistic management for rangelands not at equilibrium. Journal of Range

Management, 42, 266-274. Wikipedia, 2005. Sustainable development. Available on:

http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Sustainable_development Williams, J.K., 2000. Churchpeople, socialism, and capitalism.

Available on: http://www.libertyhaven.com/noneoftheabove/religionandchristia

ns/churchpeople.html Wilson, E., 1999. One third of world's population 2.7 billion people

will experience severe water scarcity by 2025, says new study. Future Harvest. Available on: http://www.futureharvest.org/news/03171999.shtml

Wilson, A.D. and Macleod N.D., 1991. Overgrazing: Present or absent? Journal of Range Management, 44(5), 475-482.

World Bank, 1998. Population growth rate. Available on: http://www.worldbank.org/depweb/english/modules/social/pgr/index03.html

World Resources Institute, 1994. World Resources 1994-95. New York: Oxford.

Yin, R.K., 1989. Case study research design and methods. Available on: http://www.geocities.com/zulkardi/turmudi.html

164

Zadeh, L.A., 1973. Outline of a new approach to the analysis of complex systems and decision processes. IEEE Transactions on

Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, 1 (1), 28–44. Zadeh, L.H., 1965. Fuzzy sets. Information and Control, 8, 338–353. Zilberman, D. and Alix, J., 2005. Principles of environmental

policymaking. Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of California at Berkeley. Available on: http://are.berkeley.edu/courses/ARE253/2004/handouts/envpolic

ymaking.pdf Zimmermann, H.J., 1996. Fuzzy Set Theory and its Applications

(Third Edition). Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

165

APPENDIX 1

General information of data collection Number of studied area 3 regions

Number of data collection 3 rounds

Spent time of data collection 18 months

Number of conducted major interviews 9 sessions

Number of conducted minor interviews 21 follow-ups

Average time of major interviews at first round 3 hours

Average time of major interviews at second round 3 hours

Average time of major interviews at third round 5 hours

Average time of minor interviews 2 hours

166

APPENDIX 2

If–Then Rules

EAFL Model:

167

Multi Fuzzy Model: Model 1

168

169

170

Model 2

171

172

173

174

175

176

Model 3

177