pharma pricing and reimbursement

143
HEALTHCARE Pharmaceutical Pricing and Reimbursement Strategies for market access across the US, Europe, Japan and other key geographies By Steven Seget

Upload: fatima

Post on 14-Dec-2015

24 views

Category:

Documents


7 download

DESCRIPTION

pharma industry details

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

HEALTHCARE

Pharmaceutical Pricing andReimbursementStrategies for market access across the US, Europe,Japan and other key geographies

By Steven Seget

Page 2: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

ii

Steven Seget

Steven Seget is Principal at Delphi Pharma, and provides independent strategic

consulting services to the pharmaceutical and biotechnology industries. Steven

previously managed the strategic healthcare consulting function at Datamonitor and has

an MBA from the London Business School. [email protected]

Delphi Pharma provides strategic, financial and market–based solutions to clients,

focusing primarily on the portfolio management, business development and licensing

functions. Delphi Pharma combines an extensive research network, applied analytical

expertise and an established track record to deliver high value results and measurable

impact to its clients. www.delphipharma.com

Copyright © 2007 Business Insights Ltd

This Management Report is published by Business Insights Ltd. All rights reserved. Reproduction or redistribution of this Management Report in any form for any purpose is expressly prohibited without the prior consent of Business Insights Ltd.

The views expressed in this Management Report are those of the publisher, not of Reuters. Reuters accepts no liability for the accuracy or completeness of the information, advice or comment contained in this Management Report nor for any actions taken in reliance thereon.

While information, advice or comment is believed to be correct at the time of publication, no responsibility can be accepted by Business Insights Ltd for its completeness or accuracy.

REUTERS and dotted and sphere logos are the house trade marks of Reuters Limited in more than 25 countries world-wide.

Printed and bound in Great Britain by FPC Greenaway. Ormolu House, Crimscott Street, London SE1 5TE. www.greenaways.com

Page 3: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

iii

Table of Contents

Pharmaceutical Pricing and Reimbursement

Executive Summary 10

An introduction to price optimization 10 Pricing and reimbursement in North America 11 Pricing and reimbursement in Europe 12 Pricing and reimbursement in Japan and the rest of the world 13 Global pricing strategies 14 Lifecycle pricing strategies 15

Chapter 1 An introduction to price optimization 18

Summary 18 Introduction 19 Delivering a return on investment 19 Sustained R&D productivity shortfall 19 Impending blockbuster patent expiries 23 Healthcare cost containment 24 Cost-containment initiatives 26 Pharmaceutical spend cost containment 27 Key issues impacting on pricing 29 Pharmaceutical price optimization 29 Pricing and reimbursement regulations 30 Reference pricing 34 Pharmacoeconomic evaluations 34 Parallel imports and reimportation 35 Generic substitution 37 Global versus lifecycle pricing 38

Page 4: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

iv

Chapter 2 Pricing and reimbursement in North America 42

Summary 42 Introduction 43 US pricing regulations 43 Medicare 44 Medicaid 46 Private healthcare 47 Pharmacoeconomics 48 Generic substitution 50 Recent developments in the US 51 Medicare Part B revisions 51 Medicare Part D – one year on 52 Average manufacturer price 53 Re-importation in decline 54 Follow-on biologics 55 Reverse payments to generic companies 56 Future pricing scenarios in the US 58 Best case pricing scenario 58 Worst case pricing scenario 59 Most likely pricing scenario 60 Canadian pricing regulations 60 Federal measures 61 Provincial measures 62 Common drug review expansion 64 Patented Medicine Price Review Board progress 65

Chapter 3 Pricing and reimbursement in Europe 68

Summary 68 Introduction 69 European pricing regulations 69 French pricing regulations 70 State of the industry 71 Recent developments in France 72 Parallel trade 72 Generic substitution 72 German pricing regulations 73 State of the industry 74 Recent developments in Germany 74 The Statutory Health Insurance Competition Enhancement law 74

Page 5: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

v

Italian pricing regulations 75 State of the industry 77 Recent developments in Italy 77 Regional cost-containment 77 2007 Finance Law 78 Spanish pricing regulations 78 State of the industry 80 Recent developments in Spain 81 Regional cost-containment 81 Modified reference price system 82 Anti-parallel trade strategies 82 UK pricing regulations 83 Recent developments in the UK 84 The future of the PPRS 84 Risk sharing schemes 85 Declining parallel trade 86 Expanding the NICE remit 86 Future pricing scenarios in Europe 87 Best case pricing scenario 87 Worst case pricing scenario 88 Most likely pricing scenario 89

Chapter 4 Pricing and reimbursement in Japan and the rest of the world 92

Summary 92 Introduction 93 Japanese pricing regulations 93 Recent developments in Japan 95 Biennial price cut 95 Generic substitution introduced 97 Future pricing scenarios in Japan 97 Best case pricing scenario 98 Worst case pricing scenario 99 Most likely pricing scenario 100 Australian pricing regulations 101 Benchmark pricing 102 Cost plus method 102 Average monthly treatment cost 103 Prices for new items 103 Recent developments in Australia 104 Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme reform 104 Chinese pricing regulations 104

Page 6: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

vi

Recent developments in China 105 New drug pricing procedures 105 Price cuts 106 Generic prescribing 106

Chapter 5 Global pricing strategies 108

Summary 108 Introduction 109 Local optimization 109 Market access and reimbursement 109

Free price markets 110 Orphan drugs 111

Pharmacoeconomic evaluations 111 Global coordination 113 Launch sequence 113

EU launch order 114 Optimal price differentials 115 Implementing global pricing strategies 119

Chapter 6 Lifecycle pricing strategies 122

Summary 122 Introduction 123 Launch phase pricing considerations 123 Submission dossiers 123 Identifying key decision makers 125 Failure to secure reimbursement 126

Working with decision makers 126 Applying pressure through lobbying 127 Brokering deals 127

Patent protected phase pricing considerations 128 Case study: the respiratory market 128 Innovative pricing strategies 131 Patent expiry phase pricing considerations 132 Price changes 132

US patent expiry 133 European patent expiry 134

Case study: generic simvastatin 135 Biosimilar pricing 136 Implementing lifecycle pricing strategies 137

Page 7: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

vii

Chapter 7 Appendix 140

Glossary 140 Sources 142

Page 8: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

viii

List of Figures Figure 1.1: Declining trend in number of NDA and NME approvals, 1997-2006 21 Figure 1.2: Rise in the cost of drug development, 1975-2001 23 Figure 1.3: US patent expiries for top ten selling drugs, 2006-2011 24 Figure 1.4: Trends in healthcare spending as a proportion of GDP, 1970-2005 26 Figure 1.5: Pharmaceutical expenditure as a share of total healthcare expenditure in 2005 27 Figure 2.6: Source of prescription drug expenditures, 2005-2006 53 Figure 2.7: Canadian cross border internet pharmacy sales, 2002-2006 55 Figure 2.8: Compensatory final settlements (reverse payments), 2004-2006 57 Figure 3.9: Average ex-factory drug prices in key European markets, 2005 81 Figure 4.10: NHI price cuts by therapeutic class, 2006 96 Figure 5.11: Market share for new products launched in last five years, 2005 110 Figure 5.12: External reference pricing in Europe, 2007 117 Figure 5.13: Global pricing and the interaction between countries 118 Figure 5.14: Global pricing strategies 120 Figure 6.15: Leading respiratory drugs by global sales, 2006 129 Figure 6.16: Lifecycle pricing strategies 138

List of Tables Table 1.1: Number of NDA and NME approvals by the FDA, 1990-2006 20 Table 1.2: R&D expenditure within the US and abroad by PhRMA members, 1980-2006 22 Table 1.3: Trends in healthcare spending as a proportion of GDP, 1970-2005 (%) 25 Table 2.4: Future pricing scenarios in the US 58 Table 3.5: Future pricing scenarios in Europe 87 Table 4.6: Co-payments for drugs/services in Japan 94 Table 4.7: Classification for price premium (Japanese healthcare system) 95 Table 4.8: Future pricing scenarios in Japan 98

Page 9: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

9

Executive Summary

Page 10: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

10

Executive Summary

An introduction to price optimization

Optimizing global product prices and securing the broadest possible reimbursement

status for a product is becoming increasingly important as pharmaceutical

companies seek to generate a high return on investment from current and future

drugs in light of a sustained R&D productivity shortfall and a wave of impending

blockbuster patent expiries.

While the pharmaceutical industry faces pressure to maintain revenue and earnings

growth, healthcare providers face pressures of their own with respect to containing

increasing healthcare costs. Over the past decade, there has been significant growth

in global healthcare expenditure, with healthcare representing a growing share of

gross domestic product (GDP) in developed nations. In 2007, the Organization for

Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) published data demonstrating

that the annual increase in per capita spending on healthcare across OECD

countries has increased by more than 80% in real terms between 1990 and 2005,

compared with the 37% growth in per capita GDP growth. One in four OECD

countries now spends over 10% of GDP on healthcare.

The key issues involved with the optimization of pharmaceutical pricing begin with

developing an understanding of the explicit aims of price optimization. The key

levers of cost containment set the current price optimization climate, which

involves a proliferation of reimbursement regulations and the increasing use of

reference pricing systems.

Price optimization is also significantly affected by a number of related disciplines,

including the use of pharmacoeconomic evaluations, the impact of parallel trade

and reimportation and the pricing effects of generic substitution.

Page 11: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

11

Pricing and reimbursement in North America

Unlike the other major pharmaceutical markets, the US does not have a

government-sponsored health insurance plan that ensures access to healthcare for

the entire population. As a result, the national government does not directly

influence the prices of pharmaceuticals, but allows drug prices to be determined by

the free market.

Drug prices are influenced by competition between rival products, the market size

of the drug, the number of substitute products, the costs of R&D for new products,

and most importantly the willingness to pay demonstrated by payors.

Medicare Part D benefits were introduced by the Medicare Prescription Drug,

Improvement, and Modernization Act of 2003 and came into effect on 1st January

2006. The federal program subsidizes the costs of prescription drugs for Medicare

beneficiaries. The benefit is administered by private insurance plans that are

reimbursed by the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services.

According to CMS, nearly 24 million individuals were enrolled in Medicare Part D

drug plans as of January 2007.

Under the most likely future pricing scenario for pharmaceutical companies in the

US, the introduction of Medicare Part D will generate mixed results, including

increased access and compliance alongside future budget cuts. State-level

supplementary Medicaid rebates will be more limited in the future, while overall

government drug expenditure will remain relatively high.

Health economics will be used more frequently to justify premium prices, while

reimportation will remain limited to the private level.

Page 12: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

12

Pricing and reimbursement in Europe

The major European pharmaceutical markets operate a variety of different

healthcare systems subject to differing cost containment measures. In price-

controlled countries, such as Spain and Italy, budgetary responsibilities and

controls are devolved to the regional level. In traditional prescriber-led markets,

such as the UK and Germany, national hurdles including NICE and positive lists

have been introduced.

Historically, European regulatory authorities have taken different approaches to

controlling public drug benefits, with some focusing on limiting demand, as

evidenced by the devolved budgets found in Germany and the UK, and others on

regulating price, as is found in France, Italy and Spain. However, some countries,

including Italy and Spain, are adopting both approaches, extending greater regional

autonomy for healthcare and budget delivery.

Over the next five years, the most likely European pricing scenario will involve

continued convergence of prices across different markets, resulting from the

ongoing pressures of parallel trade and reference pricing. Average prices will tend

towards the middle of the current range, with high price markets such as the UK

and Germany lowering prices and low price markets such as France, Italy and

Spain increasing average prices, particularly for innovative therapies.

In the most likely pricing scenario the impact of pharmacoeconomics, parallel trade

and generic substitution will continue to increase gradually. These indirect cost

containment measures will continue to play an important role in managing the

healthcare spend for all European governments. The accession of 10 new countries

to the EU will have a small, but negative, effect on prices throughout the EU-15.

Reference pricing systems will be adjusted to protect against a lower average EU

price, but some reference pricing relationships will inevitably result in downward

pressure on prices.

Page 13: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

13

Pricing and reimbursement in Japan and the rest of the world

The Japanese healthcare system is characterized by high pharmaceutical

expenditure and price controls are an important part of the system. The upper limit

for pharmaceutical prices in Japan is the NHI drug price. The NHI drug price list

fixes the names and prices of drugs for which healthcare providers can be

reimbursed under Japan’s health insurance programs. The reimbursement price is

determined separately by the MHLW. All drugs included in the NHI drug price list

are fully reimbursed except for a patient co-payment.

On 1st April 2006, the Ministry of Health Labour and Welfare (MHLW) announced

a 6.7% average price cut on drugs listed on the National Health Insurance (NHI)

reimbursement list. These were the highest price cuts for six years, following

average cuts of 4.2% and 6.3% in 2004 and 2002 respectively.

Over the next five years, the most likely pricing scenario prevailing in Japan will

involve a continuation of the current reimbursement reform led by biennial price-

cutting. By weighting the cuts against generic and ‘me-too’ products, innovative

products can still continue to receive premium prices, while the overall drugs bill is

reduced.

Price setting is likely to become more complex in the Japan, with the addition of

health economic data and pro-generics regulations to the current reference pricing

system. However, the Japanese market will continue to be protected from parallel

trade. With no principle of international exhaustion in Japan, companies will

continue to prevent their products from being imported from other countries using

their trademark rights.

Page 14: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

14

Global pricing strategies

The global price perspective has two parts. The complexity of global drug prices

are a result of local differences in pricing and reimbursement systems.

Understanding these complexities and developing locally optimal pricing strategies

for key drugs is critical for maximizing the returns from pharmaceutical

investments. In addition to the local perspective, a global coordination of prices and

price-differentials between key markets is also required. The impact of external

reference price schemes and parallel trade require prices to be optimized across

markets.

Local optimization involves adapting pricing strategies to fit national-level, and in

some cases regional-level, regulations. The successful development and approval of

new drugs is not enough to guarantee market access. Countries place different

levels of ‘fourth hurdle’ barriers to receiving full reimbursement, which require

economic data to ensure a broad use at a high price. These evaluations have begun

to limit the ability of pharmaceutical companies to set prices for new drugs in

traditionally free price markets and restrict access to drugs targeted at areas of

significant unmet need.

The coordination of local pricing at the global level ensures that price differentials

that impact on external reference pricing and parallel trade or optimized. The global

price perspective involves determining appropriate launch sequences and the

optimal price differentials between country markets. However, the two processes

are inextricably linked.

Through the impact of reference pricing and parallel trade, the ability of

pharmaceutical companies to achieve premium prices in some markets can be

compromised by lower prices in others. These cross-country pressures are best

illustrated by the situation in Europe, where both reference pricing and parallel

trade have a significant impact on pricing.

Page 15: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

15

Lifecycle pricing strategies

Lifecycle pricing strategies are largely dominated by two major lifecycle events,

launch and patent expiry. Pricing at launch has the primary window for achieving

an optimal price and reimbursement coverage, while patent expiry strategies

involve maximizing brand value in competition with low-priced generics. However,

at all points in the drug lifecycle between launch and patent expiry there are key

competitive considerations that significantly impact on pricing strategies.

It is imperative that pharmaceutical companies ensure that evidence demonstrating

product value in support of the initial case for reimbursement is effectively

communicated and accounted for in the reimbursement decision-making process.

Companies must therefore identify and exploit opportunities to communicate the

value of products and influence decision-makers’ thinking.

Following the successful launch of a drug, the competitive environment can

regularly change following the launch, expansion or patent expiry of competitor

products. In response, pharmaceutical companies must be able to identify the

pricing implications associated with on-patent lifecyle events and respond

appropriately. A number of novel approaches to pricing and reimbursement have

emerged that deal with reactions by payors to initial prices a launch.

Following the loss of patent protection, the branded drug faces significant

downward pricing pressure from the introduction of generic competition. However,

a brand’s optimal retaliatory strategy differs by market, but both upward amd

downward price adjustments have been successfully applied in the past.

Page 16: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

16

Page 17: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

17

CHAPTER 1

An introduction to price optimization

Page 18: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

18

Chapter 1 An introduction to price optimization

Summary

Optimizing global product prices and securing the broadest possible reimbursement status for a product is becoming increasingly important, as pharmaceutical companies seek to generate a high return on investment from current and future drugs in light of a sustained R&D productivity shortfall and a wave of impending blockbuster patent expiries.

While the pharmaceutical industry faces pressure to maintain revenue and earnings growth, healthcare providers face pressures of their own with respect to containing increasing healthcare costs. Over the past decade, there has been significant growth in global healthcare expenditure, with healthcare representing a growing share of gross domestic product (GDP) in developed nations.

In 2007, the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) published data demonstrating that the annual increase in per capita spending on healthcare across OECD countries has increased by more than 80% in real terms between 1990 and 2005, compared with the 37% growth in per capita GDP growth. One in four OECD countries now spends over 10% of GDP on healthcare.

The key issues involved with the optimization of pharmaceutical pricing begin with developing an understanding of the explicit aims of price optimization. The key levers of cost containment set the current price optimization climate, which involves a proliferation of reimbursement regulations and the increasing use of reference pricing systems.

Price optimization is also significantly affected by a number of related disciplines, including the use of pharmacoeconomic evaluations, the impact of parallel trade and reimportation and the pricing effects of generic substitution.

Page 19: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

19

Introduction

Business Insights’ Pharmaceutical Pricing and Reimbursement Outlook report outlines

the critical importance of price optimization in the pharmaceutical industry. Navigating

a pricing and reimbursement policy through many different markets and competitive

environments is increasingly complex and difficult to coordinate. A global, product-

based view allows for consistent development and positioning efforts, but this must be

balanced against an individual country-level view accounting for the specific pricing

and reimbursement developments in each of the key markets. It is essential, therefore,

to manage the pricing function effectively by retaining a clear understanding of both

the key strategic issues surrounding pricing as well as the different pricing and

reimbursement environments found across North America, Europe and the rest of the

world.

Delivering a return on investment

Optimizing global product prices and securing the broadest possible reimbursement

status for a product is becoming increasingly important, as pharmaceutical companies

seek to generate a high return on investment from current and future drugs in light of a

sustained R&D productivity shortfall and a wave of impending blockbuster patent

expiries.

Sustained R&D productivity shortfall

The pharmaceutical industry is currently in the grips of research and development

productivity shortfall. This continued fall in R&D productivity is clearly illustrated by

examining annual Food and Drug Administration (FDA) data relating to the number of

new drug applications (NDA) and new molecular entities (NME) approved by the FDA

each year.

Page 20: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

20

Despite a wave of high innovation during the early 1990s, peaking in 1996 when 131

NDAs and 53 NMEs were approved, pharmaceutical R&D productivity has declined

on almost a year-on-year basis through to 2003. In 2004, the number of NDAs and

NMEs increased, but largely as a result of the inclusion of therapeutic biologics, which

where now to be approved through the CDER, rather than the CBER. Despite this

technical change, the number of NDAs approved annually has declined by 3 year-on-

year and NMEs by 3.1 year-on-year over the past 10 years. Table 1.1 and Figure 1.1

show the trend in the number of NDAs and NMEs approved by the FDA between 1990

and 2006.

Table 1.1: Number of NDA and NME approvals by the FDA, 1990-2006 NME approvals NDA approvals 1990 23 64 1991 30 63 1992 26 91 1993 25 70 1994 22 62 1995 28 82 1996 53 131 1997 39 121 1998 30 90 1999 35 83 2000 27 98 2001 24 66 2002 17 78 2003 21 72 2004 37 119 2005 20 80 2006 22 101

Source: FDA Business Insights

While pharmaceutical R&D productivity levels have slowed, R&D expenditures have

continued to increase. According to the industry group Pharmaceutical Research and

Manufacturers of America (PhRMA), R&D investment has increased significantly

year-on-year for the last three decades. Total pharmaceutical R&D spend has increased

from $1,977 million in 1980 to $42,974 million in 2006, representing a compound

annual growth rate (CAGR) of 12.6%..

Page 21: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

21

Figure 1.1: Declining trend in number of NDA and NME approvals, 1997-2006

Source: FDA Business Insights

Table 1.2 shows trends in R&D expenditure within the US and abroad by PhRMA

members between 1980 and 2006.

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

14019

97

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

NDAapprovals

NMEapprovals

Trend (NDAapprovals)

Trend(NMEapprovals)

Page 22: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

22

Table 1.2: R&D expenditure within the US and abroad by PhRMA members, 1980-2006

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006* US 1,594 3,379 6,803 11,874 21,364 23,502 25,655 27,065 29,556 30,969 33,968 Non-US 428 699 1,617 3,334 4,667 6,221 5,357 7,388 7,463 8,889 9,006 Total 1,977 4,078 8,402 15,208 26,031 29,723 31,012 34,453 37,018 39,858 42,974 * PhRMA estimates

Source: Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America (PhRMA) Business Insights

The overall investment required to successfully develop a new drug has also increased

over the last 20 years. In 2001, the Tufts Center for the Study of Drug Development

(CSDD) revised its estimate of the average cost to develop a new prescription drug to

$802 million. This figure was the result of a Tufts study using information obtained

directly from research-based pharmaceutical companies. Tufts performed a similar

study nearly two decades ago estimating that the average cost of a new drug developed

in 1987 was just $231 million, without adjusting for interest and inflation rates. The

$231 million figure in 1987 would be equivalent to $318 million in 2000 US dollars,

adjusted for inflation.

Figure 1.2 shows the rise in drug development costs between 1975 and 2001, expressed

in equivalent 2000 US dollars.

Page 23: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

23

Figure 1.2: Rise in the cost of drug development, 1975-2001

Source: PhRMA; DiMasi J et al. (2003) Business Insights

Impending blockbuster patent expiries

Alongside low productivity and rising R&D expenditures, the wave of pharmaceutical

innovation experienced in the 1990s is now being followed by a related wave of patent

expiries. Figure 1.3 shows the impact of US patent expiries on the top ten selling drugs

in 2006. Patent expiries will impact on five of the leading 10 pharmaceuticals by sales

in 2006, representing more than half their overall market value. Norvasc has lost patent

protection in 2007, and will be followed by Advair/ Seretide in 2008. Prevacid comes

off-patent in 2009, followed by the market leading drug, Lipitor, in 2010. Finally,

Zyprexa will lose patent protection in 2011.

$802

$318

$138$0

$100

$200

$300

$400

$500

$600

$700

$800

$900

1975 1987 2001

Exp

endi

ture

per

new

dru

g($

mill

ions

, 200

0)

Page 24: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

24

Figure 1.3: US patent expiries for top ten selling drugs, 2006-2011

On-patent drugs (2006 sales)

Source: Company financials, FDA Orange Book Business Insights

Leading pharmaceutical companies will experience a significant reduction in their

revenues associated with blockbuster products as generic competition erodes market

share. As a result, given that R&D productivity has stagnated while the cost of

developing new drugs has risen to an all time high, the pharmaceutical industry faces

considerable challenges with respect to delivering significant revenue and earnings

growth in the future.

Healthcare cost containment

While the pharmaceutical industry faces pressure to maintain revenue and earnings

growth, healthcare providers face pressures of their own with respect to containing

increasing healthcare costs. Over the past decade, there has been significant growth in

global healthcare expenditure, with healthcare representing a growing share of gross

domestic product (GDP) in developed nations. In 2007, the Organization for Economic

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

2006sales

2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

2006

glo

bal s

ales

($bn

)

Diovan

Prevacid

Zyprexa

Remicade

Enbrel

Nexium

Norvasc

Plavix

Advair/ Seretide

Lipitor

Page 25: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

25

Co-operation and Development (OECD) published data demonstrating that the annual

increase in per capita spending on healthcare across OECD countries has increased by

more than 80% in real terms between 1990 and 2005, compared with the 37% growth

in per capita GDP growth. One in four OECD countries now spends over 10% of GDP

on healthcare.

Table 1.3 and Figure 1.4 show the trends in healthcare spending as a proportion of

GDP between 1970 and 2005. Throughout this period, the US spent the highest share

of GDP on healthcare, with expenditure increasing from 11.9% of GDP in 1990 to

15.3% in 2005. Additionally, the US spends more on healthcare per capita than any

other country.

Table 1.3: Trends in healthcare spending as a proportion of GDP, 1970-2005 (%)

1970 1980 1990 1995 2000 2005 US 7.0 8.8 11.9 13.3 13.2 15.3 France 5.4 7.0 8.4 9.9 9.6 11.1 Germany 6.0 8.4 8.3 10.1 10.3 10.7 Italy - - 7.7 7.3 8.1 8.9 UK 4.5 5.6 6.0 7.0 7.3 8.3 Spain 3.5 5.3 6.5 7.4 7.2 8.2 Japan 4.6 6.5 6.0 6.9 7.7 - OECD average 5.0 - 6.9 - - 9.0

Source: OECD Health Data 2007 Business Insights

Page 26: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

26

Figure 1.4: Trends in healthcare spending as a proportion of GDP, 1970-2005

Source: OECD Health Data 2007 Business Insights

The recent growth in health expenditure has been, in part, a deliberate policy in some

countries, such as the UK and Canada, which realized that cost containment during the

mid-1990s had strained their healthcare systems. However, all governments are under

continuous pressure to reconcile economic and health concerns, with public funds

continuing to contribute the bulk of health spending in most countries.

Cost-containment initiatives

In the light of increasing budgetary pressure, many countries are seeking to restrict

growth in healthcare spending and have implemented a range of cost-containment

initiatives. Three main types of cost-containment policies have been employed:

Regulating prices, input resources and healthcare service volumes;

capping health spending;

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

US France Germany Italy UK Spain Japan OECDHeal

thca

re s

pend

as

a pr

opor

tion

of G

DP (%

)

1970 1980 1990 1995 2000 2005

Page 27: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

27

shifting costs to the private sector.

Pharmaceutical spend cost containment

Advances in medical technologies, population ageing and rising public expectations

have resulted in significant health spending growth, and particularly in the area of

pharmaceuticals. Between 1995 and 2005, spending on pharmaceuticals in the US grew

by 1.4 times the rate of total health expenditure growth. Pharmaceutical expenditure

accounted for between 12.4% and 22.9% of total health spending in the leading

pharmaceutical markets in 2005. Figure 1.5 shows the share of healthcare expenditure

generated by pharmaceutical expenditure in 2005 across the main markets.

Figure 1.5: Pharmaceutical expenditure as a share of total healthcare expenditure in 2005

Latest data for Japan is from 2004

Source: OECD Health Data 2007 Business Insights

22.9%

20.1%

19.0%

16.4%

15.2%

12.4%

Spain

Italy

Japan

France

Germany

US

Page 28: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

28

The key factors driving pharmaceutical spend growth include:

The ageing population;

the emergence of ‘life-style’ drugs;

a shift to newer and more expensive drugs;

an increase in therapeutic coverage (i.e. new drugs for diseases that previously

could not be treated).

Many governments are using the systems employed to price and reimburse

pharmaceuticals as a key component of their strategy to reduce healthcare expenditure.

This has resulted in a fundamental shift in the way in which pricing and reimbursement

decisions are made. Healthcare decision-makers have moved towards cost management

and quality assurance strategies for healthcare provision in order to find the most

efficient and effective combinations of medical care.

The current approach to healthcare provision has been accompanied by a shift towards

the inclusion of economic considerations in healthcare decision-making, and in

particular, with respect to pharmaceuticals. As a consequence, efficacy, safety and the

degree of medical need are no longer the only key product attributes with respect to

reimbursement decision-making. Economic considerations have emerged as a major

influencing factor.

While governments in major markets are being forced to adopt cost containment

strategies due to budgetary pressures, providers of private healthcare coverage are also

placing increased emphasis on economic evaluations as they strive to increase

efficiency and improve their competitiveness.

Page 29: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

29

Key issues impacting on pricing

The key issues involved with the optimization of pharmaceutical pricing begin with

developing an understanding of the explicit aims of price optimization. The key levers

of cost containment set the current price optimization climate, which involves a

proliferation of reimbursement regulations and the increasing use of reference pricing

systems. Price optimization is also significantly affected by a number of related

disciplines, including the use of pharmacoeconomic evaluations, the impact of parallel

trade and reimportation and the pricing effects of generic substitution.

Pharmaceutical price optimization

Strategic pricing in the pharmaceutical industry is a critical mechanism through which

companies attempt to maximize profitability. However, successfully obtaining a high,

reimbursed price is increasingly difficult given that pharmaceutical companies operate

in markets subject to various country-specific legislations and regulations. When

pharmaceutical companies have little or no restriction on price, which is largely true

only in the US, they can maximize profits by pricing pharmaceuticals like any other

product, subject to price-volume forecasts. Outside of the Medicare and Medicaid

programs the US government does not fund a national health insurance scheme. With

no central regulation on pharmaceutical prices, the US has the highest drug prescription

prices of the developed world and generates more than 60% of the average major

pharmaceutical company profits.

National governments outside of the US have put in place legislative and regulatory

mechanisms to restrain healthcare expenditure. Examples include the UK’s profit

control mechanisms, Germany’s budgetary ceiling for general practitioners and

reference price system, and France’s price cuts and rebates to control the costs of

health care. These pricing and reimbursement regulations distort price optimization

efforts, with pharmaceutical pricing decisions often simplified down to a negotiation

for the highest price with various reimbursement bodies.

Page 30: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

30

In the context of regulated markets, pharmaceutical price optimization primarily

involves supporting a claim to gain the highest reimbursement price. High prices

require substantive data showing that a product is safe, efficacious and that it provides

a relative therapeutic improvement on available treatments. In some markets additional

data showing a drugs pharmacoeconomic benefit is also used to help support a high

price. Notable exemptions from this rule are ‘lifestyle drugs’ used to treat conditions

such as sexual dysfunction, baldness and obesity. These drugs are considered not to

warrant a high reimbursement price and are instead often launched outside of

reimbursement in order to achieve optimal returns.

The ultimate aims of pharmaceutical price optimization are to generate sufficient

returns in order to fund continued R&D efforts and to launch and market new products.

Pharmaceutical innovation involves significant investment and risk and therefore

warrants a high level of reward. However, where pharmaceutical purchasing power is

centralized by large reimbursement bodies, including health maintenance organizations

(HMO) and national health systems, a significant share of the power to set prices is

ceded to the buyer. In light of continued cost containment pressures, pharmaceutical

manufacturers must be prepared to defend their claims for high reimbursement prices

ever more vociferously in the future.

Pricing and reimbursement regulations

The pricing and reimbursement framework for pharmaceuticals is primarily set by

individual national regulations. There are several tools used by governments, to

varying degrees, to regulate prescribing and reimbursement:

Reference pricing systems set pricing levels using a cohort of prices taken from

similar drugs or from the same drug across different national markets;

reimbursement groups determine proportional price levels up to which products are

reimbursed. For example, products for chronic and acute serious diseases are often

reimbursed to 100%, while non-life-threatening diseases are reimbursed to a lower

proportion of the actual price;

Page 31: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

31

patient co-payment levels determine the relative contributions of patients and

reimburser;

pharmaceutical spending budgets are used to force physicians to keep the cost of

their annual prescriptions below a set ceiling.

The free pricing of pharmaceutical products is considered to be an effective lever for

encouraging innovation and the overall development of the pharmaceutical industry.

The US has the closest system to a free market, where the government has no direct

control over prices. However, pharmaceutical prices of drugs are indirectly controlled

by large agencies such as the Veterans’ Administration, Medicaid retailers, chain

pharmacies, and managed care providers. Other countries have free pricing schemes for

parts of their market. For example, Germany freely prices patented products, while the

government directly influences off-patent and generic prices through a reference

pricing system.

Profit control measures limit prices indirectly by arbitrarily capping the profits made by

pharmaceutical companies, based on the capital invested into research, development,

and manufacturing. The most prominent example of profit control measures is the

Pharmaceutical Price Regulation Scheme in the UK. While this scheme is voluntary,

companies comply because the agreement effectively bars non-compliant

manufacturers from operating in the UK.

The general agreement is negotiated between the Department of Health and the

Association of the British Pharmaceutical Industry, with individual company details

negotiated directly between the Department of Health and the company concerned. The

agreement operates at the level of a pharmaceutical company’s total business with the

National Health Service (NHS), rather than in relation to individual products.

Companies within the scheme have a profit cap, measured as a return on average

historic capital employed. This means that building, plant, land and other relevant

items are valued at the time they were purchased as opposed to current prices. If

excessive profits are not reached, pharmaceutical companies can increase their prices.

Page 32: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

32

Alternatively, if profits exceed target profits, then these profits must be returned to the

government.

Direct price controls describe a situation whereby the government or payer directly

influences pharmaceutical prices. Direct price controls are country specific, and often

take into consideration the production costs of the product, including the costs of local

R&D and promotion. Governments can then determine an appropriate price through

intense negotiations, and potentially comparing the prices set in other benchmark

countries. Reference pricing is a direct price control tool currently used in a number of

markets to price drugs.

A further way to control pharmaceutical expenditure is to introduce incremental price

cuts on established reimbursement rates. Price cuts reduce the amount governments

will reimburse over a certain time period. This method is used widely across many

European markets, including France and Italy. In Japan, wide-ranging rounds of price

cuts are implemented every two years as a way of reducing pharmaceutical

expenditures.

Negative lists contain the names of pharmaceutical products that do not receive

reimbursement. This type of pricing control has been used in a number of European

countries since the 1980s and has been periodically updated and extended in those

countries. Products are added to a negative list where there are better, more effective

drugs available or where the price is set at an excessively high level. European

countries making use of negative lists include Germany, Spain and the UK.

Positive lists include products that receive some level of reimbursement. Products not

on the positive list do not receive reimbursement from healthcare providers, and

therefore the positive list is a stronger form of price control than the negative list.

Positive lists can be found in Belgium, Denmark, France, Greece, Italy, Portugal,

Spain, and Germany. In the US, there is no government organized positive list, but

Page 33: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

33

some of the most powerful pharmaceutical buyers, such as the Health Maintenance

Organizations (HMOs), operate their own versions of positive lists via formularies.

Pharmaceutical expenditure ceilings place an overall cap on pharmaceutical

expenditure within a country’s budget. This system is used to contain cost, but is very

difficult to implement and manage, with budget overspending often having no direct

consequences for the authorities. In the countries where expenditure ceilings have been

in operation, including Italy and Spain, budgets have been breached several times.

Pharmacoeconomics has emerged as a ‘fourth hurdle’ to gaining reimbursement in a

number of healthcare systems. After assessing a product’s safety, quality and efficacy

in markets such as Australia, the Canadian province of Ontario and the Netherlands,

there is a mandatory requirement by reimbursement authorities to present evidence of a

product’s cost effectiveness. Regulatory authorities and governments that use

pharmacoeconomics have adopted one of two approaches. The first is a mandatory

pharmacoeconomic assessment before a new product’s reimbursement status or price is

allocated, and the second is to use a pharmacoeconomic assessment after a product’s

launch to provide guidelines for its use.

Of all the countries operating government-led reimbursement systems, Japan and

Germany have the most generous reimbursement systems. In these countries, all

products are generally covered by the statutory health insurances and reimbursed to

100%, except for relatively low patient co-payment per prescription item. The UK

reimbursement system works in a similar way, but the criteria for placing products on

the positive list are stricter than in Japan and Germany. In France and Italy, patients

with chronic diseases receive 100% reimbursement on their prescriptions, while other

conditions have partial or no reimbursement. In Spain, outpatient prescriptions are

never fully reimbursed, except for those for retired people.

Page 34: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

34

Reference pricing

Internal and external reference pricing is being used more and more widely in markets

outside the US. Internal reference pricing of products based on the active ingredient is

becoming increasingly widespread, often in combination with the promotion of generic

substitution by pharmacists. Internal reference pricing represents an attempt by

governments to lower the price of a branded product once it loses patent protection, as

opposed to waiting for market forces to take their effect. The most important

implication for pharmaceutical companies is that pricing options following patent

expiry of a key product become more limited. Previously, branded pharmaceutical

companies could attempt to compete with generic versions of their drugs through the

strength of their brand, often maintaining a higher price for their original product.

However, under a reference pricing system based on generics this is not possible.

Drug prices are no longer priced independently in Europe and are becoming

increasingly controlled elsewhere. Price differentials between different countries are

becoming more transparent as companies increasingly operate globally, leading

governments to compare prices externally as well as internally. As countries continue

to reference each other’s prices, drug prices will continue to converge, both in Europe

and in the rest of the world.

Reference pricing affects products in different ways. When drugs are priced with

reference to similar drugs in the same market, prices tend to converge to the lower end

or middle of the price corridor. When the price of a product is compared externally

with the price of the same product in other countries, the price of the drug tends to

harmonize across the relevant markets. However, products sold in countries with strict

price control are generally still below the average EU price.

Pharmacoeconomic evaluations

Over the last decade, cost containment pressures in the healthcare industry have led to

the emergence of pharmacoeconomic and health economic evaluations, both of which

aim to determine the optimal allocation of resources within a restricted budget. For

Page 35: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

35

pharmaceutical companies, the rise of pharmacoeconomics and closely related

disciplines, such as health economics and outcomes research, has generated a need for

new processes and areas of expertise. However, pharmacoeconomic procedures are not

established to the same extent in all markets, since requirements and regulations differ

widely, making a comprehensive strategic approach difficult for pharmaceutical

companies.

The major driver of pharmacoeconomics lies in the increasingly cost-conscious

healthcare environment. This has led to a need for more effective and consistent

resource allocation within a limited healthcare budget. Resistors to pharmacoeconomic

approaches are often related to negative perceptions of the methodologies on which the

studies are based, as well as difficulties arising from integrating such studies into R&D

and drug approval processes. Although the cost of pharmacoeconomic studies is

relatively low compared to pharmaceutical R&D and marketing budgets, it is

sometimes mentioned as a potential resistor.

Parallel imports and reimportation

Parallel importing does not yet play a significant role in the two largest pharmaceutical

markets, Japan and the US. Although the US operates a general principle of complete

international exhaustion of intellectual property rights, since 1988 it has been illegal for

pharmaceutical products to be imported in bulk into the country because of the

perceived fear of low quality or counterfeit products entering the market. Japan does

not subscribe to the principle of international exhaustion, with companies able to

prevent their products from being imported from other countries using their trademark

rights.

Parallel importing has a particularly significant effect upon those pharmaceutical

markets found within the EU. With individual countries operating different degrees of

control over the prices of pharmaceutical products, price disparities remain strong

despite the free trade within the area. As a result, parallel importing has become a

Page 36: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

36

significant factor in the development of the European pharmaceutical market, affecting

company sales and related pricing strategies.

Parallel importing in Europe had its genesis in the early 1980s when pharmacists in

high priced countries, such as Germany and the UK, realized that they could increase

their profit margins by buying pharmaceutical products outside of their domestic

markets. Since then it has gradually grown into an industry sector that has a significant

impact on the pharmaceutical market within low price export markets, such as Spain,

and high cost import markets, such as Germany and the UK.

Following the creation of the European free market, a series of court cases brought by

pharmaceutical companies against importers during the 1990s has clarified the extent to

which manufacturers can prevent parallel trade impacting their own sales. To date, the

importers have won every major case and this has stimulated further development of

the sector.

The key factor in a parallel trader’s decision to import a product is the difference in

price between the source and import markets. It is this single factor that most clearly

influences the amount of profit that can be achieved by importing a drug. Although

most parallel traders are unwilling to specify the critical range for price differentials, a

margin of less than 15% is considered highly unlikely to be profitable.

In principle, it is unimportant whether an imported drug is a premium priced product

carrying a high margin for the manufacturer or a low cost, low margin drug, given that

an importer’s margin is generated entirely by the price differential. However, given the

impact of reference pricing on pricing in some European countries, a drug that is

premium priced in one or more markets is more likely to carry a high cost differential.

As a result, premium priced, high margin products can generate a high level of parallel

importing.

Page 37: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

37

Since margins can be relatively low for drug importation, drugs for diseases with large

patient populations are preferred. In addition, chronic diseases with consistent demand

for drug therapy are also highly attractive. For example, an anti-hypertensive is more

likely to be affected by parallel importing than an antibacterial, even though they may

have the same market size.

Generic substitution

Generic substitution continues to have a significant impact on the pricing of

pharmaceutical products both pre- and post-patent expiry. The ability to protect the

original product from generic substitution is largely determined by the size and market

presence of the product’s marketer. It is clear that branded pharmaceutical products

cannot compete effectively on price with generic products and, as a result, the growth

of the generics industry will continue to have a significant influence on pricing

throughout the product lifecycle.

With pricing regulations varying considerably from country to country, the effects of a

growing generics industry on pricing will be diverse. In the US’s comparatively free

market prices and pricing strategies are relatively flexible, while in more heavily

regulated European markets the potential to change prices and pricing strategies is

more limited.

For major pharmaceutical companies a large part of the battle against the destructive

effects of generic substitution is over once generics reach the market. As a result, major

pharmaceutical companies’ pricing strategies focus on maximizing pre-patent expiry

revenues and then rely upon a strong brand presence in order to retain as much market

share as possible following patent expiry.

The loss of patent protection for gold standard products in major disease markets, such

as the antidepressant Prozac (fluoxetine) and the anti-ulcerant Losec (omeprazole),

commonly has a major effect on the pricing of other patent protected products in the

same class. The key factors in determining the size of the pricing effect include the

Page 38: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

38

level of generic competition, physician awareness of generic equivalents and the

therapeutic profile of the competing proprietary products. If a competing patented

product can be reformulated to show therapeutic advantages over the generic version,

then its market share is likely to have some protection and pricing strategies will not

change significantly. However, if there is little difference between the generic gold

standard and the competing patented product, the pharmaceutical company will need to

reduce the price of its drug in an attempt to maintain volume share.

The treatment regime associated with a gold standard generic also determines the

degree to which it will affect competing branded products. For chronic conditions, such

as severe depression, where a product is likely to be prescribed for a period of several

years, competition from similar generic products will be relatively slow because

physicians are often unwilling to change a patient’s long-term treatment on the basis of

cost alone. However, patent protected drugs indicated for conditions where shorter

periods of treatment are the norm, such as bacterial infections, will experience greater

indirect competition from gold standard generics. In this situation, physicians are less

concerned with slight variations in a drug’s therapeutic profile and are more inclined to

prescribe the most cost-effective therapy.

Global versus lifecycle pricing

Pharmaceutical companies are tasked with two distinct challenges in optimizing the

price for a pharmaceutical product. At a global level, a great deal of coordination is

required in order to maximize price and reimbursement coverage across different

markets with different regulations and pricing environments. A keen local knowledge

is required in order to adapt pricing policy to the different pricing and reimbursement

systems found across key North American, European and other markets. However, a

more comprehensive global view is also required in order to mitigate against the effects

of international reference pricing schemes and potential parallel trade.

Page 39: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

39

The pricing of drugs also involves a lifecycle dimension, whereby the competitive

pricing environment changes over the lifecycle of the drug. Most work around pricing

is conducted at the approval and launch stage of the product lifecycle. However, the

data used to achieve price premiums are collected during in clinical trials carried out in

advance of receiving approval for launch. At the later stages of the product lifecycle

new competitors enter the market or go off-patent to alter the competitive pricing

environment, following by the eventual loss of patent protection for the drug itself and

the associated generic competition. Both regulatory and competitive pressures provide

a dynamic pricing journey right across the product lifecycle.

Page 40: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

40

Page 41: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

41

CHAPTER 2

Pricing and reimbursement in North America

Page 42: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

42

Chapter 2 Pricing and reimbursement in North America

Summary

Unlike the other major pharmaceutical markets, the US does not have a government-sponsored health insurance plan that ensures access to healthcare for the entire population. As a result, the national government does not directly influence the prices of pharmaceuticals, but allows drug prices to be determined by the free market.

Drug prices are influenced by competition between rival products, the market size of the drug, the number of substitute products, the costs of R&D for new products, and most importantly the willingness to pay demonstrated by payors.

Medicare Part D benefits were introduced by the Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, and Modernization Act of 2003 and came into effect on 1st January 2006. The federal program subsidizes the costs of prescription drugs for Medicare beneficiaries.

The benefit is administered by private insurance plans that are reimbursed by the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services. According to CMS, nearly 24 million individuals were enrolled in Medicare Part D drug plans as of January 2007.

Under the most likely future pricing scenario for pharmaceutical companies in the US, the introduction of Medicare Part D will generate mixed results, including increased access and compliance alongside future budget cuts.

State-level supplementary Medicaid rebates will be more limited in the future, while overall government drug expenditure will remain relatively high. Health economics will be used more frequently to justify premium prices, while reimportation will remain limited to the private level.

Page 43: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

43

Introduction

This chapter outlines the current pricing regulations impacting on the US

pharmaceutical market. Recent developments are analyzed, along with future pricing

scenarios for the next five years. A brief overview of the Canadian price and

reimbursement system is also presented.

US pricing regulations

Unlike the other major pharmaceutical markets, the US does not have a government-

sponsored health insurance plan that ensures access to healthcare for the entire

population. As a result, the national government does not directly influence the prices

of pharmaceuticals, but allows drug prices to be determined by the free market. Drug

prices are influenced by competition between rival products, the market size of the

drug, the number of substitute products, the costs of R&D for new products, and most

importantly the willingness to pay demonstrated by payors.

Although the federal government does not directly regulate drug prices, they are

influenced by other segments of the market. The US healthcare market is managed

through a number of different schemes, including private health insurance, health

maintenance organizations (HMOs), and the federal sponsored health insurance plans

for the poor and the elderly. The market is financed primarily by private health

insurance, which charge different premiums to different segments of the population

based on a range of health risk factors. A growing trend in the US is the use of HMOs.

These organizations combine an insurance company and a medical team in order to

give cost effective incentives to medical workers. The premiums paid to HMOs are

generally based on a flat rate, taking the average of low and high risk individuals.

However, low risk individuals who consider their risk to be lower than the costs of

health insurance often opt out of full insurance coverage.

Page 44: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

44

In addition to those individuals paying into private health insurance schemes and

HMOs there is also a significant part of the US population that cannot afford health

insurance. The federal government provides for the very old through Medicare and

each state manages its own healthcare insurance, Medicaid, for the very poor. As a

result, healthcare provision in the US is very diverse, and so is the coverage of

prescription drugs. The ‘out of pocket’ prices for prescription drugs vary across

individuals based on their level of health insurance coverage.

Hospital, institutional, and managed care customers usually pay well below the

manufacturer’s list price as a result of heavy discounting and negotiations between the

pharmaceutical companies and those organizations. These high discounts are

principally the result of the significant purchasing power held by these organizations.

Drugs sold directly to wholesale distributors and pharmacy chains for individual

physicians and patients are priced at the higher end of the price scale. Recently, drug

prices have become a key political issue in the US, as the price differentials within the

US and between the US and different countries have become increasingly highlighted

and discussed in the public arena.

Medicare

Medicare is a federal insurance scheme made available for people over the age of 65.

In addition to this demographic group, in some circumstances people under the age of

65 with disabilities are also covered. The scheme currently covers approximately 40

million US citizens, corresponding to around 15% of the US population.

The Medicare scheme has traditionally been divided into two main parts. Part A

provides basic cover for hospital care and certain follow-up costs, such as post-hospital

nursing. Medicare pays a certain amount of hospital costs for any period of illness,

dependent on the chosen provider, such as hospital, psychiatric clinic, nursing facility.

Page 45: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

45

Part B of the Medicare scheme covers basic medical outpatient costs, including

physician’s fees, medical tests performed on an outpatient basis, medical equipment

and supplies, such as glucose monitoring equipment and heart pacemakers, and

outpatient hospital treatment. However, most notably Medicare has not historically

covered prescription drugs given to outpatients. Many routine examinations are also

not reimbursed, resulting in the reimbursement of only around 50% of all medical bills

incurred by Medicare patients.

Medicare remained similar to its original form until 1997 when Part C,

Medicare+Choice, a Medicare plus private managed care scheme, was added to control

costs and offer expanded benefits, most notably, prescription drug coverage. To fill

some of the gaps in Medicare’s insurance coverage, patients have the option to join

Medigap, a private health insurance scheme that works in conjunction with Medicare.

Following the Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, and Modernization Act of

2003, Medicare+Choice plans became known as Medicare Advantage plans, which can

also offer Part D coverage.

Medicare Part D benefits were introduced by the Medicare Prescription Drug,

Improvement, and Modernization Act of 2003 and came into effect on 1st January

2006. The federal program subsidizes the costs of prescription drugs for Medicare

beneficiaries. The benefit is administered by private insurance plans that are

reimbursed by the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services. According to CMS,

nearly 24 million individuals were enrolled in Medicare Part D drug plans as of

January 2007.

Beneficiaries most enroll in one of two types of private plan. Prescription Drug Plans

(PDP) provide drug coverage only, while a Medicare Advantage plan (MA) covers

both medical services and prescription drugs. The drug plans control drug costs

through tiered formularies whereby lower cost drugs are assigned to lower tiers to

make prescribing easier. In 2007, the standard benefit includes a $265 deductible, a

25% co-payment and a coverage limit of $2,400.

Page 46: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

46

Part D drug coverage does not have an established formulary but excludes drugs not

approved by the Food and Drug Administration (FDA), drugs not used for approved

indications and drugs covered under Parts A or B of Medicare.

Medicaid

Medicaid is a public health insurance program put in place in 1965 for individuals and

families with low-income and also acts as an additional insurance program for low-

income elderly and disabled Medicare beneficiaries.

Medicaid is overseen at the federal level and is administered on a state-by-state basis.

As such, benefits vary widely between states. Under federal guidelines, each state has

autonomy over standards of eligibility, scope, type and amount of services, payment

rates for services and overall program administration. However, changes made to state

guidelines require federal approval. Therefore, in reality there are in excess of 50

Medicaid programs, with each state, the District of Columbia and other US territories

operate their programs differently.

The flexibility built into the Medicaid system allows states to provide optional services.

The provision of prescription drugs is one such service and currently 50 states and the

District of Columbia have opted to include this benefit. Under federal requirements

Medicaid covers all prescription drugs deemed to be medically necessary and there is

no exclusion solely on the basis of cost. The maximum reimbursement for classes of

drugs is set at the federal level.

The states and the federal government share responsibility for funding Medicaid with

the federal government matching state spending. The federal matching rate varies by

state and is determined by a formula based on income per capita in each state. The

federal contribution varies from 50–76% with the US average close to 60%. Medicaid

represents a significant proportion of federal and states spending.

Page 47: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

47

Medicaid spending growth declined for the first time in 2006, with a 0.2% fall largely

the result of Medicare Part D drug benefits shifting the coverage of prescription drugs

for dual eligibles from Medicaid to Medicare. Enrollment growth was also down in

2006 as a result of an improving economy and state efforts to control program growth.

Pharmaceutical companies also price drugs for government organizations such as the

Medicaid program and the Veterans Administration on a negotiated discount basis. The

Medicaid Drug Rebate Program, created by the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act

(OBRA) of 1990, requires a drug manufacturer to enter into and have in effect a

national rebate agreement with the Secretary of the Department of Health and Human

Services for States. This agreement allows the drug manufacturer to receive federal

funding for outpatient drugs dispensed to Medicaid patients. The drug rebate program

is administered by Health Care Financing Administration’s (HCFA) Center for

Medicaid and State Operations (CMSO). In 1992, this law was amended by the

Veterans Health Care Act, which requires a drug manufacturer to enter into discount

pricing agreements with the Department of Veterans Affairs in order to have its drugs

covered by Medicaid.

Private healthcare

Managed care is a cost containment system that has arisen in the US over the last three

decades as a response to high growth in healthcare expenditure. Managed care

organizations (MCO) now cover upwards of 95% of employer-insured Americans.

Managed care plans seek to manage the costs, access and quality of the healthcare

services provided for their members. Health expenditures are controlled through the

central management of a range of services for large numbers of enrolled patients.

However, criticisms relating to the decreased quality of care caused by such programs

are often leveled by patient groups and healthcare providers. As part of ongoing cost-

containment efforts, MCOs restrict patients’ choices of primary care physicians and

specialists and limit the number of reimbursed medical procedures.

Page 48: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

48

Within the fragmented private healthcare insurance landscape, HMOs are the most

common type of MCO. HMOs fix prices in advance of treatment, set up formulary lists

of reimbursable drugs and collaborate with pharmacy benefit managers to offer the

most cost-effective treatments available. For limited access to specialist services,

HMOs often either contract with or directly employ physicians and other healthcare

providers.

According to the Pharmaceutical Care Management Association (PCMA), more than

80% of all prescriptions dispensed in the US annually are paid through a prescription

benefit plan administered by a pharmacy benefit manager (PBM). PBMs offer

employers and health insurer plans cost savings by organizing large networks

combining the purchasing power of their participants. With 95% of all US retail

pharmacies included in PBM networks, PBMs leverage their purchasing power to

secure rebates from manufacturers and discounts from retail pharmacies. PBMs

manage prescription benefit plans through contracting directly with health plans,

HMOs, managed care groups, employers, insurance companies, unions, Medicare and

Medicaid managed care plans, and government entities at the local, state and federal

levels.

Pharmacoeconomics

There have been no significant regulatory developments in the use of

pharmacoeconomics by either the public or private bodies that provide healthcare in the

US. However, considerable cost containment pressures on formularies make

pharmacoeconomics a supporting tool for price negotiations with both private and

public insurers.

The Healthcare Financing Authority (HCFA) is a US government organization that,

through Medicare and Medicaid, funds healthcare for the elderly and those with low

incomes. The HCFA establishes policies for paying healthcare providers, assesses the

effectiveness of different methods of healthcare management, treatment and financing

and takes actions to guarantee a certain level of quality care. However, at present, the

Page 49: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

49

HCFA has no formal mechanisms for evaluating the cost-effectiveness of a

pharmaceutical product or for using pharmacoeconomic studies to support

reimbursement decisions.

Private healthcare providers in the US attempt to contain costs by issuing restricted

formularies of reimbursable drugs. These formularies also give private healthcare

providers some leverage over the prices set by pharmaceutical companies, as the

generation of successful sales for a pharmaceutical product will require formulary

inclusion. The use of pharmacoeconomics continues to be limited within the private

market in the US, both amongst MCOs and HMOs. There is no explicit inclusion of

pharmacoeconomic criteria to aid reimbursement-related formulary decisions. For

example, one of the largest MCOs, Blue Cross/Blue Shield, generally allows FDA

approved drugs to be reimbursed based on the single criterion of clinical efficacy.

In October 2000, in an attempt to standardize the content of formulary submissions, the

Academy for Managed Care Pharmacy (AMCP) published a set of guidelines entitled

“Format for Formulary Submissions”. While only guidance, since publication, adoption

of the AMCP Format by health systems and the pharmaceutical industry has exceeded

AMCP’s expectations. Over the past five years, a network has developed among health

systems stimulating initial adoption by managed healthcare systems and PBMs and

most recently by hospitals, integrated healthcare systems, state Medicaid agencies and

the Department of Defense. As adoption of the Format has spread, manufacturers have

begun to standardize the framework within which they present formulary submissions.

Traditionally, formulary decisions have been made on the basis of efficacy, safety and

acquisition cost of pharmaceutical products. However, now the additional hurdle of

demonstrating value for money has been introduced. Products failing to meet these

standards will either appear low down on the treatment list or will be made available

only at full price. Certain drug classes for life-threatening diseases, such as cancer and

HIV, will be exempt from this practice.

Page 50: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

50

The highly fragmented nature of the market for pharmaceutical products in the US,

together with the limited role of pharmacoeconomic analysis in formulary evaluations,

has prevented the emergence of national guidelines for information and analysis to

support formulary submissions. For guidelines to have any significant effect on the

reimbursement process in the US, they would have to be enforced by MCOs and

HMOs as well as by Medicare and Medicaid.

It is likely that the growing emphasis on cost containment within formulary decisions

will see cost-effectiveness been used more frequently in the US. The nature of

competition prevailing throughout the US healthcare market will promote the

differentiation of products through cost-effectiveness and, therefore, this factor may

help determine reimbursement decisions.

Generic substitution

The Waxman-Hatch Act, which dates back to 1984, is an integral part of FDA

regulations and its influence on prescription drug pricing and development makes the

US a particularly attractive market for generic products. The Act is designed to

encourage generics manufacturers to launch products as soon as possible after a

branded product has lost patent protection. The Roche/ Bolar provision of the

Waxman-Hatch Act of 1984 allows generics companies to develop versions of patent

protected products (i.e. run production and laboratory tests) while the patent is still in

force. Furthermore, Waxman-Hatch permits generics manufacturers to view the

original drug developer’s safety and efficacy data filed at the FDA as part of the

regulatory approval process. After this, generics companies can submit an abbreviated

new drug application (ANDA) to the FDA, together with proof of bioequivalence.

Finally, a 180-day exclusivity period is granted to a generics manufacturer that

successfully challenged a brand patent’s validity (a paragraph IV litigation). In return

for these privileges and to reward and encourage innovation, brand manufacturers may

be entitled to additional patent protection from generic competition:

Five years of additional market exclusivity may be granted for new active

ingredients;

Page 51: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

51

three years of additional exclusivity may be granted for a new drug application

(NDA) if another NDA with the same active ingredient has previously been

approved and certain other conditions are met;

three years of additional exclusivity may be granted for an NDA supplement.

According to IMS Health, generic medicines accounted for 63% of all prescriptions

dispensed in the United States amounting to sales of $54.1 billion. 8,730 of the 11,487

drugs listed in the FDA’s Orange book have generic counterparts. On average, generics

cost 30-80% less than their reference brands. According to The National Association of

Chain Drug Stores, the average retail price of a generic prescription drug was $32.23 in

2006, compared with an average price of $111.02 brand name drugs.

Recent developments in the US

Medicare Part B revisions

The Medicare Modernization Act included significant changes to the reimbursement

for Part B drugs as well as introducing Part D drug benefits. On 1st January 2005 the

reimbursement of Part B drugs changed from 85% of average wholesale price (AWP)

to 106% of the average selling price (ASP), excluding best price exempt purchases

such as Medicaid and the Veterans’ Associations (VA). By taking away the margin

payment system the changes are directed at reducing overpayments caused by

inappropriate physician utilization incentives.

Part B drug reimbursement was also affected by the introduction of a Competitive

Acquisition Program (CAP) intended to further remove physicians’ financial interest

from drug selection. CAP empowers third party intermediaries to acquire drugs and

biologics on a competitive basis resulting in lower prices and mitigated risk to

physicians associated with drug access. However, how the CAP system will play is

difficult to foresee as it is not clear physicians are giving up on managing drug

acquisition despite the ASP plus 6% basis on which reimbursement is established.

Page 52: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

52

Medicare Part D – one year on

Despite much controversy and skepticism when Medicare Part D plans were initially

outlined, the first year experience of the drug plan seems largely positive. Uptake for

the voluntary drug benefit has approached 90% with very high satisfaction levels. Over

the same period, drug prescription costs for beneficiaries have more than halved, which

in turn has helped to improve overall compliance rates for chronic disorders.

However, with drug costs continuing to rise – healthcare is set to increase from 16% to

20% of GDP in the US over the next ten years – significant pressure is building on

Medicare drug prices. House bill ‘HR 4: Medicare Prescription Drug Price Negotiation

Act of 2007’ is looking to replace private plan price negotiations with direct

government intervention for Part D drugs. While direct price negotiation might not

prove to be the most effective way of limiting drug prices, the increase in the

government’s share of overall drug expenditures looks likely to result in significant

pressure on prices. The figure below shows the increase in the government’s share of

expenditures on drug prescriptions between 2005 and 2006, increasing from 24% to

41% largely as a result of Part D drug benefit uptake.

Page 53: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

53

Figure 2.6: Source of prescription drug expenditures, 2005-2006

Source: CMS, Office of the Actuary, National Health Statistics, 2005 Business Insights

Average manufacturer price

Modifications to Medicaid payments for prescription drugs set to come into force on 1st

October 2007 have been published by the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services

(CMS). As well as being used as the basis for determining manufacturers’ Medicaid

rebates, the average manufacturer price (AMP) can also now be used by states to set

reimbursement limits and by the CMS to set Federal Upper Limits (FUL) for

multisource products. The AMP is the average unit price paid by wholesalers for drugs

distributed through retail pharmacies.

The CMS has also outlined a more consistent definition as to how AMPs are

calculated. Retail pharmacy sales will exclude those sales to pharmacy benefit

managers (PBM) and all third party payers. Prompt payment discounts routinely

offered to wholesalers will also be excluded. Sales to mail-order pharmacies will now

by included, along with the sales of authorized generics to wholesalers.

28%

9%

4%

4%

47%

39%

29%20%

2%

18%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

2005 2006

Sou

rce

of p

resc

riptio

n dr

ug s

pend Out-of-pocket

Private insurance

Other public spending

Medicaid

Medicare

24%

41%

Page 54: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

54

Another key change is the intention of the CMS to make AMPs publicly available.

Monthly updates on AMPs will replace quarterly updates with the previously

considered proprietary information now disclosed on the internet.

Re-importation in decline

Given its impact on reducing the burden of healthcare costs, re-importation from

Canada continues to generate significant interest at the political level in the US. Bulk

reimportation of products into the US continues to be prohibited in the US and, despite

importation legislations being included in the currently proposed legislation (the

Pharmaceutical Market Access and Drug Safety Act of 2007), the ban is likely to

continue for the foreseeable future.

Recent trends have also shown a decline in the level of personal importation occurring

in the US. As shown in Figure 2.7, Canadian cross border internet pharmacy sales have

been in decline since 2004, largely as a result of changes in relative exchange rates.

However, continued decline in 2006 was also aided by the introduction of Medicare

Part D drug benefits, which provide seniors (the most prolific reimporters) with

comprehensive coverage, but does not cover purchases from sources outside the US.

Page 55: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

55

Figure 2.7: Canadian cross border internet pharmacy sales, 2002-2006

Source: Neil Turner, RTI Health Solutions based on IMS Health data Business Insights

Follow-on biologics

Momentum has finally begun to build in the US, looking to move closer to initiating a

regulatory framework for the approval of biosimilars (follow-on biologics). In February

2007, a bill was introduced to amend the public health service act (PHSA) authorizing

the Secretary of Health and Human Services to approve abbreviated applications for

products deemed ‘comparable’ to approved, reference biological products in the same

way in which small molecule generics are approved. It must be demonstrated that ‘no

clinically meaningful differences’ exist between an original product and a comparable

biological with respect to safety and effectiveness. In addition to comparability, the two

products must also share the same mechanism of action, route of administration, dosage

form and strength.

The bill also provides the opportunity for biosimilar manufacturers to demonstrate

‘interchangeability’, which requires both proof of comparability and an expectation to

581.9 593.1

420.1

211.2252.0

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

Cros

s bo

rder

sal

es (C

an$

mill

ion)

Page 56: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

56

produce the same clinical results in any given patient. As with the burden of

comparability, the required studies are at the discretion of the Secretary, and are likely

to be assigned on a case-by-case basis. The first applicant to receive interchangeability

status would gain a period of market exclusivity up to 180 days post-marketing. The

bill would prohibit the marketing of a rebranded interchangeable product by the

reference product holder during the exclusive marketing period.

It is clear that the difficulty of demonstrating comparability and interchangeability for

biosimilars, coupled with complexity of the patent situation for biologics will continue

to limit the ability of legislators to map out satisfactory approval frameworks.

However, with significant price pressures in the US beginning to focus on the high cost

of biologics, and with effective biosimilar regulations beginning to rolled out across

Europe, Australia and elsewhere, some progress in expediting the approval if

biosimilars in the US is inevitable in the short to medium term.

Reverse payments to generic companies

Reverse payments, or exclusion payment settlements, refer to agreements made

between brand and generic companies resulting in the abandonment or delay of

marketing for a new generic product. Reverse payments made in compensation to a

generic company as part of patent litigation settlements include payments for

intellectual property to the brand, an agreement by the brand not compete with an

authorized generic, payments for co-promoting the branded drug and co-development

payments relating to collaborative R&D projects.

The number of final settlement agreements involving compensation paid to the generics

company has increased significantly over the past three years. As shown in Figure 2.8,

according to Federal Trade Commission (FTC) figures, the number of compensatory

settlements has increased from five in 2004 to 14 in 2006.

Page 57: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

57

Figure 2.8: Compensatory final settlements (reverse payments), 2004-2006

Source: Federal Trade Commission Business Insights

The recent increase in reverse payments follows the Eleventh Circuit Appeals court

decision in March 2005 upholding the legality of such agreements, following a long-

running legal case brought by the FTC against earlier settlements involving the heart

drug, K-Dur 20, between Schering-Plough and the generic manufacturers, Upsher-

Smith Laboratories and ESI Lederle. However, concerns that such practices are

restricting patient access to cheaper generic products have resulted in the introduction

of the ‘Preserve Access to Affordable Generics Act’ bill, which expressly prohibits

brand name drug manufacturers from pay-off agreements to keep generics from

entering the market. However, the high cost of entering into long running patent

litigation battles with big pharma companies with deep pockets may instead result in a

reduction of initial patent challenges should patent litigation payoffs be restricted,

which may result in reduced rather than expanded access to low-priced generics.

42

91

1

5

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

2004 2005 2006

Fiscal year (October - September)

Num

ber

of a

gree

men

ts

Reverse payments forother generic applicants

Reverse payments tofirst-filers

Page 58: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

58

Future pricing scenarios in the US

In a continually changing pricing environment, it can be difficult to predict future

pricing scenarios. However, for the purposes of planning and forecasting, three

alternative pricing scenarios in the US are presented below. The scenarios are based on

a five year outlook and include a best case, worst case and most likely scenario.

Scenarios are presented from the perspective of the pharmaceutical company aiming to

achieve the highest price possible and the broadest coverage for its products.

Table 2.4: Future pricing scenarios in the US Best case Worst case Most likely Wider access and compliance Medicare Part D results in Mixed results from Medicare through Medicare funding, lower prices, limited access bill, including wider access/ while maintaining high prices and budget cuts elsewhere compliance and budget cuts Limited state-level cost cutting Cost containment limits State-level rebate interventions while Medicare and Medicaid Medicaid expenditure, while are limited, while government expenditure increases individual states negotiate expenditure remains high additional rebates Re-enforced protection from Health economics used to justify Canadian reimportation and PBM use of health economics, premium prices, reimportation slow development of generics reimportation legislation and limited to private-level and and biogeneric regulations biogeneric equivalent ANDAs generic competition unchanged

Source: Delphi Pharma Business Insights

Best case pricing scenario

Under the best case pricing scenario for pharmaceutical companies in the US, the 2003

Medicare Prescription Drug Act and the introduction of Medicare Part D drug plans

would lead to wider access, improved compliance and increased utilization. Prices for

effective drugs would remain high while volumes would increase in line with the

widened coverage. The reduced pressure from lobbying seniors means that drug prices

for chronic diseases associated with old age remain high into the future.

A best case pricing scenario would also involve a cut-back on state-level activity

involving the negotiating of supplemental rebates for Medicaid. Rebate schemes would

Page 59: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

59

be limited to the handful of states already running such schemes, such as Maine and

Florida, and would not be extended nationwide. Federal level and high court-level

intervention would limit state-rebates. Meanwhile, the overall increase in combined

Medicare and Medicaid spending remains high with budget relief coming from other

cuts in federal level funds.

Finally, a best case scenario would involve re-enforced protection from Canadian

reimportation. Legislative plans will be shelved and state-level importation programs

will be successfully challenged in the courts and limited though limitations in supply.

Generic legislation will continue unchanged, but pharma companies will work harder

to challenge generic entry and limit uptake through line extensions and reformulations.

Biogeneric regulations will be enforced requiring submission of full trial data for

follow-up copy products.

Worst case pricing scenario

Under a worst case pricing scenario, the pharmaceutical industry in the US would be

hard hit by the results of the government’s $400 billion Medicare bill. The results of

the extended coverage would be slow in generating further increased usage, while

quick in generating cost containment cuts across Medicare and other government-level

drug benefit schemes.

In a worse case pricing scenario Medicaid expenditure would be severely limited in the

future in order to reverse 10 years of continued growth. The result would be significant

rebates and limited formulary lists for Medicaid drug plans. At the same time, more

states would sign on to individual supplemental rebate schemes, generating significant

rebates on a company-by-company basis.

Finally, in a worse case scenario, PBMs would make a wider use of pharmacoeconomic

evaluations in line with AMCP guidelines. Reimportation legislation would come into

force, allowing the free trade of products from Canada by licensed wholesalers. At the

same time regulations would be established allowing biogeneric copy products to

Page 60: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

60

submit ANDA-type submissions based on bioequivalence and requiring no additional

studies.

Most likely pricing scenario

Over the next five years, the most likely pricing scenario in the US will involve mixed

results from the recent Medicare drug plan. Returns from widened access appear

positive, while increases in government funded drug prescriptions are likely to result in

some degree of negative influence on prices.

In the most likely pricing scenario state-level rebate interventions already in place will

continue, but will not escalate to a wider number of states. Cost containment at the

state level will continue but will maintain Medicaid budgets at their current levels.

Budgets will still be overallocated, but Medicaid expenditure will be given high

priority and remain high.

Finally, in a most likely scenario health economic evaluations will only be used on a

voluntary basis for pharmaceutical companies to justify high prices for premium

products. Canadian reimportation will continue to be limited to personal use and state-

level programs, with no consensus reached at the legislative level. Generic competition

will continue unchanged, striking a balance between the protection of innovative

product returns and maximizing access to effective medicines, with no significant

progress in definitive biosimilar legislation.

Canadian pricing regulations

Health care provision in Canada is primarily funded by the federal government, with

the majority of healthcare free at the point of use, The federal government pays transfer

payments to each province, which in turn manage the delivery of health care. The

Canada Health Act sets out the regulatory framework within which Canadian provinces

administer the majority of health care services. However, the Act only covers

Page 61: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

61

medications prescribed as part of institutional care. All other aspects of pharmaceutical

policy are left to individual provincial health care ministries. A wide variation exists

across provinces in the way in which medicines are financed.

Public funding is used primarily to subsidize drug costs for the elderly and those

receiving social assistance. As a result, the share of total pharmaceutical expenditure

accounted for by public expenditure is significantly lower in Canada compared with

other developed countries. Each of the provinces subsidizes the cost of prescription

medicines for some part of the population through their provincial drug benefit

programs. The vast majority of Canadians also have some form of private coverage for

prescription medicines.

Federal measures

The patented medicines price review board (PMPRB) is an independent body created

by Parliament in 1987 to protect consumer interests and contribute to Canadian health

care by ensuring manufacturers do not charge excessive prices. The PMPRB reports

directly to Parliament through the Minister of Health.

The PMPRB is responsible for regulating the prices of patented prescription and non-

prescription products. If the Board finds that an ex-manufacturing price is excessive it

may order the patentee to reduce the price and take measures to offset any excessive

revenues received. The PMPRB has no authority to regulate the prices of non-patented

drugs, including generic drugs sold under compulsory licenses, and does not have

jurisdiction over prices charged by wholesalers or pharmacists.

Section 85(1) of the 1987 Patent Act sets out those factors that the PMPRB must take

into account when determining whether a medicine is being sold at an excessive price.

These factors include:

The prices at which the medicine has been sold in the relevant market;

the prices of other medicines in the same therapeutic class;

Page 62: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

62

the prices of the medicine and of the other medicines in other countries;

changes in the Consumer Price Index;

such other factors as may be specified by regulations.

The ‘reasonable relationship test’ considers the association between the strength and

the price of the same medication in the same or comparable dosage forms. The test

defines a maximum non-excessive introductory price for the new drug.

The ‘therapeutic class comparison test’ compares the price of the new drug under

review with the prices of drugs that are clinically equivalent and are sold in the same

market at prices that the PMPRB considers not to be excessive.

The ‘international price comparison test’ compares the average transaction price of the

drug under review with the publicly available ex-manufacturing prices of the same

medicine sold in other countries, including Germany, France, Italy, Sweden,

Switzerland, the UK and the US.

Government-led measures have recently looked to ease access to generics. Changes to

intellectual property regulations have been proposed to speed up the market entry of

generic drugs, while at the same time encouraging the continued research and

development of innovative new drugs. Generic manufacturers have welcomed the

regulations limiting the practice of ‘evergreening’, which in the past has allowed brand

manufacturers to file new patents on a product towards the end of the original patent’s

life, with the purpose of delaying generic competition.

Provincial measures

The provincial drug benefit programs differ in the subsection of the population they

assist. The provinces of Alberta, British Columbia, Quebec, Manitoba and

Saskatchewan offer universal coverage. In Ontario, the Tillium Drug Plan is available

Page 63: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

63

to those not covered by the Ontario Drug Benefit Plan, providing they meet the income

requirements.

Large variations exist in employee benefit plans, both in terms of the services covered

and the amount of coverage. Typically, the terms of coverage and contributions are

arrived at through negotiations between individual employers and insurance

companies. Each provincial drug plan, except BC’s Pharmacare, employs a formulary

to set out the drugs available for reimbursement. If a drug is not included on a

formulary, the drug plan will reimburse only the cost of a therapeutically equivalent

product.

In British Columbia, a reference pricing system was introduced in 1996 by the

provinces Pharmacare drug benefit program. In this system drugs which are used to

treat the same clinical conditions are assigned to the same reference class. Patients are

reimbursed at the price of the lowest cost drug within a reference class. Patients

prescribed higher priced products have the option to pay above the reference price, or

to ask for a cheaper drug. Reference pricing has also been introduced in the province of

New Brunswick, with a system similar to that of the system used in British Columbia.

Each province employs a committee which reviews drug submissions to determine if a

product can be placed on the formulary of the drug benefits list of approved

medications.

Each provincial drug benefit program includes cost sharing or user fees policies.

Beneficiaries are required to make a financial contribution towards the price of the

medicines they acquire. These policies are able to reduce overall costs, but do not

necessarily lead to increased use of lower cost medicines.

Generic medicine prices are established in provincial formulary pricing policies.

Across the country, the average discount in price associated with purchasing a generic

versus an originator drug is estimated at 50%. In Ontario, it has been determined since

Page 64: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

64

1994 that the first generic product on the market must be 25% cheaper than the original

brand, and subsequent generic entrants must be priced a further 10% lower.

All provincial drug benefit plans have prescribing guidelines and formularies that favor

generic medicines. Additional policies to encourage the prescribing of generics by

physicians includes instruction and encouragement during medical education to use

generic drug names and prescribe generic medicines.

Each province in Canada mandates generic substitution to some extent. The methods

used are to either regulate substitution by pharmacists as mandatory, or to cover only

the low cost alternative or reference-based price in the reimbursement conditions of the

provincial plan. In the provinces of Alberta, British Columbia, and Quebec the latter

system is in place.

Common drug review expansion

Since its introduction in 2003, the Common Drug Review (CDR) has been restricted to

clinical and cost-effectiveness reviews of new molecular entities and combination

products. However, from the end of 2007 the CDR will begin to review all new

indications for already approved drugs. Reviews for new indications will now be

centralized in order to provide a single, consistent process for receiving inclusion on

the formularies of all federal, provincial and territorial drug plans.

If the centralized CDR approach was to replace the need for public drug plans’

independent reviews then new indications should receive a more efficient route to

market access. However, it appears likely that a certain amount of independent re-

assessment at the public drug plan level will persist resulting in the CDR becoming an

additional, rather than alternative, hurdle for gaining market access in new indications.

An additional hurdle represented by the current CDR process is the failure of the cost-

effectiveness process to capture the value of drugs for significant unmet needs. A

number of orphan drugs, including Somavert for acromegaly, Xolair for chronic asthma

Page 65: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

65

and Sensipar for chronic kidney disease, are approved widely in the US and across

Europe, but have failed to pass the CDR cost-effectiveness hurdle. There is growing

pressure to remove this group of drugs from the remit of the CDR process, as is the

case for cancer biologics, and more recently oral oncology drugs for ambulatory use.

Patented Medicine Price Review Board progress

The Patented Medicine Price Review Board (PMPRB) is tasked with the role of

ensuring ex-factory prices for patented drugs are not excessive. As part of its work a

series of Excessive Price Guidelines were published for advanced consultation in 2006.

These guidelines included limiting prices for most new patent drugs to the equivalent

highest cost of therapy for existing drugs to treat the same disease, while the prices of

breakthrough new patented drugs will generally be limited to the median prices for the

drug found in France, Germany, Italy, Sweden, Switzerland, the UK and the US.

Annual price increases were also limited by links to the consumer price index.

Eight Voluntary Compliance Undertakings (VCU) were initiated in 2005 by

manufacturers found not to be in compliance with the PMPRB’s guidelines. These

commitments to reduce prices in line with the guidelines were given for Janssen-

Ortho’s Evra, 7/7/7 and Risperdal, for GlaxoSmithKline’s Paxil CR, for Hoffman-La

Roche’s Tamiflu, for Amersham Health’s Ceretec, for Novartis’s Starlix and for Sanofi

Pasteur’s Dukoral. Pending hearings to determine non-compliance for 2006 include

Shire’s Adderall XR, Janssen-Ortho’s Risperdal Consta, 3M’s Airomir and Teva’s

Copaxone.

Page 66: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

66

Page 67: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

67

CHAPTER 3

Pricing and reimbursement in Europe

Page 68: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

68

Chapter 3 Pricing and reimbursement in Europe

Summary

The major European pharmaceutical markets operate a variety of different healthcare systems subject to differing cost containment measures. In price-controlled countries, such as Spain and Italy, budgetary responsibilities and controls are devolved to the regional level. In traditional prescriber-led markets, such as the UK and Germany, national hurdles including NICE and positive lists have been introduced.

Historically, European regulatory authorities have taken different approaches to controlling public drug benefits, with some focusing on limiting demand, as evidenced by the devolved budgets found in Germany and the UK, and others on regulating price, as is found in France, Italy and Spain. However, some countries, including Italy and Spain, are adopting both approaches, extending greater regional autonomy for healthcare and budget delivery.

Over the next five years, the most likely European pricing scenario will involve continued convergence of prices across different markets, resulting from the ongoing pressures of parallel trade and reference pricing. Average prices will tend towards the middle of the current range, with high price markets such as the UK and Germany lowering prices and low price markets such as France, Italy and Spain increasing average prices, particularly for innovative therapies.

In the most likely pricing scenario the impact of pharmacoeconomics, parallel trade and generic substitution will continue to increase gradually. These indirect cost containment measures will continue to play an important role in managing the healthcare spend for all European governments. The accession of 10 new countries to the EU will have a small, but negative, effect on prices throughout the EU-15. Reference pricing systems will be adjusted to protect against a lower average EU price, but some reference pricing relationships will inevitably result in downward pressure on prices.

Page 69: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

69

Introduction

This chapter outlines the current pricing regulations impacting on the key European

pharmaceutical markets. The different regulations underpinning the French, German,

Italian, Spanish and UK markets are presented in detail. Recent developments are also

analyzed, along with future pricing scenarios for the next five years.

European pricing regulations

The major European pharmaceutical markets operate a variety of different healthcare

systems subject to differing cost containment measures. In price-controlled countries,

such as Spain and Italy, budgetary responsibilities and controls are devolved to the

regional level. In traditional prescriber-led markets, such as the UK and Germany,

national hurdles including NICE and positive lists have been introduced.

Historically, European regulatory authorities have taken different approaches to

controlling public drug benefits, with some focusing on limiting demand, as evidenced

by the devolved budgets found in Germany and the UK, and others on regulating price,

as is found in France, Italy and Spain. However, some countries, including Italy and

Spain, are adopting both approaches, extending greater regional autonomy for

healthcare and budget delivery.

Economic evaluations are increasingly being used by decision-makers as part of the

pricing and reimbursement process. Most of the major pharmaceutical markets now

either require mandatory submission of economic evaluations by pharmaceutical

companies or will use economic evaluations to some degree in decision-making.

Adoption has occurred rapidly over the past five years and there is a shift towards the

adoption of mandatory requirements.

Page 70: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

70

In Europe, three of the five major pharmaceutical markets employ external reference

pricing systems. France, Italy and Spain reference the prices of drugs in other European

markets in order to arrive at a weighted price for reimbursement. Along with parallel

trade, international reference pricing reinforces the links between key European

markets, whereby prices in one market can directly affect price and sales in another

market.

French pricing regulations

The French statutory health insurance system has close to universal coverage of the

country’s population. Individuals are enrolled into an insurance fund based on their

occupational status. Approximately 90% of the French population are voluntary

members of supplementary sickness funds or subscribe to private health insurance.

To gain reimbursement, drugs must be registered on the list of reimbursable drugs with

costs covered for members of the social security scheme (liste Sécurité Sociale et

Collectivités). To achieve registration, drugs are assessed by the Transparency

Commission. Whereas approval is based on efficacy, tolerance and safety of use, the

Transparency Commission assesses the medical benefit delivered by the new drug.

Technical dossiers, which manufacturers must submit to the Transparency

Commission, contain a wide range of details:

Product characteristics (classification, pharmacology);

epidemiology of the disease;

comparator products;

recommendation of a therapeutic strategy;

analysis of clinical trial results (safety and efficacy);

sales estimates by target population.

Page 71: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

71

Drugs are also assessed in the context of the ‘Amelioration du Service Medical Rendu’

(ASMR). The ASMR is a scale that evaluates the level of medical service delivered by

a drug. In applying the ASMR, the Commission considers the added therapeutic value

that the proposed drug would offer to the French healthcare system. The medical

benefit offered by a new drug is then compared with that of existing therapies.

The Transparency Commission then forms an opinion as to whether a drug should be

added to the list of drugs that are reimbursable under the national health system, and at

which particular reimbursement rate. Depending on the results of these assessments,

reimbursement can range from 35% to 100% of a product’s cost. The Transparency

Commission then passes its opinions onto the Economic Committee for Health

Products (Comité des Produits de Santé, CEPS), which has final responsible for setting

the product’s price.

The drug’s manufacturer must submit a separate dossier to the CEPS containing

information regarding any economic evaluations that have been carried out and any

comparisons of cost with other products. As part of its assessment, the CEPS may

consult with an advisory group of experts in pharmacoeconomic evaluations. The

CEPS will then engage in negotiations with manufacturers, which ultimately result in

agreement over the product’s pricing.

Over recent years, the French authorities have sought to increase the role of economic

evaluations in pricing and reimbursement decisions for new drugs. Submission of

economic evaluations is not mandatory, but pharmaceutical companies are advised that

submission is good practice and as such economic evaluations are a regular component

of submissions.

State of the industry

In 2006 total reimbursed medicine sales increased by just 1.8% to €22.9 billion

according to the French pricing committee, Comité Economique des Produits de Santé

(CEPS). The slow down in sales growth was in part the result of several cost

Page 72: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

72

containment measures initiated in 2005-2006. Price cuts on off-patent medicines

affecting 19-20% of the market by value resulted in a reduction of €450 million, while

delisting drugs of ‘insufficient medical benefit’ resulted in further savings of €320

million.

Sales of generics through retail pharmacies rose 11.5% to €1.6 billion in 2006, largely

as a result of a number of high price drugs entering the off-patent market. Hospital

sector drug sales increased by 7% to €4.8 billion in 2006, with around half of all sales

relating to drugs on the retrocession list.

Recent developments in France

Parallel trade

France’s first parallel import licenses were approved in early 2007, 33 years after the

Netherlands granted its first licenses. While French drug price levels do not offer the

same opportunities to parallel importers as those found in Germany and the UK, a

number of companies, including Pharma Lab and Mediwin UK, are now beginning to

ship drugs to the French market. Initial imports are set to include AstraZeneca’s

Arimidex (anastrozole) from Spain and the UK, Servier’s Coversyl (perindopril) from

Spain and Takeda’s Ogast (lansoprazole) from Portugal.

Generic substitution

An agreement between the three main pharmacists’ associations and the National

Union of Health Insurers (UNCAM) set the national generic substitution rate target at

75% for 2007. The target rate involves drugs on the substitution list (repertoire des

medicaments génériques) and will remain at 75% through to 2011. A total of 30 active

ingredients were issued with separate substitution targets in 2007.

Page 73: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

73

German pricing regulations

Germany’s statutory healthcare system covers 90% of the population and is financed

by payroll and general taxes (80%) coupled with a contribution (20%) from private

insurance and patient co-payments.

The state health system covers approximately 80% of prescription drug costs. In

general, the reimbursement rate for most prescription pharmaceuticals runs at 100%.

Patients typically pay a small fee per dispensed pack of between four to five euros. For

some products, patient have to pay the difference between a fixed price (Festbetrag) set

by the government and the actual price. However, pharmaceutical companies tend to

set prices below this level.

Historically, the pharmaceutical industry has enjoyed a relatively free pricing system in

Germany leading to some of the highest pharmaceutical prices outside of the US. A

reference system has been in place since 1989, and primarily covers older genericized

drugs. The German association responsible for setting the reference prices, the Federal

Committee of Physicians and Sickness Insurance Funds (BAK) considers the following

factors when deciding on a pricing reference group:

Whether the indication for a product is actually a disease;

whether the disease must be treated by the Statutory Health Insurance Scheme

(GKV);

if the disease is to be treated under the GKV, whether there already are drugs

available to do this;

whether the disease can be treated equally well with simple, non-pharmacological

methods;

how the cost-effectiveness of the different options compare.

Page 74: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

74

State of the industry

Out-of-hospital pharmaceutical sales in Germany increased by 16.8% to €25.3 billion

in 2005, according to the annual drug prescription report (Arzneiverordnungs). The

growth has been generated by a 3.6% increase in the total number of prescriptions

alongside a continued shift towards the prescription of innovative, more expensive

drugs. Drug spend accounted for 16.5% of total statutory healthcare insurance

expenditure in 2005, compared with 15.6% in 2004.

Recent developments in Germany

The Statutory Health Insurance Competition Enhancement law

A new healthcare reform law in Germany, the Statutory Health Insurance Competition

Enhancement law (GKV-WSG) came into effect on 1st April 2007. A key element of

the reform is the centralization of healthcare funding from 2009 in order to promote

efficiencies across Germany’s 242 statutory health insurers. The centralized health

fund (Geshundheitsfonds) will be financed through employee and employer

contributions and through the tax system. As of 2009, private health insurers must also

offer a basic rate package comparable to those of the statutory health insurers.

A number of pharmaceutical sector changes also accompany the healthcare funding

reforms outlined in the GKV-WSG. A major reform is the introduction of cost-benefit

assessment for new, already approved drugs. These assessments will be carried out by

the Institute for Quality and Economic Efficiency within the Health Service. While

reimbursement decisions will be carried out in advance of any cost-benefit assessment,

a negative result can result in statutory health insurers imposing a maximum

reimbursement price for drugs not included in the reference pricing system.

GKV-WSG also reformed the generic substitution regulations. Agreements between

statutory health insurers and pharmacies now require a pharmacist to dispense versions

of the prescribed drug falling under a discount agreement, unless a doctor prohibits

Page 75: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

75

generic substitution. As of August 2007, around 200 statutory health insurers had

agreed discount deals with over 50 generic manufacturers according to the ABDA

pharmacists’ association.

Italian pricing regulations

The pricing of drugs in Italy is controlled through the Central Pricing Agency

(Comitato Interministeriale per la Programmazione Economica, CIPE). For new drugs,

pricing negotiations take into account a number of factors, including:

The degree of innovation;

the product’s price in other countries;

sales estimates;

epidemiology;

the target population for the drug;

the number of patients expected to take the drug;

comparator products;

relationship to other therapies;

improvements in quality of life;

any available pharmacoeconomic data.

Within the Italian reimbursement system, prices are set using the average European

price as a guide for each product. Prices are set according to the average for equivalent

products in 12 EU benchmark countries, of which at least four are mandatory and two

have to be price controlled. Failure by manufacturers to bring the price of a product in

Page 76: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

76

line with the European average results in an immediate delisting from the fully

reimbursed Class A to the non-reimbursed Class C.

Prescription pharmaceuticals are grouped into four reimbursement categories:

Category A – Fully reimbursed and including drugs for chronic diseases. Patients

often have to pay a fixed price depending on the number and type of items

prescribed;

Category B – Partially reimbursed and including “important” drugs not covered by

category “A”. For these, 50% of the price is reimbursed by the state (this category

was removed in January 2003);

Category C – Non-reimbursed products and manufactures are free to set prices for

this category;

Category H – Hospital only drugs.

The assignment of a product to a reimbursement category is based on the importance of

the disease, the drug’s risk-benefit profile (safety versus efficacy) and the cost of

therapy. While economic evaluations are formally required for the negotiation of

prices, reimbursement decisions look only at the cost of therapy in relation to the

national drug expenditure budget.

The Italian Group for Pharmacoeconomic Studies (GISF) provides guidelines for use in

agreeing prices for products approved through the EU centralized and mutual

recognition procedures. Apart from these guidelines, CIPE regulations detail the

pharmacoeconomic methodology to be used to derive the required cost-effectiveness

data for submissions. These studies are particularly important for innovative products

in new classes, or in classes where existing therapies are not adequate or where the

product is claimed to have a better cost-benefit profile than products available for the

same indication.

Page 77: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

77

State of the industry

According to the Italian pharmacy association, Federfarma, pharmaceutical expenditure

in Italy increased by just 4% in 2006 to €12.3 billion. The number of prescription

dispensed increased by 5.8% between 2005 and 2006. Price cuts introduced by the

Medicines Agency (AIFA) in July and October of 2006 where the main causes of the

slowdown in drug sales growth.

Recent developments in Italy

Regional cost-containment

Committed to clearing their healthcare budget deficits by 2009, the regions with the

most serious deficits have begun implementing a series of new cost-containment

measures. Liguria, Lazio and Calabria will introduce therapeutic reference pricing

policies that operate in addition to the national reference price system. The main

change to therapeutic prices in these regions will be the limitation of full

reimbursement for generic lansoprazole in the proton pump inhibitors class.

Other regional cost-containment measures include a restriction on multiple

prescriptions and a requirement to prescribe generics where appropriate and available

in Calabria. Lazio is set to extend the direct distribution of drugs to include interferon

and antibiotics, while Sicily will introduce a temporary co-payment system based on

drug price.

The Italian pharmaceutical industry association (Farmaindustria) and the Italian

Medicines Agency (AIFI) are opposed to additional regional fragmentation in

healthcare services. Both groups are concerned that regional reference pricing and cost-

containment measures will lead to different levels of access to drugs and healthcare

across regions.

Page 78: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

78

2007 Finance Law

The 2007 Finance Law set the public healthcare budget at €96.0 billion in 2007,

including a further €2 billion to cover the 2006 healthcare budget deficit. Medicines

Agency (AIFA) cost containment measures already in place were reconfirmed,

including 5% price cuts, 0.6% manufacturers’ discounts, and selected price reductions

up to 10%. These measures are anticipated to save over €2 billion during 2007.

Manufacturers have been offered a payback option in order to avoid the 5% price cuts

scheduled for October 2007. New updated diagnostic and therapeutic guidelines will

also be introduced along with electronic prescribing, enabling the Health Ministry to

more closely control and monitor drug use and consumption levels.

Spanish pricing regulations

Spanish pharmaceutical prices are set by the Interministerial Commission of

Pharmaceutical Prices. Spain operates a ‘cost plus’ pricing system where maximum

drug prices are based on the costs incurred by the drug’s manufacturer (R&D,

manufacturing and marketing and administration) plus a premium. The maximum

return on each product is limited to between 12% and 18% over capital employed with

the exact percentage determined by level of innovation and the availability of

therapeutic equivalents and their prices. In addition, European price comparisons and

the potential volume and value of sales are also taken into account. Tight control of

pricing has traditionally kept Spanish prices well below those prevailing in other major

European markets.

Reimbursement decisions are undertaken by the National Committee for Rational Use

of Medicines and are largely based upon the following factors:

Importance of the disease;

priorities of different population groups;

therapeutic and social utility of the drug;

Page 79: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

79

budget limitations;

availability of similar or better alternatives at a lower price or lower treatment cost.

The Spanish reimbursement system uses three different reimbursement levels:

Drugs in class R include chronic diseases, such as diabetes, hypertension, HIV or

depression, which are reimbursed at a level of 90%;

drugs in group N are reimbursed to a level of 60%;

remaining drugs are not reimbursed at all.

Retired people receive all drugs in groups R and N free of charge. However, in 2001

the Health Minister, Celia Villalobos, re-opened a debate looking at reviewing

reimbursement for the elderly. The government considered changing the current system

so that pensioners would pay 10% of the price of medicines, with the other 90% being

reimbursed by the state. This would be used as a ‘deterrent measure’ to combat fraud

and over purchasing.

During the late 1990s, Spain’s healthcare and pharmaceutical policy has been

concerned primarily with cost containment. In recent years Spain has experienced an

annual growth in public prescription drug spending in the order of 10% and there is

concern that the public reimbursement system, which is regarded as one of the most

generous in Europe, is unsustainable. Spain has traditionally used a wide range of

unconnected pharmaceutical policies influencing the supplier side of the market in

order to drive its cost-containment efforts. These include:

Negative lists of excluded drugs;

rebates;

reference pricing (introduced December 2000);

price cuts;

Page 80: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

80

pharmacy discounts;

encouragement of generic substitution;

international price comparisons.

Historically, the system has had little positive impact on prescription drug spend and

has been criticized for being unfocused and ultimately exhibiting a lack of control.

State of the industry

The Spanish pharmaceutical industry association (Farmaindustria) reported that the

Spanish pharmaceutical sales increased by 7.3% to €12.2 billion in 2006. Retail

prescription pharmacy sales increased by just 6.7% to €8.9 billion in 2006, feeling the

effects of a 2% across the board price cut imposed in 2006. Generics represented just

6.1% of total prescription drug sales in 2006, with new generic products accounting for

75% of all new drug launches in 2006.

The weighted average drug price for all drugs marketed in Spain was €7.91 in 2006.

European prices continue to harmonize, but as shown in Figure 3.9, average drug prices

in Spain continue to be almost half those found in Europe’s biggest pharmaceutical

market, Germany.

Page 81: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

81

Figure 3.9: Average ex-factory drug prices in key European markets, 2005

Source: Farmaindustria Business Insights

Recent developments in Spain

Regional cost-containment

Following decentralization of the Spanish healthcare system in 2002, the regions have

become increasingly active in initiating demand-side measures to reduce healthcare

expenditures. Prescribing budgets in Andalucia involve rewards for physicians if INN

prescriptions (non-proprietary name prescriptions facilitating generic substitution)

account for over 60% of total prescriptions. Andalucia, Cataluna and Pais Vasco have

joined together to form the Joint Committee for the Evaluation of New Medicines

aimed at sharing data on perceived benefits for new drugs.

Maximum reimbursement prices below those in place at the national level have

historically been used as an effective cost containment mechanism at the regional level.

14.91

12.06 11.60

6.44 6.447.70

11.38

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

German

y

Netherlan

ds

Belgium UK

Spain

Italy

France

Aver

age

ex-fa

ctor

y dr

ug p

rice,

200

5 (€

)

Page 82: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

82

However, the implementation of the modified reference price system in March 2007

has led to regional maximum price reimbursement schemes been withdrawn. The new

reference price system involves substitution based on an identical product at the

cheapest price and not the second or third generic in a reference group used by regional

maximum price schemes.

Modified reference price system

A modified reference pricing system come into force in March 2007. The reference

price system, which dates back to 2000, now covers a total of 4,237 drug presentations

applicable to 119 active ingredients. Products continue to be grouped by active

ingredient and route of administration with each group containing at least one generic

version.

The reference price level will continue to be based on the arithmetic mean of the daily

treatment cost of the three cheapest drugs regardless of market share. However, there is

no longer the requirement for selected drugs to be produced by different companies.

Other changes include the pricing of off-patent drugs for which no identical

substitutable generic is marketed at or below the reference price level.

As was previously the case, prescriptions will be dispensed as written if the drug is

priced at or below the reference price. If a drug’s price is higher than the reference

price the pharmacist must dispense the cheapest identical product. Drugs, such as

insulins, coagulation factors and cardiac glucosides, that are difficult to substitute will

now be excluded from the reference price system.

Anti-parallel trade strategies

Dual pricing in Spain, whereby pharmaceuticals are priced differently depending on

whether they are distributed and dispensed in Spain or not, was first introduced by

GlaxoSmithKline (GSK) in 1998 and by government regulations in 1999. However, the

European Commission’s ruling that GSK’s actions were uncompetitive led to the

scheme being abandoned before reinstatement following the 2006 European Union’s

Page 83: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

83

Court of First Instance ruling partially annulling the earlier decision. In October 2006,

Janssen-Cilag announced its intention to initiate a dual price system for its products,

followed by Merck, Sharp & Dohme’s decision in February 2007 to apply a dual price

system to 14 key drugs including Cozaar (losartan) and Zocor (simvastatin).

Another strategy to limit parallel exports from the Spanish market is direct distribution.

Early intentions by Pfizer to initiate direct distribution in 2005 were replaced by a new

national distribution agreement and dual price contracts for which Pfizer is now

currently under investigation relating to anticompetitive behavior similar to GSK

above. However, since July 2006, Eli Lilly has directly distributed Zyprexa Velotab

(olanzapine) to retail pharmacies in order to limit supply shortages of the drug resulting

from exportation. The government is currently considering several options to help

improve the traceability of drugs through the distribution to both help limit parallel

exportation, but also to limit the unilateral efforts applied by leading drug

manufacturers in the areas of dual pricing and direct distribution.

UK pricing regulations

The National Health Service (NHS) is a statutory health system with total coverage of

UK residents. The Department of Health (DoH), overseen by the Secretary of State for

Health, is responsible for health services in the UK.

The majority of drugs sold in the UK are reimbursed under the NHS at a price

determined by the manufacturer. However, while the UK operates a system relatively

free of direct price controls, prices of prescription drugs are controlled in an indirect

manner by the Pharmaceutical Price Regulation Scheme (PPRS). The scheme

represents an agreement between government and the pharmaceutical industry that

controls the profit that pharmaceutical companies are able to make through their

trading with the NHS. The explicit aim of the scheme has been to balance the

conflicting needs of the NHS with the needs of the research-based pharmaceutical

industry.

Page 84: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

84

In January 2005, a revised 5-year PPRS came into force. The new PPRS restricts the

profit (or return on capital) that manufacturers can make on sales of medicines to the

NHS to 21% of a company’s total NHS sales. The headline news was a 7% price cut on

the NHS list price of all PPRS-covered medicines from 1 January 2005. However, as a

five-year deal it was considered to offer the industry some degree of stability for

ongoing R&D investments.

Aside from the price cut, the biggest change to the PPRS agreement is the allowances

that companies can claim against their sales to the NHS, which have been modernized

to reflect recent changes to the structure of the NHS. The R&D allowance has been

raised to a maximum of 28% under the new PPRS, compared with 23% under the old

agreement. The R&D allowance is seen as a way of countering the price cut and

helping to promote a strong R&D-based industry in the UK.

Drugs prescribed on the NHS are fully reimbursed with the exception of a fixed patient

charge per prescription item. The names of drugs that cannot be prescribed on the NHS

are kept on the limited list, which has been extended periodically since its introduction.

Recent developments in the UK

The future of the PPRS

In 2007, the Office of Fair Trading (OFT) published the results of its investigation into

the impact of the Pharmaceutical Price Regulation Scheme’s (PPRS) most recent

revision in 2005. The results were critical of the PPRS’s ability to meet its key

objectives:

Securing NHS medicines at reasonable prices;

promoting a strong and profitable pharmaceutical industry;

Page 85: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

85

encouraging the efficient and competitive supply of current and future medicines to

the UK and elsewhere.

The OFT determined that £500 million of 2005 drug expenditures could have been

saved by the NHS through more cost-effective prescribing. The OFT recommended the

replacement of current profit and price controls with a value-based pricing system,

linking a drug’s price to its clinical and therapeutic value as can be found in Canada,

Australia and Sweden.

Despite continued support from the pharmaceutical industry for the current PPRS

scheme, it seems inevitable that the PPRS will be overhauled. However, the

introduction of value-based pricing will be complex and as a result is likely to be

introduced in incremental phases. Certainly, the current PPRS appears likely to remain

largely intact through to its completion at the end of 2009.

Risk sharing schemes

In February 2002, the Department of Health (DoH) formed an agreement with four

leading manufacturers of Multiple Sclerosis (MS) drugs to support the provision of MS

drugs through the National Health Service (NHS). Despite a negative opinion for the

use of beta interferons and glatiramer acetate in the long-term treatment of MS given

by the National Institute for Clinical Excellence (NICE), significant pressure from

patient groups resulted in a payment by results risk sharing scheme. In essence the

scheme involves a commitment by the four manufacturers to reduce prices if their MS

drugs fail to meet agreed cost effectiveness benchmarks over time.

A second risk sharing scheme was recommended by NICE in June 2007, involving

Janssen-Cilag’s (J&J) cancer drug, Velcade (bortezomib). The proposed refund

guarantee scheme followed the failure of NICE to recommend Velcade for routine use

in the NHS determining that the drug failed to meet its usual cost-effective thresholds.

Under the proposed payment by results agreement the NHS would receive a refund for

the cost of providing the product to patients who do not respond positively within four

Page 86: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

86

cycles of treatment. From the perspective of J&J the scheme would allow UK market

access while protecting its UK list price, which would shield from any effects on price

in countries that currently reference UK prices.

Declining parallel trade

After being the largest market by volume of parallel trade for some time, recent

declines in parallel imports to the UK have resulted in it being overtaken by the

German market. The trend is largely a result of the 2005 Pharmaceutical Price

Regulation Scheme (PPRS) which included modulation provisions allowing

manufacturers to move prices up and down in order to maximize sales. Many

companies chose to use the provision to help mitigate against the arbitrage opportunity

for parallel traders and reduce the level of parallel imports for key products.

Further measures in the UK that are likely to result in a restriction on parallel import

opportunities are current trends towards direct distribution systems. Pfizer established a

direct distribution system in March 2007 in an attempt to limit the risk of counterfeit

products entering the supply chain, with other large companies are likely to follow suit.

However, direct distribution will also result in a block both on parallel imports and

exports to and from the UK.

Expanding the NICE remit

At the end of 2006, it was announced that the National Institute for Health and Clinical

Excellence’s (NICE) remit would be expanded to look at the use of ineffective

technologies currently on the market. This will result in recommendations that certain

ineffective technologies should be withdrawn from use, while other technologies would

be replaced by more appropriate approaches.

Page 87: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

87

Future pricing scenarios in Europe

In a continually changing pricing environment, it can be difficult to predict future

pricing scenarios. However, for the purposes of planning and forecasting three

alternative pricing scenarios in Europe are presented below. The scenarios are based on

a five year outlook and include a best case, worst case and most likely scenario.

Scenarios are presented from the perspective of the pharmaceutical company aiming to

achieve the highest price possible with the broadest reimbursement coverage for its

products.

Table 3.5: Future pricing scenarios in Europe Best case Worst case Most likely Continued reference pricing Continued reference pricing Continued reference pricing and and parallel trade results in a and parallel trade result in a parallel trade result in some convergence of European convergence of European convergence of European prices prices at the high end of the prices at the low end of the at the middle of the current current range current range range, but with some differences No significant increase in the A significant increase in the A gradual increase in the impact of health economics, impact of health economics impact of health economics, parallel trade and generic parallel trade and generic parallel trade and generic substitution substitution substitution Limited negative exposure to Significant exposure to Gradual negative exposure to low reference prices in EU low reference prices in EU low reference prices in EU accession countries accession countries accession countries

Source: Delphi Pharma Business Insights

Best case pricing scenario

In a best case pricing scenario, European prices will converge at the high end of the

current range as result of successful protection strategies against the pressures of

parallel trade and reference pricing. European prices would be maximized through

protecting the high prices currently achieved in the UK and Germany and raising the

lower prices prevailing in France, Italy and Spain. While some convergence of prices

appears inevitable, achieving a high average price will rely on the support of

Page 88: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

88

governments in low price countries, which is unlikely given continued cost-

containment measures.

Where cost containment concentrates on older and generic products, the opportunity

for achieving high prices in support of innovative and effective treatments will remain.

Even in light of the high cost of healthcare provision, most governments continue to

recognize the need for an incentives mechanism for innovative new therapies. In a best

case pricing scenario current levels of generic substitution and use of health economics

will prevail across European markets. Governments, such as the UK, are unlikely to

reverse pro-generics or pharmacoeconomics regulations, but similar legislation will not

be enforced in new markets, or extended in established ones.

In a best case pricing scenario the accession of 10 new countries to the EU will not

have any significant effect on prices throughout the EU-15. Reference pricing systems

will be adjusted to protect against a lower average EU price, and current measures

protecting against parallel imports and generic substitution will be extended.

Worst case pricing scenario

In a worst case pricing scenario, European prices will converge at the low end of the

current range as companies fail to protect against the pressures of parallel trade and

reference pricing. If pharmaceutical companies were unable to initiate adequate

protection strategies against parallel trade and reference pricing, European prices

would be minimized through eventual price reductions in high price markets such as

Germany and the UK. While some convergence of prices appears inevitable, without

the continued support of governments in high price countries average European prices

will decline to levels similar to those found in low price countries.

In a worst case pricing scenario, government reimbursement bodies across Europe will

continue to implement wide-ranging cost containment measures. The prices of all

pharmaceuticals, including old, generic and innovative new therapies, will be cut and

reimbursement access will be limited. Governments may begin to compromise the need

Page 89: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

89

for R&D incentives in order to achieve the significant reductions in healthcare costs

needed to provide continued coverage. In a worst case pricing scenario current levels of

generic substitution and use of health economics will be increased across all European

markets. Governments, such as the UK, that already implement pro-generics or

pharmacoeconomics regulations will extend their regulations, while those markets

without such regulations will implement new ones.

In a worst case pricing scenario the accession of 10 new countries to the EU will have a

negative effect on prices throughout the EU-15. Reference pricing systems will be

affected by a lower average EU price, and parallel imports and generic substitution will

be increased.

Most likely pricing scenario

Over the next five years, the most likely European pricing scenario will involve

continued convergence of prices across different markets, resulting from the ongoing

pressures of parallel trade and reference pricing. Average prices will tend towards the

middle of the current range, with high price markets such as the UK and Germany

lowering prices and low price markets such as France, Italy and Spain increasing

average prices, particularly for innovative therapies. However, the availability of some

protection against the effects of parallel trade and reference pricing will result in some

continued price differentials between markets.

In the most likely pricing scenario the impact of pharmacoeconomics, parallel trade and

generic substitution will continue to increase gradually. These indirect cost

containment measures will continue to play an important role in managing the

healthcare spend for all European governments. The speed of uptake for these measures

will continue to be tempered by general objection from the pharmaceutical industry,

but inevitably the objectives of governments and the patient will carry greater weight

than the financial aims of pharmaceutical companies.

Page 90: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

90

In a most likely case pricing scenario the accession of 10 new countries to the EU will

have a small, but negative, effect on prices throughout the EU-15. Reference pricing

systems will be adjusted to protect against a lower average EU price, but some

reference pricing relationships will inevitably result in downward pressure on prices.

Current measures protecting against parallel imports and generic substitution will be

extended, but general levels of activity will eventually be increased by the inclusion of

the new low-cost accession markets.

Page 91: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

91

CHAPTER 4

Pricing and reimbursement in Japan and the rest of the

world

Page 92: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

92

Chapter 4 Pricing and reimbursement in Japan and the rest of the world

Summary

The Japanese healthcare system is characterized by high pharmaceutical expenditure and price controls are an important part of the system. The upper limit for pharmaceutical prices in Japan is the NHI drug price. The NHI drug price list fixes the names and prices of drugs for which healthcare providers can be reimbursed under Japan’s health insurance programs. The reimbursement price is determined separately by the MHLW. All drugs included in the NHI drug price list are fully reimbursed except for a patient co-payment.

On 1st April 2006, the Ministry of Health Labour and Welfare (MHLW) announced a 6.7% average price cut on drugs listed on the National Health Insurance (NHI) reimbursement list. These were the highest price cuts for six years, following average cuts of 4.2% and 6.3% in 2004 and 2002 respectively.

Over the next five years, the most likely pricing scenario prevailing in Japan will involve a continuation of the current reimbursement reform led by biennial price-cutting. By weighting the cuts against generic and ‘me-too’ products, innovative products can still continue to receive premium prices, while the overall drugs bill is reduced.

Price setting is likely to become more complex in the Japan, with the addition of health economic data and pro-generics regulations to the current reference pricing system. However, the Japanese market will continue to be protected from parallel trade. With no principle of international exhaustion in Japan, companies will continue to prevent their products from being imported from other countries using their trademark rights.

Page 93: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

93

Introduction

This chapter outlines the current pricing regulations impacting on the Japanese

pharmaceutical market. Recent developments are analyzed, along with future pricing

scenarios for the next five years. A brief overview of the Australian and Chinese price

and reimbursement systems are also presented.

Japanese pricing regulations

Japan operates a mandatory National Health Insurance (NHI) system covering the

entire Japanese population. Healthcare is financed by insurance premiums paid by

those enrolled in the country’s various health insurance schemes (employee health

insurance scheme, mutual aid associations and a health program for the elderly). The

Ministry of Health, Labor and Welfare (MHLW) manages pharmaceutical regulatory

affairs in Japan.

The Japanese healthcare system is characterized by high pharmaceutical expenditure

and price controls are an important part of the system. The upper limit for

pharmaceutical prices in Japan is the NHI drug price. The NHI drug price list fixes the

names and prices of drugs for which healthcare providers can be reimbursed under

Japan’s health insurance programs. The reimbursement price is determined separately

by the MHLW. All drugs included in the NHI drug price list are fully reimbursed

except for a patient co-payment. The level of patient co-payment is determined by

patients’ occupation and can range from less than 10% for an elderly inpatient to a 30%

contribution by agricultural workers and the self-employed.

Page 94: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

94

Table 4.6: Co-payments for drugs/services in Japan Occupational status Level of co-payment per drug/service Agricultural workers/Self-employed 30% Employees 20% Family members of employees (Outpatient) 30% Family members of employees (Inpatient) 20% Elderly (Outpatient) 10% (different methods in hospitals and clinics) Elderly (Inpatient) 10% (maximum; varies by income level)

Source: Japan Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Association Business Insights

The NHI price indicates the level at which health insurers will reimburse hospitals,

clinics and pharmacies for drugs dispensed to patients. Hospitals and clinics are able to

negotiate discounts from the manufacturer or wholesaler but can still claim full

reimbursement at the NHI listed price. The price discrepancy is known as yakkasa and

can be kept by the prescribing party. This practice has been a significant driver of

prescribing rates.

The MHW has tried to counteract the effects of yakkasa by encouraging bungyo.

Bungyo is the separation of the prescribing and dispensing functions, which used to be

carried out by hospitals under the Japanese medical system. Because yakkasa is

decreasing, Bungyo pharmacies are a growing feature of the Japanese market.

However, the reforms are not welcomed by, among others, hospitals or clinics, since

these specifically have to sacrifice the profits associated with yakkasa.

New chemical entities (NCEs) are added to the NHI drug price lists four times a year

and comparator drugs are used to determine prices. Drugs for comparison are selected

based on therapeutic category. The price of the new drug is based on the comparator’s

price with additional premiums being added based on the level of innovation,

usefulness and market size. The Drug Pricing Organization (DPO), established in 2000,

acts as an advisory body with the role of providing a secondary opinion on the price of

drugs.

Page 95: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

95

Table 4.7: Classification for price premium (Japanese healthcare system) Classification based on usefulness Premium Innovative Standard 40%, range 20–60% Useful (I) Standard 10%, range 5–15% Useful (II) Standard 3%, range 1.5–4.5% Classification based on market size Premium Designated as orphan and pharmacologically new Standard 10%, range 5–15% Small market and pharmacologically new Standard 3%

Source: Japan Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Association Business Insights

Price cuts are a commonly used cost-containment tool in Japan and the MHLW revises

drug prices every two years. This has the effect of closing the gap between NHI drug

prices and market prices. Drug prices may also be changed following a review of

changes in market size, indications, dosage and administration. This is known as

'repricing'.

The price of generic drugs is listed annually. The initial price of a generic drug is set at

70% (previously 80%) of the price of the brand name drug. However, if other generics

are already out in the market, the price of the new generic drug is the price of the

cheapest existing generic drug. If there are 20 or more existing generic drugs, the new

generic drug will be priced 10% lower than the cheapest existing drug.

Recent developments in Japan

Biennial price cut

On 1st April 2006, the Ministry of Health Labour and Welfare (MHLW) announced a

6.7% average price cut on drugs listed on the National Health Insurance (NHI)

reimbursement list. These were the highest price cuts for six years, following average

cuts of 4.2% and 6.3% in 2004 and 2002 respectively. As shown in Figure 4.10, hardest

hit by the price cuts were the anti-ulcerants, with an average price cut of 10.5%, closely

Page 96: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

96

followed by anti-hyperlipidemics and anti-bacterials. These classes represent areas with

limited class innovation, characterized by a high degree of off-patent and ‘me-too’ drug

availability.

Figure 4.10: NHI price cuts by therapeutic class, 2006

Source: Pharma Japan Business Insights

The pricing of generic changed slightly in 2006, with the first generic entrant price

capped at 0.7 times (rather than 0.8 times) the NHI price of the reference branded

product. Subsequent generic entries are priced at the lowest price among existing

generics and 0.9 times that level once 20 different generics have been introduced.

Average price cut

10.5%

9.1%

8.9%

8.2%

8.0%

8.0%

7.9%

7.5%

7.0%

6.8%

6.7%

6.3%

6.2%

5.4%

5.0%

4.7%

Anti-ulcerants

Anti-hypertensives

Agents for gram-positive and negative bacteria

Synthetic antibacterials

Other anti-allergy drugs

Vitamins A and D

Anti-hypertensives

Vasodilative agents

Antipyretic, analgesic, anti-inf lammatory agents

Antiarrythmics

Average NHI price cut

Other cardiovascular agents

Spasmolytics

Metabolic drugs

Vitamin B

Kampo (traditional) medicines

Page 97: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

97

Other changes involved improvements to the price incentives for new innovative drugs.

The premium for innovativeness increased from 40-100% to 50-100% in 2006.

Premiums for usefulness were also increased, along with the introduction of a premium

for pediatric drugs.

Generic substitution introduced

Generic substation was introduced in Japan on 1st April 2006. Pharmacists are now

permitted to substitute a prescribed branded product with a generic with permission

from the prescribing doctor. Financial incentives provide the basis for promoting

generic substitution. Pharmacists receive 20 Yen for dispensing a generic and 100 Yen

if written information about the product is also provided. Physicians also receive 20

Yen if they prescribe a generic or mark the ‘generic substitution allowed’ box on the

prescription.

In efforts to further expand the availability of generic alternatives for generic

substitution the government is also set to introduce an obligation for manufacturers that

supply a given drug to provide all available strengths of the National Health Insurance

(NHI)-listed branded product. All new generics approved and NHI-listed from 1st April

2006 are required to comply with the rule from 1st April 2008. Manufacturers of older

generics will have until 31st March 2012 to comply.

Future pricing scenarios in Japan

In a continually changing pricing environment, it can be difficult to predict future

pricing scenarios. However, for the purposes of planning and forecasting three

alternative pricing scenarios in Japan are presented below. The scenarios are based on a

five year outlook and include a best case, worst case and most likely scenario.

Scenarios are presented from the perspective of the pharmaceutical company aiming to

achieve the highest price possible with the broadest reimbursement coverage for its

products.

Page 98: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

98

Table 4.8: Future pricing scenarios in Japan Best case Worst case Most likely Continued pricing cuts in the Wide-ranging pricing reform Gradual pricing reform led by place of wide-ranging reform resulting in significant differential price cuts resulting in price differentials downward pressure on prices, supporting innovative products supporting high prices for reimbursement levels and innovation prescription volumes Introduction of health economics and pro-generics Refined reference pricing Strict internal and external regulations alongside refined accounting for purchasing reference pricing resulting in reference pricing power disparities and product lower prices differentiation Continued protection from Legislative changes resulting parallel trade Continued protection against in introduction of parallel trade, parallel trade and significant increased generic substitution generic substitution and use of health economics

Source: Delphi Pharma Business Insights

Best case pricing scenario

In a best case pricing scenario, the Japanese MHW would continue to postpone

significant, wide-ranging reform of the healthcare reimbursement system. Biennial

price cuts would continue, but their level would decline and their differential impact

increase, weighted more heavily towards older drugs and generics. Under this scenario

new products could still continue to command high prices, while current effective

therapies would not be significantly affected by price cuts or reform.

The reference pricing system would be refined over time, ensuring effective therapies

are isolated from the rigid referencing structure. Internal reference pricing parameters

will be relaxed to allow greater disparities between effective and ineffective therapies,

while external parameters would reflect differences in purchasing power prevailing

between Japan and its European reference markets. This would allow Japanese prices

to continue to display a greater level of internal and external price differentiation

compared to reference pricing in European countries.

Page 99: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

99

Under a best case scenario, the Japanese pharmaceutical industry would continue to be

protected from both parallel imports and high levels of generic substitution. Until the

round of price cuts in April 2002 generic products were allowed prices often no

cheaper than a number of ‘me-too’ branded products within a drug class. The

mechanisms for an effective generic substitution policy would require continued price

discounts for generics relative to their branded equivalents.

Worst case pricing scenario

In a worse case pricing scenario, the Japanese MHW would undertake wide-ranging

reform to the healthcare reimbursement system, in place of continued price cutting.

Any reform would be aimed at achieving significant cost containment and a complete

reversal of yakkasa prescribing. Although the specific details of any such reform are

difficult to forecast, the effects are likely to result in both lower reimbursable prices, as

well as cuts in reimbursing per se. Whether reimbursement is cut as a whole through

formulary lists or physician budgets, or whether patient co-payments are increased, the

likely result would be a decline in prescription volumes for the pharmaceutical

industry.

The internal and external reference pricing parameters currently applied to price setting

would be made stricter in order to reduce prices further. Internal reference pricing

would drag high prices lower in line with cheaper ‘me-too’ products and generics.

External reference pricing would use the lower prices in European reference markets to

place further downward pressure on the prices of current and future products sold in the

Japanese market.

In a worse case scenario, Japanese legislation could be updated opening up the market

to parallel trade. As global trade advances in all Japanese industries, it would seem

inevitable that the barriers to parallel trade with the domestic market would be relaxed

over time. Similar changes to legislation and regulations would also result in high

growth in the generics industry and in the utilization of pharmacoeconomic

evaluations. With levels of generic substitution in Japan amongst the lowest of all

Page 100: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

100

major international markets, significant impact could be made by a robust, government-

led generics substitution strategy. Similarly, if pharmacoeconomic evaluations were to

be used more widely in the price-setting and reimbursement processes in Japan, further

cost containment pressures would be likely to follow.

Most likely pricing scenario

Over the next five years, the most likely pricing scenario prevailing in Japan will

involve a continuation of the current reimbursement reform led by biennial price-

cutting. By weighting the cuts against generic and ‘me-too’ products, innovative

products can still continue to receive premium prices, while the overall drugs bill is

reduced. A shift in the criteria needed to achieve a high reimbursement price is,

therefore, likely to occur, putting pressure on the innovation generated through R&D in

Japan.

Price setting is likely to become more complex in the Japan, with the addition of health

economic data and pro-generics regulations to the current reference pricing system.

While the parameters used in reference pricing decision are unlikely to change

significantly in the future, the addition of health economics evaluations to pricing

applications is likely to result in a further barrier to achieving higher prices. An

effective therapy does not always generate positive results in pharmacoeconomic

evaluations, depending on the criteria and parameters used. Further steps protecting the

generics industry in Japan, and regulating the right to launch a copy product rapidly

following a patent expiry, are likely to result in greater pressure on the prices of post-

patent branded products.

In a most likely scenario the Japanese market will continue to be protected from

parallel trade. With no principle of international exhaustion in Japan, companies will

continue to prevent their products from being imported from other countries using their

trademark rights. While it is likely that such measures will be reversed over time, as

result of internal cost containment pressures and external free trade pressures, any

significant moves are unlikely over the next five years.

Page 101: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

101

Australian pricing regulations

In Australia, a national Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme (PBS) provides timely,

reliable and affordable access to necessary and cost effective pharmaceuticals.

Considerable subsidies are paid for pharmaceuticals covered by the PBS, resulting in

lower consumer prices. Approximately 90% of prescriptions in the Australian

pharmaceutical market are prescribed for PBS items.

Pharmaceuticals listed under the PBS fall into 3 categories:

Unrestricted – these medications have no restrictions on their therapeutic uses;

Restricted Benefit – the listing in the PBS Schedule details the specific therapeutic

uses for which these medications can be prescribed;

Authority Required Benefit – as with the Restricted Benefit, the Schedule lists the

specific uses for which these medications can be prescribed. In addition, for items

listed under this category, the prescriber is required to obtain prior approval from

the Health Insurance Commission.

The majority of prescriptions in Australia are written for medications subsidized under

the PBS. The price of all products listed on the PBS are reviewed annually by the

Pharmaceutical Benefits Pricing Authority (PBPA). The price reviewed and agreed to

with suppliers is at the price to pharmacists level (including a 10% wholesaler’s

margin).

In reviewing the price of listed items and in considering the price of items

recommended for listing, the PBPA takes into account a number of factors:

Pharmaceutical Benefits Advisory Committee comments on clinical and cost

effectiveness aspects of items;

the price of alternative brands of a drug;

Page 102: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

102

comparative prices of drugs in the same therapeutic group;

cost information provided by the supplier;

prescription volumes, economies of scale and other factors such as expiry dating,

storage requirements, product stability and special manufacturing requirements;

the level of activity being undertaken by a company in Australia, including new

investment, production, research and development;

prices of the drug in reasonably comparable countries;

other relevant factors which the applicant company may wish the PBPA to

consider;

any directions of the Minister for Health.

Benchmark pricing

The PBPA considers drugs in their therapeutic sub groups when reviewing prices. A

benchmark product is chosen on the basis of the lowest costs and other products are

priced in line with the benchmark product.

A premium above the benchmark price is allowed where the supplier of the product is

able to demonstrate an advantage in clinical and cost effectiveness terms. Most

products listed on the PBS are priced under this method. However, it is often the case

that no price increases can be justified as one or more products in the therapeutic group

have not sought any increase or prices are considered reasonable by the PBPA.

Cost plus method

Under the cost plus approach, the price recommended by the PBPA is based on the cost

of manufacture plus a margin. Costs allowed under this method do not include

distribution costs, promotional or marketing activity or general administration. This

Page 103: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

103

method is used for stand alone items and for benchmark products. It relies on

pharmaceutical suppliers providing the PBPA with accurate cost data.

The margin provided under this approach can vary from 15% to 40% (equivalent to a

mark-up of between 18% and 67%) depending on a number of factors including the

price sought by supplier, the estimated usage, the unit price and overseas prices.

Average monthly treatment cost

This is a variation of the reference price method which can be applied within a

therapeutic sub group usually where a medicine used to treat chronic conditions is

supplied in a number of strengths. The method takes into account actual clinical usage

and requires detailed utilization data.

Prices for new items

The main mechanism to determine initial prices is the advice from the Pharmaceutical

Benefits Advisory Committee (PBAC) which is an independent body of medical

experts established to advise the Minister for Health about which products and for what

indications products should be subsidized by the government. PBAC provides advice

on clinical effectiveness and cost effectiveness. It has been a requirement for drugs

sponsors to submit cost effectiveness data on new items since the start of 1993.

In recent years, the PBPA has increasingly recommended the use of price/volume

arrangements (unit prices decrease as volume increases), particularly where unit prices

are reasonably high and there is the potential for significant volumes or where there is

uncertainty about future volumes.

Page 104: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

104

Recent developments in Australia

Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme reform

The Australian government is carrying out significant reforms of the Pharmaceutical

Benefits Scheme (PBS) in order to control future drug costs. A major element of these

reforms is the pricing of listed drugs, resulting in lower prices for generic and off-

patent drugs. PBS covered drugs will be split into two formularies as of 1st August

2007. F1 largely covers patented drugs with the exception of those affected by the

therapeutic reference pricing system such as ACE inhibitors, calcium channel blockers

and proton pump inhibitors. F2 includes off-patent and generic products, as well as the

interchangeable patented drugs mentioned above.

Products listed in the F2 formulary are to face a series of price reductions from 1st

August 2008 in an attempt to divert the discounts currently offered by generic

manufacturers to pharmacists to prescribe their products. For drugs considered to

involve low price competition for the off-patent product a series of 2% price reductions

are scheduled over the next three years. For drugs where price competition is

considered high for the off-patent product a one-off 25% mandatory price reduction

will be introduced in 2008. All newly listed F2 formulary drugs will be required to

disclose their actual market prices to ensure the PBS reimbursement price for generic

and off-patent drugs more closely reflects the actual price at which the drug is supplied

to pharmacies.

Chinese pricing regulations

Starting as an experiment in Shanghai in 1994, China now maintains both a national

and provincial/local set of reimbursement lists for the sale of pharmaceutical products

in state-run hospitals or clinics. The national list contains more than 1,400 drugs that

are acceptable for reimbursement from state-controlled insurance organizations.

Page 105: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

105

Provincial/local lists must mirror the national list but are given a 10% “local re-

adjustment” flexibility. Inclusion on the lists is a largely negotiated process.

Prices for drugs on the reimbursement lists are tightly controlled and many foreign

importers have found prices too low for their inclusion. Since 80% of drugs sold in

China are sold through hospital pharmacies, being excluded from these lists means

huge losses in sales. However, only 10-15% of the population is covered by state-

controlled insurance plans, and exclusion from one or more of theses lists may not have

any significant adverse effects on a foreign importers market share.

The Chinese government currently imposes a tariff of around 9.6% on imported

pharmaceuticals, plus a 17% VAT charge, customs clearing charges and drug

inspection costs. However, pharmaceutical prices are further inflated by high

distribution costs and hospital mark-ups, with retail prices paid by hospitals often as

much as 10 times higher than the manufacturer’s price.

As in most developing nations, China is struggling to contain health care-related costs.

This problem is compounded by the fact that around 70% of China’s total health care

costs are directly related to the sale of pharmaceuticals. More than 50% of this cost

can, in turn, be traced to the expensive imported drugs. In response to this, Chinese

central government authorities have established guidelines designed to place price caps

on imported drugs, with domestic drugs already subject to such measures.

Recent developments in China

New drug pricing procedures

From 1st March 2007, a new drug pricing procedure was implemented to improve

transparency and reduce corruption in the price setting process. The National

Development and Reform Commission outlined five stages for setting the price of a

pharmaceutical product:

Page 106: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

106

Two drug price regulators visit the manufacturer to check the cost of raw materials;

new expert group on drug pricing evaluates the proposed price;

public hearing collects public comments on proposed price;

group discussions;

completion of group examinations.

Price cuts

In January 2007, the National development and Reform commission (NDRC) cut the

prices of more than 240 drugs by an average of 20%. These price cuts followed earlier

NDRC cuts in June 2006 involving an average 23% cut in the prices of 67 oncology

drugs.

Generic prescribing

Regulations requiring physicians to prescribe generically rather than by brand name

came into force on 1st May 2007. The reform is an effort to limit the kickbacks offered

by to physicians from drug manufacturers to incentivize the prescribing of expensive

and unnecessary drugs.

Page 107: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

107

CHAPTER 5

Global pricing strategies

Page 108: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

108

Chapter 5 Global pricing strategies

Summary

The global price perspective has two parts. The complexity of global drug prices is a result of local differences in pricing and reimbursement systems. Understanding these complexities and developing locally optimal pricing strategies is critical for maximizing the returns from pharmaceutical investments.

In addition to the local perspective, a global coordination of prices and price-differentials between key markets is also required. The impact of external reference price schemes and parallel trade require prices to be optimized across markets.

Local optimization involves adapting pricing strategies to fit national-level, and in some cases regional-level, regulations. The successful development and approval of new drugs is not enough to guarantee market access.

Countries place different levels of ‘fourth hurdle’ barriers to receiving full reimbursement, which require economic data to ensure a broad use at a high price. These evaluations have begun to limit the ability of pharmaceutical companies to set prices for new drugs in traditionally free price markets and restrict access to drugs targeted at areas of significant unmet need.

The coordination of local pricing at the global level ensures that price differentials that impact on external reference pricing and parallel trade or optimized. The global price perspective involves determining appropriate launch sequences and the optimal price differentials between country markets. However, the two processes are inextricably linked.

Through the impact of reference pricing and parallel trade, the ability of pharmaceutical companies to achieve premium prices in some markets can be compromised by lower prices in others. These cross-country pressures are best illustrated by the situation in Europe, where both reference pricing and parallel trade have a significant impact on pricing.

Page 109: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

109

Introduction

The global price perspective has two parts. The complexity of global drug prices is a

result of local differences in pricing and reimbursement systems. Understanding these

complexities and developing locally optimal pricing strategies for key drugs is critical

for maximizing the returns from pharmaceutical investments. In addition to the local

perspective, a global coordination of prices and price-differentials between key markets

is also required. The impact of external reference price schemes and parallel trade

require prices to be optimized across markets. This chapter is divided between the local

optimization and global coordination perspectives.

Local optimization

Local optimization involves adapting pricing strategies to fit national-level, and in

some cases regional-level, regulations. The previous three chapters outline these

differences, but national-differences in market access and pharmacoeconomics require

further analysis.

Market access and reimbursement

Figures published by the Association of the British Pharmaceutical Industry (ABPI)

show that the UK is the slowest country in Europe to take up innovative drugs, second

only to Japan amongst leading pharmaceutical markets. In the UK, recent cancer

breakthrough medicines are still being prescribed at two-thirds the rate found in

comparable countries. As shown in Figure 5.11, more than a quarter of pharmaceutical

sales in 2005 in the US were generated by products launched in the previous five years.

Page 110: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

110

Figure 5.11: Market share for new products launched in last five years, 2005

Source: Association of the British Pharmaceutical Industry Business Insights

The successful development and approval of new drugs is not enough to guarantee

market access. Countries place different levels of ‘fourth hurdle’ barriers to receiving

full reimbursement, which require economic data to ensure a broad use at a high price.

These evaluations have begun to limit the ability of pharmaceutical companies to set

prices for new drugs in traditionally free price markets and restrict access to drugs

targeted at areas of significant unmet need.

Free price markets

The UK and German markets have long been heralded as Europe’s free pricing

markets, where newly approved drugs could be launched under free market conditions.

However, the impact of NICE in the UK and the IQWiQ in Germany are beginning to

create a serious fourth hurdle in these two major European pharmaceutical markets.

While neither body has any impact on pricing, its pharmacoeconomics-based advice

14% 15%18%

24% 24%27%

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

Japan UK Italy France Spain US

Mar

ket s

hare

for

new

pro

duct

s

Page 111: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

111

does impact directly on reimbursement and clinical guidance at the national level. As a

result access to these markets involves preparation work in the early stages of

development, often as early as phase II. Drugs that cannot demonstrate clinically

superior economic profiles at review time will face restrictions on their use to more

limited patient populations in the UK and caps in the reimbursement level in Germany.

Orphan drugs

Orphan drugs have long stepped outside the traditional model of incentives offered by

price and reimbursement. However, as uptake of pharmacoeconomic evaluations

continues, the basis on which orphan drugs are priced requires further thought. Here,

the cost of developing and manufacturing/ distributing the drug begin to impact on the

required price incentive to ensure the future development of drugs for orphan diseases.

As has been found in Canada, the Common Drug Review’s cost-benefit criteria have

proved inappropriate for evaluating drugs for high unmet needs that have managed to

receive broad market access outside Canada. The social costs of diseases with few

patients but high unmet need to be highlighted to ensure a continued interest in the

development of orphan drugs.

Orphan drug schemes in the US and Europe have offered approval and market

exclusivity incentives for some years now, resulting in the development of several

groundbreaking drugs for orphan diseases. However, establishing an appropriate price

and then successfully receiving reimbursement from payers is still difficult.

Pharmacoeconomic evaluations

Pharmacoeconomics emerged at the National level during in the 1990s as a reaction to

rising healthcare costs and a heightened requirement to demonstrate value for money in

healthcare budgets. In 1993, Australia set out binding guidelines requiring the

submission of economic analyses as part of the reimbursement system. Following this

groundbreaking development the rest of the world’s key pharmaceutical payers

responded with their own guidelines. Europe’s systematic use of pharmacoeconomics

as part of the reimbursement process began in the late 1990s with the introduction of

Page 112: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

112

health economics assessments in Denmark, France and Italy. The UK, Portugal,

Finland, Belgium, Norway, the Netherlands and Austria have also introduced

pharmacoeconomic evaluations into their pricing and reimbursement processes.

In the US, individual managed care organizations were the first to employ

pharmacoeconomic guidelines, beginning with Regence Blue Shield in 1994. Revisions

of these guidelines have resulted in the Academy of Managed Care Pharmacy’s

(AMCP) Format for Formulary Submissions. The AMCP’s Format has now become

widespread and is used by most private plans to provide guidance on

pharmacoeconomic requirements.

For many years, pharmacoeconomic assessments have played a notional role in pricing

decisions in Japan, while in practice have proved to have little impact on decision-

making. Currently, there are renewed efforts to develop guidelines at the national level

to support the National Health Insurance pricing and reimbursement process.

In Germany, the Institute for Quality and Economic Efficiency has traditionally been

tasked with therapeutic evaluations for new drugs, with economic considerations only

added in 2007. Similarly, clinical, as opposed to economic, considerations continue to

be the primary end-point studied in support of pricing and reimbursement decisions in

France. In Spain and Italy, regional-level pharmacoeconomic evaluations continue to

provide a lack of clarity and consistency to reimbursement decision making.

The UK market has been at the forefront of recent developments in pharmacoeconomic

assessments, through its evaluations body, National Institute for Health and Clinical

Excellence (NICE). The agency takes into account health economic studies presented

by the industry and other external agencies in making their recommendations on

clinical use and reimbursement.

No major pharmaceutical market makes direct use of heath economic data in making its

pricing and reimbursement decisions. However, in some smaller markets, including

Page 113: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

113

Canada, Australia, Sweden and New Zealand, pharmacoeconomics plays a more

central role. Despite this limited application, the use of pharmacoeconomics is set to

play an ever more important role in price and reimbursement decisions across major

markets. Following on from the work of NICE in the UK, the US and Germany are

likely to be charged with the next phase of pharmacoeconomic development,

implementing health economics analysis into their statutory healthcare provision

through the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) and the Institute for

Quality and Economic Efficiency (IQWiQ) respectively.

This array of different pharmacoeconomic requirements across different markets leaves

significant work for pharmaceutical companies looking to generate reimbursement

coverage for their products. Ensuring the availability of adequate trial and economic

data for reimbursement submissions would require a combination of global and local

resources in order to be sympathetic to local needs while generating efficiencies at the

global level. Determining what elements of the pharmacoeconomic requirements for

local submissions can be centralized at the global level will provide competitive

advantages in achieving quick and successful price and reimbursement approvals.

Global coordination

The coordination of local pricing at the global level ensures that price differentials that

impact on external reference pricing and parallel trade or optimized. The global price

perspective involves determining appropriate launch sequences and the optimal price

differentials between country markets. However, the two processes are inextricably

linked.

Launch sequence

With respect to international launch sequence, a full understanding of who influences

and is influenced by who is required. As a result this might lead to a prioritizing of

product launches in free pricing markets, such as Germany and United Kingdom,

Page 114: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

114

before eventually launching in large externally referencing countries such as France,

Spain and Italy. However, other variables such as historical price levels, approval

timings and local pricing and reimbursement policies will also impact on optimal

launch sequencing. In Europe, where reference pricing and parallel trade impact most

heavily on prices, great care is needed in determining an appropriate launch order.

EU launch order

Of the five major pharmaceutical markets in the EU, the UK provides the best

opportunity for initial product launch. Drugs are allowed to enter into a high value

market with freedom to command prices without the limitation set by reference pricing.

Companies have flexibility over their drug prices although, this is in part limited by the

profit caps found within the pharmaceutical price regulation scheme (PPRS).

France, Finland, Denmark and Sweden provide good opportunities as ‘second launch’

countries. The healthcare payers in these countries do not favor high priced branded

drugs unless the products come from an innovative drug class or have new modes of

actions. France has initiated a new reference pricing system that encourages the use of

generic drugs, imposed price cuts to branded products already on the market, and

reclassified the reimbursement system. However, in a move to create a positive

environment for innovative products, the country is seeking to raise prices for these

therapies to be in line with northern European markets. Finland and Denmark have

both amended their pricing criteria so that drug prices are in line with the European

average. Finland is proposing to reform its reimbursement system so that drugs will be

reclassified. In Denmark, a new reimbursement scheme has been introduced, which is

based on a medical need-dependent system. In Sweden, the healthcare system is

decentralized giving regional councils greater influence in pricing and reimbursement

decisions. Regions can then be targeted as a result of different healthcare needs defined

by regional demographics and budgets. However, they may also be fragmented due to

these differences.

Page 115: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

115

Within the five major markets in the EU, Spain and Italy provide the best opportunities

as ‘third launch’ countries. Other major EU countries included in this launch sequence

are the Netherlands, Ireland, Luxembourg, Belgium, Portugal and Austria. These

countries have a mixture of pricing and reimbursement policies that do not always

favor newer products that have moderately better benefits than predecessors indicated

for a similar disease market.

Spain and Italy both have regionalization policies that have led to the decentralization

of healthcare control. As a result, pricing and reimbursement negotiations may be more

complex due to the variations in healthcare needs and budgets between different

regions. Furthermore, both countries have implemented industry-government

agreements that have led to price cuts and capping. In a positive move for the industry,

Spain is addressing its healthcare needs by encouraging R&D innovation through the

funding of more non-industry-based research projects.

Although Germany is one of the five major pharmaceutical markets in the EU, the

country has recently undergone radical healthcare reform that will impose challenges to

the pharmaceutical industry. These cost containment legislations place the country as a

‘hostile’ environment to launch products into. Therefore, Germany is chosen as the

‘fourth choice’ country to launch in. Recent cost cutting measures has seen the

introduction of a new reference pricing system, plus requiring pharmacists to substitute

generic drugs over branded products. Furthermore, recent changes targeting the social

health system by reducing healthcare contributions will influence the choice and use of

drugs.

Optimal price differentials

As the impact of external reference pricing and parallel trade continues to increase the

interaction of prices between different markets is also increasing. The optimization of

pharmaceutical prices can no longer be limited to a market-by-market approach, but

must involve a comprehensive understanding of the interactions prevailing between

country prices. Country-specific pricing and product managers can no longer work in

Page 116: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

116

isolation, but must collaborate to understand the impact of pricing in one country on

other markets.

Figure 5.12 illustrates the increasing interdependency and complexity found in

European price setting. The reference country coverage for the three major European

markets currently engaging in external reference pricing are outlined, with Ireland and

Portugal also included as illustrations of how intermediary countries can also result in

reference links between the five major markets. For example, not only does France

reference the UK, but it also references Ireland that in turn references the UK. France

also references Portugal, which in turn references Italy, which in turn potentially

references the UK through its flexible EU reference scheme.

Page 117: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

117

Figure 5.12: External reference pricing in Europe, 2007

Source: Delphi Pharma Business Insights

Reference pricing can also impact on pricing by changes in a specific country’s pricing

policy. For example, in 2007 Portugal added Greece to its three previous reference

countries, Spain, Italy and France. Given that average prices in Greece are lower than

in Spain, Italy and France, average prices in Portugal are also likely to fall. However,

given that Portugal is a reference country for Spain, Italy and France in particular,

prices in these markets may also be expected to fall.

UK Germany

Spain

ItalyIreland

Rest of EU

Portugal

France

A BCountry Areferencescountry B

UK Germany

Spain

ItalyIreland

Rest of EU

Portugal

France

A BCountry Areferencescountry B

Page 118: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

118

Through the impact of reference pricing and parallel trade, the ability of

pharmaceutical companies to achieve premium prices in some markets can be

compromised by lower prices in others. These cross-country pressures are best

illustrated by the situation in Europe, where both reference pricing and parallel trade

have a significant impact on pricing.

Using the example of just two companies, France and Spain, the impact of pricing in

one country on pricing in another country can be shown. Prices in Spain are generally

amongst the lowest in Europe. However, France references the prices of Spain,

amongst other countries, in order to determine prices. Therefore, in order to be

reimbursed the price differential must be minimized. Similarly, a high price differential

results in parallel imports from Spain to France, cannibalizing pharmaceutical sales

revenues in France. Therefore, parallel imports results in further pressure to minimize

the price differential between countries. The pricing decision in France is impacted

significantly by the price in Spain and, therefore, the two markets and their interaction

must be considered together.

Figure 5.13: Global pricing and the interaction between countries

Source: Delphi Pharma Business Insights

Spain FrancePricedifferential

Parallel trade

Reference pricing

Spain FrancePricedifferential

Parallel trade

Reference pricing

Page 119: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

119

Implementing global pricing strategies

Global pricing strategies involve setting a delicate balance between price optimization

at the local level and high-level coordination at the global level. Rather than being

distinct processes, there is an iterative relationship between ongoing local and global

pricing efforts. An effective organizational effort at delivering local optimization

alongside global coordination would involve the following steps:

Global-level review and preparation of key product benefits and pricing policy;

Local-level feedback regarding competitive situation and pricing and

reimbursement environment;

Global-level plans for target price, price differentials and launch order;

Local-level preparations for pricing and reimbursement submissions;

Global-level support in provision of critical data and expertise;

Local-level submissions, negotiations and results;

Global-level reaction to unforeseen local-level results.

Page 120: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

120

Figure 5.14: Global pricing strategies

Source: Delphi Pharma Business Insights

Successful global pricing strategies require companies to develop effective channels of

communication between local and global pricing and reimbursement departments. Only

those companies able to manage the global-local relationship while providing informal

feedback channels in order to react quickly and effectively to changes as they occur

will deliver optimal global pharmaceutical prices. Buy-in across local markets for

global launch sequence and target price plans is critical to ensure new drugs are

launched as quickly, with the highest price and reimbursement coverage profile as

possible.

Local optimization

GlobalCoordination

Local optimization

GlobalCoordination

Page 121: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

121

CHAPTER 6

Lifecycle pricing strategies

Page 122: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

122

Chapter 6 Lifecycle pricing strategies

Summary

Lifecycle pricing strategies are largely dominated by two major lifecycle events, launch and patent expiry. Pricing at launch has the primary window for achieving an optimal price and reimbursement coverage, while patent expiry strategies involve maximizing brand value in competition with low-priced generics.

However, at all points in the drug lifecycle between launch and patent expiry there are key competitive considerations that significantly impact on pricing strategies.

It is imperative that pharmaceutical companies ensure that evidence demonstrating product value in support of the initial case for reimbursement is effectively communicated and accounted for in the reimbursement decision-making process. Companies must therefore identify and exploit opportunities to communicate the value of products and influence decision-makers’ thinking.

Following the successful launch of a drug, the competitive environment can regularly change following the expansion or patent expiry of competitor products. In response, pharmaceutical companies must be able to identify the pricing implications associated with on-patent lifecyle events and respond appropriately. A number of novel approaches to pricing and reimbursement have emerged that deal with reactions by payors to initial prices at launch.

Following the loss of patent protection, the branded drug faces significant downward pricing pressure from the introduction of generic competition. However, a brand’s optimal retaliatory strategy differs by market, but both upward amd downward price adjustments have been successfully applied in the past.

Page 123: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

123

Introduction

Lifecycle pricing strategies are largely dominated by two major lifecycle events, launch

and patent expiry. Pricing at launch has the primary window for achieving an optimal

price and reimbursement coverage, while patent expiry strategies involve maximizing

brand value in competition with low-priced generics. However, at all points in the drug

lifecycle between launch and patent expiry there are key competitive considerations

that significantly impact on pricing strategies. This chapter is divided between the

launch, patent protected and patent expiry phases of the drug lifecycle.

Launch phase pricing considerations

It is imperative that pharmaceutical companies ensure that evidence demonstrating

product value in support of the initial case for reimbursement is effectively

communicated and accounted for in the reimbursement decision-making process.

Companies must therefore identify and exploit opportunities to communicate the value

of products and influence decision-makers’ thinking. Ideally, activities initiated early in

product development (focus groups, policy tracking etc.) will have formed

relationships with decision-makers, enabling a detailed understanding of their

priorities, information requirements and decision making processes.

Submission dossiers

Submission dossiers are often the primary source of information available to decision-

makers when undertaking evaluations upon which reimbursement decisions are made.

As such, they represent the primary opportunity for pharmaceutical companies to

communicate product value and present arguments to support pricing and

reimbursement. While the precise requirements of each decision-maker will vary,

submission dossiers should seek to:

Page 124: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

124

Describe the product fully;

demonstrate how the product will be used in therapy (description of the clinical

condition being treated and the role of the product in its treatment);

provide evidence of clinical safety, efficacy and effectiveness;

provide relevant economic and quality of life data;

present economic evaluations of the impact on healthcare systems and wider

“societal impacts” (clinical outcomes and cost/resource impact supported by

models);

provide independent evidence to support arguments.

In short, and in the words of the Academy for Managed Care Pharmacy, submissions

should contain “all possible clinical and economic information necessary to assess the

overall clinical utility and value that a product brings to a specific patient population

and healthcare system.”

In most cases, when a product enters the market it displaces other treatment strategies

or other aspects of healthcare provision. As a result, every decision is based upon the

concept of displacement (i.e. decision-makers will look to see what is likely to be

displaced by the product, either by way of other products or by way of costs). It is,

therefore, critical that companies ensure that dossiers compare products to the

treatment strategies and interventions (drug or otherwise) that are likely to be

displaced.

In order to maximize the opportunity to communicate product value in submission

dossiers, pharmaceutical companies must commit time and resources to working in

partnership with decision-makers in advance of submissions. Companies should seek to

notify decision-makers of the status of products in development and of their intent to

submit for assessment well in advance of submissions, clearly indicating intended

timelines. Meetings should then be scheduled with decision-makers in order to cement

Page 125: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

125

an understanding of specific submission requirements. This process will ensure that the

information contained within dossiers is:

Delivered to the standards and format required by each decision-maker;

appropriate in scope;

of high quality, clear and verifiable;

relevant to the priorities of the decision-maker. For example, data must be relevant

to the healthcare system and population under the jurisdiction of the decision-

maker;

delivered in a timely manner;

transparent, for example complex economic models/data must be fully described,

easy to use and investigate, and all assumptions fully detailed.

Following the submission of evidence, pharmaceutical companies must ensure that they

are equipped to provide appropriate support to decisions makers. For example,

companies must be prepared to provide further information quickly upon request and

lines of contact, detailing personnel equipped to provide additional information, should

be made clear.

Identifying key decision makers

While pricing and reimbursement decisions are often made on a national level,

independent assessments for pricing and reimbursement purposes will often be

undertaken below this level. In France for example, the country’s largest healthcare

institution, the Assistance Publique - Hopitaux de Paris (AP-HP), will put products

through its own reimbursement criteria. Therefore, as part of an effective strategy,

companies must identify and understand the needs and priorities of the decision-makers

down to the lowest level in each market (i.e. to the level of local hospital formulary,

local general practice formulary or private practice formulary).

Page 126: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

126

While formal submission dossiers may not be required for each healthcare provider,

companies must be positioned to provide multiple packages (e.g. economic models,

analysis of impact of healthcare setting) that communicate product value and support

formulary inclusion. Critically, each initiative must be tailored to the specific needs and

priorities of each audience. In best practice, understanding the needs and perspectives

of each decision-maker will have been undertaken in the early stages of the product

lifecycle, and development subsequently steered to take into account key issues.

Failure to secure reimbursement

In an ideal scenario, having compiled and submitted a strong dossier, a company will

achieve the desired reimbursement status prior to, or shortly after product launch.

However, in practice, companies often find themselves in a position in which they are

forced to launch products with only partial, or in the worst case, no reimbursement. In

cases such as these, companies can seek to implement strategies to improve the

reimbursement coverage for products.

Broadly, companies have three available options:

Work with decision-makers to address issues underlying the reimbursement

decision;

apply pressure on decision-makers through lobbying activities;

broker compromise agreements with healthcare payors.

In most cases, companies will implement a combination of the above.

Working with decision makers

Upon failure to achieve a desired reimbursement status, companies should seek

dialogue with decision-makers to identify the specific issues underlying their decisions.

It may be the case that decision-makers require additional evidence or that there are

misconceptions relating to the original submission. Having identified the drivers of the

Page 127: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

127

decision, companies will be positioned to either undertake studies to present new data

that will promote a review of the product’s reimbursement status or clarify and educate

decision-makers with respect to the data originally submitted.

Applying pressure through lobbying

The ability to lobby decision-makers effectively is becoming an increasingly important

competence for pharmaceutical companies. In the US, for example, a number of issues

such as the potential for legislative action to control drug costs have prompted

companies to boost their lobbying capabilities in recent years.

In a number of cases, lobbying campaigns have been critical in improving the

reimbursement status of products and pharmaceutical companies must be prepared to

carry out such campaigns in cases where products are assigned a reimbursement status

that fails to reflect their value. The development of internal lobbying and policy

functions is an essential step in building lobbying capability.

Brokering deals

One strategy that has emerged in recent years is to seek compromise agreements with

healthcare payors. In such agreements, healthcare payors and companies agree to an

initial price or reimbursement rate for a product following launch and a set of pre-

agreed conditions, that can trigger a reduction in the price or reimbursement rate at a

later date. Agreements are structured to manage financial risk to both the healthcare

system and the pharmaceutical company. Examples of such agreements include:

linking price/ reimbursement reductions to sales. The healthcare payor agrees to

reimburse a product at a higher rate until the product achieves a pre-agreed sales

target, after which the price or reimbursement rate is reduced by a predetermined

amount;

linking price/ reimbursement reductions to time after launch. The healthcare payor

agrees to a high initial price/reimbursement rate for a pre-agreed period of time,

Page 128: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

128

after which the price or reimbursement rate is reduced by a predetermined amount

regardless of sales;

linking pricing/ reimbursement to specific performance criteria. The payor agrees to

a high price/ reimbursement rate as long as particular performance criteria are met.

For example, if the cost effectiveness of a product drops below a certain threshold,

the price or reimbursement rate will be reduced. These reductions may be based on

a sliding scale.

Historically, the most common agreements to have emerged from pricing and

reimbursement negotiations link the price or reimbursement rate of a product to its

sales performance. However, more recently there have been examples of departures

from this deal structure. An agreement between the French government and Pfizer and

Pharmacia over the pricing of the arthritis drug Celebrex (April 2001) involved linking

price cuts to formulary access, while an agreement in the UK for the multiple sclerosis

drug beta interferon (July 2000) established a risk-sharing arrangement between

manufacturer and payer. More is said about innovative broker agreements in the

following section.

Patent protected phase pricing considerations

Following the successful launch of a drug, the competitive environment can regularly

change following the launch, expansion or patent expiry of competitor products. In

response, pharmaceutical companies must be able to identify the pricing implications

associated with on-patent lifecyle events and respond appropriately. A number of novel

approaches to pricing and reimbursement have emerged that deal with reactions by

payors to initial prices a launch.

Case study: the respiratory market

The respiratory market provides a good illustration of pricing strategies facing

incumbent and new entrant players across the product lifecycle. The impact of new

Page 129: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

129

drug classes, formulations and patent expiries have a significant impact on the market

and the successes and relative failures within the market provide excellent insight into

how pricing strategies evolve over the lifecycle of products and entire product classes.

According to IMS Health, respiratory agents generated global sales of $24.1 billion in

2006, a year-on-year increase of 10.4% in constant dollars. As shown in Figure 6.15,

the leading products in 2006 were GlaxoSmithKline’s Advair/ Seretide and Merck’s

Singulair. The major growth drivers in the market for asthma and chronic obstructive

pulmonary disease were the anticholinergic, Spiriva, and the leukotriene receptor

antagonist, Singulair.

Figure 6.15: Leading respiratory drugs by global sales, 2006

Source: Delphi Pharma Business Insights

Lifecycle management is critical in the asthma/ COPD market in order to maintain

pricing. Improving the accuracy or efficacy of drug delivery or patient compliance can

earn price premiums at launch.

6.2

3.6

1.71.3 1.2 1.2

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Advair/Seretide

Singulair Spiriva Pulmicort Flovent/Flixotide

Symbicort

Glo

bal s

ales

, 200

6 ($

bill

ion)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Yea

r-on-

year

gro

wth

, 200

5-06

2006 sales 2005-06 growth

Page 130: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

130

Combination products are becoming increasingly common. However, despite

improving compliance and therefore efficacy and safety they are priced close to parity

or at a discount to the constituent drugs. Proven clinical benefit through improved

compliance is often difficult to substantiate. However, the parity pricing can help lead

to early use in the treatment pathway, as recommended by NICE in the UK.

One strategy, employed by Singulair, is to launch in a niche market – for extreme

symptoms or patients with poorly controlled symptoms. This presents the opportunity

to launch at premium initially and then to expand indications into other areas/ patient

groups. However, Singulair failed to measure up as a premium product in the wider

market, where its premium pricing restricted its uptake, instead being prescribed as a

last option.

The patented inhaler compliments have helped to keep patients and subscribers loyal,

resulting in very little generic competition. Generic entrants would have to encourage

inhaler change as well as drug change. When patents do begin to expire, generic

entrants will increase, particularly for combination products that are prescribed more

frequently by primary care physicians. As average prices begin to fall, new entrants

may find it more difficult to launch at current price premium levels.

The Montreal Protocol and other environmental regulations have led to a phasing out

of CFC propellants for generic metered-dose inhalers to be replaced with HFA

propellants. As a result, the HFA propellants now offer patent protection against

generic competition even following the loss of US patents for leading inhaled steroids,

fluticasone, flunisolide and beclomethasone. Other lifecycle management strategies

have been the switching of patients to dry powder inhalers (DPI) and the increased use

of combination products in the primary care setting.

Advair is set to lose patent protection in the US in 2011, which will have a significant

impact on single-ingredient inhaled steroids and B2 stimulants. These classes will face

Page 131: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

131

competition from generic combination drugs that are comparably priced or even

cheaper while offering a dual mode of action.

Advair launched at a premium over Flovent by demonstrating superiority. Symbicort

may also be able to charge a premium over Advair as a result of its variable dosing

claims, which mitigate against the risk of excessive dosing. However, without a

significant body of data demonstrating superior efficacy, asthma drugs are not able to

justify price premiums to evaluation bodies such as NICE in the UK, who consider the

market to have a generally low level of unmet need.

In contrast to the treatment of asthma, the COPD still offers premium pricing

opportunities for drugs addressing the largely unmet need for inexpensive and effective

treatment option. Boehringer Ingelheim’s Spiriva has become the first choice drug for

many physicians while retaining a premium price.

The dominant players in the respiratory market, Sanofi-Aventis and GlaxoSmithKline,

are able to assert a great deal of negotiating power over payers and distributors, this

providing them with a competitive advantage over the market’s smaller players. This

may further protect pricing as the market becomes fragmented through generic

competition.

Innovative pricing strategies

A number of innovative pricing strategies have emerged across different

pharmaceutical markets where prices and reimbursement levels are linked to

performance-based and financial-based contracts. Performance-based contracts link

risk to the quality of the product’s performance. Reimbursement or subsequent refunds

to payers are linked directly to the success or failure of a drug to meet its clinically

claimed outcomes. In Italy, Bayer’s Nexavar (sarofenib) is reimbursed at an initial 50%

discount for the first two-months of treatment, with full reimbursement then offered for

responding patients. In Canada, Sanofi-Aventis only received formulary reimbursement

for Taxotere (docetaxel) following a six month period of patient progression

Page 132: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

132

monitoring that would have resulted in a fill refund to regional payers if it had been

unsuccessful.

Financial-based contracts link risk to utilization guarantees. The basis of the agreement

is on price and/ or expenditure caps which can operate at the overall healthcare budget

or individual product spend level. In the US, a number of cancer therapies operate

under price or product expenditure caps in order to maintain market access. The price

of Genentech’s Avastin (bevacizumab) is capped at $55,000 a year for all approved

FDA indications for patients below a given income level. Bristol-Myers Squibb’s

Erbitux (cetuximab) is provided at zero cost to low-income patients who have reached

a $10,000 monthly price cap.

Patent expiry phase pricing considerations

Following the loss of patent protection, the branded drug faces significant downward

pricing pressure from the introduction of generic competition. However, a brand’s

optimal retaliatory strategy differs by market, but both upward amd downward price

adjustments have been successfully applied in the past.

Recent legislative and approval breakthroughs in the market for biosimilars have raised

pricing concerns in key biotechnology product classes. However, with the market for

biosimilars still in its infancy, the impact on prices of patent expiries in the

biotechnology industry are still relatively unproven.

Price changes

A branded manufacturer has a limited number of options with regard to pricing at

patent expiry, it can either increase its price, decrease it, or maintain it at a constant

level. However, there are a number of ways in which each of these pricing strategies

could be implemented.

Page 133: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

133

Where limited generic competition is anticipated, or where high levels of brand loyalty

is expected to retain a segment of the customer base post patent expiry, there is a strong

case for maintaining or even raising the price in order to sustain sales value. Also,

increasing the price prior to generic entry can result in generic prices being set at a

higher level upon entry. In most cases though, significant price increases will not be

possible in Europe, due to strict governmental pharmaceutical price controls.

Implementing a price decrease at or prior to patent expiry allows brands to compete on

a price basis with generics, and may enable the company to maintain its relationships

with wholesalers and pharmacists by offering a known and trusted product and service

while going some way to matching the generics manufacturers on price.

US patent expiry

Brand companies that cut their prices in the face of generic competition are often faced

with a corresponding decrease in price of the generic. The rise of Indian generics

players, with extremely low cost bases has increased the level of price competition seen

in the US generics market, particularly within the commodity generics sector, where

this is unlikely to be an attractive strategy for the branded company.

As patients in the US vary in their level of cost sensitivity, depending on the nature of

their insurance coverage, branded companies have the potential to retain a segment of

the market that is not cost-sensitive, and it can therefore pay to maintain the price of

the brand post-patent expiry (in price inelastic segments of the market, there may even

be the potential to increase the revenue generated, by reducing the discounts offered by

the pharmaceutical company to pharmacists and wholesalers) in order to follow a

maximize value strategy. For instance, patients covered by a fee-for-service/ indemnity

plan, who pay high monthly premiums but enjoy full medical coverage are unlikely to

be motivated to switch from the branded to generic version. Meanwhile, patients

enrolled in HMO plans are likely to be subject to restrictive formularies with tiered

patient co-payments, with financial incentives to use the generic. As the proportion of

patients enrolled in indemnity plans decline, and these plans increasingly adopt the

Page 134: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

134

pharmaceutical cost containment methods used in managed care, the potential of the

branded industry to profit from this strategy may be reduced.

European patent expiry

There are effectively three ways a manufacturer can reduce the price of its product:

cut list price – cutting the official list price for a product may not be an attractive

strategy, as it risks parallel importing into other European markets, can reduce the

price of the brand in non-patent expired markets that use external reference price

systems, and reduces the price for all parties, even those that might otherwise pay

the higher price. In some markets though, it may be necessary to drop the price if

the brand is to retain reimbursement status;

selective price cuts – companies can offer packages for wholesalers to reward high

volume users. Such a strategy can be particularly effective in the hospital

environment, where companies can sell off-patent products as part of a bundle with

their newer brands;

discounts/rebates – a manufacturer may prefer to give a rebate than drop their price.

This gives wholesalers and pharmacists an incentive to dispense the company’s

product by improving their profit margins on sale of the brand.

In the UK mandated price cuts under the PPRS have in the past offered flexibility as to

which drugs in a company’s portfolio the cuts could to be applied to. The result is that

older, off-patent brands had their prices disproportionately reduced, and perhaps

benefited from reduced levels of generic erosion, while prices of newer brands were

maintained at higher levels than would otherwise have been possible. This popular

“brand equalization” strategy will be removed with the introduction of a revised UK

PPRS in 2005, which specifies that price modulation will not be allowed to include

price reductions made on products with SPC or patent expiry occurring between 1st

July 2004 and 1st January 2006. Nor will companies be allowed to include sales where

additional discounts result in branded products being dispensed against prescriptions

written generically.

Page 135: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

135

Case study: generic simvastatin

Patent protection for Merck’s Zocor (simvastatin) expired in the US in June 2006.

Generic versions of Zocor were made available the day after patent expiry, with Teva

and Ranbaxy launching versions of Zocor’s various approved strengths. These first

generics were launched with 180-day market exclusivity periods, afforded to them

though successfully challenging Zocor patents, as listed in the FDA’s Orange Book.

The exclusivity period enables first generics to launch with prices offering only a small

discount to the branded version, thereby earning significant returns before second an

third generics are launched reducing prices to half that of the brand or lower.

In response to impending generic competition and market share erosion, Merck took

the unusual step of heavily discounting the price of branded Zocor to certain health

insurers in the US in order to compete for market share. Insurers that reached a deal

with Merck, including United Healthcare and Wellpoint, offered lower patient

copayments to the branded version of simvastatin than for the generic. Branded drug

manufacturers tend to maintain the price of the branded product following patent

expiry in order to capture smaller volume share at a higher price, while some even

increase price to exploit residual brand loyalty.

An additional strategy employed by Merck for maximizing simvastatin revenues post

patent expiry was to allow Dr Reddy to launch an authorized generic version in Zocor

in return for a share in returns. In the US, authorized generics are a contentious issue,

with many arguing that they are anti-competitive. Their impact on the market as a

whole is to increase generic competition in advance of the 180-day exclusivity period,

resulting in lower generic prices and the impact those prices have on branded drug

sales.

The wide-ranging impact of low priced generics on the wider therapeutic class of drugs

is also illustrated by generic Zocor and its impact on the statin drug class. Days after

the introduction of generic simvastatin, General Motors, one of the largest providers of

healthcare in the US, began encouraging its beneficiaries to switch from all brand name

Page 136: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

136

statins to generic simvastatin in order to reduce costs. This would have a significant

effect on the sales of other leading statins, such as Pfizer’s Lipitor (atorvastatin). Cost-

effectiveness evaluation across a class of drugs can result in quite different

recommendations once a key drug goes off-patent and its price is reduced significantly.

By way of a response, Pfizer released economic analysis directly comparing Lipitor

with Zocor. The Incremental Decrease in Endpoints Through Aggressive Lipid

Lowering (IDEAL) pharmacoeconomic data showed that patients on Lipitor had

greater reductions in heart attacks, strokes and cardiovascular procedures suggesting

that savings from the use of generic statins may be largely offset by higher patient care

and other indirect costs.

Biosimilar pricing

Following approval by the EMEA in 2006, Sandoz’s Omnitrope was initially launched

in Germany at small discount of 20% to the reference product. This reflects the

difference between biosimilars and small molecule generics, whereby significant

marketing and promotion is required to convince physicians. As a result, biosimilars

will be initially marketed as a new brand. A second human growth hormone (HGH)

biosimilar, Biopartners/ LG Life Sciences’ Valtropin will be forced to match

Omnitrope’s price and positioning, thereby resulting in an increasingly competitive

market space. The price response of established HGH players and the overall

acceptance of payers and physicians will ultimately determine the success of the trail-

blazing biosimilars.

The first biosimilar products are unlikely to reach the US market before 2010. With the

high costs associated with development, manufacturing and promotion, a 20-25% price

reduction is the most that can be expected. However, in price insensitive markets, such

as endocrinology, this price decrease is unlikely to attract a significant market share

unless accompanied by brand-level marketing and promotion efforts. Price cuts without

clinical data and promotion would need to be more significant, in the region of 50%.

By way of an example, the first biosimilar to be introduced in the Indian market, Dr

Reddy’s G-CSF branded generic, Grafeel, was launched in 2001 with a 60% discount

Page 137: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

137

over the market incumbent. Over the proceeding four years, the drug was able to build

a 45% market share, despite a reactionary reduction in the price of Roche’s market

leading brand, Neupogen.

Continued lifecycle development of existing brands is also likely to restrict the overall

uptake of biosimilar products.

Implementing lifecycle pricing strategies

Lifecycle pricing strategies address the pricing challenges found within three distinct

phases of the product lifecycle. In the launch phase companies must be able to

coordinate across local markets in order to ensure maximum price and coverage. It is

the role of corporate headquarters to generate a dynamic, multidimensional view of a

product’s global price in order to limit the impact of external reference pricing and

parallel trade.

In the patent protected phase of the product lifecycle, companies are largely tasked

with reacting to given market events. The involvement of pricing and reimbursement

expertise in key competitive positioning and promotion strategies is critical to ensure

prices are optimized following changes in the competitive and regulatory environment.

Highly innovative products often require innovative reimbursement strategies to

protect premium prices.

In the patent expiry phase of the product lifecycle, companies must prepare well in

advance for the entrance of low-priced generic competition. The best generic defense

strategies involve line extension, reformulation and second-generation product

switching strategies in order to transfer patient loyalty to a new patent-protected drug.

Once generics arrive, companies must determine an appropriate pricing response,

which depend on the degree of patient loyalty involved and the technical difficulty

involved with producing generic products, For example, those operating in the

Page 138: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

138

biotechnology field are likely to face competition from the launch of biosimilars, but

similar to the launch of a ‘me too’ branded product rather than a low –priced generic.

Figure 6.16: Lifecycle pricing strategies

Source: Delphi Pharma Business Insights

Time

Sale

s

Launchphase

Patentprotected

phase

Patentexpiryphase

Time

Sale

s

Launchphase

Patentprotected

phase

Patentexpiryphase

Page 139: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

139

CHAPTER 7

Appendix

Page 140: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

140

Chapter 7 Appendix

Glossary

ANDA Abbreviated New Drug Application, a shortened version of a new

drug application (NDA) submitted instead of an NDA for

approval of a new formulation of an existing drug or

investigational drugs that are similar to already approved drugs

including generics

BIO Biotechnology Industry Organization, an industry organization

representing the interests of biotechnology companies

Bungyo the separation of the prescribing and dispensing functions in

Japan

GDP Gross Domestic Product, a measure a national wealth

HMO Health Maintenance Organization, a private health insurance in

the US combining a range of coverages in a group basis

MCO Managed Care Organization, a health care plan designed to

provide medical services through groups of doctors, hospital and

specialty providers

Medicaid a statutory insurance scheme made available by the US

government to people below a certain income who are unable to

afford private health insurance

Medicare a federal insurance scheme made available by US states for

people over the age of 65

MHW Ministry of Health and Welfare, the government department

overseeing national healthcare expenditure in Japan

Page 141: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

141

NHI National Health Insurance, the national healthcare reimbursement

body in Japan

NICE National Institute of Clinical Excellence, a Special Health

Authority covering England and Wales producing and

disseminating clinical guidelines, both for medicines and medical

technologies

Parallel imports the transportation of a pharmaceutical product from its original

market, where it was sold directly by its manufacturer or

marketing partner, to a different market for resale by the importer

Pharmacoeconomics the application of economic principles to the use of drug

therapies, allocating a monetary value or qualitative measurement

to alternative treatments and their outcomes in order to achieve

the most efficient allocation of limited healthcare resources

PhRMA Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America, an

industry organization representing the interests of pharmaceutical

companies

Yakkasa the difference between the reimbursement price and purchase

price for Japanese pharmaceutical products

Page 142: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

142

Sources

A wide range of sources for pharmaceutical pricing and reimbursement information

have been used in the compilation of this report. Significant desk and library research

has been conducted to develop comprehensive pricing and reimbursement profiles for

the leading pharmaceutical markets. A number of specific sources have been used in

developing and shaping the analyses presented in this report, including:

European Pharmaceutical Pricing: Optimising Launch Sequence to Maximise Product

Value. Ken Fyvie & Gavin Crouch. Critical Eye. Dec 2003 – Feb 2004

Industry Profile 2007. PhRMA. www.phrma.org

International pricing strategy for pharmaceuticals. Inpharmation. 2007

Medicaid Enrollment and Spending Trends, 2007. The Kaiser Commission on

Medicaid and the uninsured. The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation

NHI Drug Price System. Japan Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Association (JPMA).

2007

OECD Health Data 2007. www.oecd.org

Overview of pharmaceutical pricing and reimbursement regulation in Europe. Panos

Kanavos. LSE Health and Social Care. Feb 2001

Pharmaceutical Pricing & Reimbursement, 2007. Cambridge Pharma Consultancy.

IMS Health

Page 143: Pharma Pricing and Reimbursement

143

Pricing Climate Heats Up in US and Europe. Neil Turner. Pharmaceutical Executive.

July 2004

Recent Medicaid Prescription Drug Laws and Strategies, 2001-2007. National

Conference of State Legislatures

The Pricing Ecosystem. Pharmaceutical Executive. November 2004