ownership structure financial structure and r&d investment evid

97
Singapore Management University Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University Dissertations and eses Collection (Open Access) Dissertations and eses 2010 Ownership Structure, Financial Structure and R&D Investment: Evidence from Korean Firms Yanghua Chen Singapore Management University, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: hp://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/etd_coll Part of the Business Administration, Management, and Operations Commons , and the Technology and Innovation Commons is Master esis is brought to you for free and open access by the Dissertations and eses at Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University. It has been accepted for inclusion in Dissertations and eses Collection (Open Access) by an authorized administrator of Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University. For more information, please email [email protected]. Recommended Citation Chen, Yanghua, "Ownership Structure, Financial Structure and R&D Investment: Evidence from Korean Firms" (2010). Dissertations and eses Collection (Open Access). Paper 69.

Upload: tyokanankiri

Post on 20-Aug-2015

284 views

Category:

Economy & Finance


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Singapore Management UniversityInstitutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University

Dissertations and Theses Collection (Open Access) Dissertations and Theses

2010

Ownership Structure, Financial Structure andR&D Investment: Evidence from Korean FirmsYanghua ChenSingapore Management University, [email protected]

Follow this and additional works at: http://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/etd_collPart of the Business Administration, Management, and Operations Commons, and the

Technology and Innovation Commons

This Master Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Dissertations and Theses at Institutional Knowledge at Singapore ManagementUniversity. It has been accepted for inclusion in Dissertations and Theses Collection (Open Access) by an authorized administrator of InstitutionalKnowledge at Singapore Management University. For more information, please email [email protected].

Recommended CitationChen, Yanghua, "Ownership Structure, Financial Structure and R&D Investment: Evidence from Korean Firms" (2010). Dissertationsand Theses Collection (Open Access). Paper 69.

OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE, FINANCIAL STRUCTURE

AND R&D INVESTMENTS: EVIDENCE FROM KOREAN

FIRMS

CHEN YANGHUA

SINGAPORE MANAGEMENT UNIVERSITY

2010

Ownership Structure, Financial Structure and R&D

Investments: Evidence from Korean Firms

by

Chen Yanghua

Submitted to Lee Kong Chian School of Business in

partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Degree of

Master of Science in Management

Supervisor: Prof Young Rok CHOI

Singapore Management University

2010

Copyright (2010) Chen Yanghua

Ownership Structure, Financial Structure and R&D Investments:

Evidence from Korean Firms

Chen Yanghua

Abstract

Understanding factors that can enhance a firm‟s innovativeness is of critical

concern in management research. Prior studies in strategy and financial economics have

advanced our understanding of how resource allocation into innovation is shaped in a

firm, mainly from the perspectives of ownership and financial structures. However, the

extant literature is incomplete, because it treats ownership and financial structures as

separate determinants, even though theoretical arguments and empirical evidences

suggest that they are interdependent. This study investigates the determinants of firm‟s

R&D investments by bridging ownership and financial structures. Ownerships held by

inside and external owners are considered for ownership structure, while financial slack

and leverage ratio are considered for financial structures.

Exploiting simultaneous equation modeling technique and data sample of Korean

firms, I found the direct and indirect effects of different types of ownership on R&D

investments. Different from previous studies, this paper showed that financial factors

such as financial slack and leverage ratio that were used to be considered as determinants

of R&D investments are just mediators through which ownership structure affects firm‟s

strategic decision indirectly.

i

Contents

Acknowledgement ......................................................................................................... iii

Chapter 1 Introduction ..................................................................................................... 1

Chapter 2 Literature Review ............................................................................................ 5

2.1 R&D investments .................................................................................................. 5

2.1.1 The importance of R&D investments .............................................................. 6

2.1.2 The characteristics of R&D investments .......................................................... 7

2.1.3 R&D investments and firm value .................................................................... 7

2.1.4 The determinants of R&D investments ............................................................ 8

2.2 Ownership sructure ................................................................................................ 9

2.2.1 Controlling owner ......................................................................................... 10

2.2.2 Institutional investors .................................................................................... 13

2.2.3 Ownership structure and R&D investments ................................................... 14

2.2.4 Empirical evidence........................................................................................ 15

2.3 Financial structure ............................................................................................... 17

2.3.1 Financial slack and R&D investments ........................................................... 17

2.3.2 Capital structure and R&D investments ......................................................... 19

2.4 Ownership structure and financial structure ......................................................... 24

2.4.1 Ownership structure and financial slack ........................................................ 24

2.4.2 Ownership structure and capital structure ...................................................... 27

2.5 Summary ............................................................................................................. 29

Chapter 3 Theory and Hypotheses ................................................................................. 30

3.1 Ownership structure and R&D investments .......................................................... 30

3.1.1 Controlling ownership and R&D investments ............................................... 30

3.1.2 Institutional ownership and R&D investments ............................................... 32

3.2 The mediating effects of financial structures ........................................................ 34

3.2.1 Financial slack and R&D investments ........................................................... 34

3.2.2 Leverage ratio and R&D investments ............................................................ 35

ii

3.2.3 The mediating effects of financial slack ........................................................ 36

3.2.4 The mediating effects of leverage ratio .......................................................... 38

Chapter 4 Empirical Study............................................................................................. 42

4.1 Data and measurements ....................................................................................... 42

4.1.1 Sample .......................................................................................................... 42

4.1.2 Measurements ............................................................................................... 42

4.2 Summary statistics and model design ................................................................... 45

4.2.1 Summary statistics ........................................................................................ 45

4.2.2 Model ........................................................................................................... 49

4.3 Results ................................................................................................................. 50

4.4 Robustness test .................................................................................................... 53

Chapter 5 Discussion and Conclusion ............................................................................ 58

5.1 Conclusions ......................................................................................................... 58

5.2 Discussions .......................................................................................................... 58

5.3 Limitations .......................................................................................................... 62

5.4 Implications ......................................................................................................... 63

Appendix A ................................................................................................................... 64

Appendix B ................................................................................................................... 66

Appendix C ................................................................................................................... 68

Appendix D ................................................................................................................... 69

References ..................................................................................................................... 70

iii

Acknowledgement

I highly appreciate my supervisor Prof. Young Rok CHOI, who patiently

motivates me to conceive and finish the thesis. This thesis owes much to his thoughtful

and helpful comments. This paper would not have been possible without his guidance and

inspiration. I want to thank the Lee Kong Chian School of Business for giving me this

opportunity to study at Singapore and to do the research work.

Also, my gratitude is devoted to Prof. Kenneth HUANG Guang-Lih and Prof.

Burkhard SCHRAGE. Thanks for having reading a draft of this thesis and having made

their precious comments and suggestions. As for the left errors, the responsibility for the

text rests completely upon the author. My classmates from the Department of

Management support me in my research work. I want to thank them for all their help,

support and valuable hints. I would like to express my gratitude to everyone who directly

or indirectly offered his or her help to this thesis.

I cannot end without thanking my family, on whose constant encouragement and

love I have relied throughout my life. My deepest appreciation goes to them, namely my

parents and my two sisters.

1

CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION

The importance of R&D investment has received increasing attentions from

policy-makers and researchers in the fields of economics and strategic management, since

a lot of empirical evidence have showed that investment in R&D has a significant

positive effect on economic growth. The proponents of new growth theory such as Romer

(1990), Lucas (1988) all realized the contribution of R&D activities in pushing economic

growth. In the OECD report written by Guellec and Van-Pottelsberghe (2001), they

found that one percent increase in R&D stock would contribute 0.13 percent increase in

the growth of multi-factor productivity. These studies emphasized the importance of

R&D investments in contributing to country‟s economic growth and enhancing

comprehensive national power from the macro level.

As the importance of R&D stock to a country, appropriate expenditure on R&D

investments is also essential for firm‟s survival and growth, especially for firms in R&D-

intensive industry. This paper tries to investigate the determinants of R&D investments

from micro level, namely from firm‟s specific characteristics. As Franko (1989) pointed

out, firms especially in technologically industries rely on R&D investments to guarantee

firm‟s viability and generate sustained competitive advantages. However, firms differ in

committing their resources to R&D investments even after controlling for the industry,

firm size and performance (Ettlie, 1998; Mosakowski, 1993). Rumelt et al. (1994)

claimed that the presence of heterogeneity in R&D expenditures on the firm-level is still

the fundamental research in the area of strategic management, because understanding the

differences in firm‟s R&D investments may help us explain the existence of

2

heterogeneity in other dimensions, for example, firm performance and absorptive

capability.

Reviewing the literature, we can find two research streams on the determinants of

R&D investments. The first stream concerns about the influence of ownership structure,

which is mainly based on agency theory. For example, Lee and O‟Neill (2003)

investigated the different effects of ownership concentration on firm‟s R&D intensity in

US and Japanese contexts. The second research line focuses on the role financial

structures such as financial slack and debt conditions. Researches done in this stream are

mainly based on behavioral search theory, pecking order theory, signaling, and agency

theory. For instance, Long and Ravenscraf (1993) studied the impact of leverage ratio on

R&D intensity for firms undergoing a leveraged buyout. However, most of previous

studies treated ownership and financial structures as separate determinants, even though

theoretical arguments and empirical evidence suggest that they are interdependent.

Therefore, the extant literature ignores the potential interplay of ownership

structures and financial structures in decisions where R&D investments are determined. I

argue that this void may lead to a serious limitation in understanding firms‟ R&D

investments, because the current division of the literature may give incomplete

understanding of what are the relationships between the antecedents of R&D investments

(due to missing some relationship between ownership structures and financial structures

such as mediation relationships) and what are the consequences of the relationships

between those antecedents on R&D investments (such as over-investments etc.).

Therefore, identifying the direct and indirect effects of the salient factors of R&D

3

investments in a simultaneous model will help us to reveal new insights on the

relationship as well as avoid any false attribution of causality between those structure

factors and R&D investments.

The aim of this paper is to provide a systematic view on the determinants of R&D

investments on firm level, which has important implications in explaining firm‟s superior

performance and competitive advantages. Therefore, the main research questions of this

paper are: What are the determinants of R&D investments? What are the influences of

controlling owners and institutional owners in emerging markets? Are financial structures

such as financial slack and leverage ratio mediating factors in affecting R&D investments?

This paper contributes to the literature as follows: 1) it extends our understanding

of how ownership structure shapes strategic decisions such as R&D investments in

emerging markets. Since La Porta et al. (1999) and Claessons et al. (2000)‟s finding that

there is little separation between control and ownership in emerging markets all around

the world, many studies have been done to discern the role of controlling owners.

However, whether these controlling owners are long-term oriented and promote R&D

investments are still not clear. What‟s more, the drastic debate regarding the effect of

institutional investors on firms‟ R&D investments are most based on US governance

mechanism. I argue that different governance mechanisms and environment such as legal

protection may change their orientations. This paper enriches our understanding of their

roles in emerging markets. 2) It fills the literature void by bridging the relationships

between ownership structure and financial structure, which was neglected by previous

researchers. Kim et al. (2008) argued that ownership structure has moderating effect on

4

the relationship between financial slack and R&D investments. However, this paper

views financial structures such as financial slack and leverage ratio as mediating factors.

And my empirical study showed support for this perspective. 3) It verifies some

conventional wisdom such as the role of leverage ratio on R&D investments in Korean

context.

The rest of this paper is structured as follows. In Chapter 2, I reviewed the

literature regarding the roles of ownership structure such as controlling ownership and

institutional ownership and financial structures such as financial slack and leverage ratio

in determining firm‟s R&D investments, and reviewed the potential links between

ownership structure and financial structure. In Chapter 3, I proposed the main hypotheses

about the relationship between the antecedents of R&D investments and their influences

on R&D investments. In Chapter 4, I did the empirical test and presented the results.

Finally, I concluded with implications and pointed out the directions for future research.

5

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW

Since this paper aims to investigate the relationships between the antecedents of

R&D investments and their impacts on R&D investments, in the following parts I will

review the literature regarding these constructs such as R&D investments, ownership

structure and their relationships. First, some aspects of R&D investments such as its

importance, characteristics, determinants and its contribution to firm‟s value are

introduced in detail. According to the literature, there are two main determinants of R&D

investments that are wildly identified by previous scholars, namely ownership structure

and financial structure. Thus, previous studies about ownership structure and financial

structure are reviewed respectively. Finally, this paper provides a short summary of this

literature review part.

2.1 R&D investments

R&D is the abbreviation of research and development. R&D activity refers to

"creative work undertaken on a systematic basis in order to increase the stock of

knowledge, including knowledge of man, culture and society, and the use of this stock of

knowledge to devise new applications" (OECD, 2008), includes fundamental research,

applied research and development test. The scale of R&D activities or R&D intensity

constitutes an important criterion to measure the scientific and technological strength or

core competency of a country. Similarly, the scale of R&D activities untaken by a firm

represents its value and competitiveness. Almost all famous international companies view

R&D activities as the blood of a firm and invest lots of resources in R&D activities. In

6

the following paragraphs, this paper will talk about the importance of R&D investments,

the characteristics of R&D investments, determinants and its contribution to firm‟s value.

2.1.1 The importance of R&D investments

The importance of R&D has received increasing attentions from policy-makers

and researchers in the fields of economics and strategic management, since a lot of

empirical evidences have showed that investment in R&D has a significant positive effect

on economic growth (Bettina and Nigel, 2008). From the macro level, the proponents of

new growth theory such as Romer (1990), Lucas (1988) all realized the contribution of

R&D activities in pushing economic growth. In the OECD report written by Guellec and

Van-Pottelsberghe (2001), they found that one percent increase in R&D stock would

contribute 0.13 percent increase in the growth of multi-factor productivity. From the

micro level, firm faces more competitions as the economies globalized. The appropriate

expenditure spends on R&D activities is very important for firm‟s survival and growth,

especially for the technology intensive industry such as IT industry (Chan et al., 1990).

These R&D activities are mainly the sources of innovativeness and help firm generate

sustained competitive advantages (Aboody and Lev, 2000; Franko, 1989; Hall, 1998).

However, firms differ in committing their resources to R&D investments even after

controlling for the industry, firm size and performance (Ettlie, 1998; Mosakowski, 1993).

Since strategy literature shifted away from industry structure and towards firm

heterogeneity, theories such as resource-based view are developed to explain firm

heterogeneity. Rumelt et al. (1994) claimed that the presence of heterogeneity in R&D

expenditures on the firm-level is still the fundamental research in the area of strategic

7

management, because understanding the differences in firm‟s R&D investments may help

us explain the existence of heterogeneity in other dimensions, for example, firm

performance and core capability.

2.1.2 The characteristics of R&D investments

R&D investment is one kind of special investments that its result is usually

unknown. Mezghanni (2009) concluded that R&D investment has the following three

characteristics: high asset specificity, long investment horizon and high failure rate. High

asset specificity means that the outputs of R&D activities are specialized and can only be

fully deployed in its only firm (Williamson, 1988). If such kind of asset is transferred to

another firm, it will lose value to some extent. In order to get innovative technologies in

some area, firms need to input a lot of human and financial resources continuously, which

means long investment horizon. High failure rate refers to the high uncertainty of R&D

activities, means that the expenditure in R&D investments may not get any return or may

get some return only after many years. Because of these characteristics of R&D activities,

financing for them is different from other kind of investments (Bah and Dumontier, 2001;

Singh and Faircloth, 2005).

2.1.3 R&D investments and firm value

It is commonly shared by the literature that R&D investments are crucial to the

technology intensive firms and ensure their sustainability and competitiveness

(Mezghanni, 2009). Hence, it is expected that R&D investments should help improve

firm performance. Early empirical studies investigated the relationship between R&D

investments and firm value with two approaches. First approach studied the market

8

reaction about announcements of changes in R&D spending. For example, Jarrell et al.

(1985) reported a positive impact of announcements that firms were starting new R&D

projects; Woolridge (1988) studied the market response to the announcements of long-

term investments including R&D projects, and got the same conclusion with Jarrell et al.

(1985).

The other approach investigated the relationship between R&D investments and

firm value. Ben-Zion (1984) found that R&D intensity has a positive effect on firm‟s

market value. Using a panel of British manufacturing firms, Blundell et al. (1999)

reported a robust and positive relationship between the headcounts of innovation and

market value. Connolly and Hirschey (1984) found the positive effect of R&D

investments on Tobin‟s Q. Using a sample of Australian firms, Chan et al. (2007) found

that higher R&D intensity is associated with better firm value regardless of the

accounting methods used. Above abundant of empirical studies confirmed our

conventional wisdom that it is worth investing in R&D activities.

2.1.4 The determinants of R&D investments

According to the upper-echelons perspective, firms‟ actions are reflections of

their top management teams (Hambrick and Mason, 1984). Therefore, decisions about the

magnitude and allocation of R&D investments are at the discretion of top management

team. Thus, the amount of expenditure on R&D activities depends on managers‟ risk

aversion and preferences. Exploiting the resource-based view, it is obvious that the

resources a firm possesses will determine the type of strategies it will take. What‟s more,

managers‟ decisions and behavior are monitored by various types of shareholders (Jensen

9

and Meckling, 1976). Hence, while shareholders may affect firms‟ R&D investment

decisions through monitoring managers, resources such as internal finance constraint

firms from investing more in R&D activities.

Based on above logic, we can divide literature about the determinants of R&D

investments into two streams. The first stream focuses on the role financial structures

such as financial slack and debt conditions. Researches done in this stream are mainly

based on behavioral search theory, pecking order theory, signaling, and agency theory.

The second stream concentrates on the influence of ownership structure. Because

different types of owners have different preferences, investment horizons and monitoring

power (Hoskisson et al., 2002), they may have different influences on firm‟s strategic

decisions such R&D investments. Researches that have been done in this stream mostly

draw on agency theory. This paper will review the determinants of R&D investments

according to these two streams.

2.2 Ownership structure

As Williamson (1963) suggested, ownership structure is the basis of corporate

governance. Abundant studies have been done on the effects of ownership structure on

firm performance, capital structure, innovation and diversification strategy and other

aspects. Thus, the research studying about the effects of ownership structure on R&D

investments becomes one main area. Since controlling ownership and institutional

ownership are of most significance in ownership structure, especially in emerging

markets, the following sections are going to review the literature on the roles of

institutional investors and controlling owners.

10

2.2.1 Controlling owner

Different from developed countries such as US and UK where shareholder

protection is good, publicly listed firms in most countries are usually characterized with

concentrated ownership structure and controlled by a single and large shareholder

(Claessens et al., 2000; La Porta et al., 1999; Faccio et al., 2002). Previous studies name

this kind of shareholder as controlling owner or controlling shareholder. These

controlling owners are usually the founders of firms or their family members. According

to the data of Classens et al. (2000), more than two thirds of controlling shareholders in

Asian countries are family owners. In firms with controlling owners, there are little

separation between control and ownership. These controlling owners generally own more

control rights than cash flow rights through a pyramidal structure, cross-share holdings

and issuing multi-class shares (Cronqvist and Nilsson, 2003; Yeh, 2005). Reviewing the

literature on the role of controlling shareholder, we can find two opposite perspectives,

namely agency perspective and stewardship perspective.

Agency perspective

According to the early work of agency theory, Jensen and Meckling (1976)

argued that the interest conflicts between owners and managers are minimized in family

firms. However, they also noted that family owners have the incentive to expropriate

from minority shareholders. Later researchers developed this view as principle-principle

conflict perspective (PP). This expropriation can happen because controlling shareholder

can not only control how to run his firm, but also determine how to distribute firm‟s

profits (Classens and Fan, 2003). As long as they don‟t have 100% ownership, they may

11

consume lots of perquisites before distribute profits to other shareholders. La Porta et al.

(2000) emphasized that expropriation from minority shareholders are more likely to

happen in countries where there is limited investor protection. They also listed the forms

of expropriations such as asset stripping, resource transferring and ownership dilution.

Thus, while controlling shareholders largely reduce the agency cost of managers, whether

their presences are good for firms depends on their expropriation behaviors.

Based on PP perspective, researchers have done lots of studies hoping to find the

evidence of expropriation (Joh, 2003; Shleifer and Vishny, 1997; Wiwattanakantang,

2001; Yeh, 2005). Using data from Korean firms during 1993-1997, Joh (2003) found

that controlling shareholders‟ expropriation happens when their ownership is lower. His

study indicates the negative effect of control-ownership disparity. He also found “the

tunneling” behavior, which is one way of expropriation among affiliates of large business

groups. Exploiting the data from Taiwan listed firms, Yeh (2005) got the same

conclusion as Joh (2003) that the corporate value is lower when the gap between control

rights and cash flow rights is larger. Wiwattanakantang (2001) reported the positive

relationship between firm value and family ownership for Thailand firms where family

owners usually don‟t adopt pyramidal structures. Above empirical studies seem to

confirm the expropriation behavior of controlling owners.

Stewardship perspective

While agency theory assumes that man is self-interested, stewardship theory

argues that owners and managers are motivated by high order needs such as growth,

achievement and self-actualization, and they promote pro-organizational and

12

collectivistic behaviors (Davis et al., 1997). Since family owners‟ fortune and reputation

are closely tied to their businesses, they have deep emotional investment and

psychological attached to their firms (Bubolz, 2001). Burkart et al. (2003) and Casson

(1999) claimed that family owners generally want to pass their firms to next generations.

Anderson and Reeb (2003) identified that strategic investments in family firms are long-

term oriented. Le Breton-Miller and Miller (2006) and David and Laurie (2008)

suggested that family firms tend to have long-term orientation in other activities, say,

maintaining long run relationships with debt holders and suppliers. All these points seem

to support Miller and Le Breton-Miller‟s (2006) argument that stewardship attitude is

more likely to breed in family business.

Since most controlling shareholders are family owners, there are several studies

trying to discern whether controlling owners are stewards (Eddleston and Kellermanns,

2007; Miller et al., 2008; Zahra et al., 2008). Miller et al. (2008) reported totally support

for stewardship perspective. For instance, they found long-term orientation in strategic

investments, firm‟s reputation and relationships with employees and customers in family

firms. Using data from 248 family firms in food processing industry, Zahra et al. (2008)

found that stewardship-oriented organizational culture is conducive to strategic flexibility

and positively moderate the relationship between family commitment and strategic

flexibility. Eddleston and Kellermanns (2007) by utilizing stewardship theory argued that

altruism in family firm is conducive to breed a participative strategy process in which

firms are more likely to improve performance.

13

2.2.2 Institutional investors

Institutional investors are specialized financial institutions which consist of

pension funds, insurance companies, mutual funds (Davis and Steil, 2001). They are

playing more and more important role in the global stock markets as their assets increases

(Hansen and Hill, 1991). These investors usually hold diversified portfolios and provide a

better trade-off of risk and return than individual investors. Previous scholars (see David

et al., 2001; Hoskisson et al., 2002) classified institutional investors into two categories:

short-term oriented and long-term oriented. Pension funds and insurance companies are

identified as long-term investors, since they are both instruments for long-term saving

and their goals are to get long-term returns (Fortune, 1993). Gilson and Kraakman (1991)

suggested that pension funds emphasize indexing and usually have an investment horizon

for about 10 years. However, mutual funds and other professional investment funds are

more interested in short-term return, since short-term return is the most important

indicator showing whether their management teams are competent. Individual investors

generally choose professional investment funds according to their short-term returns.

What‟s more, these professional investment fund managers have the incentive to compete

in the short-term return, since their compensation is market-based (Khorana, 1996).

As different types of institutional investors have different investment horizons and

focuses, there monitoring powers and influences on invested firms are different (Douma

et al, 2006). For pension funds, they are active in monitoring firms and care for firms‟

long-term developments (Fortune, 1993). While for mutual funds, they trade frequently

and vote by feet when firm‟s performance is poor (Froot et al., 1992). Based on their

14

different monitoring power and trading behavior, there have been a lot of studies done

regarding their influences on firm performance and strategic decisions.

2.2.3 Ownership structure and R&D investments

Previous studies mainly use agency theory to investigate the influences of

ownership structure on R&D investments. Agency problem happens because of interests‟

conflict and information asymmetry between owners and managers (Fama and Jensen,

1983; Eisenhardt, 1989). Thus, previous researchers link R&D investments with

ownership structure in terms of incentive misalignment and information asymmetry (Lee

and O‟Neill, 2003).

Incentive misalignment: Abundant of studies pointed out that top management

teams tend to be reluctant in investing in R&D (e.g., Froot et al., 1992; Stein, 1988;

Jensen and Meckling, 1976), which is named as “managerial myopic” behavior. One

thing to support this argument is that R&D investment involves high risk and high failure

rate. While outside shareholders can diversify risk by holding diversified portfolios,

managers cannot and bear high risk since their job safety and compensation are related to

firms‟ performance in their contract‟s periods (Hoskisson et al., 1993; Kor, 2006; Laverty,

1996). So managers tend to build empires and invest more in marketing and acquisition

activities to get firm‟s good short-term performance (Kor, 2006). The other thing is that

managers usually get pressures from stockholders who are interested in short-term

financial return (Froot et al., 1992). These stockholders may sell their stock when they

see the bad quarterly or annually reports (Froot et al., 1992; Lee and O‟Neill, 2003). If

many investors have the same opinion toward the announcement of these reports, namely

15

to sell the stocks, then the firms‟ value will decrease. What‟s more, as Laverty (1996)

argued that the professional investment institutions evaluate the value of a firm

emphasizing less on the intangible assets which are the results of R&D investments. Thus,

in order to get good pay and secure their jobs, managers wouldn‟t like to take the risk of

investing on the long-run. Therefore, because of the misaligned incentives, managerial

opportunism has been identified as one obstacle for R&D investments by many

researchers.

Information asymmetry: Information asymmetry between owners and managers

would lead to the inappropriate evaluation of R&D investments (Laverty, 1996; Lee and

O‟Neill, 2003), which is identified as another obstacle of R&D investments. One reason

for existence of information asymmetry is that outsider stockholders have costs to collect

information on firm‟s strategic actions (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). For the other, the

nature of information on R&D investments put some obstacles for outsiders to get to

know them (Myers, 1984). The information publication on the R&D projects would put

the firm at a competitive disadvantage if this information provides crucial signal to its

competitors (Bhattacharya and Ritter, 1983). Thus, Lee and O‟Neill (2003) argued that

frequent communication between managers and investors can help alleviate the latter

ones‟ pressure.

2.2.4 Empirical evidence

Lots of empirical studies have been contributed to study the relationship between

ownership and R&D investments using above two explanations (i.e. managerial myopic

and information asymmetry). Most of these studies focus on the effect of institutional

16

ownership. In the 1980s, as the level of institutional ownership of public firms increases,

researchers began to worry about its effect on long-term investment such R&D projects

(Graves, 1988). Researchers such as Drucker (1986), Mitroff (1987) and Scherer (1984)

held the view that institutional investors are short-term oriented which lead to their

myopic investment strategy. However, the first empirical study done on this issue by

Jarrell and Lehn (1985) indicated the opposite.

The debate regarding the role of institutional investors didn‟t stop at their work,

but led to more empirical studies. For example, using firm data in the computer industry,

Graves (1988) found that increased institutional investor ownership decreases R&D

investments; Baysinger et al. (1991) reported the positive effect for 176 Fortune 500

firms; longitudinal study conducted by Hansen and Hill (1991) also indicate the positive

effect. For the above contrary conclusions, Hoskisson et al. (2002) provided one

persuasive argument that different types of institutional investors have different

investment horizons. Therefore, empirical studies using datasets composed by different

weights of types of institutional investors might lead to different conclusions.

Regarding the effect of controlling ownership on long-term investment, empirical

studies are sparse and most of them were done in recent years. Using panel data of U.S.

family and non-family firms and exploiting Bayesian approach, Block and Thams (2008)

didn‟t find evidence that family firms are more long-term oriented. However, Kim et al.

(2008) reported that controlling owners promote R&D investments for Korean firms.

Therefore, more empirical studies need to be done to discern the role of controlling

owners on R&D investments.

17

2.3 Financial structure

According to resource-based view, the resources a firm possesses decide its

strategy. Financial factors such as financial slack and debt condition have been

considered as important resources in determining firm‟s R&D investments. While

organizational researchers, such as Cyert, March and Bourgeois, emphasized the

important role of slack resources in promoting firm‟s experimentation and innovation

activities, financial researcher, such as Myers, Majluf and Williamson, argued that debt

condition has enormous effect on financing R&D projects. The literature on financial

slack, leverage ratio and their relationships with R&D investments is reviewed in

following paragraphs.

2.3.1 Financial slack and R&D investments

Slack resources

The concept “slack” has been the focus of organizational literature for a long time

since Cyert and March‟s (1963) work, and it was usually treated as independent variable

to explain organizational behavior (Bourgeois, 1981). Since different scholars captured

different aspects and functions of slack resources, there have been many definitions of

organizational slack (cf. Child, 1972; Cyert and March, 1963; Litschert and Bonham,

1978). Bourgeosi (1981) suggested a definition by paraphrasing March‟s work which was

adopted by most researchers as follows:

Organizational slack is that cushion of actual or potential resources which allows an organization

to adapt successfully to internal pressures for adjustment or to external pressures for change in

policy, as well as to initiate changes in strategy with respect to the external environment.

18

As he suggested, it is important to operationalize slack in terms of measurable

items to facilitate empirical study. Based on his work, Bourgeois and Singh (1983)

classified slack into three categories: available slack, recoverable and potential slack.

Sharfman et al. (1988) simplified their classification and identified slack resources from

high discretion (e.g. cash, marketable securities) to low discretion (e.g. inventory, labor

and low flexibility machine capacity). This paper is going to investigate the role of

financial slack, which is one kind of high-discretion slack, including cash and receivables

(Greve, 2003; George, 2005; Kim et al., 2008).

Regarding to the functions of slack, there have been two contrary views.

Proponents of slack such as Cyert and March (1963), Bourgeois (1981), Singh (1986)

argued that slack resources allow firms to engage in experimentation and innovation

activities. According to the economic equilibrium theory, there should be no slack in the

equilibrium point. Thus, opponents of slack viewed it as phenomenon of inefficiency and

argued that slack breeds the sense of complacency in organization and diminish

incentives to innovate (Nohria and Gulati, 1996). Agency theorists such as Jensen and

Meckling (1976), Triantis (2000) suggested that slack allows managers to pursue their

own interests and promotes undisciplined R&D projects.

Slack and innovation

According to the perspective from Cyert and March (1963) and their following

proponents, it is definitely the case that slack promotes R&D activities. Several empirical

studies have showed supports for it. Using the questionnaires data of 64 large U.S. and

19

Canadian firms and exploiting structure model equation, Singh (1986) reported that both

absorbed and unabsorbed slack have a positive relationship with risk taking projects.

Zajac et al. (1991) studied the factors that might enhance innovation in internal corporate

joint venture, and found that organizational slack is positively related to innovativeness.

However, organizational economists and agency theorists claim that slack is kind

of unnecessary cost and is not conducive to innovation. Thus, this view predicts negative

relationship between slack and R&D investments. Nohria and Gulati (1996) reconciled

above contradictive views by arguing that there is an inverse U-shaped relationship

between slack and innovation, which was also supported by their empirical test. Kim et al.

(2008) provided further evidence for Korean firms that the relationship between slack and

R&D investments is curvilinear. Therefore, these studies showed that certain amount of

slack resources is needed for innovation while too much slack indicates wastes of

resources.

2.3.2 Capital structure and R&D investments

Since Modigliani and Miller (1958) advanced the classic proposition about the

capital structure „irrelevance‟, the theory of capital structure started. Various theories

such as pecking order theory, information asymmetry perspective, transaction cost theory

and agency theory were developed to investigate organizational factors‟ influences on

capital structure. On the other hand, capital structure is an important factor affecting the

whole organization, from performance to strategic decisions. While researchers in the

area of strategy mainly emphasized that the kind of strategy (innovation strategy or

diversification strategy) a firm pursues affects capital structure, most financial

20

researchers claimed that capital structure decides strategy. In the following paragraphs,

this paper first reviews the literature about the traditional explanations of capital structure,

then the causal relationship between capital structure and R&D investments, and finally

the empirical evidence.

Traditional explanation of capital structure

Modigliani and Miller (1958) stated: “in the absence of taxes, bankruptcy costs,

and asymmetric information, and in an efficient market, the value of a firm is unaffected

by how that firm is financed”, which means that a firm‟s financial structure is irrelevant

to its investment decision. This famous conclusion violated conventional wisdom at that

time and ignited interest in the study of capital structure. However, the real world is not

that frictionless. Several years later, Modigliani and Miller (1963) corrected their model

by relaxing the assumption of a tax-free world and got the conclusion that the value of a

firm is positively related to leverage ratio, which is because of the tax benefits of interest

payments.

While Modigliani and Miller (1963) showed the tax benefits of debt financing,

other researchers found the costs of it. We can find two kinds of costs of debt financing

from the literature. First, Jensen and Meckling (1976) pointed out that there‟re agency

costs of debt. In their model, owner-manager of a firm first issues debt, and then decides

what investments to take. In the modern corporation, owner-manager has limited liability,

thus moral hazard problem happens. The equity holders have incentives to pursue riskier

investment projects, since the downside risk of the investment decisions are borne by the

bondholders. Realizing this problem, the bondholders will probably demand protection

21

via monitoring and bonding mechanisms, or demand a premium, which increases the

costs of debt financing. Second, financial distress is another cost of debt financing. When

a firm cannot meet its debt obligations, it causes the firm to lose value going through

bankruptcy (Andrade and Kaplan, 1998). Jensen (1986) corrected the conclusion that

there are agency costs associated with debt financing, and argued that it also has some

benefits. Realizing that managers are self-interested and may invest in unproductive

projects, he noted that debt financing increased the leverage ratio and deceased the

amount of free cash flow that managers have discretion over, thus reduce the total agency

costs within a firm.

Another different perspective on capital structure is Myers and Majluf‟s (1984)

pecking order theory. Their model showed that internal finance is most preferred because

of information asymmetry and capital market imperfection. When internal finance is not

sufficient, the firm will issue debt first and then equity.

The links between capital structure and R&D investments

After the classic work of Modigliani and Miller (1958), various theories were

developed to study the puzzle of capital structure. These theories include pecking order

theory, transaction cost theory, information asymmetry perspective. Although some of

them indicate the influences of characteristics of R&D investments on the choice of

financing, others study the effect of leverage ratio on R&D investments. However, these

theories seem to predict the same relationship between leverage ratio and R&D intensity.

Each of these theories is reviewed in the following paragraphs respectively:

22

Information asymmetries: As argued previously, regarding the investments on

R&D activities, while the information asymmetry problem exists between managers and

shareholders, it also exists between managers and debtholders because of the

confidentiality nature of R&D projects (Bhattacharya and Ritter, 1983). As Jensen and

Meckling (1976) pointed out, after R&D projects are financed, moral hazard problems

may happen. Because of the limited liability, shareholders have the incentive to invest in

riskier projects. Realizing this problem and the difficulty to monitor their behavior,

debtholders usually demand high premium on their finance. Bah and Dumontier (2001)

argued that his high premium makes equity financing more attractive than debt financing.

Thus, if firms pursing innovation strategy finance R&D projects using equity, the

leverage ratio should be maintained at a low level.

Transaction cost theory: Williamson (1988) suggested that debt financing is

preferred to equity when the transaction cost of negotiation is low. He argued that the

transaction cost is positively related to asset-specificity. For example, when a firm‟s

asset-specificity is lower, it can be easily redeployed and sold to other firm. Thus, it

transaction cost is lower when debtholders execute the option of asset sales and

liquidation. But when a firm‟s asset cannot be easily sold to another firm (high asset

specificity), the cost of transferring these assets are high (Long and Ravenscraft, 1993). It

is well known that R&D investments are highly specialized that have low redeployability.

Therefore, the implication from Williamson‟s theory is similar to the perspective of

information asymmetry.

23

Leverage as bonding device: Similar to above transaction cost perspective, assets

generated by R&D investments are not only highly specialized, but also worth low value

when severs as collateral guarantee (Long and Malitz, 1985). Without sufficient collateral

guarantee, debt provides are unlikely to lend money to these firms. Thus, a firm invests

too much in R&D activities cannot support high leverage ratio. On the other hand, as

Mishra and McConaughy (1999) suggested, high leverage ratio indicating the high

default of risk increases difficulty in funding for R&D projects. Therefore, a firm with a

high leverage ratio is less likely to be financed. Above two points predict the negative

relationship between leverage ratio and R&D intensity.

Myopic cash flow generation: Peyer and Shivdasani (2001) suggested that

debtholders prefer firms to follow stable strategies that can generate cash flow in short-

term, rather than investing in risky R&D projects. When a firm‟s leverage is higher, they

will force managers focusing on generating cash flow to pay the interest of their debts.

Free cash flow is very important in …Thus, reduced free cash flow makes the firm‟s

current R&D projects uncontinuous or invests less for future projects. Whited (1992)

supported for this view by arguing that higher leveraged firms face greater financial

constraints. More financial constraint makes firm more difficult in getting finance for

R&D activities. Hence, higher leverage ratio prevents firm pursuing innovation strategy

and decreases the expenditure in R&D projects.

Empirical evidence

Most empirical studies have confirmed above prediction that leverage ratio is

negatively associated with R&D intensity. Using a sample of 971 COMPUSTAT firms,

24

Baysinger and Hoskisson (1989) found strong significant negative relationship between

the long-term leverage ratio and R&D intensity. Bhagat and Welch (1995) reported a

negative relation between debt levels and R&D expenses. By comparing a sample of

R&D intensive firms to a sample of non-R&D ones for firms in the UK, US, Japan and

Europe, Bah and Dumontier (2001) found the former ones exhibit significantly lower

leverage ratio and dividend payout ratio, but longer debt maturity and higher cash levels.

Using a sample of large US manufacturing corporations, Singh and Faircloth (2005)

found a strong negatively relationship between leverage ratio and the level of R&D

expenditure that firms undertake. Jordan et al. (1998) found that innovation-based

strategy is associated with the lowest level of debt, while cost-leadership based strategy

had the highest leverage ratio. O‟Brien (2003) got the same conclusion that innovation-

based strategy is associated with the lower level of debt.

However, above empirical studies were done based on the contexts of developed

countries. Empirical studies regarding the relationship between capital structure and

R&D investments in emerging markets are sparse. Different institutional background and

governance mechanisms in emerging markets may change above conclusion that is

derived from developed countries.

2.4 Ownership structure and financial structure

2.4.1 Ownership structure and financial slack

Investigating the influence of ownership structure on firm‟s strategic decisions,

performance and other aspects has been the main research area in the domain of corporate

25

governance. However, according to my literature review, rare research has been done on

the direct relationship between ownership structure and financial slack. Most studies have

contributed to study the relationships between ownership structure and financial policies

such as dividend policy using agency theory. Since retained earnings are the main source

of financial slack, we may find some implicit relationships between ownership structure

and financial slack in the financial economics and strategy literatures.

The link between ownership structure and financial policy is recognized in many

early works such as Williamson (1964) and Jensen (1986). Based on their recognition,

later scholars have done lots of studies on the relationship between managerial ownership

and dividend policy (for example, Rozeff, 1982; Jensen et al., 1992; Eckbo and Verma,

1994). Until 1990s, researchers began to realize the role of institutional investors in

affecting firm‟s financial policy (for example, Chaganti and Damanpour, 1991; Bathala et

al., 1994). As the recent increasing interests in the domain of family business, researchers

in this area start to investigate the relationship between family ownership and dividend

policy (for example, Faccio et al, 2001; Hu et al. 2007).

In the eyes of agency theorists, ownership structure and dividend policy are all

governance mechanisms that can be used to align the interests between managers and

owners. For example, Jensen and Meckling (1976) suggested that increasing managerial

ownership can help mitigate the interest conflicts between managers and owners; Rozeff

(1982) and Easterbrook (1984) claimed that increasing dividends payout reduces the cash

at the discretion of managers and forces them to get additional funds from external capital

market, which in turn will monitor their behavior. Hence, managerial ownership and

26

dividends have the same function in reducing agency cost. Exploiting their substitution

effects, Crutchley and Hansen (1989) found the negative relationship between managerial

ownership and dividend payout ratio. Using simultaneous equation, Jensen et al. (1992)

got the same relationship.

Regarding the role of institutional investors on dividend policy, previous studies

are mainly based on tax-based theory and agency theory. From tax-based perspective, it

is well known that institutional investors have tax benefits. Thus, institutional investors

are likely to demand more dividend payout ratio. From agency perspective, Jensen (1986)

points out that managers tend to retain cash under their control and pay less dividends. In

order to reduce agency cost, institutional investors may force managers to pay more

dividends (Short et al., 2002). Therefore, above two perspectives all predict the positive

relationship between institutional ownership and dividend ratio. However, Grinstein and

Michaely (2005) claimed that there is selection procedure in which institutional investors

choose invested firms. Empirical researches on this line also produced mixed results.

Short et al. (2002) found the positive relationship between institutional ownership and

dividend policy using UK panel data; using data of public U.S. firms, Grinstein and

Michaely (2005) didn‟t find any relationship between them; Kouki and Guizani (2009)

found significant negative relationship for Tunisian firms. For above inconsistency, I

would think the context matters on one hand. On the other hand, as Hoskisson et al.

(2002) pointed out, institutional investors are heterogeneous and have different

investment horizons. Hence, long-term oriented institutional investors may not demand

too much dividends on the short run while short-oriented ones probably will do.

27

Controlling owners are criticized by researchers such as La Porta et al. (2000) and

Faccio et al. (2002) on their expropriation behavior from minority shareholders. They are

claimed to pay lower dividend ratio (Faccio et al., 2002). Hu et al. (2007) supported this

argument, and found that family firms pay lower dividend than nonfamily firms.

However, direct empirical evidence on the relationship between controlling ownership

and dividend ratio is really sparse.

2.4.2 Ownership structure and capital structure

Earlier studies on the relationship between ownership structure and capital

structure concern about the role of managerial ownership. Amihud and Lev (1981)

argued that professional managers have undiversified employment risk and tend to reduce

it by ensuring the viability of their firms. Since high leverage ratio increases the

probability of financial stress, Friend and Long (1988) claimed that decreasing the debt

holdings can reduce managers‟ employment risk. Thus, based on managers‟ self-interest

behavior, it might be the case that they hold the debt level below the optimal level

(Brailsford et al., 2002).

As managerial ownership helps align the interests between managers and

shareholders, its effect on capital structure has drawn amount of studies (see Brailsford et

al., 2002; Crutchley and Hansen, 1989; Jensen et al., 1992). Incentive alignment will

prompt manager to behave on the behalf of shareholders (Morck et al., 1988). Thus,

increasing managerial ownership will increase debt holding. However, as their ownership

increases to a point, McConnell and Servaes (1990) argued that entrench effect will

dominate and results in managerial opportunism. Therefore, above logic suggests an

28

inverted U-shaped relationship between managerial ownership and leverage ratio.

Brailsford et al. (2002) found support for this argument while most of earlier studies such

Crutchley and Hansen (1989) and Jensen et al. (1992) found a negative relationship.

From the agency perspective, most of governance mechanisms are designed to

constraint managerial opportunism. The role of institutional investors is identified as a

way to increasing shareholders‟ monitoring power (Friend and Lang, 1998). Thus, when

managers pursue a strategy that the debt level is below optimal, institutional investors

may have influence in countering their decision. Therefore, this perspective predicts the

positive relationship between leverage ratio and institutional ownership. Brailsford et al.

(2002) supported for this perspective. However, an alternative view leads the opposite

conclusion. Jensen‟s (1986) cash flow theory indicates that debt is a way to reduce

agency cost, since interest payment of debt reduces managers‟ control over firm‟s cash

flow. Thus, debt policy has been viewed as internal governance mechanism by agency

theorists in restricting managers‟ self-interest pursuing behavior where institutional

investors play the same function (Grossman and Hart, 1980). According this view, debt

policy and the role of institutional investors can be substituted by each other. Hence, a

negative relationship is expected between them, which is also supported by Bathala et al.

(1994)‟s empirical study.

As the resurgence in the area of family business, several studies have contributed

to investigate the capital structure in family firms (King and Santor, 2008; Mishra and

McConaughy, 1999). As similar to managers, controlling owners hold undiversified

stakes in their firms. Thus, they care for firm‟s viability and long-term development

29

(Anderson and Reeb, 2003; Anderson et al., 2003; Villalonga and Amit, 2006). On the

other hand, family owners fear losing control over their firm (Mishra and McConaughy,

1999). In addition, Burkart et al. (2003) argued that family owners suffer far more lose

than just their assets when going bankruptcy. Hence, family owners have much more

incentive than any types of shareholders in maintaining control and ensuring firms‟

survival (Mishra and McConaughy, 1999). Therefore, King and Santor (2008) and

Mishra and McConaughy (1999) argued that family firms tend to be more risk aversion

and maintain lower level of debt ratio than nonfamily firms. Their empirical studies

showed supports for this view.

2.5 Summary

By reviewing the literature, I found two main determinants of R&D investments,

namely ownership structure and financial structure. However, according to my

knowledge, the literature on the determinants of R&D investments is incomplete, since

these two research streams treat ownership structure and financial structures as separate

factors, even though there are some arguments and empirical evidences showing these

two are interdependent. For example, ownership structure affects firm‟s financial policy

and capital structure. Therefore, the extant literature ignores the potential interplay of

ownership structures and financial structures in decisions where R&D investments are

determined, which may lead to false attribution of causality between those factors and

R&D investments.

30

CHAPTER 3 THEORY AND HYPOTHESES

3.1 Ownership structure and R&D investments

3.1.1 Controlling ownership and R&D investments

Controlling owners in Korean firms are usually founders and founders‟ relatives,

they often present on the board of directors or top management teams (Kim et al., 2008).

As such, controlling owners often have great influence on their firms‟ strategic decisions.

While agency problems may be severe in professional manager-managed firms,

managerial opportunism is largely restricted in firms with controlling owners, since

managers are under effective monitoring or controlling owners may be managers

themselves. Therefore, according to the upper-echelons perspective, in Korean context,

we can conclude that firms‟ R&D investment decisions, to a large extent, depend on

controlling owners‟ intentions.

Reviewing the literature, I have found two conflicting voices about the role of

controlling owner, namely PP perspective and stewardship perspective. And most of

previous studies that done using above two perspectives generally tried to investigate the

relationship between controlling ownership and firm performance. It is obvious as Le

Breton-Miller and Miller (2006) suggested that expropriation behavior is detrimental to

firm performance while stewards can help improve firm performance. While these two

conflicting views may predict the opposites regarding the influences of controlling

ownership on performance, I argue that they don‟t have conflicts in predicting the

relationship between controlling ownership and R&D intensity.

31

Controlling owners can be psychologically tied to their firms (Le Breton-Miller

and Miller, 2006) and want to pass firms to their heirs (Burkart et al.,2003; Casson, 1999).

They can also be long-term oriented in making strategic decisions (Anderson and Reeb,

2003), and maintain long run relationships with employees and suppliers (Le Breton-

Miller and Miller, 2006; David and Laurie, 2008). At the same time, they may pay little

dividend ratio and expropriate from minority shareholders (La Porta et al., 1999; Young

et al., 2008). But as long as controlling owners care for firm‟s viability and long-term

development (Anderson and Reeb, 2003; Villalonga and Amit, 2006) and realize that

R&D investments can help firm generate competitive capabilities (Franko, 1989), they

would like to invest more in R&D activities.

Previous studies investigated the influences of ownership structure on R&D

investments mainly using perspectives derived from agency theory, namely managerial

myopic and information asymmetry. Exploiting these perspectives also suggests a positive

relationship between controlling ownership and R&D intensity. For the managerial

myopic problem, no matter the firm is owner-managed or not, managers pursuing self-

interest behavior should be largely restricted as controlling ownership increases, because

the benefits of monitoring increase. According to Lee and O‟Neill (2003), increased

ownership would increase owners‟ incentive to collect information about R&D projects,

which leads to their appropriation valuation on these projects. What‟s more, controlling

owners usually grow with their firms and are very familiar with the businesses and

projects. Thus, they will evaluate R&D activities appropriately. Therefore, in the firms

with controlling owners, the problems of managerial myopic and information asymmetry

which impede managers from investing in R&D projects don‟t exist anymore.

32

Therefore, both stewardship theory and agency theory predict the positive

relationship between controlling ownership and R&D intensity.

H1: Controlling ownership is positively associated with R&D intensity.

3.1.2 Institutional ownership and R&D investments

Foreign institutional ownership in emerging markets is mostly owned by

institutional investors from U.S. and European countries (Choe et al., 1999). As the

economies globalized and liberalized, these investors hold more and more diversified

percentages of stock portfolios in emerging markets to reduce systematic risk. According

to the statistics published in Business Week (2006), foreign ownership has increased to 42%

of public Korean firms in terms of capitalization in year 2006. Although the aggregate

ownership is large, their ownerships are usually dispersed as long as their goals are to

diversify risk. Korean laws also don‟t allow foreign investor to hold a large proportion of

shares in one company (Jung and Kwon, 2002). Another characteristic of foreign

institutional investors is that they trade frequently (David et al., 2006), since most of

foreign investors are professional investment companies who tend to have short-term

horizons and need to shuffle their portfolios. These characteristics and their orientation

make them behave like Korean domestic financial institutional investors (Choe et al.,

1999; Kim et al., 2008). Thus, in the following paragraphs, I will use the term

“institutional investors” refer to foreign institutional investors and domestic financial

institutional investors.

For the role of institutional investors, most prior studies have showed the positive

relationship between institutional ownership and R&D investments (Hansen and Hill,

33

1991; Hill and Snell, 1988). For these studies, their argument is that increased ownership

reduce information asymmetry problem, which lead to their appropriate evaluation on

firms‟ innovation activities. Hoskisson et al. (2002) provided more detailed analysis of

institutional investors. They argued that different types of institutional investors have

different strategy orientation. Since these studies are all done in U.S. context, the focus is

on the conflicting preferences between institutional investors and managers concerning

about R&D projects, where there is an agent context according to Lee and O‟Neill (2003)

and the latter ones are supposed to prefer short-term investments.

However, the case is different in Korea where the conflicting preferences are

between institutional investors and controlling owners. While the latter ones are usually

strategic investors who prefer R&D investments, I argue that some conditions make

institutional investors more likely to be short-term oriented compare to the U.S. context.

First, weak laws on shareholder protection don‟t guarantee investors‟ return (La Porta et

al., 2000). Second, most of foreign investors are investment companies and less of them

are pension funds. In addition, according to Hoskisson et al. (2002), foreign institutional

investors tend not to be interested in R&D investments.

While prior studies that support the positive relationship between institutional

ownership and R&D investments assuming that institutional investors have pressures on

managers in U.S., I argue they may not have influence on controlling owners in Korea.

David et al. (2001) found that ownership alone is not sufficient to firms‟ R&D

investments decisions. And they argue that only engaging in activism such as initiation of

shareholder proposals, negotiations with managers and the launching of proxy contests

34

can have effect on managers‟ decision. However, in Korean, institutional investors are

not allowed to exercise voting rights based on the “shadow voting” rule before the 1997

financial crisis (Hong and Lee, 1998). Although this restriction was removed after the

crisis and other corporate governance reforms implemented in Korea, the power and

influence of institutional investors is still not as strong as theirs in US (Solomon et al.,

2002). Therefore, I get the following hypothesis:

H2: Institutional ownership is not associated with R&D intensity.

3.2 The mediating effects of financial structures

3.2.1 Financial slack and R&D investments

Although existing literature indicated two contrary views on the role of financial

slack on innovation, namely promoting innovation and wastes of resources, I would think

they have the same implication on the relationship between financial slack and R&D

investments. First, proponents of slack all agreed that more slack resources allow firms to

take more experimentation and engage in more R&D activities (Bourgeois, 1981; Cyert

and March, 1963). Second, opponents of slack emphasized that too much slack resources

are the indicator of inefficiency and allow managers to pursue their own interests, for

example, engaging in excessive diversification and investing more in unproductive R&D

projects (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Thus, opponents of slack resources acknowledge

that more resources will lead to more R&D activities but may not lead to more innovation.

Innovation is the result of R&D investments, but not all R&D investments would lead to

35

innovation. As Holmstrom (1989) pointed out, innovation requires both strong

managerial incentives and careful monitoring.

As long as this paper concerns about the determinants of R&D investments, these

above two views all support the argument that more financial slack would lead to more

R&D investments where the opponent view claimed that these R&D investments may not

be transformed to innovation.

3.2.2 Leverage ratio and R&D investments

According to pecking order theory, because of information asymmetry problem,

internal finance is first preferred, then debt and equity is ranked at the bottom among this

three. However, the characteristics of R&D activities make information asymmetry

problem severer and debt financing more inappropriate than equity (Bah and Dumontier,

2001). So firms who want to invest in R&D projects have to finance internally or through

equity. Hence, firms pursuing innovativeness should exhibit lower leverage ratio.

Transaction cost theory tells us that transaction cost is positively related to asset-

specificity (Williamson, 1988). R&D investment is considered to be highly specialized

and the results of it such as patents are not easily deployed by other firms, which makes

R&D assets as poor collateral. Thus, R&D investments cannot support a high level of

debt (Long and Malitz, 1995).

Above theories all investigate the effects of R&D investments on capital structure.

However, capital structure also influences R&D investments in turn. Higher debt ratio

increases the probability of bankruptcy and the difficulty in financing for R&D projects

(Mishra and McConaughy, 1999). Whited (1992) supported this view by arguing that

36

higher leveraged firms face greater financial constraints. Therefore, increased leverage

ratio is associated with less R&D investments. No matter how R&D investments affects

capital structure and how leverage ratio influences R&D investments, above perspectives

all predict the negative relationship between the two.

3.2.3 The mediating effects of financial slack

Controlling owner

Controlling owners are identified by previous researchers as long-term oriented

(Anderson and Reeb, 2003; David and Laurie, 2008), it is unlikely that these firms would

pay large amount of dividends (Jensen et al., 1992; Hu et al., 2007), since more retained

earnings can help firm get out of financial distress and grasp growth opportunities

(Mishra and McConaughy, 1999). What‟s more, according to the tax policy, as

controlling owners are generally individuals, they will pay higher dividend tax ratio than

institutional investors. Thus, controlling owners probably would prefer lower dividend

ratio to avoid high tax rate. Hu et al. (2007) provided evidence for above argument that

family firms tend to have lower dividend payout ratio than nonfamily firms. Lower

dividends payout ratio increases firm‟s financial slack indirectly.

Controlling owners are identified as psychologically tied to their firms and even

take them as “children” (Bubolz, 2001). Thus, they have strong incentive to maintain and

ensure control over their firms (Mishra and McConaughy, 1999). As issuing equity will

dilute their control, study of De Angelo and De Angelo (1985) indicates that controlling

owners usually issue non-voting stocks. As the market imperfection and information

asymmetry problems make external finance such as equity and debt more expensive

37

(Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Myers and Majluf, 1984), controlling owners are more

likely to rely on internal finance. Internal finance generally comes from firm‟s retained

earnings, which are important part of financial slack. Hence, I predict that controlling

owners tend to maintain high level of financial slack.

Institutional investors

From the agency perspective, institutional owners tend to demand more dividends

in order to reduce agency costs. However, there is no consistent empirical conclusion

about it (see Grinstein and Michaely, 2005; Kouki and Guizani, 2009; Short et al., 2002).

Based on the implication from Hoskisson et al. (2002) that institutional investors are

heterogeneous, I argue that the relationship between dividend payout ratio and

institutional ownership depends on the types of top management teams and institutional

investors. In the context of Korea, it is clear that the top management teams are usually

controlled by family owners to a large extent. As suggested by La Porta et al. (2000),

they may behave like entrenched managers who will expropriate from minority investors.

Thus, their expropriation incentives and poor shareholder protection will force

institutional investors demand more dividends. In addition, institutional investors in

emerging markets are usually mutual funds and other types of professional investors who

are short-term oriented. So these institutional investors focus on the short-term return

rather than long-term return. Hence, for the certain environment in Korea, it is likely that

institutional ownership is positively related to dividend payout ratio.

The problem is whether institutional investors can affect controlling owners‟

financial policies or not. Controlling owners may need the presences of institutional

38

investors on their firms‟ shareholders list to signal outsider investors that their firms are

well run. So they may pay more dividend ratio to please these institutional investors.

What if controlling owners don‟t take this action? I argue that institutional investors can

still adjust their portfolios and choose the companies that pay high dividend ratio, since

they short-term oriented. Higher dividend ratio decreased financial slack, since more

dividends reduce retained earnings. Therefore, this paper predicts that institutional

ownership is negatively associated with financial slack.

3.2.4 The mediating effects of leverage ratio

Controlling owner

Existing literature on ownership and capital structure indicates that the level of

financial leverage depends on “manager‟s risk aversion, the costs of monitoring and

bankruptcy, the threat of takeovers, and the growth opportunities of the firm” (King and

Santor, 2008: 2425). However, these views are developed in developed markets. In the

Korean context, the threats of takeover are very seldom. As there is little separation

between ownership and management, agency cost of managers is largely restricted. So

firm leverage ratio mainly depends on controlling owners‟ risk aversion, the cost of

bankruptcy and growth opportunity.

For their undiversified and large stakes in firms, controlling owners are identified

to be more risk averse than professional managers, since they will lose more than just

their assets (Burkard et al., 2003). As emphasized by Mishra and McConaughy (1999)

that family owners have strong desire to maintain control over their firms and care for

firm‟s survival, the cost of losing control and bankruptcy is extremely large. Although

39

high leverage ratio increases the probability of financial distress, financing through equity

causes other problems. First, underdeveloped equity market in Korea makes the cost of

equity financing much more expensive. It is wildly recognized that Korea corporate

governance is bank-oriented, which makes financing through debt much cheaper. Second,

financing through equity diluted controlling owners‟ control over their firms. It is the

case what controlling owners fear most. Therefore, in order to grow their firms and get

finance for strategic investments, but not to weaken their controls, they are more likely to

finance through debt rather than equity. According to this argument, it is expected that

controlling ownership is positively associated with leverage ratio.

Institutional investors

Agency theorists view both outsider ownership concentration and debt financing

as monitoring devices. Because of substitution effects between these two, increased

institutional ownership makes debt financing less necessary. According to the signaling

model, the presence of institutional investor gives minority shareholders confidence and

signals that the firm is committed (Wiwattanakantang, 1999). Hence, these two theories

predict the negative relationship between leverage ratio and institutional ownership.

Institutional investors‟ frequently trading behaviors which increase the stock

liquidity can help reduce information asymmetry (Brennan and Tamarowshi, 2000),

which further reduce the cost of capital. What‟s more, the presence of institutional

investors on shareholder list gives debtors more confidence that that firm is well-

managed and has low risk of default. Thus, institutional investors may influence

controlling owners‟ finance decisions (David et al., 2006). It is well known that Korean

40

firms are highly leveraged even after 1997 financial crisis. From the lesson of that crisis,

institutional investors may force firms to reduce debt ratio or may tend to choose the

firms that present low level of debt to protect their held stake (Grinstein and Michaely,

2005). Therefore, this paper predicts the negative relationship between institutional

ownership and leverage ratio.

Based on the above arguments, I get the following relationships between

ownership structure, financial structure and R&D investments (refer to Figure 1 and

Figure 2):

H3a: Financial slack mediates the relationship between controlling ownership and R&D

intensity, such that financial slack increases the positive effect of controlling ownership

on R&D intensity;

H3b: Financial slack mediates the relationship between institutional ownership and

R&D intensity, such that institutional ownership indirectly negatively affects R&D

intensity;

H4a: Leverage ratio mediates the relationship between controlling ownership and R&D

intensity, such that leverage ratio decreases the positive effect of controlling ownership

on R&D intensity;

H4b: Leverage ratio mediates the relationship between institutional ownership and R&D

intensity, such that institutional ownership indirectly positively affects R&D intensity.

41

Figure 1. Proposed model of relationships between controlling ownership,

leverage ratio, financial slack and R&D investments.

Figure 2. Proposed model of relationships between institutional ownership,

leverage ratio, financial slack and R&D investments.

Controlling

Ownership

Financial slack R&D

Investments

+

Leverage

ratio

+

- +

Institutional

Ownership

Financial slack

R&D

Investments

- +

Leverage ratio - -

+

42

CHAPTER 4 EMPIRICAL STUDY

4.1 Data and measurements

4.1.1 Sample

To test these hypotheses, I used a database developed by the Korea Investor

Service, which contains information about company‟s profiles, ownership structure and

financial structure for all Korean publicly listed firms. The data structure is similar to

those found in COMPUSTST, and has been used by many previous scholars (see Chang

and Hong, 2002; Kim et al., 2008). Since R&D investment is relatively more important

for manufacturing industry, I selected companies in this industry during the 1995-2007

periods. After eliminating observations with incomplete information, there were 999

firms and 10518 firm-years left for analysis.

4.1.2 Measurements

Dependent and independent variables

Dependent variable: R&D intensity (rdint), was measured by the ratio of

expenditure to total sales. This measure has been widely used by previous studies (e.g.,

Greve, 2003; Lee and O’Neill, 2003; Kim et al., 2008).

Independent variables: (1) Financial slack (fs), was measured by the ratio of

operation cash flow to total sales. According to Singh (1986), financial slack can be

measure by the ratio of quick assets (such as cash and receivables) to total assets or total

sales. Operation cash flow consists of these quick assets.

43

(2) Leverage ratio (da), was measured by the ratio of total debt to total assets.

(3) Controlling ownership (owner_p), was measured by the percentage of equity

shares owned by the person who actually controls the firm and his/her family members

and relatives.

(4) Institutional ownership (inst_p), was measured by the adding foreign

institutional ownership and domestic institutional ownership. Domestic institutional

ownership is the total percentage of equity ownership held by domestic institutional

investors composed of insurance companies, securities firms, and merchant banks, while

foreign institutional ownership is the total percentage of equity ownership held by foreign

financial institutions. These variables and their corresponding abbreviations are listed in

table 1.

Control variables

(1) ROA (roa): net income divided by total assets. ROA indicates the profitability

of a firm which would influence firm‟s strategic decisions directly. Many empirical

studies, e.g., Lotta Vänänen‟s (2003), showed support for it. The profitability of a firm is

also likely to affect its dividend payout ratio and capital structure (Jensen et al., 1992).

(2) Firm size (emp): the total number of employees. Firm size is considered to be

a main factor to explain firm-specific heterogeneity. Choi et al. (2008) showed the

necessity to control it for Korean firms.

(3) Industry R&D intensity (inddrint): average of R&D intensity in the each

detailed industry. It is reasonable to account for industry effect, since the importance of

44

R&D investments to the industry of food products and beverages is different to its

importance to the industry of rubber and plastics products.

(4) Total assets (logta): take the natural log value of total asset. Crutchley and

Hansen (1989)‟s empirical study showed its influence on dividend payout ratio and

capital structure.

(5) Affiliated (bgmember): dummy variable, to control for the affiliated effect.

Affiliated to a business group is very common in Korean firms. This affiliation would

have effect on firm‟s corporate governance mechanisms and possessed resources

(Khanna and Yafeh, 2007).

(6) Export ratio (exportr): the ratio of total export to total sales. Choi et al. (2008)

showed the necessity to control it, because it may be the case that internationally oriented

firms tend to invest more in R&D activities, which would enhance their competitiveness

in international market.

(7) Growth opportunity (go): the increased ratio of total sale. Early studies (e.g.,

David et al., 2006; Wright et al., 1996) talked about the efficiency of R&D investments

by investigating whether these R&D investments are made consistent with growth

opportunity. Thus, it can be expected that when growth opportunity appears, firm is more

likely to investment in R&D activities. What‟s more, previous studies (e.g. Jensen et al.,

1992; Eckbo and Verma, 1994) have showed that growth opportunity affects firm‟s

capital structure and financial slack.

45

(8) Dividend ratio (divr): the percentage of cash dividend amount divided by total

assets. Agency theorists view dividend policy as a tool to reduce agency cost, which is

similar to the function of debt financing. So dividend ratio might have substitute effect on

leverage ratio. As a source of financial slack, dividend ratio is supposed to affect

financial slack. All control variables and their corresponding abbreviations are listed in

table 1.

Table 1. All variables and their corresponding abbreviations

Variables Corresponding

abbreviations

R&D intensity rdint

Financial slack fs

Debt ratio da

Controlling ownership owner_p

Institutional ownership inst_p

ROA roa

Firm size emp

Industry R&D intensity inddrint

Total assets logta

Affiliated bgmember

Export ratio exportr

Growth opportunity go

Dividend ratio divr

4.2 Summary statistics and model design

4.2.1 Summary statistics

Table 2 gives out the sample distribution among each year. From this table, we

can see that the data sample is an unbalance panel. As more and more firms went public,

the number of sample increased in the later years. In the year 1995, the size of Korean

stock market is 566, and it increased to 980 in the year 2007.

46

Table 2. Sample distribution among each year

Year Freq. Percent Cum.

1995 566 5.38 5.38

1996 614 5.84 11.22 1997 645 6.13 17.35

1998 670 6.37 23.72

1999 711 6.76 30.48

2000 763 7.25 37.74 2001 836 7.95 45.68

2002 897 8.53 54.21

2003 938 8.92 63.13 2004 951 9.04 72.17

2005 966 9.18 81.36

2006 981 9.33 90.68 2007 980 9.32 100.00

Total 10,518 100.00

Figure 3. Firms’ R&D intensity on average in the period of 1995-2007

.01

.02

.03

.04

.05

R&

D inte

nsity

1995 2000 2005 2010Year

47

Figure 4. Firms’ ROA on average in the period of 1995-2007

Figure 3 and Figure 4 give out the trends of firm‟s R&D intensity and ROA on

average in the period of 1995-2007. From Figure 3, we can see that R&D intensity firms

increased in first several years and decreased after the year 2001. The trend for ROA is

much more complicated than the trend for R&D intensity. From Figure 4, we can see

that there is a deep decrease in the year 1998, and then a sharp increase in the following

two years, and the main tread of the remaining years is decreasing. We may explain the

first decrease by 1997‟s financial crisis, after which Korean firms cut down budget to

invest in R&D activities. However, we still don‟t know what caused the complicated

change in Korean firms‟ R&D intensity after the year 2000.

-.02

0

.02

.04

.06

RO

A

1995 2000 2005 2010Year

48

Table 3. Summary statistics for all variables

Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max

rdint 10518 .0246 .0468 0 .4880

fs 10518 .0424 .1947 -5.438 1.490

da 10518 .4944 .2081 .0110 .9992

owner_p 10518 .2591 .2236 0 1

inst_p 10518 .0563 .1254 0 1

divr 10518 .0076 .0123 0 .2807

roa 10518 .0321 .1461 -.9888 .9731

emp 10518 697.43 3368.7 1 85813

indrdint 10518 .0684 .1496 0 .8863

logta 10518 10.95 1.492 5.198 17.993

bgmember 7765 .1030 .3040 0 1

go 9677 .1266 .3886 -5.337 5.613

exportr 10518 .2885 .3105 0 1

Table 3 is the summary statistics for all variables. From this table, we can see that

the numbers of observations for variables bgmember and go are less that others‟. For the

former one, it is because there‟re some missing values in my data; while for the latter one,

the value of go is missing in the beginning year for a firm, since I take the first year as a

base year. The mean value for R&D intensity (rdint) is 0.0246 and the maximum value is

0.0468, which indicates the large variance of R&D intensity of Korean firms. It is same

case indicated by Lee and O‟Neill (2003)‟s study. The variance for financial slack (fs) is

even larger, since the minimum value is -5.438, the maximum is 1.490 while the mean is

0.0424. While many scholars have attributed the causes of 1997‟s financial crisis to the

high leverage ratio of Korean Chaebols, the leverage ratio reduced a lot after Korean

government‟s reform. The mean value of leverage ratio (da) is 0.4944. But there are still

some firms with high leverage ratio, since the maximum value is 0.9992. The mean value

of controlling ownership (owner_p) and institutional ownership (inst_p) are 0.2591 and

0 .0563.

49

4.2.2 Model

In order to indentify the direct and indirect effects of ownership structure on R&D

investments, this paper builds a simultaneous equation model as follows:

rdint = f (fs, da, exportr, emp, roa, go, bgmember, indrint, owner_p, inst_p) (1)

fs= g (owner_p, inst_p, divr, logta, roa, go) (2)

da= h (owner_p, inst_p, divr, logta, roa, go) (3)

It is usually the case that top management team makes the budget plans and

strategic decision at the beginning fiscal year, so the factors this year are likely to

influence next year‟s R&D investments. Thus, the variables in the right side of equation

(1) were all lagged by one year except the affiliation indicator, bgmember. In equation (2)

and equation (3) only ownership variables were lagged by one year, since the ownership

effect maybe hysteretic. From above simultaneous equations, we can see that equation (2)

and equation (3) are independent from equation (1) while equation (1) depends on the

other two. Hence, I estimate equation (2) and equation (3) independently and use two-

stage estimation for equation (1). For the estimation of equation (2) and equation (3), I

exploit the most common method, namely Fixed Effect model. To test whether Fixed

Effect model is appropriate, the F statistics and Hausman statistics are reported in the

result.

One characteristic of R&D investment is long investment horizon. While one

R&D project is ratified and starts to implement, various resources are needed

continuously. So it is more likely the case that the expenditure of R&D investments this

50

year is related to it in the last year. Thus, I add lagged dependent variables as independent

variables. For such model setting, it may cause biased estimation while using Ordinary

Least Square (OLS). Using the generalized method of moments (GMM) estimation,

Arellano and Bond (1991) have shown that the lagged dependent and explanatory

variables are valid instruments, under the assumption that the error terms are not serially

correlated. The GMM estimator in such a situation achieves asymptotic efficiency. The

dynamic panel GMM estimation method has advantageous capacities to deal with

unobserved firm-specific heterogeneity, endogeneity problems, and the presence of the

unknown heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation in panel data (Arellano 2003). Therefore,

I used the generalized method of moments (GMM) estimation and dynamic panel data

model – Arellano-Bond regression for equation (1) in the second stage. However, the

validity of the GMM estimation relies on the validity of the assumption that the error

terms are not serially correlated. If the assumption is valid, there should be evidence of

significant negative first-order serial correlation in difference residuals and no evidence

of second-order serial correlation in the difference residuals (Baltagi 2005). Thus, I test

this assumption with an Arellano-Bond test of second-order serial correlation.

4.3 Results

Table 4 is the correlation matrix for all the variables. From this table, we can see

that the correlation coefficients between these variables are all not very high, which

reduces the probability of multicollinearity problem.

The estimation results of equation (2) and equation (3) are illustrated in Table 5.

From the two Hausman statistics and F statistics, we can see that Fixed effect (F.E.)

51

models are appropriate. From the results in Table 5, we can conclude that both

controlling ownership and institutional ownership influence financial slack and leverage

ratio significantly. Hypothesis 3a predicts that controlling ownership positively affects

financial slack. The regression coefficient of controlling ownership (owner_p) in

equation (1) is 0.0306 and is statistically significant, which is consistent with my

prediction. Hypothesis 3b predicts that institutional ownership negatively affects financial

slack. The regression coefficient of institutional ownership (inst_p) in equation (1) is

negative and statistically significant, which indicates my prediction is correct.

My predictions about the influence of ownership structure on capital structure are

that controlling ownership positively affects leverage ratio while institutional ownership

negatively affects leverage ratio. However, the estimation results in equation (2) don‟t

show support for the effect of controlling ownership on leverage ratio but support for the

effect of institutional ownership, since the regress coefficients of controlling ownership

(owner_p) and institutional ownership (inst_p) in equation (2) are -0.0308 and -0.0491,

and both them are statistically significant.

To dismantle the direct and indirect effects of ownership structure on R&D

investments, I used two-stage estimation method. First, to estimate the direct effect of

controlling ownership on R&D investments, I regressed controlling ownership (owner_p)

on financial slack (fs), leverage ratio (da) and other variables and got the predicted value

of owner_p, which is uncorrelated with fs, da. Then, I substituted the owner_p with the

predicted value of owner_p in equation (1). Repeat the same procedures for institutional

ownership (inst_p). Finally, I did the Arellano-Bond dynamic panel-data estimation for

52

equation (1). Hence, in the regression results of Arellano-Bond dynamic panel-data

estimation, the coefficient for controlling ownership (owner_p) is the direct effect of

controlling ownership on R&D investments, while the coefficient for institutional

ownership (inst_p) is the direct effect of institutional ownership on R&D investments.

The two-stage estimation results for the direct and indirect effects of controlling

ownership and institutional ownership on R&D investments are presented in Table 6.

Hypothesis 1 predicts that controlling ownership is positively associated with

R&D intensity. From Table 6, we can see that the coefficient of controlling ownership

(owner_p) is 0.1008 and statistically significant, which means that controlling ownership

has direct positive effect on R&D investments. Thus, hypothesis 1 is supported.

Hypothesis 2 predicts that institutional ownership has no impact on R&D intensity. The

coefficient of institutional ownership (inst_p) is -0.0525 but not statistically significant,

which means that institutional ownership has no direct negative effect on R&D

investments. So hypothesis 2 is also supported.

Hypotheses H3a, H3b, H4a, H4b argue that financial slack and leverage ratio are

mediators through which controlling owners and institutional investors influence R&D

investments. From Table 6, we can see that the coefficients signs for leverage ratio (da)

and financial slack (fs) are negative and positive, and both of them are significant, which

are consistent with my predictions that more financial slack will lead to more R&D

investments while higher leverage ratio is associated with less R&D investments.

Combined with the results presented in Table 5, namely controlling ownership is

positively associated with financial slack and negatively associated with leverage ratio

53

while institutional ownership is negatively associated with both financial slack and

leverage ratio, we can conclude: (1) financial slack positively mediates the relationship

between controlling ownership and R&D intensity; (2) financial slack negatively

mediates the relationship between institutional ownership and R&D intensity; (3)

leverage ratio positively mediates the relationship between controlling ownership and

R&D intensity; (4) leverage ratio positively mediates the relationship between

institutional ownership and R&D intensity. Therefore, Hypotheses H3a, H3b, H4b are

supported, but hypothesis H4a is not supported.

4.4 Robustness test

To check the robustness of above empirical results, I did the following tests:

(1) Delete observations where R&D intensity is above its mean three standard

deviations. After this deletion, repeat the analysis model in Table 5 and Table 6, I found

that both controlling ownership and institutional ownership influences financial structures,

namely financial slack and leverage ratio, significantly with the same impacts as I got in

above empirical studies. I also found that controlling ownership affects R&D intensity

directly while institutional ownership has no direct impact on it. Compared to earlier

study, the only difference after this deletion is that the prediction “financial slack

positively affects R&D intensity” is not supported. Detailed result is presented in Table 7

and Table 8 in Appendix A.

(2) After the 1997‟s financial crisis, Korean government has initiated some

corporate governance reforms. To control for the effects of these institutional change, I

54

choose the sample after year 1997. Consistent with earlier study, I got the same

relationships between ownership structure, financial structure and R&D investments.

Detailed result is presented in Table 9 and Table 10 in Appendix B.

(3) Use the natural logarithm of total assets to measure firm size. In the primary

analysis, I used the number of employees to measure firm size. However, the natural

logarithm total assets is an alternative measure of firm size that is wildly used in the areas

of finance of strategy. Substitute Ln(totoal assets) for the number of employees and

repeat the analysis model in Table 6, I found that no differences compared to the results

in Table 6. Detailed result of this change is presented in Appendix C.

(4) Delete some insignificant control variables. From Table 6, we can see that the

control variables such as firm size (emp), ROA and affiliated (bgmember) don‟t have

significant influence on R&D intensity. Dropping these control variables, the results

found in earlier study still don‟t change. Detailed result is presented in Appendix D.

From above model changes and tests, we can see that the results found in my

primary study are not changed, indicating the robustness of these results.

55

Table 4. Correlation Matrix

rdint exportr indrdint emp roa da fs owner_p inst_p go logta bgmember divr

rdint 1.000

exportr 0.005 1.000

indrdint 0.167 0.098 1.000

emp 0.013 0.136 -0.006 1.000

roa -0.111 0.011 -0.011 0.030 1.000

da -0.178 0.028 -0.049 0.070 -0.248 1.000

fs -0.094 0.064 -0.017 0.067 0.445 -0.149 1.000

owner_p -0.092 -0.032 -0.064 -0.077 0.187 -0.114 0.133 1.000

inst_p -0.042 0.052 0.085 0.183 0.095 0.107 0.093 -0.054 1.000

go -0.073 0.003 0.023 0.010 0.301 -0.004 0.201 0.046 0.033 1.000

logta -0.156 0.196 -0.106 0.491 0.092 0.194 0.142 -0.038 0.298 0.012 1.000

bgmember -0.078 0.138 -0.067 0.376 0.029 0.159 0.074 0.024 0.186 0.010 0.622 1.000

divr -0.046 0.004 -0.016 0.002 0.314 -0.381 0.232 0.153 0.021 0.132 -0.005 -0.026 1.000

56

Table 5. Panel Regression Results for equation (2) and equation (3)

Dependent variable: Financial slack (fs)

Dependent variable: Leverage ratio (da)

Independent variables Coef. Coef. Controlling ownership

(owner_pt-1) .0306

**

(.0107) -.0308

***

(.0078) Institutional ownership

(inst_pt-1) -.0428

*

(.0183) -.0491

*** (.0134)

Dividend ratio (divrt-1)

.0860 (.1982)

-1.551***

(.1451) Ln(total assets)

(logtat-1) .0121

**

(.0043) .0017

(.0031) ROA

(roat-1) .3093

***

(.0163) -.1446

***

(.0119) Growth Opportunity

(got-1) .0222

***

(.0052) .0189

*** (.0038)

_cons -.1029*

(.0460) .6566

***

(.0336) Obs. 8486 8486 Firm 991 991

F Stat. 2.86***

12.21***

Hausman Stat. 254.83***

171.63***

Model F.E. F.E. R-square 0.0823 0.3124

1. The figures in the parentless are the standard deviations for the coefficients;

2. *** indicates the significance level at 0.1%,** indicates the significance level at 1%,* indicates the significance

level at 5%,+ indicates the significance level at 10%;

3. Year dummies are controlled for above models but not reported in this table.

57

Table 6. Two-Stage estimation and Arellano-Bond dynamic panel-data estimation

Dependent variable: R&D intensity (rdint)

Independent variables Coef.

R&D intensity (rdintt-1)

.4098***

(.0254) R&D intensity

(rdintt-2) -.0473

** (.0152)

Leverage ratio (dat-1)

-.0233***

(.0048) Financial slack

(fst-1) .0068

*

(.0035) Export ratio (exportrt-1)

-.0061+

(.0034) Firm size (empt-1)

-5.27e-07 (7.10e-07)

ROA (roat-1)

.0008 (.0043)

Growth Opportunity (got-1)

.0120***

(.0013)

Affilated (bgmember)

.0021 (.0065)

Industry R&D intensity

(indrdintt-1) -.0072

**

(.0028) Controlling ownership

(owner_pt-1) .1008

**

(.0390) Institutional ownership

(inst_pt-1) -.0525 (.0726)

_cons .0233***

(.0064)

Obs. 5740 Firm 901

Wald stat. 436.08***

Sargan Stat. 491.22***

AR(1) -5.45***

AR(2) .977 1. The figures in the parentless are the standard deviations for the coefficients;

2. *** indicates the significance level at 0.1%,** indicates the significance level at 1%,* indicates the significance

level at 5%,+ indicates the significance level at 10%.

3. Year dummies are controlled for above models but not reported in this table.

58

CHAPTER 5 DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

5.1 Conclusions

Realizing the importance of R&D investments to firm‟s survival and growth, this

paper investigated the determinants of R&D investments in Korean context. Exploiting

simultaneous equation modeling technique, this paper obtained the following conclusions:

(1) Controlling owners have direct impact on firms‟ strategic decisions, and they

promote R&D investments. Apart from this direct effect, controlling owners

tend to maintain high level of financial slack and low level of leverage ratio,

with both financial factors increase R&D investments;

(2) Institutional investors have no direct impact on R&D investment because of

the corporate governance environment where their monitoring power is

limited. However, they have influences on financial slack and leverage ratio.

Contrary to the effect of controlling ownership, institutional ownership is

negatively associated with financial slack and leverage ratio.

5.2 Discussions

While previous studies mainly draw agency theory to investigate the direct

relationships between different types of ownership and R&D investments, this paper tried

to find the different mechanisms about how different types of ownership influence R&D

investments. Mainly based on agency theory, stewardship theory and financial theories

such as pecking order theory, this paper predicted that different types of ownership may

59

not only affect R&D investments directly, but also influence it indirectly through

financial structures such as leverage ratio and financial slack.

Exploiting simultaneous equation modeling, my empirical study has showed that

controlling ownership has direct positive effect on R&D intensity while institutional

ownership has no influence. For the mediation effects, my empirical work showed:

financial slack positively mediates the relationship between controlling ownership and

R&D intensity but negatively mediates the relationship between institutional ownership

and R&D intensity; while leverage ratio both positively mediates the relationship

between controlling ownership and R&D intensity and the relationship between

institutional ownership and R&D intensity. The whole effects of ownership structure on

R&D investments are concluded in Figure 5 and Figure 6.

Consistent with previous studies, this paper found that controlling owners have

impact on firms‟ strategic decisions. As La Porta et al. (1999) and Claessons et al. (2000)

found, there is little separation between control and ownership among firms with

controlling owners in developing countries all around the world. Since controlling owners

both dominate the boards of directors and top management teams, it is reasonable that

they have impact on firm‟s strategic decisions such as R&D investments. Drawing on

agency theory and stewardship theory, this paper predicted that controlling ownership

positively affect R&D intensity, which is also supported by the empirical study.

Previous studies that have been done in the context of US showed the positive

relationship between institutional ownership and R&D intensity. However, this paper

didn‟t find the direct impact of institutional ownership. The different conclusions in

60

Figure 5. The model indicated by empirical study on the direct and indirect

effects of controlling ownership on R&D investments.

Figure 6. The model indicated by empirical study on the direct and indirect

effects of institutional ownership on R&D investments.

-0.0308*** Leverage

ratio

Controlling

Ownership

+0.0306** + 0.1008**

-0.0233***

R&D

Investments +0.0068*

Financial slack

-0.0491***

Leverage

ratio

Institutional

Ownership

-0.0525

-0.0233***

-.0428*

R&D

Investments +0.0068*

Financial slack

61

different contexts can be explained by different corporate governance mechanisms and

law environments. While shareholder protection laws in US and UK require public firms

to publish more information and give shareholders more ways to monitor professional

managers in these firms, shareholders‟ rights are limited in emerging markets. For

example, in Korea, institutional investors were not allowed to exercise voting rights

based on the “shadow voting” before 1997. Although there‟re some improvements after

Korean government reform, Solomon et al. (2002) argued that the culturally embedded

governance system is no easy to change, and doubted that institutional investors still may

not play an active role in monitoring. What‟s more, unlike professional managers,

controlling owners don‟t have job concerns and may not be enslaved to institutional

investors. Thus, institutional investors don‟t have direct influence on R&D investments.

Apart from different owners‟ direct impact on R&D investments, this paper

argued that financial structures such as financial slack and leverage ratio might mediate

the relationship between different types of ownership and R&D intensity. For example,

since controlling owners have large influence on firms‟ behavior, it is straightforward

that they affect firms‟ capital structure and financial slack; while institutional investors

don‟t influence R&D investments directly, they may affect firms‟ dividend policy and

capital structure. While controlling owners tend to maintain firms‟ control and care for

long-term development, institutional investors only care for short-term return. Consistent

with these perspectives, this paper showed that controlling ownership is positively

associated with financial slack and but negatively associated with leverage ratio while

institutional ownership is negatively associated with these financial factors.

62

There have been many empirical studies regarding the influences of these

financial factors on R&D investments. Consistent with these studies, this paper found that

financial slack positively affects R&D intensity while leverage ratio negatively affects it.

Therefore, above findings indicate that financial factors such as financial slack and

leverage ratio that were used to be considered as determinants of R&D investments are

just mediators through which ownership structure affects firm‟s strategic decision

indirectly.

5.3 Limitations

Above conclusions are reached based on an emerging economy, Korea. So these

findings may not be generalized to other contexts. For example, whereas institutional

investors are long-term oriented and promote R&D investments in United States (Hansen

and Hill, 1991), I found that foreign and domestic institutional investors have no impact

in Korea. One explanation for this difference is that controlling owners may not be

enslaved to institutional investor‟ pressures in Korea but professional managers in US

will do.

My sample data only covers manufacturing industry, so above conclusions might

also not be generalized to other industries. For instance, controlling owners are willing to

invest in R&D activities may be only when these R&D activities are essential to their

firms‟ survival and growth. R&D investments is especially important for manufacturing

industry, but not for many other industries. So the different characteristics of different

industries may influence different types of owners‟ orientations and preferences.

63

5.4 Implications

Whereas prior studies treated financial factors such as financial slack and leverage

ratio as important determinants of firm‟s R&D investments, this paper found that they are

only some mediators through which ownership structure affects firm‟s strategy.

Consistent with Williamson (1963)‟s view that ownership structure is the basis of

corporate governance, ownership structure is the ultimate and most important factor that

causes firm heterogeneity within an industry.

In Korean context where legal protection of outsider investors is weak and rights

of them are limited, to large extent firm‟s strategic decisions reflect its controlling owners‟

orientation and preferences. The specific governance environment in Korea endows

controlling owners with strong power in determining firms‟ decisions. This governance

setting might have some bad consequences. For example, controlling owners usually

initiate projects that are good for themselves, no matter whether these activities would be

detrimental to other shareholders; my study showed that they promote R&D investments

but whether they overinvest in R&D activities is still not clear. Therefore, this study

emphasizes the importance of improving the corporate governance mechanisms and

environment in emerging markets, including improving legal protection of outside

shareholders and debt holders, developing capital market and takeover market and so on.

Only when corporate governance mechanisms and environment give balance the powers

among all the stakeholders (i.e. controlling owners, institutional investors, minority

shareholders, managers, debtholders) can impel controlling owners make appropriate

strategic decisions.

64

APPENDIX A

Delete observations where R&D intensity is above its mean three standard deviations

Table 7. Panel Regression Results for equation (2) and equation (3)

Dependent variable: Financial slack (fs)

Dependent variable: Leverage ratio (da)

Independent variables Coef. Coef. Controlling ownership

(owner_pt-1) .0208

*

(.0092) -.0310

***

(.0077) Institutional ownership

(inst_pt-1) -.0311

+

(.0168) -.0474

*** (.0133)

Dividend ratio (divrt-1)

.5638***

(.1714)

-1.4668***

(.1445) Ln(total assets)

(logtat-1) .0140

***

(.0019) .0069

*

(.0033) ROA

(roat-1) .3849

***

(.0152) -.1477

***

(.0122) Growth Opportunity

(got-1) .0216

***

(.0051) .0235

*** (.0040)

_cons -.1315***

(.0216)

.6013***

(.0348)

Obs. 8237 8237 Firm 982 982

F Stat. 2.60***

12.33 ***

Hausman Stat. 228.98***

173.91***

Model F.E. F.E. R-square 0.0803 0.3220

1. The figures in the parentless are the standard deviations for the coefficients;

2. *** indicates the significance level at 0.1%,** indicates the significance level at 1%,* indicates the significance

level at 5%,+ indicates the significance level at 10%;

3. Year dummies are controlled for above models but not reported in this table.

65

Table 8. Two-Stage estimation and Arellano-Bond dynamic panel-data estimation

Dependent variable: R&D intensity (rdint)

Independent variables Coef.

R&D intensity (rdintt-1)

.1308 (.0878)

R&D intensity (rdintt-2)

.0002 (.0017)

Leverage ratio (dat-1)

-.0091***

(.0032) Financial slack

(fst-1) -.0007 (.0027)

Export ratio (exportrt-1)

.0008 (.0020)

Firm size (empt-1)

-2.60e-07 (5.20e-07)

ROA (roat-1)

.0006 (.0036)

Growth Opportunity (got-1)

.0015 (.0012)

Affilated (bgmember)

.0012 (.0015)

Industry R&D intensity

(indrdintt-1) .0002

(.0017) Controlling ownership

(owner_pt-1) .0450

*

(.0178) Institutional ownership

(inst_pt-1) -.0523 (.0367)

_cons .0175***

(.0043)

Obs. 5523 Firm 878

Wald stat. 83.97***

Sargan Stat. 463.01***

AR(1) -3.81***

AR(2) .287 1. The figures in the parentless are the standard deviations for the coefficients;

2. *** indicates the significance level at 0.1%,** indicates the significance level at 1%,* indicates the significance

level at 5%,+ indicates the significance level at 10%.

3. Year dummies are controlled for above models but not reported in this table.

66

APPENDIX B

Control for the effect of institutional change

Table 9. Panel Regression Results for equation (2) and equation (3)

Dependent variable: Financial slack (fs)

Dependent variable: Leverage ratio (da)

Independent variables Coef. Coef. Controlling ownership

(owner_pt-1) .0429

***

(.0122) -.0283

***

(.0085) Institutional ownership

(inst_pt-1) -.0572

**

(.0210) -.0268

+ (.0146)

Dividend ratio (divrt-1)

-.0202 (.2156)

-1.168***

(.1503) Ln(total assets)

(logtat-1) .0159

**

(.0051) .0052

(.0036) ROA

(roat-1) .2938

***

(.0172) -.1263

***

(.0120) Growth Opportunity

(got-1) .0226

***

(.0055) .0176

*** (.0038)

_cons -.1038+

(.0541) .4912

***

(.0377) Obs. 7539 7539 Firm 991 991

F Stat. 2.60***

12.50***

Hausman Stat. 47.96***

173.91***

Model F.E. F.E. R-square 0.0824 0.1155

1. The figures in the parentless are the standard deviations for the coefficients;

2. *** indicates the significance level at 0.1%,** indicates the significance level at 1%,* indicates the significance

level at 5%,+ indicates the significance level at 10%;

3. Year dummies are controlled for above models but not reported in this table.

67

Table 10. Two-Stage estimation and Arellano-Bond dynamic panel-data estimation

Dependent variable: R&D intensity (rdint)

Independent variables Coef.

R&D intensity (rdintt-1)

.4928***

(.0301) R&D intensity

(rdintt-2) -.0327

+ (.0173)

Leverage ratio (dat-1)

-.0270***

(.0055) Financial slack

(fst-1) .0080

*

(.0048) Export ratio (exportrt-1)

-.0039 (.0042)

Firm size (empt-1)

-1.26e-06 (9.50e-07)

ROA (roat-1)

-.00002 (.0050)

Growth Opportunity (got-1)

.0135***

(.0016)

Affilated (bgmember)

.0035 (.0091)

Industry R&D intensity

(indrdintt-1) -.0134

***

(.0037) Controlling ownership

(owner_pt-1) .1553

*

(.0659) Institutional ownership

(inst_pt-1) -.1628 (.1344)

_cons .0088 (.0068)

Obs. 4659 Firm 900

Wald stat. 385.87***

Sargan Stat. 247.36***

AR(1) -5.16***

AR(2) 1.14 1. The figures in the parentless are the standard deviations for the coefficients;

2. *** indicates the significance level at 0.1%,** indicates the significance level at 1%,* indicates the significance

level at 5%,+ indicates the significance level at 10%.

3. Year dummies are controlled for above models but not reported in this table.

68

APPENDIX C

Different measure of firm size

Table 11. Two-Stage estimation and Arellano-Bond dynamic panel-data estimation

Dependent variable: R&D intensity (rdint)

Independent variables Coef.

R&D intensity (rdintt-1)

.4124***

(.0254)

R&D intensity (rdintt-2)

-.0458**

(.0153)

Leverage ratio (dat-1)

-.0198**

(.0067) Financial slack

(fst-1) .0059

+

(.0037) Export ratio (exportrt-1)

-.0060+

(.0034) Firm size (logtat-1)

-.0068 (.0052)

ROA (roat-1)

.0062 (.0068)

Growth Opportunity (got-1)

.0120***

(.0013)

Affilated (bgmember)

.0022 (.0065)

Industry R&D intensity

(indrdintt-1) -.0075

**

(.0028) Controlling ownership

(owner_pt-1) .1268

**

(.0451) Institutional ownership

(inst_pt-1) .0561

(.1013) _cons .0807

+

(.0436) Obs. 5740 Firm 901

Wald stat. 438.52***

Sargan Stat. 487.13***

AR(1) -5.457***

AR(2) 1.00 1. The figures in the parentless are the standard deviations for the coefficients;

2. *** indicates the significance level at 0.1%,** indicates the significance level at 1%,* indicates the significance

level at 5%,+ indicates the significance level at 10%.

3. Year dummies are controlled for above models but not reported in this table.

69

APPENDIX D

Drop insignificant control variables

Table 12. Two-Stage estimation and Arellano-Bond dynamic panel-data estimation

Dependent variable: R&D intensity (rdint)

Independent variables Coef.

R&D intensity (rdintt-1)

.3963***

(.0199) R&D intensity

(rdintt-2) -.0182 (.0125)

Leverage ratio (dat-1)

-.0267***

(.0038) Financial slack

(fst-1) .0064

*

(.0031) Export ratio (exportrt-1)

-.0062*

(.0028) Growth Opportunity

(got-1) .0100

***

(.0011) Industry R&D intensity

(indrdintt-1) -.0072

**

(.0025) Controlling ownership

(owner_pt-1) .0616

*

(.0296) Institutional ownership

(inst_pt-1) -.0101 (.0581)

_cons .0279 (.0048)

Obs. 7072 Firm 960

Wald stat. 566.19***

Sargan Stat. 458.20***

AR(1) -6.38***

AR(2) .854 1. The figures in the parentless are the standard deviations for the coefficients;

2. *** indicates the significance level at 0.1%,** indicates the significance level at 1%,* indicates the significance

level at 5%,+ indicates the significance level at 10%.

3. Year dummies are controlled for above models but not reported in this table.

70

REFERENCES

Amihud, Y., & Lev, B. (1981). Risk Reduction as a Managerial Motive for Conglomerate

Mergers. The Bell Journal of Economics, 12(2), 605-617.

Aboody, D. and Lev, B. 2000. Information asymmetry, R&D and insider gains. The

Journal of Finance, 55: 2747-2766.

Anderson, R. C., & Reeb, D. M. (2003). Founding-Family Ownership and Firm

Performance: Evidence from the S&P 500. The Journal of Finance, 58(3), 1301-

1328.

Anderson, R. C., Mansi, S. A., & Reeb, D. M. (2003). Founding family ownership and

the agency cost of debt. Journal of Financial Economics, 68(2), 263-285.

Andrade, G., & Kaplan, S. N. (1998). How Costly Is Financial (Not Economic) Distress?

Evidence from Highly Leveraged Transactions That Became Distressed. The

Journal of Finance, 53(5), 1443-1493.

Arellano, M. 2003. Panel Data Econometrics. Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK.

71

Arellano, M., S.R. Bond. 1991. Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo

evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic

Studies, 58, 277-297.

Alby L., Auerbach R. (1984). Differential adhesion of tumor cells to capillary endothelial

cells in vitro. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, USA, 81: 5739–

5743

Rahim, B., & Pascal, D. (2001). R&D Intensity and Corporate Financial Policy: Some

International Evidence. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 28(5-6), 671-

692.

Bathala, C. T., Moon, K. P., & Rao, R. P. (1994). Managerial Ownership, Debt Policy,

and the Impact of Institutional Holdings: An Agency Perspective. Financial

Management, 23(3), 38-50.

Baltagi, B.H. 2005. Econometric Analysis of Panel Data, Third edition. Wiley,

Chichester.

Bathala, C. T., Moon, K. P., & Rao, R. P. (1994). Managerial Ownership, Debt Policy,

and the Impact of Institutional Holdings: An Agency Perspective. Financial

Management, 23(3), 38-50.

72

Baysinger, B., & Hoskisson, R. E. (1990). The Composition of Boards of Directors and

Strategic Control: Effects on Corporate Strategy. The Academy of Management

Review, 15(1), 72-87.

Baysinger, B. D., Kosnik, R. D., & Turk, T. A. (1991). Effects of Board and Ownership

Structure on Corporate R&D Strategy. The Academy of Management Journal,

34(1), 205-214.

Ben-Zion U. 1984. The R&D and investment decision and its relationship to the firm‟s

market value: Some preliminary results. In Z.Griliches, R&D, patents and

productivity, NBER, The University of Chicago Press, 299-312.

Becker, B., & Pain, N. What Determines Industrial R&D Expenditure in the UK?

Manchester School, Vol. 76, Issue 1, pp. 66-87, January 2008.

Bhagat, S., & Welch, I. (1995). Corporate research & development investments

international comparisons. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 19(2-3), 443-

470.

Bhattacharya, S., & Ritter, J. R. (1983). Innovation and Communication: Signalling with

Partial Disclosure. The Review of Economic Studies, 50(2), 331-346.

73

Bhojraj, S., & Sengupta, P. (2003). Effect of Corporate Governance on Bond Ratings and

Yields: The Role of Institutional Investors and outside Directors. The Journal of

Business, 76(3), 455-475.

Block, J. H., & Thams, A. (2008). Long-Term Orientation in Family Firms: A Bayesian

Analysis of R&D Spending. SSRN eLibrary.

Blundell, R., Griffith, R. & Van Reenen J. 1999. Market share, market value and

innovation in a panel of British manufacturing firms. Review of Economic Studies,

66: 529-554.

Bourgeois, L.J., & Singh, J. V. 1983. Organizational slack and political behavior within

top management groups. Academy of Management Proceedings: 43-49.

Bourgeois, L. J., III (1981). On the Measurement of Organizational Slack. The Academy

of Management Review, 6(1), 29-39.

Brailsford, Timothy J., Oliver, Barry R. and Pua, Lay Hwa Sandra, On the Relation

Between Ownership Structure and Capital Structure. Accounting and Finance,

Vol. 42, pp. 1-26, 2002.

Brennan MJ, Tamarowski C. 2000. Investor relations, liquidity, and stock prices. Journal

of Applied Corporate Finance, 12(4): 26–37.

74

Bubolz, M. M. (2001). Family as source, user, and builder of social capital. Journal of

Socio-Economics, 30(2), 129-131.

Burkart, M., Panunzi, F., & Shleifer, A. (2003). Family Firms. The Journal of Finance,

58(5), 2167-2201.

Business Week, 2006. The world's most innovative companies. 24 April.

Casson, M. (1999). The Economics of the family firm. Scandinavian Economic History

Review, 47, 10-23.

Chaganti, R., & Damanpour, F. (1991). Institutional Ownership, Capital Structure, and

Firm Performance. Strategic Management Journal, 12(7), 479-491.

Chan, H.W.H., Faff, R.W., Gharghori, P. and Ho, Y.K. 2007. The relation between R&D

intensity and future market returns: does expensing versus capitalization matter?

Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 29: 25–51.

Chan, S.H., Martin, J.D. and Kensenger, j.w. 1990. Corporate research & development

expenditures and share value. Journal of Financial Economics, 26: 255-276.

Chang, S.J., J. Hong. 2002. How much does the business group matter in Korea?

Strategic Management J. 23: 265 – 274.

75

Child, J. (1972). Organizational structure, environment and performance: The role of

strategic choice. Sociology, 6: 1-22.

Choe, H., Kho, B.-C., & Stulz, R. M. (1999). Do foreign investors destabilize stock

markets? The Korean experience in 1997. Journal of Financial Economics, 54(2),

227-264.

Choi Y. R., T. Yoshikawa, Zahra S. A. and Han B. H., 2008. The Effects of Institutional

Change on Efficient R&D Investments among Korean Technology Firms: Do

Business Groups Maintain Advantage? Working paper.

Claessens, S., Djankov, S., & Lang, L. H. P. (2000). The separation of ownership and

control in East Asian Corporations. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1-2), 81-

112.

Claessens, S., Simeon, D., Fan, J. P. H., & Lang, L. H. P. (2002). Disentangling the

Incentive and Entrenchment Effects of Large Shareholdings. The Journal of

Finance, 57(6), 2741-2771.

Cannolly, R. A. & Hirschey, M. 2005. Firm size and the effect of R&D on Tobin‟s q.

R&D Management, 35: 217-223.

76

Cronqvist, H., & Nilsson, M. (2003). Agency Costs of Controlling Minority Shareholders.

The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 38(4), 695-719.

Crutchley, C. E., & Hansen, R. S. (1989). A Test of the Agency Theory of Managerial

Ownership, Corporate Leverage, and Corporate Dividends. Financial

Management, 18(4), 36-46.

Cyert, Richard M., and James G. March. 1963. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm.

Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.

David, M., & Laurie, M. (2008). Exploring the debate on short-termism: a theoretical and

empirical analysis. Strategic Management Journal, 29(3), 273-292.

David, P., Hitt, M. A., & Gimeno, J. (2001). The Influence of Activism by Institutional

Investors on R&D. The Academy of Management Journal, 44(1), 144-157.

David, P., T. Yoshikawa, M.D.R. Chari, A.A. Rasheed (2006). Strategic investments in

Japanese corporations: Do foreign portfolio owners foster underinvestment or

appropriate investment? . Strategic Management Journal, 27, 591-600.

Davis, E.P. and Steil, B. (2001), Institutional Investors, MIT Press.

77

Davis, J. H., Schoorman, F. D., & Donaldson, L. (1997). Toward a Stewardship Theory

of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 22(1), 20-47.

DeAngelo, H., & DeAngelo, L. (1985). Managerial ownership of voting rights : A study

of public corporations with dual classes of common stock. Journal of Financial

Economics, 14(1), 33-69.

Douma, S., George, R., & Kabir, R. (2006). Foreign and domestic ownership, business

groups, and firm performance: evidence from a large emerging market. Strategic

Management Journal, 27(7), 637-657.

Drucker, P. F. (1986). The Changed World Economy. Foreign Affairs, 64(4), 768-791.

Easterbrook, F. H. (1984). Two Agency-Cost Explanations of Dividends. The American

Economic Review, 74(4), 650-659.

Eddleston, K. A., & Kellermanns, F. W. (2007). Destructive and productive family

relationships: A stewardship theory perspective. Journal of Business Venturing,

22(4), 545-565.

Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). Making Fast Strategic Decisions in High-Velocity

Environments. The Academy of Management Journal, 32(3), 543-576.

78

Espen Eckbo, B., & Verma, S. (1994). Managerial shareownership, voting power, and

cash dividend policy. Journal of Corporate Finance, 1(1), 33-62.

Ettlie, J. E. (1998). R&D and Global Manufacturing Performance. Management Science,

44(1), 1-11.

Faccio, M., Lang, Larry H.P., Young, Leslie (2001). Debt and corporate governance.

Working paper.Notre Dame and The Chinese Univ. of Hong Kong.

Faccio, M., & Lang, L. H. P. (2002). The ultimate ownership of Western European

corporations. Journal of Financial Economics, 65(3), 365-395.

Fama, E. F., & Jensen, M. C. (1983). Separation of Ownership and Control. Journal of

Law and Economics, 26(2), 301-325.

Fortune. 1993. What activist investors want. March 8: 59-63.

Franko, L. G. (1989). Global Corporate Competition: Who's Winning, Who's Losing, and

the R&D Factor as One Reason Why. Strategic Management Journal, 10(5), 449-

474.

Friend, I., & Lang, L. H. P. (1988). An Empirical Test of the Impact of Managerial Self-

Interest on Corporate Capital Structure. The Journal of Finance, 43(2), 271-281.

79

Froot, K., Andre Perold, and Jeremy Stein (1992). Shareholder trading practices and

corporate investment horizons. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 6, 42-58.

George, Gerard. (2005). Slack Resources and the Performance of Privately Held Firms.

Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 48.

Gibson R, and Kraakman R. (1991). Reinventing the Outside Director: An Agenda for

Institutional Investors‟. Stanford Law Review, 43:863.

Graves, S. B. (1988). Institutional Ownership and Corporate R&D in the Computer

Industry. The Academy of Management Journal, 31(2), 417-428.

Greve, H. R. (2003). A Behavioral Theory of R&D Expenditures and Innovations:

Evidence from Shipbuilding. The Academy of Management Journal, 46(6), 685-

702.

Grinstein, Y., & Michaely, R. (2005). Institutional Holdings and Payout Policy. The

Journal of Finance, 60(3), 1389-1426.

Grossman, S. J., & Hart, O. D. (1980). Takeover Bids, The Free-Rider Problem, and the

Theory of the Corporation. The Bell Journal of Economics, 11(1), 42-64.

80

Guellec, D. and Van-Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. (2001). R&D and Productivity

Growth: Panel Data Analysis of 16 OECD Countries. OECD Economic Studies,

Vol. 33, pp. 103–127.

Hall, Bronwyn H. (1998). Innovation and Market Value. NBER Working Paper Series.

Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=226407

Hall, B. H. (2002). The Financing of Research and Development. Oxford Review of

Economic Policy, Vol. 18, pp. 35–51.

Hambrick, D. C., & Mason, P. A. (1984). Upper Echelons: The Organization as a

Reflection of Its Top Managers. The Academy of Management Review, 9(2), 193-

206.

Hansen, G. S., & Hill, C. W. L. (1991). Are Institutional Investors Myopic? A Time-

Series Study of Four Technology- Driven Industries. Strategic Management

Journal, 12(1), 1-16.

Hill, C. W. L., & Snell, S. A. (1988). External Control, Corporate Strategy, and Firm

Performance in Research- Intensive Industries. Strategic Management Journal,

9(6), 577-590.

81

Holmstrom, B. (1989). Agency costs and innovation. Journal of Economic Behavior &

Organization, 12(3), 305-327.

Hong, S. and Lee, J. (1998). Institutional Investors to be Granted Voting Rights,

Joongang IIbo, Februray.

Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A., Johnson, R. A., & Moesel, D. D. (1993). Construct

Validity of an Objective (Entropy) Categorical Measure of Diversification

Strategy. Strategic Management Journal, 14(3), 215-235.

Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A., Johnson, R. A., & Grossman, W. (2002). Conflicting

Voices: The Effects of Institutional Ownership Heterogeneity and Internal

Governance on Corporate Innovation Strategies. The Academy of Management

Journal, 45(4), 697-716.

Hu, Y., Wang, D. D., & Zhang, S. (2007). Founding Family Ownership, Management

and Payout Policy. SSRN eLibrary.

Jarrell, G.A., Lehn, K., & Marr, W. (1985). Institutional ownership, tender offers and

long-term investments. Working paper, Office of the Chief Economist, Securities

and Exchange Commission, Washington, DC.

82

G. A. Jarrell et al. (1985). Institutional ownership, tender offers, and long-term

investments. Photocopied, Office of the Chief Economist, Securities and

Exchange Commission, Washington, DC.

Jensen, M. C. (1986). Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and

Takeovers. The American Economic Review, 76(2), 323-329.

Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior,

Agency Costs and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4),

305-360.

Jensen, G. R., Solberg, D. P., & Zorn, T. S. (1992). Simultaneous Determination of

Insider Ownership, Debt, and Dividend Policies. The Journal of Financial and

Quantitative Analysis, 27(2), 247-263.

Joh, S. W. (2003). Corporate governance and firm profitability: evidence from Korea

before the economic crisis. Journal of Financial Economics, 68(2), 287-322.

Jordan, J., J. Lowe and P. Taylor. (1998). Strategy and Financial Policy in U.K. Small

Firms. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 25(1), 1–27.

Jung, K., & Kwon, S. Y. (2002). Ownership structure and earnings informativeness:

Evidence from Korea. The International Journal of Accounting, 37(3), 301-325.

83

Khanna, T., & Yafeh, Y. (2007). Business Groups in Emerging Markets: Paragons or

Parasites? Journal of Economic Literature, 45(2), 331-372.

Khorana, A. (1996). Top management turnover an empirical investigation of mutual fund

managers. Journal of Financial Economics, 40(3), 403-427.

Kim, H., Kim, H., & Lee, P. M. (2008). Ownership Structure and the Relationship

Between Financial Slack and R&D Investments: Evidence from Korean Firms.

ORGANIZATION SCIENCE, 19(3), 404-418.

King, M. R., & Santor, E. (2008). Family values: Ownership structure, performance and

capital structure of Canadian firms. Journal of Banking & Finance, 32(11), 2423-

2432.

Kor, Y. Y. (2006). Direct and interaction effects of top management team and board

compositions on R&D investment strategy. Strategic Management Journal,

27(11), 1081-1099.

Kouki, M., & Guizani, M. (2009). Ownership Structure and Dividend Policy Evidence

from the Tunisian Stock Market. European Journal of Scientific Research, 25(1),

pp.42-53.

84

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1999). The quality of

government. J Law Econ Organ, 15(1), 222-279.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (2000). Investor protection

and corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1-2), 3-27.

Laverty, K. J. (1996). Economic "Short-Termism": The Debate, the Unresolved Issues,

and the Implications for Management Practice and Research. The Academy of

Management Review, 21(3), 825-860.

Lee, P. M., & O'Neill, H. M. (2003). Ownership Structures and R&D Investments of U.S.

and Japanese Firms: Agency and Stewardship Perspectives. The Academy of

Management Journal, 46(2), 212-225.

Leland, H. E., & Pyle, D. H. (1977). Informational Asymmetries, Financial Structure, and

Financial Intermediation. The Journal of Finance, 32(2), 371-387.

Lippman, S. A., & Rumelt, R. P. (1982). Uncertain Imitability: An Analysis of Interfirm

Differences in Efficiency under Competition. The Bell Journal of Economics,

13(2), 418-438.

Litschert, R. J., & Bonham, T. W. (1978). A Conceptual Model of Strategy Formation.

The Academy of Management Review, 3(2), 211-219.

85

Long, W. F., & Ravenscraft, D. J. (1993). LBOs, Debt and R&D Intensity. Strategic

Management Journal, 14, 119-135.

Lotta Vänänen. (2003). Agency costs and R&D: Evidence From Finnish SMEs.

Keskusteluaiheita—Discussion papers No.859.

Lucas, R. E. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary

Economics, 22(1), 3-42.

McConnell, J., and H. Servaes. (1990). Additional Evidence on Equity Ownership and

Corporate Value. Journal of Financial Economics, 27: 595-613.

Mezghanni, B.S. (2009). R&D INVESTMENT AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: THE

MODERATING EFFECTS OF OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE AND BOARD OF

DIRECTORS. Working Paper, www.affi2009-brest.com

Miller, D., & Le Breton-Miller, I. (2006). Family Governance and Firm Performance:

Agency, Stewardship, and Capabilities. Family Business Review, 19(1), 73-87.

Miller, D., Le Breton-Miller, I., & Scholnick, B. (2008). Stewardship vs. Stagnation: An

Empirical Comparison of Small Family and Non-Family Businesses. Journal of

Management Studies, 45(1), 51-78.

86

Mishra, C. S., & McConaughy, D. L. (Writer) (1999). Founding Family Control and

Capital Structure: The Risk of Loss of Control and the Aversion to Debt [Article],

Entrepreneurship: Theory & Practice: Blackwell Publishing Limited.

Mitroff, Ian I. (1987). Business not as usual. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.

Modigliani, F., & Merton, H. M. (1958). The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and

the Theory of Investment. The American Economic Review, 48(3), 261-297.

Morck, R., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1988). Management ownership and market

valuation: An empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 20, 293-315.

Mosakowski, E. (1993). A Resource-Based Perspective on the Dynamic Strategy-

Performance Relationship: An Empirical Examination of the Focus and

Differentiation Strategies in Entrepreneurial Firms. Journal of Management, 19(4),

819-839.

Myers, S. C. and N. Majluf, (1984). Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions

When Firms Have Information That Investors Do Not Have. Journal of Financial

Economics, vol. 13, pp. 187-221.

Myers, S. C. (1984). The Capital Structure Puzzle. The Journal of Finance, 39(3), 575-

592.

87

Nohria, N., & Gulati, R. (1996). Is Slack Good or Bad for Innovation? The Academy of

Management Journal, 39(5), 1245-1264.

O'Brien, J. P. (2003). The Capital Structure Implications of Pursuing a Strategy of

Innovation. Strategic Management Journal, 24(5), 415-431.

OECD Factbook 2008: Economic, Environmental and Social Statistics

Peyer, U. C., & Shivdasani, A. (2001). Leverage and internal capital markets: evidence

from leveraged recapitalizations. Journal of Financial Economics, 59(3), 477-515.

Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous Technological Change. The Journal of Political

Economy, 98(5), S71-S102.

Rozeff, M. S. (Writer) (1982). Growth, beta and agency costs as determinants of dividend

payout ratios. Journal of Financial Research: Blackwell Publishing Limited.

Rumelt, R., Schendel, D. and Teece, D. (1994). Fundamental Issues in Strategy: A

Research Agenda. Harvard Business School Press: Boston.

SCHERER, F.M. (1967). Research and Development Resource Allocation under Rivalry.

Quart. J. Econ., 81(3): 359-94.

88

Sharfman, M. P., Wolf, G., Chase, R. B., & Tansik, D. A. (1988). Antecedents of

Organizational Slack. The Academy of Management Review, 13(4), 601-614.

Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). A Survey of Corporate Governance. The Journal of

Finance, 52(2), 737-783.

Short, H., Zhang, H. and Keasey, K. (2002). The link between dividend policy and

institutional ownership. Journal of Corporate Finance, vol. 8(2), pp. 105–22

Singh, J. V. (1986). Performance, Slack, and Risk Taking in Organizational Decision

Making. The Academy of Management Journal, 29(3), 562-585.

Singh, M., & Faircloth, S. (Writer) (2005). The impact of corporate debt on long term

investment and firm performance [Article], Applied Economics: Routledge.

Solomon, J., Solomon, A., & Park, C.-Y. (2002). The Evolving Role of Institutional

Investors in South Korean Corporate Governance: Some Empirical Evidence.

SSRN eLibrary, 10, 211-224.

Stein, J. C. (1988). Takeover Threats and Managerial Myopia. The Journal of Political

Economy, 96(1), 61-80.

89

Bebchuk, L., Reinier, K., and George Triantis. (2000). "Stock Pyramids, Cross-

Ownership, and Dual Class Equity: The Creation and Agency Costs of Separating

Control from Cash Flow Rights." in Concentrated Corporate Ownership, edited

by Randall Morck, University of Chicago Press.

Villalonga, B., & Amit, R. (2006). How do family ownership, control and management

affect firm value? Journal of Financial Economics, 80(2), 385-417.

Whited, T. M. (1992). Debt, Liquidity Constraints, and Corporate Investment: Evidence

from Panel Data. The Journal of Finance, 47(4), 1425-1460.

Williamson, O. E. (1963). Managerial Discretion and Business Behavior. The American

Economic Review, 53(5), 1032-1057.

Williamson, Oliver. (1964). The Economics of Discretionary Behavior: Managerial

Objectives in a Theory of the Firm. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, N.J.

Oliver E. Williamson. (1988). The logic of economic organization. Journal of Law,

Economics, and Organization, 4: 65-93.

Wiwattanakantang, Y. (2001). Controlling shareholders and corporate value: Evidence

from Thailand. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 9(4), 323-362.

90

Woolridge, J. R. (1988). COMPETITIVE DECLINE AND CORPORATE

RESTRUCTURING: IS A MYOPIC STOCK MARKET To BLAME? Journal of

Applied Corporate Finance, 1(1), 26-36.

Yeh, Yin-Hua. (2005). Do Controlling Shareholders Enhance Corporate Value?

Corporate Governance: An International Review, Vol. 13, No. 2, pp. 313-325.

Young, M. N., Peng, M. W., Ahlstrom, D., Bruton, G. D., & Jiang, Y. (2008). Corporate

Governance in Emerging Economies: A Review of the Principal-Principal

Perspective. Journal of Management Studies, 45(1), 196-220.

Zahra, S. A., Hayton, J. C., Neubaum, D. O., Dibrell, C., & Craig, J. (2008). Culture of

Family Commitment and Strategic Flexibility: The Moderating Effect of

Stewardship. Entrepreneurship: Theory & Practice, 32(6), 1035-1054

Zajac, E. J., Golden, B. R., & Shortell, S. M. (1991). New organizational forms for

enhancing innovation: The case of internal corporate joint ventures.

Management Science, 37: 170- 184.